35
In the Shadow of Hegemony: Strategic Choices Wei Zongyou* A problem that frequently arises for states in international politics is that of how to deal with one particular state’s rapid growth in power and subsequent hegemonic ambitions. The ‘standard solution’ provided by the realist theory of international relations (IR) is that of other states increas- ing their power (internally balancing) or allying with others (externally balancing) in order to counter the rising power and ensure their own security and survival. Kenneth Waltz, one of the founders of structural realism, contends that in an international system characterized by anarchy where no overarching government exists to enforce laws, ‘balancing, not bandwagon- ing, is the behaviour induced by the system’. 1 When examining historical and current cases, however, there are many instances where states facing the threat of a rising hegemon or global empire do not adopt a balancing strategy. In many cases, they avoid responsibility, do not get involved in the conflict, or bandwagon with the potential hegemon. Why does this happen? What are the motives behind a country’s actions? What factors play an essential role in a state’s decision-making process? How do different strategic choices affect a country’s future survival and prosperity and what are the resulting gains and losses? This essay addresses questions such as these. The essay is split into four parts. The first part analyzes Waltz’s balance of power theory, examines his main ideas and views, and raises logical problems and historical inconsistencies in relation to the theory. The second part lays out the essay’s hypothesis and theoretical assumptions and reveals parameters of state conduct. In the third part, the ‘Warring States’ period of Chinese history is taken as a case-study to test this hypothesis. The fourth and final part is a research summary that draws certain conclusions. Criticisms of Waltz’s Balance of Power Theory In his Theory of International Politics, Waltz established the foundations of the structural realism upon which he constructed his balance of * Corresponding author. Email: [email protected] 1 Kenneth N. Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill Publishing Company, 1979), pp. 125–6. Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195–229 doi:10.1093/cjip/pol015 Reproduced from the Science of International Politics, with kind permission of the authors and the Institute of International Studies, Tsinghua University. by guest on October 30, 2014 http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/ Downloaded from

In the Shadow of Hegemony Strategic Choices

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Text about Chinese Culture

Citation preview

  • In the Shadow of Hegemony:Strategic Choices

    Wei Zongyou*

    A problem that frequently arises for states in international politics is that

    of how to deal with one particular states rapid growth in power and

    subsequent hegemonic ambitions. The standard solution provided by the

    realist theory of international relations (IR) is that of other states increas-

    ing their power (internally balancing) or allying with others (externally

    balancing) in order to counter the rising power and ensure their own security

    and survival. Kenneth Waltz, one of the founders of structural realism,

    contends that in an international system characterized by anarchy where no

    overarching government exists to enforce laws, balancing, not bandwagon-

    ing, is the behaviour induced by the system.1

    When examining historical and current cases, however, there are many

    instances where states facing the threat of a rising hegemon or global empire

    do not adopt a balancing strategy. In many cases, they avoid responsibility,

    do not get involved in the conflict, or bandwagon with the potential

    hegemon. Why does this happen? What are the motives behind a countrys

    actions? What factors play an essential role in a states decision-making

    process? How do different strategic choices affect a countrys future survival

    and prosperity and what are the resulting gains and losses? This essay

    addresses questions such as these.

    The essay is split into four parts. The first part analyzes Waltzs balance

    of power theory, examines his main ideas and views, and raises logical

    problems and historical inconsistencies in relation to the theory. The second

    part lays out the essays hypothesis and theoretical assumptions and

    reveals parameters of state conduct. In the third part, the Warring States

    period of Chinese history is taken as a case-study to test this hypothesis.

    The fourth and final part is a research summary that draws certain

    conclusions.

    Criticisms of Waltzs Balance of Power Theory

    In his Theory of International Politics, Waltz established the foundations

    of the structural realism upon which he constructed his balance of

    * Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

    1 Kenneth N. Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill PublishingCompany, 1979), pp. 1256.

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    doi:10.1093/cjip/pol015

    Reproduced from the Science of International Politics, with kind permission of the authors

    and the Institute of International Studies, Tsinghua University.

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • power theory. He asserts that international politics operates in an anarchical

    system where there is no overarching government and where power is the

    ultimate arbiter. Each country exists in a Hobbesian state of nature and

    faces tremendous pressure in the competition to survive. This competitive

    pressure engenders different types of state behavior: on the one hand, it

    requires members of the international system to imitate the actions of the

    most successful states, which leads to socialization and like units; on the

    other, a rapid increase in one states power prompts others to augment

    theirs in response to it and, if this is insufficient, to ally with other states in

    order to contain the latent hegemon. Once a balance of power occurs,

    hegemonic ambitions disappear. In this sense, the anarchical international

    system resembles Adam Smiths invisible hand of the marketplace. Under

    such conditions, structural constraints emerge and patterns of behavior

    develop that either reward or punish different state actions. As self-

    interested state actors continue to pursue selfish goals under the pressure of

    this invisible hand, one unexpected by-product is a balance of power.2

    Waltzs balance of power theory posits that states are more inclined to

    practice balancing than bandwagoning strategies, and that the phenomenon

    of states balancing against others is actually a unique aspect of the anarchical

    international system. He writes [s]econdary states, if they are free to choose,

    flock to the weaker side.3 He confidently asserts that [b]alance-of-power

    politics prevail wherever two, and only two, requirements are met: that the

    order be anarchic and that it be populated by units wishing to survive.4

    Although Waltzs balance of power theory possesses certain strengths as

    regards simplicity and clarity, it is sorely lacking in explanations. The theory

    does explain why certain historical European powers with hegemonic

    ambitions (e.g., France under Louis XIV, the Napoleonic Empire, the

    Weimar Republic and Nazi Germany) ultimately failed and were destroyed,

    but only on a superficial level. While, to some extent, it explains the

    subsequent return to a balance of power on continental Europe, a deeper

    analysis reveals that each campaign against the rising hegemonic power

    involved state actions of a nonbalancing nature. Some states, for instance,

    attempted to remain neutral and stay out of the conflict, while others sided

    with the rising hegemon. In todays post-Cold War global environment, the

    United States (US) has clearly become the dominant power and a hegemonic

    force. Waltzs theory would predict other states attempting to counter US

    supremacy, thereby leading to a new balance of power in international

    politics. But this has not been the case; on the contrary, many states have

    chosen to participate in American power and primacy. Moreover, when

    reviewing the history of non-European regions, it is clear that balances of

    2 Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics, pp. 8893.3 Ibid., pp. 1267.4 Ibid., p. 121.

    196 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • power have not frequently occurred. Also, that the existence of hegemonic

    states or empires is possible within the realm of international politics. During

    Chinas Warring States (475221 BC) period the ultimate result of the seven

    powers competition was not seven powers co-existence, but the creation of a

    unified empire after the state of Qin had destroyed the other six.

    Scholars and academics continue to question and criticize Waltzs balance

    of power theory. Among them, the assessments of Stephen Walt, Randall

    Schweller, and Paul Schroeder are representative examples.

    Walt points out that when a state weighs its alliance options, it is risk-

    evaluation and the level of threat rather than power that constitute the

    deciding factor. If, for instance, one state regards another as a direct threat

    to its survival, it will endeavor to create a balance, whether or not the state in

    question possesses advantages of power and influence. If, on the other hand,

    one state does not regard another as a threat to its survival in any way,

    shape, or form, it will not typically adopt a balancing strategy, even if the

    state in question possesses advantages of power and influence. After a

    thorough analysis of the US/Soviet alliance in the Middle East during the

    Cold War, and the alliance between Southeast Asia and Europe during the

    1930s, Walt draws three conclusions: first, that states balance against

    threats, not simply power; second, that balancing strategies heavily

    outnumber those of bandwagoning in international politics; and third,

    that bandwagoning is a strategy only weak states pursue, usually under

    special circumstances and on a temporary basis. It is not a general strategy.5

    Schweller tries to bring the concept of the revisionist state back into the

    language of realism. He does not believe that the world consists of identical

    states that all seek to maintain the status quo, but that there are state quo

    states and revisionist states. The former are supporters of the current

    international system and intent upon preserving their own status and

    position within the system. They are satisfied states. The latter are losers

    under the current arrangement, or sometimes outside of it, and want to

    revise the existing system.6 Status quo states balance against states and

    alliances they perceive as a threat to their own security and/or the security of

    the system as a whole; they are security-maximizing states. Revisionist

    states, on the other hand, are primarily concerned with destroying the

    current order and making additional gains. Many, therefore, choose to

    bandwagon with revisionist great powers bent on constructing a new

    international system; they are power-maximizing states.7

    5 Stephen M. Walt, The Origins of Alliances (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1987), pp.212, 2933, and 14852.

    6 Randall L. Schweller, Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In,International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (1994), pp. 878.

    7 Randall L. Schweller, Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitlers Strategy of WorldConquest (New York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1998), Chapter 1.

