221
Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity market returns An Australian study Stefan Mero Bachelor of Economics (Hons) 2016 This thesis is presented for the degree of Master of Philosophy at The University of Western Australia Business School Accounting and Finance

Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

market returns

An Australian study

Stefan Mero

Bachelor of Economics (Hons)

2016

This thesis is presented for the degree of Master of Philosophy at

The University of Western Australia

Business School Accounting and Finance

Page 2: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity
Page 3: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity
Page 4: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity
Page 5: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

Abstract

Understanding macroeconomic risk is a fundamental aspect of economic and financial

decision-making. More recently, attention has turned to identifying macroeconomic

variables as risk factors (Chen, Ross & Roll 1986; Chan, Karceski & Lakonishok

1998; Flannery & Protopapdakis 2002).

Most research, to date, has focused on the relationship between macroeconomic data

values and stock market prices over long time horizons. This study extends the

existing Australian stock market based literature by examining the relationship

between macroeconomic news and stock market returns/return volatility at daily a

level, in an event study framework. The study covers the period before, during and

after the Global Financial Crisis in 2008 to determine whether the effects of news

differ during different phases of stock market activity.

In the stock market boom leading up to the Crisis, higher than expected overnight

cash rate news was found to have a negative impact on stock returns that disappears

in the subsequent period of subdued stock market price growth after the Crisis.

Macroeconomic fundamentals - such as unemployment, the consumer price index and

real gross domestic product - matter only after the onset of the Crisis. Over the whole

period, consumer sentiment and real gross domestic product surprises are the only

macroeconomic variables to impact stock market volatility.

Page 6: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 i

Contents

1 Introduction .................................................................................................... 7

1.1 Theoretical, Empirical and Industry Perspectives ............................................ 7

1.2 Thesis Contribution ........................................................................................ 10

1.3 Thesis Structure .............................................................................................. 14

2 Literature Review ......................................................................................... 16

2.1 Theoretical Background ................................................................................. 16

2.2 Australian Studies ........................................................................................... 20

2.2.1 Australian Stock Market Returns ................................................................... 20

2.2.2 Australian Stock Market Return Volatility ..................................................... 30

2.2.3 The Australian Stock Market and Efficient Market Hypothesis .................... 31

2.3 Foreign Studies ............................................................................................... 35

2.3.1 Foreign Stock Markets and Macroeconomic Surprises .................................. 35

2.3.2 Business Cycles and Macroeconomic Factor relationships with Stock

Markets ........................................................................................................... 41

2.4 Conclusions from the Literature ..................................................................... 42

3 Hypothesis ..................................................................................................... 46

3.1 Unemployment ............................................................................................... 49

3.2 Balance of Trade............................................................................................. 52

3.3 Retail Sales ..................................................................................................... 54

3.4 Producer Price Index ...................................................................................... 56

3.5 Consumer Price Index .................................................................................... 58

3.6 Real Gross Domestic Product ......................................................................... 60

3.7 Overnight Cash Rate....................................................................................... 62

3.8 Consumer Sentiment ...................................................................................... 64

4 Methodology .................................................................................................. 67

4.1 Returns ............................................................................................................ 67

4.2 Surprises (Unexpected Components of Announcements) .............................. 67

4.3 Control Variables............................................................................................ 68

4.4 Returns Estimation ......................................................................................... 70

4.5 Volatility Estimation ...................................................................................... 72

5 Data ................................................................................................................ 75

5.1 Stock Market Indices ...................................................................................... 75

5.1.1 Stationarity of Stock Returns .......................................................................... 79

Page 7: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 ii

5.2 Macroeconomic Surprises .............................................................................. 80

5.2.1 Forecasts ......................................................................................................... 80

5.2.2 Announcements .............................................................................................. 82

5.2.3 Surprises ......................................................................................................... 84

5.3 Control Variables .......................................................................................... 102

6 Results .......................................................................................................... 110

6.1 Continuous Model Results ........................................................................... 110

6.2 Dummy Variable Based Model Results ....................................................... 115

6.3 Continuous Model Results: Pre- and Post-Global Financial Crisis .............. 120

6.4 Dummy Variable Based Model Results: Pre- and Post-Global Financial

Crisis ............................................................................................................. 125

6.5 Robustness Tests .......................................................................................... 132

6.6 Summary and Discussion of Results ............................................................ 133

7 Conclusion ................................................................................................... 141

7.1 Thesis Contribution ...................................................................................... 141

7.2 Main Results ................................................................................................. 142

7.3 Limitations and Possible Extensions ............................................................ 147

7.4 Final Conclusion ........................................................................................... 149

8 References.................................................................................................... 152

9 Appendices .................................................................................................. 163

9.1 Appendix A – Structure of Macroeconomic Announcement Data and

Dates ............................................................................................................. 163

9.2 Appendix B – Model Fitting ......................................................................... 166

9.2.1 Fitting ARMA for Stock Market Return Modelling ..................................... 166

9.2.2 Fitting GARCH/EGARCH for Stock Market Return and Time Varying

Volatility Modelling ..................................................................................... 168

9.3 Appendix C – Robustness Tests ................................................................... 171

9.3.1 All Ordinaries Index Based Regressions ...................................................... 171

9.3.2 Single Macroeconomic Variable Regressions .............................................. 184

9.3.3 Alternate Break-Point Regressions ............................................................... 210

Page 8: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 iii

Tables

Table 1 Australian Literature Review Summary ................................................ 32

Table 2 Foreign Literature Review Summary .................................................... 39

Table 3 ASX 200 Index Total Daily Returns –Summary Statistics ................... 78

Table 4 All Ordinaries Index Total Daily Returns – Summary Statistics .......... 79

Table 5 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Unit Root Tests - No Drift or Trend ........... 80

Table 6 Money Market Services Consensus Macroeconomic Forecasts ........... 81

Table 7 Other Macroeconomic Forecasts ........................................................... 82

Table 8 Macroeconomic Announcement Values ............................................... 83

Table 9 Summary Statistics for Macroeconomic Surprises ............................... 84

Table 10 Real GDP Growth – ADF Test and Akaike Information Criterion ....... 95

Table 11 Consumer Sentiment – ADF Tests and Akaike Information Criteria . 100

Table 12 Continuous EGARCH model results based on full period sample ..... 111

Table 13 Dummy variable EGARCH model results based on full period

sample ................................................................................................. 116

Table 14 Continuous EGARCH model results: Pre- and Post-GFC .................. 120

Table 15 Dummy variable EGARCH model results: Pre/Post-GFC ................. 125

Table 16 Summary of Results by Macroeconomic Variable.............................. 132

Table 17 Summary of Results Surviving Robustness Tests ............................... 133

Table 18 Summary of Results - Returns............................................................. 151

Table 19 Summary of Results - Return Volatility .............................................. 151

Table 20 Macroeconomic Announcement Date Structure ................................. 164

Table 21 Raw Macroeconomic Announcement Data Series Structure .............. 164

Table 22 AIC - All Ordinaries Total Returns ARMA Regression ..................... 166

Table 23 Q-Statistics on ARMA Model Squared Standardised Residuals......... 167

Table 24 ARCH LM Test on ARMA Squared Residuals .................................. 167

Table 25 Continuous Model using All Ordinaries Index based Returns ............ 172

Table 26 Dummy Variable Model using All Ordinaries Index .......................... 175

Table 27 Continuous Model using All Ordinaries Index: Pre- and Post-GFC ... 178

Table 28 Dummy Variable Model using All Ordinaries Index: Pre- and Post-

GFC ..................................................................................................... 181

Table 29 Unemployment Dummy Variable based Regression: Post-GFC ........ 185

Table 30 Retail Sales Dummy Variable based Regression: Pre-GFC ................ 187

Table 31 Producer Price Index Continuous Regression ..................................... 189

Table 32 Consumer Price Index Continuous Regression ................................... 191

Table 33 Consumer Price Index Continuous Regression: Post-GFC ................. 193

Page 9: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 iv

Table 34 Consumer Price Index Dummy Variable based Regression: Post-

GFC ..................................................................................................... 195

Table 35 Real GDP Dummy Variable based Regression ................................... 197

Table 36 Real GDP Dummy based Regression: Pre- and Post-GFC ................. 199

Table 37 Overnight Cash Rate Continuous Regression: Pre-GFC ..................... 201

Table 38 Overnight Cash Rate Dummy Variable based Regression: Pre-GFC . 203

Table 39 Consumer Sentiment Index Continuous Regression ........................... 205

Table 40 Consumer Sentiment Index Dummy Variable based Regression........ 207

Table 41 Consumer Sentiment Index Dummy Variable based Regression: Post-

GFC ..................................................................................................... 209

Table 42 Continuous Model Results using Alternate Breakpoints: Pre- and Post-

GFC ..................................................................................................... 211

Table 43 Dummy Variable Model Results using Alternate Breakpoints: Pre- and

Post-GFC ............................................................................................. 214

Page 10: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 v

Figures

Figure 1 ASX 200 Index Total Daily Returns ..................................................... 77

Figure 2 Australian All Ordinaries Index Total Daily Returns ........................... 78

Figure 3 Unemployment Rate Surprises .............................................................. 86

Figure 4 Balance of Trade Surprises .................................................................... 88

Figure 5 Retail Sales Surprises ............................................................................ 90

Figure 6 Producer Price Index Surprises ............................................................. 92

Figure 7 Consumer Price Index Surprises ........................................................... 93

Figure 8 Real GDP Surprises ............................................................................... 96

Figure 9 Interest Rate Surprises ........................................................................... 98

Figure 10 Consumer Sentiment Surprises ........................................................... 101

Figure 11 Brent Crude Oil One-Month Futures Prices and Returns .................... 103

Figure 12 Lagged US Standard and Poor’s 500 Index Returns ........................... 104

Figure 13 Term Spread - Australian Commonwealth Government Bonds ......... 107

Figure 14 5-Year Australian Corporate Bond Default Spread ............................ 109

Figure 15 ASX 200 Index - Sector Composition ................................................. 134

Figure 16 ASX 200 Index - Total Daily Returns ................................................. 136

Figure 17 Westpac-Melbourne Institute Consumer Sentiment Index ................. 137

Figure 18 Consumer Sentiment Surprises ........................................................... 138

Figure 19 EGARCH Normal Distribution Quantile Plot ..................................... 170

Page 11: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 6

Acknowledgements

My supervisors, Professor Richard Heaney and Dr. Joey Wenling Yang, spent many

hours reading, editing, analysing data and advising me. I am thankful for their efforts,

patience and ability to stimulate a creative learning and research environment. My

research is a richer tapestry of findings on account of Professor Heaney’s ability to

encourage creative thinking, and his guidance on research design. Dr Yang has

improved my understanding of financial econometrics, academic conventions in

drafting research and skills in managing the scope of research.

My editor, Eleanor Mulder and my father, Jonn Mero, also spent hours reading,

editing and providing useful comments on my drafting. My employer, Greg

Watkinson, also provided useful suggestions regarding my written communication of

ideas and document structure. These people improved the readability of my thesis

immeasurably.

Finally, I would like to thank Adam Hearman and Robyn Oliver, for minimising the

administrative burden and thereby making my experience as a research student at the

university all the more pleasant.

Page 12: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 7

1 Introduction

Understanding macroeconomic risk, in order to price individual assets, is a

fundamental aspect of economic and financial decision-making.1 More recently,

attention has turned to identifying macroeconomic variables as risk factors (Chen,

Ross & Roll 1986; Chan, Karceski & Lakonishok 1998; Flannery & Protopapdakis

2002). A well-functioning financial system should incorporate important

macroeconomic information in stock prices and returns quickly and rationally, or in

the words of Fama (1970, p.383), the market should be ‘semi-strong form’ efficient.

The returns on an equity market index in an economy with a well-functioning

financial system should, therefore, respond quickly to important macroeconomic risk

factors because the index is comprised of individual firms. The effect of these risk

factors should be identifiable in short run returns. The idea that certain

macroeconomic variables are risk factors in stock market returns is well accepted

from a theoretical, empirical and industrial perspective.

1.1 Theoretical, Empirical and Industry Perspectives

From a theoretical perspective, the share price of individual firms that are used to

construct a stock market index, within an economy, are affected by broader economic

conditions. This is because economic conditions generally affect the expected future

earnings and dividends of individual firms. In addition, expected future earnings and

dividends are related to the firm’s share price through the required rate of return

(Gordon 1962; Campbell & Shiller 1988). The required rate of return itself may also

be affected by macroeconomic factors (Ross 1976). This means any variable affecting

1 For example see Markowitz 1952, Treynor, cited in Ross 1976, p.341, Sharpe 1964, Lintner 1965,

Fama & French 1992, Black 1972, Ross 1976, Jagannathan & Wang 1996.

Page 13: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 8

earnings, dividends, or the required (or expected) future rate of a firm’s return, also

affects a broad market index made up of firms. Market indices should therefore

respond to macroeconomic news (Fama 1981; Schwert 1990).

From an empirical perspective, the link between macroeconomic variables and stock

returns is supported by evidence from major economies, such as the United States

(US), Europe and Japan. In the US, Fama (1981) observed that future real activity,

measured by industrial production and real Gross National Product (GNP), eliminated

the explanatory power of inflation when included as a variable in a regression used

for explaining stock returns. Schwert (1990) confirmed the relationship between

growth rates in future production and stock returns, which was discovered by Fama

(1981) using 100 years of data. An early application of Arbitrage Pricing Theory

(APT) by Chen, Ross & Roll (1986) identified macroeconomic variables and non-

equity asset returns as risk factors when explaining equity returns. Industrial

production, changes in risk premia, the term structure of the yield curve and also

inflation were found to be significant explanatory factors. Cheung and Ng (1998)

concluded that future real GNP growth has a significant positive influence on US

stock returns. Ratanapakorn & Sharma (2007) showed money supply, industrial

production, inflation, the Japanese Yen/US dollar exchange rate and short-term

interest rates are positively related to US stock returns, while long-term interest rates

are negatively related to stock returns. The relationship between US stock prices and

the two variables - industrial production and long-term interest rates - is also found in

a later study by Humpe & Macmillan (2009). However, in contrast to Ratanapakorn

& Sharma (2007), Humpe & Macmillan (2009, p.118) found a negative relationship

between inflation and stock returns.

Page 14: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 9

In Europe, Asprem (1989) examined the relationship between the major stock index

and macroeconomic variables in ten different countries. Interest rates, inflation,

imports and (perhaps surprisingly) employment were shown as negatively related to

stock prices, whereas changes in future industrial production and broad money supply

were shown as positively related to changes in stock prices. The results of the

cointegrating techniques employed by Cheung and Ng (1998, p.293), for German

stock returns, indicated future real GNP growth has a significant positive influence

on returns.

Following the spectacular rise of the Tokyo Stock Exchange (TSE) leading up to

1990, Mukherjee and Naka (1995) studied the long-term relationship between

Japanese macroeconomic variables and TSE index based returns. Their model found,

in the long run, local currency depreciation, money supply, industrial production, and

short-term interest rates are positively related to stock market returns, while inflation

and long-term interest rates are negatively related. Cheung & Ng (1998) reported

similar results for Japan, finding lagged money supply and future real GNP are both

positively related to Japanese stock market returns. Humpe and Macmillan (2009)

also documented Japanese stock returns have a positive relationship with industrial

production. Unlike Mukherjee and Naka (1995), Humpe and Macmillan (2009, p.118)

found Japanese returns have a negative relationship with the money supply in Japan.

Turning to an industrial perspective, Australian financial media coverage on the share

market frequently and continuously attributes changes in daily returns to

macroeconomic variables, such as employment:

‘Shares on Thursday fell for a fourth straight day, but ended well off the day's

lows, thanks to strong jobs data …’ (Cauchi 2015)

Page 15: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 10

Real GDP:

‘Stocks ended near unchanged today after a rally spurred by surprisingly strong

growth in the nation's economy…’ (Australian Associated Press 31 October 2003)

Inflation and interest rates:

‘The Australian share market is expected to open strongly tomorrow with

financial markets awaiting key inflation figures that will offer clues surrounding

possible interest rate rises…’ (Carter 2007).

This highlights it is generally accepted that certain macroeconomic variables are risk

factors in Australian stock returns. In this study, I seek to identify and quantify the

effect of such risk factors in Australian stock returns. I will also assess whether their

effects on stock returns differ between rapid and more subdued periods of stock price

growth, as theory and evidence suggest this may be the case (Shiller 2003;

Binswanger 2004).

1.2 Thesis Contribution

The most common methods employed to detect macroeconomic risk factors in stock

returns are based on APT, present value, or cointegration models, which tend to focus

on the relationships between macroeconomic variables and stock market returns over

time horizons far longer than one day. Few studies examine the effect of the

unexpected component of macroeconomic announcements (news or surprises) on

stock market returns over the short run. Most existing research tends to focus on the

relationship between announced macroeconomic data values and stock market prices

over the long run. The distinction between announced macroeconomic data and news

is an important one. Announced macroeconomic data is the reported value for a

macroeconomic variable, typically by a statistical agency or other sovereign authority.

Page 16: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 11

Macroeconomic news, however, is the difference between the market participant's

expected value of the macroeconomic variable and the announced value. I assume if

there is no difference, then no news exists – news by definition must be new

information, or in other words, a ‘surprise’. Assuming stock markets are efficient, and

an estimate of the market participant’s expected value of a macroeconomic variable

reflects broader market expectations, news associated with this variable should

quickly cause stock market prices to change if it is a risk factor. Any information that

is not new is (by assumption) already reflected in the current market price (Fama

1970, 1991). Those studies that have incorporated news or ‘innovations’ typically do

so within a cointegrating framework, which again, have a focus on long run

relationships (Cheung & Ng 1998; Humpe & Macmillan 2009). Additionally, a

minority of the macroeconomic risk factor research uses the ‘event study’

methodology, which focuses on a ‘window’ of time around an event, such as a

macroeconomic announcement, to examine the extent to which macroeconomic news

is incorporated in prices.

