21
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 19, 533–553 (1998) MANAGEMENT AND OWNERSHIP EFFECTS: EVIDENCE FROM FIVE COUNTRIES ERIC R. GEDAJLOVIC 1 * AND DANIEL M. SHAPIRO 2 1 School of Business, Rutgers University, New Brunswick, New Jersey, U.S.A. 2 Faculty of Business Administration, Simon Fraser University at Harbour Center, Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada Despite the growing recognition in the corporate governance literature that the relationship between ownership concentration and profitability is context dependent, this issue has not yet been subjected to direct empirical investigation using a single cross-national sample. This study empirically examines the ownership concentration–performance relationship across the nations of Canada, France, Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Essentially, we argue that the correlation (if any) between ownership concentration and firm profitability differs across countries in a systematic way determined by the national system of corporate governance. Results indicate that important and statistically significant differences do in fact exist across the countries studied. 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt J. Vol. 19, 533–553 (1998) INTRODUCTION In The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Michael Porter notes the importance of ownership structure and corporate governance in determining corporate strategy: Company goals are most strongly determined by ownership structure, the motivation of owners and holders of debt, the nature of corporate governance, and the incentive processes that shape the motivation of senior managers. The goals of publicly held corporations reflect the characteristics of that nation’s capital markets. (1990: 110) Recent surveys of corporate governance have clearly demonstrated that countries differ pro- foundly in terms of the institutional contexts in Key words: corporate governance; ownership and con- trol; managerial discretion; corporate performance; cross-national strategy * Correspondence to: Eric R. Gedajlovic, School of Business, Rutgers University, Janice H. Levin Building, New Brunswick, NJ 08903, U.S.A. CCC 0143–2095/98/060533–21 $17.50 Received 24 February 1995 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Final revision received 27 June 1997 which corporate governance relationships are embedded (Fukao, 1995; Charkham, 1994; Dani- els and Morck, 1995; Bishop, 1994; Roe, 1993; Jenkinson and Mayer, 1992; Rao and Lee-Sing, 1996; Porter, 1992). Broadly speaking the literature tends to identify two general systems of corporate governance. One, associated with the United States and the United Kingdom, is characterized by relatively passive shareholders, Boards of Directors that are not always independent of managers, and active markets for corporate control. The other, associated with Continental Europe and Japan, is associated with coalitions of active shareholders (often other companies or banks), Boards of Directors (BODs) that are more independent of management, and limited markets for corporate control. These differences likely affect the goals and performance of public companies. There is little empirical evidence regarding the effect of national differences in corporate govern- ance on firm performance. In this study we explore this issue by examining the relationship between ownership concentration and firm prof-

MANAGEMENT AND OWNERSHIP EFFECTS: EVIDENCE FROM …

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 19, 533–553 (1998)

MANAGEMENT AND OWNERSHIP EFFECTS:EVIDENCE FROM FIVE COUNTRIES

ERIC R. GEDAJLOVIC1* AND DANIEL M. SHAPIRO2

1School of Business, Rutgers University, New Brunswick, New Jersey, U.S.A.2Faculty of Business Administration, Simon Fraser University at Harbour Center,Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada

Despite the growing recognition in the corporate governance literature that the relationshipbetween ownership concentration and profitability is context dependent, this issue has not yetbeen subjected to direct empirical investigation using a single cross-national sample. This studyempirically examines the ownership concentration–performance relationship across the nationsof Canada, France, Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Essentially, weargue that the correlation (if any) between ownership concentration and firm profitabilitydiffers across countries in a systematic way determined by the national system of corporategovernance. Results indicate that important and statistically significant differences do in factexist across the countries studied. 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

Strat. Mgmt J.Vol. 19, 533–553 (1998)

INTRODUCTION

In The Competitive Advantage of Nations,Michael Porter notes the importance of ownershipstructure and corporate governance in determiningcorporate strategy:

Company goals are most strongly determined byownership structure, the motivation of ownersand holders of debt, the nature of corporategovernance, and the incentive processes thatshape the motivation of senior managers. Thegoals of publicly held corporations reflect thecharacteristics of that nation’s capital markets.(1990: 110)

Recent surveys of corporate governance haveclearly demonstrated that countries differ pro-foundly in terms of the institutional contexts in

Key words: corporate governance; ownership and con-trol; managerial discretion; corporate performance;cross-national strategy* Correspondence to: Eric R. Gedajlovic, School of Business,Rutgers University, Janice H. Levin Building, New Brunswick,NJ 08903, U.S.A.

CCC 0143–2095/98/060533–21 $17.50 Received 24 February 1995 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Final revision received 27 June 1997

which corporate governance relationships areembedded (Fukao, 1995; Charkham, 1994; Dani-els and Morck, 1995; Bishop, 1994; Roe, 1993;Jenkinson and Mayer, 1992; Rao and Lee-Sing,1996; Porter, 1992).

Broadly speaking the literature tends to identifytwo general systems of corporate governance.One, associated with the United States and theUnited Kingdom, is characterized by relativelypassive shareholders, Boards of Directors that arenot always independent of managers, and activemarkets for corporate control. The other,associated with Continental Europe and Japan, isassociated with coalitions of active shareholders(often other companies or banks), Boards ofDirectors (BODs) that are more independent ofmanagement, and limited markets for corporatecontrol. These differences likely affect the goalsand performance of public companies.

There is little empirical evidence regarding theeffect of national differences in corporate govern-ance on firm performance. In this study weexplore this issue by examining the relationshipbetween ownership concentration and firm prof-

534 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

itability in five countries: the United States, theUnited Kingdom, Germany, France, and Canada.Essentially we argue that the correlation (if any)between ownership concentration and firm prof-itability differs across countries in a systematicway determined by the national system of corpo-rate governance.

We focus on the relationship between owner-ship concentration and firm performance becauseit has been so widely studied. Originally moti-vated by the separation of ownership from control(Berle and Means, 1932), and more recently byagency theory (Fama and Jensen, 1983; Jensen,1989), these studies begin with the premise thatmanagers and owners (shareholders) may havedivergent interests. Specifically, it is argued thatshareholders wish to maximize profits while man-agers may prefer various self-interested,nonprofit-maximizing strategies and that concen-trated ownership obviates the problems createdby these divergent interests (Demsetz and Lehn,1985). Following from this logic, the corehypothesis in the separation of ownership andcontrol literature is that concentrated ownershipis associated with higher profitability.

Indeed, there have been dozens of such studiesexamining the relationship between ownershipconcentration and firm performance beginning inthe 1930s and continuing to the present time(Bentson, 1985). In a recent review of thesestudies, Short (1994: 206) concludes that ‘themajority of studies find some support for themanagerial hypothesis that owner controlled (OC)firms should report higher profitability measuresthan manager controlled firms (MC) . . .’ Earliersurveys by Hunt (1986) and Vining and Board-man (1992) arrive at similar conclusions.

Most of the studies cited by Short used U.S.data and most of these have found that owner-controlled firms outperform firms where effectivecontrol rests in the hands of management. How-ever, few studies examining non-U.S. firms werecited by Short, and among those that were, sup-porting evidence was decidedly more mixed. Inparticular, the cited evidence from France andGermany did not indicate strong support for thehypothesis that concentrated ownership is posi-tively related to corporate performance.

While there has been some recognition that theownership concentration–profitability relationshipmay not be applicable in all national contexts,there has been no direct test of this proposition

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

using a single cross-national sample. The primarypurpose of this study is to determine whether therelationship between ownership concentration andprofitability varies across countries in ways thatare related to national differences in corporategovernance.

This paper contributes to the empirical litera-ture in one other way: we are more explicit inspecifying the microprocesses that may resultfrom managerial discretion. Specifically, we dis-tinguish between short-run tactical behaviorresulting in cost escalations and long-run strategicbehavior resulting in profit reduction (often theresult of poor diversification decisions). This dis-tinction is used to specify and estimate the rel-evant equations.

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

Agency theory suggests that the interests of prin-cipals and agents will not coincide. In the absenceof either appropriate incentives, or sufficientmonitoring, agents will be able to exercise theirdiscretion to the detriment of principals (Alchianand Demsetz, 1972; Jensen and Meckling, 1976;Eisenhardt, 1989). In the context of the moderncorporation, agency theory has been applied tothe relationship between managers and share-holders. The argument is that owners wish tomaximize profits, but that their designated agents(managers) may have neither the interest nor theincentive to do so (Berle and Means, 1932). Assuch, corporate performance depends in part onthe ability of owners to effectively monitor andcontrol managers.

The nature of managerial discretion

The literature has identified two broad manifes-tations of managerial discretion that may createagency costs. The first is that managers engagein short-run cost-augmenting activities designedto enhance their nonsalary income, or to provideother forms of on-the-job consumption(Williamson, 1964; Jensen and Meckling, 1976).This type of behavior reduces corporate profitsby increasing costs. For example, Jensen andMeckling argue that the managerial tendency tocost-pad is inversely related to their ownershipstake in the firm. This occurs because as man-agement’s right to residual income decreases, they

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 535

appropriate income from other corporate sourcesin the form of assorted perks.

A second manifestation of managerial discre-tion occurs when managers indulge their needsfor power, prestige, and status (Baumol, 1959)by making long-run strategic choices designed tomaximize corporate size and growth rather thancorporate profits. In essence, managers overinvestin size and/or growth-enhancing assets (Marris,1964; Grabowski and Mueller, 1972; Jensen,1988). The most commonly cited example of suchself-interested strategizing occurs when managersoverdiversify (Amihud and Lev, 1981). In thiscase, firm profits are reduced by accepting proj-ects whose anticipated returns are poor.

Although short-run cost augmentation and self-interested strategizing reflect two quite differentprocesses, they both predict that where managerialdiscretion is present, firm profitability will bereduced. The fact that they lead to the samepredicted effect on profits may have led empiricalresearchers to ignore the important differencesbetween them. We explore the implications ofthese differences below.

