30
0 Legal Regime and Corporate Financial Reporting Quality Andrei Filip Assistant Professor ESSEC Business School [email protected] Réal Labelle Chair in Governance and Forensic Accounting HEC Montréal [email protected] Stéphane Rousseau Chair in Business Law and International Trade Faculty of Law, Université de Montréal [email protected] November 2009 Acknowledgements: The authors are grateful for comments received by Christine Pochet, Cédric Lesage, Voltec???, Heidi Wechtler and other participants in the Paris1-IAE research workshop. The usual caveat applies.

Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

  • Upload
    mricky

  • View
    605

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

 

Citation preview

Page 1: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

0

Legal Regime and Corporate Financial Reporting Quality

Andrei Filip

Assistant Professor

ESSEC Business School

[email protected]

Réal Labelle

Chair in Governance and Forensic Accounting

HEC Montréal

[email protected]

Stéphane Rousseau

Chair in Business Law and International Trade

Faculty of Law, Université de Montréal

[email protected]

November 2009

Acknowledgements: The authors are grateful for comments received by Christine Pochet, Cédric Lesage, Voltec???, Heidi Wechtler and other participants in the Paris1-IAE research workshop. The usual caveat applies.

Page 2: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

1

Legal Regime and Corporate Financial Reporting Quality

Abstract

This article uses the unique Canadian bi-juralism environment where Common Law

coexists with Civil Law, as a laboratory to contribute to the international debate on the

influence, or even superiority, of one legal system over the other regarding firms’

financial reporting quality. Our results show that, the relationship between the legal

regime and the corporate financial reporting quality is not as simple as we expected.

Ceteris paribus, in the Civil Law environment the quality of corporate financial reporting

seems to be higher.

Page 3: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

2

1. Introduction

Investors' confidence in corporate governance and financial reporting has been shaken

severely and on several occasions since the beginning of the century. These upheavals

induced and are still nourishing an international wave of regulatory shocks rarely seen

before with the Sarbanes-Oxley Act as its epicenter. These reforms reveal a strong

concern by legal, regulatory and standard setting bodies around the world for public

companies’ financial information quality.

This concern for corporate financial reporting quality (FRQ) is echoed at the academic

level by La Porta et al. (2006) which report significant benefits of full disclosure for

investor protection and stock market development with regard to firms issuing securities

to the public. Djankov et al. (2008) also conclude that laws mandating extensive

disclosure and facilitating private enforcement through liability rules, that facilitates the

compensation of the investors, benefit stock markets. Furthermore, in line with the results

of La Porta et al. (1997 & 1998), Djankov et al. (2008, p. 462) conclude that, for all the

measures of shareholder protection they have considered, there is a pronounced

difference in favor of Common Law countries over French Civil Law countries. For

example, Common Law countries subject related party transactions to greater disclosure

requirements than do French Civil Law countries.

In this article, we use the unique Canadian bijuralism environment, where Common Law

coexists with French Civil Law, as a field study to contribute to the international debate

on the influence, or even superiority, of one legal system over the other regarding firms’

financial information. This setting allows us to compare both systems including their

enforcement conditions with regard to FRQ. We also aim at reconciling this line of

Page 4: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

3

research with Ball et al. (2008) results which are more consistent with the ‘‘costly

contracting’’ than with the ‘‘value relevance’’ school of accounting thought1. Our

research question is: Caeteris paribus, is the nature of the legal system including its

enforcement conditions likely to affect the quality of corporate financial reporting?

Canada offers a legal framework and an exceptional empirical field with the coexistence

of two systems: the Civil Law in the province of Quebec and the Common Law in the rest

of Canada. Further, Quebec provides us with an interesting context in which comparative

studies can be performed as two corporate statutes co-exist in the province: the

Companies Act (QCA), adopted by the provincial legislator, and the Canada Business

Corporations Act (CBCA), decreed by the federal legislator. Both statutes are available

to Quebec firms that want to incorporate their business, but they differ with respect to the

level of protection afforded to minority shareholders, QCA being perceived as less

protective than CBCA (Québec, 2007). It is therefore a good setting for examining their

presumed differential influence on the quality of financial information published by

corporations and on the responsibility of the external auditors as an enforcement

mechanism. This is equally a context where several alternative explanations regarding the

quality of financial information are practically eliminated such as the quality of the

accounting and auditing standard setting processes, the level of economical growth and of

financial development, the political framework, etc. All these are factors that the vast

majority of previous studies that used different countries or an international sample of

firms attempted to control for or have been simply forced to ignore and admit as limits of

their research.

1 The two schools of thought are debated in Holthausen and Watts (2001) and Barth et al. (2001).

Page 5: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

4

In the next section, we develop this study’s theoretical framework and review prior

research on the institutional determinants of corporate financial reporting. This stream of

empirical research mainly uses international data. In the third section, we explain why we

believe the Canadian institutional setting constitutes a good laboratory to compare the

presumed influence of the legal origin on FRQ. In the fourth one, we develop our

research design and FRQ models. In the fifth section, we present and analyse our results

before concluding in the last section.

2. Hypothesis development and prior research

We draw from the law and finance2 strand of research and to a lesser degree from the

value relevance and costly contracting literatures to analyze the incidence of the legal

regime on the quality of corporate financial reporting. The ultimate objective of this line

of research is a better understanding of the role of law and financial reporting in the

development of financial markets (La Porta et al. 1998) and, thereby, in the economical

growth of nations (Rajan and Zingales, 1996).

In Figure 1, we summarize the theoretical development and attempt to reconcile the

competing hypotheses of value relevance and costly contracting. La Porta et al. (1998)

and Djankov et al. (2008) show that investor protection is generally stronger in Common

Law than in French Civil Law countries. These authors also conclude that the legal

tradition affects capital markets, a better investor protection inducing more developed

financial markets. More developed financial markets offer larger opportunities for

external financing, and lead to less ownership concentration (La Porta et al. 1999).

