Industrial Strategy of India China

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    1/26

    Term paper part 1: Analysis of Indian Manufacturing Sector

    Anurag Rawat (061/46)

    Amit Ambre (030/46)

    ContentsIntroduction:......................................................................................2

    Comparison of Reforms and growth trajectories of India and China:......2

    Development of manufacturing capability in India................................8

    India's relative underperformance in Manufacturing............................9

    I. Role of Investment: Comparison of India and China.........................10

    II. Foreign Direct Investment: Comparison of India and China............11

    III. Structural and Policy Factors............................................................16

    Potential for growth in Investment rate in India:................................17

    Special Economic Zones: Comparison of India and China.....................18

    Focus on R&D...................................................................................19

    Recommendations:...........................................................................21

    References:......................................................................................23

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    2/26

    Introduction:India and China are two major economies in South Asia that are both large with

    huge population and growing fast. In this paper, we present a critical analysis of

    growth of the Indian industry, specially concentrating on high tech industry in

    general and medical devices in particular. The analysis primarily builds on Indias

    comparison with China, which has succeeded in developing a strong industrial

    base and manufacturing capability in high-tech sector in quick time. India and

    China are similar in many respects which makes a case for comparison of the

    growth of the two economies. Historically, though different in their extents, both

    India and China had established central planning systems where the role of

    government has been dominant in the production mechanisms and economic

    decisions. Both the countries have vast territorial extension and large population

    (together the two account for nearly a third of the world population). Both the

    countries started the economic reforms process from late 1970s/ early 1980s

    onwards.

    This paper is structured as follows:

    A brief about the economic reforms and their impact on the development

    of different sectors in the two countries.

    Detailed analysis on where India has lacked in developing its

    manufacturing capability

    Present a case for why India needs to develop manufacturing capability in

    high- tech sector

    Study of medical devices market and industry in India and the world. We

    will present an economic and social case for development of medical

    device and equipment industry in India

    Finally, we will give policy recommendations for development of

    manufacturing capability in India

    Comparison of Reforms and growth trajectories of India and

    China:

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    3/26

    Both India and China have witnessed rapid economic growth since the last

    decade of the 20th century. While China's growth has been powered by a strong

    manufacturing sector, Services has been the major source of India's GDP. After

    three decades of Soviet- style planned development strategy, economic reforms

    were introduced in China starting in 1978. The first part of Chinese economic

    reform involved implementing the Household Responsibility System (HRS) in

    agriculture, by which farmers were able to retain surplus over individual plots of

    land rather than farming for the collective. By the end of 1984, approximately

    98 percent of all farm households were under the HRS and the agriculture

    output and the household income started to increase. This policy was followed by

    incentives to rural industrialization through the establishment of the

    Township and Village Enterprises (TVE's), which were industries owned by

    townships and villages. The TVE's resulted in a boom in investment and

    entrepreneurship and were considered to be the growth engines of the country

    till the 1990s.

    The second stage of reforms, started in early 1980s, aimed at creating a price

    driven market system, creating market institutions and opening to foreign trade.

    This stage of the reforms in the 1980s can be termed as pro-market reforms.

    From an administered pricing regime in the early 1980s, most of the goods wereshifted to market prices by the early 1990s. Foreign trade was regarded as an

    important source of investment funds and modern technology and restrictions on

    commercial flows were relaxed and foreign investment was legalized allowing

    and encouraging joint ventures with foreign firms. Special Economic Zones

    (SEZs) were established that stimulated productive exchanges between foreign

    firms with advanced technology and major Chinese economic networks.

    Still till the 1990s, China could be called a socialist market economy. The main

    sources of production were owned by the government. From 1994, another set of

    reforms that can be termed broadly as "pro-business reforms", started taking

    shape. In 1994, private ownership was considered for the first time a

    "supplementary component of the economy which in 1997 was elevated to an

    "important component of the economy". Privatization of State Owned

    Enterprises (SOEs) and layoffs of state workers began to emerge on a

    large scale. By early 2000s, nearly two thirds of China's GDP was in the private

    sector.

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    4/26

    While China adopted a "pro-market" policy followed by "pro-business", India first

    implemented "pro-business" followed by "pro-market" policy. Starting the early

    1980s, the restriction on industrial production due to the licensing system was

    reduced considerably. This was accompanied with increase in trade barriers to

    protect the domestic industries from foreign competition. India was one the

    closest economies during this period.

    The Indian reform process switched towards the pro-market orientation

    after the financial and political crisis in 1991. While, the previous initiatives

    towards privatization and the removal of the system of licences were intensified,

    a high priority was put to the lowering of foreign trade barriers and to the

    enhancement of international integration. Tariff and non-tariff barriers were

    reduced over time for most intermediate and capital goods and numerous

    initiatives were also put in place to attract foreign capital, especially in

    services.

