1
E very year billions of dollars in aid ow from rich nations to poor onesand right back again. Grants and loans pay for machinery and equipment imported from the in- dustrialized world, construction over- seen by U.S., European or Japanese en- gineering rms, consulting work done by international aid organizations and, not least, interest payments on previous loans. Meanwhile many of the nations that receive these enormous amounts of aid remain poor. Development economists will imme- diately point out that this situation (ex- cept for the intractable poverty) is ex- actly as it should be. After all, if a coun- trys needs can be met by its own or- ganizations and businesses, then it does not need help from abroad. Outside as- sistance should go to providing those goods and services that a country can- not provide for itself. Furthermore, aid comes in the form of hard currencyyen, marks or dol- larsthat can be used only for buying goods from the industrialized world. Even if aid organizations wanted to give grants in local money, they would have to acquire it by trading their currency, and so the recipients foreign exchange position would be precisely the same. In theory, development aid works to the benet of both the donor and recip- ient countries: the recipient gets a dam, steel mill or banking system, and the donor gets an immediate economic stim- ulus (from purchases of goods and ser- vices with the aid money) plus a new market if the development project pans out. Indeed, if the aid is in the form of a loan from the World Bank or some other multilateral organization, the orig- inal money spent earns interest and must eventually be repaid. Historians can point to cases where the theory has worked wonders. Dur- ing the 19th century, for example, the U.S. was a prime recipient of foreign loans. Railroads, canals, mines and fac- tories were built with huge infusions of European capital, and U.S. trade with Europe enriched both sides. After World War II, Marshall Plan dollars rebuilt Eu- rope, and the U.S. vaulted to preemi- nence in exports. So why dont things work so well to- day? Candidate causes abound: corrup- tion, incompetence and inappropriate projects top the lists of people at fund- ing agencies. Recipients, meanwhile, of- ten complain about tyingconditions on aid that dictate where the recipient can buy goods or whom it can hire to oversee projects. Such ties raise the suspicion that the purpose of aid is largely to subsidize rms in the donor country. Legislators in the U.S. and elsewhere often justify foreign aid budgets on the basis of the economic benets they will provide at home, and nations also use aid as a lever to open commercial markets. Economist Elliot Berg of Development Alternatives in Bethesda, Md., consid- ers such concerns ill founded. If the U.S. wants to subsidize U.S. rms, he says, it can do so by building bridges in Kentucky just as easily as by building them in Indonesia. Furthermore, tying allows donors to exercise control over the direction of a project and can help minimize corruption in the recipient country. Although most bilateral aid (grants and loans made directly from one na- tion to another) is tied, most multilat- eral aid (that dispensed by the World Bank and other international organi- zations) is not. Indeed, when competi- tive bids are solicited for projects fund- ed by the World Bank, local businesses may win jobs even if their bids are 15 percent higher than those of more es- tablished international rms. This pref- erence helps to develop management expertise in the recipient country, even if the local company still ends up pur- chasing most of its supplies on the in- ternational market. Even without explicit tying, the re- quirements of donor organizations may still shape development decisions. When economic ocials are determining the appropriate level of capital investment in their country, says Jim Boomgard of Development Alternatives, it makes lit- tle dierence to them what particular forms that investment takes. If this year the World Bank is into dams, he says, countries will propose building a dam. If microenterprise loans are the order of the day, they will set up rural credit cooperatives. There is every incentive to draw up big projects with little economic value, comments George Ayittey, a Ghanaian economist now at American University. He asserts that dams, generators and similar large installations have often served as visible symbols of assistance that gladden the hearts of donors rather than helping recipients. And in the ve years or more that a project may take to come to fruition, things happen: the government may be overthrown, a min- ister may be corrupt and demand 10 percent of all contracts, or prices may rise and $100 million becomes insu- cient to complete the project, so it is abandoned. In addition to the potential for dis- torting investment priorities, this kind of decision making has dangerous so- cial consequences, according to Gabriel Roth, a former World Bank economist. Regardless of whether a development project succeeds or fails, he asserts, it will increase the power of government ocials. The World Bank caused aid to ow for housing in Zambia, he recalls, and to no ones surprise all the houses went to supporters of the governing party. Roth contends that multilateral aid organizations should focus less on simply transferring funds and more on helping governments to create laws and institutions that assist investment. Government-to-government loans, Roth says, are particularly dangerous because they must be repaid regardless of whether the project they were in- tended to fund is successfully complet- ed. As a result, aid organizations have little nancial reason to lend money only for viable ideas. Last year an inter- nal World Bank study reportedly found that the banks proportion of prob- lem projects had more than doubled between 1981 and 1991; it now stands just under 40 percent. In contrast to the railroad bonds of the 19th century, it is not the investors in the industrialized world who bear the nancial risk of a project gone wrong. Rather it is the citizens of the nation that received the aid. Paul Wallich and Marguerite Holloway More Protable to Give Than to Receive? THE ANALYTICAL ECONOMIST 142 SCIENTIFIC AMERICAN March 1993 There is every incentive to draw up big projects with little economic value. Copyright 1993 Scientific American, Inc.

More Profitable to Give than to Receive?

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: More Profitable to Give than to Receive?

Every year billions of dollars in aidßow from rich nations to pooronesÑand right back again.

Grants and loans pay for machineryand equipment imported from the in-dustrialized world, construction over-seen by U.S., European or Japanese en-gineering Þrms, consulting work doneby international aid organizations and,not least, interest payments on previousloans. Meanwhile many of the nationsthat receive these enormous amountsof aid remain poor.

