32
The duration of research joint ventures: theory and evidence from the Eureka program K. Miyagiwa (Emory and Kobe) and A. Sissoko (LCU)

K. Miyagiwa (Emory and Kobe) and A. Sissoko (LCU)

  • View
    219

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • Slide 1
  • K. Miyagiwa (Emory and Kobe) and A. Sissoko (LCU)
  • Slide 2
  • Introduction - 1 RJV = partners (A) coordinate research efforts and (B) share innovation Incentives for RJVs Avoid duplications (Katz 1986) Internalize technical spillovers (dAsprement and Jacquemin 1988, Kamien et al. 1992, Miyagiwa and Ohno 2002)
  • Slide 3
  • Introduction - 2 Instability of RJVs Lack of monitoring of R&D effort (free-rider problem) Solutions to monitoring problems 1. random termination 2. green-porter 3. deadlines (Miyagiwa 2011)
  • Slide 4
  • Introduction - 3 Theory: Pre-commitment to the dissolution of RJV at a pre-set date (duration) Optimal duration is positively related to innovation values
  • Slide 5
  • Introduction - 4 Time consistency problem Solution for RJVs Private research grants have time limits Help from government regulations RJVs are required to ask for permission from government to be exempted from antitrust laws U.S. DOC Advanced Technology Program (ATP) Europe EUREKA
  • Slide 6
  • Flow of the presentation Theory Model of optimal RJV durations Properties of optimal RJV durations Empirical Data from Eureka Main estimation results Robustness checks
  • Slide 7
  • Part 1: Theory Infinite horizon, discrete time t = 1, 2 m firms try to find a new product or technology Going it alone: v : expected value of R&D per firm (v 0).
  • Slide 8
  • RJV parameters RJV => share innovation, independent R&D effort = value of innovation per partner k = R&D cost (fixed) q = (conditional) probability of failure per partner per time q m = (conditional) joint probability of failure for RJV
  • Slide 9
  • RJV without monitoring RJV with an infinite duration No monitoring and no punishing shirking V = value of RJV per firm when everyone exerts effort V = - k + (1 q m ) + q m V V = [- k + (1 q m )]/(1 q m ) Assumption 1: V > v (RJV is worthwhile)
  • Slide 10
  • Unstable RJV Shirking saves k but lowers (joint) probability of innovation, yielding to a shirker the payoff W d = (1 q m-1 ) + q m-1 V Assumption 2: V W d < 0. V W d = - k + q m-1 (1 q)( V) < 0.
  • Slide 11
  • A one-period RJV Agree to dissolve RJV between t = 1 and t = 2 Equilibrium payoff R(1) = = - k + (1 q m ) + q m v Shirking yields R d (1)= (1 q m-1 ) + q m-1 v R(1) - R d (1)= - k + q m-1 (1 q)( v)
  • Slide 12
  • Prop 1: Given assumption 1 (V > v) and assumption 2 (V W d < 0), there are ranges of parameters in which R(1) - R d (1) 0. Compare: R(1) - R d (1)= - k + q m-1 (1 q)( v) 0 V W d = - k + q m-1 (1 q)( V) < 0
  • Slide 13
  • Extending duration If prop 1 holds, consider a two-period RJV R(2) = - k + (1 q m ) + q m R(1). An n-period RJV R(n) = - k + (1 q m ) + q m R(n-1) Properties of R(n) R(n) is increasing in n. As n goes to infinity, R(n) goes to V
  • Slide 14
  • Optimal duration Prop 2: If prop 1 holds, there is an optimal duration n* Shirking (at date 1) yields R d (n)= (1 q m-1 ) + q m-1 R(n-1) As n goes to infinity, R d (n) goes to W d R(1) - R d (1) > 0 As n goes to infinity, R(n) R d (n) goes to V - W d < 0,
  • Slide 15
  • Properties of optimal duration (n*) Prop 3: An increase in tends to raise n*. Proof: In R(n) appears with positive probability so an increase in raises R(n) R d (n)= - k + q m-1 (1 q)( R(n-1)).
  • Slide 16
  • Properties - 2 An increase in the number of partners (m) has two effects: reduces (value per member) raises probability of success The effect on R(n) and hence on n* are ambiguous. Let the data determine the effect.