    Strategic Choices 197

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • Schweller points out that Walzs analyzing the situation solely from a

    status quo-state perspective amounts to turning a blind eye to the band-

    wagoning actions of revisionist states, and as such, to the strategy of

    bandwagoning itself. On a more fundamental level, Waltz neglects to make a

    theoretical examination of bandwagoning.8 Schweller goes on to say that

    balancing usually comes at a heavy cost, while bandwagoning can often lead

    to unexpected gains. But revisionist states intent upon destroying the

    current system are willing to pay the higher cost of balancing that would

    allow them to act. Based on his analysis, however, Schweller concludes that

    bandwagoning is actually more prevalent than balancing in international

    politics.9

    Historian Paul Schroeder criticizes Waltz from a historical reality

    perspective, arguing that his theoretical generalizations are incompatible

    with events during the past few centuries of European diplomatic history.10

    Schroeder points out that balancing has not been a strategy commonly

    practiced in major international conflict since 1648 AD, while bandwagon-

    ing has been widespread among small and great powers. The main reason

    for states not pursuing a balancing strategy is its high cost. Most states

    under most circumstances simply cannot bear the burden, and opt for a less

    costly strategy. Schroeder believes that when under threat, a state has a

    number of strategies from which to choose: balancing, hiding, transcending,

    and bandwagoning. Balancing is actually the least common strategy

    adopted, and is usually a last resort, while bandwagoning and hiding are

    far more common.11

    In response to his critics, Waltz points out that theory is not meant to

    mirror reality. Forcing more empirical content into a theory would . . . turn

    a general theory into a particular explanation. Only when moving from

    international political theory to foreign-policy application one has to

    consider such matters as statesmens assessments of threats, but they do

    not thereby become part of the theory [Waltzs italics].12 Waltz recognizes

    that in a realistic environment, states may indeed pursue a strategy of

    bandwagoning, [v]ery weak states cannot make themselves secure by their

    own efforts. Whatever the risks, their main chance may be to jump on a

    bandwagon pulled by stronger states. In addition, [s]tates sometimes

    blunder when trying to respond sensibly to both internal and external

    pressures, so there may be times when the system itself breaks down.

    8 Randall L. Schweller, New Realist Research on Alliances: Refining, Not Refuting,Waltzs Balancing Proposition, American Political Science Review, Vol. 91, No. 4 (1997),pp. 9289.

    9 Randall L. Schweller, Bandwagoning for Profit, pp. 89104.10 Paul Schroeder, Historical Reality vs. Neo-Realist Theory, International Security, Vol. 19,

    No. 1 (1994), p. 115.11 Ibid., pp. 11724, 13347.12 Kenneth N. Waltz, Evaluating Theories, American Political Science Review, Vol. 91, No. 4

    (1997), p. 916.

    198 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • Waltz, however, firmly believes that if a state violates the basic rules of

    international politics, it will be punished accordingly, albeit not

    immediately.13

    Waltzs response generated even more reviews. In their analysis of the

    post-Cold War international political environment and its new settings,

    William Wohlforth, G. John Ikenberry, and Thomas Risse each criticize

    Waltzs theoretical viewpoints from the points of view of realism, liberalism,

    and constructivism.14 Certain scholars, furthermore, are dissatisfied with

    Waltzs exclusion of foreign policy from his balance of power theory.

    Hans Mouritzen, for example, argues that Waltz uses examples based on the

    results of international politics (such as the ongoing balance of power

    between states) and the actions of individual states (such as adopting a

    balancing strategy) to endorse the theory, which they do, but only from a

    status quo-state point of view. Waltz neglects to take into account

    the obvious influence of foreign policy on state strategy, so pushing the

    fairly common strategy of bandwagoning out of the explanatory bounds

    of his IR theory, into the realm of foreign policy theory, or going as far as

    to classify it as an exception. In so doing, he makes his own theory

    watertight.15

    Strategic Options in the Shadow of Hegemony

    Logically speaking, when the international system is in a state of anarchy

    with no overarching government to enforce laws, self-help becomes the

    primary means by which states survive. The pressures of conflict and an

    inherently unstable system make the strategy of balancing against states that

    have hegemonic ambitions and rapidly growing power seem reasonably

    sound. States that persistently fail to play the game according to these rules

    will eventually be eliminated. However, states operating in the international

    jungle arena are not isolated billiard balls that choose strategies based

    solely on their own circumstances. Strategic decisions are made in an

    environment of interdependence among different states, and not in a

    laboratory setting where large numbers of factors and variables can be

    controlled. For example, the length of time before a threat materializes,

    the ability of various actors to recognize this threat, the historical

    interactions between different states, and their power differentials all

    influence a states strategic behavior. Moreover, as the decision-making

    actors are limited by their own experience, history and knowledge, they

    13 Ibid., p. 915.14 See G. John Ikenberry, ed.,Meiguo Wudi: Junshi de Weilai, (America Unrivaled: the Future

    of the Balance of Power), trans. Han Zhaoying (Beijing: Beijing Daxue Chubanshe, 2005).15 Hans Mouritzen, Kenneth Waltz: A Critical Rationalist between International Politics and

    Foreign Policy, in Iver B. Neumann and Ole Waever, eds, The Future of InternationalRelations: Masters in the Making? (New York, NY: Routledge, 1997), pp. 789.

    Strategic Choices 199

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • cannot accurately predict what other states will do. For all these reasons,

    it is extremely difficult for a states foreign policy to be completely rational

    at all times, which is why it will often seek a satisfactory rather than

    maximum outcome.

    In amalgamating the viewpoints of the various scholars earlier discussed,

    this essay argues that when facing a hegemonic threat,16 states in the system

    have three strategic options from which to choose: balancing, bandwagon-

    ing, and withdrawing. In selecting the balancing strategy, a state, either on

    its own or with others, opposes the hegemonic threat through warfare,

    political coalitions, and military alliances. In selecting the bandwagoning

    strategy, a state forms political and military alliances with the hegemon or

    potential hegemon, thus joining its camp. In selecting the withdrawing

    strategy, a state joins neither side, and attempts to stay out of the conflict.

    There are various ways of pursuing a withdrawing strategy. They include: a

    states distancing itself from the hegemon and its allies, thereby hiding

    from the threat; or adopting a wait and see attitude in order to join in the

    conflict at the most opportune moment; or assuming the isolationist stance

    of keeping a safe distance and completely ignoring the struggle. In other

    words, withdrawing encompasses the strategic options external to balancing

    and bandwagoning that have been raised by various scholars.17 Taking into

    account the high costs associated with balancing and the advantages of

    bandwagoning or withdrawing in order to eliminate short-term threats, from

    a systemic perspective, the latter two strategies are much more common than

    that of balancing.

    In the next section, the main research questions and theoretical viewpoints

    of this essay will be laid out. Its focus will be on analyzing why states choose

    to adopt certain foreign policy strategies, and the factors and variables that

    influence their decision.

    Structural-Level Factors

    At the structural level, two factors play an important role: the anarchical

    nature of the international system and its polarity.

    Anarchical nature of the international system

    In Waltzs analysis, anarchy is a constant within IR. This fundamentally

    means that the international system lacks an overarching authority structure

    16 In this essay, a hegemonic threat is used to portray the hegemons or potentialhegemons with rapidly growing power who pose a threat to the system as a whole as well asto the various units in it. It is not intended to depict the unitary threat one state posesto another.

    17 See Randall L. Schweller, Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitlers Strategy of WorldConquest, Chapter 3; Robert Powell, In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies inInternational Politics (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1999), p. 156; John J.Mearsheimer, The Tragedy of Great Power Politics (New York, NY: W. W. Norton &Company, 2001), Chapter 5.

    200 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • capable of enforcing laws. Alexander Wendt, however, points out that

    anarchy is more of a variable than a constant. An anarchical system not only

    signifies the absence of a central governing institution, but also that it is

    instrumental in constructing a common structural identity or structural

    culture. Different structural identities lead to different structural cultures

    and the creation of different types of anarchical system. Under a

    Hobbesian system, states view each other as enemies, and interaction

    between them is normally characterized by warfare; under a Lockean

    system, states view each other as opponents, so warfare is a possible course

    of action in state-to-state relations but not the norm; under a Kantian

    system, states view each other as friends, and warfare is not the method of

    resolving conflict.18

    These three types of anarchical system affect a states foreign-policy

    strategy in the following fashion. First, within a Hobbesian system, the

    prisoners dilemma is dominant because states see each other as enemies.

    In the face of a hegemonic threat, constructing a balancing coalition is

    not an agreeable option because treachery, whereby a hegemon divides and

    conquers, is likely to occur. Second, within a Lockean system, creating a

    balancing coalition against hegemonic threats is less risky because states see

    each other as opponents rather than enemies. Owing, however, to differing

    perceptions of what constitutes a threat there is no effective means of

    enforcement. Balancing coalitions, therefore, often encounter collective-

    action problems, that result in inefficiency that could result in defeat at the

    hands of a hegemon.19 Third, within a Kantian system, states do not

    threaten each other because they see one another as friends, thus creating

    a secure community that does not call for internal balancing behavior.20

    When an external source threatens this secure community, all Member

    States collectively adopt a balancing strategy to oppose it.

    Polarity

    A systems polarity is defined by the apportionment of power among its

    various Member States, according to Waltz. The most common basis

    of calculation is that of the proportion of great powers in any one

    system.21 Different polarities have different affects on a states strategic

    behavior.

    18 Alexander Wendt, Guoji Zhengzhi de Shehui Lilun, (Social Theory of International Politics),trans. Qin Yaqing (Shanghai, China: Shanghai Renmin Chubanshe, 2000), pp. 31383.

