Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    1/28

    Paper Presented atIncreasing Returns and Economic Analysis:An International Conference in Honour of

    Professor Arrow, Monash University

    7-8 September, 1995

    INDUSTRIALISATION POLICYANDTHE BIG PUSH*

    by

    Joshua S. GansSchool of Economics

    University of New South WalesSydney, NSW 2052

    Australia

    E-Mail: [email protected]

    First Draft: 25 January, 1994This Version: November 21, 1996

    The economic development literature of the 1940s and 1950s wasconcerned with the question of whether industrialisation policy should have abroad or balanced orientation or if it should target a few key sectors, i.e., beunbalanced in its focus. This paper reconsiders this long-standing debate inlight of the recent formalisations of big push theories of industrialisation.A dynamic model of industrialisation exhibiting multiple Pareto-rankablesteady states is developed to consider this issue. It is shown that time lags inproduction mean that costless policies, such as indicative planning, areunlikely to be successful. This means that, under cost minimisation,industrialisation policy, will not be concentrated but more gradual over timeand that it will become progressively more balanced. Finally, it is found thatthe cost minimising industrialisation policy should be more unbalanced thestronger are increasing returns, the less scarce are entrepreneurial resources,and the smaller is the intrinsic market size but that the strength of linkages hasan ambiguous effect on the optimal degree of balance. Journal of Economic

    Literature Classification Numbers: D10, O10, O14 & O20.

    Keywords: industrialisation, balanced and unbalanced growth, transition,technology adoption, complementarities, linkages, increasing returns,gradualism.

    * This paper is an amended version of Chapter 4 of my Ph.D. dissertation from Stanford University (seeGans, 1994a). I wish to thank Susan Athey, Antonio Ciccone, Avner Greif, Yingyi Qian, Philip Trostel,Graham Voss, seminar participants at Stanford University, Monash University and the World Congress of

    the Econometric Society (Tokyo, 1995), and especially, Kenneth Arrow, Paul Milgrom and Scott Stern forhelpful discussions and comments. I also thank the Fulbright Commission for financial support. Allerrors are my responsibility.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    2/28

    I . Introduction

    The recent theoretical literature on industrialisation has formalised the long standing

    idea that development traps are the result of a failure of economic organisation rather than a

    lack of resources or other technological constraints. The so-called big push models of

    industrialisation have shown how, in the presence of increasing returns, many equilibria are

    possible with some Pareto dominating others. Such a view not only provides an

    explanation for the co-existence of industrialised and non-industrialised economies, but also

    a rationale for government intervention to coordinate investment in a big push towards

    industrialisation (Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny, 1989, p.1024). Moreover, unlike

    competing theories, these models emphasise the temporary nature of any policy.1 Thus,

    industrialisation policy involves facilitating an adjustment from one equilibrium to another

    rather than any change in the nature of the set of equilibria per se.

    While the recent formalisation makes clear the possible role for the government in

    coordinating economic activity, little has been said about the form such a policy should

    take. Many have recently argued that intervention should target many sectors and that this

    should occur more or less simultaneously (Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny, 1989). But an

    earlier informal literature suggests that such conclusions are not obvious and perhaps that

    even the reverse is true. That is, in the presence of coordination failure, industrialisation

    policy might still be successful with a more limited focus and a more gradual application.

    It is the purpose of this paper to construct a formal model to analyse the question:

    what form should the big push take? In so doing, it will be shown here that the notion

    that industrialisation policy should be broad and immediate is not a necessary implication

    of such models. In this paper, it is argued that while many different industrialisation

    policies can be successful in generating escapes from development traps, the form of the

    policy that minimises the costs of this transition depends on the characteristics of the

    economic situation at hand. Factors such as the strength of complementarities, externalities

    1 This is in contrast to theories attributing the lack of industrialisation to a pure lack of incentives to adoptmodern technologies, leading to policies such as the building of new institutions for property rights and thelike (e.g., Rosenberg and Birdzell, 1986; Greif, 1992).

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    3/28

    2

    and increasing returns, among others, all play a role in influencing the nature of

    industrialisation policy.

    Such ideas were present in the debates in development economics in the 1940s and

    1950s regarding the form of industrialisation policy. The ideas underlying these less

    formal debates inspired the recent formal literature but the policy elements of these have not

    been addressed, to date, in any formal manner.

    Principal among the earlier policy debates was that surrounding the efficacy and

    costs involved in the alternative strategies of balanced versus unbalanced growth.

    Rosenstein-Rodan (1943, 1961) and Nurkse (1952, 1953) provided the rationale for the

    notion that the adoption of modern technologies must proceed across a wide range of

    industries more or less simultaneously. It was argued that the neglect of investment in a

    sector (or sectors) could undermine any industrialisation strategy.2

    Reacting to this policy prescription was the unbalanced growth school led by

    Hirschman (1958) and Streeten (1956, 1963). They saw the balanced strategy as far too

    costly: The initial resources for simultaneous developments on many fronts are generally

    lacking. (Singer quoted by Hirschman, 1958, p.53) By targeting many sectors, it was

    argued that scarce resources would be spread too thin -- so thin, that industrialisation would

    be thwarted. It seemed more fruitful to target a small number of leading sectors,

    (Rostow, 1960)3 relying on their development to encourage technology adoption in other

    sectors. To that school the existence of complementarity between investments and

    increasing returns motivates an unbalanced approach.4 Curiously, at the same time,

    [c]omplementarity of different industries provides the most important set of arguments in

    favour of a large-scale planned industrialisation. (Rosenstein-Rodan, 1943, p.205)

    It is not the task of this paper to reconstruct and piece together the lines of logic that

    drove the past debate on balanced and unbalanced growth. Both sides appeared to have

    2 Other work associated with the balanced growth school included Scitovsky (1954), Fleming (1955),

    Chenery (1959) and Nath (1960).3 Also termed propulsive industries (Perroux, 1958) or development blocks (Dahmen, 1950).4 Other early opponents of balanced growth included Ellis (1958) and Myint (1960).

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    4/28

    3

    agreed that a big push was warranted, but they disagreed as to its composition (i.e., how

    many and what type of sectors should be targeted). My purpose here is to use the

    guidelines provided by the recent formalisation of the big push theory of industrialisation

    to clarify the issue of the appropriate timing and degree of focus for industrialisation policy.

    After all, the recent literature has stressed the roles of complementarities and increasing

    returns that both of the older schools saw lying at the heart of their policy prescriptions. 5

    Nonetheless, throughout the paper, I will revisit aspects of the arguments of both schools

    to link the formalism with the earlier discussions.

    II . A Dynamic Model of Industrialisation

    In this section, I present a simplified version of the model in Gans (1994a, 1995)

    that itself is a dynamic version of Ciccone (1993). This model provides a rich array of

    parameters to characterise the optimal choice of the government and weakens the strong

    labour market assumptions made by Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny (1989). Moreover,

    unlike that model (and similar models such as those of Matsuyama, 1992, and Ciccone and

    Matsuyama, 1993) this model here allows for a clear separation of substitution and

    complementary effects from entry.