Development economists will imme-diately point out that this situation (ex-cept for the intractable poverty) is ex-actly as it should be. After all, if a coun-tryÕs needs can be met by its own or-ganizations and businesses, then it doesnot need help from abroad. Outside as-sistance should go to providing thosegoods and services that a country can-not provide for itself.

Furthermore, aid comes in the formof hard currencyÑyen, marks or dol-larsÑthat can be used only for buyinggoods from the industrialized world.Even if aid organizations wanted to givegrants in local money, they would haveto acquire it by trading their currency,and so the recipientÕs foreign exchangeposition would be precisely the same.

In theory, development aid works tothe beneÞt of both the donor and recip-ient countries: the recipient gets a dam,steel mill or banking system, and thedonor gets an immediate economic stim-ulus (from purchases of goods and ser-vices with the aid money) plus a newmarket if the development project pansout. Indeed, if the aid is in the form ofa loan from the World Bank or someother multilateral organization, the orig-inal money spent earns interest andmust eventually be repaid.

Historians can point to cases wherethe theory has worked wonders. Dur-ing the 19th century, for example, theU.S. was a prime recipient of foreignloans. Railroads, canals, mines and fac-tories were built with huge infusions ofEuropean capital, and U.S. trade withEurope enriched both sides. After WorldWar II, Marshall Plan dollars rebuilt Eu-rope, and the U.S. vaulted to preemi-nence in exports.

So why donÕt things work so well to-day? Candidate causes abound: corrup-

tion, incompetence and inappropriateprojects top the lists of people at fund-ing agencies. Recipients, meanwhile, of-ten complain about ÒtyingÓÑconditionson aid that dictate where the recipientcan buy goods or whom it can hire tooversee projects.

Such ties raise the suspicion that thepurpose of aid is largely to subsidizeÞrms in the donor country. Legislatorsin the U.S. and elsewhere often justifyforeign aid budgets on the basis of theeconomic beneÞts they will provide athome, and nations also use aid as alever to open commercial markets.

Economist Elliot Berg of DevelopmentAlternatives in Bethesda, Md., consid-ers such concerns ill founded. If theU.S. wants to subsidize U.S. Þrms, hesays, it can do so by building bridges inKentucky just as easily as by buildingthem in Indonesia. Furthermore, tyingallows donors to exercise control over

the direction of a project and can helpminimize corruption in the recipientcountry.

Although most bilateral aid (grantsand loans made directly from one na-tion to another) is tied, most multilat-eral aid (that dispensed by the WorldBank and other international organi-zations) is not. Indeed, when competi-tive bids are solicited for projects fund-ed by the World Bank, local businessesmay win jobs even if their bids are 15percent higher than those of more es-tablished international Þrms. This pref-erence helps to develop managementexpertise in the recipient country, evenif the local company still ends up pur-chasing most of its supplies on the in-ternational market.

Even without explicit tying, the re-quirements of donor organizations maystill shape development decisions. Wheneconomic oÛcials are determining theappropriate level of capital investmentin their country, says Jim Boomgard ofDevelopment Alternatives, it makes lit-

tle diÝerence to them what particularforms that investment takes. If Òthisyear the World Bank is into dams,Ó hesays, countries will propose building adam. If microenterprise loans are theorder of the day, they will set up ruralcredit cooperatives.

ÒThere is every incentive to draw upbig projects with little economic value,Ócomments George Ayittey, a Ghanaianeconomist now at American University.He asserts that dams, generators andsimilar large installations have oftenserved as Òvisible symbols of assistanceÓthat gladden the hearts of donors ratherthan helping recipients. And in the Þveyears or more that a project may taketo come to fruition, Òthings happen: thegovernment may be overthrown, a min-ister may be corrupt and demand 10percent of all contracts, or prices mayrise and $100 million becomes insuÛ-cient to complete the project, so it isabandoned.Ó

In addition to the potential for dis-torting investment priorities, this kindof decision making has dangerous so-cial consequences, according to GabrielRoth, a former World Bank economist.Regardless of whether a developmentproject succeeds or fails, he asserts, itwill increase the power of governmentoÛcials. The World Bank Òcaused aid toßowÓ for housing in Zambia, he recalls,Òand to no oneÕs surprise all the houseswent to supporters of the governingparty.Ó Roth contends that multilateralaid organizations should focus less onsimply transferring funds and more onhelping governments to create laws andinstitutions that assist investment.

Government-to-government loans,Roth says, are particularly dangerousbecause they must be repaid regardlessof whether the project they were in-tended to fund is successfully complet-ed. As a result, aid organizations havelittle Þnancial reason to lend moneyonly for viable ideas. Last year an inter-nal World Bank study reportedly foundthat the bankÕs proportion of Òprob-lemÓ projects had more than doubledbetween 1981 and 1991; it now standsjust under 40 percent.

In contrast to the railroad bonds ofthe 19th century, it is not the investorsin the industrialized world who bear theÞnancial risk of a project gone wrong.Rather it is the citizens of the nationthat received the aid.ÑPaul Wallich and Marguerite Holloway

More ProÞtable to Give Than to Receive?

THE ANALYTICAL ECONOMIST

142 SCIENTIFIC AMERICAN March 1993

ÒThere is every incentiveto draw up bigprojects with littleeconomic value.Ó

Copyright 1993 Scientific American, Inc.