    Political events and main economic reforms, China [8]

    YEAR POLITICAL EVENTS MAIN ECONOMIC REFORMS

    1976 1966-1976 Cultural Revolution

    1978

    Election of Deng

    Xiaoping

    1979

    Creation of HRS (Household Responsibility System),

    peasants allowed to retain over-quota output

    1980 Creation of Special Economic Zones

    1981

    Beginning of 1980s: creation of TVEs (Township and

    Village Enterprises)

    1983

    The People's Bank of China was nominally

    designated a central bank

    1984

    1982-1983 elimination of price controls on more 500

    small consumer items 1980-1983 fiscal contracting

    system, local governments allowed to retain over-

    quota revenues Dual-track system, enterprises were

    allowed to sell over-quota product at market prices

    1989

    Tiananmen Square

    Event

    1990 Two stock exchanges were set up

    1992 Socialist MarketEconomy declaration

    Commercialization" of SOEs (State OwnedEnterprises) Regulations on Transforming the

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    5/26

    Management Mechanism of State-Run Industrial

    Enterprises "

    Full price marketizationAbolishment of the iron rice bowl (the permanent

    employment system)

    1993 New accounting system

    Tax reform

    1994

    Abolishment of dual-track exchange rate Separating

    tax reform, a brand new unified tax system including

    VAT, and recentralization of tax collection to central

    governmentAdoption of four major state banks of the

    international accounting standard1995 Privatization of small SOEs

    Budget Law Central Bank Law, central bank has the

    mandate for monetary policy independent from the

    central government

    1999

    Private ownership and the rule of law incorporated

    into the Constitution

    2001 Ascension to WTO

    2004

    Constitution amended to guarantee private property

    rights

    Political events and main economic reforms, India [8]

    YEAR

    POLITICAL

    EVENTS MAIN ECONOMIC REFORMS

    1975 During the '70s the Green Revolution was implented

    1976

    Re-introduction of OGL (Open General Licensing, list of

    goods with no license for import) list with 79 capital

    items

    1978

    By the end of '70s, increasing pressures for

    liberalization policy from industrial lobbies

    1980

    Re-election of

    I. Gandhi

    1981Removal of licensing requirements in 20 industries andsome relaxation of import controls

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    6/26

    1984

    Murder of I.

    GandhiElection of R.

    Gandhi

    1985Introduction of replenishment licenses to exporters asincentives

    1985

    Introduction of replenishment licenses to exporters as

    incentives50% of business profits from exports made income tax

    deductibleThe interest rate on export credit was reduced from

    12% to 9%47 product groups free from the industrial licensing

    systemPrice and distribution controls on cement and aluminium

    abolished

    1986

    Canalization declined from 67% in 1980 to 27% of total

    importsDuty-free imports of capital goods allowed in selected

    thrust" export industries "

    28 industry groups broad banded, no license for product

    differentiationCapacity utilization allowed to expand in firms reaching

    80% capacity utilizationBetween 1985/1986 relaxation of MRTP (Monopolies and

    Restrictive Trade Policies)

    1987

    OGL reaches 1007 capital goods and 620 intermediate

    goods

    1988

    100% of business profits from exports made income tax

    deductibleOGL reaches 1170 capital goods and 949 intermediate

    goods

    1990

    Between 1985/1990 the real exchange rate was

    depreciated by 30% (nominally 45%)OGL reaches 1329 capital goods Introduction of

    MODVAT (Modified Value Added Tax) covering all

    manufacturing sub sectors (excl. Petroleum, textiles and

    tobacco)

    1991

    Murder of R.

    Gandhi Statement of Industrial Policy

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    7/26

    Election of N.

    Rao

    Public monopoly limited to 8 sectors, all the others

    opened to private investmentsFinance

    Minister M.

    Singh Relaxation of controls on FDICreation of Special Economic Zones where 100% of FDI

    allowed in manufacturing sectors

    1992

    Devaluation of the rupee by 22% against dollar

    Introduction of a dual exchange rate: exporters allowed

    to sell 60% of their exchange in the free market, and

    40% to the government at a lower official price

    1993

    Foreign companies own up to 51% equity in 34 high

    priority industries

    1994

    The highest tariff rate on import fell to 85% (it was

    355% in 1990)

    1996

    Win of BJP,

    first no-left

    party

    National Telecommunications Policy for private and FDI

    in cellular and telephone services The highest tariff rate

    on import fell to 50%

    1997

    Instability

    BJP/Congress

    1998

    Election of

    A.B.Vajpayee

    (BJP)

    1999

    The Insurance Regulatory and Development Authority

    permits private and FDI to operate in the insurance

    market

    Liberalization of banking

    NTP defined FDI in internet servicesInfrastructure sectors opened to private and FDI (excl.

