34
Negative Advertising and Political Competition * Amit Gandhi University of Wisconsin-Madison Daniela Iorio UAB, MOVE and Barcelona GSE Carly Urban University of Wisconsin-Madison October 2011 Abstract Why is negative advertising such a prominent feature of competition in the political market? We propose an explanation that is based on the “fewness” of competitors in a political race. The typical election in the United States is a two-candidate race. In such duopoly contests, there is a simple economic rationale for “going negative” relative to non- duopoly contests: when the number of competitors is greater than two, engaging in negative ads creates positive externalities for opponents that are not the object of the attack. In contrast, positive ads benefit only the advertiser. To empirically investigate the hypothesis that the number of competitors can explain the volume of negative advertising in an election, we focus on US non-presidential primary contests in 2004, where the nature of primaries provides us with a cross section of independent races and large variation in the number of entrants. Our estimation employs novel data from the Wisconsin Advertising Project, which contains information on all political advertisements aired in the top 100 media markets in 2004 races. We find that duopolies are twice as likely to air a negative ad when compared to non-duopolies, and that doubling the number of competitors drives the rate of negative advertising in an election close to zero. These results are robust to the inclusion of a variety of controls and instruments for entrants in the race. * We thank Andrea Mattozzi, Riccardo Puglisi, Karl Scholz, Erik Snowberg, Chris Taber, and seminar par- ticipants at University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1st IGIER Political Economy Workshop and 2nd Petralia Sottana Workshop for helpful comments and discussions. We owe a special thanks to Ken Goldstein who helped pro- vide the data and offered much useful discussion about political primaries. Daniela Iorio acknowledges financial support from SEJ2006-00712, ECO2009-07616ECON, the Barcelona GSE and the Government of Catalonia.

Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Negative Advertising and Political Competition∗

Amit Gandhi

University of Wisconsin-Madison

Daniela Iorio

UAB, MOVE and Barcelona GSE

Carly Urban

University of Wisconsin-Madison

October 2011

Abstract

Why is negative advertising such a prominent feature of competition in the political

market? We propose an explanation that is based on the “fewness” of competitors in a

political race. The typical election in the United States is a two-candidate race. In such

duopoly contests, there is a simple economic rationale for “going negative” relative to non-

duopoly contests: when the number of competitors is greater than two, engaging in negative

ads creates positive externalities for opponents that are not the object of the attack. In

contrast, positive ads benefit only the advertiser. To empirically investigate the hypothesis

that the number of competitors can explain the volume of negative advertising in an election,

we focus on US non-presidential primary contests in 2004, where the nature of primaries

provides us with a cross section of independent races and large variation in the number of

entrants. Our estimation employs novel data from the Wisconsin Advertising Project, which

contains information on all political advertisements aired in the top 100 media markets in

2004 races. We find that duopolies are twice as likely to air a negative ad when compared

to non-duopolies, and that doubling the number of competitors drives the rate of negative

advertising in an election close to zero. These results are robust to the inclusion of a variety

of controls and instruments for entrants in the race.

∗We thank Andrea Mattozzi, Riccardo Puglisi, Karl Scholz, Erik Snowberg, Chris Taber, and seminar par-ticipants at University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1st IGIER Political Economy Workshop and 2nd Petralia SottanaWorkshop for helpful comments and discussions. We owe a special thanks to Ken Goldstein who helped pro-vide the data and offered much useful discussion about political primaries. Daniela Iorio acknowledges financialsupport from SEJ2006-00712, ECO2009-07616ECON, the Barcelona GSE and the Government of Catalonia.

Page 2: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

1 Introduction

Political competition has long been famous for using negative portrayals of one’s opponent

as a strategic weapon. Indeed negative advertising, or “mudslinging” as it is sometimes called, is

usually considered par for the course in any political contest. What is more alarming is the sheer

amount spent on negative advertising. For example, Senator John Kerry and President George

Bush together spent $522 million in the 2004 presidential campaign, with over $365 million (or

69.9 percent) of this amount being spent on negative advertising.1 In the 2009-2010 election cycle

(the November 2010 electoral contests for state and federal offices), a media analysis company

has reported that 80 percent of advertisements have been negative (NPR 2010).

The widespread presence of negative advertising in the political market has been a serious

concern to policymakers and commentators alike. Critics have long bemoaned negative advertis-

ing as harmful to the health of a democracy. This perspective is consistent with the conclusions

of a strand of studies (see e.g., Crotty and Jacobson (1980), Cappella and Jamieson (1997),

Ansolabehere and Iyengar (1995)) that find negativity alienates the political middle and harms

participation. The fear that negative ads turn off voters has prompted policymakers in recent

times to regulate its usage. One such well known piece of legislation is the “Stand By Your

Ad” provision of the Bipartisan Campaign Reform Act in 2002, which requires each candidate

to provide a statement identifying himself and his approval of the communication. By forcing

candidates to personally associate themselves with their campaign message, the belief is that

candidates will be less inclined to air attack ads.

What is missing from the debate about negative advertising in politics is a clear understand-

ing of why negative advertising is such a central feature of political competition. That is, while

there has been much interest in both the political science and economics literature as to the

consequences of campaigning for election outcomes, virtually no empirical attention has been

devoted to the supply side incentives to produce negativity. If negative advertising is the norm in

political competition, why is it not the norm in the marketing of non-political consumer goods?

What is it about the nature of political competition, especially in the United States, that lends

itself towards “going negative”?

In this paper we hypothesize that an important part of the explanation lies in a unique

feature of the structure of political markets. In particular, the two-party system effectively gives

rise to duopoly competition between political candidates in a general election, whereas pure

duopolies are rarely observed in the consumer product market.2 We conjecture that there is a

clear economic rationale for why duopolies are more likely to “go negative”: when the number

of competitors is greater than two, engaging in negative ads creates positive externalities to

those opponents that are not the object of the attack. In contrast, positive ads benefit only the

1Calculation based on WiscAds 2004 presidential data (Goldstein and Rivlin 2007b)2While a number of industries might feature two dominant firms, even in these cases there will typically be a

group of firms with smaller market share that impact the behavior of the dominant firms.

1

Page 3: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

advertiser. Therefore, the presence of a spillover effect makes it less beneficial to use negative

advertising when you face more than one opponent. Moreover the benefit of negative advertising

is decreasing in the number of opponents you face (since the spillover to another candidate is more

likely when there are more substitutes available). This link between the incentives to produce

negative advertising and duopolistic market structures does not appear to have been previously

recognized or explored in either the industrial organization or political economy literature.

Our economic explanation for negative advertising seems to accord with a familiar armchair

observation - for the most obvious cases where a consumer product market also looks like a

duopoly, there exist some very well known negative advertising campaigns (Apple versus Mi-

crosoft and Verizon versus AT&T). However, there could be other confounding factors that

contribute to explain the larger use of negative ads in politics when compared to everyday prod-

uct markets. For example, political markets are “winner take all markets” where it is winning a

plurality of votes rather than the absolute market share that matters, and hence the convexity

of the objective function could partly fuel the incentive to go negative. Furthermore, the time

horizon is different: whereas firms repeatedly interact without a definite end in sight, competi-

tors in a political campaign face a finite horizon that ends with the election day, and hence it

may be harder to cooperate on staying positive. Lastly, whereas the FTC regulates deceptive

advertising by businesses, it does not have any jurisdiction over political ads, perhaps giving

politicians more legal leeway to air attack ads.

How then can we empirically isolate the effect of the number of competitors in a market on

the incentive to go negative? An ideal strategy is to only use data on political races that share

the same institutional features, but have different number of competitors. This strategy however

gives rise to a natural problem: if political markets in the United States are for the most part

characterized by head to head competition between the two major party candidates, how can we

determine the effect of the number of competitors on the propensity for “going negative” when

there is little to no variation in the number of candidates? Our strategy is to instead exploit

the inherent variation in non-presidential primary contests within the United States, i.e., the

contest among Democrats or Republicans that decide who will become the party nominee in

a particular House, Senate, or gubernatorial race. The local nature of these primary contests

provides us with a cross section of independent races that exhibit a rich degree of variation in

the number of entrants. Using this variation, we seek to measure the effect of the number of

competitors on the likelihood that a political ad is negative.

We use a unique dataset from the Wisconsin Advertising Project (WiscAds), which contains

information on all political advertisements aired in the top 100 media markets in the United

States 2004 elections. As the data contains a comprehensive record of the amount of political

advertising and its content, we are able to measure the probability of going negative at the ad

level as a function of market and candidate characteristics. Our main findings are that duopolies

2

Page 4: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

have over twice as high a likelihood of airing a negative ad as compared to non-duopolies,

and depending on the measure of negativity we use, cutting the number of competitors in half

generates a five to ten fold increase in the rate of negative advertising. These magnitudes suggest

that even just a handful of competitors can all but eliminate the incentives to “go negative”

as compared to the duopoly case. These results remain robust to the inclusion of a variety of

controls as well as instruments that we construct for the number of competitors in a race.