    19 Regarding collective-action problems and its effects on balancing behavior, see WeiZongyou, Jitixingdong de Nanti yu Zhiheng Baquan (Balancing Hegemonic Threats:Collective-Action Problems), Guoji Guancha (International Review), No. 4 (2003),pp. 2127.

    20 Thomas Risse makes a similar point. See Thomas Risse, Ziyou Anquan Gongtongti deMeiguo Quanli, (US Power in a Liberal Security Community) in G. John Ikenberry, ed.,America Unrivaled, p. 267.

    21 Kenneth N. Waltz, The Emerging Structure of International Politics, InternationalSecurity, Vol. 18, No. 2 (1993), p. 73.

    Strategic Choices 201

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • In a uni-polar system, power is concentrated at the top, resulting in a

    hierarchical order. In the face of such a large power differential, states do

    not choose a balancing strategy lightly, as the chances of success are slim

    and likely reprisals in the form of retaliation from the hegemonic power

    would be at a cost too high to bear. On the other hand, pursuing a

    bandwagoning strategy could bring unexpected benefits from the hege-

    mon.22 Then again, if a state were to pursue a withdrawing strategy, it could

    avoid any potential conflict with the hegemon, and put some distance

    between it and them. This could well lead to an isolationist position in which

    the state focuses on its own interests and needs, on the pretext of avoiding

    contamination by an evil hegemonic force, thereby protecting its own

    prestige while projecting an image of justness.

    In a bi-polar system, the ultimate goal of two opposing super powers and

    their respective foreign policies is adoption of a balancing strategy that will

    prevent either from gaining hegemonic strength. Both sides rely not only on

    their internal strength, but also on help from friends and allies in this

    regard.23 This opens the way for other Member States of the system toward

    a bandwagoning strategy. At the same time, it is in the interests of both

    super powers to provide incentives that attract potential bandwagoners to

    their respective camps, as the ultimate aim of both powers is to be victor in

    this battle for hegemony. Middling and small powers that have no interest in

    this conflict are likely follow the withdrawing strategy, so as to ensure their

    own survival and independence. All three strategies, therefore, are employed

    in a bi-polar system. Balancing is the default strategy of both super powers,

    while other members of the system will pursue that of either bandwagoning

    or withdrawing.

    In a multi-polar system, the strategies of bandwagoning and withdrawing

    are far more common than that of balancing. Multi-polar systems are

    characterized by a relatively diffuse division of power wherein no one state

    can single handedly become the hegemon. If one state starts to manifest

    hegemonic ambitions, it can be easily defeated by the others, which makes

    the costs of balancing significantly lower.24 This does not mean, however,

    that balancing becomes the default option, as there are many factors that are

    not conducive to such a strategy. Under multi-polarity, there are too many

    poles to permit any of them to draw clear and fixed lines between allies and

    enemies and to be certain of what is happening in the system . . .Hence, there

    22 For thoughts, see William C. Wohlforth, Danjishijie Zhong de Meiguo Zhanlue,(US Strategy in a Unipolar World) in G. John Ikenberry, ed., America Unrivaled,pp. 98118.

    23 Kenneth N. Waltz, The Emerging Structure of International Politics, p. 73.24 This relates to what Barry Posen and others argue as defense prevails. For more, see Barry

    Posen, The Sources of Military Doctrine (New York, NY: Cornell University Press, 1984).

    202 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • is a tendency to pass the buck.25 In a multi-polar system, balancing

    strategies also face the collective-action problems mentioned earlier, where

    every state acts on the incentive of a free ride in the hope that others will do

    the balancing while they sit back and relax. When every state has such a

    mindset, the result is that no state, or only a small number, balances against

    the potential hegemon.

    Polarity nonetheless has only an indirect effect on a states strategic

    behavior. The polarity of a system shapes and influences it rather than

    causing it to choose one strategy over another. This is why even when

    systems have similar polarities, different states may pursue all three

    strategies of balancing, bandwagoning and withdrawing.

    Interactive-Level Factors

    Power balance

    Power balance and polarity are two different concepts. Power balance

    indicates the power differential between two or more states and their overall

    capabilities (particularly military power), their relative sizes, and their

    strengths and weaknesses. It is classified as an interactive level variable.

    Polarity, on the other hand, describes how power is organized within the

    system. Juxtaposed, power balance affects a states strategic behavior

    more directly than polarity. This is true for the following reasons. Firstly,

    there is a difference between the strategies adopted by greater and smaller

    powers. From an IR perspective, although states may not differ much in

    functionality, they do substantially in capabilities. This leads to exten-

    sive divergence as regards which strategic option a state chooses. When

    facing a hegemonic threat, for example, great powers react differently from

    small powers. As Robert Rothstein argues, the strategies of small powers

    differ in many aspects from those of great powers: first, small powers are

    rarely able to resolve a threatening situation alone and often require outside

    help; second, because they occupy only a small secure space, smaller powers

    must act with extreme caution. Sometimes, a small power has no alternative

    but to adopt a strategy that will resolve its short-term needs, even if this

    endangers its long-term security and stability.26 A great powers interests,

    however, are not confined to the survival of its own territory, but overspill

    into other regions and the security and stability of the system as a whole.

    When a hegemonic threat is perceived as endangering the entire system or

    other regions of importance to a great power, it will rise up in opposition

    25 Ted Hopf, Polarity, the OffenseDefense Balance, and War, American Political ScienceReview, Vol. 85, No. 2 (1991), p. 476.

    26 Robert L. Rothstein, Alliances and Small Powers (New York, NY: Columbia UniversityPress, 1968), pp. 246.

    Strategic Choices 203

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • and adopt a balancing strategy. Great powers will also often balance for

    reasons of prestige and reputation.

    For great powers, the costs of bandwagoning far outweigh the benefits

    because their interests are likely to contradict or clash with those of the

    potential hegemon. Bandwagoning, therefore, is not a desirable strategy. But

    this is not the case if the great power is a revisionist state that is dissatisfied

    with the current system. As Schweller argues, if the revisionist power does

    not have the strength to destroy the current international order alone, it will

    be happy to bandwagon with a stronger prospective hegemon and share in

    the creation of a new global political system. Italy has historically taken this

    road.

    For small powers, the costs of balancing are simply too great. Just one

    failure or miscalculation could mean destruction. Furthermore, small

    powers have narrow, limited interests that are generally confined to their

    own territory. Any overspill is minimal. As they are seldom overly

    concerned about prestige, withdrawing and bandwagoning are their most

    commonly adopted strategies.

    Second, there are differences in the strategies adopted by the potential

    hegemonic force and its opposition in relation to discrepancies in their

    relative power. When other factors are similar, and the power differential

    between the potential hegemon and its opposition is small, then the incentive

    to adopt a balancing strategy increases significantly, and it becomes more

    widespread. If, however, there is a significant power disparity between the

    two sides, balancing is less likely to occur. Under these circumstances,

    adopting a balancing strategy would amount to state suicide. Many states,

    therefore, tend either toward treachery or free-riding, and withdrawing and

    bandwagoning are also frequently adopted.

    Geopolitics

    Geopolitics refers to a states location and the circumstances surrounding its

    survival, and is classified as an interactive-level factor. It affects a states

    strategic behavior primarily through determining the effectiveness of its

    power projection capabilities. Kenneth Boulding, Patrick OSullivan and

    other scholars point out that in the process of transmitting power, there is a

    gradual diminishment effect, where distance is inversely proportional to the

    amount of power actually projected. For example, the greater the distance of

    power projection, the higher the costs and the less power it actually sends to

    the target; conversely, the closer the object of power projection, the lower

    the costs and the more effectively projected power.27 States will hence be

    particularly aware of increases in their neighbor states power, while not

    27 Patrick OSullivan, Dili Zhengzhi Lun: Guoji Jian de Jingzheng yu Hezuo, (Geopolitics),trans. Li Yiming et al. (Beijing: Guoji Wenhua Chuban Gongsi, 1991), pp. 112, 703;Kenneth N. Boulding, Conflict and Defense: A General Theory (New York, NY: Harperand Brothers, 1962).

    204 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • paying too much attention to those of more distant states. Furthermore, due

    to their close proximity, neighboring states are more likely to have similar

    interests and needs, which could increase the possibility of cooperation, but

    could also mean a higher probability of conflict. This could then result in

    what Walt describes as states balancing against powerful neighbors while

    ignoring the strongest states in the system as a whole.

    When other conditions are similar, geopolitics influences a states strategic

    behavior in the following fashion: when a state is far from the hegemonic

    conflict or possesses some form of unique geographic feature (such as vast

    oceans or great mountains) that provides effective defense, then the costs

    associated with power projection against it become extremely high. It is

    consequently more likely to withdraw and observe the situation from afar.

    For great powers facing a threat from neighboring states, the most common

    strategy is balancing, while for small powers in similar circumstances, the

    risks of balancing are too great. Unless they receive strong support from

    outside sources, most small states will bandwagon.