Constraints on managerial discretion

According to the classical separation of ownershipand control perspective, a dominant or majorityshareholder has both the incentive and ability tomonitor management so that the firm is managedin a manner consistent with profit maximization.The incentive to monitor is high because themajority shareholder has a claim on all residualprofit (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972), and theability to monitor is high because the dominantshareholder can often control the BOD (Tosiand Gomez-Mejia, 1989; Fama and Jensen, 1983;Salancik and Pfeffer, 1980). When the BOD isunder the control of a dominant shareholder, thecosts of organizing a coalition to oppose existingmanagement are avoided. In contrast, when share-holdings are widely diffused, neither the incentivenor the ability to monitor agents is present andso managers are afforded a greater degree ofdiscretion which allows them to not maximizeprofits (and shareholder wealth). Thus, concen-trated ownership is a powerful constraint onmanagerial discretion.

Research grounded in the separation of owner-ship and control thesis therefore typically makesthe simplifying assumption that managerial

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

discretion is essentially a negative function ofownership concentration. As such, individual,organizational, and environmental factors(Hambrick and Finkelstein, 1987) other thanownership concentration which may impact uponmanagerial discretion are typically ignored.Nevertheless, even though modern corporationsare often characterized by diffused ownership,managers are not necessarily able to engage indiscretionary behavior (Oviatt, 1988).

There is much literature devoted to an analysisof the various constraints on managerial discretionand their impact on the power of top management(Finkelstein, 1992). These constraints may beclassified as internal, or external (Walsh andSeward, 1990). Internal constraints largely ema-nate from the BOD and are exercised on behalfof shareholders (owners). Internal constraintsreflect the composition and powers of the BOD,including the ease by which shareholders canappoint or remove Board members, and the rulesgoverning voting. External constraints pertain tothe role of markets in monitoring and discipliningmanagers. The most widely noted external con-straint is the market for corporate control (Jensen,1989), but other market-related constraints arisefrom managerial labor markets, product markets,and financial markets.

Consider the internal constraint represented bythe BOD and its composition. A Board that rep-resents shareholder (or stakeholder) interests caneffectively monitor managers by virtue of itsproximity to sources of information. Also,because the BOD is a relatively small body,monitoring costs are low (Kesner, 1987; Bay-singer and Hoskisson, 1990; Baysinger, Kosnikand Turk, 1991). Needless to say, the efficacy ofinternal constraints is dependent on the BODacting in the interests of shareholders (orstakeholders), an assumption which may notalways be justified (Herman, 1981). Unless boardmembers are significant shareholders, their incen-tive to monitor is low and will not approachthat of a dominant, or majority shareholder.1 In

1 In contrast to the classical agency theory position, recentevidence suggests that Boards may still be vigilant monitorseven in the absence of dominant shareholder. Indeed, Fink-elstein and D’Aveni (1994) suggest that vigilant boards com-prised of independent outsiders may have a strong incentiveto monitor managers when they are shareholders. Further,even in the absence of share ownership, Board members havetheir personal reputations as directors at stake, which provides

536 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

countries where workers or other stakeholders arerepresented on the BOD, the incentive as well asthe ability to monitor can also be quite high.

An essential characteristic of internal con-straints is that the responsibility for monitoringfalls to insiders (e.g., owners, or the BOD) whoare directly charged with the responsibility forcorporate governance. What is common to theexternal constraints is that they rely on a varietyof markets or market-based measures to alignthe competing interests and thus, when effective,render monitoring of managers unnecessary. Inthe case of external constraints, shareholders areessentially transferring monitoring responsibilityto markets. In the case of the market for corporatecontrol, managers who do not maximize returnsto shareholders will see their firms acquired andthemselves displaced in favor of more proficientmanagers (Jensen, 1989).

CONSTRAINTS IN A CROSS-NATIONAL CONTEXT

Institutional contexts do generally differ acrosscountries (Hamilton and Biggart, 1988; Estrinand Perotin, 1991; Porter, 1992). Although manyconstraints on managerial discretion are operativein developed market economies, within eachcountry a particular nexus of constraints willemerge. In terms of corporate governance, thesecross-national differences have been quite exten-sively documented (Fukao, 1995; Charkham,1994; Daniels and Morck, 1995; Bishop, 1994;Roe, 1993; Jenkinson and Mayer, 1992).

There is some agreement in the literature thata distinction can be made between the Anglo-American model of corporate governance and thatof Continental Europe and Japan. The former ischaracterized by relatively passive shareholdersand institutional investors, BODs that are notalways independent of management, and moreactive markets for corporate control; the latter ischaracterized by coalitions of active shareholdersand stakeholders, BODs that are more inde-pendent of management, and limited markets forcorporate control.

We summarize the most salient differences in

them with an incentive to be vigilant monitors (Fama andJensen, 1983).

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

Table 1 for the five countries that comprise oursample: the United States, the United Kingdom,Canada, France, and Germany).2 Each element inTable 1 comprises a distinct research topic, wellbeyond the scope of this paper. While there maybe some disagreement about the evaluation of aparticular cell, or even which cells are included,our purpose is to illustrate the factors that haveled to the distinction between the Anglo-Saxonand Continental European systems of corporategovernance.3

In the United States and the United Kingdomshares in most large firms are relatively widelyheld, such that the largest shareholder holds amodest stake in the company. In both the UnitedStates and the United Kingdom, the largest share-holders are increasingly institutions, particularlypension and mutual funds which invest on behalfof individuals. However, in the United States,some 50 percent of all shares are held by individ-uals, double the percentage in the United King-dom (The Economist, 2 December 1995: 107). Inboth countries, shareholders tend to be passive,or what Roe (1994) calls ‘distant shareholders.’Fukao (1995) provides an extensive list of factorsthat restrict the ability of institutional shareholdersin the US to become actively involved in man-agement.

In France, Canada and Germany, the ownershipof firms is less widely dispersed than in the USor UK. Ownership concentration is particularlyapparent in Germany and Canada, where themajority of large firms have a dominant share-holder (Fukao, 1995; Khemani, 1988; Schneider-Lenne, 1992). Of the 400 largest Canadian com-panies, 382 are controlled by a single shareholder,and many of the very largest firms are controlledby families (Price Waterhouse, 1989a; Khemani,1988). In Germany, some 85 percent of the larg-

2 We set out to study all the G7 countries. However, we wereunable to secure sufficient data for Italy and in the course ofour research we decided that Japan represented a sufficientlyspecial case that it warranted more detailed examination. Thatleft the five countries noted in the text.3 One apparent omission is executive compensation, but thisis noted under shareholder powers. Executive compensationschemes are designed to align the interests of managers andowners by providing the appropriate incentives to maximizeprofits (Murphy, 1985; Tosi and Gomez-Mejia, 1989).Another is product market competition. Despite differences inmarket size and domestic competition, all five countries aremembers of a free-trade zone, so that foreign competition isrelatively intense in all cases. Globalization of markets haslikely made this factor relatively similar across countries.

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 537

Table 1. Cross-national comparison of corporate governance

U.S. U.K. Canada France Germany

Ownership dispersion Very high High Low Medium LowOwnership identity Individuals Pension Family Corporate Banks

Pension Mutual Corporate State CorporateMutual fundsfunds

Board of directors Managers Managers Owners Owners OwnersOutsiders Outsiders Managers Workers Workers

OutsidersShareholder powers Low Low Moderate High HighTakeover High High Moderate Low LowFinancing Equity Equity Equity/debt Debt/equity Debt

This table is designed to indicate the salient comparative features of corporate governance structures across countries. Thereforeit highlights differences rather than absolute characteristics. For example, all companies in all countries rely on a mix of debtand equity financing. Our entries indicate the relative importance of each in a cross-national context. More detailed discussionsare found in Fukao (1995), Charkham (1994), Bishop (1994), Daniels and Morck (1995), Roe (1993), Jenkinson and Mayer(1992), and Milgrom and Roberts (1992).

est firms have a dominant shareholder who hasan ownership stake exceeding 25 percent (TheEconomist, 21 January 1995: 71).

France and Germany are characterized by dif-ferent types of owners; in France by nonfinancialcorporations and the state; and in Germany bynonfinancial corporations and banks (Jenkinsonand Mayer, 1992). Although the majority ofFrench firms are not owned by the government,and although there has been considerable privati-zation in France, the French government stillretains ownership positions in several of thatcountry’s key sectors. Relative to the other fourcountries, the extent of state ownership in Franceis distinctly high.

German banks play an important role in theGerman economy. German banks typically holdboth large debt and equity positions in thatnation’s largest corporations. The influence ofGerman banks is augmented by the fact thatshareholders typically deposit their shares withthese financial institutions. The banks collect divi-dends for the individual investor, and are giventhe shareholder’s proxy. This contributes to arelatively high degree of ownership concentration(Edwards and Fischer, 1994).

The role of the BOD flows in part from thestructure of ownership (Li, 1994). In Germanyand France, the composition of the BOD reflectsthe institutions (other firms, banks, government)that are the major shareholders. In addition Ger-

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

many requires large public corporations to adopta two-tiered board. The executive board is com-prised of managers, while the nonexecutive,supervisory board is elected, half by shareholdersand half by employees. The German systemallows for a clear distinction between executiveand nonexecutive (monitoring) functions(Charkham, 1994). In France, firms have theoption of choosing a one- or two-tiered system,although the latter has been rarely used (Fukao,1995). Workers’ representatives have the right toattend meetings, but do not vote. Thus, in Franceand Germany the BOD represents the variousstakeholders in large firms (Jenkinson andMayer, 1992).

In contrast, BODs in the United States andthe United Kingdom are typically comprised ofexecutives (managers) of the firm itself as wellas outside directors who have no ownership stakein the company. Shareholder involvement is mini-mized, particularly in the United States, by theneed to avoid obtaining inside information thatwould legally limit their ability to trade shares(Fukao, 1995).

In terms of the BOD, Canada appears to rep-resent the middle ground between the Anglo-American and Continental European models. Asa consequence of its concentrated ownershipstructure, Canadian boards tend to have significantshareholder representation, and it is often the casethat the positions of CEO and chair are split

538 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

(Daniels and Morck, 1995). However, the Cana-dian model is not one based on stakeholderssince banks, suppliers, and employees are nottypically represented.