    Sectoral Structure and Technology

    The economy consists of two production sectors. The first is a downstream sector

    with a measure one continuum of firms producing a homogenous final good, Y. Firms are

    competitive price-takers and employ both labour, LY, and a composite of intermediate

    inputs, X, according to, Y t X t L t Y( ) ( ) ( )+ =1 1 , > 0. From the outset, the critical

    feature to note about this production technology is that production of the final good takes

    one period. The introduction of the lag structure here distinguishes this model from other

    dynamic models of industrialisation (cf., Ciccone and Matsuyama, 1993). Nonetheless,

    5 See Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny (1989) and Krugman (1992).

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    5/28

    4

    this time element adds a small amount of realism to the model that will turn out to have

    important policy implications. The final good, Y, is taken as numeraire.

    The intermediate input composite is assembled by upstream producers according to,

    X t x t dnn( ) ( ) , ,=

    >

    1

    1

    0

    1

    where xn denotes the amount of intermediate input of type n employed.

    Households consume final goods not used in production and supply one unit of

    labour inelastically for which they receive a wage, w(t) in period t. Here I make the simple

    assumption that household utility is linear in total consumption so that households solve:

    max ( )( )C t

    t

    tt

    C t{ }

    =

    =

    01

    subject to 111

    11

    1

    0+=

    +=

    ( ) ( ) + r tt

    t

    r t

    t

    t

    C t L w t v( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ),

    where v(0) is the value of share holdings in upstream firms, L is the constant total labour

    endowment , and r(t) is the interest rate in t. Linear utility means that the interest rate is

    constant over time and equal to r t( ) ( ) / = 1 .6

    Each variety of intermediate input, n, is produced by a single monopolist in the

    upstream sector. There is a continuum of such firms lying on the (extended) real line.

    Apart from the usual pricing decisions, potential producers in this sector face the decision

    of whether to enter into production or not. As such, as in Ciccone and Matsuyama (1993)

    and Rodriguez-Clare (1993), the number of firms entering will constitute a measure of the

    level ofindustrialisation.7

    6 Many of the basic results of the model can be generalised beyond this specific assumption to generalutility functions. These issues are discussed in depth in Gans (1995). Because the focus here is on policyissues it is convenient to focus on this special case. Note, however, that if there is perfectly mobile capitalinternationally, then the interest rate will be fixed at its international level. The model here is s tillconsistent with this assumption if it is assumed that intermediate inputs are nontradables such as services.Such an approach is taken by Rodriguez-Clare (1993).7 In Gans (1994a, 1995), I develop a similar model that incorporates the view of industrialisation as theadoption of increasing returns technologies (Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny, 1989) as well as the view here

    that industrialisation involves the use of a greater variety of inputs in production (Ciccone and Matsuyama,1993; Rodriguez-Clare, 1993). The decision to focus on a unidimensional measure of industrialisationsimplifies the exposition here, eliminating certain complicating factors addressed in Gans (1994a).

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    6/28

    5

    The Decision to Enter

    In order to facilitate a discussion of policy issues, I assume that there are two broadclasses of intermediate input varieties distinguished by their respective entry costs. First,

    there are basic varieties with indexes n kB[ , ]0 . Such varieties are assumed to have

    already entered into production. Such producers are assumed to be monopolists.8 Second,

    there are modern varieties with indexes n kB [ , ) . For these varieties, entry is costly in

    that they cannot be produced without incurring a charge ofFunits of the final good. Thus,

    it is a pure sunk cost of entry and need only be incurred in the period of the firms start-up.

    As will be apparent below, firms will find it optimal to enter production if and only if they

    face non-negative profits upon entry (given their optimal pricing decision) and having

    entered they find it optimal to produce in all subsequent periods.

    The technologies of production are the same across intermediate input sectors

    (whether basic or modern). Upstream producers, after they have entered production, can

    generate output according to, x t l t n n( ) ( )= .

    Having specified the sectoral structure, tastes and technology for this economy, it

    can be shown that the possibility of industrialisation or non-industrialisation in this model

    rests on the outcome of a game played among intermediate input producers in their entry

    decisions. With a bit of work it can be shown how the payoffs of this game arise out of the

    general equilibrium structure of the model.9 This is done by first solving for optimal

    household and final good producer allocation decisions and the optimal pricing decisions of

    intermediate input producers. Then good and labour market clearing is imposed. This

    yields to a precise specification of the equilibrium prices in the economy in each period --

    pn(t) for each intermediate input variety and wages, w(t) -- contingent on the number of

    firms in the economy, k(t), itself a measure of the level of industrialisation in each period.

    8 The assumption that basic producers are monopolists is made for notational simplicity. It could havebeen assumed that these sectors were perfectly competitive. This, however, would have served merely to

    increase algebra in the pricing equations below without any change in the substantive results that are thefocus of this paper. Here k

    Brepresents an initial condition.

    9 See Gans (1995) for a derivation.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    7/28

    6

    Using this can be shown that, in each period, the operating cash flow of a producer

    of modern varieties is, n n nt p t w t x t w t L k t ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )= ( ) = ( )1 , with the charge ofF

    being deducted in ns first period of production. Substituting the relevant aggregate

    variables into this equation gives a convenient reduced form for the payoffs of an

    intermediate input producer producing a positive output in period t,

    n tk t

    k t( )

    ( )

    ( )=

    1 1 .

    where = ( ) ( ) L

    ( ) ( ) ( )1 11

    . Observe that if 1 , then, from a

    system-wide point of view, there exists apositive feedbackbetween the past entry choices

    of intermediate input producers and the firms current choice, if it is a modern variety

    producer. To see this more clearly, suppose that there is no further increase in overall

    industrialisation in period t. Then operating cash flow is increasing in k t( ) 1 if and only

    if k t k t ( ) ( ) 1 1 1

    is nondecreasing in k t( ) 1 . Holding the current increment to

    industrialisation, k t k t k t ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 , constant, this is equivalent to requiring that,

    k t k tk t k t

    ( ) ( )( ) ( )

    +

    1 11

    0

    1

    ,

    which is true if and only if 1 . Then, ceteris paribus, the greater the past level of

    industrialisation, the greater is the return to entry. Thus, if the so-called increasing returns

    due to specialisation (( ) 1 1) outweigh the decreasing returns to additional use of the

    intermediate input composite (), the game between intermediate input producers exhibits,

    in this sense, strategic complementarities. I will have more to say about these parameters in

    a later section. For the rest of this paper, it is assumed that 1 .