    Unit-Level Factors

    This section primarily analyses the viewpoint of state actors. All four

    variables discussed earlier: the anarchical system, polarity, power balance

    and geopolitics, must filter through the perception of the decision-makers

    prior to their influencing a states strategic behavior. Perception, at times,

    can be a correct understanding of certain events or things, but it is often a

    flawed or mistaken awareness. Robert Jervis calls this misperception. He

    points out that it does not matter whether a perception is correct or not,

    once formed, it will have lasting impact on a states strategic behavior. Once

    a person develops an image of the otherespecially a hostile image of the

    otherambiguous and even discrepant information will be assimilated to

    that image . . . If they think that a state is hostile, behaviour that others might

    see as neutral or friendly will be ignored, distorted, or seen as attempted

    duplicity.28 Jervis concludes: the roots of many important disputes about

    policies lie in differing perceptions.29 In his analysis of the European

    political and alliance situation from 1865 to 1940, Thomas Christensen notes

    that the perception of decision-makers has a huge influence on the future

    foreign policies of a state. If leaders misperceive the distribution of

    capabilities, they may stand aside at crucial junctures in a conflict, overreact

    to insignificant threats, or even assist the wrong side in a war. If leaders

    mistake stronger states for weaker ones, they may even join the side of the

    28 Robert Jervis, Perception and Misperception in International Politics (Princeton, NJ:Princeton University Press, 1976), p. 68.

    29 Ibid., p. 31.

    Strategic Choices 205

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • mighty, thereby behaving more like bandwagoners than balancers.30 During

    the Cold War, its inherent bias against Communism and fears of a domino

    effect strongly influenced US foreign policy, and lead to many avoidable

    conflicts and crises.

    When other conditions are similar, if decision-makers perceive the

    potential hegemonic force as overtly aggressive, they are likely to adopt a

    balancing strategy, because making concessions to states with an insatiable

    appetite will only lead to further greed and additional desires. Unless a state

    opposes them, it will eventually be destroyed. On the other hand, if decision-

    makers perceive the potential hegemon as benevolent or not overtly hostile,

    they are likely to adopt a withdrawing or even bandwagoning strategy. The

    reasons are simple: by not confronting the rising hegemon, a state can avoid

    antagonizing it and stirring up subsequent conflict; it can also react to the

    changing situation and possibly reap additional profits.

    In the above discussion, this essays theoretical viewpoints and assump-

    tions have been laid out. They can be summarized as follows: first, when

    facing hegemonic threats, there are three general strategies that a state can

    adopt: balancing, bandwagoning or withdrawing. Second, states generally

    react in a finitely rational manner when confronting hegemonic threats.

    After analyzing the five variables identified as influencing a states strategic

    behavior, either individually or jointly, it has been determined that, contrary

    to Waltzs belief, balancing does not become the default strategy. Many

    states continue to pursue balancing, but bandwagoning and withdrawing are

    more widespread and commonly used strategies. Third, different anarchical

    systems result in different structural reasoning. In a Hobbesian system, the

    prisoners dilemma makes balancing difficult to achieve, so bandwagoning

    and withdrawing become the prevalent strategies; in a Lockean system,

    balancing faces collective-action problems while the other two strategies of

    withdrawing and bandwagoning are also commonly adopted. Whether or

    not balancing against a hegemonic threat can succeed depends largely on the

    ability to resolve these collective-action problems. In a Kantian system,

    threats come from external rather than internal sources, and when faced

    with such external threats, states band together in secure communities as a

    means of balancing. Fourth, under conditions of similar polarity, states of

    comparable power attempt to balance each others hegemonic ambitions,

    while states of considerable power disparity, as well as weaker states that

    have no strong source of external support, have more of a tendency to

    bandwagon. Fifth, states possessing particular geographic features, such as

    island-states protected on all four sides by vast oceans, or hidden states

    protected by great mountains, or those far from the source of conflict, can

    for a certain period of time adopt a withdrawing strategy. It makes no

    30 Thomas J. Christensen, Perceptions and Alliances in Europe, 18651940, InternationalOrganization, Vol. 51, No. 1 (1997), p. 68.

    206 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • difference whether or not they are great or small powers, their geographic

    advantage affords them this option. Sixth, if a potential hegemon is

    perceived as benevolent, the chances of other states balancing against it

    decrease significantly, while bandwagoning and withdrawing are more

    widespread strategies; if a potential hegemon is perceived as aggressive and

    evil, then the likelihood of balancing rises astronomically.

    ChinaAnnexation Wars during the WarringStates Period

    Collapse of the Zhou Hierarchy and the Seven PowersCo-Existence Period

    In the early Western Zhou dynasty (C.1100C.771 BC), the Zhou Imperial

    Court established its central authority and internal hierarchy within the

    dynasty through enfeoffment and the patriarchal clan system. The Spring/

    Autumn period, however, saw the rise of feudal lords with individual

    . . . kingdoms becoming more powerful until the dynasty was shattered31

    that rendered the Zhou imperial court powerless. The initiation of all

    interactions, whether ritual or war, began to be undertaken by feudal lords

    without deference to the imperial court. In the following Warring States

    period (475221 BC), the Zhou imperial courts impotence reached its nadir.

    The King of Zhou was little more than a figurehead, incapable of curbing

    the ambitions of the various feudal lords that now barely acknowledged his

    existence. In the preceding Spring/Autumn period (770476 BC), these lords

    had, in the midst of wars with one another, rhetorically evinced symbolic

    respect for the Zhou imperial court. Commencement of the Warring States

    period, however, marked the end of even this token respect. Kingdoms

    engaged in warfare as they saw fit with no liaison whatever with the Zhou

    Court. Each lord and kingdom acted as an independent political entity

    subject to no outside authority. Their aim was to survive, expand, and

    defeat whichever kingdom got in the way. The goal was no longer that

    of hegemony among lords,32 but of eliminating any opposing kingdom.

    In Schwellers words, they were not status quo but revisionist powers

    intent on overthrowing the existing order and establishing a new hierarchy

    with themselves at the center of power. Meanwhile, the ailing Zhou imperial

    court system slid into collapse. The eminent Qing dynasty scholar Gu

    31 Liu Zehua, Zhongguo de Wangquan Zhuyi (Chinas Hegemonism) (Shanghai: ShanghaiRenmin Chubanshe, 2000), p. 3.

    32 It should be pointed out that hegemony (ba) during the SpringAutumn and WarringStates periods is different from the concept of hegemony used today. The former means toseek domination under the hierarchical order of the Zhou dynasty while still paying tributeto the Zhou Imperial Court. In this sense, competition for hegemony is for the power toregulate the internal relationships among kingdoms.

    Strategic Choices 207

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • Yanwu describes vividly the changing order as the Spring/Autumn period

    gave way to that of the Warring States:

    During the SpringAutumn period, ritual and trust still existed but the seven

    warring states no longer cared about ritual and trust; during the Spring

    Autumn period, lords still respected the Zhou Court, but the seven warring

    states no longer respected the Zhou Court; during the SpringAutumn period,

    lords still made sacrificial offerings, but the seven warring states no longer did

    that; during the SpringAutumn period, a lords family name and family tree

    were still emphasized but the seven warring states no longer cared about that;

    during the SpringAutumn period, lords still sang Zhou poems which

    represented the authority of the Zhou dynasty, but the seven warring states

    no longer did that; during the SpringAutumn period, lords still openly

    presented symbolic notice to the Zhou court but the seven warring states simply

    ignored the Zhou court. State-to-state relations became unsettling and shi

    [educated and policy advisors] often switched loyalties. All of this happened

    within 133 years.33

    Waltzs contention is that under an anarchical order, competitive pressure

    compels a state to pursue successful strategies and to emulate the behavior

    of other successful states, thereby socializing itself into the system. This

    contention is endorsed by events in the early days of the Warring States

    succession to the SpringAutumn period, which marked the start of

    hundreds of years of inter-kingdom war. A new inter-kingdom order

    emerged in which seven major powers co-existed. This is what history terms

    the Seven Powers of the Warring States period. Among the seven, Chu had

    the biggest territory, followed by Qin, Zhao, Qi, Wei, Yan, and the smallest,

    Han. The seven kingdoms persistently attacked other smaller lords in order

    to expand territory and achieve hegemonic status, but also conducted

    widespread political, economic and military reforms, their intention being

    to . . . promote what is beneficial and abolish what is harmful, enrich their

    respective kingdoms and strengthen their military power. The resultant

    internal stability facilitated due preparations for future wars within the

    ongoing hegemonic competition. Examples of reforms generated by the

    competitive wars between the Seven include those of Li Kui in Wei, Gong

    Zhonglian in Zhao, Wu Qi in Chu, Shen Buhai in Han, Zou Ji in Qi, and

    of Shang Yang in Qin. These, and others reforms gained strength for each

    kingdom and sustained the period of the Seven Powers co-existence. The

    emergence of the seven Warring States and the downfall of the Zhou

    Imperial Court indicate the existence of a multi-polar system during this

    period in Chinese history.

    33 GuYanwu,Rizhilu, Vol. 13, quoted fromYang Hua, Xianqin Liyue Wenhua (Ritual Culturein the Pre-Qin Era) (Wuhan,: Hubei JiaoyuChubanshe, 1996), p. 229.

    208 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • The Rise and Fall of Wei

    Among the seven warring states, Wei was the first to rise and declare wang

    (King) status. The Weis poor geographical location in the middle of China,

    surrounded by potentially hostile neighbours and facing war from four

    sides was a severe handicap to its hegemonic ambitions. Weis bold, far

    reaching internal reforms, however, helped it to be the first kingdom to

    emerge as a hegemonic force. Reforms, for instance, under Wei Wenhous

    (Duke Wen of Wei) governance (445396 BC) included the banning of

    nepotistic appointments and making those based on merit the law. Wei

    Prime Minister and eminent legalist Li Kui instituted wide-ranging reforms

    that lead to establishment of a centralized government that consolidated

    both the economy and the military. The Wei was indeed a rising power.

