27
Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary Migration in China and the One Child Policy * de la Rupelle, Maelys Deng Quheng Abstract Rural-urban migration in China plays an important role in China development and urbanization. Despite important imbalances across the territory, this migra- tion is mostly temporary. This striking feature can be related to institutional constraints, to agriculture seasonality, to unsecure property rights. In this paper, we provide an additional explanation, showing how family planning policies are impacting migrants’ decision, by constraining ulterior off-farm labor participation decision. No or few siblings means reduced resources in labour power at the house- hold level, which translates into higher constraints on individual decisions. Using the exogenous shift in fertility introduced by the One Child Policy, we compare the elder children born before and after its implementation. We find that individuals subject to this policy are experiencing shorter duration of migration. The Chinese case allows us to document precisely the impact of family size on migration. JEL Classification : D63, P48, O13, I20, J13, O1. Keywords : fertility, migration, household economics, China. * This paper has benefited from comments by Marc Gurgand, Terry Sicular, Nancy Qian, Xing Chun- bing, Sylvie D´ emurger, Philippe de Vreyer, Gilles Postel-Vinay, Tatiana Goetghebuer and Imane Chaara. PSE (Paris-Jourdan Sciences Economiques/Paris School of Economics), 48 boulevard Jourdan, 75014 Paris, France. Email: [email protected], phone: (+33)(0)143136314. CASS (Chinese Academy of Social Sciences), Yuetan Beixiaojie, Beijing 100732, China. Email: [email protected] 1

Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Migration Duration and Family Economics :

Temporary Migration in China and the One Child

Policy ∗

de la Rupelle, Maelys †

Deng Quheng‡

Abstract

Rural-urban migration in China plays an important role in China development

and urbanization. Despite important imbalances across the territory, this migra-

tion is mostly temporary. This striking feature can be related to institutional

constraints, to agriculture seasonality, to unsecure property rights. In this paper,

we provide an additional explanation, showing how family planning policies are

impacting migrants’ decision, by constraining ulterior off-farm labor participation

decision. No or few siblings means reduced resources in labour power at the house-

hold level, which translates into higher constraints on individual decisions. Using

the exogenous shift in fertility introduced by the One Child Policy, we compare the

elder children born before and after its implementation. We find that individuals

subject to this policy are experiencing shorter duration of migration. The Chinese

case allows us to document precisely the impact of family size on migration.

JEL Classification: D63, P48, O13, I20, J13, O1.

Keywords: fertility, migration, household economics, China.

∗This paper has benefited from comments by Marc Gurgand, Terry Sicular, Nancy Qian, Xing Chun-

bing, Sylvie Demurger, Philippe de Vreyer, Gilles Postel-Vinay, Tatiana Goetghebuer and Imane Chaara.†PSE (Paris-Jourdan Sciences Economiques/Paris School of Economics), 48 boulevard Jourdan, 75014

Paris, France. Email: [email protected], phone: (+33)(0)143136314.‡CASS (Chinese Academy of Social Sciences), Yuetan Beixiaojie, Beijing 100732, China. Email:

[email protected]

1

Page 2: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

1 Introduction

Beside having experienced impressive growth and drastic economic changes, China factors

markets display two striking macroeconomic features : a high rate of savings, and a high

share of temporary migrant workers. Regarding the former one, savings had increased

dramatically after the 1980s, skyrocketing to 37% of household income in the mid 1990s.

As for the latter, there were 140 million of rural-urban migrant workers in 2008, (according

to the National Bureau of Statistics1). Internal migration are not per se surprising - it

is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization. What is remarkable in the

Chinese case is the nature of these migrations : most of the migrants are temporary

migrants. Indeed, in a survey carried on in 2005 by the State Council Research Bureau

(see State Council Research Bureau (2006)), only 8.13% of the interviewed migrants

declare that they plan a long term stay at their migration destination. Two years later,

in 2008, the 5000 migrants surveyed by the RUMiCI survey are only 9.5% to say that,

would policy allowed, they would stay forever in cities.

These two striking features of the Chinese economy may find some of their origin in

China specificities regarding fertility patterns, that have been greatly affected by family

planning policies. Banerjee et al. (2010) have shown that the importance of savings rate

in urban area can be related to family planning programs. 40 % of the growth of savings

rate in the last three decades can be explained by the policies designed to curb population

growth.

In this paper, we show that the One Child Policy is a determinant of migration

temporality in rural China : a reduced number of siblings has an impact on the migration

patterns of individuals. The One Child Policy did reduce the total number of children

per family in rural area, though it was less effective than in urban areas. We find that

the cohorts with less siblings subsequently to family planning policies have systematically

experienced shorter duration of migration when they first migrated.

Family size has, theoretically, two opposing effects on migration. On the one hand, if

migration is used to diversify risk (Stark and Levhari (1982), Stark and Bloom (1985)),

one needs to migrate less if one has more siblings. Thus, individuals with fewer siblings

are more likely to migrate. On the other hand, if hired labor is not a good substitute for

the labor of households members, then fewer siblings may mean that an individual is less

likely to migrate. For some households’ needs, hired labor might be an inferior substitute,

like for example the care of elderly parents or children. Tending the farm might as well

requires household members’ labor, especially if their land rights are jeopardized by a

long absence, and if the high seasonality of agriculture results in shortages in farm labour

1See Li (2010)

2

Page 3: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

supply. Migration itself might be more difficult in the absence of migrating siblings: they

could provide information or advices (as shown by Kesztenbaum (2008)). In this paper,

we want to estimate the net of these two opposing forces.

This is difficult to investigate, both for econometric and practical reasons, linked to

the lack of appropriate data and to endogeneity concerns. Family size and migration

decision may be affected by a third factor. Parents with a smaller number of kids might

adopt different attitudes toward schooling decision. Migrating parents may have a specific

fertility, while their experience may help their children to migrate later on.

Using a unique survey of migrants conducted in fifteen cities of China in Spring 2008,

we deal with these endogeneity issues by using the family planning policies implemented

in China at the end of the 1970s, a period where migration were not allowed.