Shareholders have different powers acrosscountries in terms of their control over the BOD.In France and Germany it is relatively easy forshareholders to nominate members to the(supervisory) board, while in Canada, the UnitedStates, and the United Kingdom it is difficult. Inthe latter countries, either a proxy fight must belaunched, or a sizeable shareholding is requiredin order to nominate board members. Likewise,it is possible for shareholders to remove boardmembers by direct vote in France and Germany,but not in the other countries. Fukao (1995) alsocontends that in the United States and to a lesserextent the United Kingdom executive compen-sation is not under the effective control of acorporation’s owners. Fukao goes on to contrastthis with Germany, where employee represen-tation on supervisory boards restrains the abilityof managers to pay themselves excessive salaries.

Fukao (1995) concludes that the above con-siderations indicate that shareholder powers aregenerally higher in France and Germany than inthe United States or the United Kingdom. Again,Canada appears to be somewhere in between.Although Canadian rules and regulations are simi-lar to those in the United States and the UnitedKingdom, Canada’s high levels of ownership con-centration suggest thatde factoshareholder pow-ers are somewhat higher.

The threat of a corporate takeover can be apowerful constraint on executive behavior sincetop managers are likely to lose their jobs sub-sequent to a merger (Jensen, 1989). However,the extent to which the takeover constraint isoperative is a function of both public policyregarding mergers and acquisitions as well asthe degree to which ownership structures permithostile takeovers.

Legislation is on the books in most countrieswhich permits authorities to review and prohibitmergers. The powers of the French governmentare especially sweeping in this regard. Despitethe active market for corporate control in theUnited States, federal antitrust regulation has tra-ditionally curtailed horizontal merger activity(Montgomery and Wilson, 1986; Porter, 1987).In contrast, the Canadian government has takena much morelaissez faireposition on horizontal

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

mergers and even the new Competition Act ismore relaxed regarding mergers (Khemani andShapiro, 1994). In Canada and France, mergerswhich involve foreign entities taking over a do-mestic concern may be subject to special reviews,and this limits the market for corporate controlin these countries.

However, the most important differences in theoperation of the market for corporate controlemerge not from public policy differences, butfrom differences in corporate ownership and con-trol. In Canada, Germany, and France the concen-tration of ownership and the degree of intercorpo-rate holdings make hostile takeovers moredifficult. This is particularly so in Germany,where bank ownership severely restricts the mar-ket for corporate control so that hostile takeoversare very rare (Jenkinson and Mayer, 1992). Ingeneral, markets for corporate control are mostactive in the United States and the United King-dom (Fukao, 1995; Jenkinson and Mayer, 1992).

The need for external sources of financing canalso present a powerful constraint on managerialbehavior (Milgrom and Roberts, 1992). The factthat managers must periodically go outside thefirm for financing may serve to lessen both costpadding and self-interested strategizing. Theextent to which managers face a financing con-straint is largely a function of disclosure require-ments (i.e., the amount of information managersmust disclose to outside investors) and the natureof the debt and equity contracts (Williamson,1985).

In general, firms in the United States, theUnited Kingdom and, to a lesser extent Canadaand France, are relatively more reliant on equityas sources of funds. One consequence has beenthat disclosure rules are more stringent in thesecountries, particularly the United States. Franceand Canada also have quite comprehensive dis-closure requirements. German disclosure require-ments are rather lax and lag far behind otherWestern nations in this regard (Euromoney, 1990;Price Waterhouse, 1988, 1989a, 1989b, 1990,1991a).

Summary

Although the concentration and identity of ownersas well as the nature of the constraints faced bymanagers vary quite markedly across nationalcontexts, two pairs of countries apparently share

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 539

similar characteristics. Relative to firms in theUnited States and the United Kingdom, firms inFrance and Germany are more concentrated andstable in terms of ownership and have boardsthat better represent owners’ interests. Moreover,the more concentrated ownership structure ofFrench and German firms, the important roleGerman banks and the French firms play as share-holders, and the influence of workers minimizethe use of take-overs as an external constraint.Conversely, firms in the United States and theUnited Kingdom rely more heavily on take-overmarkets and equity markets as means of influenc-ing or displacing managers. However, in theUnited States and United Kingdom internal con-straints are relatively weak because of high levelsof ownership dispersion and BODs that areresponsible to management, not shareholders.

The contrast between the United States and theUnited Kingdom, where control relies more onselling a company, to Germany and France (andJapan), where control relies more on direct inter-action between shareholders and management,leads Fukao to conclude that corporate controlpractices tend to represent two distinct ‘philoso-phies’ (1995: 34). Others arrive at the same con-clusion, but apply different names to the twophilosophies. Charkham (1994: 360) refers to‘networked’ and ‘high tension’ systems to dis-tinguish Germany and Japan from the UnitedStates and the United Kingdom, and placesFrance somewhere in between. Nickell (1995)refers to Type I and Type II systems; Jenkinsonand Mayer (1992) to ‘insider’ and ‘outsider’ sys-tems; Rybczynski (1986) to ‘bank oriented’ and‘market oriented’ systems; andThe Economist(10 February, 1996) calls them ‘stakeholder’ and‘shareholder capitalisms’.4

We prefer to use terminology consistent withthe analysis of internal and external constraintson managerial discretion developed earlier. Thus,the main constraints on managerial behavior inFrance and Germany appear to be internal, ratherthan external to the firm. That is, in those coun-

4 Of course, there exist differences in opinion regardingwhether such simple dichotomies can be applied to all coun-tries. As noted, Charkham (1994) tends to classify Francesomewhat differently. It would appear to be the case thatGermany (and Japan) and the United States can be moreclearly distinguished along these simple lines, and someauthors (Roe, 1994) do restrict themselves to comparing onlythese countries.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

tries constraints mainly emanate from the variousstakeholders in the firm. External constraints arerelatively more powerful in the United States andthe United Kindom, where markets, particularlymarkets for corporate control, are relied upon.These conclusions are summarized in Figure 1.

Canada appears to be a country that does noteasily fit into a simple dichotomous world. In thecontext of this study Canada appears to be aunique case. As a small open economy with fairlypermissive merger policy (Caves, Porter, andSpence, 1980), Canadian managers are likely toface powerful outside constraints on their discre-tion. However, the concentrated nature of corpo-rate ownership in Canada indicates that Canadianmanagers will face powerful internal constraintsas well. In Canada, both external and internalconstraints are relied upon through the combi-nation of an open economy, an active market forcorporate control and large numbers of closelyheld firms (Caveset al., 1980). Given that bothtypes of constraints are operative it is not surpris-ing that there is little empirical evidence indicat-ing that managerial discretion has been importantin Canada (Shapiro, Sims, and Hughes, 1984;Daniels and Morck, 1995).

There are no firms from countries with neitherinternal nor external constraint mechanisms rep-resented in our sample. Indeed, we believe thatthere are few countries that could be characterizedin this way. One possible example is China,where there is both a limited market for corporate

Figure 1. Comparative governance structures

540 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

control as well as limitations on internal con-straints created by ownership restrictions. Suchan arrangement is likely unstable in a marketenvironment with private property. In such acase we would expect that some arrangement formonitoring managers would evolve, as suggestedby Demsetz and Lehn (1985).

GENERAL HYPOTHESES

In this section we summarize and synthesize thetheoretical and comparative institutional literatureon corporate governance in order to generate aset of general, testable hypotheses. Our hypoth-eses refer to the degree to which national differ-ences moderate the relationship between owner-ship concentration and profitability in asystematic way. These hypotheses are made spe-cific in the subsequent section.

Our empirical tests and hypotheses are basedon the relationship between firm performance(profitability) and ownership concentration, arelationship emerging from the literature on theseparation of ownership from control. The basichypothesis in that literature, tested many times,is that profitability is a positive function of own-ership concentration because shareholders withlarge stakes in the firm have both the incentiveand ability to monitor managers. In order to drawcomparative inferences from this relationship, therole of other constraints on managerial discretionmust be introduced.

Ownership concentration is but one dimensionof corporate governance; there are other dimen-sions that may serve to limit managerial discretionand enhance firm performance. Using thetypology of Walsh and Seward (1990), we havecharacterized these as internal and external con-straints. The degree to which the constraints arebinding shapes the ownership concentration–performance relationship. If one or more of theseconstraints forces managers to maximize profits,then ownership dispersion is irrelevant and oneshould find no relationship between ownershipconcentration and profitability.

We assume that a positive relationship betweenownership concentration and profitability existsonly if internal and/or external constraints do notexist, or operate imperfectly. When internal andexternal constraints are effectively present, mana-

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

gerial discretion is limited even in the absenceof a dominant shareholder.

The recent literature on comparative govern-ance structures suggests that the internal/externalconstraint dichotomy can be usefully extended todescribe cross-national differences. Earlier, weconcluded that in general the Anglo-Americanmodel relies more heavily on external constraints,while the Continental European model relies moreheavily on internal constraints.

The conclusion that there are two basic modelsof corporate governance is probably not contro-versial, although some (including ourselves)would suggest that not every country fits wellinto one or the other model. More controversialis the question of which of these models is moreeffective. On this question there is much opinion,but little evidence. Walsh and Seward providea systematic analysis of internal and externalconstraints in the United States, but stop short ofconcluding that one is more effective than theother. They do, however, note that ‘in a well-functioning market, it should be less costly toimplement control changes internally rather thanthrough external corporate control contests’(1990: 442).