    Railways)

    2003

    Electricity Bill privatized generation, transmission and

    distribution of electricity

    2004

    Election of

    M.Singh

    (Congress) The highest tariff rate on import fell to 25%

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    8/26

    Development of manufacturing capability in IndiaAfter the economic reforms introduced in 1991, India has witnessed rapid

    economic growth. A major feature of this development is the role of services

    sector in driving growth. While the share of agriculture has reduced, almost the

    entire share of agriculture has moved to services sector, which have come to

    acquire nearly 55% of the GDP, and the share of manufacturing has remained

    constant at 15-17%.

    Statistics: i. GDP growth rates over last 20 years; manufacturing and services

    growth ii. sector share in GDP. Iii. Per capita figures

    Sourced from:Annual Report 2009-10, DIPP [1]

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    9/26

    Source: World Development Indicators 2006

    While the emphasis on services rather than manufacturing has been widely

    noted, within manufacturing India has emphasized skill-intensive rather than

    labour-intensive manufacturing, and industries with typically higher average

    scale. Indias relative under-performance in manufacturing is matter of concern

    especially with regard to the high technology manufacturing. Indias CurrentAccount Deficit has been inflating with imports of electronic and other high tech

    goods forming an increasing part of it.

    What is required is a restructuring of the economy such that industry acquires a

    much higher share. Why does it matter? As Panagariya (2005, pp. 193195)

    quoted: Because typically, under liberal trade policies, developing countries are

    much more likely to be able to expand exports and imports if a large portion of

    their output originates in industry.

    India's relative underperformance in Manufacturing

    While India has experienced high rates of growth since the early 1990s onwards,

    the share of manufacturing in the GDP has remained stagnant at around 15-17%.

    A major portion of the growth is driven by services sector which now has more

    than 55% share in the GDP. Almost the entire reduction the agriculture share of

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    10/26

    GDP has gone to the Services sector. In it trajectory of economic development,

    India is said to have missed the manufacturing growth phase. Industry in China,

    on the other hand, has nearly 55% share in the GDP. So why has manufacturing

    sector in India lagged behind compared to China?

    A lot of research has been done in this area and we will directly state the reasons

    asserted for the same. In a general sense, it can be said that the investment

    climate in India is not good compared to China.

    I. Role of Investment: Comparison of India and China

    The main difference between China and India lies in the relative importance

    of investment. [5] Investment has played a much more important role inpropelling economic growth in China. Gross fixed capital formation in China as

    a share of GDP stood at a staggering 42.5% in 2003, while the comparable

    figure for India was substantially lower at 27.7%. During 19802003,

    investment grew at an annual average rate of 11.7% in China, compared to

    6.8% in India. Due to the higher growth rate, as well as to the higher

    proportion of investment in total output, the contribution of investment to

    overall growth in China far exceeds that in India (this is calculated as the

    product of the share of investment in GDP times the growth rate of

    investment, divided by the growth rate of GDP). During 19802003,

    investment contributed on average about 40% of total growth in China, while

    its contribution in India was 25.5%. [6] Figure below shows the investment

    shares of the two economies.

    The importance of investment in China seems to mirror the experience of

    some of the East Asian newly industrialized economies. Young (1995, pp.

    644645), for example, noted that investment shares in these economies rose

    substantially during the years of rapid growth. Singapores investment to GDP

    ratio (measured at constant local currency prices), stood at 10% in

    1960, before going on to reach 39% in 1980 and 47% in 1984, after which it

    declined to below

    30% by 1988, only to begin another rise in the late 1980s and reached almost

    40% in 1997. In Korea, investment shares were around 5% in the early 1950s,

    but climbed to 20% in the late 1960s and to 30% by the late 1970s. They

    were approaching 40% by 1991. In Taiwan, the share was around 10% in the

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    11/26

    early 1950s, from which it grew steadily to 27% in 1975, after which it has

    fluctuated at around 22%. [7] We conclude that the major factor explaining

    the difference in growth rates between the two economies lies in the

    differentials in the share of investment and in the rate of capital

    accumulation.

    Gross fixed capital formation as a share of GDP (%)

    Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators

    II. Foreign Direct Investment: Comparison of India and China

    In this section, we will outline the reasons why India has not been able to

    attract FDI flows as China has. Besides that, the issue of quality of FDI is will

    be discussed. Finally, suggestions to attract greater more and better quality

    FDI will be presented.