    It is worth noting, however, that the decision to enter in the current period is a

    strategic substitute with the current entry choices of other intermediate input producers. So

    while a greater level of past industrialisation raises the return to entry today, greater current

    entry dampens those incentives. The former (complementary) effect emerges because

    greater past industrialisation pushes up current wages which in turn raises demand for

    intermediate inputs through higher aggregate demand. On the other hand, the latter

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    8/28

    7

    (substitution) effect occurs because of the reduction in current intermediate input prices

    caused by lower marginal costs of production and the competition of entrants.

    Equilibria

    Having derived the payoff functions, the equilibria in the game between

    intermediate input producers can be considered. A sequence of entry decisions translates

    into a sequence of states, { ( )}k t . Such a sequence, {( )}k t , constitutes a pure strategy

    Nash equilibrium results if, for each t, (i)

    t

    ntk k F n k t

    < > ( ( ), ( )) , ( )1 and

    (ii)

    t

    nt k k F n k t

    (

    ( ),

    ( )) ,

    ( )1 . Thus, in equilibrium, if they chose to

    enter, non-active firms would earn negative profits and all active firms earn non-negative

    total discounted profits.

    Two broad types of equilibria are possible. If <

    F kB( )11

    1

    (i.e., the number

    of basic varieties is small, the market size is small and fixed costs are large), then the

    economy will be in a development trap with only firms producing basic varieties active.

    However, persistent industrialisation is also possible. It can be shown (see Gans,

    1995), that if at some time k(t) becomes greater than some critical level, k* where

    kF

    *

    ( )= ( )

    1

    1

    11

    , the level of industrialisation will continue to expand thereafter.10 Thus,

    in the spirit of big push theories of industrialisation, the economy can be stuck in a

    development trap from which an escape could be made provided sufficient coordination of

    the decisions of intermediate input producers is achieved.11

    Note, however, that this model of dynamic coordination failure differs from

    analogous static models in that optimistic expectations would not generate an escape from

    the development trap. In many models of coordination failure, there exist rational

    10 This result is related to the Momentum Theorem, initially stated in Milgrom, Qian and Roberts (1991)for contracting problems, and was extended, in Gans (1994b), to game theoretic contexts. It provides asimple method of proof of the existence of a steady state in a discrete time framework.11 Indeed, using the zero profit condition, it is easy to see that for the case of persistent industrialisation the

    dynamic equation for k(t) is: k t k t F

    ( ) ( )( )

    = 1

    11 1

    .

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    9/28

    8

    expectations paths between equilibria. Here, however, there exists no rational expectations

    or perfect foresight paths from non-industrialisation to industrialisation.

    To see this, beginning in the development trap, suppose that all potential modern

    intermediate input producers expect k kB others to enter in the current period. Suppose

    that k > k*, so that expected level of industrialisation would make these entry decisions

    profitable when considered over time. The question must be asked: is it profitable for a

    given modern input producer to enter this period? The alternative would be to wait one

    period. To consider the optimal decision, all that is relevant are the cash flows of firms in

    the current and next period. The two period cash flow from entering today is,

    k k k F B

    +

    + 11

    11 , and the two period cash flow from waiting until tomorrow to enter

    is,

    k F+

    1

    1 . Thus, there is a trade-off between the earnings from production today

    and deferring the sunk costs of entry. An intermediate input producer will choose to wait

    rather than produce if ( )1 1 1

    F k kB . This inequality holds for any k kB , strictly,

    by the condition for the development trap. This makes it always optimal to wait.

    This argument leads to the following proposition.

    Proposition 1. Given any initial level of industrialisation, k(0), if k k ( ) *0 < then theeconomy is in a development trap for all t. Otherwise, it is in a state of persistentindustrialisation.

    The optimality of waiting means that no decentralised rational expectations/perfect foresight

    path exists from the development trap to persistent industrialisation. The reason for this is

    that if it is always optimal for one intermediate input producer to wait, by symmetry, it is

    optimal for all firms to do so.12 As a consequence no industrialisation occurs and hence,

    any expectations to the contrary would not be fulfilled. Observe that this result holds for

    any positive discount rate.13 Thus, the non-industrialisation equilibrium is absorbing in the

    12 This distinguishes the model from Matsuyama (1991, 1992) and Krugman (1991) both of whom rely onan exogenously specified adjustment cost to generate their results. Here the inertia is endogenous arisingout of general equilibrium interactions. This result is similar in flavour to the example of Rauch (1993)although he assumes the differing substitution and complementary effects rather than deriving them as isdone here.

    13 Moreover, this result holds for more general utility functions (see Gans, 1995) and for the case of ansmall open economy with non-tradable intermediate inputs and perfect capital mobility since, in that case,interest rates are exogenously determined.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    10/28

    9

    sense of Matsuyama (1991, 1992).14 Note also that there is no rational expectations path

    from industralisation back to the development trap. This latter feature is a direct

    consequences of the irreversibility of entry.

    The above result follows directly from the assumed time lag in production of the

    final good. This assumption makes entry today a strategic substitute with similar decisions

    on the part of other producers. That is, each individual producer of modern varieties

    benefits from the current entry of others in that it makes future entry profitable. However,

    for each, the current entry decision is dominated by the decision to wait an additional

    period. Therefore, there exists a multiperson prisoners dilemma among intermediate input

    producers with a resultant failure to industrialise.

    The Impossibility of Successful Indicative Planning

    When a development trap is purely the result of coordination failure, it is often

    argued that the role for the government is to coordinate the expectations of individual

    agents, making them consistent with those for persistent industrialisation. This is also the

    stated goal of indicative planning. If possible, such a policy would be costless (save,

    perhaps, the costs of communication), and firms would modernise on the basis of

    optimistic expectations.

    Proposition 1 shows that this solution will not work. This is essentially because the

    problem, while one of a failure to coordinate investment, is not one of a failure to

    coordinate expectations. If a government were to announce that a sufficient number of

    firms should start-up, even if this were believed perfectly by firms , each individual firm

    would still have an incentive to wait one period before entering into production. And, in

    that case, the optimistic expectations created by the government would not be realised and

    the policy would be ineffective.

    14 Matsuyama (1991) states that one state is accessible from another if there exists a rationalexpectations/perfect foresight equilibrium path from one that state that reaches or converges to the other. Astate is absorbing if, within a neighbourhood of it, no other state is accessible.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    11/28

    10

    Irreversibility and the time lag of production mean that history rather than

    expectations matter for equilibrium selection.15 The previous level of industrialisation

    determines what path the economy will take in the future. This is why it is difficult to

    characterise the industrialising paths of the economy. It is also difficult to characterise the

    optimality, or otherwise, of industrialisation. Therefore, I will simply assume here that

    preferences are such that industrialisation is a desirable policy goal.