Our empirical findings, which tie together the number of competitors and the tone of the

campaign, also shed new light on the consequences that the policies aimed at shaping the “com-

petitiveness” of primary elections (and therefore entry) may have on the tone of the campaign,

and in turn on voters’ behavior. We discuss such policy implications in the conclusion.

The plan of the paper is the following. In Section 2 we review the related literature. In Section

3 we introduce the data, and in Section 4 we carry out the empirical analysis and illustrate the

key empirical relationships in the data. We also include a discussion of the robustness of the

raw effects in the data to omitted variable bias by both controlling for relevant race covariates

and finding instruments that exploit the primary structure of the races. Finally, in Section

5, to formally illustrate our hypothesis, which is that the introduction of more competitors

creates a spillover effect that diminishes the incentive to negatively advertise, as it pertains

to political competition, we construct a theoretical example that draws upon ideas from the

political literature based on games of voters’ mobilization, which were first developed by Snyder

(1989) and Shachar and Nalebuff (1999). We conclude in Section 6.

2 Related Literature

This paper is broadly related to a vast literature in economics and political science that

examines political advertising. Empirical studies of political advertising primarily investigate

the effects of campaigning on voter behavior.3 Shachar and Nalebuff (1999), Coate and Conlin

(2004) and reference therein focus on the effect of advertising on turnout. Other works, such

as Gerber et al. (2007), Stromberg (2008), Gerber (1998) and Levitt (1994), investigate the

relationship between campaign spending and vote choice, in gubernatorial, Presidential, Senate

and House elections respectively. In a more recent work, De Mello and Da Silveira (2011)

overcome the endogeneity problem of campaign spending using races where candidates’ TV time

is split equally among them (in a second round), and document a large effect of TV advertising

on voting outcomes. Finally, a number of papers focus on the effects of negative advertising on

3The empirical literature focusing on the supply side (i.e., candidates behavior) remains scarce. Notable excep-tions are (Gordon and Hartmann 2010), who estimate a model where candidates strategically choose advertisinglevels across markets, using the methodology in Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) to account for the endogeneityof political advertising; (Erikson and Palfrey 2000) who investigate the simultaneity problem in estimating theeffect of campaign spending on election outcomes. None of the mentioned papers differentiate between positiveand negative advertising.

3

Page 5: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

voter behavior.4 Based on the findings of these papers, there is no clear consensus on whether

negative advertising has a mobilizing or a stimulating effect on turnout. A possible explanation

that reconciles the mixed evidence has been provided by Lovett and Shachar (2010), who argue

that the effect of negative advertising on voters behavior depends on voters prior knowledge. In

this respect, Landi and Yip (2006) find that the tone of the campaign only affects the turnout

of Independents.5 We differ from these studies in that, instead of focusing on the demand side

(i.e., voters) and addressing the question of who is affected by advertising and why, we examine

the campaign choices of candidates, positive or negative, and investigate how their advertising

strategy changes with the number of competitors in the race. Regarding the supply side, our

work is more closely related to the work of Lovett and Shachar (2010) who estimate a model

of electoral competition where candidates decide how much to advertise and how to allocate

the advertising expenditure between positive and negative advertising. However, the strategies

of candidates do not explicitly take into account the spillover effect of negative ads since they

consider only races with two competitors. On the contrary, the focus of our work is the spillover

effect that arises when there are more than two candidates.

3 Data Description

In order to explore the empirical relevance of the spillover effect, we assembled data from the

2004 primary elections in the United States. First we obtain data on each House, Senate, and

gubernatorial primary election in 2004 from the records kept in America Votes (Alice, Scammon

and Cook 2005). Throughout our analysis, we refer to an election (or electoral contest) as

each specific race (e.g., Democratic Primary for Wisconsin Governor). Thus, for each electoral

contest, we collected data about the number of candidates in the race, along with the name of

each candidate, the vote share (percentage) obtained in the primary election, and her partisan

affiliation. We then eliminate the unopposed elections (i.e., elections with only one candidate

running) and all elections where no candidates ran. In a strongly Democratic district, for

example, it is not uncommon for there to be no Republican candidates running in a primary.

Overall there were 966 elections from 2004 Senate, House, and gubernatorial primaries; but of

these, 558 elections were unopposed and 68 elections had no candidates, which leaves us with

340 primary elections that had two or more competitors (199 are two-candidate races and 141

elections have three or more candidates).6

4See, for example, Ansolabehere et al. (1994), Freedman and Goldstein (1999), Freedman et al. (2004),Peterson and Djupe (2005), Lau et al. (2007), Che et al. (2007) and references therein.

5Another strand on the empirical literature focus on the impact of media market expansion on voter turnout.See for instance, Della Vigna and Kaplan (2007) and citations therein. While they analyze the effects of mediabias, they do not precisely study advertisements.

6Candidates make an extensive use of televised advertising. For example, in the 2008 US pres-idential election, candidates spent over $360 million on broadcast time throughout their campaigns.Broadcast media accounted for the highest share of the overall media expenditure, followed by mis-

4

Page 6: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

We then match this data with advertising data from TNSMI/Campaign Media Analysis

Group (CMAG) that was made available to us by the University of Wisconsin Advertising

Project (WiscAds).7 A unique aspect of this dataset is that it contains information on each

airing of a political advertisement in the top 100 media markets in the United States for all

elections in 2004, including all special and run-off elections. The top 100 media markets cover

about 85% of the US population (see Figure 1). Throughout the entire 2004 election season, over

half a million television spots (558,989 ads) were aired in favor of gubernatorial, U.S. Senate,

and U.S. House candidates. Of these ads, 254,368 were aired during the primary campaigns for

these elections, which are the focus of this paper due to their large variation in the number of

candidates.8 When we merged the primary election data with the advertising data, we lost 214

House races, 7 gubernatorial races and 13 Senate races. Of these dropped races that arose in the

match with the advertising data, approximately 20% were due to the fact that they were outside

of the top 100 media markets, and about 80% were due to the fact that there was no advertising

for the primary election.9 Concern may arise that those races without televised advertising

have different entry incentives than those with televised advertising. However, we find that the

number of viable candidates is approximately the same for elections with and without televised

advertising: 2.66 and 2.25 respectively.

In the final dataset, there are 104 primary elections with two or more candidates and active

campaign advertising, with 26 for the Senate, 63 for the House, and 15 for gubernatorial elections.

As shown in Table 1, 75% of the electoral contests have two to four candidates on the ballot,

with similar patterns across gubernatorial, House and Senate races. The most candidates that

compete in a primary contest is ten. As reported in Table 2, we observed 242,461 ads in the

campaign of these races, of which 42% are from Senate elections, 18% from House elections, and

40% from gubernatorial elections. Given the fact that media markets are almost always larger

than House districts, it is not surprising that a small percentage of campaign advertising is for

House candidates. Senate and gubernatorial elections, on the other hand, are state-wide, and

candidates typically campaign via televised advertising.

The CMAG data provides a rich set of information for each ad aired throughout the election,

as the unit of analysis is an individual television broadcast of a single advertisement. The data

contains information on when the advertisement aired (date, time of day, and program) and

cellaneous media ($273 million), internet media ($43 million) and print media ($21 million). Seehttp://www.opensecrets.org/pres08/expenditures.php?cycle=2008.

7See (Goldstein and Rivlin 2007a) for a detailed description of the WiscAds data.8Whether an advertisement was aired during the primary or general election was determined by the date of

the primary in each state. If the ad aired prior to the primary election, then it was counted as a primary ad; ifit aired between a primary and a primary run-off, it was considered to be part of that campaign. Any ads thataired after the primary (or after the primary run-off if the state had one) were dropped from the dataset.

9We drop one Louisiana governor race, since it had a runoff after the primary. We also drop Ronnie Musgrove’sadvertising in a 5 candidate Mississippi election, since he (the incumbent) was prematurely attacking the generalelection candidate, which does not pertain to primary competition.

5

Page 7: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

where the ad aired (television station and media market) in addition to the cost of the ad.10 11

The WiscAds coders then examine the content of each advertisement in the CMAG data and

record a number of variables related to the content of the ad, including the name of the favored

candidate, his/her political party, the race being contested, the tone, and issues addressed.

Specifically related to the tone of the advertisement, coders are asked to determine whether the

objective of the ad is to promote a candidate, attack a candidate, or a contrast of the two.12

The WiscAds data also includes measures for whether or not the opposing candidate is pictured

in the ad, and if the focus of the ad is on personal or policy matters.13 It is possible to construct

various measures of negativity based on this data. Five possible measures of negativity, which

are not mutually exclusive, are the following (each of which is coded as one if the advertisement

is designated as “negative” under a specific set of criteria, and zero otherwise):

Negative1 includes ads that either spend the entire time attacking an opponent or spend some

time promoting and some attacking (attack plus contrast ads).

Negative2 includes ads that attack for at least half of the airtime.

Negative3 includes only those ads that end with an attack.

Negative4 includes all ads that only attack the opponent.

Negative5 includes ads that attack for at least half of the airtime and are focused on personal

issues rather than policy.