    FDI is defined as: An investor based in one country acquires an asset in

    another country with the intent to manage that asset (OECD, 2000). FDI has

    become very important in global trade and economic development. The

    global stock of FDI at the end of 2006 stood at $10 trillion. A large part of this

    FDI stock (more than two-thirds) is between the TNCs (Trans National

    Corporations). FDI in developing countries increased by 40% in 2004. This

    was mainly due to M&A activity and Greenfield FDI rising. The success of

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    12/26

    Asian Tigers- South Korea, Hong Kong, Taiwan, and Singapore in last two

    decades has been largely attributed to FDI (Zhang, 2001 [10]; Lall, 1993

    [11]). Trying to mimic this success story many countries are trying to attract

    FDI in a variety of ways. China has seen the largest volume of net FDI inflows

    than any other country in the past few years.

    FDI Statistics: The stock of foreign direct investment (FDI) in India soared

    from less than US$2 billion in 1991, when India undertook major reforms to

    open up the economy, to almost US$ 39 billion in 2004 [12].Annual Report

    2009-10, Department of Industrial Policy and Promotion For the period

    April, 09 to December, 09 of Financial year 2009-10, the FDI equity inflow was

    Rs. 100,539 crore (US$ 20.9 billion). The cumulative FDI inflow from August

    1991 to December, 2009 is Rs. 5,54,270 crore (US$ 127.5 billion). . Mauritius

    is the main source, followed by Singapore, the US, the UK, the Netherlands

    and Japan.

    FDI overview, selected years

    (Millions of Dollars)

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    13/26

    Sector-wise Distribution of FDI: Total FDI inflows are estimated at US$90

    billion during April 2000 to March 2009. Services sector; computer hardware

    & software; telecommunications; real estate; construction; automobiles;

    power; metallurgical industries; petroleum and natural gas; and chemicals

    received the highest FDI. The sector-wise distribution of FDI in India hasundergone a significant change over the past recent past. We have divided

    the period after 1991 into 2 parts for comparison. Emergence of service

    sector is clear from the figures below.

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    14/26

    How does FDI help? Emerging markets do not have sufficient internal capital.

    The government is devoid of resources and the private sector lacks

    resources. Internal savings are insufficient to support rapid growth that the

    economies need. Besides, they lack the technological expertise and know-

    how to invest in large projects.

    Basic factors affecting FDI:Market growth rates, political stability,

    corruption, exchange rate, labor productivity, economic freedom,

    infrastructure, openness, human capital, and taxes affect FDI flows to global

    markets (Sinha, Kent and Shomali, 2007 [12]). Overall, this means creating a

    better investment climate and ease of doing business increases FDI flow.

    Factors restricting FDI flows in India: Lack of Infrastructure is a major issue

    restricting foreign capital investment. The power supply is in-sufficient and

    unreliable. Industries have to employ their own generators that add cost to

    manufacturing. The ports and internal transportation networks are under-

    developed. The growth has been restricted to certain areas and sectors with

    few major states (Maharashtra, Gujarat, Hyderabad, Andhra Pradesh, Tamil

    Nadu, and Delhi) taking a disproportionate share of FDI and services sector

    contributing to more than 50% of GDP. Several political parties have stood

    against entry of foreign competition resulting in policies that restricted FDI.

    Tariffs and taxes on the TNCs have been high. Many sectors have not been

    opened up for foreign investment and there have been caps on most others.

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    15/26

    Fiscal deficits and corruption, combined with lack of privatization have

    affected capital formulation. Archaic labour laws and missing diaspora

    involvement have prevented creation of a conducive business climate (Sinha,

    Kent and Shomali, 2007 [12]).

    FDI Quality: There is skepticism about the growth effects of FDI in India. This

    skepticism is justified for several reasons. Setting aside the recent boom, FDI

    inflows may still be too low to make a big difference. It forms too small a

    portion of the gross fixed capital formation to be considered an important

    driver of economic growth. Secondly, there is skepticism about the change in

    the quality of FDI from the economic reforms. It is widely believed that the

    quality of FDI and its structural combination matter at least as much as the

    volume of the inward flows. FDI that promotes exports, transfers technologies

    to host country, and/or has economic spillover effects promoting local

    enterprises and benefitting local workers is considered to be of higher quality.

    While this skepticism prevailed in early years of the decade, there have been

    indications that FDI in manufacturing sector falls somewhat in line with the

    definition of quality FDI.

    FDI in Manufacturing: Analysis by Chakraborty and Nunnenkamp [13] and

    many others, finds that favourable growth effects of FDI are largely restrictedto the manufacturing sector. There is no evidence of any causal relationship

    of FDI in the primary sector. The causality in services sector is the reverse,

    greater output leads to greater FDI. However, there is an indication of

    spillover effect of FDI from the services to manufacturing sector.