Our strategy, building upon Qian (2009), compares migration duration of first borns

belonging to cohorts born before and after the introduction of restrictive family planning

policies. The understanding of the family planning policies in China requires to take into

account their successive steps. A four-year birth spacing law was introduced in 1972. The

One Child Policy was implemented in 1980s. Combined with the former, the One Child

Policy was actually binding for the cohorts born in 1976, as stressed by Qian (2009). We

will therefore compare elder children born before and after 1976.

The results found are the following. Migrants with a lower probability of having

siblings have systematically shorter job duration when first migrating. Cohorts bound

by the One Child Policy migrate in average 3 months less than previous ones, while the

average first job duration is 14 months. To assess the relevance of our interpretation,

and to avoid capturing an other effect of the One Child Policy, namely its impact on sex

ratio, we also consider a sample with male elders only. We find that the difference goes

up to 4 months. We conclude with robustness checks and further comments.

The plan of this paper is the following. Section 2 provides elements on the institutional

context of rural China, regarding family planning policies, agricultural activities and

migration policies. Section 3 describes our data. Section 4 explains our identification

strategy. Section 5 displays our results.

2 Institutional Context

In this section, we will present briefly some institutional aspects relevant for our study,

regarding the family planning policies and the rural-urban migration.

3

Page 4: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

2.1 Family Planning Policies in China

After a period of policies promoting a high natality, the Chinese government started to

advocate family planning in the late 1950s. However, no effective birth control measures

were implemented before the 1970s. Introduced in 1972, the “Wan Xi Shao” Policy,

meaning “Later [age], longer [the spacing of births], fewer [number of children]”, was

encouraging four-year birth spacing, and was recommending three children per rural

couple.

The One Child Policy (OCP), implemented from 1978 to 1980, was actually announced

in 19792. Couples complying with the policy were entitled to a “one-child pledge” cer-

tificate and to the economic rewards associated, while “unplanned” birth were exposing

them to fines.

Because the One Child Policy was preceded by the four-year birth spacing law, its

effect started to appear for cohorts born slightly before the OCP, as shown by Qian

(2009). Households who had one child had to wait four years before the next child; if the

first birth occurred in the late 1970s, the One Child Policy stopped them from having a

second child. Qian (2009) uses the timing and the geography of the relaxation of the OCP

to show that its restrictive effect appears in 1976; the cohorts who gained an additional

sibling when the One Child Policy was relaxed were the cohorts born in 1976 and after.

Given the lack of enforcement and the rural preference for numerous families, the

One Child Policy actually bound families at two children rather than one. Kaufman

et al. (1989) report how officials eventually regarded a two-child limitation as an adequate

policy achievement, while other officials were suggesting that “if the government promotes

a one-child policy, then people will stop at two; if a two-child policy is promoted, then

people will stop at three”. The tiny number of households with only one child is further

explained by policy changes occurring afterwards.

All across China, the family planning policies increased female infanticide, forced

abortion and sterilization. After worries raised by the coercive means employed at the

local level, as well as the persistent social resistance to birth control, it was decided to

loosen these policies in the 1980s. In 1984, a second child was allowed for households

facing difficulties or whose first born was a girl, under the condition that a birth spacing

was respected, usually of three or four years. A few areas started to relax the One Child

Policy slightly before, in 1982 and 1983.

Many studies have shown that the birth control policies were responsible for much of

the drop in fertility rate in rural areas (Shultz and Zeng (1995) and McElroy and Yang

(2000)). While few rural households were found to have only one child, the planning

2Qian (2009)

4

Page 5: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

policies affected nonetheless their fertility pattern.

Statistical evidence To sum up, family planning policies of the 1970s curbed fertility

rate in rural China, reducing the potential number of siblings of rural individuals. We do

not have census data to show what exactly happened in terms of households fertility, as we

do not have detailed information on migrants’ siblings. Yet, more extensive information

on the cohorts born in the 1970s can be found in the rural sample of the RUMiCI project

(8000 households). Information on household’s 1970s demographic situation is partial, as

this survey has been conducted in 2008. Data on the number of children per household

are biased by deaths and household splittings. Luckily enough, we know the birth rank

of the surveyed individuals.

If family planning policies have impacted rural households fertility, we should observe

variation in the respective share of each birth rank by birth cohort. Births of high order

should diminish in cohorts constrained by family planning policies. We should see that

the share of children born as the first child increases. In Figure 1, we compute, for each

birth cohort, the proportion of first, second, and third and above children. We plot the

percentages obtained. We plot a similar graph for the male children in Figure 2.

20

30

40

50

Perc

enta

ge in the c

ohort

197619721960 1965 1970 1975 1980

Birth year of the cohort considered

elder child second

third and above

all - rural sample

share of individuals of a given birth rank by cohort

Figure 1: Share of birth ranks within birth cohort

The first remark is in line with what has been previously said regarding policies

implementation in rural areas : the One Child Policy did not translate into cohorts of

only-child, where all the newborns would be the first child of the households. There are

many children who were born as second child in 1980 : the share of second order births

remains quite stable until the early 1980s. Yet, we see that in 1980 there is a clear drop

in the share of birth of higher order, which becomes almost null.

The second remark is that the birth spacing policies implemented before have been

5

Page 6: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

20

30

40

50

Pe

rce

nta

ge

in

th

e c

oh

ort

197619721960 1965 1970 1975 1980

Birth year of the cohort considered

elder child second

third and above

men - rural sample

share of individuals of a given birth rank by cohort

Figure 2: Share of birth ranks by cohort - male

effective. The share of births of third order and above starts to decrease in 1972, and

does even more so four years after, in 1976.

In Figure 1, we see that although the major part of births in the 1960s were occurring

in families having already two or more kids, (they account for more than 40 % of births),

there is a clear shift in the mid 1970s, and 1976 is the first year where the share of first

borns is higher than the share of births of third or higher order. If we restrict our sample

to males, (Figure 2), differences are made clearer. Again, a sharp decrease takes place at

the end of the 1970s.