We contend that the most important of theexternal constraints, the market for corporate con-trol, has serious limitations. Markets do fail, andthe market for corporate control is subject toseveral potential market failures: informationasymmetries, transaction costs, and strategicdeterrence (Besanko, Dranove, and Shanley,1996). Information asymmetries arise becausecorporate insiders are typically more informedthan shareholders and other potential acquirers,and this asymmetry is greater the more dispersedare the shareholders and the more strict are theinsider-trading rules that limit the provision ofinformation to shareholders. Potential acquirersare unlikely to have access to full informationregarding the actions of managers. This is trueof internal constraints as well, but is exacerbatedin the case of outsiders or small shareholders.Even if information is fully available, takeoversare an extremely expensive solution. The trans-action costs of effecting a change in ownershipare very high, and therefore can deter suchactions. These costs effectively limit both thenumber of potential acquirers and the number ofpotential targets. Potential targets have also beenlimited by the widespread strategic use of anti-

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 541

takeover devices, thus deterring potential acqui-sitions. In addition, since takeovers tend to occurin waves, the use of the takeover market as ameans of disciplining managers may not be avail-able at all times. The recent emphasis on thecomposition of the Board and the related attemptsto impose a minimum level of external represen-tation suggest that many believe that market-based constraints have not been powerful enoughto fully constrain managers.5

While it is true that all constraints are likelyimperfect in their ability to constrain managers(Walsh and Seward, 1990), the failures associatedwith the market for corporate control seem partic-ularly acute. Because this is the most important ofthe external constraints, we assume that externalconstraints are in general less effective in con-straining managers than are internal constraints.

The preceding lines of argument allow us toformulate general hypotheses regarding the man-ner in which ownership concentration affectsprofitability across countries. We assume thatownership concentration will be important onlywhen other constraints (both internal andexternal) are not binding, or are not effective.We conclude that France and Germany arecharacterized by a relative reliance on internalconstraints, and we assume that these are moreeffective than external constraints. Thus, in gen-eral:

Hypothesis 1: In countries characterized byinternal constraints, ownership concentrationwill be unrelated to profitability. This hypoth-esis holds for France and Germany.

On the other hand, relative reliance on external

5 The relative effectiveness of the constraints may also differaccording to the nature of managerial behavior. External andinternal constraints may be equally effective in monitoringcost-augmenting behavior because the ability to monitor iseasier. Cost-augmenting expenditure, such as corporate jets areboth more visible and discernible through publicly availableinformation such as financial statements and news reports.However, internal constraints may be superior where self-interested strategizing is more of a concern. The evaluationof strategic conduct, at least in the short term, is not soeasily discerned from financial statements and published newsreports. To the extent that insiders are better able to discernboth the intentions of managers and the context in whichstrategic decisions are made, insiders will have a ‘thicker’(Geertz, 1973) understanding of managerial activities. Thus,markets may be less effective in monitoring strategicdecisions.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

constraints characterizes the United States and theUnited Kingdom, and we assume these to be lesseffective than internal constraints. Thus:

Hypothesis 2: In countries characterized byexternal constraints, ownership concentrationwill be positively related to profitability. Thishypothesis holds for the United States and theUnited Kingdom.

Although Canada is a country that superficiallyresembles the United States and the United King-dom, with its reliance on external constraints, theconcentrated nature of corporate ownership inCanada suggests that internal constraints arepowerful in that country. The importance of inter-nal constraints leads to:

Hypothesis 3: In countries characterized byboth internal and external constraints owner-ship concentration will be unrelated to prof-itability. This hypothesis holds for Canada.

RESEARCH DESIGN AND SPECIFICHYPOTHESES

In order to make our general hypotheses moreconcrete, we specify and estimate an empiricalmodel linking ownership concentration and prof-itability. We begin by addressing the problem ofhow to specify the relevant equation(s).

Most empirical studies have analyzed therelationship between profitability (p) and owner-ship concentration (OWN) by estimating an equ-ation of the general formp = F(OWN, X), whereX is a vector of control variables such as industryand firm size. Expressed in linear form (andsuppressing the error term) the equation may bewritten as:

p = a + b * OWN + d * X (1)

The hypothesis is thatb .0. In some versions asquared ownership term is included, an issuedeveloped below.

The problem with Equation 1 is that ownershipconcentration is used as a general measure of theextent of managerial discretion, but it does notdistinguish between cost-augmenting and self-interested strategizing results of managerialdiscretion. While both types of behavior are more

542 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

likely when ownership is relatively dispersed(assuming that the constraints are not binding),the OWN term is in a sense measured with errorand its coefficient may be biased towards zeroand could even be negative (as some studieshave found).

The argument may be illustrated as follows.Consider a model in which corporate performance(p) is determined by both short-run cost-augmenting behavior (C) and self-interested strat-egizing (I), as well as by other factors (X). Thus,p = f(C,I,X). However, both C and I are func-tions of ownership concentration, C= g(OWN)and I= h(OWN), each having a separate impacton performance. If one estimates an equationsuch as Equation 1, the two effects are con-founded since OWN represents both C and I.

We can specify a version of Equation 1 thatattempts to disentangle these two effects. Wefollow the traditional approach with respect tocost escalation; that is, we take it as unobservableand therefore assume that cost escalation is afunction of ownership concentration, so that, C=g(OWN) as above. We initially assume a simpleproportionate relationship, C= b1 * OWN. Theimplied relationship is negative since the capacityfor managers to escalate costs in order to providethemselves with perks is reduced when ownershipis concentrated, other things equal.

While many profit-reducing activities are alsounobservable, there is one that is observable andhas been documented in the literature: diversifi-cation. There is evidence that diversification isnegatively related to ownership concentration(Amihud and Lev, 1981; Hansen and Hill, 1991)and so we assume that self-interested strategizingoccurs primarily through the vehicle of excessivediversification. We follow this literature inassuming that excessive diversification is relatedto ownership concentration in the sense thatunmonitored managers (in firms with low owner-ship concentration) will diversify in ways incon-sistent with profit maximization. Specifically, weassume that the ratio of excessive diversification(DIVE) to total, observed diversification (DIV)is given by:

DIVE/DIV = d0 + d1 * OWN

As ownership concentration increases, managersare more constrained in their investment behaviorand are less able to undertake diversification

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

activity aimed at maximizing their own utility.As a consequence, d1 is expected to be negativewhile d0 must be positive.6

For estimation purposes, we multiply both sidesby DIV, which is observable, so that:

DIVE = d0 * DIV + d1 * OWN * DIV

These steps allow us to amend Equation 1. Ingeneral we seek to estimate an equation of theform p = f(C,I,X). Our proxy for C is b1 *OWN and our proxy for I is d0 * DIV+ d1 *OWN * DIV. In linear form and after substitutionour amended equation is:

p = a + b1 * OWN + b2 * OWN * DIV

+ b3 * DIV + d * X (2)

Since cost-augmenting behavior (b1 * OWN)decreases profitability, and since b1 is negative,we expect b1 . 0: the same prediction as theexisting literature. Likewise, since excessivediversification (d0 * DIV + d1 * OWN * DIV)reduces profitability and since d1 is negative, wealso expectb2 . 0, a result suggesting that anynegative diversification effects are reduced byconcentrated ownership. Finally, we expect thatb3 , 0 since d0 is positive. This too is consistentwith the existing literature.

For the purposes of this paper, we are inter-ested in the ownership terms. The presence ofsignificant ownership effects is indicated byb1 . 0 and b2 . 0. That is, ownership concen-tration increases profits directly (b1 . 0) andreduces the negative effects of profit-reducingdiversification (b2 . 0).

Recent empirical evidence suggests that therelationship between performance and ownershipconcentration may be nonlinear in nature (Morck,Shleifer and Vishny, 1988). A nonlinear relation-ship is suggested if at low levels of ownershipconcentration the costs of monitoring exceed thebenefits (which must be shared with othershareholders), while the reverse is true at higher

6 Assume that OWN is scaled such that it varies between 0and 1, where a value of 1 indicates that the firm is whollyowned by a single person. If OWN= 1 we expect that man-agers will be completely monitored and so no excessivediversification will be possible, that is, DIVE= 0. Thus,DIVE/DIV = 0 = d0 + d1 * 1. Since d1, 0, d0 must be posi-tive (and equal in absolute value to d1).

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 543

levels of ownership concentration. This argumentsuggests that the relationship between ownershipconcentration and profitability may initially benegative, but will become positive as concen-tration increases. The interactive specification inEquation 2 is consistent with a nonlinear relation-ship betweenp and OWN if DIV is itself afunction of OWN. However, given the possibilitythat the nonlinear relationship betweenp andOWN persists, even after inclusion of the inter-active term, we also estimate the followingmodel:

p = a + B1 * OWN + B2 * OWN2

+ B3 * OWN * DIV

+ B4 * DIV + d * X (3)

In the case of Equation 3, significant ownershipeffects will exist if B1, 0 and B2. 0 (reflectingthe argument above), but the combined effect ispositive over a significant range of firms, and/orif B3 . 0 (as before).

Our specific hypotheses may now be summa-rized in terms of Equations 2 and 3. Our generalhypotheses suggest that ownership effects will bepresent in the United States and the United King-dom, but not in France, Germany, or Canada.The resulting specific hypotheses based on ourmodel are found in Table 2.

Table 2. Summary of specific hypotheses

OWN OWN * DIV OWN2

U.S., U.K. POSITIVE POSITIVE(b1 . 0) (b2 . 0)

U.S., U.K. NEGATIVE POSITIVE POSITIVE(b1 , 0) (b3 . 0) (b2 . 0)

Germany, ZERO ZEROFrance, (b1 = 0) (b2 = 0)CanadaGermany, ZERO ZERO ZEROFrance, (b1 = 0) (b3 = 0) (b2 = 0)Canada

OWN refers to ownership concentration, DIV to the degreeof diversification, and OWN * DIV to their interaction. Entriesin the table refer to the expected sign of the estimatedcoefficients on these terms.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

DATA AND VARIABLES

Sample selection and data collection

The sample consists of 1030 medium to large-sized publicly traded, private sector (not state-owned) firms (minimum assets, US $50 million).The sample is drawn from five countries (Canada,France, Germany, the United Kingdom, and theUnited States), 11 industrial sectors (Automobile(AUTO), Food and Beverage (FOOD), Chemicals(CHEM), Construction (CONS), Electrical(ELEC), Machinery (MACH), Electronic(TRON), Oil and Gas (OIL), Pulp and Paper(PAPR), and Retailing (RETL)) and spans 6years: 1986–91. U.S. firms make up 60.7 percentof the sample, followed by U.K. firms (12.9%),German firms (9.6%), Canadian firms (8.8%),and French firms (8.0%). Thus the U.S. sampleis considerably larger than the others, which arein turn of roughly equal size. The sample wasrestricted to industries where sufficient represen-tation from each of the five countries was pos-sible.