    Quoting the results from a study by NCAER [2] gives the following striking

    features of FDI in manufacturing sector:

    A significant proportion (54 %) of manufacturing plants is located in

    Class-3 cities compared to the 35% services facilities.

    44% of FDI received in manufacturing sector has moved to tier-3 cities

    compared to only 8% in services

    About half the total output of FDI-enabled manufacturing firms

    originates in Class-3 cities; 48% of value-added originates in Class-3

    cities; 45% of the payments to employees originates in small cities

    FDI-enabled firms in manufacturing sectors provide employment to

    about 15.6 lakh persons, accounting for about 4 to 5% of the total

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    16/26

    employment in the organised sector. Sectors providing a relatively high

    share of employment in Class-3 cities include transport equipment;

    growing and processing of crops; construction parts; textiles; and non-

    metallic mineral products.

    FDI-enabled manufacturing firms pay higher wage per rupee of net

    fixed capital than domestically invested manufacturing firms. Output-

    capital ratio is also higher in FDI firms than in similar domestic firms.

    FDI Promotion: The current euphoria about FDI may be over-optimism on

    about its merits. Nonetheless, FDI needs to be promoted in a strategic way

    that promotes growth and technological advancement. Only opening FDI to

    new industries is not sufficient. The policy challenge is to improve local

    conditions to make FDI more effective.

    Development of strategic infrastructure: Availability of road transport,

    electricity, water, telecommunications and other resources promotes

    efficiency and ease in doing business. The infrastructure should be

    strategic in the sense of location, reflecting the demographic realities

    and supporting the strategic intent of promoting a specific economic

    activity. Economic clusters should be developed that are self

    contained, with connectivity and proximity with the markets or ports,

    and equipped with the necessary infrastructure and talent generation

    facilities.

    Openness to trade is important for strengthening linkages between

    foreign and local companies, especially in the manufacturing sector.

    Development of financial sector, promotion of entrepreneurship and

    human capital development will both attract FDI and create linkages

    across sectors.

    Spreading the growth geographically areas with relatively low

    economic development will create spillover effects that will be more

    favourable.

    The availability of sufficiently skilled labour as well as adequate

    infrastructure, particularly telecommunications, would support the

    process of off-shoring higher value-added services to India and the

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    17/26

    dissemination of the benefits of IT-related services throughout the

    Indian economy (UNCTAD, 2004, pp. 207208; World Bank, 2005, p.

    76).

    I. Structural and Policy Factors

    1) Long time to start up and exit a business: The World Bank's

    "Doing Business" database shows that In China the average time taken

    to secure necessary clearances to start up, or to complete a

    bankruptcy procedure is much shorter than India.

    2) Rigid labour laws: Indian labour laws give firms far less flexibility with

    their employees than in China, Brazil, Mexico or Russia. Retrenchment,

    closure and layoffs are governed by the Industrial Disputes Act, which

    requires prior government permission to lay-off workers or close

    businesses employing 100 or more workers. Permission is not easily

    obtained. Private firms have successfully downsized using voluntary

    retirement schemes. Foreign banks are also required to get the RBI's

    approval for closing branches.

    Lack of Infrastructure: The situation of power supply is alarming in

    India, with frequent power outages and high costs. Because of this,

    power generators have become standard industrial equipments in

    India. Almost 61% of Indian manufacturing firms own generators, the

    figure is 27% for China and 17 % for Brazil. The combined real cost of

    power in India is 74% higher than Malaysia's and 39% higher than

    China's. The situation of transport also needs to be improvedsignificantly.

    Capital Constraints and inefficient land markets: Evidence from

    the World Bank report suggests that India might be losing productivity

    because of capital constraints and inefficient urban land markets.

    Inefficient land markets have driven cost of doing business in India

    more than anywhere in East Asia.

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    18/26

    Corruption: U.S. firms have identified corruption as one obstacle to

    foreign direct investment. Indian businessmen agree that red tape and

    wide-ranging administrative discretion serve as a pretext to extort

    money. According to some foreign business representatives in India,

    corruption lies in the lack of transparency in the rules of governance,

    extremely cumbersome official procedures, and excessive and

    unregulated discretionary power in the hands of politicians and

    bureaucrats.