20

30

40

50

60

Pe

rce

nta

ge

in

th

e c

oh

ort

197619721960 1965 1970 1975 1980

Birth year of the cohort considered

elder child second

third and above

all- migrant sample

share of individuals of a given birth rank by cohort

Figure 3: Share of birth ranks within cohort among rural-urban migrants

6

Page 7: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

20

30

40

50

60

Perc

enta

ge in t

he c

ohort

197619721960 1965 1970 1975 1980

Birth year of the cohort considered

elder child second

third and above

men- migrant sample

share of individuals of a given birth rank by cohort

Figure 4: Share of birth ranks within cohort among rural-urban male migrants

We might be worried that the rural sample fails to account for households whose

members are all rural migrants. First, given the size of rural population, it is unlikely that

the clear patterns we observe are driven by migration. Still, we provide similar graphics

for the different cohorts of the rural-migrant sample. In rural-migrant population, we see

as well that individuals born after 1980 are more likely to be the elder child. The share

of first born children increases slightly after 1976, as the figures 3 and 4 show.

2.2 Migration, Land and Family Help

Various institutions restrict rural-urban migration.

Land rights uncertainty affects the mobility of rural outmigrants, as shown by Lohmar

(1999), Shi (2004) and de la Rupelle et al. (2009).

Migration decision may be affected by parents health, as shown by Giles and Ren

(2007). In rural area, help given to origin households is mostly done through labor

exchange (Lee and Xiao (1998)). The harvest season is a critical period, where all families

may lack labor, and where therefore the help of relatives can be of crucial importance.

Not only markets are imperfect; but China institutional system may also increase the role

plaid by family size. Through the household registration system, rural households are

granted use rights on a piece of land, for which they have to fulfill quota requirements.

Household land area depends on household size and household number of laborers; yet,

an increased family size, through economies of scale and deeper inclusion in village’s labor

exchange, releases somehow the constraints attached with tax duties.

Restrictions on migration give additional value to household’s resources in labor

7

Page 8: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

power.

3 Data

The data used in this paper comes from the RUMiCI (Rural-Urban Migration in China

and Indonesia) Project3.

The main originality of this project relies in the method used. The sampling frame

was based on a first census conducted among migrant workers at their workplaces. City

areas (including suburban areas where factories are located) were divided into blocks of

500 × 500 meter. In the randomly selected blocks 4, all the workplaces were surveyed.

This census was then used to sample migrants, whose household was also surveyed5.

An important advantage is that we have information on a crucial step of a migrant

experience : the very first one. We know the duration of the first job as migrant. Un-

derstanding the conditions of the primary migration experience is interesting, and it can

help to avoid troubles arising when comparing individuals at various time in their life

cycle, who have heterogeneous background as migrants. The experience gained and the

contacts established during the first job as migrant may shape a migrant trajectory.

The data provides the duration, in months, of the first job as a migrant. We consider

it is a good proxy for the duration of the first migration, as staying in cities without

employment is more costly than coming back. In the years during which most of the

first migration experiences occurred, (second half of the 1990s decade), migration poli-

cies were quite restrictive. Even recently, despite considerable loosening of institutional

constraints, the massive shutdowns in the aftermath of the financial crisis caused many

laid off migrants to come back to their origin village.

The main inconvenient is that we do not have the total number of siblings in our data.

We know only individual’s birth rank. Our identification strategy will have to take into

account this shortcoming.

The sample we use is of 5 000 rural-urban migrants, who were surveyed in 15 cities 6.

3This project, funded by the Australian Research Council, the Australian Agency for International

Development (AusAID) and the Ford Foundation, was initiated as a collaboration between the Australian

National University and the Beijing Normal University.4(accounting for 12 % of each city size)5More information on the sampling method are available at the following address :

http://rumici.anu.edu.au/6Shanghai, Guangzhou, Shenzhen, Dongguan, Nanjing, Wuxi, Hangzhou, Ningbo, Wuhan,

Chongqing, Chengdu, Hefei, Bangbu, Luoyang and Zhenzghou.

8

Page 9: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

4 Empirical Strategy

If family size affects migration, its effect is nonetheless hard to identify properly. Some

characteristics may jointly determine fertility decision and ulterior migration of the chil-

dren. For example, it could be that parents who have a smaller number of kids adopt

different attitudes toward schooling decision, that will later have an impact on their

situation on the labor market.

Interestingly enough, before the 1980s, migration was prohibited, and its control was

strictly enforced. The loosening of the structures of collective economy in the 1980s

relaxed somehow the constraints affecting migration, without legalizing it. Therefore,

the parents who were affected by the family planning programs in the 1970s had very

little - if none - experience as migrant. So we should not worry about this endogeneity

channel.

To deal with other endogeneity sources, we take advantage of China family planning

policies that were introduced during the seventies. The introduction of these policies

produced an exogenous shock on family size. The number of siblings decreased for cohorts

born in the 1970s.

We will compare the elder born before and after the implementation of family planning

policy. There are three reasons for us to focus on the first born children. First, as birth

rank may affect individuals trajectories, and as birth ranks of high order are made rarer

by family planning policies, it would be misleading to simply compare people born before

and after their implementation : we might capture the effect of a higher share of first

born in the population. Second, the number of siblings may have a different impact if

they are older or younger. Last, we can consider that the “treatment effect” of family

planning policies is higher for the elders. It is true that all birth orders are affected

by a reduced family size. All the individuals born after 1976 should have been the last

child of their parents. But the higher the birth rank is, the higher the chance that the

family has already reached the desired number of children, and is not constrained by

the policy. Moreover, the bigger the family is, the higher the probability is to select a

family in an area where the planning policies were poorly implemented. The population

of elder children includes all the households who were the most heavily constrained by

the planning policies.