The large representation of U.S. firms mightbe attributable to three factors. First, the largeabsolute size of the U.S. economy means thatmore firms are likely to meet the U.S. $50 millioncut-off. Second, the rigorous disclosure require-ments imposed upon U.S. firms by the SECmeans that sufficient financial and ownership dataare more likely to be available for those firms.Finally, public (government) sector ownership ismore common in Canada, France, Germany, andthe United Kingdom than it is in the UnitedStates and this study considers only private sector(i.e., not state-owned) firms. As such, the mediumto large-sized state-run enterprises that are a moresalient feature of Canada, France, Germany, andthe United Kingdom than the United States isanother contributing factor to the large represen-tation of U.S. firms.

The data source for financial and strategic vari-ables was theDisclosure–Spectrum–Ownership(WorldScope-Disclosure, 1991) data base, andthis source established the number of observationsand the basic sample. However, it does notinclude ownership data and this had to be col-lected from other country-specific sources. Cana-dian ownership data were collected fromTheFinancial Post Survey of Industrials; French datafrom Dun and Bradstreet’sFrance 30,000; Ger-man data from Commerzbank’sA Guide to Capi-

544 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

tal Links in German Companies; U.K. data fromThe European Companies Handbook(PriceWaterhouse, 1991b); and U.S. data from theDisclosure–Spectrum–Ownership(WorldScope-Disclosure, 1991) data base. Ownership data formost firms could only be obtained for 1991.

Variable measurement

Ownership concentration (OWN)

A variety of measures of ownership concentrationhave appeared in the literature. In this study wemeasure ownership concentration by the percent-age of shares outstanding held by the largestshareholder. The square of OWN is referred toas OWNSQ.

This measure is among the most widelyemployed in the literature and is the most widelyavailable and accurate measure to obtain acrosscountries, and is easy to interpret. For thesereasons we chose it over other measures, bothcontinuous and discrete. Discrete (threshold) mea-sures are not considered because there is noconsensus on the appropriate threshold of stockconcentration to distinguish between owner andmanager-controlled firms (Kaulmann, 1987). Theproblem of selecting an owner-controlled/manager-controlled threshold is particularly acutewhen employing a cross-national sample becausethresholds are likely to vary across countries. Inorder to evaluate the comparability of the OWNvariable with other ownership measures, two othercontinuous measures of ownership were calcu-lated (the percentage of shares held in blocks of5%, or more (Bethel and Liebeskind, 1993; Redi-ker and Seth, 1995), as well as a Herfindahlindex of stock concentration (Demsetz and Lehn,1985). The OWN measure used here is correlatedat r = 0.84 (p , 0.001) with the 5 percent blockmeasure and also highly correlated atr = 0.81(p , 0.001) with the Herfindahl measure. Thesecorrelations between alternative continuous meas-ures of ownership are consistent with thosereported by Demsetz and Lehn (1985) and morerecently by Rediker and Seth (1995), who reporta correlation ofr = 0.95 between the OWN meas-ure used in this study and the 5 percent block-holder measure. These results strongly indicatethat alternative continuous measures of ownershipare highly correlated.

Because ownership information is available for

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

1 year only, we take the 1991 level of ownershipconcentration as the best available estimate forall years. While not ideal, this approach allowspooled cross-sectional analysis over a period thatincludes periods of both expansion and contrac-tion. There is some evidence that ownership con-centration is stable over time, a result which isnot unexpected given that significant sharehold-ings are likely to be sold in blocks, leavinganother shareholder with a concentrated owner-ship stake.7

Return on assets (ROA)

ROA is measured as the ratio of net income tototal assets. This is the dependent variable inall equations.

Diversification (DIV)

Worldscope lists the 4-digit SIC industries inwhich the firm operates. It does not list therevenues generated within each industry, but doeslist them in order of importance. Thus, it ispossible to measure diversification by a simpleSIC count. This is, however, a somewhat crudemeasure (Hill and Snell, 1988) and for this reasonwe measured diversification using the weightingmethod proposed by Caves (1975) and employedby Caves et al. (1980) and Pomfret andShapiro (1981).

DIV = S Pi * d ij

where i = a firm’s primary market segmentj = a firm’s secondary market

segmentdij = 0 if the firm operates in only

one 4-digit industry= 1 if j is in the same 3-digit

industry asi= 2 if j is in the same 2-digit

industry asi= 3 if i and j are in different 2-

digit industries

Pi = a weight imputed to each industry, assumed

7 See Morcket al. (1988) for both theoretical and empiricalsupport of the idea that ownership concentration is stableover time and Gedajlovic (1993) for evidence that it is stablein Canada over the time period considered in this paper.

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 545

to decline geometrically: 1, 2, 4, 8, 16. Forexample, if a firm operates in two industries, therevenues are assumed to be distributed in a 2 : 1ratio, that is a 2/3 weight is attributed to the firstSIC code and a 1/3 weight to the second SICcode. If the firm operates in three industries, theweights would be 4/7, 2/7 and 1/7.

The DIV measure is similar to a standardHerfindahl measure of diversification, except thatthe industry weights are imputed from a geo-metric series rather than being taken from actualline of business data. This measure does accountfor the various elements of diversification notedby Palepu (1985) in that it accounts for thenumber of product market segments in which thefirm competes, it factors in the distribution ofsales across the segments, and it incorporates ameasure of relatedness.8 This variable could onlybe calculated for 1 year, 1991, and is thereforeassumed to be constant over the relevant period.The interaction between DIV and OWN isreferred to as OWN * DIV.

The following variables constitute additionalexogenous variables, previously subsumed underthe X-vector in Equations 2 and 3. These vari-ables have been chosen to control for factorsother than ownership concentration and diversifi-cation which have been found in the literature toaffect profitability.

Growth (SALESG)

The growth rate of firms is included to measuredemand conditions facing the firm, as well asproduct cycle effects. Firms in relatively fast-growing markets (and/or in the growth phase ofthe product cycle) are expected to experienceabove-average profitability. Inclusion of a growthterm has become common in the industrialorganization literature, originating with Hall andWeiss (1967) and Shepherd (1972). A morerecent example in a related context is providedby Markides (1995: Ch. 8), who finds a positiverelationship between profitability and growth. Thevariable employed is measured in terms of

8 It was possible to calculate the Herfindahl measure of diver-sification in some cases (553) because revenues were listedby type of business. The correlation coefficient between thismeasure and DIV is 0.84. The correlation between DIV anda simple count of industries is 0.8.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

changes in year-to-year sales, SALESG= 1 −Salest/Salest−1.

Firm size (LASSETS)

The size of a firm is included to account for thepotential economies of scale and scope accruingto large firms. If present, these would produce apositive relationship between firm size and prof-itability. This argument also has its roots in theearly industrial organization literature (Baumol,1959; Hall and Weiss, 1967; Shepherd, 1972),and Markides (1995) again provides a morerecent example. Firm size is measured by thelogarithm of total assets.

Geographic scope (FASSETS)

The degree to which firms operate abroad isincluded as an exogenous factor and is measuredas FASSETS= (foreign assets/total assets) * 100.The literature on the Multinational Enterprise sug-gests that MNEs, or their subsidiaries, tend topossess firm-specific assets that provide them withperformance advantages (Caves, 1996). Thus, itmight be expected that firms with significant for-eign operations would be more profitable (Jung,1991; Grant, 1987; Morck and Yeung, 1991).

Industry effects (INDUSTRY)

Industry effects account for the nature of thecompetitive environment in which a firm operates,for example the number and size dispersion ofindustry rivals and the rate of growth of theindustry. In order to capture these effects, a seriesof industry indicator variables is created and eachfirm is allocated to an industry according tothe firm’s primary activity. Schmalensee (1985),Montgomery and Wernerfelt (1988) and Rumelt(1991) all use indicator variables to captureindustry effects.

Temporal effects (YEAR)

A firm’s year-to-year performance will be affec-ted by general economic conditions and businesscycle conditions. As suggested by Rumelt (1991),the effects of the general business climate arecontrolled for as an exogenous factor by includinga series of five indicator variables, one for eachyear in the period 1986–90.

546 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

SPECIFICATION AND ESTIMATION

The models to be estimated are Equations 2 and3, wherep is measured by ROA, OWN and DIVare as defined above, and the X-vector consistsof SALESG, FASSETS, LASSETS, as well asdummy variables for industry affiliation(INDUSTRY) and year (YEAR).

The data are pooled over the 6-year period1986–91. Because the panel is relatively short inyears, but broad in terms of the cross-section offirms, heteroscedasticity was deemed an importantissue. All estimates are therefore ordinary leastsquares with heteroscedastic consistent standarderrors calculated according to White’s method.The indicator variables for each year account forserial correlation.

The model was first estimated by pooling alldata from all countries and was then estimatedon a country-by-country basis. Chow tests indi-cated that pooling was not appropriate and soresults are presented for each country.

With one exception, we report the same equ-ation for each country. The exception is the OWNterm. For each country we ran the model withand without the squared term and test for itsinclusion using a standardF-test. The result isthat the nonlinear specification was confirmed forthe United States, Germany, and France, whilethe linear (OWN only) was confirmed for theUnited Kingdom and Canada. The results arereported accordingly.

A variety of alternative specifications involvingthe inclusion or exclusion of other variables(primarily because of some multicollinearity)were examined, but these do not alter the basicresults unless otherwise noted and we thereforereport only the most general equation.

RESULTS

Descriptive statistics are found in Table 3. Themeans indicate that, for our sample, mean size isnot very different across countries, nor is themean level of diversification except for the U.S.sample, which is on average much less diversi-fied. Ownership concentration varies greatlyacross countries, with the United States and theUnited Kingdom least concentrated and Germanythe most. Average growth rates, average profitrates, and average degree of foreign diversifi-cation also differ considerably across countries.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

The explanatory power of the regression equa-tions is very similar across countries. There issome multicollinearity between OWN * DIV andDIV or OWN, but deletion of the former doesnot alter the results in terms of either DIV orOWN. The regression results (excluding thosefor the industry and year dummy variables) aresummarized in Table 4 and we organize ourdiscussion around this table. Full results can befound in Table 5.