    III. Engendering Transition

    Using this model of industrialisation, it is now possible to consider the policy

    issues and decisions facing a government. As discussed earlier, the aim of this paper is to

    address the issue of how a government can facilitate a transition from the development trap

    to a state of persistent industrialisation. Thus, it is imagined that, for historical reasons, the

    economy, while producing some of the final good, has not industrialised. Given this

    situation, what should a government do to facilitate a transition to an industrialising path?16

    Proposition 1 implies that if a level of industrialisation greater than the critical level,

    k*, can be generated, then the economy will escape from the development trap. The issue

    for the government, therefore, is to intervene when the economy is in the development trap

    so as to generate the critical level of industrialisation. After this, no more intervention is

    required to ensure that the process of industrialisation persists. Nonetheless, generating the

    critical level of industrialisation may involve certain costs. It is the nature of these costs that

    drives the policy choices a government must make.

    The Costs of Inducing Change

    Here it is assumed that the costs of inducing a firm to enter into production can be

    represented by the function, c k tn( ( ), )1 . This function is the individual (transition)

    15 See Krugman (1991) for an extensive discussion of this point.16 For a general discussion of the policy issues in the face of coordination failure see Gans (1994b).

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    12/28

    11

    cost for period t and it is everywhere positive. represents the vector of exogenous

    parameters, , , , Fand L .

    What are the potential sources of such costs? One could suppose that in order

    convince a firm to enter and adopt more modern technologies one would need to

    compensate it for its perceived potential losses. Thus, the cost could take the form of an

    investment subsidy. On the other hand, since in many respects the reason individual firms

    do not enter and adopt more efficient technologies is due to insufficient demand, this cost

    could take the form of a direct demand stimulus. Finally, these costs could represent the

    transactions costs associated with insurance or loan policies of government.17

    Of course, these alternative mechanisms for inducing individuals to change their

    behaviour would involve different costs in of themselves, but in considering the issue of

    the degree of balance in industrialisation policy and its timing, the significant point is that

    there are such costs. After all, it was the fear that scarce resources would be spread too thin

    that drove the entire logic the unbalanced growth school.

    In order to characterise the optimal policy choices of the government, the way the

    level of industrialisation influences these individual transition costs, cn , deserves some

    comment. A complete specification might also have the current level of industrialisation in

    the cost function. The effect of this on costs is, however, a complicated manner. If firms

    were somewhat myopic, greater current levels of industrialisation might raise individual

    transition costs. But if they were farsighted it may reduce them. To avoid these

    difficulties, it is assumed that the current level of industrialisation influences future but not

    present costs.

    As for the past level of industrialisation, as was discussed in Section II, there exists

    a positive feedback between the past level of industrialisation and the entry decisions of

    firms. The marginal returns to entry are raised by greater past industrialisation. Therefore,

    17 If there were no time lags in production and the model was one of pure coordination failure, theconsiderations here would still apply if one believed that the cost functions represented the expenses ofcommunicating plans to additional sectors.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    13/28

    12

    it reasonable to assume that greater past levels of industrialisation lower individual

    transition costs of entry. That is,

    (A) c k tn( ( ), ) 1 is nonincreasing in k t( )1 , n t, .

    The precise way the exogenous parameters enters into the cost function turns out to have no

    influence on the results that follow, so no restrictions are imposed here.

    IV . The Governments Optimisation Problem

    A government with utilitarian goals would aim to maximise the utility of the

    representative household over time. This would involve, not only engendering transition,

    but undertaking policies that ensured optimal growth thereafter. Since the concern of this

    paper lies solely with the former policy, here I choose to focus on a more restricted goal for

    the government -- cost minimisation. That is, the government chooses the

    industrialisation policy that minimises the sum of individual transition costs incurred over

    time subject to the constraint that a big push, (i.e., critical level of industrialisation) is

    realised. From that point, industrialisation will proceed of its own accord. This goal is

    reasonable since these costs may involve the sacrificing of consumption or may be funded

    from some resource constrained external source.18

    Funding

    If cost minimisation is the goal of the optimal transition policy, then the precise

    source of funding is immaterial. The early debate on industrialisation policy often implicitly

    supposed that the funds or goods needed for industrialisation would come from some

    external source. This implied some sort of foreign aid or loans. Such external resources

    18 The instruments of inducing individual change may also be imperfect mechanisms involving somedeadweight losses for the economy.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    14/28

    13

    might be limited, especially if they were in the form of final goods, and thus, minimising

    costs was considered an explicit goal.

    A similar criterion applies for internal funding (which is possible since there is

    some production even in the development trap). Suppose that the funds for transition are

    raised internally through a lump sum tax on the incomes of households. The aggregate

    revenues from this tax at time tis denoted by (t). Note, however, that it must be assumed

    that (t) < Y(t) always. In each period, household consumption is reduced by (t).

    Nonetheless, regardless of whether the instrument for inducing change is an investment

    subsidy or direct demand stimulus,19 the total transition costs are being added to the

    aggregate cash flow of intermediate input producers. Thus, there is no direct effect on

    aggregate income (apart from any dead-weight losses from intervention), only a re-

    distribution of it from households to firms. In this respect, there is an effect on aggregate

    consumption, making it desirable to minimise the costs of transition and, hence, the level of

    the tax.

    The Cost Minimising Industrialisation Policy

    In general, in addition to the length of the intervention, the government chooses the

    number of firms targeted for change in each period. That is, in each period, t, the

    government chooses a set of firms, K t( ) + , that have not entered into production in the

    past, to induce to do so.

    Suppose that the government chose to intervene from period t to period T.20 Then

    in order to generate persistent industrialisation after period T, the total number of firms

    targeted, K ss t

    T( )

    = , must be greater than k kB* . Thus, for this application, the level ofk kB

    * defines the magnitude of the big push required to generate persistent

    industrialisation. It is important to note that the goal of achieving this minimal level of

    19 Since the governments additional demand would be inelastic, I am assuming implicitly that firmscontinue to charge the same price to them as to final goods producers.20

    The actual choice ofTwill be governed by preference considerations as well as costs. As such, it is notconsidered explicitly here. Nonetheless, if persistent industrialisation is a desirable long-run outcome, it isreasonable to suppose that Tis finite.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    15/28

    14

    industrialisation is independent of the issue of timing. Given the effective irreversibility of

    entry, the minimal level of industrialisation need not be generated in a single period. While

    not an issue with respect to whether an escape from the development trap will be

    successful, by smoothing the costs of transition over a period of time, the government can

    take advantage of the fact that the individual transition costs fall with past entry.

    Formally, given a choice of the length of intervention, T - t, the governments

    choice of industrialisation policy is determined by the solution to the following optimisation

    problem,

    min ( ( ), )( )

    ( )

    K s n

    K ss t

    T

    s t

    T c k s dn{ }

    ==

    1 subject to K s k k s tT

    B( )*

    = .

    This is quite a complicated problem. Nonetheless, the nature of the model of

    industrialisation yields some simplifying information as regards the optimal policy.