    Potential for growth in Investment rate in India:

    As noted above, the most important factor underlying differences in growthbetween China and India is capital accumulation. This is mostly the result of a

    much higher investment-to-output ratio in China.Indias investmentoutput ratio

    is only about 55% that of China, and grows much more slowly. With the slow

    growth, gap between the investmentoutput ratios of the two countries has

    widened more. Between 1981 and 1999, Chinas investment share was above

    Indias by 12.9 percentage points on average. In 1999, the gap was 17.9

    percentage points. Thus, the rising investment share has played a major role in

    explaining Chinas rapid capital accumulation and, therefore, the difference in

    capital accumulation between the two economies. Although the capital

    productivity is higher in India compared to China, the differential in the

    investment share between the two countries is so large that Indias increasing

    capital productivity cannot compensate its much lower investment share,

    resulting in a much smaller growth rate of the capital stock. A high investment

    share has an effect of increasing the speed of capital accumulation in China.

    Investment rate v/s profit rate: The ratio of the actual growth rate of capital

    accumulation to the profit rate can be interpreted as an indicator of the degree

    to which the growth potential of the economy is being utilized (Shaikh, 1999).

    [15] A ratio below 1 indicates that the countrys capacity for investment is not

    fully utilized. The more this ratio approaches 1, the higher the probability that

    excess demand will end up accelerating inflation rather than boosting growth. In

    some sense it is an indicator of the tightness of the economy.

    Ratio growth rate of the actual capital stock to the profit rate

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    19/26

    In China, the rate of capital accumulation has been close to, or exceeded, the

    profit rate. The average ratio from 1979 to 2003 was 1.1. The rate has been

    especially high since 1995 with the ratio averaging 1.4 during 19952003. In

    China virtually all profits are reinvested. [16] India exhibits a very different

    picture. The ratio between the growth rate of capital stock and profit rate

    averaged 0.3 from 1980 to 1999, with very small fluctuations.

    The low ratio of the rate of capital accumulation and the profit rate in India

    suggests that India possesses a large untapped investment potential that can lift

    growth to the rates that China has achieved. As such, it is imperative to

    understand and address the impediments to its full utilization. Existing studies

    suggest that, despite economic reforms, hurdles to investment are still high as

    the investment climate is far less favourable than that of China. Moreover, much

    of this new investment needs to be directed into infrastructure. However, withthe high level of fiscal deficit, the government is in no position to pursue an

    expansionary fiscal policy to stimulate public investment. The conclusion is that

    it appears that India will not be able to emulate China and achieve (and in

    particular sustain) growth rates in excess of 10% within the next few years

    without addressing the need for fiscal consolidation.

    Special Economic Zones: Comparison of India and China

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    20/26

    Like China, India is offering many benefits like tax breaks, duty-free imports,

    freedom from customs procedures, flexible labour laws, etc. One of the major

    comparisons between SEZs in China and India is the size. Each SEZ in China is

    well over 1000 hectares. In India, while the SEZs are smaller, the minimum size

    of SEZs has been increased after the implementation of SEZ Act, 2005.

    Another differentiating aspect is the availability of power. In China, the power

    supply in SEZs is at cheaper rates and there are no power cuts.

    In China, the decision-making for SEZs has been decentralized. This is considered

    as one of the major reasons for success of SEZs in China. Local authorities have

    been made partners and given authority to approve foreign investment. In India,

    the powers for foreign investment approval are vested with Development

    Commissioners, who are the representatives of the central government.

    The flexible labour laws with the hire-and-fire policy in SEZs have been one of

    the biggest attractions for foreign investors in China. All jobs are on a contract

    basis which stands terminated on the expiry of the term; the terms are flexible

    for a specific job. In contrast, in India, labour laws are very problematic for

    employers, with the Industrial Dispute act of 1947 not allowing companies that

    have 100 or more employees to retrench labour without prior permission from

    the concerned state government.

    Study by NCAER [2] - A few policy measures to enhance the performance of the

    SEZs include a vision in the design, establishment and operations of the SEZ; it is

    necessary to develop zones as industrial clusters of specific products. The

    backward linkages would also benefit the growth of accessories units. They,

    perhaps, could also encourage downstream industries; zones in the long run

    need to give way to industrial clusters of horizontally and vertically integrated

    industries, in general, and high-tech industries, in particular. This would not only

    help jump-start manufacturing processes, but would also improve exportcompetitiveness with greater returns. At present, there is no autonomous

    authority responsible for the development of zones and for providing single-

    window clearances in India; the zone administration functions as a government

    department office. It is recommended that the SEZs should be managed by

    autonomous authorities, which should be constituted under specific Acts and

    should be assigned the responsibility of promoting the zones.

    Focus on R&D

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    21/26

    Successful manufacturing locations around the world tend to invest heavily

    in R&D. The US spending on R&D was around USD 340 billion[6] in 2007

    with around 80 percent of this being spent by business. In contrast,

    Indias R&D expenditure was estimated at around USD 6 billion in 2006[7],

    with around 20 percent being business related R&D.