2. Shleifer and Vishny 1997; LaPorta, Lopez-De-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny 1997, 1998, 1999, 2000, 2002 and 2006; Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny 2008; Francis, Khurana and Pereira 2003; Hope 2003a.

Page 6: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

5

- insert figure 1 about here -

On the one hand, the presence of more widely held corporations exacerbates agency

problems related to asymmetry of information. Quality financial accounting information,

i.e. conservative, relevant and reliable or relatively free of earnings management, may

help reduce these agency costs caused by information asymmetry between the firms and

external investors (Ball, Kothari and Robin, 2000). Therefore, in a Common Law

environment, presumed to offer a stronger protection to investors, one expects firms to

publish value relevant audited financial information in order to respond to the stock

market demand for such information.

On the other hand, because it provides weaker investor protection, French Civil Law

induces more proximity financing such as in the case of ownership concentration and

indebtedness. In that Civil Law environment, the information asymmetry situation may

be solved by private communications and institutional means other than financial

statements (Ball et al. 2000), notably by closer and more consistent relationships with the

stakeholders. Ball et al. (2008) results are more consistent with the ‘‘costly contracting’’

than with the ‘‘value relevance’’ school of accounting thought.

Nevertheless, according to the criticisms addressed to this theoretical approach by

Deffains and Guigou (2002) and Roe (2006), a more in depth analysis of the common and

Civil Law environments is warranted. La Porta et al. (1997 & 1998) are limiting their

analysis to regulations related to securities in order to conclude to the superiority of one

system over the other regarding investor protection. As recognised by La Porta et al.

(2006), other variables have to be considered, such as the enforcement of these rules

(Deffains and Guigou, 2002: 23). Notably, is there any difference in the manner in which

Page 7: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

6

these systems treat the litigations between investors and auditors, as the ultimate

protectors of financial reporting quality?

Prior empirical studies generally report that the legal system is not without influence and

that the thesis of the neutrality of the law system, such as suggested by the theorem of

Coase, is not verified (Ayyagari et al. 2006 a and b). Nevertheless, this literature has

several shadowed areas. Notably, the empirical models (Francis et al. 2001, 2003, 2005;

Barniv et al. 2005; Bushman et al., 2004; Bushman and Piotroski 2006; Bushman and

Smith, 2003 and Hope, 2003a and b) are using international data, which weakens their

capacity to test for alternative explanations. A closer examination of the differences

between these systems is necessary. Such a comparison necessitates an in depth

knowledge of not only all the laws and regulations, but also of the conditions of

enforcement relating to the protection of minority shareholders and creditors rights, to the

responsibility of the administrators, managers and auditors, to the accounting and

governance standards, etc. This required background information is developed in the next

section.

3. Institutional setting or why use Canadian data?

Unlike the other Canadian provinces, Quebec is a mixed jurisdiction in which the Civil

law and the Chommon law systems co-exist. Common law governs public law, such as

administrative law and criminal law (Hogg, 1997), while Civil law governs private law,

such as the law of contracts and company law. Thus, in Quebec, “the backdrop of

company law is civil law” (Crête and Rousseau, 2008; Bozec et al, 2008).

Page 8: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

7

In the province of Quebec, there are two corporate statutes: one is enacted by the federal

parliament, the Canada Business Corporations Act (CBCA) and one by the National

Assembly of Quebec, the Quebec Companies Act (QCA). While similar in many ways,

these statutes diverge in one important area that pertains to shareholder protection, the

CBCA offering more effective protection of shareholders’ rights, compared to QCA. This

difference is important given the path dependency associated with the choice of QCA as

incorporation statute. Indeed, the choice of the law of incorporation is usually made by

entrepreneurs at the start-up stage. Significantly, where a business is incorporated under

the QCA, it is unlikely that the corporation can easily change its law of incorporation.

Indeed, the QCA does not provide an emigration mechanism allowing reincorporation

under another corporate statute. Since liquidation is the only option for a firm wishing to

forego its incorporation under the QCA, and reincorporate under the CBCA, changes in

this respect rarely take place. In contrast, the CBCA does enact an import and export

mechanism which allows firms to switch incorporation statutes.

3.1. Shareholder Protection under the Canada Business Corporations Act

Strongly influenced by American law, and to some extent, British law, the Dickerson

Report that produced the CBCA proposed a new corporate law framework characterized

by different fundamental approaches among which, the most relevant to our study, is the

fact that the law creates specific mechanisms to safeguard the rights and interests of

minority shareholders against managerial and dominant shareholder opportunism. For

instance, the CBCA provides mechanisms that can be used at shareholders’ general

meetings. The Act mandates the disclosure of information on the subject matters to be

Page 9: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

8

discussed at the meetings. For larger corporations, it also enacts a regime governing the

solicitation of proxies that provides additional information to the shareholders whose

votes are solicited. Further, under certain conditions, shareholders have the right to

submit proposals at the annual general meeting so they can be discussed and voted on by

the shareholder group. The Act enables the holder of at least 5% of the voting shares of

the corporation to call a special meeting of shareholders.

Under the CBCA, shareholders have the power to have their say on important decisions

taken at the general meetings. It is the shareholders who elect the directors of the

corporations as well as its auditors. Furthermore, shareholders must authorize

“fundamental changes” following a procedure that gives them clout over the decision-

making process. The concept of fundamental changes refers to a variety of changes that

affect the corporation’s constitution, such as amendments to its articles of incorporation,

amalgamation with another corporation, or the corporation’s continuation under another

corporate statute. Where the corporation undertakes a fundamental change, the CBCA

grants special class voting rights to holders of a class of shares, irrespective of whether

the shares of the class otherwise carry the right to vote, when the change contemplated is

likely to affect the specific rights of that class. The special class voting rights enable the

holders of the class to vote separately from the holders of other shares of the corporation,

giving them a form of veto over the proposed change. Further, the CBCA provides a right

of dissent or appraisal remedy enabling a shareholder to compel the corporation to buy

her shares at fair value in the case of a fundamental change.