    Symmetry among firms makes it reasonable to suppose that their individual cost functions

    are symmetric as well. Moreover, this also makes it reasonable to imagine that firms are

    targeted in order of their index. Therefore, K t k k t B( ) [ , ( )]= , K s k s k s( ) [ ( ), ( )]= 1 and

    K s k k T

    s t

    T

    B( ) [ , ( )]= =U . With this information, the governments optimisation problem can

    be re-written as,

    min ( ( ), )( )

    ( )

    ( )

    k s

    k s

    k s

    s t

    T

    s t

    T c k s dn{ }

    ==

    11

    subject to k T k( ) * .

    Even with these simplifications this problem is rather complicated. Using the

    characteristics of the model of Section II, however, some analysis of its properties is

    possible. First, the issue of the timing will be addressed, while Section VI will turn to a

    characterisation of the optimal degree of balance in industrialisation policy.

    V . The Timing of Intervention

    This section examines the notion that industrialisation should proceed

    simultaneously across targeted sectors. As noted earlier, actually achieving a successful

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    16/28

    15

    escape from the development trap is independent of the issue of timing. Nonetheless, how

    quickly should the critical aggregate be generated given cost side considerations?

    Consider the optimisation problem when the government chooses to intervene for

    one period only. This policy is referred to as a big bang, in which the government solves,

    min ( , )( )

    ( )

    k t B

    k

    k t

    c k dn

    B

    ( ) subject to k t k( )* .

    Nonetheless, such a big bang policy never minimises the total costs of transition.

    Proposition 2. Assume (A) and suppose that the intervention begins in period t.

    Then the cost minimising industrialisation policy always involves a choice of T > t.

    To see this, start from a big bang industrialisation policy with T= t. Then imagine that

    rather than targeting a few upstream firms in period t, they were targeted in period t + 1

    instead. Note that the big push constraint remains satisfied after this change. In this

    case, (A) guarantees that the individual transition costs for this firm are lower if it is

    targeted in period t+ 1 rather than t. This is because the level of industrialisation, k t( ) is

    necessarily larger than k t kB( ) =1 . Thus, total costs are reduced by extending the period

    of the intervention. Concentrating intervention in a single period does not yield any of the

    benefits associated with this fall in marginal costs. As such, this provides a reason why a

    more gradual policy would be optimal.

    Such cost-side considerations may be supported by other reasons for smoothing.

    For instance, a government concerned about the utility of the population over time as well

    as cost minimisation could be motivated for a gradual industrialisation policy for the

    traditional taste-side reasons favouring less period-by-period saving -- i.e., low discount

    rates and elasticities of intertemporal substitution. Finally, it should be noted that

    depreciation in the initial start-up investment would mitigate against the irreversibilities

    assumed in Section II and may make a less gradual approach more desirable.

    The Form of the Intervention Over Time

    The motive for spreading intervention over time raises another important issue: how

    should the number of upstream sectors targeted for change move over time? Assuming

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    17/28

    16

    (A), it is not difficult to see that the number of sectors targeted in each period will grow

    over time. The reasoning here is similar to that leading to the motivation for gradualism.

    That is, consider any two time periods, > s , and start from the situation in which

    k s k( ) ( )= . Targeting a firm for entry in a later time period has a lower marginal cost

    since the industrialisation level is higher. Therefore, in the optimal policy, k s k( ) ( ) .

    The remainder of this argument follows by induction.

    V . The Degree of Balance in Industrialisation Policy

    The debate over whether industrialisation policy should be balanced or unbalanced

    was effectively concerned with the number of sectors that needed to be targeted for change.

    ... both doctrines are examples of an acceptance of the necessity for a big push (broadlydefined) in economic development. The overt difference seems to be where and over howwide a field the push is to be applied. Thus on a cardinal issue the two doctrines areunited in their rejection of economic development by piecemeal marginalism. (Sutcliffe,1964, pp.627-628)

    The balanced growth school argued that the neglect of too many sectors could thwart a

    successful transition, while the unbalanced growth school believed that the targeting of a

    few key sectors could generate sufficient momentum for industrialisation to proceed of its

    own accord. The model of Section II argues that a big push is required to generate

    persistent industrialisation. This section will show that the cost minimising composition of

    the big push depends on the underlying economic parameters at hand.

    The degree of balance was often ill-defined in the early informal literature. While

    some proponents (e.g., Rosenstein-Rodan, Nurkse) have focused on a balance between

    horizontal sectors (e.g., among final goods producers), others have focused on

    intermediate input sectors versus final good sectors or other forms of heterogeneity (e.g.,

    Hirschman, Rostow). The model here focuses on horizontal linkages -- the

    interdependencies between decisions of sectors at the same production level -- even though

    these may be derived from upstream and downstream interactions. In this sense, the

    symmetry between the sectors being considered biases one towards a definition of the

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    18/28

    17

    degree of balance based on the number of sectors targeted for change at the same level of

    the economy. Thus, a bias is introduced in the following discussion towards the balanced

    growth school by omitting the differences between sectors.21

    On this basis, the model presented in Section II provides a clear definition of the

    degree of balance. Proposition 1 showed that if the government targeted a critical mass of

    sections, k*, for change, then industrialisation would persist thereafter. This number,

    therefore, is the natural measure of the degree of balance in my model.22 It defines

    precisely what is required for a big push to take place. Therefore, one way to

    conceptualise the debate between the balanced and unbalanced schools is to reduce it to a

    debate over what determines the magnitude of k*. Nonetheless, the way in which the

    model determines k* could potentially neglect some effects and trade-offs that play a role in

    the governments policy choices. I will return to this issue later.

    For now, it is instructive to reflect upon how the parameters of the model determine

    k* and how this relates to earlier discussions over the appropriate degree of balance. Recall

    that: k F*

    ( )= ( )

    11

    11

    . The relationship between the exogenous parameters of the model

    and k* is summarised in the following proposition.

    Proposition 3. The degree of balance ( k*) in the cost minimising industrialisation

    policy is nonincreasing in and L , and nondecreasing in F.

    This simplicity of the model of Section II yields a clear characterisation of the optimal

    industrialisation policy. The cost minimising policy will be more unbalanced the less

    upstream firms discount future earnings (higher ), the higher is the fixed size of the labour

    force (higher L ) and the lower are the sunk costs of entry (lower F). Also, note that no

    clear result is possible for the parameters and . Why this is so and the significance of

    these will be discussed at the end of this section.

    21 Nonetheless, this definition is closely related to notions of balance in other recent formal models (e.g.,the number of final goods sectors in Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny, 1989 and Matsuyama, 1992; and thenumber of intermediate input producers in Rodriguez-Claire, 1993, and Ciccone and Matsuyama, 1993).