Let us note l the duration of the first job spell of a migrant. Our identification strategy

leads us to focus on the following equation :

l = β(elder × postp) + αelder + δpostp +Xγ + ε (1)

elder is a dummy indicating whether the individuals is the elder or not. postp indi-

9

Page 10: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

cates that he was born after 1976 and the change in planning policies. X are relevant

characteristics, while ε is the error term. The interaction term (elder×postp) is our main

term of interest, as it indicates the group of individuals who were the most subjects to

family planning policies. If the number of siblings eases the family constraints weighing

on migration decision, we would expect the coefficient of the interaction term, β to be

negative. In such a setting, time-invariant differences across birth ranking will be differ-

enced out by the comparison across time. Then, changes across time which affect elder

and non elder similarly will be differenced out by the comparison across birth ranking.

As we look at the duration of job spells, it is important to recall that labor market

seasonality may have a direct impact on it; regarding the business cycle, different start-

ing period may bring systematically different opportunities regarding job length. For

instance, if a given month is a high period of long term workers recruitment, a different

starting month will bring systematically a different working duration. To control for

urban labor markets seasonality, we introduce job starting month fixed effects.

The duration of the first migration spell of a migrant who has started to work in

month m can be written as follow:

l = β(elder × postp) + αelder + δpostp + ψm + γX + ε (2)

ψm is the month fixed effect. Of course, it only controls for trends affecting all migrants

in a similar way.

However, it could be that individuals born after 1976 were more likely to face a

difficult year, or a change in business cycles trend. They would have had similar patterns

than previous cohorts, starting at a similar age, leaving their job after a similar duration.

Simply, by entering one year later in the labor market, they were more likely to experience

a specific downturn, and to be constrained to leave the city. If it was the case, our estimate

would confound the effect of change in macroeconomic situation with the effect of family

planning policies.

To control for this potential problem, we introduce dummy variables for the year in

which migrants left their job, φt. The last equation we consider is the following :

l = β(elder × postp) + αelder + δpostp + ψm + φt + γX + ε (3)

We estimate these equations using a Tobit model, therefore relying on the assumption

of errors normality.

10

Page 11: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

5 Results

The rural-urban migrant population surveyed in the RUMiCI project allows us to study

the impact of the family planning policies, as the subsamples of migrants born before

and after the implementation of family planning policies are both of reasonable size. The

migrants sampled in 2008 were 30.5 years old in average. Figure 3 plots the density of

the birth year of household heads. 40% of them were born before 1976; the median year

of birth is 1980. Besides these 5007 migrants, all the individuals staying with the migrant

have been surveyed7. Figure 4 plots the density of the birth year of all household members

staying with the head. When excluding the children under the age of 16, the median value

of the sample is 1978, while the share of individuals born before 1976 increased at 45 %.

To keep cohorts big enough to allow comparisons, but homogeneous enough for the

goal of our study, our sample is restricted to the cohorts born after 1962. These cohorts

were born after the years of natality promotion of the early 1950s, and, more important,

after the Great Chinese Famine (1958-1961) which followed the Great Leap Forward and

caused a severe drop in the birth rate, while the death rate increased sharply. Moreover,

these cohorts started to work after the end of the Cultural Revolution (1976), which

makes them even more comparable. In a subsequent set of regression, we also consider

an even more homogeneous sample by keeping all individuals who have started to work

in a liberalizing economy, by considering cohorts born after 1970.

Last, we do not consider individuals born after planning policies relaxation. As the

first local government to issue permits for a second child did so in 1982 (see Qian (2009)),

we keep only cohorts that were born before 1981.

Complete information on our dependent variable is obviously only available for people

who are not in their first migration spell anymore. As the ending date is crucial for our

study, we choose to focus on individuals whose current job is not the first job as a

migrant. They account for almost two thirds of the 1962-1981 cohorts. The average

migration duration of their first job as migrant amounts to 14 months. Figure 5 plot the

distribution of migration duration, for migrants who were born before and after 1976.

First, migrants born before after 1976 have, in average, a shorter duration of migration.

Second, the distribution is less smooth, and exhibits more seasonality. Given the hight

seasonality of agriculture, this could signal that migrants born after 1976 are more likely

to come back home for agricultural reasons. Migrants born after 1976 are less likely to

have a first job spell ending after 18 to 21 months. A second mode is visible at 24 months,

while there is almost no change for migrants born before 1976.

As our focus is on temporary migration, and to allow more comparability, we do not

7They amount to 3400 individuals, 2500 of them being above 16.

11

Page 12: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

0.0

2.0

4.0

6d

en

sity:

du

ratio

n_

firs

tjo

b

0 20 40 60number of months

born after 1976 born before 1976

sample restriction : job as migrant started after 1980 and lasted less than 5 years

months - 1961-1981 cohorts

Duration of the first job as migrant

Figure 5: Density of the duration of migrants first stay in cities

consider spells exceeding 5 years, which represent a small share (less than 4%). Our

dependent variable is therefore censored at 1 and 60 months.

As written before, the equation we estimate is the following :

l = β(elder × postp) + αelder + δpostp + ψ + φ+Xγ + ε (4)

The relevant characteristics, the X, includes characteristics at the individual, house-

hold and village level. The individual characteristics that should matter in explaining

wage level and employment opportunities are the years of education, the gender, the age

when first migrating. Then, we control for household ethnicity, which affects employment

and migration opportunities. The main village characteristic we consider is the geograph-

ical condition of village, whether it is plain, hilly or mountainous. Village topography, a

good proxy for its remoteness, captures difference in educational opportunities, economic

dynamism and connection to transportation networks and urban markets.

Table 6 in the Appendix displays the descriptive statistics, and provide as well statis-

tics for both groups of elder and non elder. It is difficult to interpret differences across

groups, as they also capture differences in age and in family types (as individuals of

higher birth ranking are belonging to more numerous families...). Table 1 displays the

regression results.