For our purposes, the most relevant categories of negative advertising are Negative1 (which

flags an ad as negative if it contains any negativity whatsoever) and Negative4 (which only flags

an ad as negative if all of its message is negative). Thus Negative1 is a more inclusive measure

than Negative4.

Demographics Data

In addition to advertising and race specific data, we also collected demographic data for

each candidate in the election, regardless of whether or not that candidate engaged in televised

10While there are cost measures in the dataset for each ad, they are estimated by TNS (the parent company ofCMAG) based on the media market, time of day, and the show the ad aired on. Part of TNS’s expertise is themeasurement of these costs. Virtually all advertisements are for 30 second television spots, so the length of an adis not a relevant issue.

11We also observe the sponsor of the ad both by name, i.e. “Paid for by Friends of Jon Jennings Committee”or “Paid for by Emily’s List” and by category, i.e. candidate, party, or special interest group. Since, however,candidates sponsored over 94% of all ads, with interest groups sponsoring only 4% of ads, we ignore the lattertwo.

12Attack ads are coded as such if the favored candidate is not mentioned in the ad at all; contrast ads mentionboth the favored and opposing candidate; promote ads mention only the favored candidate.

13Observe that while we see whether the opposing candidate was pictured or not, we do not see the identityof this opposing candidate who is the target of the attack. We do know if the ad is refuting previous negativitydirected at a candidate, which occurs about 6 percent of the time in the data.

6

Page 8: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

advertising. Information about each candidate’s age, education, race, and political experience

(including dynastic links to a political office) were obtained from the official Biographical Direc-

tory of the U.S. Congress (1789-present) if the candidate has ever been a member of Congress.

Otherwise, we used alternative web-based data sources, such as online versions of state and local

newspapers and wikipedia.14

In Table 3 we show the differences in the observable characteristics of elections across different

levels of entry to ensure that different market sizes do not attract intrinsically different types of

competitors. As can be seen, the demographics of entrants do not systematically change across

races of different size,15 and political experience (whether the individual has held political office

in the past) does seem to slightly vary amongst duopolies and non-duopolies, making it crucial

for us to control for this in the analysis to follow.

With this information on candidates’ characteristics, we want to be sure that the demo-

graphics characteristics of entrants are not different for television advertisers and those that do

not advertise on television, as the data we use for the remainder of the analysis uses information

pertaining only to advertisers. These statistics appear in Table 4, where we see that the two dif-

fer slightly in that advertisers are more likely to have political experience and to have attended

law school. The most common profession in our data were lawyers, followed by businessmen,

and the average age of the candidates who advertise is 53, with approximately two thirds of

candidates between 45 and 60 years of age. In addition, 84% of the candidates in our data were

men, and 90% of the candidates were white. Thus, we see that the “modal” entrant is a white

male between 45 and 60 years old, who is an attorney or businessman.16

4 Empirical Analysis

We now seek to empirically examine the effect of the number of competitors in a race on the

incentive to air negative ads in the data. We expect that increasing the number of competitors

beyond two players generates a spillover effect that reduces the benefit of negative advertising.

The spillover effect thus suggests two predictions about the data:

1. Duopoly markets should exhibit a greater tendency for negative advertising than non-

duopoly markets.

2. The tendency for negative advertising should decrease monotonically with the number of

competitors.

Both predictions are products of the spillover story. Our analysis will be concerned with seeing

whether these effects are present in the data and quantifying their magnitude. Assessing the

14Specific candidate information and sources are available upon request.15Also, duopolies do not appear to reduce a candidate’s probability of winning the general election16The correlation between the percent of the vote share obtained and whether or not we have a candidate’s

demographic information is 0.02.

7

Page 9: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

magnitudes will provide a sense of the order of importance of the competition as a means of

explaining negativity.

We start with the first prediction and plot the proportion of negative ads under the five

different measure of negativity for both duopoly and non-duopoly markets. The result is shown

in Figure 2. The figure reveals a clear consistency with our hypothesis: across all the negativity

measures, duopoly markets exhibit a significantly higher probability of airing a negative ad as

opposed to non-duopoly markets. The magnitude of this “duopoly effect” is striking: across all

measures, duopolies exhibit over twice as high a likelihood of airing a negative ad as compared

to non-duopolies.

There is a natural concern that our measure of the number of competitors, which is the

number of candidates who appear on the primary ballot (we refer to this measure of candidates

as “Ballot N”) may be overstated, since there could be a number of “fringe” candidates on the

ballot who pose no real competitive threat to the “viable” candidates (meaning that the viable

candidates effectively ignore potential spillover to the fringe candidate in making advertising

choices). We thus construct an alternative measure of the number of candidates in a race by

ignoring candidates who earned less than 5 percent of the popular vote in the election. We shall

refer to this alternative measure as “Effective N”. Table 5 shows the effect on the distribution

of the number of candidates across races, and as can be seen, the “Effective N” measure puts

more mass of the distribution on races with 2, 3, or 4 candidates (since elections with 5 or more

candidates are getting re-classified into one of these groups). The more compressed distribution

accords with common sense that primary races with 5 or more credible candidates vying for

votes are quite rare.17

Figure 3 reproduces the comparison between duopoly and non-duopoly using “Effective N”

as the measure of competition as opposed to the “Ballot N”. As can be seen, the duopoly effects

grow even larger, with duopolies now exhibiting a likelihood of negative advertising that ranges

from approximately 2.5 to 3.5 times higher than non-duopolies.18 The relative increase in the rate

of negative advertising for duopoly markets is larger when one considers the Negative4 measure

as opposed to the Negative1 measure. This accords with our theory since since Negative4 only

counts ads that spend the whole time attacking as negative while Negative1 counts ads that

spend any part of the ad attacking as negative. Thus the reduction in the benefits of using

17If we revise this measure to candidates who earned more than 2% of the vote share or increase the thresholdto candidates who received more than 10% of the vote share, the number of 2 candidate, 3 candidate, and 4candidate elections remain similar. The only variability comes from races with 5 or more candidates. All resultsthat follow are robust to altering the threshold to 2 or 10 percent.

18An alternative measure of the number of effective candidates could be obtained using polling data collectedat an early stage of the campaigns. However, it is hard to find reliable data of polls for all 2004 primary elections.A popular resource on trends in American public opinion is PollingReport, which systematically reports all theelectoral polling data that have been collected during a US campaign. According to PollingReport we couldrecover information about only 31 primary races that actually have primary match-up polls. With this smallsample size, we still find that duopolies have more than double the probability of going negative when comparedto non-duopolies.

8

Page 10: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

negative advertising for non-duopoly markets should be even larger under Negative4 advertising

as compared to Negative1 advertising.

Table 6 breaks out the information in Figure 2 further by showing the proportion of ads that

are negative under the five different measures conditional on the number of competitors in each

election. Here we see that the trend in the tables is consistent with prediction 2 - there is a

monotone relation on negativity as we add competitors beyond two. Interestingly, for most of

the measures, the bulk of the reduction is realized in just doubling the number of players from

2 to 4 players (two person races having between 4 and 10 times the rate of negative ads as four

person races). If we restrict attention to advertising that spends the whole time attacking, i.e.,

Negative4, we also see that with just 5 players, the rate of negative advertising virtually goes

to zero (note that while the number of races with five or more players is small, the number of

advertisements with five or more races is not, the sample size being close to 8,000). Thus with

just a handful of competitors, we see that the monotone effect of negativity in the number of

players can drive negativity to almost zero.

Robustness

The evidence presented in the previous section illustrated a revealing empirical relationship

between the number of competitors and the incentives for going negative. The steep reduction

in the rate of negative advertising that is associated with adding just a few players suggests

that our hypothesis is a first order reason for the high rates of negative advertising in political

markets overall (since most elections in the United States are head to head duopoly races). In

this section we will consider the robustness of these results to the possible presence of omitted

variable bias. The possible endogeneity concern is that factors that lead a race to only have a

few candidates might also be related to the factors that cause the “tone” of an election to be

more negative. While we view entry into a primary race as a highly idiosyncratic event and

hence exogenous to the decision to go negative upon entering (which accords with a common

wisdom in political science, see e.g., Brady et al. (2007)), we can nevertheless show that our

main results do not rely on requiring entry in primary races to be exogenous. First, we show that

introducing control variables that are likely candidates for explaining negativity do not alter the

estimated magnitude of the effect of competition on negativity. We then show robustness to

instrumenting for the number of competitors in a race, which we construct by exploiting the

primary structure of the electoral campaigns we consider.19 We restrict attention to the two

19One might also be concerned that primaries with prospects of a close general election may have more candi-dates and less negativity, as politicians fear they may alienate their electorate. However, we find that there wasno significant difference in entry when the general election was close. The mean “Effective N” was 3.08 for closeelections and 3.17 for elections that were less close, where we define “close” as within a 5% margin. Even if werelax this to 10%, we obtain the same result.