    See Sutcliffe (1964) for an interesting discussion of the earlier informal literature on this point.22 Rauch (1992) and Litwack and Qian (1993) also consider similar definitions of the balance of governmentindustrial policy but their analyses are made in very different contexts.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    19/28

    18

    All of the results of Proposition 3 is driven by the monotonic relationship between a

    parameter and k*. Increasing L , raises the operating profits earned in each period of

    production but, more importantly, raises n t t( ) / ( ) 1 , the strength of strategic

    complementarity among upstream sectors. Likewise, by lowering the cost of entry, a

    smaller Fraises the returns to entry regardless of the level of industrialisation. Finally, a

    lower discount rate (higher ) shifts weight to the future benefits of entry and away from

    current costs, again raising the incentive to enter. Each of these forces has the effect of

    lowering k*, the critical level of industrialisation making entry profitable. This means that

    the incentives of individual firms to enter production at low levels of industrialisation are

    more sensitive to positive entry decisions by a few firms and hence, more unbalanced

    policies will be successful. Of course, the goal of cost minimisation means that a

    government would not wish to target more than k* firms in any industrialisation policy.

    Of these parameters Fhas probably received the most discussion. In many ways,

    this parameter represents the strength of increasing returns in the production technology of

    producers of modern varieties. This is because lower levels ofF imply lower sunk entry

    costs. Therefore, while one requires some degree of increasing returns to generate the

    rationale for a big push intervention, the stronger these are the more an unbalanced

    industrialisation policy is preferred (Hirschman, 1958).

    Another parameter that seems to have been given a potential role in the past debate

    on industrialisation policy is the discount rate, . Matsuyama (1992) interprets the discount

    rate as a measure of the effectiveness of entrepreneurship in coordinating investment -- a

    low discount rate indicating the existence of greater entrepreneurial resources, i.e.,

    farsighted decision-making.23 If this is so, then the above result implies that with a relative

    scarcity of entrepreneurial talent a more balanced approach ought to be followed.

    Curiously, it was, however, the relative scarcity of entrepreneurial talent that seemed to

    Hirschman at make the success of a balanced strategy unlikely: ... the major bone that I

    23 Matsuyamas (1992) definition also encompasses adjustment costs which are not part of the model here.Using different language, Bresnahan and Trajtenberg (1994) have a similar interpretation of the discount rate.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    20/28

    19

    have to pick with the balanced growth theory: its application requires huge amounts of

    precisely those abilities which we have identified as likely to be in very limited supply in

    underdeveloped countries. (Hirschman, 1958, p.53) While I do not argue that the logic

    of Proposition 3 contradicts the line of argument of Hirschman, it does indicate that the

    issues here are quite subtle.24

    The Strength of Linkages and Complementarities

    The existence of a complementarity among the decisions made in different sectors

    drives the rationale for a big push into persistent industrialisation. But a major dispute in

    the earlier industrialisation policy literature is whether this very fact implies the optimality of

    a balanced or unbalanced approach. Therefore, a natural question to ask is how the

    strength of complementarities affects the degree of balance in industrialisation policy?

    The model of Section II, like many recent models, shows that the determinant of the

    success of industrialisation policy is the size of variables such as k*, the critical level of

    industrialisation to achieve any escape. This leaves no room for any choice regarding the

    total number of sectors targeted for change and hence, a first approximation to answering

    the above question is to understand the relationship between the strength of

    complementarities and k*.

    It has been argued by several authors with similar models (e.g., Romer, 1987;

    Ciccone and Matsuyama, 1993; and Ciccone, 1993) that the parameters and are

    measures of the strength of complementarities or linkages among sectors (see Ciccone and

    Matsuyama, 1993, and Romer, 1994). These parameters are, however, only imperfect

    measures of the linkage strength. Take, for example, which parameterises the technical

    complementarity between intermediate input varieties in the production of the composite,X,

    with a lower implying stronger technical complementarities.25 The stronger are these

    24 Although if one were to interpret the quote as emphasising the importance of the existence of basic

    varieties then Hirschmans argument would be supported by Proposition 3.25 This can be seen most clearly be observing that the derivative ofX with respect to a simultaneous

    increase in the quantity employed of some (non-measure zero) group of varieties is larger the lower is .

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    21/28

    20

    complementarities the closer the market linkage between the demand for any given variety

    and the demand for other varieties. This effect is sometimes referred to as the returns to

    specialisation (Ethier, 1982; Romer, 1987). The idea here is that a lower raises the

    marginal returns to employing a greater variety of inputs in production.26 Thus, lowering

    should result in a lower k*.

    But lowering also influences the total wage workers receive and hence, total

    profits. This effect is ambiguous, but it is possible that a reduction in , could reduce

    wages by enough so as to lower the marginal returns to entry favouring a more balanced

    approach. Similar considerations apply to .

    The model then does not contain a parameter that measures perfectly the strength of

    complementarities or linkages among sectors. Despite this, the considerations addressed

    thus far can shed some light on the issue at hand. As discussed earlier, the lower is k*, the

    more likely will individual upstream producers enter in response to similar past entry

    decisions by others. Therefore, there is a sense in which the level of k* itself describes the

    strength of complementarities among upstream sectors (i.e., a lower k* means a greater

    strength of complementarity). One might describe this as essentially a Hirschman effect in

    industrialisation policy. As more entry takes place, those investments would ... call forth

    complementary investments in the next period with a will and logic of their own: they block

    out a part of the road that lies ahead and virtually compel certain additional investment

    decisions. (Hirschman, 1958, p.42) That is, the stronger are strategic complementarities

    or linkages among sectors (as represented by a smaller k*

    ), the more forcefully will

    individual firms react to small increases in industrialisation.

    But the focus on this effect is an artifact of the model presented here -- an artifact

    shared by most other big push style models of industrialisation. The uni-dimensional

    choice of entry means that k* is fully determined by the parameters of the model. Thus,

    26 Alternatively, one could argue, as does Romer (1994), that a lower (higher ) means that a greaterproportion of the returns to entry are appropriatedby individual firms rather than workers. This is because

    the ratio of profit to wage income is decreasing in .

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    22/28

    21

    varying any parameter directly influences the level of k* and hence, the magnitude of the

    big push. The larger the required big push, of necessity, the greater are the number of

    sectors that need to be targeted for change over time. Cost-side considerations do not enter

    into the calculus here nor is there any degree of freedom regarding the ultimate composition

    of the big push.

    In Gans (1994a), in addition to entry, firms can also undertake investments to raise

    labour productivity (i.e., adopt more modern technologies).27 This gives a second

    dimension to industrialisation. To obtain a target level of industrialisation, the government

    can choose both the firms targeted for entry and also firms targeted for modernisation.

    Indeed, to achieve the critical level of industrialisation, the government faces a trade-off

    between these two dimensions. A big push can be achieved by many alternative

    strategies: for instance, targeting a smaller number of firms to enter and modernise to a

    large degree (an unbalanced strategy) or targeting many firms to enter and modernise just a

    little (a balanced strategy). In this case, the big push constraint does not uniquely

    determine the degree of focus in industrialisation policy but leaves numerous options open

    to the government with the final choice resting on cost-side considerations.