Studies examining the effect of news on short run stock returns, for a fairly

comprehensive set of macroeconomic variables, have been carried out for the US,

United Kingdom (UK) and also for some European markets (Wasserfallen 1989;

Becker, Finnerty and Friedman 1995; Flannery & Protopapadakis 2002). Australian

studies examining the effects of macroeconomic variables on returns over short time

periods (daily) have, to date, focused on a limited number of macroeconomic

variables (Singh 1993; Singh 1995; Brooks et al 1999; Kim & In 2002; Akhtar et al

2011; Hasan & Ratti 2012). Akhtar et al (2011) found a relationship between

consumer sentiment and Australian stock market returns, and Hasan and Ratti (2012)

found a relationship between oil prices and Australian stock returns. While Kim and

In (2002) found Australian stock return volatility was higher on real GDP

Page 17: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 12

announcement days, the relationships between short run stock market returns and

fundamental macroeconomic variables, such as unemployment, the consumer price

index (CPI) and output, are yet to be established in Australia.2

My literature review yields eight macroeconomic variables as candidates for

examination: (1) unemployment, (2) balance of trade, (3) retail sales, (4) producer

price index (PPI), (5) CPI, (6) real Gross Domestic Product (GDP), (7) overnight cash

rates and (8) consumer sentiment. I examine the effects of these variables on stock

market index returns and volatility using the event study methodology, undertaken

within a regression framework. The regression framework is an exponential

generalised autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (GARCH) specification. To

construct macroeconomic surprises, announcement data is sourced from the

Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS), the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) and

Westpac-Melbourne Institute. The corresponding expected values for the

announcements are either sourced from Money Market Services (MMS) Australia or

modelled using an autoregressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) model, which

is based on prior observations of announcements. A time series of surprises is then

constructed for each macroeconomic variable as the difference between the

announcements and their corresponding expected value.

I employ two different variants of the models used to explain returns. The first variant

uses continuous macroeconomic surprise values and attempts to measure the

sensitivity of returns/return volatility to the change in magnitude of macroeconomic

surprises. Put another way, this variant of the model measures the per cent change in

returns/return volatility per one per cent of error in macroeconomic forecasts. The

second model assigns a dummy variable to each macroeconomic announcement day,

2 Kim and In (2002, p.578) found some evidence that real GDP news days are positively related to

futures returns, but not stock returns based on spot prices.

Page 18: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 13

which is equal to one only if the macroeconomic surprise is not equal to zero and zero

otherwise. This captures the average effect of macroeconomic surprises on stock

returns. An additional dummy variable is assigned to macroeconomic surprises

assumed to be ‘bad’ news, which captures additional information on whether bad

news has a different effect to good news.

Good and bad news in this context does not relate to presupposed effects on returns,

rather, it is an assumed perception of whether the news is a good or bad sign for the

economy. My assumption of what constitutes good and bad surprises follows Kim

(2003, p.619) for all variables except cash rates and consumer sentiment, which were

not included in his study. For cash rates, I assume the perspective of a leveraged

entity, and in this case, higher cash rates are deemed bad news because of higher

interest payments and capital costs more generally. For consumer sentiment, I assume

the perspective of an entity that relies on sales activity. Higher levels of consumer

sentiment mean good news because of higher consumer spending and, therefore,

higher sales.

The continuous model finds robust relationships for the CPI and consumer sentiment.

The dummy variable based model detects robust relationships for unemployment, the

CPI, real GDP and the overnight cash rate. These results largely corroborate findings

in the reviewed literature that conclude real GDP has, in particular, a strong positive

relationship with stock market returns.

My study benefits from access to data with a large number of observations falling

over a period of prolonged stock market expansion, contraction and subsequent

subdued growth following the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) in 2008. This enables

me to examine whether relationships differ during these phases of stock market

activity, as is empirically observed by Binswanger (2004) in foreign markets.

Page 19: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 14

With the exception of the overnight cash rate, all of the significant macroeconomic

variables appear to explain stock market returns only in the period following the GFC.

Lagged stock returns appear to play a greater role than fundamental macroeconomic

factors during the stock market boom leading up to the GFC. This is consistent with

Binswanger’s (2004, p.248) finding that fundamentals cease to explain stock prices

during stock market booms. Amongst the variables with significant coefficients, all

news assumed to be good economic news is associated with increased returns, while

all news assumed to be bad economic news is associated with decreased returns. Real

GDP and the consumer sentiment index significantly influence return volatility both

before and after the GFC. Real GDP news exhibits asymmetric effects, which shows

good news is more important than bad news.

1.3 Thesis Structure

In Chapter 2, I review the relevant literature. I begin by reviewing some of the most

relevant theories, such as the APT, the efficient markets hypothesis (EMH) and the

event study methodology. An overview of studies on the influence of macroeconomic

variables, specific to Australian share market returns and return volatility, follows.

Foreign studies, specifically examining the effect of macroeconomic surprises on

stock markets, are also reviewed because of the similarity of their research design

with my study. I finish by drawing conclusions from the literature that impact my

research design.

The relationships between macroeconomic variables and stock returns, observed in

the literature, are reserved for discussion in Chapter 3. In this chapter, I outline my

null hypotheses with respect to the effect of each of the macroeconomic variables'

associated surprises on Australian stock returns, along with details of alternative

hypotheses. Chapter 4 explains how data is processed and how the econometric

Page 20: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 15

models are used to test for relationships between macroeconomic variables and stock

returns. The data sources and their characteristics are one of the most important parts

of my study. These are presented and discussed at some length in Chapter 5. Chapter

6 is a discussion of the results vis-à-vis the hypothesis chapter, followed by an

overview of robustness tests and a discussion on the results surviving the robustness

tests. Conclusions are drawn in Chapter 7, which also highlights some areas for future

research.

Page 21: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 16

2 Literature Review

My literature review begins by outlining some of the theories most relevant to my

study. I note the issues found in the literature that studies these theories, and their

implications for this study. Studies that examine the relationship between

macroeconomic variables and the stock market in Australia are reviewed with a focus

on the aspects relevant to my study. Foreign studies that examine the relationship

between macroeconomic variables and stock markets, specifically using

macroeconomic surprises, are also discussed in a similar way. Finally, conclusions

are drawn from the literature, and the contribution of my thesis is explained.

2.1 Theoretical Background

Below are some well-established theories and a description of their relevance to my

study.

Arbitrage pricing theory proposes the expected return on a particular asset can be

explained by risk premia that are associated with a number of macroeconomic risk

factors, as well as the risk free rate of return (Ross 1976). Macroeconomic risk factors

are identified using a statistical process. If the price of an asset differs from that

predicted by the model, an arbitrage opportunity exists, and in an efficient market,

this is rapidly taken advantage of. My study has parallels to the multifactor model

proposed by Ross (1976) because it identifies potential macroeconomic risk factors

and uses them to explain returns. Ross’s (1976) focus, however, is on stock market

returns in excess of the risk free rate, whereas my study examines the return on the

stock market index without deducting the risk free rate. Also, unlike Ross (1976), I

examine whether prices react quickly to the unexpected component of macroeconomic

risk factor announcements.

Page 22: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 17

The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) is important to my study because it relates to

the speed and degree to which financial market prices incorporate new information or

surprises. My study is based on the assumption this happens rapidly in an efficient

stock market. If a macroeconomic announcement has an effect on stock returns, then

I expect this to be reflected in stock prices on the day of the announcement.

The EMH postulates a capital market is efficient if prices always ‘fully reflect’ all

available information (Fama 1970, p.383). To establish the point at which this

hypothesis breaks down, Fama (1970) reviewed tests based on three subsets of

information:

weak form tests based on historical prices;

semi-strong form tests based on obviously available (public) information, such

as company and economic announcements; and

strong-form tests based on privately available information.

No important empirical evidence was found to disprove the hypothesis that security

prices reflected the first two information sets. However, limited evidence that went

against the hypothesis, tested on the strong-form set of information, was found. Semi-

strong form tests, in particular, are concerned with the speed at which prices adjust to

publicly available information. Tests based on company and macroeconomic

announcements indicated prices reacted at the time of the announcement.

Additionally, there is some evidence to suggest prices moved in anticipation of the

announcement, and these movements appeared to be unbiased. My study proceeds on

the assumption stock prices incorporate the semi-strong form information set.

The cost of getting prices to reflect information is not always zero, and this is

explicitly accounted for in Fama’s 1991 study. Consequently, prices are hypothesised

to reflect information, often to the point where marginal profits, made from acting on

Page 23: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 18

information, are offset by the marginal cost. Additionally, Fama (1991, p.1575)

emphasised a test of market efficiency requires an equilibrium asset price determined

by a model that itself may be the source of pricing errors. A rejection of the EMH

could be a result of a bad pricing model and/or market inefficiency. This was referred

to as the joint-hypothesis problem. The weak, semi-strong and strong form tests were

replaced by the following three classifications of research identified in the literature:

tests for return predictability;

event studies; and

test for private information.

Tests for return predictability and event studies are the most relevant to my study, and

so, the most pertinent of Fama’s (1991) findings on these tests are outlined below.

Aside from testing the EMH, tests for return predictability are important in the

formulation of the models used in my study when establishing a relationship between

stock returns and macroeconomic announcements. To maximise the possibility of

detecting such relationships, the effect of other variables that affect or ‘predict’ returns

needs to be both accounted and controlled for when testing.

Tests for return predictability, reviewed in Fama (1991, p.1578), included tests for

autocorrelation (that is, the effect of past returns on future returns). The studies found

significant positive autocorrelation, and it was more prevalent in those market indices

with many small stocks. This point is important when considering whether a stock

index with many smaller capitalised stocks should be used in a study of stock returns.

This issue is revisited when selecting a stock return index. With respect to market

efficiency, however, Fama (1991, p.1609) noted the predictable part of returns was

only a small proportion of the variance, and could not warrant a conclusion of

substantial market inefficiency. Incidentally, the studies reviewed also showed

Page 24: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 19

differences between return variances for trading and non-trading hours. This is linked

to differences in the flow of information collected during trading and non-trading

hours.

The findings on autocorrelation and differing variances around non-trading hours,

such as holidays, indicate these effects should be and are controlled for in my study.

Fama’s (1991, p.1586) review acknowledged tests based on the volatility of returns

are a useful way to show expected returns can vary through time. The tests reviewed,

however, could not explain whether this variation is rational (and therefore efficient)

or a result of irrational bubbles. Early literature reviewed provided evidence of several

cases of return seasonality, in addition to periods such as holidays. These included the

day-of-the-week effect, intra-day effects and the January effect. This evidence

highlights such effects may also need to be controlled for.3

With respect to market efficiency, Monday, holiday and end-of-month effects were

small compared to the bid-ask spread of the average stock, while the January effect

was small in relation to the bid-ask spread of small stocks. Fama’s (1991, p.1587)

view was these effects are market microstructure anomalies, and so, observation of

these effects need not necessarily result in the rejection of the hypothesis of market

efficiency.

Event studies, reviewed in Fama (1991, p.1601), benefited from the use of high

frequency data, which allowed a more precise measurement of the speed at which

stock prices respond to a given event. It also substantially assisted the study to

overcome the joint-hypothesis problem, particularly when stock price responses were

large and concentrated in a few days. This is because the issue of finding an asset-

pricing model that correctly measures daily returns is not so critical for statistical

3 This is controlled for in my model by the use of holiday dummy variables. See Section 5.3.

Page 25: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 20

inference when the abnormal returns are very pronounced and expected return

variation is small. The typical result from these studies is stock prices appear to adjust

within a day of event announcements. This suggests day-to-day changes in stock

prices are suitable for my study. This speed of adjustment was viewed to be consistent

with the hypothesis of market efficiency.

Event studies still do not entirely resolve issues relating to market uncertainty and the

joint hypothesis problem. A common finding in the review of event studies is the

dispersion of returns increases around information events. Event studies only explain

the average variation around events, while the residual variation is unexplained. It is

not, therefore, possible to determine whether the remaining increase in variation is a

rational reaction to uncertainty about new fundamentals or irrational over/under-

reaction, and thus, indicative of inefficiency. This suggests using a model that

accounts for changes in the variance of returns, around the macroeconomic

announcements in this thesis, will result in a more precise test for responses in returns

(and thus, market efficiency) to public announcements.

2.2 Australian Studies

A review of studies on Australian stock market returns is detailed below. This is

followed by a review of studies specifically dealing with stock market return

volatility. In light of the importance of the EMH to my thesis, an additional Australian

stock market study testing the hypothesis is outlined at the end of this section. A

summary of these Australian studies is presented in Table 1.

2.2.1 Australian Stock Market Returns

Gultekin (1983) tests the relationship between stock returns and inflation in a number

of countries including Australia. This study is motivated by the Fisher hypothesis that

Page 26: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 21

the real rate of return on assets is independent of the expected inflation rate in efficient

markets (that is, nominal returns on assets will vary one for one with expected

inflation). Nominal returns were regressed on expected inflation, which was

approximated by the realised inflation rate at the beginning of the return holding

period.4 No significant relationship was found between the two variables in Australia.

These findings indicate, in Australia, inflation realised in a past quarter has no effect

on the nominal returns realised in the subsequent quarter.

Jaffe (1984) tests stock market data for four countries, including Australia, for a

‘week-end’ effect. Other studies, typically based on US data, had found returns were

abnormally high on Friday and abnormally low on Monday. Returns were, therefore,

regressed on dummy variables, representing each trading day. The hypothesis that

returns were equal on each trading day was rejected. Tuesdays were found to have

significantly lower mean returns than all other days.

Jaffe (1984, p.4) hypothesises the effect may be a result of the timing difference

between the Australian stock exchange and the New York stock exchange. The New

York exchange tended to experience its lowest mean returns on Mondays, and by

then, Monday trading in Australia had already closed. A regression of the differences

in returns, between the Australian market and lagged values of the US market on day-

of-the-week dummy variables, found days of the week have unequal effects on the

differential, providing evidence to support the hypothesis. This result highlights the

importance of lagging US return values when testing for these relationships with the

Australian market.

4 For countries other than Australia in this study expected inflation was also estimated using

ARIMA models and derived from short-term interest rate data.

Page 27: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 22

Additional tests are carried out in Jaffe’s study (1984) to determine whether any part

of the day-of-the-week effect found in Australia is independent of those observed in

the US market. The results provided evidence that at least part of the day-of-the-week

effect is unique to the Australian market. Such effects should thus be controlled for

in studies of Australian stock returns.

Singh (1993) conducts a study on the response of Australian stock prices to money

supply announcements. His treatment of the money supply data is of particular

interest for my study because it involves modelling the expected and unexpected

component of a macroeconomic announcement. This is in addition to using surveyed

Money Market Services (MMS) forecasts. Singh (1993, p.48) used money supply

forecasts sourced from MMS Australia for broad money (M3). Multiple ARIMA

models were used for forecasting, so only subsequent models incorporated previously

unavailable information as it became available with each passing day. This ensured

ARIMA forecasts on each day were based only on information available at that time.

This avoided biasing the forecasts toward the actual announced outcomes, which

would have been the case if the unavailable future data were used to fit an ARIMA

model on each day historically.

The announcements detailing the money supply’s preliminary estimates were sourced

from RBA press releases for both narrow money (M1) and M3. Changes in stock price

indices are regressed on both expected and unexpected changes in money supply,

using ARIMA forecasts in one particular case and MMS forecasts in another. At

conventional levels of statistical significance, the results showed no significant

relationship between changes in stock prices and money supply changes. The survey-

based forecasts appear to be somewhat more reflective of market expectations than

ARIMA based forecasts and produced higher absolute values of t-statistics, despite

Page 28: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 23

neither forecast producing statistically significant results at conventional levels

(Singh 1993, p.50). There is, therefore, some support for the use of survey forecasts

over modelled forecasts, though this is a moot point given the lack of strong statistical

support.

Singh (1995) examines the role of current account deficit announcements on a number

of financial markets, including the Australian stock market. Changes in stock prices

were modelled as a function of expected and unexpected announcements, with the

expected component being represented by forecasts. Including dummy variables in

the model controlled for day-of-the-week effects. Monthly announcements of the

current account balances are sourced from the ABS. A survey of the expected value

of the current account deficit was sourced from MMS. An ARIMA model was, again,

used to model expected and unexpected components of announcements as in Singh

(1993). The expected component, based on the MMS survey data, was found to have

an insignificant effect on stock returns, while the unexpected component had a

negative effect significant at the 10 per cent level. Day-of-the-week effects are found

to have no significant effect. When undertaken with ARIMA forecasts as opposed to

MMS data, the analysis produced comparable results but reported slightly lower t-

values. Again, these findings are consistent with Singh’s (1993, p.51) previous

suggestion that MMS surveyed forecasts contain more information than ARIMA

forecasts (based only on past values).

Brooks et al (1999) test the effect of unexpected current account deficit (CAD) and

GDP announcements, including revisions, on daily observations of the All Ordinaries

share price index. An ARIMA model is used to decompose the initial announcements

into their expected and unexpected components, by producing one-step-ahead

forecasts representing the expected component, and forecast errors representing the

Page 29: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 24

unexpected component. An Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) model, regressing returns

on the unexpected component of announcements and revisions, is used to test for

significant effects. The results suggested CAD and GDP announcements and

revisions have no significant effect on returns. The results were unchanged when the

announcements and revisions were separated into good news (positive sign) and bad

news (negative sign) announcements.

An additional point to note in Brooks et al (1999, p.199) is the discussion regarding

the use of MMS forecast survey data in Australia compared to ARIMA models for

forecasting. They advocate the latter on the basis that survey data suffers from the

effects of ‘herding behaviour’, survival bias and its reliance on median expectations

in survey forecasts. They argue the use of the median is inappropriate given there is

no reason to expect the marginal investor to hold the median expectation.