    Wei embarked on a series of expansionist wars with overtly hegemonic

    intent. Aware of its inferior military might, Weis strategy was to ally with

    the Han and Zhao kingdoms, both of whom had the same feudal lord as

    Wei, rather than advance alone. But Weis rapid rise to power appeared as a

    threat to the Han and the Zhao kingdoms, taking into account that of the

    three, Wei persistently took the biggest share of the spoils. Zhao broke away

    from its alliance with Wei, whose encroachments were also putting the three

    bigger powers the Qi, Qin, and Chu kingdoms on the alert. Matters came to

    a head in the two famous battles of Guiling and Maling.

    The Battle of Guiling

    The Battle of Guiling was fought in 353 BC. At its root was the

    dissatisfaction of Zhao, the kingdom that benefited least from the

    expansionist wars initiated by Wei, which prompted it to gain extra profit

    by attacking, Wei* Weis tributary kingdom.34 This intensified the conflict

    between Zhao and Wei,35 and in 354 BC, Zhao again attacked Wei*, forcing

    the tiny kingdom to pay tribute. This incensed Wei, which sent its army, lead

    by the well-known military leader, Pang Jun, to attack the Zhao capital

    Handan. Zhao, facing destruction, called on Qi and Chu for help.

    It was obvious to the Qi and Chu kingdoms that if Wei annexed Zhao, its

    greater power would enable it control of all central Chinaan intolerable

    prospect. As Wei had already annexed territories belonging to Qi and Chu,

    the competition between the two had become a typical zero-sum game.

    The most rational move for Qi and Chu, therefore, was to assist Zhao in

    order to prevent Weis further rise. As Wei, however, had previously

    defeated Qi and Chu on a number of occasions, engaging in direct combat

    34 In Chinese, the names of these two kingdoms are different but their English spelling is thesame. Henceforth, Wei refers to the kingdom referenced as one of the seven warring stateswhile Wei* refers to the smaller, tributary kingdom that owed allegiance to Wei.

    35 See Zhongguo Junshi Shi, Di Er JuanBinglue, Shang (Chinese Military History,Vol. 2Military Strategies, Part I) (Beijing, China: Jiefangjun Chubanshe, 1986),pp. 98102.

    Strategic Choices 209

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • with it would be risky. Qi and Chu also had their respective motivations for

    helping Zhao and checking Wei. Qi was well advised to help Zhao, because

    Weis annexation of it would directly imperil Qi interests. It was key Qi

    official, Duan Ganpeng, which raised the strategy of delaying joining in the

    Wei/Zhao battle until both sides were worn out. His reasoning was that Qis

    entering the war too early would enable Zhao to retain its capital but inflict

    negligible damage on Wei. The duke believed the better option would be to

    wait a while and then attack the southern Wei city of Xiangling. This seemed

    a relatively safe alternative, because even if the Zhao capital city were to be

    taken by Wei, the remaining Wei forces would be too exhausted to defend

    Xiangling. Handan may be lost, but Qi would benefit from a late entering

    policy by beating Wei.36 The Chu kingdom had similar motivations. On the

    one hand, Chus not entering the war could bring no benefit and would be

    costly if Wei were to annex Zhao, because it would then become powerful to

    the extent that it no longer feared the bigger Chu kingdom. The possible

    joint Wei/Qi attack on Zhao was hence not in Chus interests. Chu advisors

    suggested sending reinforcements to Zhao, sufficient to strengthen Zhao

    resistance and prolong the battle, as a show of support. At the point where

    both Wei and Zhao troops were exhausted, Chu could then move in and

    profit from the strife, and possibly annex Wei. Another possibility was that

    of letting Zhao and Wei battle it out before moving in and defeating Wei as

    a united Qi/Chu/Qin force.37

    Qis and Chus reluctance to send reinforcement troops to Zhao resulted,

    in 353 BC, in the Wei armys capture of the Zhao capital, Handan. It was at

    this expedient moment that Qi entered the war. The Qi kingdom had

    appointed Tian Ji as army commander, and eminent military strategist Sun

    Bin as military advisor on the attack on Wei to save Zhao. Chu, meanwhile,

    appointed Jingshe to lead its army in the offensive. This joint Qi/Chu

    campaign, particularly the direct military threat it constituted to the Wei

    capital city of Daliang, forced Wei to order a retreat. As the Wei army

    marched homeward through Guiling, Qi troops ambushed and defeated it.

    In the midst of battling against Qi and Chu, Wei also suffered attacks from

    the Qin kingdom, which won the battle of Yuanli, and captured the Wei

    territory of Shaoliang.38 The Battle of Guiling, thus seriously depleted Weis

    overall strength.

    36 Liu Xiang, ed., Zhanguo Ce: Qi Yi (Comments on the Warring States: Qi, Part I) (Shanghai:Shanghai Guji Chubanshe, 1985), p. 314.

    37 Liu Xiang, ed., Zhanguo Ce: Chu Yi (Comments on the Warring States: Chu, Part I),pp. 4834.

    38 Mu Zhongyue and Wu Guoqing, Zhongguo Zhanzheng Shi (Chinese War History) (Beijing:Jincheng Chubanshe, 1992), p. 276.

    210 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • The Battle of Maling

    Wei was weakened but not sufficiently so to make it relinquish its hegemonic

    ambitions. In 352 BC, Wei allied with Han to defeat a Qi army, forcing Qi to

    make peace. One year later, in order to concentrate its power and counter

    Qin expansion, Wei returned the captured Zhao capital Handan, and made

    peace with Zhao on the Zhang River, thereby halting Wei eastern military

    incursions. After making peaceful settlements with Qi and Zhao, Wei

    focused its power westward toward the Qin Kingdom. After recapturing its

    lost territories, Wei attacked the Qin city of Dingyang, a severe blow that

    forced lord Qin Xiaogong (Duke Xiao of Qin) to meet Wei Huiwang (King

    Hui of Wei) at Tong in 350 BC, and pay friendly respects and, for the time

    being, accept Weis hegemony. In 344 BC, Wei Huiwang (King Hui of Wei)

    after officially declaring himself King, accordingly built a palace, ordered

    clothes in red imperial cloth, created a nine-banner family tree, and matched

    his seven-star flag with his new, self-imposed status.39 Soon after, Wei

    forced lords of the small kingdoms of Song, Wei*, Zou, and Lu to

    participate in the Fengze Meeting, also attended by Qin heir-apparent,

    Prince Shaogong. Wei power reached its peak at this time.

    In 342 BC, using the Hans refusal to attend the Fengze Meeting as an

    excuse, Wei attacked its former ally. Unable to withstand, the Han kingdom

    asked Qi for help. War once again broke out between Qi and Wei,

    culminating in the Battle of Maling. Upon receiving the Han request for

    help, the Qi adopted tactics similar to those employed during Zhaos similar

    plight. It waited on the sidelines while Wei and Han troops fought it out

    until both sides were exhausted, and then sent in a massive army to attack

    Wei. The rationale behind this decision was that, If Han and Wei are not

    weakened by the war and we participate on the Han side, Wei will weaken us

    and Han will benefit. As Wei is determined to defeat Han, Han has no

    choice but to come to us for help. If we were to enter the war late, we could

    save Han and also avoid aggression from Wei because both armies would be

    tired out; we could thus strengthen, gain profit, and win high reputation.40

    This wait-and-see strategy exacerbated the huge power imbalance between

    the Wei and the Han that resulted in the Hans defeated in five major battles.

    In 341 BC, the Han once again asked for Qi help. By this time both the Wei

    and the Han had suffered heavy casualties, so Qi took the opportunity to

    gain both profit and reputation with the minimum of effort. Echoing its

    earlier Zhao strategy, Qi eventually entered battle as Hans ally, again with

    Tian Ji and Tian Ying as chief military commanders and Sun Bin as chief

    military advisor. Sun Bins brilliant strategies won Qi a major victory at

    the Battle of Maling, in which a hundred thousand elite Wei soldiers

    were annihilated. This constituted a mortal blow to Weis military strength.

    39 Liu Xiang, ed., Zhanguo Ce: Qi Wu (Comments on the Warring States: Qi, Part V), p. 442.40 Liu Xiang, ed., Comments on the Warring States: Qi, Part I, p. 316.

    Strategic Choices 211

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • Upon Weis defeat at Maling, the Zhao and Qin allied with the Qi with the

    intent of carving Wei up. Attacks from the front and the rear lost the Wei

    Kingdom a large amount of territory. In 340 BC, Wei was again defeated by

    Qin and its heir Yin was captured. Weis depleted might gave it no choice

    but to make friendly overtures toward Qi and also cede territory to Qin in

    the hopes it would desist in military aggression toward the Wei Kingdom.

    From this point, Wei entered into a rapid, irreversible decline.