The coefficients of primary consequence to thisstudy are those for the ownership concentrationterms (OWN and OWNSQ) and for the inter-action of diversification and ownership concen-tration, OWN * DIV. The signs on these termsclearly differ across countries, suggesting that theconstraints on managerial discretion do vary ineffectiveness across countries. Strong ownershipeffects are found in the United States, weakereffects in Germany, traces of effects in the UnitedKingdom, and no effects at all in Canada orFrance.

Given that there are intercountry differencesin the way that ownership concentration affectsprofitability, can these differences be explainedby the systematic cross-national differences ingovernance structures summarized in Figure 1and formalized in the specific hypotheses summa-rized in Table 2? Not completely. These hypoth-eses suggest that no ownership effects of anykind should be found in Germany, France orCanada (albeit for slightly different reasons). Thisis certainly true for France and Canada. Forthese countries the coefficients of OWN and/orOWNSQ are not different from 0 and the coef-ficient of OWN * DIV is also not different from0. In Canada and France more concentrated own-ership does not enhance profitability eitherdirectly or indirectly through its effect on diversi-fication. We interpret this as meaning that neithercost-augmenting nor self-interested strategizingare affected by ownership concentration in Can-ada or France.

Our hypotheses suggest that ownership effectsshould be similar in the United States and UnitedKingdom. This is not quite what we find. Forthe United States, direct nonlinear ownershipeffects are found (the OWN coefficient is nega-tive and significant; OWNSQ is positive andsignificant). For a nondiversified U.S. company(DIV = 0), profitability declines with ownershipconcentration up to an ownership concentrationlevel of about 43 percent, more than twice the

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 547

Table 3. Descriptive statistics means and (standard deviations)

U.S. U.K. Germany France Canada

DIV 0.53 0.97 0.92 0.94 0.94(0.49) (0.42) (0.38) (0.45) (0.45)

OWN 18.96 21.00 68.48 46.89 48.76(17.25) (23.32) (30.17) (27.34) (29.25)

OWNSQ 657.06 983.98 5598.12 2944.07 3231.74(1251.73) (2229.95) (3893.53) (2938.32) (3095.79)

OWN * DIV 9.21 19.91 61.80 42.01 47.76(14.79) (26.50) (40.19) (32.31) (37.54)

LASSETS 2.61 3.06 2.92 2.59 2.66(0.77) (0.65) (0.60) (0.57) (0.57)

SALESG 13.25 6.63 8.20 14.51 13.46(37.32) (60.21) (22.50) (41.86) (43.81)

FASSETS 12.68 2.13 0.39 6.03 18.84(17.49) (8.64) (3.75) (13.19) (21.31)

ROA 7.92 11.02 5.26 7.62 6.32(8.96) (7.58) (8.94) (8.37) (9.35)

Variable definitions: OWN is ownership concentration (share of the largest shareholder); OWNSQ is the square of OWN;DIV is weighted diversification; OWN * DIV is the interaction of OWN and DIV; LASSETS is the natural logarithm of totalassets; SALESG is the growth of sales, 1986–91; FASSETS is foreign assets (assets abroad as a percentage of total assets);ROA is return on assets. Details regarding calculations are found in the text.

Table 4. Summary of regression results (dependentvariable: ROA)

Variable U.S. U.K. Germany France Canada

OWN − −(t) − 0 0

OWNSQ + N.A. + 0 N.A.

OWN * DIV + +(t) +(t) 0 0

DIV − − 0 −(t) 0

LASSETS + −(t) − 0 0

SALESG + + + + +

FASSETS − 0 − + 0

+: coefficient is positive and statistically significant at 95%levels of confidence, two-tailed test;− : coefficient is negativeand statistically significant at 95% levels of confidence, two-tailed test; 0: t-statistic approximates 0 (i.e. 1. (t) , −1),two-tailed test; N.A.: not in the equation;+(t): coefficient ispositive and thet-statistic exceeds 1;−(t): coefficient isnegative and thet-statistic exceeds 1.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

U.S. mean, after which it becomes positive. Fora U.S. company diversified at the mean level(DIV = 0.53), the turning point occurs at an own-ership concentration level of about 33 percent,slightly less than twice the concentration meanand approximately one standard deviation abovethe mean. In the United States, concentrated own-ership does not exert a positive marginal effecton profitability unless the firm is either highlyconcentrated, or highly diversified.

For the United States, direct positive ownershipeffects exist, but only for a relatively small num-ber of firms. We interpret this as providing someconfirmation that cost-augmenting managerialbehavior is not rampant in the United States andthat for most firms the market-based constraintscommon to that country are effective.

As we hypothesized, the interaction betweendiversification and ownership concentration(OWN * DIV) positively affects profitability inthe United States. The negative effects of diversi-fication in the United States are eroded by about0.055 for each unit increase in ownership concen-tration and are eliminated at an ownership con-centration level of about 36 percent. We takethis as providing some confirmation that profit-reducing investment activity does take place, ashypothesized. The U.S. evidence is, on balance,consistent with our hypotheses.

548 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

Table 5. Regression results: Dependent variable ROA

Predictor U.S. U.K. German France Canada

C 5.32*** 12.86*** 13.47*** 8.99*** 2.63Y1 −0.11* 1.99* 0.82 1.64 −2.57**Y2 0.42 5.76*** 0.65 2.00* −2.25*Y3 1.00 4.31*** 0.47 2.82*** 0.82Y4 0.03 0.75*** 0.19 0.53* −0.004Y5 −0.95 2.40*** 0.28 −0.28 −0.03AUTO 0.74*** 0.94 3.25*** −1.25 3.44**FOOD 3.84*** 2.65*** −2.60 −1.27 3.83**CHEM 4.64 3.94*** 4.13*** −2.10 6.02***CONS 0.15 2.19** −0.61 3.46* 4.93***ELEC 1.28 3.92*** 17.71*** −3.88** 4.40**TRON 2.88*** 5.63 1.69 −3.15** 2.14MACH 1.36* 2.84** 0.89 −4.54** 4.23**OIL −2.67*** 0.07 0.86 −4.71*** 2.76PAPR 3.40*** 1.04 2.67** −0.85 3.29**RETL 1.14* 5.40*** 1.29 −5.16*** 3.18**DIV −1.99*** −4.39*** −1.63 −1.55 1.31OWN −0.13*** −0.06 −0.24*** −0.005 −0.004OWN2 0.02*** 0.02*** −0.003OWN * DIV 0.06** 0.04 0.04* 0.02 0.04LASSETS 0.81*** −0.88* −2.05*** −0.52 −0.45SALESG 0.08*** 0.04*** 0.05* 0.08*** 0.10***FASSETS −0.02** −0.01 −0.62*** 0.07*** −0.02Adjusted R2 0.20 0.22 0.23 0.25 0.26F 27.65*** 10.23*** 8.61*** 7.12*** 9.12***

Standard errors shown are heteroscedastic-consistent estimates using White’s method.*** p , 0.01; **p , 0.05; *p , 0.1C is the constant; Y1–Y5 are dummy variables for each year, 1986–90; AUTO–RETL are industry dummy variables; theother variables are as defined in Table 3 and the text.

The United Kingdom was hypothesized to becomparable to the United States. That is not thecase. No nonlinear relationship between owner-ship concentration and profitability was found inthe United Kingdom, and the coefficient on theOWN term is negative, but not significant. How-ever, the coefficient on the interactive term, whilepositive, is not statistically significant and this isnot consistent with our hypotheses. However,when the size term (LASSETS) is removed fromthe U.K. equation, the OWN * DIV coefficientremains positive, and thet-statistic rises to 1.76,nearly significant at conventional levels on a two-tailed test.9

If any country approximates the U.S. results itis Germany. In that country, direct ownershipeffects are nonlinear and both the OWN and

9 In this instance we might be entitled to a one-tailed test,since the hypothesis is clearly that OWN * DIV is positive.However, since we cannot be so unambiguous in all cases,we have chosen to use two-tailed tests throughout.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

OWNSQ coefficients are significant (negative andpositive respectively). The point at which owner-ship concentration exerts a positive effect for anondiversified firm is at OWN= 70 percent,roughly the German mean. Thus, relatively moreGerman firms are likely to lie in the positiverange than would be the case in the United States.The OWN * DIV coefficient is positive with at-statistic of 1.77, which would make it statisticallysignificant at between 90 percent and 95 percentconfidence levels (two-tailed test). This is clearlycontrary to our hypothesis. However, it shouldbe noted that no negative diversification effectsare found in Germany, so that it is not clearwhat the interaction term actually implies. If thesize term (LASSETS) is deleted, then DIVbecomes significant and negative and OWN *DIV becomes significant and positive, again con-trary to our expectations.

At the most general level, it is evident that theresults do differ from country to country. Theonly variable whose coefficient is both of the

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 549

same sign and is statistically significant acrosscountries is the firm’s growth of sales (SALESG).Firms which grow faster are on average moreprofitable in all countries. Even so, the value ofthe coefficients varies considerably so that impactof growth on profitability differs across countries.Beyond this, there is very little in common acrossequations. Greater foreign diversification reducesprofitability in the United States and Germany,enhances it in France, and has no impact inCanada or the United Kingdom. Larger size isadvantageous in the United States but not inGermany, and has no impact in the other coun-tries. Greater diversification reduces profitabilityin the United States and the United Kingdom,but has no impact on profitability in Canada,France, or Germany.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS

Despite the integration of national economies andproduct, capital, and factor markets, countriesdiffer markedly in terms of the institutionalarrangements regarding corporate governance.The results reported in the previous section offersome confirmation of the importance of nationalcontext on corporate governance relationships.Our results do suggest that country effects existin the ownership concentration–profitabilityrelationship. Institutional differences across coun-tries matter, but in ways that we have not beenable to identify in a completely satisfactory man-ner.