9

Page 11: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

most straightforward categories of negativity, i.e., Negative1 and Negative4.20

We start with the results pertaining to Negative1. Table 7 reproduces the main effect we

found in the data within a regression framework. In particular, we employ a linear probability

model for the event that an advertisement in the data is negative (where we are careful to cluster

the ad level observations at the election level to control for any unobserved shock that correlates

observations within an election, and we are also careful to use robust standard errors to control

for heteroskedasticity).21 22 Specification (1) shows the regression of negative advertising on

the log number of effective candidates, and specification (5) shows the regression of negativity

on a duopoly indicator variable. Both of these regressions are run without any controls, and as

can be seen, the coefficients capture the unconditional moment found in Figure 3 and Table 6:

doubling the number of candidates (say going from 2 to 4) leads to an absolute decline in the

probability of going negative of about 40 percent, and duopolies have a 25 percent absolute

higher probability of airing a negative ad than non-duopolies (or more than double).

Next, we introduce several controls in order to ensure that the spillover effect is indeed the

mechanism generating the increased negativity. In doing so, we incorporate controls at 3 levels

of analysis: ad, candidate, and election. At the ad level, we look at the number of days from the

primary election that the ad aired, as the WiscAds data provides us with the specific date each

ad airs. Since each primary has a different duration, we standardize this measure normalizing

it by the length of the campaign. “Days until Election” is continuous on the interval (0,1),

and takes a value equal to one at the farthest day away from the election and 0 at the election

day. One would expect that as the election approaches, all candidates may be more likely to

engage in negative advertising. At the candidate level, we include an indicator for whether or

not the advertiser is the incumbent, since we may expect that there are different incentives

to going negative for the incumbent when compared to competitors. Recall that this study

restricts its analysis to primaries, so each election does not have an incumbent and a challenger,

as in general elections. In fact, only 24 of the 104 races in the dataset contain an incumbent.

Additional candidate level covariates contained in our analysis are gender, race, education, and

political experience, which is defined as having held an elected office at the state level or higher

(i.e. state Senate). We also include controls at the election level, including the type of race, the

partisan color of the primary, and the total advertising volume. First, we expect that the varying

term structures or the nature of the offices we investigate can generate different incentives for

20Wel use the “Effective N” measure of competition, however the robustness results that we present would alsohold if we had used the Ballot measure of N.

21We opt for a linear probability model for the simplicity of implementing the IV. Our basic marginal effectsdo not change in an economically significant way when we use a logit instead of a linear probability model asillustrated in Table 11.

22Our use of clustered standard errors throughout the paper is a conservative strategy for the standard errors.Given our data has a “long panel” dimension (many advertisements within each race), imposing more modelstructure would allow us to improve upon standard errors. It is reassuring that such additional modelling structureis not needed for our main substantive results to hold.

10

Page 12: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

going negative. For instance, if the two-year House term forces Congressmen to be constantly

up for re-election, this may make the races more cutthroat and increase the probability he runs

a negative ad. Second, we may worry that one party historically has more negative primaries

than the other, so we also control for whether or not the race was Republican. Third, we control

for the total volume of advertising in an election, where we take the natural log of this number,

as elections with more ads will likely increase the probability that each ad is negative.

Specifications (2) and (6) in Table 7 then show that the effects from the unconditional

regressions (1) and (5) remain approximately the same when we add control variables that might

also be related to the likelihood of an advertisement being negative. The significant controls

across specifications, as described above, are the partisan color of the primary, whether it is a

primary for a House race, the total ad volume, and the time to election. The latter variable’s

estimated coefficient is significant and negative in specification (2), meaning that as we get closer

to the election day the probability of going negative increases. Interestingly, the incumbency of

the candidate does not seem to play a role.23 One of the potential omitted variable concerns

is that incumbency is likely to be correlated with both the number of candidates in the race

(i.e., the presence of the incumbent may deter entry) as well as the likelihood of engaging in

negative advertising (it could be more likely to observe attacks directed towards the incumbent).

However, our results show that this potential confounding effect due to incumbency does not

appear to play a role in the data. In both specifications (2) and (6) we see that Republicans

are more likely to attack in primaries than Democrats, and House races, when compared to

gubernatorial and Senate races, have a higher propensity to go negative. Also, elections with a

higher total quantity of advertising allocate a larger fraction of those ads towards being negative.

In specification (6), we see that additional political experience increases the inclination for a

candidate to run a negative ad, though we do not see this same relationship in column (2).

Before the election, we may anticipate some level of negativity based on the specific marketing

of the particular area in which the televised advertisements are aired. For instance, if we are

concerned that Illinois Senators are more pre-disposed to negative advertising in Chicago, as the

fast-paced city residents may be more susceptible to negative ads than they are in the Paducah

media market, we expect the specific area to play a role in determining the amount of negativity.

If we expect the specific media market to help determine the propensity to “go negative” before

the campaign even starts, then this should not vary across elections, meaning that both parties

primaries if advertising in the same media market, will have the same ex-ante probability of

going negative in that market. In addition, this will not vary across offices. For instance, if an

Illinois governor, Senate, and House candidates all advertise in the Chicago market, we expect

that this may make him more inclined to “go negativie” even prior to the start of the election.24

23When we instead control for the presence of an incumbent in a race, we obtain the same insignificant coefficientfor incumbency, and it does not alter the sign and magnitude of the estimated coefficient for Effective N.

24While House candidates generally have smaller geographic constituent-bases than Senate and gubernatorial

11

Page 13: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

We capture this effect with media market level fixed effects in specifications (3) and (7) of

Table 7. Including these market-level fixed effects reduces the magnitudes of the coefficients on

both log(EffectiveN) and the duopoly indicator by almost a half, explaining a large portion of

the negativity for that election. In specifications (4) and (8), we include these fixed effects, as

well as the candidate, ad, and election level controls, where we find a similar effect.

Of course, it could be the case that even after including controls, there could still exist

unobserved factors that explain the relationship between competition and negativity. To address

this concern, we now turn to the discussion of an instrumental variable strategy for the number

of entrants in a race. We motivate the IVs by thinking about two possible incentives a candidate

may have for entering the primary: to hold political office or achieve other benefits unrelated to

winning the general election, such as personal gain from exposure.

The main reason to enter a political primary is to win the political office. Any factors

that would make it less likely to win the general election would be a deterrence to entry. Our

instrument in this regard uses a unique feature of the political primary process - the existence

of the opposing party’s primary for the same political seat. If the opposing party is fielding an

especially strong candidate, then it makes it less likely that anyone from a candidate’s own party

will succeed in the general election. Intuitively, if a strong candidate runs in the Democratic

primary, this can deter entry in the Republican primary, as candidates may anticipate their low

probability of winning the general election. To measure this, we construct the opposing party’s

Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (henceforth, HHI), a measure of concentration of the popular vote

share across candidates. As HHI gets large, the popular vote is becoming more concentrated

on a small number of candidates. Thus a more concentrated HHI captures the presence of a

dominant candidate in the election.25

There may be initial concern that the excluded party primary is not a valid “exclusion restric-

tion,” since if the Democrats are running a strong candidate, this might weaken the negativity in

Republican advertising, as Republicans are internalizing their general election prospects. How-

ever, it is a commonly accepted wisdom that primary candidates do not internalize general

election effects in their primary campaigning (i.e., they do not hold back on attacking for fear

that the attack can be used against the primary opponent in the general election). This wis-

dom is consistent with Malhotra and Snowberg’s (2010) finding that each state’s presidential

primary contest/campaign in the 2008 election did not change the probability a party would win

the general election. Moreover, in the data we do not find evidence that the excluded party’s

HHI is related to negativity in a primary after controlling for the number of competitors.26

candidates, multiple House districts often overlay media markets. This gives us many occurrences where multipleHouse races advertise in the same market, as well as where House candidates advertise in multiple markets.

25When the opposing party has no entrants, we set HHI to 0, and when the opposing party’s candidate runsunopposed, HHI=1, as in a monopoly.

26When we regress negativity on the number of candidates and opposing party HHI, the latter coefficient isinsignificant. If we exclude the number of candidates in this regression, the opposing party’s HHI is also unableto explain negativity.

12

Page 14: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

However, if we think that this instrument is endogenous, meaning that higher opposing party

HHI results in a higher likelihood that the opposing party runs a strong candidate, then this

may reduce the likelihood that one’s own party runs a negative campaign. Thus, higher the

HHI in the opposing party deters entry, but also reduces negativity if one proports that the

candidates are less likely to attack to preserve party’s general election prospects. With this, we

expect that with higher opposing party HHI results in less own party entry, which should mean

that we see LESS negativity, but we actually see MORE negativity when we use this IV.

Table 8 shows the first stage results of instrumenting for entry using the HHI of the opposing

party, where we see that when the vote is concentrated on fewer candidates in the opposing party,

this is likely to deter entry in one’s own party. Here, we see that in columns (3), (4), (7), and

(8), when we include media market fixed effects, our instrument becomes significantly stronger,

as the first stage F-statistic jumps up. In addition, the magnitude of the coefficients on the IV,

HHI opposing party, reduce in magnitude when the the market level fixed effects are included.