From the first regression we run, we see that the interaction term between being the

elder child and being born after 1976 has a negative and significant effect. An exogenous

decrease in the number of younger siblings has led first born individuals to shorten their

migration duration by two months. Given that the average duration of migration among

12

Page 13: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Table 1: Migration duration and family sizeMigration duration and family size

Dependent variable : first job duration as migrant (months). Tobit model.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

first reg with interaction term with land final year dummy head only

education 0.387*** 0.393*** 0.347*** 0.252** 0.167

[0.120] [0.120] [0.129] [0.127] [0.152]

male -2.219*** -2.200*** -2.366*** -1.776*** -2.124**

[0.602] [0.601] [0.637] [0.623] [0.849]

age at start -0.152*** -0.152*** -0.176*** -0.789*** -0.701***

[0.0524] [0.0523] [0.0550] [0.0956] [0.118]

elder -0.743 0.297 0.382 0.393 -0.357

[0.624] [0.822] [0.862] [0.842] [1.017]

born after 1976 -3.622*** -2.801*** -2.186*** -8.170*** -6.974***

[0.666] [0.789] [0.828] [1.121] [1.357]

minority 0.363 0.230 -1.492 -1.115 -1.750

[2.109] [2.108] [2.257] [2.201] [2.537]

elder X born after 1976 -2.426* -3.004** -3.151** -3.457**

[1.252] [1.313] [1.279] [1.537]

log hh land -0.940* -0.993** -0.759

[0.510] [0.499] [0.593]

hometown geography yes yes yes yes yes

starting month dummies yes yes yes yes yes

final year dummies no no no yes yes

Constant 17.15*** 16.77*** 17.88*** 46.45*** 45.15***

[2.103] [2.110] [2.234] [12.37] [12.74]

Observations 1789 1789 1586 1586 1118

Pseudo R2 0.005 0.005 0.006 0.015 0.015

Standard errors in brackets

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sample restricted to 1962-1981 cohorts whose first job initiated after 1980 and lasted less than 5 years

13

Page 14: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

the sample considered is 14 months, it is a non negligible effect.

The other variables have non surprising effects. Education plays a positive role on

duration, though a small one, implying that more educated migrants are also more stable

in their first working experience as a migrant. The dummy male has a negative and

significant effect. We believe that male migrants shorten their migration to participate

in agricultural work, more than female migrants.

If household involvement in agricultural work matters, we should find a sharper effect

when excluding the migrants whose households do not use any farmland, and may there-

fore have more flexible work schedules. To test this hypothesis, we drop the 200 migrants

coming from a household who does not hold any land, and we control for the logarithm of

land per person in the family. 8 The regression is presented in the third column of Table

1. In this regression, the coefficient of the term of interest is more significant, which is

consistent with our interpretation.

As mentioned in the previous section, such a setting fails to control properly for

business cycles or year specific shocks. It would be worrisome if elders, having migrating

earlier, were more likely to face this special year, either at their destination area or at

their home village, that would have require them to go back home. Our specification fails

to capture shocks affecting differently elder and younger siblings both born after 1976.

Therefore, we add dummies controlling for the year in which the migrant interrupted

his job. The regression is presented in the column four of Table 1. Our results remain

unchanged.

In all regressions, we have considered all the surveyed individuals : the migrants

selected through the sampling process, and the household members living with them.

They might be migrants’ kids or spouse. In the regression displayed in the fifth column

of Table 1, we restrict our sample to the initial migrants sample. The column is labeled

“head only” 9. Our results hold : the coefficient of the interaction term is still negative

and significant at the 5% level.

8Though the mean of land endowment in origin household is at around two mu per person (One mu

is equal to 666,67 m2 (25,8m × 25,8m)), around 40 migrants of our sample rely on 10 mu and more per

person. We take the logarithm so that our findings will not be driven by families relying on a big amount

of land.9It is important to note that this term does not refer to intra-household decision making process but

to the survey sampling frame.

14

Page 15: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

5.1 Robustness checks

5.1.1 Alternative samples

Sector specific shocks When interpreting these results, one may want to know whether

this shortened duration is reflecting macroeconomic shocks or if it is the result of a choice.

Luckily enough, we know the condition under which the job ended, namely whether

the job was left voluntarily, or not. There is no reason to believe that a firm would

prefer to fire employees without siblings rather than employees with a numerous family.

Although mechanisms are not very clear, we could imagine that if elder versus non elder

are employed in very different types of sector, and if a specific sectoral shock decreases

considerably job duration for the youngest cohorts, it would impact the coefficient of

the interaction term. One way to check that we are not actually capturing differences

in sectoral shocks is to drop the 300 migrants in our regression sample who did not left

voluntarily their job. If the effect disappears, this will put into question our interpretation.

If the effect persists, though it will not rule out alternative explanation, at least it will

be consistent with our explanation. When we exclude them, we see that our results are

holding, as shown in Table 2. The coefficient of interaction term is still significant at the

5% level.

Gender A more serious concern relates to the main characteristic that changed for

elder who were born before and after the implementation of the One Child Policy : the

gender. The One Child Policy had an impact on the sex ratio, it increased the practice of

female infanticide or selective abortion. Our result may capture the fact that babies born

after 1976 were mostly males. We are then just capturing a change in gender composition

within cohort. However, in 1976, only the 4-year birth spacing policies was enforced - the

One Child Policy was to be announced and implemented four years later. The households

did not know that their baby was meant to be the only one, so sex selection was not as

dramatic as in the early 1980s. It does not mean that sex selection did not occur, but

there is no reason to believe that it suddenly increased between 1975 and 1976. Last, if

birth spacing has given rise to sex selection, then it would have started in 1972, when the

policy was implemented, not in 1976.

Moreover, in the 1980s, planning policies were partially relaxed in rural areas, allowing

families with only one girl to have a second child. As a result, first born women born after

1976 have usually gained a sibling afterwards; Qian (2009) confirms it. The treatment

effect captured by our term of interest is therefore weaker on female elder. So not only

we hope to obtain a significant coefficient for our interacted term, but we hope also it

will have a bigger magnitude.

