15
Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals.

Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

Lecture 6:

Achieving the efficient level of residuals.

Page 2: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

• [We have learned to value resources according to their shadow values. We can now construct MD and MAC curves. MAC costs are added horizontally, though administration, monitoring and enforcement costs should be added vertically to per emission abatement costs. I won’t ask you to do this.]

• Having MD and MAC, we can find the socially efficient level of emissions. But how to get society to this point?

• The reason society that is not at the socially efficient level of emissions must be market failures, or the absence of a market. Identify the market failures and correct them as best you can.

Page 3: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

• Information failures can be addressed by providing information.

• Market concentration failures can be addressed by breaking up monopolies or monopsonies.

• Open access resources can be managed by controlling access.

• Public goods can be provided by governments or social agencies.

• Externalities can be internalized by manipulating prices through taxes, subsidies or tradable permit systems. This is a market-based way of influencing social behaviour.

• Finally, command-and-control methods can simply mandate consumers’ and firms’ emission levels directly, or indirectly by mandating their choice of technology or production methods.

Page 4: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

Which method is best?

• A policy should get us as close to the socially efficient level of emissions as possible.

• A policy should also be cost-effective. Abatement and administration costs should be as low as possible. For abatement costs to be as low as possible, lower cost firms or households should abate more than higher cost ones.

• The policy should be politically attractive: easy to understand, and seeming fair. “Polluter pays” is one principle of fairness, but who exactly is the polluter?

• A good policy should provide an incentive to innovate. If emissions can be abated at lower cost than before because of a breakthrough in technology, money and resources are released to be used elsewhere in society.

Page 5: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

Correcting Information Failures

• The obvious way to correct for information failures is to research and publish information. Research activity generally has a large positive externality, and is undersupplied by the market.

• Patents restrict use of information and put a price on it. However, most information is not marketed at all.

• Marketed information will be sold where private marginal benefits = private marginal costs. However, social marginal benefits are usually higher than private benefits, so the government has an incentive to encourage research and spread the knowledge around.

• What is the best way to inform consumers about the environmental consequences of their actions? There are 2 main methods of increasing “eco-literacy”: Certification, and Labelling.

Page 6: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

• Certification tests a product against specific criteria. It is a pass/fail designation.

• If participation is voluntary, the low-cost abaters will participate, keeping abatement costs low.

• Since it is pass/fail, there are still some information gaps.

• Easy for consumers to understand.

• No incentive to innovate once you have been certified.

Page 7: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals
Page 8: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

• In July 2007, the Canadian Food Inspection Agency introduced a national certification process for organic food. CTV reports that to be certified organic:

-prepared food must contain at least 95% organic ingredients

-vegetables, fruits or grains must be grown using natural fertilizers

-animals must be raised in conditions that mimic nature as much as possible

• Organic foods appear to be produced with less residual impact on the environment, though the actual emissions used to produce, transport, and store the food is unknown. We need to study the complete life-cycle of the product.

• Generally, with certification, the information is limited.

• Certification makes things easier for the harried consumed and makes nonconformity more obvious.

Page 9: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

• Labelling provides more precise information as to the content or environmental footprint of a product, so that it can be compared to all other products that are labelled.

• Participation does not require abatement. Abatement costs will be low, and will stay low unless consumers rush to greener products.

• There is an ongoing incentive to innovate so as to be better than rivals.

• The information collection burden is higher than for certification.

• The information detail may be to complex for consumers. Care must be taken to present the information in a user-friendly way.

Page 10: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

• Example: Government

- Energy Star, run by the US EPA and Department of Energy, certifies appliances and buildings that are energy efficient

- Even better, in terms of information given, is Canada’s EnerGuide Program, which specifies the amount of electricity likely to be used by the appliance and compares it to other such appliances.

Page 11: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

Case Study: Food Miles

• The European Union is considering labeling grocery items with “food miles” to indicate how far the food has been transported. The average supermarket product travels 1500 miles before reaching the shelf.

• Eating locally, perhaps within a 100-mile radius around your home, is a growing trend, meant to reduce GHG emissions from transportation. Other reasons to eat locally include freshness, supporting local farmers, and food security.

• About 25% of North American’s ecological footprint comes from food…from planting to landfill. And there’s a lot more to it than transportation.

Page 12: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

• Life-cycle analysis might show that greenhouse gas (GHG) expenses are actually higher for the local food. GHG should be considered not just with regard to transportation but also with regard to lighting, heating, watering, fertilizing, cultivating, feeding, packaging, and storage etc.

• If GHG is what we are ultimately interested in, then GHG should be on the label, not miles.

• Obviously, if Canadians insisted on growing their own oranges, much electricity would be spent heating and lighting the crop. Even less exotic food may be more polluting when locally produced: researchers at Lincoln University in New Zealand argue that it would be better for the environment if Britons purchased New Zealand lamb rather than British lamb. This is largely because the New Zealand lamb is pasture-fed rather than grain fed.

• Local transportation costs may be substantial. It’s possible that all the driving by consumers to and fro local suppliers would exceed the driving used to pick up imported food from central shopping depots. E.g. Desert Lake Gardens.

Page 13: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

http://www.openthefuture.com

Page 14: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

Tips for greener eating

• Eat local food that does not require greenhouse production• Eat local food in season to avoid refrigeration • Eat low on the food chain• Buy food having less packaging• Own an efficient refrigeration, and keep it full.• Waste less food.• Compost. Food in the landfill decays anaerobically, producing

methane, a powerful greenhouse gases.

Page 15: Lecture 6: Achieving the efficient level of residuals

Moral Suasion

• Once information deficits have been corrected, externalities may yet exist so that agents do not behave optimally, even though they are fully informed as to the social consequences of their actions.

• Moral suasion is attempting to change society’s choices by means of exhortation as well as information.

• Moral suasion is very inexpensive and, since it is voluntary, requires no monitoring.

• Moral suasion has had quite a bit of success in changing attitudes about littering, smoking, recycling, and scooping doggy doo.

• Those who agree to comply have an incentive to innovate to lower their costs.

• Not all people will comply. There is no guarantee that the allocatively efficient solution will be achieved.

• Since the program is voluntary, the low-cost abaters are more likely to abate. High-cost abaters, if altruistic enough, will abate also.

• Danger: Both types of abaters may become bitter if they observe lower-cost abaters not complying.