Lec_May_19_2014

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    1/14

    Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/5 2014

    Henrik JensenDepartment of EconomicsUniversity of Copenhagen

    Monetary policymaking and the recent crisis

    1. The case for quantitative easing

    Literature: A. J. Auerbach and M. Obstfeld (2005): “The Case for Open-Market Purchases in a Liquidity

    Trap” American Economic Review  95, 110–137.

    Brief talk about exam: Hints and advice

    c   2014 Henrik Jensen. This document may be reproduced for educational and research purposes, as long as the copies contain this notice and are retained for personaluse or distributed free.

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    2/14

    Introductory remarks

     Recent monetary policy developments, since the start of the world-wide crises post-2008, have had

    two major consequences(A) Moved leading policy rates (US and in Euroland) close to zero:

    1

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    3/14

    (B) Made central banks expand their balance sheets; “quantitative easing” (“QE”):

    2

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    4/14

     In a deep recession with nominal policy rates at zero, the usual interest-rate channel is “dead” (A)

     Will quantitative easing then work instead, i.e., is (B) the answer?

     Isn’t the situation where the Zero Lower Bound on policy rates binds called a “Liquidity Trap”?

    Source: Blanchard et al. (2010): Macroeconomics. A European Perspective (Prentice Hall), Figure 5.11.

    3

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    5/14

     Why bother increasing the money supply?

     Some reasons pertain to …nancial market conditions per se:

    – After Lehman Brothers collapse, most markets “froze”; much of the quantitative easing was aimed

    at addressing con…dence crises in …nancial markets e.g., facilitating loans not happening in the

    market; helping out …rms with “toxic assets,” etc.

     From a macroeconomic stabilization point of view, however, quantitative easing may have an e¤ect

    also

     I.e., expansive monetary policy may be e¤ective in a “trap”

     The purpose of Auerbach and Obstfeld’s paper is to show under which circumstances, in a model

    that more or less uses all we have learned!

    4

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    6/14

    The AO model and the e¤ectiveness of QE

    The model in the simple version: ‡exible prices

     Model is representative agent, in…nite-horizon model of the cash-in-advance type

     Household utility

    U 0 =1X

    t=0

      tY

    s=0

     s

    !U  (C t; Lt)

    Model allows for “temporary patience”, i.e.,  s >  1  is possible, but limt!1Q

    ts=0  s = 0

     Speci…c utility function

    U  (C t; Lt) = log C t ktLt   (1)

     Households hold government debt,  Bt, and money,  M t. Total real wealth (beginning of period) is

    de…ned as

    V t = Bt + M t

    P t1

    5

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    7/14

     Households’ budget constraint is therefore

    V t+1 = Bt (1 + it)

    P t+

     M tP t

    + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t T t C t

     Nominal interest rate is   it 0. Real interest rate is de…ned as 1 + rt (1 + it) = (P t=P t1)

     Using the de…nition of real wealth and the real interest rate:

    V t+1   =  Bt (1 + it) P t1

    P tP t1+

     M tP t

    + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t T t C t

    =  Bt (1 + rt)

    P t1+

     M tP t

    + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t T t C t

    =   V t (1 + rt) (1 + rt)  M 

    tP t1 +

     M t

    P t + 

    tP t +

     wtL

    tP t

    T t C t

    =   V t (1 + rt) (1 + it) M tP t

    + M tP t

    + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t T t C t

    =   V t (1 + rt) itM tP t

    + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t T t C t

     CIA constraint:

    M t (1 +  t) P tC t   (2)

    A consumption tax,  t, is also paid by cash

    6

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    8/14

     We know that a CIA constraint is binding when  it >  0, and non binding when  it = 0 (cf. Chapter 3

    in Walsh)

     We therefore have the “complementary slackness” condition:

    itM t =  it (1 +  t) P tC t

     Inserted into budget constraint:

    V t+1   =   V t (1 + rt) itM tP t

    + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t T t C t

    =   V t (1 + rt) it (1 +  t) C t + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t T t C t

    =   V t (1 + rt) + t

    P t+ w

    tLtP t

    T t (1 + it +  tit) C t

     Total real tax payments are T t =   tC t  such that

    V t+1   =   V t (1 + rt) + tP t

    + wtLt

    P t  tC t (1 + it +  tit) C t

    =   V t (1 + rt) +

     t

    P t +

     wtLt

    P t (1 + it) (1 +  t) C t

    7

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    9/14

     Optimal behavior by households:

    U C  t (1 + it) (1 +  t) = 0;