Thus, we may see that when there is a large “innovation” in negativity for that election, it could

mean there is also a big “prize” or warchest, and thus create more entry. However, when the

other party runs a strong candidate, this could simultaneously deter entry and should restrain

the “innovation” in negativity. The controls in columns (4) and (8), when we include market

fixed effects, seem to matter more in predicting entry. This may capture the fact that, in specific

media markets, some candidates may be more likely to enter, such as African Americans in urban

markets.

Table 9 shows the effects of competition on negativity when we instrument for the “Effective

N” number of candidates in a race, using both the continuous variable and the duopoly indicator.

Both the unconditional effect and the partial effect in columns (1) and (2) tell the same basic

story as before: doubling the number of competitors (from 2 to 4, say) leads to an absolute

reduction in the probability of going negative of about 40-50 percent (that is, we go from a little

over 40 percent chance of an ad being negative in a two person race to something closer to a

5 percent probability in 4 or more person races). These numbers tightly match the coefficients

found in the previous regressions (i.e., columns (1) and (2) in Table 7). A similar result is

seen by comparing just duopolies to non-duopolies. In Table 9, when we instrument for the

duopoly indicator variable in columns (5) and (6), we see that the coefficients from the relevant

regressions from Table 7 (i.e., columns (3) and (4)) change very little.

However, when we include media market fixed effects and controls, as in columns (3) and

(4), we actually see an increase in the effect size when compared to Table 7 columns (3) and (4).

• Before the election, we anticipate some negativity as captured via market fixed effects.

• When you take out the fixed effects, what is left is the “innovation” in negativity for that

election.

13

Page 15: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

• When the innovation is big, it could reflect that there is a big “prize” and hence much

entry as well.

• When the other party runs a strong candidate, this deters entry and should restrain the

innovation in negativity.

All of this gets captured via imperfect instruments in our Table 9 columns (3) and (4) for

log(Effective N) and (7) and (8) for the duopoly indicator.

Finally we note that these results are not particular to the Negative1 measure. In Table 10,

we show the corresponding analysis for the Negative4 measure, and the same phenomenon

holds. The unconditional regressions replicate the effects found in Figure 3 and Table 6, and

the controls and instruments do not fundamentally change the order of magnitude of the effect.

5 The Spillover Effect

To formally illustrate the spillover effect in a model of political competition, we choose

to focus the model on political competition both because the data we will use comes from

political markets, and also because it allows us to consider a model where the source of the

spillover effect is less obvious than the case of advertising among firms. We follow the literature

that views voter mobilization as the primary objective of campaigning (see e.g., Snyder (1989)

and Shachar and Nalebuff (1999)).27 In the same spirit as these papers, we black-box the

underlying mechanism by which voters’ choices are affected by campaigning, and posit a model

in which candidates engage in positive (negative) advertising to mobilize (demobilize) their own

(opponent’s) supporters. The model is revealing in that there is no “spillover” directly built

into the technology that mobilizes voters - by negatively advertising against your opponent,

you only persuade his supporters to stay home rather than to vote for someone else (which

differentiates this setting from the more obvious spillover story among firms, where negative

advertising against your opponent causes some of its customers to flock to to a different firm).

The key effect we show is that when L is greater than two, engaging in negative ads nevertheless

creates positive externalities to those opponents that are not the object of the attack. On the

contrary, positive ads benefit only the advertiser. Therefore, it is the strategic nature of the

interaction that creates a spillover effect and reduces the incentive to use negative advertising

when facing more than one opponent. We emphasize that our model is not the only way to

capture the spillover effect, but just one revealing way to illustrate it.

27Another strand of the theoretical literature focuses on the informative role of advertising (see for instanceCoate (2004A), (2004B), Galeotti and Mattozzi (2009), Polborn and Yi (2006), and Prat (2002)). In particular,Polborn and Yi (2006) differentiate between positive and negative advertising. In the context of incompleteinformation, they show that balancing negative and positive advertising provides voters with the most information.They argue that negative advertisements show a different side of the candidate that a voter will not be exposedto without this type of technology.

14

Page 16: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

We begin by assuming that candidates simultaneously choose how to allocate their budget

between two different forms of campaigning to increase their support on election day. Specifically,

each candidate i chooses positive advertising (Pi) to increase the number of his own voters that go

to the polls, and negative advertising to keep candidate j’s supporters home (Nji = N1

i , . . . , NLi )

on election day. Let k = 1, . . . , L denote a candidate and Πk0 her political support in the absence

of a campaign. We assume that the number of votes that candidate i receives after the campaign

is equal to,

Πi

(Pi, N

i1, . . . , N

iL

)= Πi0

Pαi(η +

∑jN ij

)β (1)

where α, β ∈ (0, 1), and η is a small positive constant.28 Note that Pαi /(η+∑jN ij)β is increasing

and concave in Pi and decreasing and convex in N ij . This assumption captures the idea that

the number of i’s supporters that are mobilized is directly affected by both the amount of i’s

positive ads and the amount of negative ads that i receives from her opponents, and the marginal

mobilization effect of an ad is decreasing. The functional form we use is merely illustrative, and

the example can be expanded to allow for more general voter mobilization technologies.

Letting πk denote candidate k’s political market share (vote share) we have that

πi =

Πi0Pαi(

η+∑jN ij

)βL∑k=1

Πk0Pαk(

η+∑jNkj

)β.

Each candidate has the same war chest, which we normalize to be equal to 1. The objective of the

candidate is to maximize his vote share πi (·) given his budget constraint Pi+N1i + . . .+NL

i = 1,

which is a plausible assumption in primaries. Note that it will always be the case that N ii = 0

for all i.

To see how the model generates a spillover effect, let’s consider a three person race. After

substituting in the budget constraint, the problem for candidate k = 1 is

max(P1,N2

1 )

Π10

(P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)αΠ10

(P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)α+ Π20

(P2

η+N21 +N2

3

)α+ Π30

(P3

η+(1−P1−N21 )+N3

2

)α (2)

and similarly for candidates k = 2, 3. Thus we see that in (2), Π1 decreases in N12 and N1

3 (the

negative advertising of its opponents against candidate one), but it increases in N32 and N2

3 (the

negative advertising of candidate 1’s opponents against each other). Since the terms N32 and N2

3

28A small positive value of η guarantees that the expression in (1) is well-defined also when∑j

Nj is equal to

0. Other than this, η plays no role in the analysis.

15

Page 17: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

would not enter candidate 1’s objective function in a two person race, they capture the spillover

effects caused by adding competitors to a race.

The spillover effect directly translates to the equilibrium solution of the model. We focus on

the symmetric case where α = β and Πi0 is equal across candidates i. In a L = 3 person race,

the unique symmetric equilibrium is

Pi =2 + 2η

3and N j

i =1− η

6for all i.

However the unique symmetric equilibrium in an L = 2 person race is

Pi =1 + η

2and N j

i =1− η

2.

The details of the derivations are in the appendix. This result shows that when η is small, a

candidate is almost indifferent between engaging in positive or negative advertising in a two-

candidate race, but strictly prefers positive advertising in a three person race. In words, a

competitor in a three-candidate race is more likely to engage in positive rather than in negative

advertising.

6 Concluding Remarks

In this paper we provide a novel explanation for the high volume of negative advertising

that is generally found in the U.S. political market. When the number of competitors in a

market is greater than two, engaging in negative ads creates positive externalities to those

opponents that are not the object of the attack. However political competition in the U.S. is

largely characterized by “duopolies” (races with only two viable competitors, i.e. Republican

versus Democrat), where this spillover effect is not present, thus creating a greater incentive for

negative advertising.

Using primary elections in 2004 and the WiscAds data, we find that duopolies are two to

four times more likely to use negativity in an advertisement than non-duopolies. In addition,

adding just a handful of competitors drives the rate of negativity found in the data quite close

to zero. These results show that the data are not just consistent with our theory in a direc-

tional sense, but the magnitude of the results suggest that this economic mechanism appears

to have first order implications for why political markets are associated with producing more

negativity than product markets (since political contests in the United States are more likely

to be characterized by head to head duopoly competition than product markets). Our results

have policy implications for the regulation of political contests. Consider for example campaign

finance reform. If relaxing spending caps decreases the number of candidates entering races,29

29See for example Iaryczover and Mattozzi (2010).

16

Page 18: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

then an unintended consequence of such a policy would be an increase in the negative tone of

the campaign advertising. Understanding the presence of such unintended consequences should

help inform the policy debate on campaign finance reform and also the debate on controlling

the amount of negativity in politics.