This view is contrary to that of Singh (1993 and 1995), who supports survey-based

data on the basis it has more explanatory power than ARIMA forecasts. Although

none of these studies detected any significant relationships, using either MMS or

ARIMA forecasts, Singh (1993 & 1995) noted some evidence (outlined above) in

favour of the MMS forecasts. In light of Singh’s findings, survey data is generally

preferred over ARIMA forecasts in this study, although it is important to note, the

discussion that occurred in the literature. Where MMS data is not available, I consider

ARIMA forecasts the next best option.

Kim and In (2002) create a model to explain returns in the Australian stock market.

The model uses returns in foreign stock markets, and macroeconomic announcements

in Australia and overseas, as explanatory variables. Daily Australian stock returns

were based on the ASX All Ordinaries index returns, while the Standard and Poor’s

(S&P) 500, FTSE 100 and Nikkei 225 based returns are used to represent the US, UK

Page 30: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 25

and Japanese markets respectively. The study used a bivariate Glosten-Jagannathan-

Runkle (GJR) GARCH model and two-step estimation procedure. Their model makes

specific allowance for asymmetry in stock return relationships with explanatory

variables. This is an important aspect of their analysis. Unemployment, the CPI and

GDP announcements are used from both the Australian and US economy. Dummy

variables for holiday periods are also included.

The model indicates that return volatility in Australia is significantly higher on

announcement days for Australian real GDP. The model also reports a significant

positive relationship between Australian and US/UK returns, and a significant

negative relationship between Australian and Japanese stock market returns. Shocks

in the UK and Japanese stock market have a significant positive impact on the

volatility of the Australian market. US and Australian GDP announcements, as well

as holidays, were positively related to volatility. Asymmetry terms in the model were

significant, and tests of the model residuals found no remaining sign bias, indicating

the model adequately captures the asymmetric effect.

Groenewold (2003) tests for a structural break in the relationship between the

Australian stock market and real GDP, resulting from financial deregulation in

Australia, using a vector autoregression (VAR) framework and plotting impulse

response functions (IRFs). Returns are based on the All Ordinaries (non-cumulative)

price index. Real GDP, valued at 1999/2000 prices, is used to represent real output.

The control variables used include the term spread on government bonds, which is

calculated as the difference between 10 year yields on Commonwealth Government

bonds and three-month rates on Treasury notes. The default spread is calculated as

the difference between five-year yields on Commonwealth Government bonds and

State Treasury bonds.

Page 31: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 26

Over the full sample, the VAR model and IRFs found lagged output growth, term

spread and default spread had no significant effect on stock returns. In terms of

precedence, the VAR model results showed causality ran from stock market returns

to output growth (that is, stock market returns from two quarters prior caused positive

output growth. This is consistent with the theory that share market returns are a

leading indicator of output (Fama 1981; Campbell & Shiller 1988). In the pre-

deregulation period, the VAR model results still found lagged output growth, term

spread and default spread had no significant effect on stock returns at the conventional

levels of statistical significance. In the post-deregulation period, the VAR results

found lagged default spreads and term spreads had a significant negative effect on

stock market returns. As found in the results for the whole period, stock market returns

from two quarters prior caused positive output growth.

The impulse response functions and R-squared values for the VAR models suggest

any influence that output has on stock returns has weakened post-deregulation. The

implication of these findings is the relationship between the real economy and the

share market had, if anything, weakened after opening the economy to international

capital flows. In isolation, this study creates an a priori expectation that real GDP

announcements affect stock market returns. The findings on both default and term

spreads justify the inclusion of these variables as control variables in a model of

Australian stock returns.

Groenewold (2004) computed fundamental share prices in Australia, based on real

GDP, using a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) model over the period 1959 to

1999. He found positive real GDP shocks positively affected stock prices, supporting

the theory that the real value of firms is the net present value of expected dividends

(Groenewold 2004, p.660). Over the period of relatively subdued stock market price

Page 32: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 27

growth from 1988 to 1993, his computed fundamental share prices indicated stock

market prices were not too far from fundamental values. However, they departed

substantially from fundamentals in the period prior (from around 1970 to 1987), and

from around 1994 to 1999 when stock market price growth was strong. This suggests

relationships between macroeconomic fundamentals and stock market returns may

differ between strong and subdued periods of stock market price growth.

Kim (2003) investigated the effects of US and Japanese macroeconomic news

announcements on the stock markets of Australia, the US and Japan. The All

Ordinaries index observations for open, high, low and close were used to calculate

Australian market returns. Macroeconomic announcements, and surveyed

expectations of these announcements, were sourced from MMS International so the

unexpected components (or ‘news’) could be estimated by deducting expectations

from the announcements. Exponential GARCH (EGARCH) models were estimated

using Australian stock returns. Using dummy variables controlled for holidays. The

effect of macroeconomic announcements was captured using dummy variables to

indicate only those announcements with news content. These were announcements

where the announced value was not equal to the surveyed expectation. Asymmetric

properties of return and return volatility responses were captured through inclusion of

dummy variables to indicate ‘bad’ news. These were based on the sign of unexpected

components in the announcement.

Most of the US macroeconomic news announcements had a significant effect on

Australian returns. Those with a positive effect on returns included retail sales growth,

unemployment, PPI and CPI-based inflation. With respect to balance of trade, GDP

growth, retail sales growth, unemployment, PPI and CPI-based inflation, bad news

had a significantly negative effect on returns.

Page 33: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 28

All of the US news announcements also had a highly significant effect on Australian

return volatility. News announcements that increased volatility included US balance

of trade, GDP growth, unemployment and CPI based inflation. Retail sales and PPI

news announcements reduced volatility. Bad news, with respect to GDP growth, retail

sales growth, unemployment and the PPI, had a negative effect and reduced volatility.

Bad news, with respect to balance of trade and CPI, increased volatility.

In contrast, few of the Japanese macroeconomic news announcements had a

significant effect on returns; only the Japanese CPI and bad unemployment news had

a positive effect on Australian returns.

For return volatility, however, approximately half of the Japanese announcements had

a significant effect. Australian return volatility was positively affected by the Japanese

wholesale price index, CPI and bad trade balance news. Trade balance news in

general, as well as bad wholesale price index news, had a negative effect on volatility.

The study indicates the effects of US news announcements on Australian stock returns

are more important than the effects caused by Japanese news announcements. A

variable capturing the effect of US announcements (such as US stock returns) will

therefore, likely be useful in a model explaining Australian stock returns.

Chaudhuri and Smiles (2004) tested the long-term relationship between real

Australian stock prices and real macroeconomic variables, including GDP, private

consumption, money-supply and oil prices. Their study is similar to mine in many

respects, but it is based on vector error correction modelling (VECM) that focuses on

relationships over the long run.

The All Ordinaries index was used for Australian stock price data, while seasonally

adjusted M3 money supply, GDP and private personal consumption expenditure was

Page 34: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 29

sourced from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)

Main Economic Indicator database. The world oil price index was converted to

Australian dollars using the Australian-US dollar exchange rate. Their model of

Australian returns also included US, Japanese and New Zealand market returns as

explanatory variables. The base error correction model found lagged real GDP

growth, private consumption, M3 money supply and oil prices had a highly significant

role in explaining real stock price variation over an extended period. Concurrent and

lagged US stock price indices are highly significant, and they played a dominant role

in explaining long-term real stock price variation. Similar, but much weaker, effects

were also found for New Zealand stock price indices, while the Japanese index

showed no significant effects.

This study further supports the argument that US stock returns are an important

variable to include in a model explaining Australian returns; whereas Japanese returns

are not.

Akhtar et al (2011) examined the effect of consumer sentiment news on Australian

stock market returns. The Westpac-Melbourne Institute consumer sentiment index

was used to approximate investor sentiment. Returns calculated using the Australian

All Ordinaries index were regressed on dummy variables, representing negative and

positive changes in the consumer sentiment index and the Morgan Stanley Capital

Index (MSCI) (world stock market index), to control for the impact of international

factors. Negative changes in the consumer sentiment index had a significant negative

effect on returns, while positive news was found to have no effect, confirming a

negativity bias in relation to ‘bad’ news. This finding suggests the consumer

sentiment index should be included in my study as a macroeconomic variable of

interest.

Page 35: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 30

Hasan & Ratti (2012) studied the relationship between oil price shocks and volatility

in Australian stock market returns. Their study was based on sector level returns, as

opposed to a broad stock market index or returns.

Stock market indices for ten industry sectors in Australia were used to calculate a

series of ten different returns. The excess return, over Australian 90-day bank

accepted bills, was calculated for each series. Oil price volatility was based on one-

month futures prices of West Texas Intermediate crude oil because they were

considered less noisy than spot prices. A GARCH-in-mean specification was used to

model the relationship between excess returns and volatility in each industry. Excess

returns for each sector were modelled as a function of excess returns on the market

overall, as well as excess oil returns and oil return volatility. They found that oil prices

were negatively related to overall market returns, and oil return volatility was also

negatively related to overall market return volatility.

While most sectors showed that an increase in oil returns also meant a decrease in

excess returns, the energy and materials sectors’ excess returns moved in the same

direction as those of oil. Increased volatility in oil returns reduced volatility of equity

market returns for around half of the sectors (including energy and materials), while

significantly increasing equity market return volatility in the financial sector. Hasan

& Ratti’s (2012) results suggest oil returns are an important variable in explaining

Australian stock market returns.

2.2.2 Australian Stock Market Return Volatility

Kearns & Pagan (1993) examined and attempted to explain volatility in Australian

stock market index data from 1875 to 1987. A variety of models, including EGARCH,

were used to model volatility over the period. The EGARCH model was found to

explain more of the variation in returns, than either GARCH or the rolling 12-month

Page 36: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 31

standard deviation model, while the rolling 12-month standard deviation model was

superior to GARCH in this respect. Tests for sign asymmetry, between positive and

negative shocks on volatility, revealed only weak evidence of negative shocks having

a greater effect on return volatility. The high values of the lagged coefficients in the

volatility models indicated a strong persistence of shocks. This suggests a model of

returns/return volatility should account for autocorrelation in volatility.

Kearney & Daly (1998) examined the relationship between stock market volatility

and a number of macroeconomic variables, including inflation, interest rates,

industrial production, the current account balance and money supply. They employed

a conditional volatility model based on the absolute values of errors between their

returns model and realised returns. Lagged industrial production volatility (over 3

months) reported a negative relationship with stock market return volatility. Volatility

in wholesale price inflation, over one month, increased stock return volatility, as did

interest rate volatility over the same lag horizon. These findings indicate the absolute

values or size of changes in macroeconomic variables, as opposed to the direction of

changes, are important in explaining Australian stock market return volatility.

2.2.3 The Australian Stock Market and Efficient Market Hypothesis

Sadique & Silvapulle (2001) tested stock returns in several countries, including

Australia, for the presence of long memory in returns. Their study was based on the

theory that in efficient markets, arbitrage opportunities are quickly taken advantage

of and decrease the correlation between successive returns in the market. Three

procedures were used to test for long memory, including rescaled range analysis, the

Geweke and Porter-Hudak (GPH) test, and a frequency and time domain score test.

These tests found no significant evidence of long memory in the Australian stock

Page 37: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 32

market, indicating the EMH could not be dismissed. This result suggests the

Australian stock market is, at least, weak form efficient.

An overview of the Australian literature that was reviewed is outlined in Table 1.

Table 1 Australian Literature Review Summary

Study Observation

Period Method Data Frequency Results

Gultekin (1983)

Relationship

between expected

inflation and

stock market returns

January 1947

- December 1979

OLS

Regression

International Monetary Fund Australian Stock

Market Index and CPI

based Inflation

Quarterly

No significant relationship found between expected

inflation and stock market

returns

Jaffe (1984)

Day-of-the-week effect on stock

market returns

March 1973 -

November

1983

OLS

Regression and

F-Tests

Statex Actuaries Stock

Market Index and

Composite S&P 500 US stock market index and

week day dummy

variables

Daily

Days of the week were found to

have unequal effects on returns. Evidence suggested this was

partly due to correlation with

day-of-the-week effects in the US and partly due to factors

unique to the Australian market

Kearns &

Pagan (1993)

Returns asymmetry and

persistence of

shocks in Australian stock

market volatility

1875 -1987

GARCH,

EGARCH, 12 month

rolling

standard deviation

Sydney and Australian

Stock Exchange All Ordinaries Index

Monthly

Weak evidence of sign

asymmetry in the effect of stock market shocks on stock price

volatility was found. Shocks

appeared to be strongly persistent, and return volatility

is greater than that in the US,

particularly in more recent history

Singh (1993)

Relationship

between money supply and stock

returns

January 1976

- June 1987

OLS

Regression

Statex Actuaries Stock

Market Accumulation

Index, All Industrials, All Ordinaries, Banks

and Finance and

Transport indices, MMS M3 money supply

forecasts, RBA press

releases for M1 and M3, ARIMA forecasts based

on RBA press releases

Daily

No significant relationship was

found between stock returns and

money supply. Some evidence was found suggesting surveyed

expectations were more

reflective of market expectations than ARIMA base

forecasts

Singh (1995)

Relationship between current

account deficit

and stock returns

July 1985 -

October 1991

OLS

Regression

Dividend corrected

Statex Actuaries Accumulation index,

week day dummy

variables, MMS current account balance

forecasts, monthly ABS

current account balance

announcements,

ARIMA forecasts based on ABS current account

balance announcements

Daily

Results did not find any

significant relationship between

stock returns and the current account balance. Evidence was

found that suggested surveyed

forecasts contain more

information than ARIMA based

forecasts

Page 38: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 33

Kearney & Daly

(1998)

Relationship between stock

market volatility

and inflation, interest rates,

industrial

production, current account

balance and

money supply

January 1972

- January

1994

Absolute

value conditional

volatility

and GLS estimated

ARCH

ASX All Industrial Index, index of

industrial production,

OECD index of wholesale prices,

current account balance,

Australian-US Dollar exchange rate, RBA 3-

month bank accept bill

interest rate, dummy variables representing

1987 stock market crash

and monthly seasonal dummy variables

Monthly

It was shown that conditional

stock market volatility was

directly related to the conditional volatility of

wholesale price inflation and

interest rates. Industrial production, current account

balance and money supply were

indirectly related

Brooks et al

(1999)

The effect of announcements

and revisions in

GDP and current account balance

on stock returns

January 1989

- December 1993

ARIMA/O

LS

All Ordinaries Index

and announcements of

current account balance and GDP values,

ARIMA forecasts based

on current account balance and GDP

announcements.

Daily

Current account balance and GDP news announcements and

revisions were found to have no

significant effect on returns. The results were unaffected by

separating out negative and non-

negative news.

Sadique &

Silvapulle

(2001)

Tests for long-

term memory in

stock market returns

January 1983 - December

1998

Rescaled

range analysis,

GPH test,

frequency and time

domain

score test

Australian aggregate

stock price index Weekly

No significant long memory of

stock market shocks could be found indicating the efficient

market hypothesis could not be

dismissed

Kim & In

(2002)

Spill over effects

from international

stock market returns,

employment,

CPI and GDP announcement

days on

Australian stock market returns

July 1991 - December

2000

GJR GARCH

with two

step

estimation

procedure

ASX All Ordinaries Index, S&P 500, FTSE

100, Nikkei 225, Australian and US

employment, CPI and

GDP announcement day dummy variables

Daily

A significant positive relationship was found between

Australian and US/UK returns

while a significant negative relationship was found between

Australian and Japanese returns.

US and Australian GDP announcements had a positive

effect on volatility, as did Australian holidays. Shocks in

the UK and US stock market

also had a significant positive impact on Australian stock

market volatility. The model

also found asymmetry terms were significant, indicating

negative and positive shocks

had a different effect on conditional volatility

Groenewold

(2003)

Relationship between the

stock market

returns and real output, term

spreads, and

default spreads

pre- and post-

financial

deregulation

Quarter 1,

1978 - Quarter 2,

2001

VAR and

impulse response

functions

All Ordinaries Index,

Real GDP, term spread between 10 year

Commonwealth

Government Securities and 3-month Treasury

notes, default spread

between 5 year Commonwealth

Government Securities

and 5 year State Government Treasury

Bonds

Quarterly

Pre-deregulation lagged stock

returns were found to have a

significant effect on themselves. Post-deregulation lagged term

spreads and default spreads had

a significant negative effect on stock returns. Impulse response

functions (IRFs) found stock

market return shocks on themselves died out in around

1.5 years. IRFs showed output

growth had a weak negative effect on stock returns pre

deregulation, but a negligible

effect post deregulation

Page 39: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 34

Groenewold

(2004)

Relationship

between the real

stock market prices and real

output

Quarter 4,

1959 - Quarter 1,

1999

SVAR and

impulse response

functions

All Ordinaries Index

divided by the GDP

deflator and Real GDP

Quarterly

The effects of shocks to both output and share prices in the

model die out quickly, but more

slowly so for share price shocks. A positive output shock had a

positive effect on both real

output and real share prices. A positive stock market shock

initially depressed output but

the effect was only temporary. Share prices appeared to be

undervalued for most of the

1970s and overvalued for most of the 1990s

Kim (2003)

Spill over effects

of US and Japanese news

on the Australian

stock market

January 1991 - May 1999

Moving

average

EGARCH

All Ordinaries Index

high, low, open and close prices, MMS

Surveyed forecasts of

US balance of trade, real GDP, retail sales,

unemployment rate, PPI

and CPI, MMS surveyed forecasts of

Japanese trade balance,

current account balance, unemployment, money

supply, wholesale price

index and CPI, dummy variables representing

holidays

Daily

US news announcements that

increased volatility included

balance of trade, GDP growth, unemployment and CPI

inflation. Retail sales and PPI

news announcements reduced volatility. Bad news with

respect to GDP growth, retail

sales growth, unemployment and the PPI were negatively

related to volatility Japanese

CPI and bad unemployment news was positively related to

Australian returns. Australian

return volatility was positively related to the wholesale price

index, CPI and bad trade

balance news. Trade balance news on average and bad

wholesale price index news was

negatively related to volatility

Chaudhuri &

Smiles (2004)

The effect of aggregate

economic

activity on the Australian stock

market

Quarter 1, 1960 -

Quarter 4,

1998

VECM

All Ordinaries Index, OECD seasonally

adjusted Main Economic Indicators;

M3 money supply,

GDP, private personal consumption

expenditure and world

oil price converted using AUD/USD

exchange rate

Quarterly

Lagged Real GDP, real private

consumption, real M3 money supply, and real oil prices were

found as highly significant in

explaining real stock price variation over the long run

Akhtar et al

(2011)

Negatively

biased effect of

consumer sentiment

announcements

on Australian stock returns

June 1992 -

December 2009

OLS

Regression

All Ordinaries Index,

MSCI World Index,

Westpac Melbourne Institute consumer

sentiment index,

Dummy Variables signifying negative

index changes

Daily

Negative changes in the

consumer sentiment index had a

significant negative effect on returns while positive news had

no effect

Hasan & Ratti

(2012)

The effect of oil

price shocks on Australian stock

return volatility

March 2000 - December

2010

GARCH-

in-mean

Australian stock market indices for 10 GICS

sectors, one-month

West Texas Intermediate crude

future prices, and

excess stock market index returns over 90

day bank accepted bills

Daily

Oil prices were negatively

related to overall market returns

and volatility. Most sectors' excess returns were negatively

related to those of oil, however

energy and materials were positively related. Increased oil

return volatility reduced return

volatility for around half of the sectors in the study including

energy and materials, while

financial sector return volatility increased

Page 40: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 35

2.3 Foreign Studies

2.3.1 Foreign Stock Markets and Macroeconomic Surprises

My literature review found four foreign studies that specifically examined the effect

of macroeconomic surprises on stock returns. The foreign literature gives us an

additional insight into which methods and data are likely to produce informative

results. They also assist in the development of hypotheses, which are detailed in

Chapter 3.