The fact that the signs of most of the controlvariables entered into the regression equationsreported in Table 4 differ markedly across coun-tries offers an indication that institutional contextsmay play a role in moderating important strategy–performance relationships as well. Of particularnote are the collateral findings associated withthe diversification–performance relationship.

Consistent with a very large body of literaturewith its genesis in the work of Rumelt (1974),we find a negative relationship between diversifi-cation and performance in the United States.Similarly, we find a negative relationship betweendiversification and performance in the UnitedKingdom. On the other hand, results for France,Germany, and Canada indicate that the negativerelationship between diversification and perform-ance does not generalize to the experience of

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

firms operating in other industrialized countries.That is, we find no significant relationshipbetween diversification and performance inFrance, Germany, or Canada.

Unfortunately, while the results reported hereoffer an indication that institutional context mat-ters, they are less revealing of the microprocessesthat underlie the observed differences. Themethodological approach employed here wasdesigned to shed light on these microprocessesby linking agency theory with the literature oncomparative corporate governance. In dis-tinguishing between two distinct sources ofagency costs, managerial cost augmentation andself-interested strategizing, we also derived a newequation for estimating the profitability–ownership concentration equation.

This approach did result in a confirmation ofour hypotheses concerning U.S. firms. That is,we found that among firms operating in the U.S.institutional context diversification did indeedresult in profit reductions when ownership con-centration was low. Specifically, we found thatthe ownership concentration–diversification inter-action term is significant and positively relatedto performance. In contrast, direct ownership con-centration effects are positive and significant, butare only present in firms with very high levelsof ownership concentration. The results indicatethat excessive diversification is a much moreserious source of agency costs than generalizedmanagerial cost padding (Williamson, 1964;Jensen and Meckling, 1976) in the United States.The largely external constraints on managerialdiscretion in the United States appear better suitedtowards curbing cost padding than self-interested strategizing.

In the United Kingdom, like the United States,managers are confronted with significant externaland market-based constraints. However, unlikethe United States, we could not find any owner-ship effects, implying that the internal constraintsfacing the U.K. manager are more effective atresolving agency problems than we had hypothe-sized. One possible explanation is that, like theircontinental counterparts, U.K. managers may facerelatively strong internal constraints. Indeed, thehigher levels of ownership concentration wefound in U.K. firms relative to U.S. firms (Table3) suggests that U.K. managers may face strongerinternal constraints than their U.S. counterparts.Also, U.K. managers may face additional con-

550 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

straints from their Boards since U.K. directorsare legally required to represent the interests ofemployees as well as shareholders (Clark, 1985).In this regard, the constraints facing U.K. man-agers may be similar to those of Canadian man-agers who face both strong external and stronginternal constraints.

As predicted, we find that ownership concen-tration is unrelated to either cost padding, orself-interested strategizing in both France, wheremanagers face strong internal constraints, and inCanada where managers face both formidableinternal and external constraints.

The most puzzling set of findings reported hererelate to German firms.Ex ante, it was expectedthat the strong internal constraints that charac-terize the German institutional context would ren-der ownership concentration redundant in termsof limiting managerial discretion. Contrary toexpectations, we find that in Germany ownershipconcentration does in fact limit both managerialcost padding and the negative consequences ofexcessive diversification. This may indicate thatthe German corporate governance landscapeshares more in common with the U.S. contextthan is commonly believed, or understood. Inparticular, it might suggest that the role of Ger-man banks may be less important than manyhave thought. This result would be consistentwith the views of Edwards and Fischer (1994),who also argue that the role of German bankshas been exaggerated.

The results of this study indicate the needfor further cross-national studies of strategy andcorporate governance. On the one hand, theresults do suggest that institutional context is astrong moderator of corporate governance andstrategic behavior. On the other hand, the country-specific hypotheses developed earlier receivedonly mixed support. As such, the most salientconclusion which may be drawn from this studyis that institutional context matters, but that muchmore research directed at identifying themicroprocesses that underlie these institutionaldifferences is warranted and needed.

There are a number of possible reasons for ourinability to identify the causes of the differencesin the profitability–ownership concentrationrelationship across countries. For one thing, thatrelationship may be sensitive to factors other thanthe constraints we have identified. That is, theremay be missing explanatory variables in each

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

equation. Similarly, the results may be sensitiveto our choice of performance indicator (ROA).Although separate equations have been estimatedfor each country, thus minimizing the effects ofcross-national differences in accounting methods,it is still possible that the results for a specificcountry are sensitive to the choice. In general,further investigation of specification and measure-ment issues is warranted.

The findings reported here offer a number ofimportant implications for managers and publicpolicy makers.

It may be the case that the common distinctionbetween the Anglo-Saxon and Continental Euro-pean countries is simply too broad to capture theeffects on firm performance. Indeed our resultsmight suggest that this typology is too generaland that there is more cross-national variation incorporate governance structures than the typologyindicates. This would in turn suggest some cau-tion in attempts to harmonize national systemsof corporate governance using one or the other‘philosophy’ as a guide. We would thereforeagree with Michael Porter, who argues that publicpolicy makers should adopt a conservativeapproach to harmonization.10

From a managerial perspective, the results indi-cate that caution must be exercised in interpretingand generalizing results across national bound-aries. Given the ongoing globalization of markets,it is vital that both public policy makers andbusiness people who must operate in multiplenational contexts know the extent to which busi-ness and economic relationships found in theUnited States are generalizable to other nationalcontexts. Indeed, this study’s core findings indi-cate that significant differences exist across coun-tries in terms of the relationship between owner-ship concentration and firm performance. As such,it appears that the nature of constraints facingmanagers varies across institutional contexts. Thisimplies that managerial discretion is driven byparticular institutional features of a nation’s insti-tutional context. It might also imply that mana-gerial discretion reflects a variety of institutionalfactors other than ownership concentration.Indeed, recent research on managerial discretionindicates that it is multidimensional in nature andreflects environment, organizational, and individ-

10 Porter’s views are expressed in his comments to Fukao(1995: 92–95).

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 551

ual level factors (Hambrick and Finkelstein, 1987;Finkelstein, 1992). Further cross-national researchexploring the impact of the institutional environ-ment on the many factors that shape managerialdiscretion appears to be in order.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We would like to thank two anonymous reviewersfor their helpful comments and suggestions. Wewould also like to thank Aidan Vining for hisinsightful comments on earlier drafts of thismanuscript.

REFERENCES

Alchian, A. A. and H. Demsetz (1972). ‘Production,information costs and economic organization’,Amer-ican Economic Review, 62, pp. 777–795.

Amihud, Y. and B. Lev (1981). ‘Risk reduction as amanagerial motive for conglomerate mergers’,BellJournal of Economics, 12, pp. 605–617.

Baumol, W. J. (1959).Business Behavior, Value andGrowth. Wiley, New York.

Baysinger, B. B. and R. E. Hoskisson (1990). ‘Thecomposition of boards of directors and strategiccontrol: Effects on corporate strategy’,Academy ofManagement Review, 15, pp. 72–87.

Baysinger, B. B., R. D. Kosnik and T. A. Turk (1991).‘Effects of board and ownership structure on corpo-rate R&D strategy’,Academy of Management Jour-nal, 34, pp. 205–214.

Bentson, G. (1985). ‘The self-serving managementhypothesis: Some Evidence’,Journal of Accountingand Economics, 7, pp. 67–84.

Berle, A. A. and C. G. Means (1932).The ModernCorporation and Private Property. Commerce Clear-ing House, New York.

Besanko, D., D. Dranove and M. Shanley (1996).Economics of Strategy. Wiley, New York.

Bethel, J. E. and J. Liebeskind (1993). ‘The effectsof ownership structure on corporate restructuring’,Strategic Management Journal, Summer SpecialIssue,14, pp. 15–31.

Bishop, M. (1994). ‘Corporate governance’,The Econ-omist, 29 January (Survey), pp. 1–18.

Caves, R. E. (1996).Multinational Enterprise andEconomic Analysis(2nd edn.). Cambridge Univer-sity Press, Cambridge, MA.

Caves, R. E. (1975).Diversification, Foreign Invest-ment and Scale in North American ManufacturingIndustries. Economic Council of Canada, Ottawa.

Caves, R. E., M. E. Porter and A. M. Spence (1980).Competition in the Open Economy. Harvard Univer-sity Press, Cambridge, MA.

Charkham, J. P. (1994).Keeping Good Company: A

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

Study of Corporate Governance in Five Countries.Oxford University Press, New York.

Clark, R. C. (1985). ‘Agency costs versus fiduciaryduties’. In J. W. Pratt and R. J. Zeckhauser (eds.),Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business.Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA,pp. 55–80.

Commerzbank (1991).A Guide to Capital Links inGerman Companies. Commerzbank AG, Frankfurt.

Daniels, R. J. and R. Morck (1995).CorporateDecision-making in Canada. University of CalgaryPress, Calgary.

Demsetz, H. and K. Lehn (1985). ‘The structure ofcorporate ownership’,Journal of Political Economy,93, pp. 1155–1177.

Dunn and Bradstreet (1991).Dunn and Bradstreet’sFrance 30 000. Dunn and Bradstreet, Paris.

Edwards, J. and K. Fischer (1994).Banks, Financeand Investment in Germany. Cambridge UniversityPress, Cambridge, MA.

Eisenhardt, K. (1989). ‘Agency theory: An assessmentand review’, Academy of Management Review, 14,pp. 57–74.

Estrin, S. and V. Perotin (1991). ‘Does ownershipalways matter?’, International Journal IndustrialOrganization, 9, pp. 55–72.

Euromoney(1990).The European Company Handbook.Euromoney, London.

Fama, E. F. and M. C. Jensen (1983). ‘The separationof ownership and control’,Journal of Law andEconomics, 26, pp. 301–328.

Financial Post (1991). The Financial Post Survey ofIndustrials 1991. Financial Post, Toronto.