17

Page 19: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Figures

Figure 1: Top 100 Media Markets

Top 100 MediaMarketsTop 100 Media Markets

18

Page 20: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Figure 2: Frequency of Negative Ads with Two Candidates and more than Two Candidates

43.4 40.81

25.38

21 21.53 22.63

18.03

11.02 9.1

6.48

Negative1 Negative2 Negative3 Negative4 Negative5

Two Candidates More Than 2 Candidates

Figure 3: Frequency of Negative Ads with Two Effective Candidates and more than Two Effec-tive Candidates

40.62

36.02

23.98

19.27

13.42

16.85

12.93

6.64 5.89 6.62

Negative1 Negative2 Negative3 Negative4 Negative5

Two Candidates More Than 2 Candidates

19

Page 21: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Tables

Table 1: Summary of Office by Number of Candidates

Candidates Senate House Governor Races

2 8 25 5 3821.0% 65.8% 13.2%

3 5 17 3 2520.0% 68.0% 12.0%

4 4 9 2 1526.7% 60.0% 13.3%

5 1 3 0 425.0% 75.0% 0.0%

6 2 4 2 825.0% 50.0% 25.0%

7 1 2 0 333.3% 66.7% 0%

8 3 2 1 650.0% 33.3% 16.7%

9 1 0 1 250.0% 0.0% 50.0%

10 1 1 1 333.3% 33.3% 33.3%

Total Races 26 63 15 104

Table 2: Breakdown of Ads by Races

Number of Ads Percent of Total Ads

U.S. Senate 102, 051 42.09U.S. House 42, 560 17.55Governor 97, 850 40.36

Total 242, 461

20

Page 22: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Table 3: Who Enters?: Summary Stats of Candidates by Duopoly

Non-Duopoly Duopoly

Male 0.819 0.885(0.386) (0.321)

White 0.907 0.875(0.291) (0.332)

College Degree 0.931 0.923(0.255) (0.268)

Law School 0.320 0.346(0.468) (0.478)

Political Experience 0.386* 0.598*(0.488) (0.493)

Observations 295 118

Note: sources of demographic variables available upon request.

Mean of each variable with standard deviation in parentheses.

Duopoly defined using the “Effective N” measure.

* Significantly different at the 10% level.

Table 4: Who Advertises?

Non-Advertiser Advertiser

Male 0.835 0.841(0.372) (0.367)

White 0.892 0.903(0.311) (0.296)

College Degree 0.905 0.947(0.294) (0.225)

Law School 0.241* 0.396*(0.429) (0.490)

Political Experience 0.348* 0.527*(0.478) (0.501)

Observations 204 211

Note: sources of demographic variables available upon request.

Mean of each variable with standard deviation in parentheses.

* Significantly different at the 10% level.

21

Page 23: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Table 5: Ballot N and Effective N

Ballot N Frequency Percent Effective N Frequency Percent

1 0 0 1 1 0.962 38 36.54 2 49 47.123 25 24.04 3 28 26.924 15 14.42 4 16 15.385 4 3.85 5 6 5.776 8 7.69 6 3 2.887 3 2.88 7 1 0.968 6 5.77 8 0 09 2 1.92 9 0 010 3 2.88 10 0 0

Total 104 100 Total 104 100

Table 6: Percent of Negative Advertisements, using Effective N

Overall

Negative1 Negative2 Negative3 Negative4 Negative5 Sample Size

.2673 .2252 .1385 .1145 .0945 242, 461

By Number of Candidates

Negative1 Negative2 Negative3 Negative4 Negative5 Sample Size

2 0.4062 0.3602 0.2398 0.1927 0.1342 100,7363 0.2779 0.2271 0.1273 0.1135 0.114 59,9494 0.0865 0.0547 0.0226 0.0208 0.0281 73,9575 or more 0.1058 0.0852 0.014 0.0014 0.0607 7,806P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

Notes: All variables Negative1 through Negative 5 are dummies for whether or not the ad is “Negative”

given the following specifications. Negative1 includes all ads that are attack ads or contrast ads.

Negative2 encompasses all ads that attack for at least half of the airtime. Negative3 looks at attack

ads and all contrast ads that end with an attack. Negative4 includes all ads that are only attack ads.

Negative5 accounts for ads that attack for at least half of the airtime and are focused on personal

issues rather than policy. P-value is the probability that percent of negative ads is equal across N.

22

Page 24: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Tab

le7:

Raw

Eff

ects

Usi

ng

Reg

ress

ion

Fra

mew

ork

Dep

end

ent

Var

iab

le:

Neg

ativ

e1eq

ual

s1

ifth

ead

ever

atta

cked

an

opp

onen

t(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)

log(

Eff

ecti

veN

)-0

.421

∗∗∗

-0.4

26∗∗

∗-0

.270

∗∗∗

-0.2

63∗∗

(0.0

955)

(0.0

979)

(0.0

671)

(0.0

575)

Du

opoly

0.23

8∗∗

∗0.2

48∗

∗∗0.1

22∗∗

∗0.

132

∗∗∗

(0.0

731)

(0.0

737

)(0

.0428

)(0

.039

9)

Incu

mb

ent

0.0

105

-0.0

367

0.0

035

5-0

.038

9(0

.0518

)(0

.040

5)(0

.057

8)(0

.043

6)

Day

sU

nti

lE

lect

ion

-0.4

01∗∗

∗-0

.419

∗∗∗

-0.3

96∗∗

∗-0

.417

∗∗∗

(0.0

640

)(0

.042

9)(0

.064

5)(0

.043

0)

Tot

alA

dV

olu

me

0.095

0∗∗

∗0.

0673

∗∗∗

0.0

928

∗∗∗

0.066

0∗∗∗

(0.0

226)

(0.0

228)

(0.0

244

)(0

.0222

)

Rep

ub

lica

n0.0

965

∗∗0.

0709

∗∗0.1

15∗

∗0.0

808

∗∗

(0.0

415)

(0.0

338)

(0.0

482

)(0

.0350

)

Gov

ern

or

-0.0

291

0.06

09-0

.016

40.0

714

(0.0

702)

(0.0

671)

(0.0

779

)(0

.0772

)

Hou

se0.

184

∗∗∗

0.13

4∗0.1

65∗

∗∗0.

129

(0.0

401)

(0.0

676)

(0.0

475

)(0

.0684

)

Mal

e0.

012

8-0

.031

3-0

.0119

-0.0

362

(0.0

363)

(0.0

314)

(0.0

358

)(0

.0328

)

Col

lege

-0.1

69-0

.159

-0.2

11

-0.1

81(0

.203)

(0.1

43)

(0.2

01)

(0.1

32)

Wh

ite

-0.0

104

-0.0

558

-0.0

459

-0.0

722

(0.1

18)

(0.0

778)

(0.1

32)

(0.0

829)

Poli

tica

lE

xp

erie

nce

0.0

835

0.00

836

0.1

08∗

0.022

8(0

.056

3)(0

.030

2)(0

.0609

)(0

.0327

)

Mar

ket

Fix

edE

ffec

ts-

-X

X-

-X

X

Ob

serv

ati

on

s24

2448

2416

8924

2448

2416

8924

2448

241

689

2424

4824

1689

Nu

mb

erof

Gro

ups

8282

8282

Robust

standard

erro

rscl

ust

ered

at

the

elec

tion

leve

inC

olu

mns

(1),

(2),

(5),

(6),

and

at

the

mark

etle

vel

in(3

),(4

),(7

),(8

)in

pare

nth

eses

.∗p<

0.1

0,∗∗p<

0.0

5,∗∗

∗p<

0.0

1

23

Page 25: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Tab

le8:

Fir

stS

tage

Imp

erfe

ctIV

Res

ult

s

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

log(E

ffec

tive

N)

log(

Eff

ecti

ve

N)

log(

Eff

ecti

veN

)lo

g(E

ffec

tive

N)

Duop

oly

Du

op

oly

Du

op

oly

Du

op

oly

HH

IO

pp

osi

ng

Par

ty-0

.340

52∗∗

-0.3

4686

∗∗-0

.130

06∗∗

∗-0

.1224

2∗∗

∗0.

462

23∗

0.504

66∗∗

0.186

66∗∗

∗0.2

3973∗∗

(0.1

627)

(0.1

566)

(0.0

025)

(0.0

025

)(0

.263

2)(0

.253

6)(0

.0043

)(0

.0041)

Incu

mb

ent

-0.2

7301

∗∗∗

-0.1

991

3∗∗

∗0.5

226

6∗∗

∗0.4

1328∗∗

(0.0

709)

(0.0

014)

(0.1

266)

(0.0

022)

Day

sU

nti

lE

lect

ion

-0.0

3638

-0.0

1818

∗∗∗

0.0

439

00.0

2059∗∗

(0.0

226)

(0.0

013)

(0.0

361)

(0.0

020)

Tot

alA

dV

olu

me

0.01

906

0.0

107

3∗∗∗

-0.0

284

5-0

.01163∗∗

(0.0

328)

(0.0

007)

(0.0

544)

(0.0

011)

Rep

ub

lica

n0.

0195

40.

050

74∗∗

∗-0

.0867

5-0

.17495∗∗

(0.0

865)

(0.0

011)

(0.1

446)

(0.0

017)

Gov

ern

or-0

.265

12∗∗

∗-0

.2392

2∗∗

∗0.4

008

9∗∗

∗0.3

9694∗∗

(0.0

907)

(0.0

016)

(0.1

448)

(0.0

026)

Hou

se0.

0492

8-0

.0242

0∗∗∗

-0.0

138

70.0

8604∗

∗∗

(0.1

025)

(0.0

020)

(0.1

488)

(0.0

032)

Male

0.01

283

0.032

75∗∗

∗0.