Finally, the CBCA provides mechanisms enforced by the courts that offer protection to

shareholders against management or dominant shareholder opportunism. The Act

Page 10: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

9

imposes duties of care and fiduciary duties on managers in regard to the corporation.

These duties can be enforced through the derivative action that allows shareholders and

other plaintiffs to bring an action in lieu of the corporation to rectify a wrong committed

against it, such as a breach of duties. Shareholders can use the derivative action when

managers refuse to take action to redress a breach of their duties that has led to a loss for

the corporation. It is thus an important tool to ensure the enforcement of managers’

duties, and consequently, their accountability. The most powerful remedy offered to

minority shareholders is however the oppression remedy. The remedy can be used when

the business or the affairs of the corporation are being carried on or conducted, or the

directors’ powers are being exercised in a manner that is oppressive or unfairly

prejudicial to or that unfairly disregards the interests of any security holder, creditor,

director, or officer. The remedy gives the plaintiff the right to apply to the court, which

then has the power to make any order it sees fit to correct the situation. The oppression

remedy is both very powerful and broad.

3.2. Shareholder Protection under the Quebec Companies Act

There are some protective mechanisms in the QCA that operate at shareholders’ general

meetings: for instance, it enables shareholders to exercise their votes meaningfully, and

also mandates the disclosure of information on the subject matter to be discussed at the

meetings. However, unlike the CBCA, it does not currently enact a regime governing the

solicitation of proxies, nor does it grant shareholders the right to submit a proposal at the

annual general meeting.

Page 11: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

10

More importantly, the QCA does not provide a general class veto regime, as does the

CBCA, to protect minority shareholders in the case of fundamental changes. Fundamental

changes need only be authorized by at least two-thirds of the votes cast by the

shareholders who voted in respect of that resolution. Unlike the CBCA, the QCA does

not mandate shareholder approval for the sale of all or substantially all of the assets of the

corporation (Rona inc. v. Matco Ravary Inc., 2003 CANLII 52752 (Qc.S.C.)).

Furthermore, the QCA does not establish an appraisal remedy enabling minority

shareholders who oppose a fundamental change to force the corporation to buy back their

shares at fair value.

With respect to judicially enforced mechanisms providing protection to shareholders

against management or dominant shareholder opportunism, there is no derivative action

in the QCA or the Civil Code similar to the derivative action enacted by the CBCA.

Shareholders who wish to use derivative action against their directors and officers must

convince the court that the conduct of officers, directors, or dominant shareholders

amounts to a fraud. For instance, mere negligence would not be sufficient.

Finally, neither the QCA nor the Civil Code provide for an oppression remedy permitting

an aggrieved party—security holder, creditor, director, or officer—to seek redress when

the corporation has not regarded their interests fairly. Thus, in cases of abuses, minority

shareholders have traditionally had few remedies apart from the winding-up of the

corporation (Développements Urbain Candiac inc. v. Combest Corporation, [1993] R.J.Q.

1321 (Qc.C.A.)]. Widely recognized in the literature (Crête and Rousseau 2008, Martel

and Martel, 2004), the fact that QCA is less protective of minority shareholders was

underlined by the Quebec Minister of Finance in a working paper purporting to launch a

Page 12: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

11

reform of QCA: “When compared with company law in other jurisdictions in Canada,

Québec law governing legal persons currently has few legal recourses specifically

adapted to investors. Although some recourses are provided under the Civil Code of

Québec, Québec investors have less legal protection in comparison for example with the

federal regime” (Québec, 2007)3

The differences between investor protection under QCA and CBCA is summarized in the

table 1:

- insert table 1 about here -

The difference in the level of investor protection rights afforded by the QCA and the

CBCA is particularly interesting for the quality of financial information. Ex ante, investor

protection rights can influence the quality of financial information by rendering managers

more accountable and more responsive to investors’ information needs. Ex post, investor

protection rights affect the level of litigation risk which, in turn, conditions the quality of

financial information (Chung and Wynn, 2008). This difference is made even more

interesting by the fact that the common law and civil law liability regimes have proved

equally ineffective in providing an effective remedy against corporations and their

managers in the case of false or misleading disclosure (Donald, 2000; Rousseau et Crête,

1999. Further, the common law provinces and the province of Quebec have recently

enacted similar statutory liability regimes enabling investors to sue corporations and their

managers in this case.

3 Québec, Reform of the Company Act, Working Paper, 2007 [on line: http://www.finances.gouv.qc.ca/en/page.asp?sectn=2&contn=257].

Page 13: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

12

4. Research design

This section presents the research design and develops the models used to examine if the

quality of firms' financial reporting is different between the Common and Civil Law

systems. As the quality of accounting information cannot be observed per se, we build on

the existing literature, which expresses the quality of financial reporting in terms of

attributes (Schipper and Vincent, 2003). Value relevance, conservatism and reliability as

measured by a relative absence of earnings management have been interchangeably used

by prior literature as attributes of accounting quality (Barth et al. 2008, Van der Meulen

et al. 2007, and many others). Using the unique Canadian bijuralism setting, we test these

attributes for Quebec based corporations (QC - Civil Law environment) versus

corporations based in the rest of Canada (ROC - Common Law environment). We next

restrict our Quebec sample to the firms incorporated under Quebec Law (LQC). By

focusing on this specific Canadian capital market environment, other institutional factors

are kept as homogeneous as possible.

To assess FRQ, we proceed to a three step comparison of each attribute mentioned above

between the LQC, QC and ROC subsamples of firms. First, we compare the value

relevance of earnings, the incremental timely loss recognition, and the accruals quality of

the three subsamples. If the costly contracting hypothesis prevails, we anticipate that

Quebec companies exhibit higher value relevance of earnings, higher incremental timely

loss recognition, and higher accruals quality than ROC companies. If the value relevance

hypothesis prevails, we expect the opposite results.