    In a general setting, changing parameters can potentially have three important

    effects.28 First, as with the simple model here, the magnitude of the big push, i.e., the

    critical level of industrialisation, can rise or fall, directly influencing the number of sectors

    that need to be targeted for change. This is the Hirschman effect. Second, a parameter

    change can raise the returns to both entry and modernisation. This reduces the costs to

    obtaining a given level of entry and modernisation for an individual firm making it possible

    to achieve the critical aggregate by focusing on fewer firms. Finally, parameter changes

    alter the trade-off between entry and modernisation levels in the make-up of the big push.

    27 This more general model, however, involves many complications that make the proofs of all thepropositions here and the discussion throughout much more cumbersome. Therefore, I chose in this paper

    to focus on a simpler model, commenting on the potential differences as they arose.28 It turns out that the analogs of the other parameters in the model of Gans (1994a) while having some thepotential effects outlined here, do not possess the same difficulties as presented by and .

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    23/28

    22

    In order to obtain an unambiguous characterisation of the cost minimising policy, all

    three effects need to operate in the same direction. While this might be true for other

    parameters,29 at a fundamental level it will not be true for any parameter that might measure

    the strength of complementarities. For while the Hirschman effect and the cost-side effect

    are likely to be correlated in many models, as they are plausibly in the model of this paper,

    this will not be true for the third effect. That effect concerns the marginal influence of a

    firms decisions in the production of a given level of industrialisation. Thus, an

    industrialisation policy choice will be more unbalanced the more an individual firms entry

    raises the measure of the aggregate level of industrialisation. But the weaker are the

    linkages among intermediate input sectors, the more this will be the case. When linkages

    are strong, a firms entry will have a small influence on the aggregate level of

    industrialisation if other firms have not entered. This is essentially a Rosenstein-Rodan

    effect: complementarity makes to some extent all industries basic. (Rosenstein-Rodan,

    1943, p.205) Neglect of sectors in an industrialisation policy may make it highly costly to

    achieve the critical level of industrialisation.30 This effect emphasises the trade-off between

    the number of sectors and their degree of modernisation in producing the critical level of

    industrialisation with stronger linkages implying that a broad approach with shallow

    modernisation will generate this level in a less costly manner.31

    29 In Gans (1994a), it is shown that these effects all reinforce each other for the parameters, thus, generatingthe same conclusions as Proposition 3.30 In contrast to the model here, the model in Gans (1994b), eliminates the Hirschman effect and focusesexclusively on the Rosenstein-Rodan effect.31 There is evidence that the tension between the two effects was recognised. Hirschman clearly recognisesthe possibility of a Rosenstein-Rodan effect: We are not thinking here of situations where A andB must

    be employed jointly in fixed proportions. In this case it would not make much sense to say that demand forA and the subsequent increase in its output provide an incentive for the production ofB, as it is rather the

    demand for the good or service into which A and B enter jointly which explains the demand for both

    products. This is the familiar case of derived demand.... An example of the rigid type of complementarity

    in use (best treated as derived demand) is cement and reinforcing steel rods in the construction, say, ofdowntown office buildings. Examples of the looser, developmental type of complementarity (entrained

    want) can be found in the way in which the existence of the new office buildings strengthens demand for a

    great variety of goods and services: from modern office facilities, stylish secretaries, and eventually perhapsto more office buildings as the demonstration effect goes to work on the tenants of the older buildings.(Hirschman, 1958, pp.68-69; the italics are mine)

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    24/28

    23

    The Hirschman and Rosenstein-Rodan effects capture two sides of the

    complementarity coin. Complementarities and linkages are stronger when (i) increases

    aggregate activity raise the marginal returns to further activity by more; and (ii)

    simultaneous increases in individual activity raise levels of aggregate activity by more.

    Moreover, one effect favours an unbalanced and the other a balanced policy. Thus, the role

    of an informal concept such as the strength of linkages and complementarities must be

    considered carefully before its role in industrialisation policy can be assessed properly.32

    VII . Conclusions and Future Directions

    The central message of this paper is that conclusions regarding the timing of

    industrialisation policy and its degree of focus are complex and dependent on the

    characteristics of the economy under study. A big push perspective on industrialisation

    does not necessarily imply that transition can be a simple matter of coordinating

    expectations via some kind of indicative planning. Nor does it mean that policy must be

    balanced and take a big bang form in order to be successful. A wide variety of

    industrialisation policies can generate a big push and the choice between them is,

    therefore, a matter of costs.

    In a dynamic model, however, this wide variety of industrialisation policies makes a

    characterisation of the optimal policy quite difficult. To take advantage of falling entry

    costs, a gradual policy is always optimal. Moreover, in such a gradual policy, the number

    of sectors targeted in each period is rising over time. But pairwise interactions between

    choice variables and exogenous parameters tend to be qualitatively ambiguous in more

    general dynamic settings. So while the simplicity of the model presented here identified

    some characterisations of the degree of balance, there was reason to believe that with regard

    32 The model here also assumes that linkages among sectors are global with one sector affecting and being

    effected by all others. In Gans (1994a), the model is amended to a parameter allowing a variation the degreeof localisation of linkages. It was found that as linkages became more localised in nature, a moreunbalanced policy was cost minimising.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    25/28

    24

    to some parameters, ambiguities are more fundamental. For instance, weak sectoral

    linkages tend to reduce the sensitivity of individual firms to small changes in the level of

    industrialisation favouring a more balanced approach in order to minimise costs. But at the

    same time, weaker linkages allow individual firm technology adoption decisions to have a

    greater impact on the level of industrialisation itself, favouring an unbalanced strategy.

    Thus, the tensions are complex and more ambiguous than the (sometimes contradictory)

    conclusions drawn by either side in the earlier informal debate.

    Nonetheless, there is a sense in which the above model does not capture potentially

    important ingredients of the industrialisation policies described by both sides of the earlier

    debate. The model here has been symmetric. Thus, the emphasis on the heterogeneity

    between sectors that pervades the work of Hirschman (1958) is excluded. So questions

    such as: what are the characteristics of sectors that should form a critical mass and how do

    they use the information of other sectors investments, are not addressed here. Also, the

    hierarchical relations among many sectors are not a feature of the model. Should one target

    final or intermediate good producers when both face modernisation choices?33

    Another important range of issues not addressed in this paper are those concerned

    with the international trade aspects of industrialisation. If one assumes that the intermediate

    input sectors produce non-tradable goods then the model here sits easily within an open

    economy setting (as in Rodriguez-Clare, 1993). Nonetheless, a more complete treatment

    would construct a model more suitable to address open economy matters. 34 For instance,

    the appropriateness of policies of import substitution versus export promotion remains an

    open question for big push theories. The questions of which sectors might be

    appropriate targets in such policies remains an open area for formal analysis.