15

Page 16: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Table 2: Migration duration and family size when job was left voluntarilyMigration duration and family size - Job was left voluntarily

Dependent variable : first job duration as migrant (months). Tobit model.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

with land final year dummies male only male head only

education 0.273** 0.184 0.187 0.102

[0.135] [0.134] [0.173] [0.183]

male -2.187*** -1.469**

[0.664] [0.651]

age at start -0.176*** -0.793*** -0.738*** -0.726***

[0.0585] [0.101] [0.128] [0.141]

elder 0.444 0.492 1.274 0.536

[0.912] [0.890] [1.124] [1.221]

born after 1976 -2.547*** -8.669*** -9.038*** -8.655***

[0.863] [1.173] [1.499] [1.621]

elder X born after 1976 -2.690** -2.836** -4.214** -4.144**

[1.368] [1.331] [1.668] [1.819]

minority -1.107 -0.932 -2.365 -3.124

[2.303] [2.241] [2.765] [2.880]

log hh land -1.025* -1.050** -0.224 -0.0593

[0.531] [0.519] [0.637] [0.691]

hometown geography yes yes yes yes

starting month dummies yes yes yes yes

final year dummies no yes yes yes

Constant 18.77*** 17.27 15.00 33.66***

[2.340] [11.90] [11.78] [6.609]

Observations 1452 1452 897 779

Pseudo R2 0.006 0.015 0.016 0.017

Standard errors in brackets

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Sample restricted to 1962-1981 cohorts whose first job initiated after 1980; lasted less than 5 years; was left voluntarily

16

Page 17: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

We run regressions restricted to male migrants, that we present in the column 3 and

4 of Table 2. Our results remain unchanged, and the effect is stronger.

Agriculture The principal concern we have is related to the accuracy of our inter-

pretation. We have argued that agricultural work was of crucial importance; we run

additional regressions to check that this is actually the case. First, migration duration

will be shortened in order to help the household during the peak agricultural season only

if the family is actually farming its land. Households who have given away their land to

neighbors, or who are subcontracting it should be far less demanding than households

working on their plot. Their might be other reasons constraining migrants’ decision and

leading individuals with less siblings to come back earlier; yet, as we suspect that needs

related to agricultural work are of primary importance for many rural households, the

impact of the interacted term should be less significant for families who do not have

these needs. We run two regressions, restricting our sample first to migrants whose land

is farmed by family, second to migrants whose land has been subcontracted or given away.

The results, displayed in Table 3, are consistent with our interpretation. In the sample

where land is subcontracted or given away, standard errors are much higher than in the

sample where land is farmed by family. The coefficient does not changed its value, but it

is not significant anymore. One of the reason is that our sample size is smaller. However,

other regressions with small sample size keep the coefficient significance (see below).

Similarly, if our reasoning is correct, then we should find a stronger effect for the

migrants who were likely to have participated in agricultural work before migrating.

If their family lacks labor power, then the migrants were probably already involved in

farming activities when they were living in their home village. They would not have then

left their home during the harvest season, nor slightly before. We remove the individuals

who have left home between June and November, a period of intensive agriculture activity.

These individuals were not constrained by household agricultural requirements the year

during which they left. The coefficient of the interaction term conveys a stronger impact;

it is even more significant. Restricting further our sample by considering only men gives

further support. (See column 3 and 4 of Table 3.)

17

Page 18: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Table 3: Farming work and migrationRobustness check: farming work and migration

Dependent variable : first job duration as migrant (months). Tobit model.

who does the farming work? migrant left home

before June or after November

Land is : did not leave during peak season

(1) (2) (3) (4)

VARIABLES farmed by family subcontracted, given away all men only

education 0.125 0.364 0.141 0.105

[0.160] [0.247] [0.148] [0.192]

male -1.823** -0.269 -0.834

[0.750] [1.287] [0.731]

age at start -0.791*** -0.909*** -0.896*** -0.848***

[0.140] [0.177] [0.113] [0.146]

elder 1.485 0.0558 1.383 2.986**

[1.108] [1.649] [1.001] [1.274]

born after 1976 -6.715*** -8.751*** -9.265*** -9.828***

[1.374] [2.480] [1.317] [1.700]

elder X born after 1976 -3.788** -3.825 -4.303*** -5.702***

[1.509] [2.919] [1.510] [1.901]

minority 3.761 -7.354* 1.422 1.850

[2.821] [4.401] [2.750] [3.660]

log hh land -1.006* -1.641 -0.681 0.270

[0.606] [1.011] [0.587] [0.731]

hometown geography yes yes yes yes

starting month yes yes yes yes

final year yes yes yes yes

Constant 44.89*** 52.01*** 18.73 18.11

[12.19] [9.118] [11.61] [11.49]

Observations 924 447 1081 662

Pseudo R2 0.016 0.028 0.016 0.020

Standard errors in brackets

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Sample restricted to 1962-1981 cohorts whose first job initiated after 1980; lasted less than 5 years

Additional sample restriction is indicated in column header

18

Page 19: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

5.1.2 Placebo regressions

Yet, a question remains. Our results seem to be related to family needs, notably in terms

of agricultural work. Do we actually capture the effect of family planning policies, or do

we confound it with broad changes that occurred after the opening of the economy? It

could be that individuals born after 1976 were more likely to face a difficult year, or a

change in business cycles trend.

Younger and elder cohorts could also have had different experiences, strongly affecting

their migration opportunities. For example, the children born in 1976 and after were

more likely to be educated in a different context, and to enter primary schools in the

1980s. After the reforms, educational quality changed: rural enrollment rates decreased

substantially, while many rural schools of low quality were shut down (Hannum et al.

(2007)). This could be worrisome if it affected elder children in a specific way. If the elder

child was the only one to be educated, then a change in education quality would affect

elder and non elder differently. However, the schools’ shut downs mainly affected junior

secondary schools (Hannum et al. (2007)). As recalled by Qian (2009), the degradation

of education quality was important for middle-schools and highschools, while the change

in primary education was negligible.

The sample was chosen in order to be able to keep comparable cohorts. However,

the pre-1970 cohorts may have started to work before liberalization process initiates; to

further check that our effect still holds for cohorts more similar, we run a few regressions

on a restricted sample, only taking into account the 1970-1981 cohorts. All these cohorts

may have had comparable middle-school education. Results are holding, as shown in

column one and two of Table 4.