We test that our results are not driven by firms’ specific characteristics by including

control variables which are presumed in the voluntary disclosure literature to affect

Page 14: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

13

corporate FRQ. The control variables are: industry fixed effects, time fixed effects, audit

quality (Big 4 vs. Non Big 4), and Size (log of assets). Most of these controls work

against our hypothesis, in the sense that they are probably correlated with the civil and

Common Law environments (our underlying variable of interest). In fact, our results

indicate that most of these control variables exhibit only weak effects.

4.1. Value relevance

Different empirical models have been used in the past to assess the value

relevance of accounting data. All models consist in regressing accounting data on

corresponding measures of market performance. Data may be expressed in absolute

(price models) or relative (return models) values. Because price models seem to be

affected by the spurious effect of scale, while return models seem to suffer less from

econometrical problems4, we use the following return model:

Rjt α0 α1Ejt

MVjt‐1α2

∆Ejt

MVjt‐1α3 (1)

where:

RjtMVjt‐MVjt‐1 Djt

MVjt‐1 is the market return of company j in year t;

MVjt is the year-end t market value for company j;

Djt is the dividend paid by company j in year t;

Ejt and ∆Ejt are respectively the earnings and the change in earnings of

firm j in year t.

4 For a discussion on the ability of return models to capture the value relevance of accounting data, see Dumontier and Raffournier (2003).

Page 15: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

14

Although association studies do not imply any underlying valuation model, equation (2)

is often presented as deriving from the Feltham-Ohlson model (Ohlson, 1995; Feltham

and Ohlson, 1995). Within this framework, the value relevance of earnings is measured

by the explanatory power (adjusted R2) of the regression model (1).

4.2. Conservatism

Consistent with prior research, we test this attribute by using the Basu (1997) model. The

asymmetric treatment of losses and gains is captured by the pricewise linear regression of

accounting earnings on stock returns:

Ejt

MVjt‐1β0 β1DRjt β2Rjt β3DRjtRjt β4 (2)

where:

Ejt are the earnings of firm j in year t;

MVjt is the year-end t market value for company j;

RjtMVjt‐MVjt‐1 Djt

MVjt‐1 is the market return of company j in year t;

Djt is the dividend paid by company j in year t;

DRjt is a dummy variable equaling 1 if Rjt is negative (indicating

economic losses), and 0 otherwise (indicating economic

gains).

In this model, the focus is on the β3 coefficient of the product of stock return by the

return dummy which measures the incremental timeliness of loss recognition. A positive

significant coefficient implies asymmetric timely loss recognition. A higher coefficient

denotes more incremental timely loss recognition. Coefficient β2 on stock return

Page 16: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

15

measures the timeliness of gain recognition, while the sum of β2 β3 is measuring the

timely loss recognition.

4.3. Earnings management

Different empirical models have been used in previous studies to detect earnings

management. Some recent studies apply the Dechow and Dichev (2002) model to assess

accruals as a measure of earnings quality arguing that accruals are temporary adjustments

to better measure firm performance. The focus of this model is on the firm’s working

capital accruals, as related cash flow realizations generally occur within one year.

Therefore, the changes in working capital are regressed on past, present and future cash

flows:

∆WCjt

TAjtγ0 γ1

OCFjt‐1

TAjt‐1γ2

OCFjt

TAjtγ3

OCFjt 1

TAjt 1γ4 (3)

where:

∆WCjt are changes in working capital of firm j in year t;

WCjt is the working capital defined as non cash current assets

minus current liabilities (adjusted by the current portion of

debt);

TAjt is the total of assets of firm j in year t;

OCFjt is the operating cash flow of firm j in year t.

As pointed out in Dechow and Dichev (2002), a higher explanatory power of the model

indicates higher earnings or accrual quality. Therefore, the model is estimated for the QC

and ROC samples and the comparison is based on the explanatory power (adjusted R2) of

the regression model (3).

Page 17: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

16

5. Data collection and sampling

The data is collected for listed Canadian firms from the Compustat database (3’878

firms). Based on the headquarters’ address, we split the sample into Quebec firms (QC)

and rest of Canada (ROC). All firms with non-available address (1’305 firms) or with an

address outside Canada (181 firms) are eliminated from the sample. In addition, for each

QC firm we search on its internet webpage to check if the company is incorporated under

Quebec law (LQC). Because financial institutions follow specific reporting regulations,

they are deleted from the sample (582 firms). Therefore, our sample is composed of

1’810 firms.

We collect market and accounting data for the period 1998 to 2007 (10 years). Year-

observations with negative total equity for any of the years are eliminated in order to

avoid bias in our results, leading to a sample of 9’543 year-observations. For each

regression, outliers are eliminated based on the standardized residuals. Another reason for

this exclusion is the transitory nature of extreme variables. As such variations are not

expected to persist, their association should be lower than for more moderate values. A

number of year-observations are also dropped from the sample because of missing or

incomplete capital market or financial statement data in the Compustat database. In order

to obtain comparability across our different metrics, we limit our analysis only to the

year-observations with available control variables.

- insert table 2 about here -

Page 18: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

17

Our final sample consists therefore of 6’336 year-observations for model 1 and 2 and

4’698 year-observations for model 3. The difference between the two samples is

explained by data availability (because model 3 refers to past, present and future cash

flows, only 9 years can be taken into account). Table 1 presents some descriptive

statistics.

6. Results

Differences between LQC, QC and ROC firms with regard to the three attributes of FRQ

are reflected in the models’ R2. However, cross-samples comparisons would be

incomplete without employing a more formal test. For instance, Ball et al. (2000), Sami

and Zhou (2004) or Lang et al. (2006) are using the Cramer’s standard deviation in order

to assess the significance of differences between R2 across different regressions.