Wasserfallen (1989) examined the relationship between stock returns and

macroeconomic surprises in the UK, Switzerland and West Germany separately. His

study used OLS regression with distributed lags and quarterly returns based on a

prominent stock market index, present in each country at the time. He used the

Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung index for West Germany, the Swiss National Bank

index for Switzerland and the Financial Times Ordinary index for the UK. Surprises

are calculated as the difference between realised values and ARIMA forecasts

(residuals), for a number of macroeconomic variables, including real GNP, industrial

production, the unemployment rate, consumer prices, money supply, monetary base,

real exports, import prices, nominal and real interest rates, real investment, nominal

and real wages, and foreign exchange rates. His results indicated the explanatory

power of his regressions was very low. For West Germany, unexpected changes in

nominal interest rates, and consumer and import prices, have a negative relationship

with returns. That is, an unexpected increase (decrease) in these factors is associated

with decreased (increased) stock returns. Conversely, unexpected changes in money

supply have a significant positive relationship with stock market returns. In

Switzerland, unexpected real consumption was the only variable to have a relationship

Page 41: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 36

with returns, and that relationship was negative. The UK study found only unexpected

nominal wages had a relationship with real returns that was negative.

Becker, Finnerty and Friedman (1995) examined the relationship between

macroeconomic surprises and stock market returns in the UK. They employed OLS

regression on high frequency (half hourly) returns using the Financial Times Stock

Exchange (FTSE) 100 index. Macroeconomic surprises were calculated using MMS

surveyed data on the current account, industrial production, money supply (M0), PPI,

public sector borrowing requirement, retail price index, retail sales, unemployment,

and visible trade to represent expectations. Their results showed that higher than

expected visible trade and current account surprises were positively related to stock

returns. Heavier than expected government borrowing was negatively related to stock

returns.5 All other variables had no statistically significant effect.

Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002) studied the effects of seventeen macroeconomic

‘surprises’, and announcement days on stock returns, spanning the 16 years from 1980

in the US. A GARCH model was used to estimate returns as a function of surprises,

and the volatility of returns as a function of macroeconomic announcement days.

Volatility was of more interest because they thought it likely the impact of

macroeconomic news on returns was time varying, in terms of strength and sign.

Although an announcement could cause a change in stock returns, it meant the

response of returns to a given type of announcement could, at times, be negative and

at other times be positive. Volatility captured the magnitude or ‘size’ of the effect

rather than the sign.

5 Becker, Finnerty and Friedman (1995) defined surprises as the actual announced value less the

expected value which is opposite to the definition in my paper.

Page 42: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 37

Accordingly, Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002) assessed macroeconomic variables

to determine whether they were ‘risk factors’ in the stock market by also modelling

volatility as a measure of risk. Their study used the weighted index of the New York

Stock Exchange-American Stock Exchange-National Association of Securities

Dealers Automatic Quotation System (NYSE-AMEX-NASDAQ) to calculate returns

and base trading volumes. Seventeen macroeconomic variables of interest were

examined, including the CPI, PPI, money supply (M1 and M2), employment,

unemployment, balance of trade, home sales, housing starts, industrial production,

personal income, personal consumption, retail sales, interest rates, consumer credit,

construction spending and real GNP. Money supply surprises and announcement days

were the only variables to affect both the level and the volatility of returns. Surprises

had a negative effect on the level of returns, while announcement day dummies had a

positive effect on the volatility of returns. The PPI and CPI surprises negatively

affected the level of returns, while the balance of trade, employment, home starts and

real GNP announcements days had a positive impact on return volatility.

Kim (2003) produced regression results for the effects of US and Japanese

macroeconomic news announcements on their own respective stock markets. The

Dow Jones Industrial index and Nikkei 225 index were used to represent the stock

market returns of the US and Japan respectively. Observations for open, high, low

and close index prices were used to calculate market returns. MMS International

surveyed expectations of macroeconomic announcements were deducted from the

announcements themselves to estimate the unexpected components (or ‘news’). The

same EGARCH regression framework for Kim’s (2003) Australian stock return

model (outlined in Section 2.2.1) was used for estimating the stock returns.

Page 43: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 38

The regression results showed that US returns were negatively related to both good

and bad US balance of trade surprises, and positively related to bad retail sales

surprises. US return volatility was decreased by good balance of trade news, real GDP

news, retail sales news and bad unemployment news announced for the US. Bad

balance of trade and PPI news announced for the US increased US return volatility.

For Japan, the regression results showed that good Japanese trade balance news, bad

money supply news and bad CPI news decreased Japanese returns. Good current

account balance news and bad trade balance news increased returns.6 Japanese return

volatility is decreased by good unemployment and CPI news, and bad trade balance

news. Good trade balance news, current account balance news, bad unemployment

and CPI news and any wholesale price index news increases Japanese return

volatility.

An overview of some of the first foreign literature on the effect of macroeconomic

announcement surprises on stock returns is summarised in Table 2.

6 For Japan, bad news announcements for trade balance are when it is lower than expected. Bad

news announcements for money supply are when it is higher than expected.

Page 44: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 39

Table 2 Foreign Literature Review Summary

Study Country Observation Period Method Data Frequency Results

Wasserfallen (1989)

Relationship between nominal

returns and macroeconomic

surprises

West Germany

1977 - 1985

OLS distributed

lag regressions

and ARIMA

forecasts

Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung Index, real GNP,

industrial production, unemployment rate, consumer prices, money supply, monetary base, real exports,

import prices, nominal interest rate, real interest rate,

foreign exchange rates

Quarterly

Consumer price, import prices, and nominal

interest rate all had a significant negative

relationship with returns, while M1 money supply had a significant positive relationship

Switzerland

Swiss National Bank Index, real GNP, industrial production, real consumption, real investment,

consumer prices, money supply, monetary base, real

exports, import prices, nominal interest rate, real interest rate, foreign exchange rates

Only real consumption had a significant negative relationship with returns

United Kingdom

Financial Times Ordinary Index, Real GNP, industrial production, consumer prices, nominal wages, real

wages, M1, monetary base, real exports, import prices,

nominal interest rates, real interest rate, foreign exchange rates

Only nominal wages had a significant negative relationship with real returns

Becker, Finnerty and

Friedman (1995)

Relationship between surprises in macroeconomic

announcements and UK equity

market returns

United Kingdom July 1986 -December 1990

OLS Regression

FTSE 100 Index, MMS surveyed expectations and actual announcements from Economic Trends (UK) for

current account, industrial production, M0, PPI, public

sector borrowing requirement, retail price index, retail sales, unemployment and visible trade

Half hourly

Higher than expected visible trade and current account balances were positively related to

returns. Heavier than expected government

was negatively related to returns. All other variables had no statistically significant effect

Flannery and

Protopapadakis (2002)

Relationship between macroeconomic announcement

days and surprises in

announcements and US equity market returns

United States January 1980 -

December 1996 GARCH

NYSE-AMEX-NASDAQ market index from Centre for Research in Security Prices, lagged dividend to price

ratio, lagged three-month Treasury bill yields, lagged 10

year Treasury bond term premium on three-month bills, lagged default premium between Moody's BAA and

AAA seasoned corporate bond indices, surprises based

on MMS surveyed expectations and announcements on balance of trade, consumer credit, construction

spending, CPI, employment, unemployment, new home

sales, housing starts, industrial production, leading indicators, M1, M2, personal consumption, personal

income and PPI

Daily

Higher than expected consumer and producer price indices were negatively related to the

level of returns. The announcement days for

balance of trade, unemployment/employment, home starts, M1, M2 and real GNP were

positively related to the volatility of returns

Page 45: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 40

Kim (2003)

Spill over effects of US and

Japanese news on the

Australian stock market

United States

January 1991 –

May 1999

Moving average

EGARCH

Dow Jones Industrial Index high, low, open and close

prices, MMS Surveyed forecasts of US balance of trade,

real GDP, retail sales, unemployment rate, PPI and CPI

Daily

US returns were negatively related to both good and bad US balance of trade surprises

and positively related to bad retail sales

surprises. US return volatility was decreased by good balance of trade news, real GDP

news, retail sales news and bad unemployment

news. Bad balance of trade and PPI news increased US return volatility

Japan

Nikkei 225 Index high, low, open and close prices,

MMS surveyed forecasts of Japanese trade balance, current account balance, unemployment, money supply,

wholesale price index and CPI, dummy variables

representing holidays

Good trade balance news, bad money supply

news and bad CPI news decreased returns.

Good current account balance news and bad trade balance news increased returns. Return

volatility is decreased by good unemployment

and CPI news, and bad trade balance news. Good trade balance news, current account

balance news, bad unemployment and CPI

news, and any wholesale price index news increases return volatility

Page 46: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 41

2.3.2 Business Cycles and Macroeconomic Factor relationships with Stock Markets

Binswanger (2004) studied the relationship between macroeconomic fundamentals

and stock returns in Canada, Japan and an aggregate economy consisting of four

European G-7 countries. He found that the fundamental relationship between stock

returns and real GDP shown in other research disappeared during the stock market

boom of the 1980s. He concluded there is support for the hypothesis that speculative

bubbles in the stock market were an international phenomenon affecting major

economies during the 1980s and 1990s.

Andersen et al (2007) extend the literature by using high-frequency futures market

data available on a tick-by-tick basis to quantify the effect of US macroeconomic

news announcements on global stock, bond and foreign exchange markets. One of the

key findings from this study was that stock markets react differently to

macroeconomic news depending on the stage of the business cycle. Over the full

sample, including both a period of expansion and contraction, they found almost no

significant equity market responses to economic news. Once the sample was split into

expansion and contraction periods they found that equity markets responded

negatively to positive real economic shocks during expansions while responding

positively during contractions.7

Velinov and Chen (2015) examined whether macroeconomic fundamentals explained

stock prices in France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the UK and US with a special emphasis

on the period following the GFC. In all countries they found that stock prices fell back

7 Many additional papers studying various aspects of macroeconomic announcement surprises and

asset returns can also be found. Some examples include Bomfim (2003), Andersen (2003),

Brenner, Pasquariello, and Subrahmanyam (2009) and Rangel (2011).

Page 47: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 42

toward their fundamental values (approximated by industrial production) after the

GFC.

2.4 Conclusions from the Literature

The literature reviewed for examining the effect of macroeconomic variables on

Australian stock returns covers a period from 1947 to 2010. There appears to be a

dearth of Australian literature dealing with the effect of macroeconomic news or

surprises on Australian stock market returns. Kim and In (2002) made an early attempt

to detect a relationship between stock returns and announcement days for Australian

real GDP, the CPI and unemployment. While they detected a significant relationship

between real GDP announcement days and return volatility, no other relationship

were established. Additionally, their study was not based on surprises, but only

announcement days. More recent studies include Hasan and Ratti (2012), covering

the period 2000 to 2010, and Akhtar et al (2011), covering the period 1992 to 2009.

However, their focus is on the effect of a single macroeconomic variable on

Australian stock returns, rather than the effect of a variety of macroeconomic

surprises. My thesis aims to provide a contemporary analysis of the effect of a variety

of macroeconomic announcements commonly cited in the media, taking advantage of

the long high quality data sets now available, such as MMS surveys and the S&P ASX

200 index (discussed further below). I will employ an extensive set of macroeconomic

variables that are noted in the literature.

While a number of methods have been used to model Australian returns, the

EGARCH model in Kim’s (2003) model was one of the most successful in terms of

explanatory power. This approach has the benefit of modelling both returns and return

volatility simultaneously, which is of interest in return studies, as highlighted in the

theoretical and Australian literature (Fama 1991; Kearns & Pagan 1993; Kearney &

Page 48: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 43

Daly 1998). Foreign studies support the use of ARCH or GARCH type models.

Kearns and Pagan (1993, p.174) found EGARCH had superior explanatory power to

GARCH and other specifications used. Their study also presented evidence that

volatility persists in Australian returns, and so, GARCH type models that control for

these autocorrelation effects should produce more statistically robust results than

basic OLS models. This specification thus far appears to be a good candidate for my

analysis of returns.

Fama (1991, p.1601) noted the event study process, using high frequency data (such

as daily observations), allows for a more precise measurement of the speed at which

stock prices respond to a given event, such as macroeconomic announcements. The

process also assists in overcoming the joint-hypothesis problem. This supports the use

of daily data in an event study process for analysing the effect of macroeconomic

announcements on Australian stock market returns.

The ASX All Ordinaries index is the most utilised Australian stock price index in the

literature reviewed, as evidenced by its use in eight of the fifteen studies reviewed

above. I note, however, this index has been restructured to include a large number of

smaller capitalised firms from 2000 onward. This gives rise to the thin trading issues

raised in Fama (1991, p.1579), so my preference is to use the All Ordinaries index

only for checking the robustness of results. The S&P ASX 200 index gives less weight

to smaller capitalised firms and has maintained a consistent structure since its

inception. My study benefits from having access to this data series, over a time frame

that falls over a period of prolonged stock market expansion, contraction and

subsequent subdued growth following the GFC. This allows me to examine whether

relationships are different during these phases of stock market activity because the

Page 49: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 44

literature suggests this may be the case (Binswanger 2004, Andersen et al (2007),

Velinov & Chen 2015).

Two of the studies examining the Australian stock market found US returns (S&P

500) to have significant effects on Australian returns. Jaffe (1984) found evidence to

suggest negative average Monday returns in the US were correlated with the lowest

mean returns occurring on Tuesday in Australia, due to time zone differences. Kim

and In (2002, p.578) similarly found lagged US stock prices had a positive

relationship with Australian prices, affecting both the mean and variance.

The most commonly studied macroeconomic variables in the Australian literature

include inflation, balance of trade (or more specifically the CAD), interest rates, GDP,

employment and oil prices. Each of these variables was included in at least two of the

studies. Based on their prominence in the literature, I consider these variables good

candidates for inclusion in my model of stock returns, to ensure a comprehensive

study of macroeconomic risk factors whilst maintaining a parsimonious model. The

interest rate used is the overnight cash rate because its values are announced

periodically (rather than being continuously updated), which lends itself well to the

study of surprises. Retail sales and the PPI were included in my study on account of

good quality surveyed forecasts being available from MMS, and because they had

been included in foreign studies using macroeconomic surprises (Becker, Finnerty &

Friedman 1995, Flannery & Protopapadakis 2002). Consumer sentiment was

included, following the success of Akhtar et al (2011), who found it significant in

explaining Australian returns.

Singh (1993 & 1995) found evidence to suggest MMS survey data has information

content superior to naive ARIMA models of expected values for macroeconomic

announcements. In the foreign literature that examined the effect of macroeconomic

Page 50: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 45

surprises, the use of MMS survey forecasts was associated with models more

successful in terms of explanatory power than those employing ARIMA forecasts

(Kim 2003). Accordingly, I opt to use MMS survey data as forecasts in my modelling,

wherever possible, and I use ARIMA forecasts only where MMS data is insufficient.

The exception here is money supply, for which MMS data is no longer available, and

which reported disappointing results when ARIMA forecasts were used (Singh 1993).

For this reason, I exclude money supply as a macroeconomic variable in my study.

The findings of Sadique & Silvapulle (2001) suggest the Australian stock market is,

at least, weak form efficient, which is an encouraging starting point from which to

proceed because my study relies on the Australian stock market being efficient.

Page 51: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 46

3 Hypothesis

As outlined in Section 2.3.2: Conclusions from the Literature, the macroeconomic

variables examined in my study are unemployment, balance of trade, retail sales, the

producer price index, the consumer price index, real GDP, the overnight cash rate and

the consumer sentiment index.

My null hypothesis for each macroeconomic variable is that the surprise component

of related announcements has no effect on aggregate stock returns. As shown in the

literature review (Chapter 2), there are quite a number of conflicting theories and

empirical results that attempt to explain the relationship between each of the

macroeconomic variables in my study and stock market returns. Flannery and

Protopapadakis (2002, p.752) raised the possibility of such conflicts, and highlighted

that the impact of specific macroeconomic variables might vary with economic

conditions. This meant that the effect of macroeconomic risk factors might change

depending on the stage of the business cycle. Despite this, they emphasised that

economically important surprises should be associated with returns that are

abnormally large in absolute value. The models set out in Chapter 4 have been

designed to capture any relationships with abnormally large absolute values in returns.