Our effect is therefore not explained by differences between 1960s and 1970s cohorts,

and holds when doing our investigation within the 1970s cohorts.

To deal with similar concerns on specific time trends affecting elder, we run a set of

Tobit regressions, keeping everything identical but the year used to compare elder cohorts

across two groups. We expect that the coefficient of the interaction term would not be

significant for these “placebo” years.

First, we consider the full sample. The effect previously obtained is driven by the

comparison across younger and older cohorts, so we should still find an effect when

splitting the sample for other years, as there will still be a majority of unconstrained

people in the cohorts born before the “placebo” year.

So in a second step, we will drop all migrants born after 1976. The coefficient obtained

should be very different.

19

Page 20: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Table 4: Migration duration and family size - 1970-1981 cohortsMigration duration and family size - 1970-1981 cohorts

Dependent variable : first job duration as migrant (months). Tobit model.

(1) (2) (3)

final year dummies head only male only

education -0.0760 -0.107 0.0433

[0.145] [0.173] [0.188]

male -1.716** -1.905**

[0.687] [0.917]

age at start -2.213*** -2.031*** -2.030***

[0.183] [0.218] [0.227]

elder 0.804 0.204 1.051

[1.078] [1.284] [1.330]

born after 1976 -14.21*** -12.70*** -13.85***

[1.339] [1.597] [1.658]

elder X born after 1976 -3.464** -3.855** -4.418**

[1.413] [1.682] [1.758]

minority 1.566 1.925 1.064

[2.304] [2.639] [2.880]

log hh land -0.888 -0.640 -0.376

[0.546] [0.645] [0.662]

hometown geography yes yes yes

starting month dummies yes yes yes

final year dummies yes yes yes

Constant 45.59*** 32.28*** 29.88***

[11.62] [11.39] [8.571]

Observations 1164 820 719

Pseudo R2 0.025 0.026 0.026

Standard errors in brackets

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sample restricted to 1970-1981 cohorts whose first job initiated after 1980 and lasted less than 5 years

20

Page 21: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

In the figure 6, we plot the coefficients of the interaction term (elder)*(born after year

Y) obtained for different years Y. The only year exhibiting a coefficient significant at the

5% level is 1976.

In the figure 7, we do the same, but restrict our sample to individuals born before

1976. Thus we drop the individuals affected by the One Child Policy. We do not obtain

significant coefficients anymore. Even more interestingly, the coefficient value is positive,

and it seems to follow an increasing trend.

Then, we plot similar figures for the population of male only, which should be more

affected by family planning policies. In figure 8, two years exhibit significant coefficients

: 1976 and 1972. The result is interesting, as in 1972 the four-year birth spacing law was

implemented. This shows that our effect is related to family planning policies. When we

look at the results obtained on the sample of male migrants born before 1976, displayed

in figure 9, the comparison is very striking.

Figure 6: Coefficient of the interaction term between being an elder and belonging to

cohorts born after the year x. Along with the x axis, the year used as a “placebo”,

splitting the two samples, varies.

21

Page 22: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Figure 7: Coefficient of the interaction term between being an elder and belonging to

cohorts born after the year x. Along with the x axis, the year used as a “placebo”,

splitting the two samples, varies. Sample restricted to migrants born before 1976.

Figure 8: Coefficient of the interaction term between being an elder and belonging to

cohorts born after the year x. Along with the x axis, the year used as a “placebo”,

splitting the two samples, varies. Male only

22

Page 23: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Figure 9: Coefficient of the interaction term between being an elder and belonging to

cohorts born after the year x. Along with the x axis, the year used as a “placebo”,

splitting the two samples, varies. Male born before 1976 only.

Migration location Finally, we may be concerned by the fact that job durations of

migrants are shorter because they prefer to leave their place of work in order to search for

jobs in other cities. Indeed, in Bhattacharya (1990)’s theoretical framework, migration

temporariness is explained by a search process in various locations. Data provides us

with the number of cities/towns where individuals have ever migrated for work purpose.

We run regressions with this variable as dependent variable, both with OLS and Tobit

model. Our variable of interest has no impact on the number of cities that a person

has ever migrated to. Therefore, shorter migration duration can not be related to an

increased number of migration locations.

5.2 Comment on sample selection

As mentioned before, we have been doing our study on migrants whose current job is not

their first job as a migrant. This implies a sample selection along two dimensions. First,

among the urban migrants, we do not consider permanent migrants. As said before, a

definitive settling in an urban area is difficult and therefore often out of reach for most

rural outmigrants. Nevertheless, migrants who never came back home will not be included

in our sample. Second, we do not account for temporary migrants who may migrate only

once during their working life, and never come back in a city afterwards. It can be the

case if the first experience as a migrant was a bad experience (if for example they did

not get paid at the end, as it could happen for the first generation of migrants, whose

working conditions were especially harsh) or after a dramatic change in their household

23

Page 24: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

situation at home.

Regarding the former concern, a first way to answer it is to include in our sample the

migrants we had dropped and run similar regressions. The dependent variable becomes

much noisier, especially as the survey was not done at the same month for all. Most

of migrant households were interviewed in May or April (56% of the households were

surveyed in May; 32% in April), still, 11% of them were surveyed in March, June, and

even August for a handful of them. To account for these issues, duration models would

be more appropriate. The use of such models is planned for the next step of our research

project. The Tobit model already allows us to obtain promising results. The main change

made from previous regression is that an other dummy is added to the set of dummies

indicating the year in which the migration spell we terminated. It equals to one when

the migration spell “ended” after the survey was done. The last table, Table 5, shows

that the term of interest is still negative and significant.

Regarding the latter concern, one solution would consist in extending our analysis

to the rural sample of the RUMiCI survey. The short term migrants who had only one

experience as a migrant could, hopefully, be observed in this sample.

Last, an other interesting direction of research is to provide empirical elements showing

the relevance of the first migration spell in migrants trajectories.