    U L + twtP t

    = 0;

    t +  

    t+1

    t+1 (1 + r

    t+1) = 0;

    where t  is the Lagrange multiplier on the budget constraint

     With the speci…c utility function:

    1

    C t=   t (1 + it) (1 +  t) ;

    kt   =   twtP t

    ;

    t   =    t+1t+1 (1 + rt+1) ;

     This results in labor supply and Euler equations:

    C t =  wt

    kt (1 + it) (1 +  t) P t(3)

    1

    C t (1 + i

    t) (1 +  

    t)

      =    t+11

    C t+1 (1 + i

    t+1) (1 +  

    t+1)

     (1 + rt+1)

    C t+1C t

    =    t+1(1 + it) (1 +  t)

    (1 + it+1) (1 +  t+1) (1 + rt+1)

    C t+1C t

    =    t+1 (1 + it)  P t (1 +  t)

    P t+1 (1 +  t+1)  (4)

    8

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    10/14

    Monetary policy at the zero lower bound

     Assume that some shock(s) has made the CIA constraint non-binding (say   0   "), such that the

    economy starts in a “liquidity trap” with i0 = 0:

     Assume that at some  T > 0, iT  > 0, i.e., at some future date the zero lower bound will not bind (but

    the CIA constraint will)

    – E.g., if  it  is a short-term interest rate, then the observation of positive long-term rates, suggests

    that this may not be a bad assumption

     The question is whether a change in the money stock,  M 0, can have any e¤ects on the economy?

     Assume a constant consumption tax, and combine (3) and (4):

    C t+1C t

    =  t+1 (1 + it)  P tP t+1

    wt+1kt (1 + it) P twtkt+1 (1 + it+1) P t+1

    =  t+1 (1 + it)  P tP t+1

    wt+1ktwtkt+1 (1 + it+1)

     =  t+1

    An “inverse Euler equation”:wt+1kt+1

    = (1 + it+1)  t+1wtkt

    (5)

    9

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    11/14

     So, as long as the economy is at the zero lower bound, for  t < T   1

    wt+1kt+1

    =  t+1wtkt

    Nominal wage growth and price growth are determined (apparently) without reference to monetary

    policy

     When the economy is out of the zero lower bound, for  t > T   1

    C t+1C t

    =  t+1 (1 + it)  P tP t+1

    combined with the binding CIA constraint  M t = (1 +  t) P tC t   implies

    M t+1M t

    =  t+1 (1 + it)   (7)

    Inserted into the “inverse Euler equation”

    wtkt

    =   t t+1

    M t+1M t

    wt1kt1

     So, out of the zero lower bound, nominal wage growth (and price growth) is determined by nominal

    money growth.

    10

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    12/14

     For t  =  T   1 we haveC T 

    C T 1=  T 

    P T 1P T 

    ;

    and thus by the CIA constraint, which binds in T :

    M T 

    C T 1 (1 +  T ) =  T P T 1

    and thus by the labor supply equation at  T   1, where iT 1 = 0,

    M T kT 1wT 1

    =  T 

    or,

    wT 1=kT 1 = M T = T    (*)

     This “terminal condition” shows that wages (and prices) just prior to getting out of the zero lower

    bound is determined by money!

    11

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    13/14

     This “terminal condition” (*) “unravels” back to period–0  wages and prices:

    w0k0

    =QT 1

    s=0   1s

    M T  T 

    t T   1   (9a’)

     This shows that a temporary increase in the money supply at  t   = 0  will have no e¤ects unless it

    a¤ects the future money supply

    – Con…rms the nature of the liquidity trap; current money is neutral in every sense of the word: It

    does not a¤ect ANY variable

    – Shows that quantitative easing nevertheless can have e¤ects on prices, if   future  money supply is

    a¤ected; i.e., a permanent increase in the money supply will permanently increase all prices and

    wages in the same proportion

    12

  • 8/20/2019 Lec_May_19_2014

    14/14

     In a sticky-price version of the model (with two types of monopolistically produced goods and two-

    period price contracts), such an ability to a¤ect aggregate prices, will have bene…cial output e¤ects

     Crucial here is  expectations about future policy  (and thus the ability to commit)

    – If quantitative easing is expected to be reversed, it may have no e¤ects on prices and output

    – Echoes Paul Krugman’s now famous statements (1998,  Brookings Papers on Economic Activity )

    about the need for central banks to obtain credibility of being “irresponsible” when in a liquiditytrap

    - - -

    13