058

35-0

.02919∗

∗∗

(0.0

620)

(0.0

013)

(0.1

157)

(0.0

022)

Coll

ege

-0.0

1101

0.127

36∗∗

∗0.

192

86-0

.09021∗

∗∗

(0.1

167)

(0.0

027)

(0.1

483)

(0.0

044)

Wh

ite

0.08

552

0.080

14∗∗

∗-0

.0036

1-0

.03550∗∗

(0.0

615)

(0.0

022)

(0.0

984)

(0.0

036)

Pol

itic

alE

xp

erie

nce

-0.0

1548

0.036

88∗∗

∗-0

.0737

2-0

.18232∗∗

(0.0

667)

(0.0

009)

(0.1

149)

(0.0

015)

Mark

etF

ixed

Eff

ects

--

XX

--

XX

Tot

alO

bse

rvati

on

s242

448

2416

8924

2447

241

688

242

448

2416

8924

2447

241688

Nu

mb

erof

Gro

up

s82

8282

82

Fst

ati

stic

for

wea

kid

enti

fica

tion

4.380

4.90

926

30.8

232

2.2

3.0

83

3.9

60

1872

.43399.7

∗p<

0.1

0,∗∗p<

0.0

5,∗∗

∗p<

0.0

1.

Robust

standard

erro

rsin

pare

nth

eses

.

24

Page 26: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Tab

le9:

Imp

erfe

ctIV

Sec

ond

Sta

geR

esu

lts

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Neg

ati

ve1

Neg

ati

ve1

Neg

ativ

e1N

egat

ive1

Neg

ativ

e1N

egat

ive1

Neg

ativ

e1N

egat

ive1

log(E

ffec

tive

N)

-0.6

72∗

-0.6

88∗∗

-0.5

31∗∗

∗-0

.746

∗∗∗

(0.3

72)

(0.3

35)

(0.0

400)

(0.0

460)

Du

op

oly

0.49

5∗

0.4

73∗

∗0.3

70∗∗

∗0.3

81∗

∗∗

(0.2

84)

(0.2

32)

(0.0

283)

(0.0

234)

Incu

mb

ent

-0.0

855

-0.1

38∗∗

∗-0

.145

-0.1

47∗∗

(0.1

24)

(0.0

101)

(0.1

54)

(0.0

105

)

Day

sU

nti

lE

lect

ion

-0.4

15∗

∗∗-0

.428

∗∗∗

-0.4

11∗∗

∗-0

.423∗∗

(0.0

666)

(0.0

0294

)(0

.0665

)(0

.002

83)

Tot

alA

dV

olu

me

0.104

∗∗∗

0.07

56∗∗

∗0.

105

∗∗∗

0.072

1∗∗∗

(0.0

251)

(0.0

0166

)(0

.0271

)(0

.001

56)

Rep

ub

lica

n0.

079

3∗

0.08

85∗∗

∗0.1

07∗

0.117

∗∗∗

(0.0

460)

(0.0

0283

)(0

.0585

)(0

.004

12)

Gov

ern

or-0

.094

5-0

.059

0∗∗

∗-0

.102

-0.0

318

∗∗∗

(0.1

11)

(0.0

119)

(0.1

16)

(0.0

103

)

Hou

se0.

199

∗∗∗

0.12

2∗∗

∗0.1

72∗

∗∗0.

107

∗∗∗

(0.0

515)

(0.0

0452

)(0

.0587

)(0

.004

80)

Male

0.034

7-0

.007

28∗∗

-0.0

0171

-0.0

206

∗∗∗

(0.0

471)

(0.0

0367

)(0

.0469

)(0

.003

20)

Coll

ege

-0.1

77-0

.103

∗∗∗

-0.2

60

-0.1

64∗

∗∗

(0.2

06)

(0.0

0802

)(0

.214

)(0

.006

13)

Wh

ite

0.011

9-0

.018

1∗∗∗

-0.0

453

-0.0

643∗

∗∗

(0.1

16)

(0.0

0612

)(0

.141

)(0

.004

99)

Poli

tica

lE

xp

erie

nce

0.0

796

0.02

66∗∗

∗0.

125

∗∗0.0

686

∗∗∗

(0.0

535)

(0.0

0268

)(0

.0578

)(0

.004

75)

Ob

serv

atio

ns

24244

8241

689

2424

4824

1689

2424

4824

1689

2424

48241

689

Nu

mb

erof

Gro

ups

8282

82

82

Robust

standard

erro

rsin

pare

nth

eses

.∗p<

0.1

0,∗∗p<

0.0

5,∗∗

∗p<

0.0

1.

Dep

enden

tva

riable

iseq

ual

to1

ifth

ead

ever

att

ack

ed

25

Page 27: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Table 10: Negative4: Regression Results

Dependent Variable: Negative 4=1 if the Ad Only Attacked

(1) (2) (3) (4)

log(Effective N) -0.235∗∗∗ -0.0968∗∗∗

(0.0661) (0.0321)

Duopoly 0.134∗∗∗ 0.0349∗

(0.0483) (0.0187)

Incumbent 0.0214 0.0266(0.0202) (0.0214)

Days Until Election -0.155∗∗∗ -0.154∗∗∗

(0.0199) (0.0201)

Total Ad Volume 0.0394∗∗∗ 0.0386∗∗∗

(0.0114) (0.0110)

Republican 0.00556 0.00716(0.0205) (0.0211)

Governor 0.0381 0.0476(0.0365) (0.0427)

House 0.0963∗∗∗ 0.0956∗∗∗

(0.0349) (0.0359)

Male -0.000431 -0.00307(0.0195) (0.0191)

College -0.0215 -0.0304(0.0184) (0.0207)

White -0.0788 -0.0853(0.0601) (0.0617)

Political Experience -0.000294 0.00247(0.0123) (0.0142)

Market Fixed Effects - - X X

Observations 242448 242448 241689 241689Number of Groups 82 82

Robust standard errors clustered at the election level in (1), (2) and at the market level in (3), (4)

in parentheses. ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01

26

Page 28: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Tab

le11:

Com

par

ison

ofL

inea

rP

rob

abil

ity

and

Logi

t

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

OL

SL

ogit

OL

SL

ogit

OL

SL

ogi

tO

LS

Logi

tN

egat

ive1

Neg

ativ

e1N

egat

ive1

Neg

ativ

e1N

egat

ive1

Neg

ativ

e1N

egati

ve1

Neg

ativ

e1

log(

Eff

ecti

veN

)-0

.421

***

-0.4

38*

**-0

.397

***

-0.4

48**

*(0

.0955)

(0.1

03)

(0.1

12)

(0.1

09)

Du

opoly

0.23

8***

0.2

38*

**0.2

31*

*0.

219

***

(0.0

731)

(0.0

731

)(0

.084

2)(0

.083

9)In

cum

ben

t0.

0735

0.02

600.0

844

0.056

3(0

.049

9)(0

.056

4)(0

.058

7)(0

.0617

)T

ime

Unti

lE

lect

ion

-0.0

0041

6-0

.000

522*

-0.0

004

70*

-0.0

0053

7*(0

.000

253)

(0.0

0029

5)(0

.000

258)

(0.0

002

97)

Tot

al

Ad

Vol

um

e0.

108*

**0.

134*

**0.

105

***

0.128

***

(0.0

299)

(0.0

397)

(0.0

328)

(0.0

449

)R

epu

bli

can

0.10

6**

0.12

4**

0.1

20*

0.1

37*

*(0

.051

4)(0

.054

1)(0

.062

4)(0

.0667

)G

over

nor

0.06

640.

0680

0.0

975

0.114

(0.0

917)

(0.0

990)

(0.1

05)

(0.1

16)

Hou

se0.

216*

**0.

312*

**0.2

09*

**0.3

07*

**(0

.049

7)(0

.077

7)(0

.059

7)(0

.0971

)N

242,4

48

242,

448

242,

448

242,

448

242,

448

242,

448

242,

448

242

,448

Marg

inal

effec

tsre

port

ed;

Sta

ndard

erro

rscl

ust

ered

at

the

elec

tion

level

inpare

nth

eses

.*p<

0.1

0,

**p<

0.0

5,

***p<

0.0

1

27

Page 29: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Table 12: Candidate Level Regressions

(1) (2) (3) (4)Negative1 Negative1 Negative1 Negative1

log(Effective N) -0.136∗∗ -0.205∗∗∗

(0.0604) (0.0745)

Duopoly 0.0850∗ 0.138∗∗

(0.0486) (0.0602)

Incumbent -0.0402 -0.0487(0.0911) (0.0895)

Total Ad Volume 0.0237 0.0231(0.0156) (0.0160)

Republican 0.0164 0.0235(0.0454) (0.0476)

Governor -0.0819 -0.0861(0.0607) (0.0679)

House 0.0506 0.0407(0.0466) (0.0487)

Male -0.00620 -0.0169(0.0539) (0.0538)

White 0.0814 0.0767(0.0676) (0.0711)

College -0.185∗ -0.174∗

(0.0962) (0.0983)

Political Experience 0.0439 0.0464(0.0396) (0.0394)

Law School -0.00549 -0.00796(0.0423) (0.0425)

Observations 210 204 210 204

Standard errors clustered at the election level in parentheses∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01

28

Page 30: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

References

Alice, McGillivray, Richard Scammon, and Rhodes Cook, America Votes:26, 2003-2004

Election Returns by State, CQ Press, 2005.