24

Page 25: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Table 5: Sample including individuals whose current job is their first jobMigration duration and family size - Including unfinished migration spells

Dependent variable : first job duration as migrant (months). Tobit model.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Final year dummy With land Male Male heads

education 0.232** 0.204* 0.324** 0.260

[0.115] [0.123] [0.159] [0.168]

male -0.899 -0.808

[0.563] [0.599]

age at start -1.033*** -1.065*** -0.914*** -0.908***

[0.0831] [0.0877] [0.115] [0.124]

elder 0.679 0.750 1.576 0.823

[0.761] [0.802] [1.022] [1.099]

born after 1976 -10.36*** -10.05*** -8.527*** -7.883***

[1.031] [1.086] [1.408] [1.499]

elder X born after 1976 -2.574** -2.864** -4.575*** -4.072**

[1.173] [1.237] [1.576] [1.700]

minority 0.979 -1.303 -1.883 -2.231

[2.016] [2.191] [2.646] [2.692]

log hh land -0.933** -0.478 -0.305

[0.466] [0.577] [0.614]

origin village geography yes yes yes yes

starting month dummies yes yes yes yes

final year dummies yes yes yes yes

Constant 19.76 20.22 16.08 20.87***

[13.02] [12.93] [12.64] [6.223]

Observations 2305 2039 1186 1019

Pseudo R2 0.035 0.036 0.038 0.034

Standard errors in brackets

* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Sample restricted to 1962-1981 cohorts whose first job initiated after 1980

25

Page 26: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

6 Appendix

Table 6: Descriptive statistics and birth rank

Individuals All Are Are notthe elder the elder

Variables Mean St. Dev. Mean St. Dev. Mean St. Dev.

Individual characteristicseducation (years) 8.75 2.513 9.2 2.509 8.54 2.487male 0.62 0.486 0.61 0.488 0.62 0.484elder 0.32 0.467 1 0 0 0born after 1976 0.39 0.487 0.47 0.5 0.35 0.477Household characteristicsland (mu) 1.94 2.121 1.99 2.282 1.92 2.041from an ethnic minority 0.02 0.02 0.02Village characteristicsplain 0.48 0.49 0.48hills 0.29 0.3 0.29mountains 0.23 0.21 0.23First migrant jobduration (months) 14.62 11.968 14.1 11.442 14.87 12.205age at start 23.14 6.043 22.91 5.792 23.25 6.158starting month 5.35 3.014 5.5 3.041 5.28 2.999year of job ending 1996.69 5.466 1997.29 5.035 1996.41 5.638job left voluntarily 0.91 0.28 0.93 0.263 0.91 0.287

Observations 1789 574 1215

Sample restricted to 1962-1981 cohorts whose first job initiated after 1980 and lasted less than 5 years

References

Banerjee, A., Meng, X., Qian, N., September 2010. The life cycle model and household

savings : Micro evidence from urban china. Tech. rep., MIT and Yale University.

Bhattacharya, G., October 1990. Migration under uncertainty about quality of locations.

Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 14 (3-4), 721–739.

de la Rupelle, M., Deng, Q., Li, S., Vendryes, T., 2009. Land rights insecurity and

temporary migration in rural china. IZA Discussion Paper 4668, Institute for the Study

of Labor (IZA).

Giles, J., Ren, M., May 2007. Elderly parent health and the migration decision of adult

children: Evidence from rural china. Demography 44 (2), 265–288.

Hannum, E., Behrman, J., Wang, M., Liu, J., 2007. Education in the reform era. In:

Brandt, L., Rawski, T. (Eds.), China’s Great Economic Transformation. Cambridge

University Press.

26

Page 27: Migration Duration and Family Economics : Temporary ...parisschoolofeconomics.eu/docs/de-la-rupelle-maelys/migration_and… · is a crucial step in countries’ development and urbanization

Kaufman, J., Zhang, Z., Qiao, Q., Zhang, Y., December 1989. Family planning policy

and practice in china : A study of four rural counties. Population and Development

Review 15 (4), 707–729.

Kesztenbaum, L., 2008. Cooperation and coordination among siblings : Brother’s migra-

tion in france, 1870-1940. The History of the Family 13 (1).

Lee, Y.-J., Xiao, Z., 1998. Children’s support for elderly parents in urban and rural china

: Results from a national survey. Journal of Cross-Cultural Gerontology 13, 39–62.

Li, S., 2010. The economic situation of rural migrant workers in china. China Perspectives

4.

Lohmar, B., 1999. Land tenure insecurity and labor allocation in rural china. In: Ameri-

can Agricultural Economics Association, 1999 Annual meeting, August 8-11, Nashville,

TN.

McElroy, M., Yang, D. T., 2000. Carrots and sticks : Fertility effects of china’s population

policies. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 90 (2), 389–392.

Qian, N., 2009. Quantity-quality and the one child policy : the only-child disadvantage in

school enrollment in rural china. Working Paper 14973, National Bureau of Economic

Research.

Shi, X., December 2004. The impact of insecure land use rights on labor migration: The

case of china. CCER Economic Papers 4 (22), 1–24.

Shultz, T. P., Zeng, Y., November 1995. Fertility of rural china : Effects of local family

planning and health programs. Journal of Population Economics 8 (4), 329–350.

Stark, O., Bloom, D. E., May 1985. The new economics of labor migration. The Ameri-

can Economic Review 75 (2), 173–178, papers and Proceedings of the Ninety-Seventh

Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association.

Stark, O., Levhari, D., October 1982. On migration and risks in ldcs. Economic Devel-

opment and Cultural Change 31 (1), 191–196.

State Council Research Bureau, t., 2006. Chinese Rural Migrant Workers Survey Re-

search Report, Zhongguo Nongmingong Diaoyan Baogao. The main results have been

summarized by the National Population and Family Planning Commission of China,

and are available (in Chinese) at the following address:

http://www.chinapop.gov.cn/rkxx/rkxw/t20060417_58579.htm.

27