  • Slide 17
  • Part 2: Empirical European Eureka program (1985 ) Promotes pan-European RJVs with subsidies and no- interest loans Partners are sought from separate countries Monitoring problem exists as R&D conducted in different countries RJVs required to pre-commit to durations Time inconsistency problem is resolved. Ideal for testing the theory
  • Slide 18
  • Data details www.eurekanetwork.org initiation year duration costs types of industries names, addresses, and nationalities of all partners. identities and nationalities of RJV initiators. 1,716 Eureka RJVs started and completed (1985-2004) 8,520 partners: 4,700 firms and 1,937 other partners (research centers or universities) from the EU-15
  • Slide 19
  • Data summary
  • Slide 20
  • Methodology Empirically examine the factors determining the durations of the Eureka projects Normality test fails Duration or survival models Proportional hazards models death as an event Hazard decomposes into a baseline hazard h 0 and idiosyncratic characteristics of RJVs h j (t)= h 0 (t) exp(x j x ).
  • Slide 21
  • Proportional hazard models Cox model no restriction on functional form Prior info specific functional form - Weibull h 0 (t) = pt p-1 exp( 0 ) p determines the shape of a baseline hazard Baseline hazard increasing if and only if p > 1 p = 1 : exponential hazard model Strategy here Use Weibull basic model (some ancillary evidence) Use other models for robustness
  • Slide 22
  • Hazard ratio Hazard ratio = effect of a unit change in the explanatory variable Hazard ratio explanatory variable has a negative impact on RJV death (increases duration) Hazard ratio = 0 => explanatory variable has no impact
  • Slide 23
  • Explanatory variables No data on innovation values RJV cost per partner per month (in million euros) = main proxy of innovation values expected hazard ratio < 1 Number of partners - ? Initiator dummy firm initiated shorter durations Multi-sector dummy multi-sector longer durations Initiation year dummies Main industry dummies
  • Slide 24
  • Table 2: Weibull
  • Slide 25
  • Robustness testing Weibull PH model assumes that all Eureka RJVs have a common baseline hazard, which is Weibull. Model 6: questions the Weibull distribution assumption Cox (non-parametric) model
  • Slide 26
  • Table 3
  • Slide 27
  • Robustness check Model 7: common hazard assumption stratified Weibull Stratum 1: small (2 4 partners), 64 % of the samples Stratum 2: medium sized (5 - 8 partners),27.3 % Stratum 3 large RJVs (9 - 196): 8.7 per cent Results: large RJV shape para. p significant at a 5% level No significant difference between the small and the med-size Close resemblance to V
  • Slide 28
  • Stratified Weibull h 0 (t)= exp(-13.030) (2.974)t j 1.974 (small) h 0 (t)= exp(-14.029) (2.974)t j 1.974 (medium-sized) h 0 (t)= exp(-13.030) (2.542) t j 1.544 (large)
  • Slide 29
  • Large versus small and med-sized
  • Slide 30
  • Robustness checks Model 8: Hidden heterogeneity between data-wise identical RJVs frailty Weibull test baseline hazard - Zh 0 (t); Z random Model 9: make sure that time is not affecting the rsults exponential prop. Hazard model
  • Slide 31
  • Conclusions Theory RJV partners can overcome monitoring problems by committing to dissolve the RJVs at a fixed date Government oversight of RJVs help the renegotiation problem Optimal duration depends positively on innovation values Ambiguous effect from the number of partners
  • Slide 32
  • Conclusions - 2 Empirical evidence Eureka program ideal for testing Proportional hazards models RJVs cost per partner has a positive effect on duration Number of partners has a positive effect on duration Firm-initiated RJVs have shorter durations Multi-sector RJVs have longer durations