    The strategies employed in the two main battles that caused Weis

    downfall reveal the following: First, that Zhaos and Weis bigger neighbors,

    the Qin, Qi, and Chu Kingdoms, opposed Weis hegemonic ambitions and in

    no way considered and alliance with it. They were unanimous in their intent

    to check the rise of the Wei. This demonstrates that when the power

    disparity is not overwhelming, bigger powers will consider acting to contain

    anothers attempt at hegemony. Second, from the Qi and Chu responses to

    the Zhao and Han calls for help, it seems fair to conclude that while neither

    was unwilling to stand by while Wei annexed Zhao and Han, they were also

    reluctant to pay too high a price for containing Wei. The Qi and Qu both

    decided to wait until the strength of Wei and Han/Zhao had begun to flag

    before entering the war, thereby gaining the maximum advantage. This

    demonstrates that no matter how much bigger powers may oppose and seek

    to balance out a rising hegemon, they may nonetheless avoid responsibility

    and delay active participation in opposing it. Third, that during the two wars

    between Qi and Wei, the Qin Kingdom, most powerful state in the west, also

    chose to wait-and-see until it became apparent who the winner would be,

    at which point Qin entered the war to its maximum advantage. The Chu

    strategy, in turn, was similar to that of Qin.

    When faced with complex conflicts, and if circumstances permit, even big

    players in the system will adopt a wait-and-see approach because there are

    many sound reasons for doing so. Fourth, these two battles also show that

    when facing a hegemonic threat, states, for a variety of reasons such as

    geographic location and power status, choose from among a number of

    possible strategies. In dealing with the Wei hegemonic ambitions, some

    states opted for balancing, while others chose to withdraw or bandwagon.

    There was no default strategy as the states concerned used all three strategies

    as the circumstances dictated.

    The Rise of Qin, and the Hezong and Lianheng Movements

    The rise of Qin

    The Qin Kingdom was in the west, neighbor to the Shu and Di peoples, and

    regarded as less civilized by those in central China than themselves. Until the

    early Warring States period, Qin was relatively backward as regards its

    political, economic and cultural affairs and regarded as inferior by the six

    212 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • other powers.41 But after reforms implemented by Qin Xiangong (Duke

    Xian of Qin) and Qin Xiaogong (Duke Xiao of Qin), Qin power began

    to grow. When Qin Xiaogong (337311 BC) took the throne, he appointed

    Shang Yang, the foremost legalist, to guide reforms. They included

    cultivating farmland, establishing a county system, rewarding military

    accomplishment, and implementing a strict legal code. The reforms helped

    to consolidate Qin power. During the Guiling and Maling battles previously

    mentioned, Qins shrewd move in belatedly intervening brought it more

    territory and other benefits at Wei expense. Qin forced the weakened Wei to

    cede to it western portions of the Yellow River, thereby giving Qin access to

    an extremely favorable geographic position. The balance of power between

    the two gradually shifted in Qins favor until Qins power, especially in the

    military field, exceeded that of Wei.42

    When Qin Huiwenwang (King Huiwen of Qin 337311 BC) became king,

    he continued Shang Yangs reform policies, notably the solicitation and

    appointment of officials based on merit rather than family connections. The

    Qin government hailed and rewarded military accomplishment; families, no

    matter how wealthy, that had achieved none were held in contempt. Qins

    increasing power lead, in 325 BC, to its becoming the third kingdom, after

    Wei and Qi, to name itself King. The Qin then focused on eastern and

    central China in its bid for hegemony.

    Qins hegemonic ambitions became obvious during the late years of Qin

    Xiaogongs rule. In 340 BC, reformer Shang Yang told Qin Xiaogong, Qin

    and Wei are natural competitors, the Wei like an illness in Qins belly.

    Sooner or later, either Wei will annex Qin or Qin Wei. Shang Yangs

    suggested strategy was that of Qin first weakening Wei, forcing it to move

    east, thereby winning Qin the west bank of the Yellow River and the most

    advantageous geographic position. Qin could then pursue an expansionist

    route eastward and eventually become the new hegemon.43 Qins strategic

    approach in later years was exactly that of Shang Yangs design.

    Qins repeated incursions on Wei territory, and Qin Huiwenwangs

    declaring himself King, exposed its hegemonic ambitions. This was a great

    cause for concern among the six other kingdoms. Hence, new approaches

    geared toward collectively containing Qin emerged in the form of the

    hezong policy. Qin, under Prime Minister Zhang Yis guidance, responded

    by actively pursuing a lianheng policy. This marked a new period of

    warfare, competition, alliance, and betrayal among the Warring States.

    41 Sima Qian, ShijiQin Benji (Historical Recordthe Kingdom of Qin) (Beijing: TaihaiChubanshe, 2002), p. 30.

    42 Lin Jianming, Qinshi Gao (History of Qin) (Shanghai: Shanghai Renmin Chubanshe, 1981),p. 196.

    43 Sima Qian, ShijiShangjun Liezhuan (Historical RecordThe Story of Master Shang),p. 632.

    Strategic Choices 213

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • The origins of the Hezong and Lianheng movements

    Qins rise posed dual challenges to the other six kingdoms. One was a geo-

    political challenge. Qins rise was quite different from that of Wei because

    Qin had a much larger population and territory (especially after Wei gave

    Qin its seven hundred li territory west of the Yellow River44), and so was a

    major power. Another point of departure from Weis rise was that of its

    being surrounded with neighboring potential enemies, while the Qin

    Kingdom in the relatively isolated western parts of China bordered the

    three main powers Chu, Han and Wei on just one side. All of Qins other

    neighbors were small kingdoms or tribes that in no way challenged it. Hence,

    any move to expand eastward did not unduly expose the Qin flanks. Also,

    Weis ceding of the Yellow River territories to Qin made the kingdoms to the

    east vulnerable to Qin attack as they had no natural defensive barriers. Qins

    eastward military expansion was thus as easy as picking fruits out of a bag.

    Wei and Han, Qins two closest neighbors did not have the military strength

    necessary to counter Qin, especially the Wei Kingdom, which was at its

    lowest ebb at this point. In effect, the combined strength of Wei and Han

    could not match Qin power, which, overall, presented a serious geo-political

    challenge to the four other kingdoms.

    Second, Qin encroachments posed a cultural challenge. Other than Chu in

    the south, all other six kingdoms originated in the Zhou imperial court

    system and shared the rituals and musical traditions associated with the

    Zhou dynasty. Qin was only marginally affected by the central plains

    culture, having been far more greatly influenced by the less refined traditions

    of the small kingdoms and tribes that were its western neighbors.

    Consequently, most central and eastern kingdoms looked down upon Qin.

    The Qin rise, therefore, not only constituted a military threat but also one to

    the other states cultural identity. The book, Zhanguo Ce (Comments on the

    Warring States), mentions the strong aversion to the Qin kingdom on the

    part of the central kingdoms, as well as of the southern kingdom of Chu,

    which acted as an outsider during the SpringAutumn period, based on

    differences in cultural identity. An example of this cultural disdain is that of

    the famous shuoke (lobbyist), Su Qins persuading Chu to join the coalition

    against Qin because: Qin is a tigerwolf (beast) state and has ambitions to

    dominate the world. Qin is public enemy number one in the world, and those

    wanting to win Qin favor by giving it land are only helping the enemy.45 To

    Su Qin, Qin was a coarse, vulgar kingdom, uncivilized, greedy, and alien to

    those whose cultures had originated in the Zhou Dynasty. The king of Chu

    agreed, Qin, a tigerwolf kingdom, is not trustworthy.46 Xinling, the

    44 According to MengziLianghuiwang Zhangju Shang (MenciusWords of King Lianghui),This 700 hundred li territory now belongs to Qin.

    45 Liu Xiang, ed., Comments on the Warring States: Chu, Part I, p. 503.46 Ibid., p. 503.

    214 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • famous Wei lord, persuaded the king of Wei not to join Qin in its attack on

    Han because: Qin is backward and has a greedy heart, is untrustworthy and

    does not respect rituals and ethics. As long as there is benefit to be had, Qin

    would not hesitate to harm its relatives and brothers, as would not a savage.

    All people know this.47 These comments were obviously based on a

    fundamental bias toward the Qin, and as such were greatly exaggerated.

    They nonetheless indicate that many lords during the Warring States period

    regarded Qin as an alien kingdom that posed a threat to the Chinese central

    plains culture, regardless of the cultures inexorable decline in the other

    kingdoms.

    This double-headed Qin challenge gave rise to the hezong concept. Hezong

    had two strands, according to historical records. One took a geographical

    perspective, based on Qins being in the west, while Han, Zhao, and

    Wei were at the center, Yan was in the north, Chu in the south, and Qi was

    in the east. The locations of these six Warring States enabled them to form

    a vertical link from north to south, also known as a hezong, in opposi-

    tion to the Qin.48 The second hezong strand was that of an alliance

    among the weaker powers, Han, Zhao, and Wei as well as Yan and Chu, in

    order to contain the common enemy, the powerful Qin. This signified a

    belief in the weaker powers uniting to attack one powerful kingdom49

    strategy, one that seems consistent with that of balancing, as described

    in this essay.