Ansolabehere, S. and S. Iyengar, “Does Attack Advertising Demobilize the Electorate?,”

American Political Science Review, 1994, 88, 829–38.

and , Going Negative: How Political Advertisements Shrink and Polarize the Elec-

torate, Free Press, 1995.

Brady, David, Hahrie Han, and Jeremy Pope, “Primary Elections and Candidate Ide-

ology: Out of Step with the Primary Electorate?,” Legislative Studies Quarterly, 2007,

XXXII, 79–105.

Cappella, J. N. and K. H. Jamieson, Spiral of Synicism: The Press and the Public Good,

New York: Oxford University Press, 1997.

Che, H., G. Iyer, and R. Shanmugam, “Negative Advertising and Voter Choice,” Working

paper, University of Southern California, 2007.

Coate, S., “Pareto-Improving Campaign Finance Policy,” American Economic Review, 2004A,

94(3), 628–655.

, “Political Competition With Campaign Contributions and Information Advertising,”

Journal of the European Economic Association, 2004B, 2(5), 772–804.

and M. Conlin, “A Group Rule Utilitarian Approach to Voter Turnout: Theory and

Evidence,” American Economic Review, 2004, 94(5), 1476–1504.

Crotty, W. J. and G. C. Jacobson, American Parties in Decline, Boston: Little, Brown

and Company, 1980.

DellaVigna, Stefano and Ethan Kaplan, “The Fox News Effect: Media Bias and Voting,”

Quartlery Journal of Economics, 2007, 122, 1187–1234.

Erikson, R.S. and T. Palfrey, “Equilibrium in Campaign Spending Games: Theory and

Evidence,” American Political Science Review, 2000.

Freedman, P. and K. Goldstein, “Measuring media exposure and the effects of negative

campaign ads,” American Journal of Political Science 43(4), 1999.

Freedman, Paul, Michael Franz, and Kenneth Goldstein, “Campaign Advertising and

Democratic Citizenship,” American Journal of Political Science, 2004, 48, 723–741.

29

Page 31: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Galeotti, A. and A. Mattozzi, “Personal Influence: Social Context and Political Competi-

tion,” working paper, 2009.

Gerber, A., “Estimating the Effect of Campaign Spending on Senate Election Outcomes Using

Instrumental Variables,” American Political Science Review, 92(2), 401-411., 1998.

Gerber, Alan, James G. Gimpel, Donald P. Green, and Daron R. Shaw, “The Influence

of Television and Radio Advertising on Candidate Evaluations: Results from a Large Scale

Randomized Experiment,” Working Paper, Yale University, 2007.

Goldstein, Kenneth and Joel Rivlin, “Congressional and gubernatorial advertising, 2003-

2004,” The University of Wisconsin Advertising Project, The Department of Political Sci-

ence at The University of Wisconsin-Madison., 2007.

and , “Presidential advertising, 2003-2004,” The University of Wisconsin Advertising

Project, The Department of Political Science at The University of Wisconsin-Madison,

2007.

Gordon, Brett and Wesley Hartmann, “Structural Equilibrium Analysis of Political Ad-

vertising,” Working Paper, 2010.

Iaryczover, M. and M. Mattozzi, “The pro-Competitive Effect of Campaign Limits in Non-

Majoritarian Elections,” Caltech Working Paper, 2010.

Landi, Massimiliano and Chun Seng Yip, “Campaign Tactics and Citizens Electoral Deci-

sions,” Macroeconomics Working Papers, East Asian Bureau of Economic Research, 2006,

2006.10.

Lau, R., Lee Sigelman, and Ivy Brown Rovner, “The Effects of Negative Political Cam-

paigns: A Meta-Analytic Reassessment,” The Journal of Politics, 69, 1176-1209., 2007.

Levitt, Steven, “Using Repeat Challengers to Estimate the Effect of Campaign Spending on

Election Outcomes in the U.S. House,” Journal of Political Economy, 1994, 102, 777–798.

Lovett, M. and R. Shachar, “The Seeds of Negativity: Knowledge and Money,” Working

Paper, University of Rochester, 2010.

Malhotra, Neil and Erik Snowberg, “The 2008 Presidential Primaries through the Lens of

Prediction Markets,” Working Paper, 2010.

Mello, J. De and B. Da Silveira, “Campaign Advertising and Election Outcomes: Quasi-

Natural Experiment Evidence from Gubernatorial Elections in Brazil,” Review of Economic

Studies, forthcoming, 2011.

30

Page 32: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

NPR, “Negative Ads Fuel Surge In Spending,” http://www.npr.org/templates/story/story.php?storyId=129470444

2010.

Peterson and Djupe, “When primary campaigns go negative: The determinants of campaign

negativity,” Political Research Quarterly, 2005.

Polborn, Mattias K. and David T. Yi, “Informative Positive and Negative Campaigning,”

Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2006, 1, 351–371.

Prat, A., “Campaign Advertising and Voter Welfare,” Review of Economic Studies, 2002, 69(4),

999–1018.

Shacar, R. and B. Nalebuff, “Follow the Leader: Theory and Evidence on Political Partici-

pation,” American Economic Review, 1999, 89, 525–547.

Snyder, J.M., “Election Goals and Allocation of Campaign Resources,” Econometrica, 1989,

89, 525–547.

Stromberg, D., “How the Electoral College Influences Campaigns and Policy: The Probability

of Being Florida,” American Economic Review, 2008, 98(3), 769807.

31

Page 33: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

Appendix

We first show that if α = β and L = 2 then Pi and N ji approach 1

2 when η is arbitrarily

small. The problem for candidate k = 1 is

max(P1,N2

1 )

Π10

(P1

η+N12

)αΠ10

(P1

η+N12

)α+ Π20

(P2

η+N21

)α s.t. P1 +N21 = 1, (3)

and similarly for candidate k = 2. By substituting in the budget constraints we get

maxP1

1

1 +Π20Π10

(P2(η+1−P2)P1(η+1−P1)

)αmaxP2

1

1 +Π10Π20

(P1(η+1−P1)P2(η+1−P2)

)α .Note that the objectives are globally concave in P1 and P2, respectively. Furthermore they

attain a unique maximum at

Pi =1 + η

2and N j

i =1− η

2.

This result shows that when η is small a candidate is almost indifferent between engaging in

positive or negative advertising in a two-candidate race. We next show that this is not the case

in a three-candidate race. Namely, Pi > N ji when L = 3, even if α = β. After substituting in

the budget constraint, the problem for candidate k = 1 is

max(P1,N2

1 )

Π10

(P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)αΠ10

(P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)α+ Π20

(P2

η+N21 +N2

3

)α+ Π30

(P3

η+(1−P1−N21 )+N3

2

)α (4)

and similarly for candidates k = 2, 3.

The comparison between the vote share of candidate 1 (Π1) in (3) and (4) highlights the

spillover effect that rises when N = 3. For example, it is immediate to see that in (3) Π1 is

decreasing in N12 . On the contrary, in (4) Π1 still decreases in N1

2 and N13 , but it increases in N3

2

and N23 , which are the spillover effects of negative ads made by candidate 2 against candidate

3, and vice-versa.

By letting Π10 = Π20 = Π30 , and(

P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)α+(

P2

η+N21 +N2

3

)α+

(P3

η+(1−P1−N21 )+N3

2

)α= D,

we can rewrite (4) as30

30Assuming symmetry in the ex-ante market share and budget simplifies the exposition, but it is not neededfor our results.

32

Page 34: Negative Advertising and Political Competition - … ·  · 2018-04-20Negative Advertising and Political Competition Amit Gandhi ... observation - for the most ... tors in a political

max(P1,N2

1 )

(P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)αD (·)

.

Taking the first order condition with respect to P1 we obtain,

α(

P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)α1P1D − α

((P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)α1P1

+

(P3

η+(1−P1−N21 )+N3

2

)α1

η+(1−P1−N21 )+N3

2

)(P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)αD2

= 0,

which can be rewritten as,

α(

P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)α(1P1D −

(P1

η+N12 +N1

3

)α1P1−(

P3

η+(1−P1−N21 )+N3

2

)α1

η+(1−P1−N21 )+N3

2

)D2

= 0.

Since P = 0 cannot be optimal in equilibrium, α(P1/(η +N1

2 +N13 ))α> 0 and can be neglected.

Furthermore, in the symmetric equilibrium, D = 3 (P/(η + 2N))α. Hence,(P

η + 2N

)α( 2

P− 1

η + 1− P

)= 0.

Therefore, Pi = 2+2η3 and N j

i = 1−η6 for all i. It is easy to also show that the second first order

condition with respect to N21 is satisfied.

33