According to Cramer (1987), the standard deviation of the estimated R2 is a function of

the sample size, the number of independent variables (including intercept), and the “true”

R2. Following Arce and More (2002), we use a more appealing test that compares R2

from two different samples based on the following Z-statistic:

ZRLQC/QC

2 ‐RROC2

σLQC/QC2 σROC

2

Where RLQC2 , RQC

2 , and RROC2 are the R2 from LQC, QC, respectively, and ROC firms,

while σ(.) is the variance. Under the null hypothesis of no difference between both R2, this

Z-statistic is approximately standard normal in large samples. Therefore, the number

reported in the tables indicates the probability to accept the null hypothesis of no

difference in adjusted R2.

Page 19: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

18

We run separate regressions for the LQC, QC and ROC samples (for reasons of

comparison the results for the pooled sample are reported as well). Finally control

variables are introduced into the equations in order to check whether the results are

driven by firms’ specific factors, rather than by the legal environment in which they

operate.

Table 3 reports the results of the regressions for the value relevance tests (model 1). In

line with previous association studies performed on mature capital markets where

alternative sources of information are abundant, accounting information displays low

value relevance. Market returns seem to be associated to earnings in all the cases, while

earnings changes only for the QC and the ROC samples.

- insert table 3 about here -

LQC earnings and earnings changes seem to be more value relevant to investors as the

adjusted R2 reaches 16.6%, which is almost triple if compared to the adjusted R2 of 6.6%

for the ROC sample. According to the Cramer test, this difference is significant at 0.2%,

while the difference between QC and ROC is not significant. The above results hold even

after adding the control variables to the regression. Industry fixed effects and time fixed

effects are the only control factors statistically significant, while the Cramer test indicates

statistically significant differences between LQC and ROC firms. These results are

consistent with the hypothesis that the corporate financial reporting of Civil Law firms

incorporated under Quebec Law is of better quality compared to Common Law firms.

According to Basu (1997), accounting earnings reflect bad news more quickly than good

news, while market returns capture both good news and bad news simultaneously. This

conjecture is captured in model 2, and the results for the asymmetric timeliness of

Page 20: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

19

earnings are presented in table 4. Consistent with prior studies, the overall power of the

Basu model remains relatively low, but higher for LQC and QC samples (adjusted R2 of

20.4% and 18.0%) if compared to the ROC (adjusted R2 of 13.1). The Cramer test reveals

that both differences are significant. Results are similar even after controlling for other

firm-specific factors, industry fixed effects, time fixed effects, and size being the only

control variables that are significant.

- insert table 4 about here -

Turning now to the response coefficients, the only coefficient significant at 1% in all the

cases is β3 (on the product of the stock return with the return dummy) which measures the

incremental timeliness of loss recognition. Its absolute value seems to be higher for the

QC sample (0.449), and it is taking similar values for the LQC and ROC samples (0.330

and 0.353, respectively). However, given that the coefficient β1 on the return dummy is

not significant for the LQC and QC sample, it is difficult to draw conclusions with regard

to the level of conservatism.

Finally, the results with regard to accrual quality as measured by model 3 are reported in

table 5. The highest explanatory power of the model is achieved for the LQC and QC

sample (adjusted R2 of 31.1% and 26.5%), while for the ROC sample the adjusted R2 is

only 10.7%. The Cramer test reveals that these differences are statistically significant,

which confirms the hypothesis that Civil law firms do not manage earnings as much as

Common law firms. Similar results are obtained even after controlling for firms specific

factors.

- insert table 5 about here -

Page 21: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

20

As pointed out by Dechow and Dichev (2002), a positive sign is expected on both past

and future cash flows and a negative sign on current cash flows. All coefficients are

significant and have the expected sign.

7. Conclusion

This research uses the unique Canadian bi-juralism environment, where Common Law

coexists with French Civil Law, as a field study to contribute to the international debate

on the influence, or even superiority, of one legal system over the other regarding

corporate financial reporting quality. Our results show that, ceteris paribus, the nature of

the legal system is not neutral and it is the Civil Law environment that seems to

encourage firms to publish accounting data of better quality. These surprising results are

in opposition to the most intimate beliefs of researchers and seem to indicate, at least, that

the relationship between the legal regime and the corporate financial reporting quality is

not as simple as we expected.

Most of the previous studies analysing this research question are using heterogeneous

samples, which include countries extremely different not only in terms of legal systems,

but also in terms of political institutions, economic development, corporate governance

mechanisms, shareholders and creditors rights, enforcement mechanisms etc. As a

consequence, it is difficult to attribute the reported differences only to one variable.

Corporate financial reporting quality seem to be affected by a multitude of legal

incentives, market forces and firm characteristics and future research is needed to have a

clear picture of the interactions between all these variables.

Page 22: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

21

References

Ayyagari M., A. Demirguc-Kunt et V. Maksimovic. 2006a. How Important are

Financing Constraints? The Role of finance in the Business Environment. Working paper SSRN.

Ayyagari M., A. Demirguc-kunt et V. Maximovic. 2006b. What determines protection of property rights? An analysis of direct and indirect effects. Working paper SSRN.

Ali, A. et L-S. Hwang. 2000. Country specific factors related to financial reporting and the value relevance of accounting data. Journal of Accounting Research, vol. 38 (1): 1-22.

Ball, R., S. P. Kothari and A. Robin. 2000. The effect of international institutional factors on properties of accounting earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, vol. 29 (1): 1-51.

Ball, R., Robin, A. and G. Sadka. 2008. Is financial reporting shaped by equity markets or by debt markets? An international study of timeliness and conservatism. Review of Accounting Studies 13:168–205.

Barniv, R., M. J. Myring et B. T. Wayne. 2005. The association between legal and financial reporting environment and forecast performance of individual analysts, Contemporary accounting research, vol. 22 (4): 725-758.