    33 Of course, by focusing on intermediate input sectors rather than on final good production, I haveimplicitly concerned the analysis with issues closer to the discussion in Hirschman (1958).34 See Nurske (1958), Hirschman (1958), Sheahan (1958), Scitovsky (1959) and Montias (1961).

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    26/28

    25

    References

    Bresnahan, T. and M. Trajtenberg (1994), General Purpose Technologies: Engines ofGrowth,Journal of Econometrics, (forthcoming).

    Chenery, H.B. (1959), The Interdependence of Investment Decisions, in The Allocationof Economic Resources, Edited by M. Abramowitz, Stanford: Stanford UniversityPress, pp.82-120.

    Ciccone, A. (1993), The Statics and Dynamics of Industrialization and Specialization,mimeo., Stanford.

    Ciccone, A., and K. Matsuyama (1993), Start-Up Costs and Pecuniary Externalities as

    Barriers to Economic Development, Working Paper, No.4363, NBER; Journal ofDevelopment Economics (forthcoming).

    Cooper, R., and A. John (1988), Coordinating Coordination Failures in KeynesianModels, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103 (3), pp.441-463.

    Dahman, E. (1950), Entrepreneurial Activity and the Development of SwedishIndustry, 1919-1939, Homewood (IL): Irwin.

    Ellis, H.S. (1958), Accelerated Investment as a Force in Economic Development,Quarterly Journal of Economics, pp.486-495.

    Ethier, W.J. (1982), National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory ofInternational Trade,American Economic Review, 72 (3), pp.389-405.

    Fleming, J.M. (1955), External Economies and the Doctrine of Balanced Growth,Economic Journal, 65 (June), pp.241-256.

    Gans, J.S. (1994a), Essays in Economic Growth and Change, unpublished Ph.D.Dissertation, Stanford University.

    Gans, J.S. (1994b), Engendering Change, Discussion Paper, No.94/26, School ofEconomics, University of New South Wales.

    Gans, J.S. (1995), Industrialisation with Specialisation and Modernisation: Static andDynamic Considerations, Discussion Paper, N.95/46, School of Economics,University of New South Wales.

    Greif, A. (1992), Institutional Infrastructure and Economic Development: Reflectionsfrom the Commercial Revolution, mimeo., Stanford.

    Hirschman, A.O. (1958), The Strategy of Economic Development, New Haven: YaleUniversity Press.

    Krugman, P.R. (1991), History versus Expectations, Quarterly Journal of Economics,106 (2), pp.651-667.

    Krugman, P.R. (1992), Toward a Counter-Counter Revolution in Development Theory,World Bank Observer, Supplement, pp.15-61.

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    27/28

    26

    Litwack, J.M., and Y. Qian (1993), Economic Transition Strategies: Imperfect FiscalCommitment Can Favor Unbalanced Investment, mimeo., Stanford.

    Matsuyama, K. (1991), Increasing Returns, Industrialization and Indeterminacy ofEquilibria, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106 (2), pp.617-650.

    Matsuyama, K. (1992), The Market Size, Entrepreneurship, and the Big Push, Journalof the Japanese and International Economies, 6 (December), pp.347-364.

    Milgrom, P.R., Y. Qian, and J. Roberts (1991), Complementarities, Momentum and theEvolution of Modern Manufacturing, American Economic Review, 81 (2),pp.85-89.

    Montias, J.M. (1961), Balanced Growth and International Specialization: A Diagrammatic

    Analysis, Oxford Economic Papers, 13 (2), pp.203-220.

    Murphy, K.M., A. Shleifer, and R.W. Vishny (1989), Industrialization and the BigPush,Journal of Political Economy, 97 (5), pp.1003-1026.

    Myint, H. (1960), The Demand Approach to Economic Development, Review of Economic Studies, pp.124-132.

    Nath, S.K. (1962), The Theory of Balanced Growth, Oxford Economic Papers, 14.

    Nurkse, R. (1952), Some International Aspects of the Problem of EconomicDevelopment, American Economic Review, 42 (2), pp.571-583.

    Nurkse, R. (1953), Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries,Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Nurkse, R. (1956), Notes on Unbalanced Growth, Oxford Economic Papers, pp.295-297.

    Nurkse, R., (1958), The Conflict Between Balanced Growth and InternationalSpecialization, in Lectures on Economic Development, Istanbul: Istanbul andAnkara University, pp.170-176.

    Pascoa, M.R. (1993), Noncooperative Equilibrium and Chamberlinian Monopolistic

    Competition,Journal of Economic Theory, 60, pp.335-353.

    Perroux, F. (1958),La Coexistence Pacifique, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

    Rauch, J.E. (1992), Balanced and Unbalanced Growth, Discussion Paper, No.92-28,University of California, San Diego.

    Rauch, J.E. (1993), Does History Matter Only When it Matters Little? The Case of City-Industry Location, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108 (3), pp.843-867.

    Rodriguez-Clare, A. (1993), Economic Underdevelopment: A Trap with an Exit,mimeo., Stanford;Journal of Development Economics (forthcoming).

  • 8/14/2019 Industralisation Policy and the Big Push

    28/28

    27

    Romer, P.M. (1987), Growth Based on Increasing Returns Due to Specialization, American Economic Review, 77 (2), pp.56-62.

    Romer, P.M. (1990), Endogenous Technological Change, Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 98 (Supplement, Pt. 2), pp.S71-S102.

    Romer, P.M. (1994), New Goods, Old Theory, and the Welfare Costs of TradeRestrictions, Journal of Development Economics, 43, pp.5-38.

    Rosenberg, N., and L.E. Birdzell (1986), How the West Grew Rich: The EconomicTransformation of the Industrial World, New York: Basic Books.

    Rosenstein-Rodan, P.N. (1943), Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and South-eastern Europe,Economic Journal, 53 (June-September), pp.202-211.

    Rosenstein-Rodan, P.N. (1961), Notes on the Theory of the Big Push, in EconomicDevelopment for Latin America, Edited by H.S. Ellis and H.C. Wallich, NewYork: St. Martins,

    Rostow, W.W. (1960), The Stages of Economic Growth, Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.

    Scitovsky, T. (1954), Two Concepts of External Economies, Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 62 (April), pp.143-151.

    Scitovsky, T. (1959), Growth - Balanced or Unbalanced?, in The Allocation of Economic Resources, Edited by M. Abramowitz, Stanford: Stanford UniversityPress, pp.201-217.

    Sheahan, J. (1958), International Specialization and the Concept of Balanced Growth,Quarterly Journal of Economics, 52 (2), pp.183-197.

    Streeten, P. (1956), Unbalanced Growth, Oxford Economic Papers, pp.167-190.

    Streeten, P. (1963), Balanced versus Unbalanced Growth, The Economic Weekly, April20, pp.669-671.

    Sutcliffe, R.B. (1964), Balanced and Unbalanced Growth, Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 79 (4), pp.621-643.