My null hypothesis is, therefore, that no macroeconomic variables are economically

important.

Alternative theories and evidence propose that macroeconomic variables do affect

stock market returns but, all too often, explain the relationship as a time invariant

effect. Allowing for time varying stock market volatility responses (for each

macroeconomic variable) allows a greater chance of detecting economically

Page 52: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 47

important relationships with returns, in the event that the direction of the effect is time

varying.

The dummy-based model assigns a dummy variable to macroeconomic surprises that

are not zero, and a dummy variable to any ‘bad’ news that depends on the sign of the

observed value for the macroeconomic surprise. The surprise is defined in equation

(1) below:

, 1 , ,( )k t t k t k tSurprise E Announcement Announcement

Where:

1 ,( )t k tE Announcement is the forecast value for period t prior to period t ; and

,k tAnnouncement are the realised values of each of the k announcements at

time t .

In my analysis, I also refer to surprises for each macroeconomic variable as good or

bad for ease of discussion. This is because the sign of surprises (negative or positive)

has a different meaning depending on the variable in question. For example, a

negative sign could indicate good news for some variables and bad news for others. I

must emphasise good and bad news, in this context, does not relate to presupposed

effects on returns, but instead, assumed perceptions of what is good or bad news for

the economy.8 My assumption of what constitutes good and bad surprises follows

Kim (2003, p.619) for all variables except cash rates and consumer sentiment, which

are not included in his study. For the former, I assume the perspective of a leveraged

entity so higher cash rates are bad news (in terms of higher interest payments). For

the latter, I assume the perspective of an entity that relies on sales activity so high

8 The words news and surprises are used interchangeably, although strictly speaking news is only

the value of surprises that are not equal to zero. In practice, it is rare for surprises to equal exactly

zero, as this means expectations forecasted the announcement precisely.

Page 53: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 48

levels of consumer sentiment mean good news (in terms of better buying conditions

and sales).

To summarise, a positive value of surprises resulting from equation (1), for

unemployment, the PPI, CPI and overnight cash rate, is assumed to be good news.

This is based on the assumption that when announced values of these variables are

low (relative to expectations), it is typically seen as good news. Announced values of

those variables that are low (relative to expectations) result in a positive surprise value

(according to equation (1)). All negative observations in the set of t surprises, for

unemployment, the PPI, CPI and overnight cash rate, are coded with the number one

for the bad news dummy and a zero otherwise. I must also emphasise the bad news

dummies are not multiplied by the surprise value.

A positive value of surprises resulting from equation (1), for retail sales, real GDP,

balance of trade and the consumer sentiment index, is interpreted differently. For

these variables, a positive value is assumed to be bad news. This is based on the

assumption that announced values of those variables that are low (relative to

expectations) are typically seen as bad news. Thus, according to equation (1), lower

than expected announced values produce a positive surprise value, which is

interpreted as bad news. For retail sales, real GDP, balance of trade and the consumer

sentiment index, all positive values are coded with the number one for the bad news

dummy and a zero otherwise. Again, the bad news dummies are not multiplied by the

surprise value.

One final complication is that changes in one macroeconomic variable can be a

‘proxy’ for changes in another macroeconomic variable. For example, in Australia,

CPI news can influence expectations of changes in the overnight cash rate due to the

inflation targeting objective of monetary policy. There are many possible

Page 54: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 49

permutations of these interrelationships between macroeconomic variables, which

may also change depending on the phase of the business cycle. In light of this, I only

outline some of the most noted hypotheses on these relationships covered in the

literature.

3.1 Unemployment

My null hypothesis is that unemployment surprises (or news) have no effect on returns

or return volatility. Kim and In (2002, p.578) showed that Australian employment

announcement day dummies (as distinct from values) had no significant explanatory

power in Australian stock market return regressions over the period 1991 to 2000.

This finding is directly relevant to my thesis because the Australian employment

announcements used by Kim and In (2002, p.574) follow the same release schedule

as the unemployment announcements used in my study. In the foreign studies that use

the macroeconomic surprise methodology, Kim (2003) assessed the effect of US and

Japanese unemployment announcement surprises on stock return levels, and found

US unemployment announcements had no effect on US market returns. Such was also

the case in Japan; he found no significant effect between Japanese unemployment

announcement days and Japanese market returns. Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002,

p.766) confirmed Kim’s finding that there were no significant effects between US

unemployment announcements and the level of US returns over a longer, but earlier,

period. Becker, Finnerty and Friedman (1995, p.1206) found UK unemployment

announcements had no effect on UK aggregate stock returns. In West Germany,

Wasserfallen (1989, p.622) observed no relationship between unemployment values

and West German stock market returns. The null hypothesis is set out as follows:

H1: No relationship between unemployment news and stock returns/return

volatility

Page 55: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 50

The finding that there is no relationship between employment/unemployment

announcements and returns could possibly be a result of some studies failing to

capture time varying responses to unemployment news. That is, if stock returns do, in

fact, change in response to unemployment news, but the sign of the effect changes

over time, the effect may be undetectable in return levels but detectable in squared or

absolute values of returns. Time varying responses are more likely to be the case if

significant relationships are found between news and volatility (or absolute returns).

Theories supporting an alternative hypothesis, that unemployment is negatively

related to returns, are as follows. Asprem (1989, p.595) initially presumed

employment (unemployment) would be positively (negatively) related to real activity,

and thus, positively (negatively) correlated with stock returns.

Boyd, Hu & Jagannathan (2005, p.650) found the effect of unanticipated increases in

unemployment on stock returns is dependent on the state of the economy; that is,

whether the economy is expanding or contracting. The reasoning is unemployment

news contains information on corporate earnings/dividend growth expectations,

meaning unemployment news can be a proxy for growth expectations. They found an

unanticipated increase in unemployment often precedes slower growth, particularly

during contractions. The subsequent lower growth in corporate cash flows equates to

lower stock prices and returns. The alternative hypothesis, based on these theories, is

set out below:

H1a: Good unemployment news (unexpected decrease in unemployment)

increases stock returns and vice versa for bad unemployment news

The same authors also recognise another alternative hypothesis that unemployment

and stock returns are positively related. Asprem (1989, p.595) reasoned employment

(unemployment) may increase (decrease) only in the later stages of a boom period,

Page 56: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 51

and by that time, earnings expectations, and thus stock prices, are starting to decline.

That is, stock prices are based on the period ahead, while unemployment relates to the

present. Boyd, Hu & Jagannathan (2005, p.650) formed a view that both future

interest rate information and information on earnings/dividend growth are implicit in

unemployment news. The future interest rate information appears to dominate

corporate earnings/dividend growth information during expansion. They reasoned

this is because an unanticipated rise in unemployment may signal an expectation that

future interest rates will decline in response, and as a result, stock prices (expressed

as the present value of corporate cash flows) are higher. This is on account of a lower

discount rate. These theories give rise to the alternative hypothesis set out below:

H1b: Good unemployment news (unexpected decrease in unemployment)

decreases stock returns and vice versa for bad unemployment news

In turn, these theories suggest that unemployment news, both good and bad, affects

stock return volatility. Kim (2003, p.625) found, in the US, bad unemployment news

reduces return volatility. This gives rise to the following hypothesis:

H1c: Bad unemployment news (unexpected increase in unemployment) decreases

stock return volatility

In Japan, Kim (2003, p.626) found evidence to the contrary. Bad unemployment news

reduced increased Japanese return volatility, while good unemployment news

decreased it. The alternative hypothesis, based on this evidence, is set out below:

H1d: Good unemployment news (unexpected decrease in unemployment)

decreases stock return volatility, and vice versa for bad unemployment news

Page 57: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 52

3.2 Balance of Trade

My null hypothesis is that balance of trade surprises have no effect on returns or return

volatility. Brooks et al (1999) and Singh (1995) both examined whether there is any

relationship between the Australian current account balance and Australian stock

returns, but they found no evidence to suggest one. In the Japanese market, Kim’s

(2003) study did not show any relationship between Japanese balance of trade

surprises and Japanese stock returns. Flannery and Protopapadakis’s (2002) study, did

not find any evidence that the balance of trade surprises and US returns were related.

The null hypothesis is set out as follows:

H2: No relationship between balance of trade surprises and stock

returns/return volatility

Evidence exists to support the alternative hypothesis that balance of trade surprises

have a positive relationship with returns, in the sense that bad news reduces returns.

In the UK, Becker et al (1995, p.1206) found higher than expected current account

balances, which I assume to be good news, in the Australian context, increased

returns. In Japan, Kim (2003, p.626) also found good current account surprises

increase returns. The alternative hypothesis, based on this evidence, is set out below:

H2a: Good balance of trade news (unexpected increase in balance of trade)

increases stock returns, and vice versa for bad balance of trade news

Other evidence shows the sign of the relationship between balance of trade news (or

surprises) and returns can be positive or negative, suggesting an alternative hypothesis

that balance of trade news increases return volatility, as opposed to returns. In Kim’s

(2003, p.624) study US balance of trade surprises, both good and bad, had a negative

effect on US returns, highlighting the lack of consistency around the sign of the

Page 58: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 53

relationship between balance of trade surprises and returns. This indicates it may be

the absolute value of returns or volatility that is affected, as opposed to returns. More

particularly, he also found good balance of trade surprises decreased US return

volatility, while bad news increased it. Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002, p.766)

found that US balance of trade announcement days, in general, were positively related

to US return volatility over an earlier/longer period than examined by Kim (2003).

This adds additional support to the hypothesis that balance of trade news affects return

volatility. The alternative hypothesis based on this evidence is set out below:

H2b: Good balance of trade news (unexpected increase in balance of trade)

decreases stock return volatility and vice versa for bad balance of trade news

In Japan, Kim (2003, p.626) found that good current account balance surprises (larger

than expected) increase return volatility. Assuming this is driven by the balance of

trade, the alternative hypothesis, based on this evidence, is as follows:

H2c: Good balance of trade news (unexpected increase in balance of trade)

increases stock return volatility

Kearney and Daly (1998, p.603) found evidence of another alternative hypothesis.

They reported a negative relationship between the conditional volatility of the current

account deficit (negative balance of trade) and the conditional volatility of stock

returns in Australia. The alternative hypothesis, based on this evidence, is set out

below:

H2d: A negative relationship exists between the size of balance of trade surprises

and stock return volatility.

Page 59: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 54

3.3 Retail Sales

My null hypothesis for retail sales is that they have no effect on Australian stock

market returns. Becker et al’s (1995, p.1206) UK study found no relationship between

returns and retail sales announcements, although it must be kept in mind, they did not

separate the effects of good and bad news. The null hypothesis is set out below:

H3: No relationship between retail sales surprises and stock returns/return

volatility

Economic theory-based alternatives support a relationship between retail sales and

stock market returns via the indirect effect of consumption on stock returns through

real GDP. As highlighted in Chapter 1, one of the most regular empirical results is

that expected and actual output, measured using indicators such as industrial

production, real GNP, or GDP, are positively related to stock returns. Retail sales are

viewed as an economic indicator, on account of being a measure of consumption

(Stock & Watson 1989, p.390). Consumption is a component of the Keynesian model

of aggregate expenditure (Keynes 1936). The most basic representation of the model

predicts consumption is positively related to income and output.

Another possibility is that more emphasis should be placed on future expected real

GDP than current real GDP. The permanent income hypothesis emphasises a positive

relationship between changes in expectations of future income and changes in

consumption spending (Friedman 1957). Changes in consumption, therefore, may be

seen as a forecaster of changes in future income and output, and so one would expect

consumption to be positively related to measures of output, such as real GDP. In turn,

this links consumption to stock returns, through the real GDP/stock market return

relationship. The alternative hypothesis, based on this theory, assumes retail sales are

Page 60: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 55

a measure of consumption, which is a component of real GDP.9 This hypothesis,

therefore, assumes retail sales affect stock returns, through the hypothesised positive

real GDP/stock return relationship discussed in Section 3.6 below. The alterative

hypothesis for the retail sales and stock return relationship based on these theories is

outlined as follows:

H3a: Good retail sales news (unexpected increase in retail sales) increases stock

returns and vice versa for bad retail sales news

An opposing alternative is offered by neoclassical economic theory, which

characterises output (production) as either being allocated to current consumption or

investment, this implies that lower rates of current consumption mean an increased

rate of savings, investment, capital accumulation and higher potential future output

(Solow 1956, Swan 1956). Additionally, if borrowing supports current consumption,

it is future consumption, and thus expenditure and output, that may be adversely

impacted through future interest and principal repayments.

Under these circumstances, rates of consumption that are considered too high could

conceivably be related to lower levels of expected real GDP growth and thus stock

returns over the long run. Kim’s (2003, p.624) results for the US stock market provide

evidence supporting this alternative hypothesis showing that bad (lower than

expected) retail sales news announcements increase US returns. An alternative

hypothesis based on this theory and evidence is set out below:

H3b: Good retail sales news (unexpected increase in retail sales) decreases stock

returns and vice versa for bad retail sales news

9 Multicollinearity is not an issue in this study design because real GDP announcements are made on

different days to retail sales announcements and also because this study focuses on the differences

between expected and actual values of each variable which can move more independently than the

levels of the variables themselves.

Page 61: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 56

With respect to stock market volatility, Kim (2003, p.624) also found evidence to

support an alternative hypothesis of a relationship with retail sales in the US. Good

US retail sales announcements decreased stock return volatility. The alternative

hypothesis based on this evidence is as follows:

H3c: Good retail sales news (unexpected increase in retail sales) decreases stock

return volatility

3.4 Producer Price Index

My null hypothesis for the producer price index is that it has no effect on Australian

stock market returns. In the US, Kim (2003) found the PPI had no effect on the level

of returns in the stock market. Using UK data, Becker et al (1995) could not detect

any relationship between PPI announcement surprises and stock returns. Flannery and

Protopapdakis (2002) found no significant relationship between the US PPI and US

return volatility. The null hypothesis is set out below.

H4: No relationship between retail sales surprises and stock returns/return

volatility

Assuming that the producer and consumer price index are an identical measure of

inflation, the alternative hypotheses on the relationship between the consumer price

index and stock returns (outlined in Section 3.5) should hold for the producer price

index. Tiwari (2012, p.1571) sets out a theory where producer prices are normally set

as a mark-up over wage costs that are driven by consumer prices. In turn, consumer

prices are set by consumer demand. In these circumstances, consumer price changes

should precede producer price changes, and assuming both price indices contain the

same information, the stock market should react to consumer prices but not producer

prices.

Page 62: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 57

In the same study, however, Tawari (2012, p.1571) highlighted that it is equally

plausible for producer price changes to precede consumer price changes in response

to ‘cost push’ shocks such as imported input price shocks.10 The theory that PPI

changes precede CPI changes, combined with the generalised Fisher hypothesis that

postulates a one for one relationship between inflation and stock returns (outlined in

Section 3.5), gives rise to the alternative hypothesis below:

H4a: Good producer price index news (unexpected decrease in the producer price

index) decreases stock returns, and vice versa for bad producer price index news

Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002, p.766) found evidence to support an additional

alternative hypothesis for returns. Using a longer and earlier period than Kim (2003),

they showed the US PPI had a negative relationship with the level of returns on the

US market. Tiwari’s (2012) theory that PPI changes precede CPI changes, combined

with the ‘proxy effect’ hypothesis (outlined in Section 3.5), gives rise to the

alternative hypothesis stated as follows:

H4b: Good producer price index news (unexpected decrease in the producer price

index) increases stock returns, and vice versa for bad producer price index news

For return volatility, Kim (2003, p.625) found evidence of an alternative relationship

in the US, namely that bad (higher than expected) US PPI news announcements are

positively related to US equity market volatility. The alternative hypothesis for

volatility, based on this evidence, is set out below:

H4c: Bad producer price index news (unexpected increase in the producer price

index) increases stock return volatility

10 Tiwari (2012) did, however, find that in Australia consumer price changes precede producer price

changes.

Page 63: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 58

3.5 Consumer Price Index

My null hypothesis for the consumer price index is that it has no effect on Australian

stock market returns. Gultekin (1983) studied the relationship between CPI based

expected inflation and Australian stock market returns over the period January 1947

to December 1979. No significant relationship was found. Kim and In (2002) analysed

the relationship between Australian CPI announcements and returns over a later

period than Gultekin (1983), spanning July 1991 to December 2000. Again, no

significant relationship was found. In Europe, Wasserfallen (1989) found there was

no significant relationship between UK/Swiss consumer price surprises and

UK/Swiss stock market returns. Kim (2003) found no relationship between US CPI

surprises and US stock market returns. Turning to volatility in Australia, Kim and In

(2002) found no relationship between CPI announcements and stock return volatility.

Overseas, Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002) found no relationship between US CPI

announcements and US stock return volatility. Similarly, Kim (2003) found no

relationship between US CPI surprises and stock return volatility. The null hypothesis

is set out below:

H5: No relationship between retail sales surprises and stock returns/return

volatility

One of the most obvious alternative hypotheses is based on the Fisher Hypothesis.

The Fisher Hypothesis characterises interest rates as consisting of a real component,

determined by real factors, such as the time horizons of investors, productivity of

capital, and expected inflation (Fisher 1930). More generally, the hypothesis predicts

nominal expected returns on assets are positively related to expected inflation, as the

nominal component will vary one for one with inflation. An alternative hypothesis,

based on this theory, is set out as follows:

Page 64: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 59

H5a: Good consumer price index news (unexpected decrease in the consumer

price index) decreases stock returns and vice versa for bad consumer price index

news

Alternatively, Fama (1981, p.545) postulates a negative relationship between inflation

and returns may result from a ‘proxy effect’. This assumes expected future real output

is positively related to stock prices and the demand for money. If a decrease in

expected future output is not offset by a decrease in money supply, it results in higher

inflation. Inflation, therefore, becomes a proxy for changes in expected future output

and stock prices. 11 Evidence, in support of a negative relationship, is presented in

Wasserfallen (1989), Flannery and Protopapadakis’s (2002) and Kim (2003).