Barth, M.E., W.R. Landsman, and M.H. Lang. 2008. International accounting standards and accounting quality. Journal of Accounting Research. Vol. 46(3): 467-498.

Barth, M. E., Beaver, W. H., & Landsman, W. R. 2001. The relevance of the value relevance literature for financial accounting standard setting: Another view. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31,77–104.

Basu, S. 1997. The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings. Journal of Accounting & Economics. Vol. 24 (1): 3-37.

Bebchuk, Lucian, Alma Cohen and Allen Ferrell. 2004. What Matters in Corporate Governance. Discussion Paper No. 491. 09/2004, revised 11/2004. Harvard Law School, Cambridge: 51p.

Bozec, Y., S. Rousseau et C. Laurin. 2006. Law of Incorporation and Ownership Structure: The Law and Finance Theory Revisited (August 18), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=927420.

Bushman, R. M. et J. D. Piotroski. 2006. Financial Reporting Incentives for Conservative Accounting: The Influence of legal and Political Institutions. Working paper SSRN.

Bushman, R. M. et A. J. Smith. 2003. Transparency, Financial Accounting Information, and Corporate Governance. Economic Policy Review, vol. 9 (1, April): .

Bushman, R. M. Piotroski, J. D. et A. J. Smith. 2004. What Determines Corporate Transparency?. Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. 42 (2): 207 –252.

Cao, Zhiyan and Narayanamoorthy, Ganapathi. 2005. Accounting and Litigation Risk. (November). Yale SOM Working Paper No. 47 Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=853024

Chung, H.H. and J.P Wynn, 2008. “Managerial legal liability coverage and earnings conservatism” Journal of accounting and economics, Vol. 46(1): 135-153.

Clarke, Thomas. 2005. Theories of Corporate Governance. The Philosophical Foundations of Corporate Governance. Ed. By T. Clarke. Routledge, Taylor &

Page 23: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

22

Francis. London & New York: 370 p. Coase, R. H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. The Journal of Law and Economics. Vol.

3: 1-44. Dechow, P and I. Dichev. 2002. The quality of accruals and earnings: the role of accrual

estimation errors. The Accounting Review. Vol. 77 (Supplement): 35-59. Deffains, B. et J.-D. Guigou. Droit, gouvernement d’entreprise et marché des capitaux, Djankov, Simeon, La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, Shleifer,_Andrei. 2008.

The law and economics of self-dealing. Journal of Financial Economics 88: 430–465. Donald, C. 2000. “Civil Remedies for Breach of Continous Disclosure Obligations under

the Securities Act", McGill Law Journal, Vol. 45: 609. Dumontier, P. and B. Raffournier. 2002. Accounting and capital markets: a survey of the

European evidence. The European Accounting Review. Vol. 11: 119-151. Fama E. and M. Jensen. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Laws

and Economics 26: 301-325. Feltham, G., and J. Ohlson. 1995. Valuation and clean surplus accounting for operating

and financial activities. Contemporary Accounting Research. vol. 11: 689 – 687. Francis, J. R., I. K. Khurana et R. Pereira. 2003. The Role of Accounting and Auditing in

Corporate Governance, and the Development of Financial Markets around the World. Asia Pacific Journal of Accounting and Economics, Vol. 10 (1): 1-30.

Francis, J. R., Khurana, I. K. et R. Pereira. 2005. Disclosure Incentives and Effects on Cost of Capital around the World. The Accounting Review 80 (4): 1125-1163.

Francis, J. R., Khurana, I. K., Pereira, R. 2001, Investor Protection Laws, Accounting and Auditing Around the World, Working paper, University of Missouri-Columbia, 40p.

Gelb D.S., 2000, Managerial ownership and accounting disclosures : an empirical analysis, Review of Quantitative Finance & Accounting 15, 2: 169-185.

Holthausen, R. W. & Watts, R. L. 2001. The relevance of the value-relevance literature for financial accounting standard setting. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 31, 3–75.

Hayn, C. 1995. The information content of losses. Journal of Accounting and Economics. Vol. 20: 125 – 153.

Healy, Paul M., Wahlen, James M., A review of the earnings management literature and its implications for standard setting, Accounting Horizons, Dec 1999, Vol. 13, no. 4 : 365-383, ...\HealyAH00.pdf.

Hope, O.-K. 2003a. Firm level disclosures and the relative rules of culture and legal origin. Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting, vol. 14 (1): 218-248.

Hope, O.-K. 2003b. Disclosure practices, enforcement of accounting standards and analysts’ forecasts accuracy: an international study. Journal of Accounting Research, vol 41 (2): 235-272.

Krishnan, G. V., R. 2005. « Did Houston clients of Arthur Andersen recognize publicly available bad news in a timely fashion? Contemporary Accounting Research/Recherche Comptable Contemporaine, Vol. 22, No. 1 (Spring): 165-193.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes et A. Shleifer. 2000. Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 58 (1, 2): 3-27.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes et A. Shleifer. 2006. What works in securities laws? The Journal of Finance, Vol. 61 (1): 1-32.

Page 24: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

23

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer et R. Vishny. 1997. Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52 (3): 1131-1150.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer et R. Vishny. 2002. Investor protection and corporate valuation. The Journal of Finance, Vol. 57 (3): 1147-1170.

La Porta, R., F., F. López-de-Silanes et A. Shleifer. 1999. Corporate Ownership Around the World, Journal of Finance (April):.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer et R. Vishny. R. 1998, Law and Finance. Journal of Political Economy 106: 1113-1154.

Ohlson, J. 1995. Earnings, book values, and dividends in equity valuation. Contemporary Accounting Research. Vol. 11: 661 – 687.

Rajan, Raghuram, and Luigi Zingales. 1996. Financial dependence and growth, NBER Working paper 5758.

Roe, Mark J. 2006. Legal Origins and Modern Stock Markets. Harward Law School, European Corporate Governance Institute. Working paper SSRN.