    As Wei shared a border with Qin, it was periodically attacked by the

    powerful kingdom and needed to unite with Han and Zhao in resisting Qin

    expansionism and ensuring its own security and survival. With this intent,

    Wei began to consolidate its relationship with Han and Zhao, pro-actively

    pursuing a hezong policy. In 325 BC, Weihuiwang (King Hui of Wei) met

    with Hanweihou (Duke Wei of Han) (332312 BC) and respectfully

    acknowledged him as king. Later the same year, the King of Han paid a

    visit to Wei and both kings brought their heirs to meet the new Duke of

    Zhao (who later became the King of Zhao, named Zhaowulingwang). These

    three, originally Jin vassal, lords after a half centurys worth of battles and

    mutual distrust, thus once again formed a coalition. Wei also actively

    pursued a closer relationship with Qi and met with Qiweiwang (King Wei of

    Qi) on a number of occasions. In 323 BC, a Wei military leader named

    Gongsun Yin, who had originally been a Qin military officer, established the

    five-king alliance,50 which was the first to recognize the lords of Yan, Zhao

    and the smaller kingdom of Zhongshan as Kings. The three kings

    47 Liu Xiang, ed., Zhanguo Ce: Wei San (Comments on the Warring States: Wei, Part III),p. 869.

    48 Liu Xiang, ed., Comments on the Warring States: Qin, Part I, pp. 789.49 See HanfeiziWudu.50 Liu Xiang, ed., Zhanguo Ce: Zhongshan Ce (Comments on the Warring States: the Kingdom

    of Zhongshan), pp. 11704.

    Strategic Choices 215

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • subsequently banded together in an alliance with those of Wei and Han to

    counter the rising power of Qin.

    Upon initiation of the hezong movement, Zhang Yi, the Qin prime

    minister, launched the lianheng strategy counter to it. Although diame-

    trically opposed to hezong, lianheng also had a two-fold geographical/

    alliance perspective. Lianheng denoted coalition and coordinated actions

    among Qin in the west and all kingdoms in the east, thereby forming a

    horizontal or heng51 link. From an alliance perspective, lianheng was the

    manner in which Qin persuaded one of the six other kingdoms to break out

    of its coalition with Qin enemies; it was a policy of divide and conquer

    whereby the one powerful kingdom attacks all the weaker powers.52 The

    policy was one of luring one of the other six kingdoms into the Qin camp by

    means of perceived shared-interests and potential rewards. The concept of

    lianheng bears obvious similarities to the strategy of bandwagoning, as

    described in this essay.

    The purpose of Zhang Yis lianheng policy was to disrupt the hezong

    movement. This would clear the way for Qin to conquer the other states, one

    by one, and finally achieve hegemony. In 323 BC, Zhang Yi met with chief

    officials from Qi and Chu, and tried to isolate Wei by sabotaging its

    diplomatic efforts at hezong. The same year, Chu attacked Wei and occupied

    eight of its cities. Qin had occupied the Wei cities of Quwo and Pingzhou in

    322 BC, and had attacked Han and taken the Han city of Yan in 319 BC.

    Wei bent under this persistent Qin encroachment and appointed Zhang Yi as

    the new Wei new prime minister, swearing allegiance, for the time being, to

    Qin.53 Zhang Yis divide and conquer policy of lianheng thus achieved its

    first success.

    Qins aggressive behavior and Zhang Yis strategy of forcing Wei to pay

    tribute to Qin and then making others follow suit was not well received by

    the other Warring States.54 In 319 BC, Weihuiwang died and Weixiangwang

    (King Xiang of Wei) became king. Qi, Chu, Yan, Zhao, and Han collectively

    mobilized and supported the appointment as prime minister of a hezong

    advocate, Gongsun Yan, who ousted Zhang Yi and sent him back to Qin.

    The next year, Gongsun Yan helped organize the first anti-Qin coalition

    composed of five kingdoms (Chu, Yan, Zhao, Han, and Wei) with

    Chuhuaiwang (King Huai of Chu) at its head. However, this highly

    publicized event had very little actual effect. Although Chu was leader, it

    sent no troops to the planned military campaigns against Qin. Yan from the

    north also failed to send troops. Only the three kingdoms of Wei, Han and

    Zhao actually attacked Qin. As the five powers failed to unite and cooperate

    51 Liu Xiang, ed., Comments on the Warring States: Qin, Part I, p. 79.52 See HanfeiziWudu.53 Lin Jianming, History of Qin, p. 239.54 Sima Qian, ShijiZhang Yi Liezhuan (Historical Recordthe Story of Zhang Yi),

    pp. 6445.

    216 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • effectively, their forces were easily defeated by Qin troops. The following

    year, Qin defeated a large Han army at Xiuyu and slaughtered eighty

    thousand soldiers. Thus the much heralded five kingdom assault campaign

    against the Qin ended in failure.

    The struggles between Lianheng and Hezong, and the fall of Chu and Qi

    The failure of the five kingdom assault campaign and Qins victory at

    Xiuyu shifted the power disparity further in Qins favor. The Qin discerned

    intrinsic difficulties and irresolvable problems in the hezong strategy. The

    Qinhuiwang (King Hui of Qin) once said, feudal lords cannot act alone just

    like a chicken cannot survive alone,55 but as Zhang Yi also pointed out, if

    parents and children have disputes over financial interests, how could five

    different kingdoms not? From that point of view, Su Qins hezong policy

    could not succeed.56 Zhang Yis analysis bears striking resemblance to the

    Hobbesian anarchical system, whereby the kingdoms pursuing the hezong

    policy faced the prisoners dilemma. Even brothers have disputes over

    economic interests, so it should come as no surprise that six kingdoms each

    with its own needs and ambitions, find it extremely difficult to trust one

    another.

    The current favorable conditions strengthened the Qin resolve to expand

    eastward. In 316 BC, when its southern neighbor, Bashuguo, fell into

    internal turmoil, Qin quickly took the opportunity to annex it as a means of

    strengthening its flanks, thereby doubling its territory.57 As Bashuguo

    bordered Chu and was upstream of a major Chu river, Qin gained strategic

    offensive river access to Chu. In this sense, taking Bashuguo meant Qin

    could now take over Chu and then the world.58 This move further

    strengthened Qin and its strategic positioning.

    Faced with the increasing power of Qin and its obvious attempts to

    expand eastwards, owing to self-interest, the six other kingdoms failed to

    cooperate and counter Qins ambitions, preferring to engage in their own

    private warfare, thereby draining one anothers military strength. In 314 BC,

    when Yan fell into internal turmoil, Qi attacked it and killed the Yan king.

    Athough Yan eventually drove out the Qi army, it was seriously weakened.

    The kingdom of Zhongshan took this opportunity also to attack Yan and

    regained some territory.59 While Qi, Yan and Zhongshan were busy fighting,

    Qin pursued its plans to expand eastward. It soon occupied the Wei cities of

    Jiao and Quwo and in a battle at Anmen, defeated a Han army. Worn down

    55 Liu Xiang, ed., Comments on the Warring States: Qin, Part I, p. 92.56 Sima Qian, Historical Recordthe Story of Zhang Yi, p. 644; also see Liu Xiang, ed.,

    Zhanguo Ce: Wei Yi (Comments on the Warring States: Wei, Part I), p. 793.57 Bai Shouyi, ed., Zhongguo Tongshi, Di San Juan (A History of China, Vol. 3) (Shanghai:

    Shanghai Renmin Chubanshe, 1994), pp. 51920.58 Chang Ju, Huayang Guozhi (History of Huayang).59 Yang Kuan, History of the Warring States Period, p. 328.

    Strategic Choices 217

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • by Qins unrelenting attacks, the Han and Wei had no choice but to

    bandwagon with Qin. The three formed an alliance.60

    Qin having annexed Bashuguo and subdued Han and Wei, of the

    remaining major kingdoms only Qi in the east and Chu in the south could

    match its power. Qis victory over the Yan made it powerful enough, in

    alliance with Chu, to take the city of Quwo from Qin. Qinhuiwang (King

    Hui of Qin) wanted to attack Qi,61 but Qi and Chus having long ago formed

    an alliance62 presented an obstacle, and Qi was also geographically distant

    from Qin. If the Qin sent troops to attack Qi, Chu could strike them from

    the rear, putting Qin under attack from both front and back. So Qin

    adopted the lianheng policy toward Chu, manipulating it in an attempt to

    break the Qi-Chu alliance.

    The Qin Prime Minister, Zhang Yi, used six hundred li of territory as an

    incentive for Chu to break its alliance with Qi. It was a ploy that worked in

    the same way as did that of Chuhuaiwang (328299 BC). Chu took the bait

    and broke away from the Qi alliance, leaving itself isolated and vulnerable.

    Qin subsequently attacked it, and took over 600 li of territory in the

    Hanzhong area, thereby linking the old Bashuguo lands with Qins original

    territory. This provided a strong material base and strategic position for

    Qins eastward expansion strategy.

    Chus weakened state left only Qi with sufficient strength to check Qin.

    But at the time Qin attacked Chu, Qi united with Wei and Han, two

    kingdoms that constantly fell under Qin assault, and initiated a war against

    Chu and Qin. Armies from the three kingdoms first attacked and defeated

    Chu in 301 BC and in 298296 BC attacked Qin and occupied its [capital?]

    of Hanguguan, forcing Qin to negotiate a peace deal in which it returned

    former Han and Wei territories. This development indicates that although

    Qin was powerful, when other kingdoms united they were able to counter its

    hegemonic ambitions. The problem was that other kingdoms were not

    sincere in their efforts to cooperate, and often engaged in military action

    based on little more than petty jealousies. Some were even willing to

    bandwagon with Qin.