Wasserfallen (1989, p.622) found consumer price surprises in West Germany had a

negative relationship with West German stock returns over the period 1977 to 1985.

Flannery and Protopapadakis’s (2002, p.766) US study observed a negative

relationship between CPI surprises over January 1980 to December 1996. For the

Japanese stock market, Kim (2003, p.626) found bad (higher than expected) Japanese

CPI announcements were negatively related to Japanese returns. The alternative

hypothesis, based on this theory and evidence, is stated below:

H5b: Good consumer price index news (unexpected decrease in the consumer

price index) increases stock returns, and vice versa for bad consumer price index

news

In Japan, Kim’s (2003, p.627) evidence supported an alternative hypothesis for

volatility. Good (lower than expected) CPI surprises were observed to have a negative

11 For the case of Australia, it is worth noting since mid-1993, the Reserve Bank of Australia has

conducted monetary policy with a particular focus on maintaining inflation within a band of 2 to 3

per cent over the medium term (Reserve Bank of Australia 1999). The implication here is that

unexpectedly high levels of inflation may be associated with a tightening of monetary policy or an

increase in the overnight cash rate. The hypothesised effects of the overnight cash rate on stock

returns are outlined in Section 3.7 below.

Page 65: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 60

effect on Japanese stock return volatility, while bad (higher than expected) CPI

announcements had a positive effect. The alternative hypothesis based on this

evidence is set out below:

H5c: Good consumer price index news (unexpected decrease in the consumer

price index) decreases stock return volatility, and vice versa for bad consumer

price index news

3.6 Real Gross Domestic Product

My null hypothesis for real GDP is that there is no relationship with Australian stock

market returns. Over the period January 1989 to December 1993, Brooks et al (1999)

found no relationship between GDP news announcements (using ARIMA model

based forecasts) and Australian stock returns. Separating negative and positive

surprises had no effect on the results. Kim and In’s (2002) Australian study confirmed

this result using GDP announcements (but without adjustment for the expected

component) over a later period January 1991 to December 2000. Flannery and

Protopapakis (2002) found no relationship between US real GNP announcements and

the level of returns. Kim (2003) also investigated the US market, testing the effect of

real GDP announcements on the US stock market. Again no relationship was found.

The null hypothesis is set out below:

H6: No relationship between real GDP surprises and stock returns/return

volatility

Despite this, there is strong theoretical and empirical support for alternative

hypotheses, although this is mainly based on foreign studies.

A number of theories are consistent with the view that growth in real GDP (output) is

positively related to returns. Increases in output lead to increases in real rates of return

Page 66: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 61

on capital, hence attracting capital investment (Jorgenson 1971). A ‘rational

expectations’ view of the real GDP/stock market price relationship is that

expectations of future real output should set current security prices (Fama 1981).

Campbell and Shiller (1988) outlined the mechanism through which corporate

earnings (which are inextricably linked to output), forecast future dividends, thereby,

creating a link between expected output and future dividends. In turn, their expected

future dividends are discounted to set current security prices through Gordon’s (1962)

dividend growth model. These theories establish a positive relationship between

expected/actual output (measured using indicators such as industrial production, real

GNP, or GDP) and stock returns. This positive relationship is one of the most

regularly found empirical results among foreign studies (Asprem 1989, Fama 1981,

Schwert 1990, Mukherjee & Naka 1995, Cheung and Ng 1998, Ratanapakorn &

Sharma 2007, Humpe & Macmillan 2009). In Australia, Groenewold (2004, p.660)

detected a positive relationship between real GDP shocks and Australian stock

returns.12 The alternative hypothesis, based on these theories and evidence, is outlined

below:

H6a: Good real GDP news (unexpected increase in real GDP growth) increases

stock returns, and vice versa for bad real GDP news

With respect to stock market return volatility, considerable evidence is found in

Australia and overseas to show real GDP announcements affect stock return volatility.

Kim and In (2002, p.578) found that Australian return volatility was positively

influenced by Australian real GDP announcement days (that is, the announcement

itself and not the specifics of the news content). Flannery and Protopapakis’s (2002,

p.766) study on the US also found real GNP announcement days were positively

12 Groenewold (2004) differs from my study in that he had a focus on long run relationships between

output and stock prices as opposed to macroeconomic surprises and daily returns.

Page 67: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 62

related to stock return volatility. This gives rise to an alternative hypothesis that real

GDP surprises, of any sign, are positively related to stock return volatility. This

hypothesis is as follows:

H6b: Real GDP news (unexpected increase or decrease in real GDP growth)

increases stock return volatility

A second alternative, with respect to volatility, is that good (higher than expected)

real GDP surprises reduce stock return volatility. Kim (2003, p.624) observed good

real GDP surprises in the US reduce US return volatility, which supports the

hypothesis set out below:

H6c: Good real GDP news (unexpected increase in real GDP growth) decreases

stock return volatility

3.7 Overnight Cash Rate

My null hypothesis is that the overnight cash rate has no effect on Australian stock

market returns. Wasserfallen (1989) observed Swiss and UK stock market returns

showed no significant relationship with nominal or real interest rates. The null

hypothesis is outlined as follows:

H7: No relationship between overnight cash rate surprises and stock

returns/return volatility

An alternative hypothesis is that interest rates have a positive relationship with stock

returns. Expectations theory, when applied to stock returns, predicts short-term

interest rates should have a one for one relationship with stock returns. This is because

riskier classes of assets, such as stocks, have a constant premium over ‘risk free’

assets, such as sovereign bills (Campbell 1987, Fama & Schwert 1977). Constant

Page 68: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 63

returns imply stock prices will adjust to offset changes in the discount rate, stemming

from changes in risk-free rate to ensure the premium remains constant. The alternative

hypothesis, based on this theory, is set out below:

H7a: Good overnight cash rate news (unexpected decrease in overnight cash rate)

decreases stock returns and vice versa for bad overnight cash rate news

Conversely, Shiller and Beltratti (1992) outlined, in the context of a rational

expectations present value model, a rise in the expected discount rate would cause

bond prices to fall and bond yields to rise, as their traditionally fixed coupons yield

higher returns as a proportion of their price.13 This makes bonds a more attractive

investment vis-à-vis stocks, and so, stock prices need to fall to induce investors to

buy stocks. This theory was outlined in the context of long-term bonds, but would

apply equally for overnight cash rates if cash rate changes were reflected in longer

term bond yields. Empirical support for this alternative is found in Wasserfallen’s

(1989, p.622) study on the West German market. West German stock market returns

showed a significant negative relationship with nominal interest rate surprises.

Flannery and Protopadakis’s (2002, p.766) results also exhibited a negative

relationship between lagged three-month Treasury bill yields and US stock returns.

This relationship, however, was based on continuously reported market yields, as

opposed to an announcement on interest rate policy. Assuming the relationship

between continuously reported interest rates and stock returns holds for interest rate

surprises and stock returns, the alternative hypothesis, based on these theories and

empirical evidence, is set out below:

13 Discount rates are typically driven by interest rates such as the overnight cash rate which reflect

the cost of alternative investment opportunities.

Page 69: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 64

H7b: Good overnight cash rate news (unexpected decrease in overnight cash rate)

increases stock returns and vice versa for bad overnight cash rate news

Turning to volatility, the results of Kearney and Daly’s (1998, p.603) Australian study

provided support for an alternative hypothesis, showing Australian stock market

volatility is positively related to the conditional volatility of the three-month bank

accepted bill rate. I assume volatility in cash rate surprises directly translates into

three-month bank accepted bill volatility. The alternative hypothesis, based on this

evidence and assumption, is set out below:

H7c: A positive relationship exists between the absolute size of overnight cash

rate surprises and stock return volatility

3.8 Consumer Sentiment

While I refer to consumer sentiment as a macroeconomic variable, it differs from the

other variables in that it is a ‘behavioural’ factor, as opposed to a ‘macro’ factor

(Harvey, Liu & Zhu 2014, p.4). My null hypothesis is that consumer sentiment has

no relationship with Australian stock market returns. Although evidence to the

contrary exists in Australia (Akhtar et al 2011), I pose this as the null hypothesis for

the sake of consistency with the null hypotheses posited for the other macroeconomic

variables above. This is also consistent with the formulation of my statistical testing

methods, which are designed to detect evidence of a relationship through rejection of

the null hypothesis. The null hypothesis, based on this rationale, is set out below:

H8: No relationship between consumer sentiment surprises and stock

returns/return volatility

De Long et al (1990) outlined behavioural theories that support an alternative

hypothesis of a positive relationship between consumer sentiment and stock returns.

Page 70: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 65

They argued irrational investors, who trade based on sentiment, induce changes in

returns that are both costly and risky for arbitrageurs to force back to fundamental

levels. This is because risk stems from the unpredictability of investor sentiment, and

arbitrageurs typically have constraints on their investment horizons. For example, an

arbitrageur may go out of business waiting for prices to return to fundamentals.

Baker and Wurgler (2007) found when investor sentiment is low, the subsequent

returns on the stocks of firms that are difficult to value tend to become high (relative

to their long-run average). This suggests that low sentiment leads to the stocks of such

firms being initially undervalued. In the US, Qiu and Welch (2006) found the

consumer confidence index is a proxy for investor sentiment, and that it correlates

with the excess rate of return on small firms, thus linking investor sentiment to

consumer sentiment. Taken together, these studies suggest consumer sentiment is

positively related to returns; however, the studies emphasise this sentiment is linked

to irrational beliefs about future corporate cash flows. Another perspective is that

consumer sentiment is a forecaster of, and may even cause, changes in consumption

expenditure (Carroll, Fuhrer & Wilcox 1994). This could indirectly affect stock

returns through changes in output (or real GDP).

Other research shows changes in consumer sentiment precede changes in output.

Matsusaka and Sbordone (1995) hypothesised that expectations of lower income (low

consumer sentiment) lead to lower orders of goods produced to buyer specifications,

and which cannot easily be resold without significant loss. As a result, an economy’s

build-to-order firms experience lower employment, resulting in reduced

consumption, incomes and output. As per the discussion in Section 3.3, any effects

that consumer sentiment have on output, or real GDP, can result in an indirect effect

on stock returns. Given that real GDP is typically observed to be positively related to

Page 71: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 66

returns (see Section 3.6), this theory would suggest that consumer sentiment is

positively related to stock returns.

Akhtar et al (2011, p.1248) found the Westpac-Melbourne Institute consumer

sentiment index announcements were positively related to returns, although it was

only the decreases in consumer sentiment that were associated with negative

Australian stock market returns; positive announcements had no effect.14 The

alternative hypothesis, based on these theories and evidence, is set out below:

H8a: Bad consumer sentiment news (unexpected decrease in consumer

sentiment) decreases stock returns

With respect to volatility, De Long et al (1990) again provided theoretical support for

an alternative hypothesis; that is, investor sentiment may be positively related to stock

return volatility. They reasoned irrational investors, trading based on sentiment,

induced sustained price movements (in both directions) that are both costly and risky

for arbitrageurs to force back to fundamentals. The alternative hypothesis, based on

this theory, is outlined below:

H8b: A positive relationship exists between consumer sentiment surprises and

stock return volatility

14 Note that this is still a positive relationship, albeit asymmetric, because decreases in consumer

sentiment are related to decreases in returns meaning the variables move in the same direction

hence the correlation is positive.

Page 72: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 67

4 Methodology

4.1 Returns

Stock returns based on market indices are calculated using equation (2).

1

ln 100tt

t

pR x

p

Where:

tp is the closing share market index price on the trading day in question; and

1tp is the closing share market index price on the previous trading day.

4.2 Surprises (Unexpected Components of Announcements)

The surprise or ‘news’ series ,k tSurprise for each macroeconomic variable is

constructed using equation (3).

, 1 , ,( )k t t k t k tSurprise E Announcement Announcement

Where:

1 ,( )t k tE Announcement is the forecast value for period t prior to period t ; and

,k tAnnouncement are the realised values of each announcement at time t .

A positive value of the ,k tSurprise series for each of the k macroeconomic variables

indicates the expected value is high relative to the outcome. The interpretation of

whether this is considered good or bad news is not straightforward and is discussed

with direct reference to the results (Chapter 6).

Page 73: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 68

The surprise series reflects the unexpected components of the forecasts or news. News

by definition is new and unexpected information. Conversely, the expected

component of an announcement is assumed not to be news to the market.

4.3 Control Variables

US Returns

US stock market returns are calculated using equation (4).

,

, 1

ln 100US t

t

US t

pUS x

p

Where ,US tp is the US stock market index level on day t .

Oil Returns

Oil returns are calculated using equation (5).

1

ln 100tt

t

fOil x

f

Where tf is the oil future price index level on day t .

Term Spread

The term spread on government bonds is calculated using equation (6).

, ,t long t short t

TS y y

Where:

,long ty is the yield reported by Bloomberg, based on their 10-year government

bond index, and expressed as a whole number percentage; and

Page 74: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 69

,short ty is the yield reported by Bloomberg, based on their 5-year government

bond index, and expressed as a whole number percentage (details in Section 5.3).

Default Spread

The default spread on Australian corporate bonds is calculated using equation (7).

, ,t corporate t government tDS y y

Where:

,corporate ty is the yield on one of Bloomberg’s Australian corporate bond indices,

expressed as a whole number percentage (details in Section 5.3); and

,government ty is the yield on a Bloomberg government bond index that is of the

same tenor as ,corporate ty , expressed as a whole number percentage.

Page 75: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 70

4.4 Returns Estimation

The form shown in (8) is used to model returns. It is an autoregressive moving average

(ARMA) specification that is fitted to observed returns.

, ,

, , , ,

1 1

Fri

Hol t i Day i t

i Mon

TS CSI

j Control i t k Surprise k t

j US k Unem

p q

i t i i t i t

i i

t c Hol Day

Control Surprise

r

R a a a

a a

a b

Where:

tR are the daily log percentage returns on the stock market indices;

ca is a constant;

Hola is the coefficient on tHol dummy variables assigned to days after holidays;

,

Fri

i Day

i Mon

a

are the coefficients on dummy variables for Monday through to Friday,

but excluding Wednesday;

,

TS

j Control

j US

a

are the coefficients on each of the control variables: tUS , t

Oil , tDS

and tTS ;

,

CSI

k Surprise

k Unem

a

are the coefficients on the macroeconomic surprise variables;

1

p

i t i

i

ra

are the coefficients on the autoregressive lags up to order p;

1

q

i t i

i

b

are the coefficients on the moving average terms up to order q; and

t are the regression residuals.

For the sake of parsimonious presentation 1 1

p q

i t i i t i t

i i

ra b

is abbreviated to ( )M

.

Page 76: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 71

Day-of-the-week and holiday variables are used to capture any return effects that may be

attributed to different days of the week (Gultekin 1983, Fama 1991).

The holiday variable accounts for return effects resulting from information accumulated

when the Australian Stock Exchange is closed. Upon opening after a holiday, it is thought

this information is factored in.

The surprise series coefficient ,k Surprisea

quantifies the sensitivity of daily returns to each

of the k macroeconomic surprises. An additional specification is tested, replacing:

, ,

CSI

k Surprise k t

k Unem

Surprisea

with

, ,

, ,

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k tD Da a

.

Where:

,

Surprise

k tD is a dummy variable that takes the value of one if ,k tSurprise does not

equal zero or zero otherwise; and

,

Bad News

k tD is a bad news dummy variable that takes the value of one if the

announcement contains bad news, or is otherwise zero.

This additional specification is designed to capture the average effect of announcement

days containing good news surprises ,k Surprisea and the average effect of announcement

days containing bad news surprises. The latter is found by adding the marginal effect of

bad news , k Bad Newsa to good news , , k Surprise k Bad Newsaa . This specification helps to

determine if good news has a different effect on returns than bad news.

This returns equation is estimated using Eviews 7 econometric software, which fits the

specification using the least squares (NLS and ARMA) method. It is estimated alone and

then simultaneously (using the autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity method in

Eviews) with the volatility specification outlined below.

Page 77: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 72

4.5 Volatility Estimation

This study uses an EGARCH specification to model volatility, and was chosen after

carrying out the analysis conducted in Appendix B. As noted in Section 2.3.2:

Conclusions from the Literature, Kim’s (2003, p.618) EGARCH model was one of the

most successful for finding significant relationships between foreign macroeconomic

surprises and the Australian stock market.

The EGARCH specification is set out in (9).

, ,

, , , ,

1 1 1

2

2

ln( )

ln( )

Fri

Hol t i Day i t

i Mon

TS CSI

j Control i t k surprise k tj US k Unem

p qrt j t j

j j j

j j jt j t j

t

t j

Hol b Day

b Control Surprise

b

b

Where:

2ln( )t is the log of the estimated conditional variance or volatility;

is a constant;

Holb is the coefficient on tHol dummy variables assigned to days after holidays;

,

Fri

i Day

i Tue

b

are the coefficients on dummy variables for Monday through to Friday,

but excluding Wednesday;

,

TS

j Control

j US

b

are the coefficients on each of the control variables: tUS , tOil , tDS

and tTS ;

,

CSI

k

k Unem

surpriseb

are the coefficients on the absolute value of surprise variables;

1

p

j

i

are the coefficients on the lagged GARCH effects up to order p;

Page 78: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 73

1

r

j

j

are the coefficients capturing the sign or leverage effects of the

standardised residuals t j

t j

up to order r = q;

1

q

j

j

are the coefficients on absolute value of the standardised residuals t j

t j

capturing ARCH effects up to order q; and

t j is the estimated conditional standard deviation at time ( t j ) used to

standardise the regression residuals t .15

Again, for the sake of parsimonious presentation,

1 1 1

2ln( )p qr

t j t j

j j j

j j jt j t j

t j

is abbreviated to ( )V .