Rousseau, S. et R. Crête. 1999. « L’environnement législatif québécois au regard du projet d’adoption d’un régime statutaire de responsabilité civile dans le contexte du marché secondaire des valeurs mobilières ». Revue du Barreau, Vol. 59 : 627-678.

Schipper, K. and L. Vincent. 2003. Earnings quality. Accounting Horizons. Vol. 17: 97 – 108.

Shleifer, A., et R.W. Vishny. 1997. A Survey of Corporate Governance. The Journal of Finance, 52, 2, (June): 737-784.

Van der Meulen, S., A. Gaeremynck and M. Willekens. 2007. Attribute differences between U.S. GAAP and IFRS earnings: an explanatory study. The International Journal of Accounting. Vol. 42: 123 – 142.

Watts, R. L. 2003a. Conservatism in Accounting. Part I: Explanations and implications. Accounting Horizons 17 (3, September): 207-221.

Watts, R. L. 2003b. Conservatism in Accounting. Part II: Evidence and Research Opportunities. Accounting Horizons. http://ssrn.com/abstract=438662.

Page 25: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

24

Page 26: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

25

Table 1. Investor Protection under CBCA and QCA: Salient Differences

Protective mechanism CBCA QCA Shareholder approval of fundamental changes

Class veto Approval by 2/3 of shareholders

Shareholder approval of the sale of all or substantially all of the assets

Class veto N/A

Calling shareholders’ meeting

5% of the voting shares 10% of the voting shares

Right to make shareholder proposal

Provided N/A

Appraisal remedy Provided N/A Derivative action Provided Constrained by majority

rule Oppression remedy Provided N/A

Page 27: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

26

Table 2. Descriptive statistics

N Mean Standard deviation

Min Max

Rjt 6 336 0.108 0.571 -1.338 2.156

Ejt

MVjt‐1 6 336 -0.003 0.133 -0.467 0.401

∆Ejt

MVjt‐1 6 336 0.004 0.120 -0.523 0.569

∆WCjt

TAjt 4 698 0.003 0.053 -0.170 0.169

OCFjt‐1

TAjt‐1 4 698 0.046 0.117 -0.349 0.380

OCFjt

TAjt 4 698 0.053 0.112 -0.309 0.350

OCFjt 1

TAjt 1 4 698 0.053 0.118 -0.338 0.379

Where RjtMVjt‐MVjt‐1 Djt

MVjt‐1 – the market return of firm j in year t; MVjt – the market value of firm j in year t;

Djt – the dividend paid by firm j in year t; Ejt – the year-end t earnings for firm j; ∆WCjt – the change in working capital (non-cash current assets minus current liabilities adjusted for the current portion of long term debt) of firm j in year t; TAjt – the total of assets of firm j in year t; OCFjt – the operating cash flow of firm j in year t.

Page 28: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

27

Table 3. The value relevance of earnings Model 1: Rjt 0 1

Ejt

MVjt‐12

∆Ejt

MVjt‐13

Variables LQC QC ROC POOL LQC QC ROC POOL

Intercept (α0)

0.011 (0.506)

0.065*** (4.152)

0.119*** (15.401)

0.110*** (15.891)

0.036 (0.328)

-0.039 (-0.544)

0.120*** (4.163)

0.217*** (7.949)

Earnings (α1)

0.383*** (6.664)

0.256*** (7.816)

0.220*** (15.100)

0.223*** (16.763)

0.297*** (4.341)

0.223*** (5.891)

0.236*** (14.951)

0.240*** (16.471)

Change in earnings (α2)

0.059 (1.032)

0.072** (2.191)

0.071*** (4.877)

0.072*** (5.381)

0.085 (1.449)

0.089*** (2.669)

0.053*** (3.645)

0.057*** (4.310)

Industry fixed effects

YES*** YES** YES*** YES***

Time fixed effects

YES** YES*** YES*** YES***

AUDIT -0.003 (-0.051)

0.003 (0.086)

0.024 (1.642)

0.018 (1.393)

SIZE 0.008 (0.119)

-0.002 (-0.049)

-0.012 (-0.714)

-0.008 (-0.544)

N 322 1 024 5 312 6 336 322 1 024 5 312 6 336 F 32.919*** 47.848*** 188.444*** 231.339*** 5.449*** 7.395*** 40.182*** 44.918*** Adj. R2 16.6% 8.4% 6.6% 6.8% 20.8% 11.1% 12.9% 12.2% Cramer test – ROC (0.002) (0.134) (0.001) (0.577)

Where RjtMVjt‐MVjt‐1 Djt

MVjt‐1 – the market return of firm j in year t; MVjt – the market value of firm j in year t; Djt – the dividend paid by firm j in year t; Ejt – the year-

end t earnings for firm j; Industry fixed effects – control variables that take the value one if the firm belongs to a specific industry, and zero otherwise (as identified by the first digit industry code); Time fixed effects – control variables that take the value one if the observation belongs to a specific year, and zero otherwise; AUDIT – control variable that takes the value one if the audit is conducted by one of the Big 4 auditor, and zero otherwise; SIZE – control variable computed as log of total assets of firm j in year t; ROC – sample of firms with the headquarter located outside the Quebec province; QC – sample of firms with the headquarter located in the Quebec province; LQC – sample of firms incorporated under the Quebec Companies Act. ***, **, * significant at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively; t-statistics into brackets; Cramer test – the number indicates the probability to accept the null hypothesis of no difference in adjusted R2 compared to the ROC sample.