    In order to continue its eastward expansion strategy, gradually conquering

    the middle lands between Qin and Qi, and also break the new alliance

    between Qi, Han and Wei, Qin began making overtures to Qi. A recent

    internal power struggle, meanwhile resulted in Qi Prime Minister Meng

    Chang, who had advocated containing Qin, being dismissed and replaced

    60 Sima Qian, ShijiWeishijia (Historical Recordthe Family of Wei), p. 534; Sima Qian,ShijiHan shijia (Historical Recordthe Family of Han), pp. 53940.

    61 Liu Xiang, ed., Zhanguo Ce: Qin Er (Comments on the Warring States: Qin, Part II), p. 133.62 Pei Monong, Chunqiu Zhanguo Waijiao Qunxing (Leaders and Heroes of the Spring

    Autumn and Warring States Periods) (Chongqing: Chongqing Chubanshe, 1998), p. 501.

    218 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • with a Qin man, Wudafu Luli.63 Qiminwang (King Min of Qi) (300284 BC)

    was keen to annex the neighboring small kingdom of Song, and on this basis

    responded positively to Qins approaches. In 295 BC, Qi and Qin resumed

    friendly relations. After successfully breaking the Qi alliance with Han and

    Wei, Qin, true to form, sent troops to attack the two weaker states of Han

    and Wei. In 294 BC, Qin defeated a Han/Wei coalition army at Yinque,

    slaughtering two hundred and forty thousands soldiers64another heavy

    blow to these two small kingdoms. From 292 to 289 BC, Qin continued its

    relentless assault on Han and Wei. In 290 BC, Wei was forced to give up 400

    li of territory in the eastern river area to Qin who also exacted 200 li of

    territory in Wusui from Han.65 Qins lianheng policy was once again

    tremendously successful.

    Qins successful application of the lianheng strategy that so devastated the

    kingdoms of Han and Wei further stimulated the kingdoms lust for

    hegemony in central China. A turn of events occurred in 288 BC, when

    Qinzhaowang (King Zhao of Qin) (306251 BC), no longer satisfied with the

    title of King, formally declared himself Emperor (di) in the city of Yiyang.

    The Qin Prime Minister Weiran, meanwhile, went to Qi and respectfully

    referred to Qiminwang (King Min of Qi) (300284 BC) as the eastern

    Emperor (di). Thereafter, the two kingdoms of Qin and Qi jointly attacked

    Zhao. This action made plain Qins hegemonic ambitions as the Qi/Qin

    coalition posed a major threat to Wei, Han, Zhao as well as Yan. The policy

    of hezong was once again raised. By this time, however, Han and Wei had

    been so greatly weakened that they were incapable of organizing a new anti-

    Qin alliance. Yan, led by the very capable lord Yanzhaowang (King Zhao of

    Yan), gradually returned to a position of power but was unable to manage

    the situation alone. But at the same time, the Yan had not forgotten Qis

    earlier invasion and occupation of its lands, and sought revenge.66

    In Zhao, a new king named Zhaowulingwang (King Wuling of Zhao)

    (325299 BC) took the throne, and began a series of bold military reforms

    that strengthened the kingdom. Then Zhao took a chance during the Qin/Qi

    and Han/Wei wars to annex the medium sized kingdom of Zhongshan in

    the years 300296 BC. During this time, Zhao conquered large areas to its

    northwest that had belonged to the Hu people, thus doubling its own

    territory. The kingdom of Zhao was hence a formidable barrier to Qins

    further eastward expansion during the mid-late Warring States period.67

    63 Sima Qian, ShijiMengchangjun Liezhuan (Historical Recordthe Story of Master MengChang), pp. 6634.

    64 Sima Qian, ShijiQin Benji (Historical Recordthe Kingdom of Qin), p. 32.65 Sima Qian, ShijiWeishijia (Historical Recordthe Family of Wei), p. 534; Sima Qian,

    Historical Recordthe Family of Han, p. 540.66 Sima Qian, ShijiYanzhaogong Shijia (Historical Recordthe Family of Yanzhaogong),

    pp. 45960.67 Gao Rui, Zhongguo Shanggu Junshishi (Ancient Military History of China) (Beijing: Junshi

    Kexue Chubanshe, 1995), p. 415.

    Strategic Choices 219

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • Zhao was the most adept kingdom at implementing the hezong strategy

    to counter Qin expansion. Li Dui, a capable politician from Zhao, began

    communicating with Han, Wei and other kingdoms that felt threatened by

    Qin. Discussions about a new anti-Qin movement proceeded.

    Meanwhile, Su Qin, the eminent hezong advocate, arrived in Qi via Yan

    and persuaded Qiminwang to give up the title of Emperor and cooperate

    with Yan, Han, Wei, and Zhao in forming a new hezong to counter Qin

    aggression. Qi, at Su Qins urging, reversed its decision to join Qin in

    attacking Zhao and Qiminwang gave up the title of Emperor. The Qi also

    authorized Su Qin to engage in diplomacy with the other kingdoms of Han,

    Wei and Zhao with a view to forming an alliance against the Qin.

    In 287 BC, a new five kingdom anti-Qin alliance was formed, comprising

    the Qi, Han, Zhao, Wei and Yan. The motivation, however, for many

    participants in this coalition was purely that of self-interest and had nothing

    to do with the common good. For example, Qis participation was motivated

    by the intent to annex the small kingdom of Song, weakening the Qin being

    a lesser objective. Yans implicit goal was that of disrupting the relationship

    between Qi and Qin and Han/Wei/Zhao. Yan used Song as bait for Qi,

    whose aggressive moves toward it made Qi the new target of joint action.

    Yan thus got revenge on Qi for its past invasion and occupation of it. The

    ostensibly anti-Qin kingdom of Zhao was also pragmatic as regards the Qin

    issue. There were Zhao political forces that actually advocated allying with

    Qin in a joint attack on Qi. The Zhao Prime Minister, Li Dui, was also

    amenable to collaborating with Qin in an attack on Wei, as this would fulfill

    the Zhao desire to avenge past indignities suffered at Wei hands.68 Han and

    Wei were primarily interested in countering Qin but had limited strength and

    little influence. So it was that the various Warring States acted according

    to their own self-interest, with no regard for common needs. There was

    consequently common mistrust among the seven states. Throughout the

    Warring States period, coalitions were temporary and alliances were

    frequently switched; yesterdays friend could become todays enemy. Also,

    each kingdom wanted to annex the rest (in this sense they could all be

    considered revisionist states), which meant that mistrust and betrayal were

    commonplace. These opportunistic tendencies restricted the likelihood of

    successful cooperations. Every kingdom that participated in a coalition

    became a prisoner, cognizant that the other members would not think twice

    about using them as a free-ride or betraying them by making clandestine

    deals with the enemy.

    Due to the mistrust and suspicion between coalition partners, when the

    combined five-kingdom army arrived at the cities of Rongyang and

    Chenggao, it halted but did not engage in battle with Qin troops. Pressure

    68 Liu Xiang, ed., Zhanguo Ce: Zhao Si (Comments on the Warring States: Zhao, Part IV),p. 727.

    220 Wei Zongyou

    Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 1, 2006, 195229

    by guest on October 30, 2014

    http://cjip.oxfordjournals.org/D

    ownloaded from

  • from the five-kingdom army forced Qin to abandon the title of Emperor

    and return captured territory to the Wei and Zhao. This indicates that the

    five kingdoms remaining united made them capable of deflecting Qins

    hegemonic ambitions and ensuring their own security.

    However, two years after this anti-Qin coalition, the legitimacy and

    strength Qi had acquired as a member of the alliance emboldened the

    kingdom to begin its own war against Song, and soon after annex the small

    kingdom. Qi was also intent on taking the Huaibei region from Chu,

    expanding westward into Han, Wei, and Zhao lands, and eventually

    overthrowing and becoming ruler of the symbolic Zhou court, with the

    power to force all remaining feudal lords, such as those from Zou and Lu, to

    profess allegiance to Qi.69 Its hegemonic ambitions engendered Qi enemies

    on all sides and caused concern and anger among the other kingdoms,

    particularly those in central China. There was particularly bad blood

    between Yan in the north and Qi, originating in Qis past invasion and

    occupation of Yan. Yan initiated talks among itself, Zhao, Wei, and Chu

    with a view to their uniting to counter Qi expansionism. Qis annexation of

    Song directly threatened Han, Wei, and Zhao because of their close

    geographic proximity to it. The Zhao Prime Minister, Li Dui, had long been

    interested in the rich Song commercial city of Dingtao, which Zhao had

    previously attacked under Wei70 auspices. Zhao, along with Wei, therefore,

    responded positively to Yans call for an alliance. As internal struggles

    among the six other kingdoms were beneficial to the Qin strategy of divide

    and conquer, Qin voluntarily led the coalition against Qi.71 Thus, the nature

    and target of the hezong coalition shifted from that of five-kingdom anti-Qin

    to five-kingdom anti-Qi.

    In 284 BC, the five kingdoms of Qin, Han, Zhao, Wei, and Yan completed

    a series of diplomatic moves toward a five-kingdom army attack on Qi

    which devastated the kingdom and from which it never really recovered.

    This aided Qins eastward expansion strategy and achieved an important

    breakthrough as it signified that the two kingdoms with sufficient power to

    block Qin, Chu, and Qi, were greatly weakened. The central kingdoms of

    Han and Wei, because of their