    [6] Science and Engineering Indicators 2008, National Science Foundation

    [7] KPMG Analysis. UNESCO ISE, UN Statistics, Policy Brief (Jul2008) OECD

    India has the essential ingredients to transform itself as the research and design

    hub for manufacturing. Firstly, going by the population growth rate projections of

    the World Health Organization, India will have the largest pool of working agepopulation in the world with a large number of technically qualified people

    proficient in English. Secondly, Indian businesses have shown skills at managing

    to the world through the outsourcing business. Thirdly, India has well established

    and fast growing manufacturing sector which needs to innovate and invest to

    sustain and increase the growth. For this, India needs to position itself

    proactively attract a greater share of global R&D spending. Besides investment

    in technical education and increasing expenditure on R&D activities, importing

    technology and marketing are two key ways in which the country can attain

    greater technological sophistication and create an environment that fosters

    innovation.

    Technology Import:The importance of FDI and technology transfer has never

    been under-estimated but has been under-utilized by Indian manufacturing

    sector. FDI and acquisitions are the routes that should be actively pursued to

    acquire technological expertise and intellectual property, that can create a

    culture of innovation and generation of new knowledge and business practices.

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    22/26

    Regulations governing overseas acquisitions need to be eased and promoted by

    the government [study the global acquisitions regulations by GOI].

    Marketing: We should be able to market our capabilities as a good destination

    for R&D and engineering services. Human capital development and manpower

    marketing are critical tools for this. Broadening the skill base is a critical

    requirement. Prof. C.K. Prahalad suggests that we aim to have 200 million

    college graduates and 500 million certified and skilled technicians by 2022. [17]

    Recommendations:

    1) Infrastructure Development:

    According to a world bank analysis [4], most important and robust determinant

    of productivity and factor accumulation in the last two decades has been state

    development spending (spending on infrastructure, health, education etc). Public

    sector has an important role to play here. This is so since in this area, especially

    in infrastructure provision, private returns are much below social returns. This

    role gets more enhanced as India is a developing country where private capital is

    limited in supply.

    Development of Inland transport : The inland transport network needs to

    be expanded. Indian Railways is highly in-efficient and needs to be

    expanded. The Chinese experience in railways can come in handy with the

    success they achieved by privatization and India can follow the same

    course. Statistics on road and rail connectivity in India

    Rapid Expansion of power generation capability and reforms in

    distribution: Reform in power and electricity sector is necessary. The

    power distribution companies and State Electricity Boards should be

    privatized and the subsidy on power removed. Rather than free rural

    power, cheap power should be provided to reduce wastage. The

    government can generate funds from disinvestment of public sector

    enterprises. This will create dual benefits it will provide funds to the

    government and promote efficiency in those industries as the private

    sector has shown to be more efficient and greater management expertise.

    The government should then focus on promoting health care and

    education.

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    23/26

    Development of large new ports : The existing Indian ports are congested

    with poor management. Large new ports should be built in states like

    Bihar and Orissa from scratch with world class facilities that can handle

    large ships. Public private partnership with build-operate-transfer should

    be welcomed. The existing ports should be privatized and made more

    efficient using the modern operations management methods including

    just-in-time and supply chain management concepts.

    1) Focus on skill neutral manufacturing: The manufacturing sector in the

    GDP needs to be given more focus. The services sector cannot provide jobs to

    the burgeoning Indian population. Sam Pitroda commented that IT and BPO

    create only 3, 00,000 jobs against 10 million required Statistics on the

    number of jobs in Services sector. A boom in manufacturing is required to

    employ the idling population from agriculture. In last 2 decades, Indian

    manufacturing growth has seen a jobless growth. There is a large uneducated

    population in India that needs to be employed. Skill neutral mass

    manufacturing focus is required to generate employment. Large scale export

    oriented manufacturing industries should be promoted. Coastal areas in

    Bihar such as Gopalpur might be an ideal place for setting up large

    manufacturing units that can be export-oriented to feed large US west coast

    market (Sinha, Kent and Shomali [12]).

    2) Relaxation of company laws:The labour laws need to be relaxed providing

    the companies flexibility in their operations. The limit of the number of

    employees above which the companies come under the purview of labour

    laws is 100. Changes are under consideration that will make the figure to 300.

    Sinha, Kent and Shomali [12] recommend the size to be 1000 employees to

    provide the smaller size companies greater flexibility in changing their

    operations. According to a World Bank study [4], labour market flexibility, by

    itself, can improve productivity to a large extent and has a positive effect on

    employment and investment as well. Deregulation can only be useful in the

    presence of better labour laws.