Page 29: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

28

Table 4. The timeliness of earnings (Basu model) Model 2: Ejt

MVjt‐1β0 β1BNjt β2Rjt β3BNjtRjt β4

Variables LQC QC ROC POOL LQC QC ROC POOL

Intercept (β0)

0.058*** (6.096)

0.064*** (8.580)

0.038*** (10.856)

0.043*** (13.471)

0.021 (0.826)

-0.067*** (-3.795)

-0.096*** (-13.934)

-0.081*** (-12.552)

Bad news (β1)

-0.011 (-0.131)

-0.065 (-1.461)

-0.086*** (-4.172)

-0.084*** (-4.449)

-0.015 (-0.201)

-0.016 (-0.385)

-0.066*** (-3.397)

-0.058*** (-3.335)

Market return (β2)

0.144 (1.5670

-0.096** (-2.016)

-0.076*** (-3.546)

-0.084*** (-4.279)

0.127 (1.470)

-0.020 (-0.456)

0.004 (0.190)

0.002 (0.126)

Bad news * Return (β3)

0.330*** (3.954)

0.449*** (10.049)

0.353*** (17.355)

0.371*** (20.060)

0.218*** (2.701)

0.320*** (7.432)

0.250*** (12.811)

0.262*** (14.746)

Industry fixed effects

YES*** YES*** YES*** YES***

Time fixed effects

YES** YES** YES*** YES***

AUDIT -0.028 (-0.591)

-0.028 (-1.020)

0.004 (0.276)

-0.269 (0.788)

SIZE 0.172*** (2.900)

0.275*** (8.880)

0.330*** (23.188)

0.322*** (25.200)

N 322 1 024 5 312 6 336 322 1 024 5 312 6 336 F 28.390*** 75.888*** 269.017*** 342.298*** 9.111*** 23.899*** 89.584*** 111.857*** Adj. R2 20.4% 18.0% 13.1% 13.9% 33.6% 32.0% 25.9% 26.9% Cramer test – ROC (0.020) (0.011) (0.000) (0.001) Where Ejt – the year-end t earnings for firm j; MVjt – the market value of firm j in year t; BNjt – a dummy variable equal to one if Rjt is negative (indicating

economic loss), and zero otherwise; RjtMVjt‐MVjt‐1 Djt

MVjt‐1 – the market return of firm j in year t; Djt – the dividend paid by firm j in year t; Industry fixed effects –

control variables that take the value one if the firm belongs to a specific industry, and zero otherwise (as identified by the first digit industry code); Time fixed effects – control variables that take the value one if the observation belongs to a specific year, and zero otherwise; AUDIT – control variable that takes the value one if the audit is conducted by one of the Big 4 auditor, and zero otherwise; SIZE – control variable computed as log of total assets of firm j in year t; ROC – sample of firms with the headquarter located outside the Quebec province; QC – sample of firms with the headquarter located in the Quebec province; LQC – sample of firms incorporated under the Quebec Companies Act. ***, **, * significant at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively; t-statistics into brackets; Cramer test – the number indicates the probability to accept the null hypothesis of no difference in adjusted R2 compared to the ROC sample.

Page 30: Microsoft Word - 20-11-2009 Legal regime and corporate

29

Table 5. Accruals quality (Dechow and Dichev model)

Model 3: ∆WCjt

TAjtγ0 γ1

OCFjt‐1

TAjt‐1γ2

OCFjt

TAjtγ3

OCFjt 1

TAjt 1γ4

Variables LQC QC ROC POOL LQC QC ROC POOL

Intercept (γ0)

0.009** (2.082)

0.009*** (4.116)

0.004*** (4.498)

0.005*** (5.618)

0.023 (1.415)

-0.001 (-0.143)

0.007** (2.358)

0.008*** (2.791)

Cash flow–previous (γ1)

0.404*** (5.285)

0.355*** (7.919)

0.242*** (11.388)

0.261*** (13.510)

0.382*** (4.802)

0.343*** (7.667)

0.246*** (11.398)

0.263*** (13.458)

Cash flow–current (γ2)

-0.796*** (-9.704)

-0.758*** (-15.784)

-0.506*** (-21.518)

-0.545*** (-25.526)

-0.827*** (-9.628)

-0.763*** (-15.800)

-0.520*** (-21.953)

-0.557*** (-26.000)

Cash flow–next (γ3)

0.368*** (4.654)

0.338*** (7.519)

0.265*** (12.504)

0.277*** (14.344)

0.361*** (4.364)

0.346*** (7.547)

0.270*** (12.691)

0.282*** (14.547)

Industry fixed effects

YES** YES*** YES*** YES***

Time fixed effects

YES* YES** YES*** YES***

AUDIT 0.016 (0.263)

-0.016 (-0.452)

-0.007 (-0.432)

-0.008 (-0.493)

SIZE 0.031 (0.409)

0.026 (0.643)

0.001 (0.038)

0.000 (0.021)

N 213 694 4 004 4 698 213 694 4 004 4 698 F 32.962*** 84.255*** 160.222*** 224.233*** 6.587*** 14.819*** 29.100*** 39.901*** Adj. R2 31.1% 26.5% 10.7% 12.5% 33.4% 28.5% 12.3% 14.2% Cramer test – ROC (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Where ∆WCjt – the change in working capital (non-cash current assets minus current liabilities adjusted for the current portion of long term debt) of firm j in year t; TAjt – the total of assets of firm j in year t; OCFjt – the operating cash flow of firm j in year t; Industry fixed effects – control variables that take the value one if the firm belongs to a specific industry, and zero otherwise (as identified by the first digit industry code); Time fixed effects – control variables that take the value one if the observation belongs to a specific year, and zero otherwise; AUDIT – control variable that takes the value one if the audit is conducted by one of the Big 4 auditor, and zero otherwise; SIZE – control variable computed as log of total assets of firm j in year t; ROC – sample of firms with the headquarter located outside the Quebec province; QC – sample of firms with the headquarter located in the Quebec province; LQC – sample of firms incorporated under the Quebec Companies Act. ***, **, * significant at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively; t-statistics into brackets; Cramer test – the number indicates the probability to accept the null hypothesis of no difference in adjusted R2 compared to the ROC sample.