The estimated conditional variance, and hence standard deviation, is based on an

assumption made regarding the distribution of standardised residuals. This assumption is

investigated in Appendix B.

Again, holiday, day-of-the-week and control variables are included (see Section 4.4).

The coefficient on the absolute value of surprises ,

CSI

k surprisek Unem

b

captures the sensitivity of

return volatility to the absolute size of macroeconomic surprises. As with returns, an

additional specification is tested, replacing:

, ,

CSI

k surprise k tk Unem

Surpriseb

with

, , , ,

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

D Db b

15 The volatility equation used here is limited to controlling for the potentially differing effects of

negative and positive values of the control variables on volatility. Using the absolute magnitude of

movements in control variable returns would be a fruitful addition to the research allowing the

absolute size effects of control variables on volatility to be captured.

Page 79: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 74

Where:

,

Surprise

k tD is a dummy variable that takes the value of one if ,k tSurprise does not

equal zero or zero otherwise; and

,

Bad News

k tD is a bad news dummy variable that takes the value of one if the

announcement contains bad news and zero otherwise.

This additional specification is designed to capture the average effect of announcement

days that contain good news surprises ,k Surpriseb and the average effect of announcement

days containing bad news surprises. The latter is found by adding the marginal effect of

bad news , k Bad Newsb to good news: , , k Surprise k Bad Newsb b . This specification allows us

to determine whether good news has a different effect on return volatility to bad news.

Page 80: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 75

5 Data

This chapter sets out the variables of interest for my study and the data used to

represent those variables. Stock returns are the independent variable explained by

macroeconomic surprises, so here, I detail the data I intend to use, as well as their

statistical characteristics. The macroeconomic surprises (as the explanatory variables)

are then explained outlining the forecasts and the announcement series used to

calculate surprises and statistical characteristics. The chapter finishes with an outline

of the control variables, which are used to remove the effects of other factors known

to affect Australian stock returns.

All variables are observed on a daily basis over the period January 2000 to December

2013.

5.1 Stock Market Indices

The ASX All Ordinaries index is the most commonly used stock market index in

Australian literature. This index was used in the work of Kearns & Pagan (1993),

Brooks et al (1999), Kim & In (2002), Groenewold (2003), Kim (2003), Chaudhuri

& Smiles (2004) and Akhtar et al (2011). However, as of 3 April 2000, the All

Ordinaries index was restructured by the ASX to reflect a greater proportion of the

market and include the 500 largest companies. Prior to this, it reflected only 229–330

stocks (Worthington 2009, p.46).

ASX National Manager of Market Data, John Ying, noted in September 1999:

‘The existing liquidity requirements [on the All Ordinaries index] will be removed

as these are far more appropriate to benchmark indices.’ (Australian Stock

Exchange 1999)

Page 81: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 76

The announcement was made in relation to the re-establishment of the All Ordinaries

as an index to reflect overall market movements, and also the establishment of new

indices, including the ASX 200 as a ‘benchmark’ index for portfolio performance

benchmarking. The All Ordinaries index prior to 2000 is, in fact, more comparable to

the ASX 200 index, which was developed post 2000.

It is important to note the relaxation of liquidity requirements in the All Ordinaries

index is likely to lead to thin trading issues in the index, such as delayed price

reactions. This could possibly result in the All Ordinaries index being relatively slow

to reflect new information because it now includes a large number of small market

capitalisation stocks, which can trade infrequently. I have, therefore, opted to use the

ASX 200 index in this study. For the sake of robustness, however, I will use both the

ASX 200 and All Ordinaries indices to determine if the results are sensitive to the

choice of index.

Also in this study, I use the total returns (also known as cumulative) indices because

this version of the index is conventionally used in stock return studies. However, it is

worth noting Groenewold (2003, p.460) found little difference in his results, between

those estimated on the cumulative index and those estimate on the non-cumulative

index.

Daily observations of the S&P ASX 200 and the All Ordinaries total returns index

were acquired from Datastream and used as the measure of market returns.16 Daily

percentage returns for both indices were calculated as set out in 4.1.

16 The indices were not adjusted for dividend effects. The Datastream code for the S&P ASX 200

total returns index is ‘ASX200I(RI)’. The code for the All Ordinaries total returns index is

‘ASXAORD(RI)’.

Page 82: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 77

The ASX 200 Indices give 3652 daily returns observations to work with, spanning the

period 4 January 2000 to 31 December 2013. The series plotted in Figure 1 appears

to exhibit volatility clustering, particularly around 2008 and 2011, which is suggestive

of time varying volatility.

Figure 1 ASX 200 Index Total Daily Returns

The summary statistics for the series in Table 3 indicate daily returns have a

significant positive bias, as indicated by the mean of 0.0318 per cent. The minimum

daily return of -8.7 per cent occurred on 10 October 2008 with the onset of the GFC.

The maximum of 5.6 per cent is smaller by comparison and occurred just a few days

after the minimum return on 13 October 2008.

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

03/0

1/2

00

0

31/0

7/2

00

0

26/0

2/2

00

1

24/0

9/2

00

1

22/0

4/2

00

2

18/1

1/2

00

2

16/0

6/2

00

3

12/0

1/2

00

4

09/0

8/2

00

4

07/0

3/2

00

5

03/1

0/2

00

5

01/0

5/2

00

6

27/1

1/2

00

6

25/0

6/2

00

7

21/0

1/2

00

8

18/0

8/2

00

8

16/0

3/2

00

9

12/1

0/2

00

9

10/0

5/2

01

0

06/1

2/2

01

0

04/0

7/2

01

1

30/0

1/2

01

2

27/0

8/2

01

2

25/0

3/2

01

3

21/1

0/2

01

3

per cent

Page 83: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 78

Table 3 ASX 200 Index Total Daily Returns –Summary Statistics

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns (%)

Mean 0.0318

Standard Error 0.0173

Median 0.0567

Mode NA

Standard Deviation 1.0311

Sample Variance 1.0632

Kurtosis 6

Skewness 0

Range 14.33

Minimum -8.71

Maximum 5.63

Count 3542

Like the ASX 200 returns series, 3542 observations were available for the All

Ordinaries index from 4 January 2000 to 31 December 2013. Visually, the All

Ordinaries daily total returns (Figure 2) indicate a very similar pattern to the ASX 200

returns series. Clustering of volatility in the All Ordinaries returns coincides with

same time periods as the ASX 200, notably 2008 and 2011.

Figure 2 Australian All Ordinaries Index Total Daily Returns

Page 84: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 79

The differences between the All Ordinaries index and the ASX 200 returns only really

become apparent in the summary statistics (shown in Table 4). The range and standard

deviation of the All Ordinaries returns over the period are marginally smaller than

those for the ASX 200, indicating the inclusion of small market capitalised stocks

lowers the level and variability of returns over the period. The distribution also has a

slightly different shape to the ASX 200 returns, with the mean of 0.0314 sitting further

below the median of 0.0658 and a negative skew of one. This suggests a marginally

higher probability of lower returns than the ASX 200 index.

Table 4 All Ordinaries Index Total Daily Returns – Summary Statistics

All Ordinaries Daily Returns (%)

Mean 0.0314

Standard Error 0.0168

Median 0.0658

Mode NA

Standard Deviation 0.9990

Sample Variance 0.9979

Kurtosis 6

Skewness -1

Range 13.92

Minimum -8.55

Maximum 5.36

Count 3542

5.1.1 Stationarity of Stock Returns

The ASX 200 and All Ordinaries return series were tested for stationarity to ensure

they were suitable for time series modelling. An examination of Figure 1 and Figure

2 did not indicate any drift or trend in the daily returns. Accordingly, the augmented

Dicky-Fuller test without drift or trend was carried out to test for the null hypothesis

of a unit root or non-stationarity.

Page 85: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 80

Table 5 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Unit Root Tests - No Drift or Trend

Total Returns Series Index test-statistic Critical Value at 5 per cent

Standard and Poor’s ASX 200 -41.0011 -1.95

All Ordinaries -40.3838 -1.95

The results in Table 5 show the absolute value of the test statistics of both series were

far below the critical value, thus strongly rejecting the hypothesis of a unit root. Based

on the strength of these results, I considered it unnecessary to carry out any additional

stationarity tests.

5.2 Macroeconomic Surprises

As outlined in 4.2, macroeconomic surprises are the difference between the expected

component of the announcement (the forecast) and announcement itself. The equation

is reproduced in (10).

, 1 , ,( )k t t k t k tSurprise E Announcement Announcement

Where:

1 ,( )t k tE Announcement is the forecast value for period t immediately prior to

period t ; and

,k tAnnouncement are the realised values of each announcement at time t .

5.2.1 Forecasts

Consensus forecasts were obtained from Money Market Services (MMS)

International, a former subsidiary of S&P. MMS Asia surveys the forecasts of market-

making participants in Australia (Haver 2013). The medians of these surveyed

forecasts (as first reported) and their corresponding dates are accessed through

Haverselect. MMS surveys are prevalent in the literature review (see Singh 1993 &

1995, and Kim 2003, Becker, Finnerty and Friedman 1995 and Flannery and

Page 86: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 81

Protopapadakis 2002) with Singh providing evidence to suggest the survey data has

superior information content to that of basic ARIMA forecasts. Unemployment

information forecasts are available from 2003, while balance of trade, retail sales, the

PPI and CPI are available from 2003. The MMS Asia forecasts are outlined in Table

6.

Table 6 Money Market Services Consensus Macroeconomic Forecasts

Forecast

Original

Source

Format

Frequency Observation

Period Missing Forecasts

Unemployment per cent level Monthly December 2003 -

December 2013 2

Balance of Trade $ Billion Monthly June 2005 –

December 2013 0

Retail Sales

per cent change

from previous

month

Monthly June 2005 -

December 2013 1

Producer Price Index

per cent change

from previous

quarter

Quarterly September 2005 -

December 2013 0

Consumer Price Index

per cent change

from previous

quarter

Quarterly September 2005 -

September 2013 0

The observation period relates to periods (for example quarter or month) when the

macroeconomic variable was under observation.17

Real GDP, the consumer sentiment index and the overnight cash rate forecasts could

not be adequately sourced from MMS. I used other methods to obtain these forecasts,

which are outlined in their respective sections. The structure of these forecasts is

outlined in Table 7.

17 As distinct from the announcement day date which is when the value for the macroeconomic

variable observed during the observation period is released.

Page 87: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 82

Table 7 Other Macroeconomic Forecasts

Forecast Original Source

Format Frequency Observation Period

Missing

Forecasts

Real GDP per cent change from last

quarter Quarterly

March 2000 –

September 2013 0

Overnight Cash Rate per cent level Monthly September 2003 -

December 2013 0

Consumer Sentiment index level Monthly April 2004 – December

2013 0

5.2.2 Announcements

With respect to macroeconomic announcements, I consider data releases from the

Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) and Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) to be the

most relevant sources. I view these authorities as the most unbiased source of

information available to investors, given their non-commercial objectives.

Announcements made by the ABS included balance of goods and services (trade),

CPI, PPI, real GDP, unemployment and retail sales. Overnight cash rate

announcements were those made by the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA). The

Westpac-Melbourne Institute consumer sentiment index was the only announcement

sourced from a non-federal government organisation. I believe the value of the index

is sufficiently impartial to commercial interests, on account of the accuracy of the

index value itself giving it its commercial value. The announcements are outlined in

Table 8.

Page 88: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 83

Table 8 Macroeconomic Announcement Values

Announcement Format Frequency Date Range Source

Unemployment Per cent level Monthly January 2004 –

December 2013

Australian Bureau of

Statistics

Balance of Trade $ Billion Monthly August 2005–

December 2013

Australian Bureau of

Statistics

Retail Sales

per cent change

from previous

month

Monthly August 2005–

December 2013

Australian Bureau of

Statistics

Producer Price Index

per cent change

from previous

quarter

Quarterly October 2005–

November 2013

Australian Bureau of

Statistics

Consumer Price Index

per cent change

from previous

quarter

Quarterly October 2005–

October 2013

Australian Bureau of

Statistics

Real GDP per cent change

from last quarter Quarterly

January 2000–

December 2013

Australian Bureau of

Statistics

Overnight Cash Rate per cent level Monthly September 2003 –

December 2013

Reserve Bank of

Australia

Consumer Sentiment index level Monthly April 2004 –

December 2013

Westpac Melbourne

Institute

Accurately pairing the timing of macroeconomic surprises with their associated stock

market returns necessitated matching the specific date of the unrevised value to the

announcement itself. It was important to use the unrevised value because revised

values contained information that was not available on the date when the

announcement was first released and, therefore, not reflected in returns. Use of the

revised values could have masked the impact of the original unrevised values on the

stock market, thus obscuring any underlying relationship that may have existed, and

making it undetectable in regression analysis.

Unrevised macroeconomic announcement values for each of the ABS announcements

were sourced from MMS. The availability of unrevised announcements was the main

constraint on the number of observations available for analysis in my study. This is

because not all series were available over the entire period from January 2000 to

December 2013.

Page 89: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 84

5.2.3 Surprises

Before applying equation (1), data that was not expressed in unitless measures (such

as a percentage level or percentage change) was converted to percentage measures.

This was for consistency with stock market returns, which are expressed in

percentages.

The summary statistics for the resulting surprise series are shown in Table 9.

Table 9 Summary Statistics for Macroeconomic Surprises

(%) Unemployment Balance of

Trade

Retail

Sales

Producer Price

Index

Consumer

Price Index Real GDP Cash Rates

Consumer

Sentiment

Index

Mean 0.05 7.41 0.01 0.02 0 0.26 -0.01 -0.22

Standard

Error 0.02 37.01 0.07 0.1 0.05 0.07 0.01 0.51

Median 0.1 2.61 0 0.1 0 0.29 -0.01 -0.53

Mode 0 0 0.4 -0.2 -0.2 NA 0 NA

Standard

Deviation 0.21 371.96 0.66 0.57 0.28 0.53 0.08 5.54

Range 2.1 5048.02 4.4 2.4 1.1 2.88 0.75 28.98

Minimum -1.4 -2203.57 -2.4 -1.4 -0.6 -0.78 -0.25 -13.18

Maximum 0.7 2844.44 2 1 0.5 2.09 0.5 15.80

Count 118 101 100 33 33 55 114 117

Each series is explained in detail below.

Unemployment

The unemployment rate is the percentage of people in the labour force who are

unemployed as measured by the ABS monthly labour force survey (Australian Bureau

of Statistics 2014a). For example, if the results of the monthly survey show 12 million

people are in the labour force, but of these, 708,000 are classified as being

unemployed, the unemployment rate would be 5.9 per cent. The raw unemployment

Page 90: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 85

announcements and forecasts are expressed as monthly seasonally adjusted

percentage levels.18

This percentage format was desirable for the purposes of my regression, and no

further conversion was required. MMS forecasts were available from December 2003

and paired with unrevised unemployment announcements from this point on. One

unemployment announcement was missing (August 2013) and coincided with one of

two missing MMS forecasts. These missing values resulted in the loss of two of the

120 observations spanning December 2003 to November 2013. Announced values for

months after November 2013 were not used because they were announced after

December 2013 – the limit of my study’s observation period. In total, that left me with

118 pairs of observations.

The announced values were subtracted from the forecasts to create the unemployment

surprise series plotted in Figure 3.

18 The seasonally adjusted series removes the effects of estimated month-to-month seasonal variation

in unemployment.

Page 91: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 86

Figure 3 Unemployment Rate Surprises

The mean value of the forecast error was 0.05 per cent, with the standard error of 0.02

per cent, indicating a statistically significant upward bias in the forecasts.19 The

implication of these results is that the announced unemployment rate is often lower

than expected. This is highlighted in Figure 3 by the large number of values above the

zero axis representing overestimates.

Balance of Trade

The balance of trade measures the net dollar value of goods and services exported

against those imported, on a monthly basis. The data from the ABS is expressed in

seasonally adjusted billions of dollars (Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014b).20

19 This assumes that the series is normally distributed. 20 Seasonally adjusted estimates are derived by estimating the systematic calendar related influences

and removing them from the original estimates see

http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/[email protected]/90a12181d877a6a6ca2568b5007b861c/5d5081176d

8bd2cdca256f960075c84a!OpenDocument for more details.

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

15/0

1/2

00

4

13/0

5/2

00

4

09/0

9/2

00

4

13/0

1/2

00

5

12/0

5/2

00

5

08/0

9/2

00

5

12/0

1/2

00

6

11/0

5/2

00

6

07/0

9/2

00

6

11/0

1/2

00

7

10/0

5/2

00

7

06/0

9/2

00

7

17/0

1/2

00

8

08/0

5/2

00

8

11/0

9/2

00

8

15/0

1/2

00

9

07/0

5/2

00

9

10/0

9/2

00

9

14/0

1/2

01

0

13/0

5/2

01

0

09/0

9/2

01

0

13/0

1/2

01

1

12/0

5/2

01

1

08/0

9/2

01

1

19/0

1/2

01

2

10/0

5/2

01

2

06/0

9/2

01

2

17/0

1/2

01

3

09/0

5/2

01

3

12/0

9/2

01

3

per cent

Page 92: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 87

The series are converted to percentages for consistency with stock market returns in

the regression. The forecast data was converted to percentage changes using equation

(11).

1

1

( )(% ) 100

( )

t t tt t

t

E BOT BOTE BOT x

absolute value BOT

Where:

1( )t tE BOT are the balance of trade forecasts in billions of dollars;

BOT is the actual balance of trade in billions of dollars; and

( )tabsolute value BOT is the absolute value of actual BOT in billions of dollars.

The actual balance of trade data was also converted to a percentage change as shown

in (12).

1

1% 100 ( )

t tt

t

BOT BOTBOT x

absolute value BOT

The absolute values in the denominator were required to preserve the correct sign of

the change. It should be noted that values close to zero in period t might result in very

large percentage changes in period 1t . MMS forecasts were only available from

June 2005, giving me 103 observations to work with. Two observations were lost

because the November and December 2013 observation period announcements

occurred in 2014, which is outside the range of my study.