    The bankruptcy laws have to be simplified to make it easy of the companies

    especially TNCs to enter and exit the market. Employee lay-off needs to be

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    24/26

    allowed in the public sector to make them lean and more efficient. Overall,

    the legislation has to be made more congenial for business activity.

    3) SEZ development: Already discussed in the Section on SEZs

    4) Encouraging investment from NRIs:

    5) Human Capital Development:

  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    25/26

    References:

    [1] Annual Report 2009-10, Department of Industrial Policy and Promotion,

    Ministry of Commerce & Industry, Government of India

    [2] FDI in India and its Growth Linkages, August 2009, Study by National

    Council of Applied Economic Research; sponsored Department of Industrial Policy

    and Promotion, Ministry of Commerce & Industry, Government of India

    [3] ManufacturingIndia@75, KPMG-

    CIIConferenceonManufacturingCompetitiveness:

    Technology,OutsourcingandInnovation, October 17, 2008

    [4] Devashish Mitra, Beyza P. Ural, Indian Manufacturin: A slow growing sector

    in rapidly growing economy, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4233,

    May 2007.

    [5] Kalpana Kochhar, Utsav Kumar, Raghuram Rajan, Arvind Subramanian,

    Ioannis Tokatlidis. Indias pattern of Devwlopment: What Happened, What

    Follows; National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 12023

    [6] Science and Engineering Indicators 2008, National Science Foundation

    [7] KPMG Analysis. UNESCO ISE, UN Statistics, Policy Brief (Jul2008) OECD

    [8] Michele Alessandrini and Tullio Buccellato, CHINA, INDIA AND RUSSIA:

    ECONOMIC REFORMS, STRUCTURAL CHANGE AND REGIONAL DISPARITIES,

    Economics Working Paper No.97, December 2008; Centre for the Study of

    Economic and Social Change in Europe

    [9] http://www.siliconindia.com/guestcontributor/guestarticle/44/Hitech

    manufacturing an opportunity in waiting.html

    [10] Zhang, K.H., What Attracts Foreign Multinationals to China, Contemporary

    Economic

    Policy, 19:3, 2001, 336-361

    [11] Lall, Sanjaya, Foreign Direct Investment in South Asia, Asian Development

    Review,

    11:1, 103-119, 1993

    http://www.siliconindia.com/guestcontributor/guestarticle/44/Hitech_manufacturing__an_opportunity_in_waiting.htmlhttp://www.siliconindia.com/guestcontributor/guestarticle/44/Hitech_manufacturing__an_opportunity_in_waiting.htmlhttp://www.siliconindia.com/guestcontributor/guestarticle/44/Hitech_manufacturing__an_opportunity_in_waiting.htmlhttp://www.siliconindia.com/guestcontributor/guestarticle/44/Hitech_manufacturing__an_opportunity_in_waiting.html
  • 8/6/2019 Industrial Strategy of India China

    26/26

    [12] Swapna S. Sinha, David H. Kent, Hamid Shomali, COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS

    OF FDI IN CHINA AND INDIA, Journal of Asia Entrepreneurship and Sustainability,

    Volume 3, Issue 2, September 2007.

    [13] Chandana Chakraborty and Peter Nunnenkamp, Economic Reforms,

    Foreign Direct Investment and its Economic Effects in India, Kiel Working Paper

    No. 1272, The Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Duesternbrooker (Germany)

    [14] JESUS FELIPE, EDITHA LAVINA and EMMA XIAOQIN FAN, "The Diverging

    Patterns of Profitability, Investment and Growth of China and India During 1980

    2003", World Development Vol. 36, No. 5, pp. 741774, 2008

    [15] Shaikh, A. (1999). Explaining inflation and unemployment: An alternative to

    neoliberal economic policy. In A. Vachlou (Ed.), Contemporary economic theory.

    London: Macmillan.

    [16] Singh, K., & Bery, S. (2005). Growth experience. In W.Tseng, & D. Cowen

    (Eds.), Indias and Chinas recent experience with growth and reform (pp. 2358).

    New York: Palgrave Macmillan

    [17] India@75by CK Prahalad. Lecture Delivered during the India@60

    celebrations in New York, September 23, 2007

    [18] Kalim Siddiqui, The political economy of growth in China and India. Journal of

    Asian Public Policy, Vol. 2, No. 1, March 2009, 1735

    [19] National Bureau of Economic Research. (Feb 2009). Robert C. Feenstra,

    Shang-Jin Wei, Introduction to Growing Role of China in World Trade, Working

    Paper 14716.

    [20] Wang, Miao(2009) 'Manufacturing FDI and economic growth: evidence from

    Asian economies',

    Applied Economics, 41: 8, 991 1002