Finkelstein, S. (1992). ‘Power in top managementteams: Dimensions, measurement and validation’,Academy of Management Journal, 35, pp. 505–538.

Finkelstein, S. and R. A. D’Aveni (1994). ‘CEO dualityas a double-edged sword: How boards of directorsbalance entrenchment avoidance and unity of com-mand’, Academy of Management Journal, 37(5),pp. 1079–1108.

Fukao, M. (1995).Financial Integration, CorporateGovernance, and the Performance of MultinationalCompanies. The Brookings Institution, Washington,DC.

Gedajlovic, E. (1993). ‘A cross-national study of corpo-rate governance, strategy and performance’, unpub-lished doctoral dissertation, Concordia University,Montreal, Quebec, Canada.

Geertz, C. (1973).The Interpretation of Cultures. BasicBooks, New York.

Grabowski, H. G. and D. C. Mueller (1972). ‘Mana-gerial and stockholder welfare models of firm expen-ditures’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 54,pp. 9–24.

Grant, R. M. (1987). ‘Multinationality and performanceamong British manufacturing companies’,Journalof International Business Studies, 18(3), pp. 79–89.

Hall, M. and L. Weiss (1967). ‘Firm size and prof-itability’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 49(5),pp. 319–331.

Hambrick, D. C. and S. Finkelstein (1987). ‘Managerialdiscretion: A bridge between polar views on organi-

552 E. R. Gedajlovic and D. M. Shapiro

zations’. In L. L. Cummings and B. M. Staw (eds.),Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 9. JAIPress, Greenwich, CT, pp. 369–406.

Hamilton, G. G. and N. W. Biggart (1988). ‘Market,culture and authority: A comparative analysis ofmanagement and organization in the far east’,Amer-ican Journal of Sociology, 94, pp. S52–S94.

Hansen, G. S. and C. W. L. Hill (1991). ‘Are insti-tutional investors myopic? A time series study offour technology-driven industries’,Strategic Man-agement Journal, 12(1), pp. 1–16.

Herman, E. S. (1981).Corporate Control, CorporatePower. University of Cambridge Press, New York.

Hill, C. W. L. and S. A. Snell (1988). ‘Effects of own-ership structure and control on corporate pro-ductivity’, Academy of Management Journal, 32,pp. 25–46.

Hunt, H. G. (1986). ‘The separation of ownership andcontrol: Theory evidence and implications’,Journalof Accounting Literature, 5, pp. 85–124.

Jenkinson, T. and C. Mayer (1992). ‘The assessment:Corporate governance and corporate control’,OxfordReview of Economic Policy, 8(3), pp. 1–10.

Jensen, M. C. (1988). ‘Takeovers, their causes andconsequences’,Journal of Economic Perspectives,2, pp. 21–48.

Jensen, M.C. (1989). ‘Eclipse of the public corpo-ration’, Harvard Business Review, 67(5), pp. 67–74.

Jensen, M. C. and W. H. Meckling (1976). ‘Theory ofthe firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs andownership structure’,Journal of Financial Econom-ics, 3, pp. 305–360.

Jung, Y. (1991). ‘Multinationality and profitability’,Journal of Business Research, 23(2), pp. 179–187.

Kaulmann, T. (1987). ‘Managerialism versus the prop-erty rights theory of the firm’. In G. Bamberg andK. Spreman (eds.),Agency Theory, Information andIncentives. Springer, Berlin, pp. 439–459.

Kesner, I. (1987). ‘Directors’ stock ownership andorganizational performance: An investigation ofFor-tune 500 companies’,Journal of Management, 13,pp. 499–507.

Khemani, R. S. (1988). ‘The dimensions of corporateconcentration in Canada’. In R. S. Khemani, D. M.Shapiro and W. T. Stanbury (eds.),Mergers, Cor-porate Concentration and Power in Canada. Insti-tute for Research on Public Policy, Halifax,pp. 17–38.

Khemani, R. S. and D. M. Shapiro (1994). ‘The admin-istration of Canadian Merger Policy, 1986–1989’,The Antitrust Bulletin, XXXIX (3), pp. 771–795.

Li, J. (1994). ‘Ownership structure and board composi-tion: A multi-country test of agency theory predic-tions’, Managerial and Decision Economic, 15,pp. 359–368.

Markides, C. C. (1995).Diversification, Refocusing andEconomic Performance. MIT Press, Cambridge,MA.

Marris, R. (1964).The Economic Theory of ManagerialCapitalism. Macmillan, London.

Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1992).Economics, Organi-zation, and Management. Prentice-Hall, EnglewoodCliifs, NJ.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

Montgomery, C. A. and B. Wernerfelt (1988). ‘Diversi-fication, Ricardian rents, and Tobin’s q’,Rand Jour-nal of Economics, 19, pp. 623–632.

Montgomery, C. A. and V. A. Wilson (1986). ‘Mergersthat last: A Predictable Pattern’,Strategic Manage-ment Journal, 7(1), pp. 91–96.

Morck, R., A. Shleifer and R. W. Vishny (1988). ‘Man-agement ownership and market evaluation: Anempirical analysis’,Journal of Financial Economics,20, pp. 293–315.

Morck, R. and B. Yeung (1991). ‘Why investors valuemultinationality’, Journal of Business, 64, pp. 165–187.

Murphy, K. (1985). ‘Corporate performance and execu-tive remuneration’,Journal of Accounting and Eco-nomics, 7, pp. 11–42.

Nickell, S. (1995). The Performance of Companies.Blackwell, London.

Oviatt, B. (1988). ‘Agency theory and transaction costsperspectives on the manager–shareholder relation-ship’, Academy of Management Review, 13,pp. 214–225.

Palepu, K. (1985). ‘Diversification strategy, profit per-formance and the entropy measure’,Strategic Man-agement Journal, 6(3), pp. 239–255.

Pomfret, R. and D. Shapiro (1981). ‘Firm size, diversi-fication, and profitability of large corporations inCanada’, Journal of Economic Studies, 7(3),pp. 140–150.

Porter, M. E. (1987). ‘From competitive advantage tocorporate strategy’,Harvard Business Review, 65(3),pp. 43–59.

Porter, M. E. (1990).The Competitive Advantage ofNations. Free Press, New York.

Porter, M. E. (1992). ‘Capital disadvantage: America’sfailing capital investment system’,Harvard BusinessReview, 70(5), pp. 65–82.

Price Waterhouse (1988).Doing Business in Germany.Price Waterhouse, London.

Price Waterhouse (1989a).Doing Business in Canada.Price Waterhouse, London.

Price Waterhouse (1989b).Doing Business in France.Price Waterhouse, London.

Price Waterhouse (1990).Doing Business in the UnitedStates. Price Waterhouse, London.

Price Waterhouse (1991a).Doing Business in theUnited Kingdom. Price Waterhouse, London.

Price Waterhouse (1991b).The Price Waterhouse Euro-pean Companies Handbook. Analysis Corporation,London.

Rao, P. S. and C. R. Lee-Sing (1996). ‘Governancestructure, corporate decision-making and firm per-formance in North America’, Industry Canada Work-ing Paper Number 7.

Rediker, K. J. and A. Seth (1995). ‘Board of directorsand substitution effects of alternative governancemechanisms’,Strategic Management Journal, 16(2),pp. 85–99.

Roe, M. (1993). ‘Some differences in corporate struc-ture in Germany, Japan and the United States’,YaleLaw Journal, 102(8), pp. 1927–1947.

Roe, M. (1994). Strong Managers, Weak Owners.Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

Corporate Governance in Five Countries 553

Rumelt, R. P. (1974).Strategy, Structure and EconomicPerformance. Harvard University Press, Boston,MA.

Rumelt, R. P. (1991). ‘How much does industry mat-ter?’, Strategic Management Journal, 12(3),pp. 167–185.

Rybczynski, T. M. (1986).The Internationalization ofthe Financial System. World Bank, Washington, DC.

Salancik, G. R. and J. Pfeffer (1980). ‘Effects of owner-ship and performance on executive tenure in U.S.corporations’,Academy of Management Journal, 23,pp. 653–664.

Schmalensee, R. (1985). ‘Do markets differ much?’,American Economic Review, 75, pp. 341–351.

Schneider-Lenne, E. R. (1992). ‘Corporate control inGermany’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 8(Autumn), pp. 11–23.

Shapiro, D. M., W. A. Sims and G. Hughes (1984).‘The efficiency implications of earnings retentions:An extension’,Review of Economics and Statistics,66, pp. 327–331.

Shepherd, W. G. (1972). ‘The elements of market struc-ture’, Review of Economics and Statistics54(1),pp. 25–37.

Short, H. (1994). ‘Ownership, control, financial struc-ture and the performance of firms’,Journal of Eco-nomic Surveys, 8(3), pp. 203–250.

1998 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,Vol 19, 533–553 (1998)

The Economist(1 February 1992). ‘Bosses’ pay: Wor-thy of his hire?’, pp. 19–22.

The Economist (21 January 1995). ‘Those Germanbanks and their industrial treasures’, pp. 71–77.

The Economist(2 December 1995). ‘Investor types’,p. 107.

The Economist(10 February 1996). ‘Stakeholder capi-talism’, pp. 23–25.

Tosi, H. L. and L. R. Gomez-Mejia (1989). ‘Thedecoupling of C.E.O. pay and performance: Anagency theory perspective’,Administrative ScienceQuarterly, 39, pp. 169–189.

Vining, A. R. and A. E. Boardman (1992). ‘Ownershipversus competition: Efficiency in public enterprise’,Public Choice, 73, pp. 205–239.

Walsh, J. P. and J. K. Seward (1990). ‘On the efficiencyof internal and external corporate control mecha-nisms’, Academy of Management Review, 15(3),pp. 421–458.

Williamson, O. E. (1964). The Economics of Dis-cretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in aTheory of the Firm. Prentice-Hall, EnglewoodCliffs, NJ.

Williamson, O. E. (1985).The Economic Institutions ofCapitalism. Free Press, New York.

WorldScope-Disclosure (1991).Industrial CompanyProfiles. Disclosure Press, Bethesda, MD.