The resulting 101 observations are plotted in Figure 4.

Page 93: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 88

Figure 4 Balance of Trade Surprises

The large ‘spike’ and ‘dip’ shown in September 2012 and July 2013 result from the

trade balance being unusually close to zero in the month prior. That is, the

denominator in equation (11) and (12) was unusually close to zero and as a result

dramatically scaled up the expected and actual percentage change calculated by those

equations. In order to maintain consistency with the other macroeconomic surprises

and avoid manipulation of data which may be interpreted as arbitrary the outliers were

left in the data set.21

The mean forecast error is positive. However, it is very small compared to the mean’s

standard error, suggesting it is not significantly different from zero.22 The median

forecast error, however, is also greater than zero, which confirms overly optimistic

21 I note that Andersen et al (2007, p.258) implement an alternative data preparation technique in

calculating macroeconomic announcement surprises where the surprise is divided by the standard

deviation of the surprise component. This technique may possibly mitigate the effect of balance of

trade outliers. 22 This assumes a normal distribution.

-3000

-2000

-1000

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

02/0

8/2

00

5

06/1

2/2

00

5

03/0

4/2

00

6

11/0

8/2

00

6

29/1

1/2

00

6

03/0

4/2

00

7

01/0

8/2

00

7

03/1

2/2

00

7

07/0

4/2

00

8

31/0

7/2

00

8

04/1

2/2

00

8

02/0

4/2

00

9

05/0

8/2

00

9

09/1

2/2

00

9

01/0

4/2

01

0

04/0

8/2

01

0

02/1

2/2

01

0

05/0

4/2

01

1

03/0

8/2

01

1

12/1

2/2

01

1

04/0

4/2

01

2

02/0

8/2

01

2

07/1

2/2

01

2

03/0

4/2

01

3

06/0

8/2

01

3

05/1

2/2

01

3

per cent

Page 94: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 89

balance of trade forecasts were common over the period. The two extreme values are

of a similar magnitude to each other at 2844 and -2203 per cent.

Retail Sales

Retail sales are the monthly dollar value turnover of retail trade for Australian

business. The data reported by the ABS, represent month-to-month percentage

changes in dollar values that are seasonally adjusted (Australian Bureau of Statistics

2014c).23 No conversion to percentage was therefore required. Forecasts were only

available for June 2005 onward with one value missing in March 2012, reducing the

number of observations available for my study to 102. Additionally, forecasts for

November and December 2013 were not announced until after 2013, and hence, are

outside the observation period for my study. This further reduced the number of

observations to 100. The series are plotted in Figure 5.

23 Estimating the systematic calendar related influences and removing them from the original

estimates derive seasonally adjusted estimates. See

http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/[email protected]/90a12181d877a6a6ca2568b5007b861c/5d5081176d

8bd2cdca256f960075c84a!OpenDocument for more details.

Page 95: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 90

Figure 5 Retail Sales Surprises

The series exhibits a higher level of volatility from 2008 to 2010 than for the earlier

period. This could be associated with the onset of the global financial crisis. Also, the

ABS considered data on retail sales from July to November 2008 as:

‘of limited use for measuring month-to-month estimates because of the increased

volatility in these series due to the smaller sample size and the rotation effect of

having a different third of the sample reporting each month’

Consequently, at the time of this study, the ABS did not make seasonally adjusted

monthly change retail sales data available over this brief period. The data as it was

first announced however, was available through MMS and this is used to construct

the forecast errors reported in Figure 5. Statistical precision of the ABS figures is of

limited relevance – it is the stock market’s reaction to these announced figures that is

the central concern of this study.

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

02/0

8/2

00

5

30/1

1/2

00

5

31/0

3/2

00

6

02/0

8/2

00

6

30/1

1/2

00

6

02/0

4/2

00

7

01/0

8/2

00

7

04/1

2/2

00

7

04/0

4/2

00

8

31/0

7/2

00

8

02/1

2/2

00

8

01/0

4/2

00

9

04/0

8/2

00

9

03/1

2/2

00

9

31/0

3/2

01

0

03/0

8/2

01

0

02/1

2/2

01

0

31/0

3/2

01

1

03/0

8/2

01

1

01/1

2/2

01

1

03/0

4/2

01

2

02/0

8/2

01

2

03/1

2/2

01

2

04/0

4/2

01

3

05/0

8/2

01

3

03/1

2/2

01

3

per cent

Page 96: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 91

The mean absolute deviation in percentage changes was 0.01, which was not

significantly different from zero in light of the mean standard error of 0.07.24 This

suggests that forecasts are not biased. Additionally, the median is zero, which also

tends to indicate unbiasedness. However, the mode is 0.4, suggesting the most

common outcome is an overestimate.

Producer Price Index

The final commodities PPI measures the quarterly change in the price index

established by the ABS for products ready to be sold for immediate consumption,

capital formation, or export.

The quarter-on-quarter seasonally adjusted series is published as a per cent change,

and requires no conversion for consistency with the unit of measurement used for

stock returns (Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014d).25 Forecasts were available from

the 2005 September quarter onward, reducing the number of observations available

to 34. The December 2013 quarter announcement was not released until 2014,

reducing the final sample to 33 observations.26 The series are plotted in Figure 6.

24 This assumes that the series is normally distributed. 25 Estimating the systematic calendar related influences and removing them from the original

estimates derive seasonally adjusted estimates. See

http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/[email protected]/90a12181d877a6a6ca2568b5007b861c/5d5081176d

8bd2cdca256f960075c84a!OpenDocument for more details. 26 The year 2014 is beyond my study’s observation period.

Page 97: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 92

Figure 6 Producer Price Index Surprises

The mean of 0.02 per cent is not significant. The median and mode confirm the lack

of clear evidence of bias with the median exhibiting a slightly positive bias of 0.1,

while the mode conversely shows a slightly negative bias of -0.2.

Consumer Price Index

The CPI, reported on a quarterly basis, measures the general level of prices for

consumer goods and services consumed by Australian households. The index is

expressed as a quarter-on-quarter per cent change, or quarterly ‘inflation’, and no

transformation of the data is required to make it unitless (Australian Bureau of

Statistics 2014e).

Only 33 CPI forecasts were available from MMS from September 2005 onwards,

paring back the number of observations available for analysis from 56 to 33. The

surprises based on these observations are plotted in Figure 7.

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

24/1

0/2

00

5

15/0

6/2

00

6

23/1

0/2

00

6

23/0

4/2

00

7

22/1

0/2

00

7

21/0

4/2

00

8

20/1

0/2

00

8

20/0

4/2

00

9

26/1

0/2

00

9

27/0

4/2

01

0

25/1

0/2

01

0

21/0

4/2

01

1

24/1

0/2

01

1

23/0

4/2

01

2

02/1

1/2

01

2

03/0

5/2

01

3

01/1

1/2

01

3

per cent

Page 98: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 93

Figure 7 Consumer Price Index Surprises

The surprises or forecast errors appear to be fairly symmetrically distributed around

zero. This is confirmed by the mean and median returning a value of zero. The most

common surprise, however, is negative as shown by the mode of -0.2. This indicates,

if anything, the market tends to underestimate inflation.

Real Gross Domestic Product Growth

Real GDP growth measures the change in total value of goods and services produced

in Australia, holding prices constant from a particular base year. 27

The MMS real GDP consensus forecast series contained 18 forecasts spanning the

December quarter 2004 to the September quarter 2009. A more comprehensive series

of forecasts is available from the RBA spanning March 2000 to August 2011 (Reserve

Bank of Australia 2012). However, their more recent forecasts in the Statements on

27 Estimating the systematic calendar related influences and removing them from the original

estimates derive seasonally adjusted estimates. See

http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/[email protected]/90a12181d877a6a6ca2568b5007b861c/5d5081176d

8bd2cdca256f960075c84a!OpenDocument for more details.

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.62

6/1

0/2

00

5

26/0

4/2

00

6

25/1

0/2

00

6

24/0

4/2

00

7

24/1

0/2

00

7

23/0

4/2

00

8

22/1

0/2

00

8

22/0

4/2

00

9

28/1

0/2

00

9

28/0

4/2

01

0

27/1

0/2

01

0

27/0

4/2

01

1

26/1

0/2

01

1

24/0

4/2

01

2

24/1

0/2

01

2

24/0

4/2

01

3

23/1

0/2

01

3

per cent

Page 99: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 94

Monetary Policy are available only for June and December, meaning only 26

observations are available from 2000.

Additionally, in their November 2012 discussion paper, the RBA highlighted their

real GDP forecasts have very little explanatory power (Tulip & Wallace 2012, p.30).

As a result, I concluded forecasts might not be reliable or frequent enough to produce

robust estimates of market expectations of real GDP growth. As an alternative, I

sourced the most up-to-date (revised) real GDP data from the ABS, dating back to

December 1959, and modelled expectations on a naïve model based on an expanding

window of the historical data. This is similar to the approach outlined in Singh 1993

and 1995.

Augmented Dickey-Fuller unit root tests were carried out on the 216 observations of

the seasonally adjusted per cent change series spanning December 1959 to September

2013 (see Table 10).

Using the augmented Dickey-Fuller test, the series tested as stationary (when no drift

or trend was included), indicating that an ARMA model could be meaningfully fitted.

The Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) was used to compare competing models. An

AR (1) model resulted in the lowest AIC where only the intercept was statistically

significant. This suggests the historical mean of the full information set produces the

best forecast, and was used accordingly to produce forecasts.

Page 100: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 95

Table 10 Real GDP Growth – ADF Test and Akaike Information Criterion

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

t-statistic Critical Value

10 per cent 5 per cent 1 per cent

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test (no

drift or trend) -5.8151 -2.58 -1.95 -1.62

ARMA (p,q)

Akaike

Information

Criterion

Observations

216

(0,0) No Solution

(1,0) 650.13

(0,1) 650.18

(1,1) 652.04

(1,2) 650.76

(2,1) 653.9

(2,2) 653.53

(2,0) 652.56

(0,2) 651.94

parameter Value standard

error t statistic p-value

AR(1) -0.0647 0.06777 -0.954 0.34

Intercept 0.9338 0.09461 9.87 <0.0001***

A forecast for each of the 214 quarters from June 1960 to September 2013 was based

on the mean of all of the ABS observations preceding each quarter.28

Real GDP data was expressed as seasonally adjusted quarter-on-quarter per cent

changes, and so, required no conversion to percentages (Australian Bureau of

Statistics 2014f). All real GDP figures, as first announced by the ABS, were available

from MMS for the entire observation period in the study consisting of 56 quarters. I

used the real GDP estimates (explained above) as forecasts. The only constraint paring

back the observations for this series was the release date for the December 2013

28 No forecast was made for December 1959 and March 1960, as at least two observations are

required to produce an average.

Page 101: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 96

quarter, which was outside the observation period (after 2013); this resulted in the

loss of one observation. The 55 observed surprises are plotted in Figure 8.

Figure 8 Real GDP Surprises

Real GDP growth surprises appear to exhibit a significant upward bias, particularly

after 2007, which is confirmed by summary statistics. The mean of 0.26 is upward

biased and has a standard error of 0.07. The median of 0.26 is similarly upward biased.

This is likely a result of a number of quarters of unusually low actual growth deviating

from the naïve model’s predictions, particularly after 2007.29

Policy Cash Rate

The policy cash rate in my study is the overnight cash rate. That is, the interest rate at

which financial institutions borrow and lend in the overnight money market. The RBA

29 This assumes a normal distribution.

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

14/0

6/2

00

0

13/1

2/2

00

0

06/0

6/2

00

1

05/1

2/2

00

1

05/0

6/2

00

2

04/1

2/2

00

2

04/0

6/2

00

3

03/1

2/2

00

3

02/0

6/2

00

4

01/1

2/2

00

4

01/0

6/2

00

5

07/1

2/2

00

5

07/0

6/2

00

6

06/1

2/2

00

6

06/0

6/2

00

7

05/1

2/2

00

7

04/0

6/2

00

8

03/1

2/2

00

8

03/0

6/2

00

9

16/1

2/2

00

9

02/0

6/2

01

0

01/1

2/2

01

0

01/0

6/2

01

1

07/1

2/2

01

1

06/0

6/2

01

2

05/1

2/2

01

2

05/0

6/2

01

3

04/1

2/2

01

3

per cent

Page 102: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 97

sets targets for this rate in its implementation of monetary policy, which flows through

to other interest rates charged on funds in the Australian economy.

I use the market’s expectations as overnight cash rate forecasts. The expected

overnight cash rate target was derived from the price of 30-day interbank cash rate

futures contracts. The data used was a generic, and sourced from Bloomberg using

the ‘IB CMDTY’ ticker over the period August 2003 to December 2013.

The ‘latest’ price for the futures contract was used, relating to settlement in the month

in which the cash rate announcement was being made. The latest price was the price

observed the day immediately prior to the cash rate announcement, which virtually

always took place on the first Tuesday of every month.30

The formula shown in (13) was used to derive the expected value for the cash rate

announced the next day.

1t b

ta

x r nr

n

Where:

1tr is the expected value for the cash rate announced the next day;

x is 100 minus the contract price, for that month, prevailing on the close of the

day prior to the announcement;

tr is the rate prevailing prior to the announcement;

bn is the proportion of days in the month before and including the day of the

announcement; and

an is the proportion of days in the month after the announcement.

30 Except for January, where no announcement was made. For months where Tuesday was the first

day of the month, Bloomberg data had to be manually retrieved to augment the ‘generic’ 30-day

series. This is because the generic series futures prices are always aligned with the month for

which the data is being retrieved.

Page 103: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 98

Only values for February through to December were reported, as announcements were

only scheduled only for these months. This resulted in 112 one-day-ahead expected

values, which were used as forecasts.

Policy cash rate data was expressed in percentage levels, which is consistent with the

ASX 200 returns in the regression equation (in terms of being unitless), and no

transformation was required (Reserve Bank of Australia 2013). The forecasts implied

on the first Tuesday of every month (except for January), using the methodology

outlined above, were paired accordingly with their date and the announced cash rate.

The 114 resulting forecast surprises are shown in Figure 9.

Figure 9 Interest Rate Surprises

The maximum cash rate surprise is 0.5 per cent. This occurred when the cash rate was

dropped unexpectedly by this amount in October 2008 with the onset of the GFC. The

forecasts do not show any significant evidence of bias with a mean and median of -

0.01.

-0.30

-0.20

-0.10

0.00

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

0.60

02/0

9/2

00

3

06/0

1/2

00

4

04/0

5/2

00

4

07/0

9/2

00

4

01/0

2/2

00

5

07/0

6/2

00

5

04/1

0/2

00

5

07/0

3/2

00

6

04/0

7/2

00

6

05/1

2/2

00

6

01/0

5/2

00

7

06/1

1/2

00

7

04/0

3/2

00

8

01/0

7/2

00

8

04/1

1/2

00

8

03/0

3/2

00

9

07/0

7/2

00

9

03/1

1/2

00

9

02/0

3/2

01

0

03/0

8/2

01

0

07/1

2/2

01

0

03/0

5/2

01

1

06/0

9/2

01

1

07/0

2/2

01

2

05/0

6/2

01

2

02/1

0/2

01

2

05/0

2/2

01

3

02/0

7/2

01

3

05/1

1/2

01

3

per cent

Page 104: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 99

Consumer Sentiment

The Westpac-Melbourne Institute consumer sentiment index reflects consumers’

evaluations of their household finances over the past and coming year, expectations

of economic conditions over the coming years, and buying conditions for major

household items.

MMS forecasts of the index contained an insufficient number of observations to create

an adequate number of forecast errors for analysis. Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests on

the series showed the announcement series was non-stationary in levels, but stationary

in first differences (see Table 11).

This indicates that the consumer sentiment index can be modelled as an ARIMA

process to produce forecasts. The Akaike Information Criteria on a number of

specifications, modelled over the entire data set from October 1974 to June 2013,

suggested that an ARIMA (1,1,2) without an intercept was the most parsimonious fit.

An expanding window historical data set was used to estimate ARIMA (1,1,2)

specifications and produce one-step ahead forecasts. The expanding window used all

historical consumer sentiment index values dating back to October 1974, before the

month in which the forecast was made. This data was used to estimate the ARIMA

(2,1,1) specification, which in turn, was used to produce the one period ahead forecast.

For the subsequent month, the process was repeated, expanding the historical data set

by one more observation. This process was repeated for all months from January 2000

to June 2013 producing 168 forecasts.

Page 105: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 100

Table 11 Consumer Sentiment – ADF Tests and Akaike Information Criteria

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

t-statistic Critical Value

10 per cent 5 per cent 1 per cent

Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test

(no drift or trend) -5.8151 -2.58 -1.95 -1.62

ARMA (p,q) Akaike

Information

Criterion Observations

216

(0,0) No Solution

(1,0) 650.13

(0,1) 650.18

(1,1) 652.04

(1,2) 650.76

(2,1) 653.9

(2,2) 653.53

(2,0) 652.56

(0,2) 651.94

parameter Value standard

error t statistic p-value

AR(1) -0.0647 0.06777 -0.954 0.34

Intercept 0.9338 0.09461 9.87 <0.0001

The data was expressed as a seasonally adjusted index and required conversion to

percentages using the equation (14).

1

1

( )(% ) 100t t t

t t

t

E CSI CSIE CSI x

CSI

Where:

1( )t tE CSI are the modelled forecasts explained above; and

tCSI are the seasonally adjusted consumer sentiment index actual figures.

1(% )t tE CSI can be interpreted as the expected percentage change on the

current level of the CSI.

Page 106: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 101

The actuals data was also converted to percentage changes as shown in (15).

1

1% 100t tt

t

CSI CSICSI x

CSI

Equation (14) was then deducted from equation (13) to create the times series of

consumer sentiment index surprises.

On account of release dates only being available from MMS from April 2004, the

number of useful observations was reduced from 168 to 117. The sample was further

reduced to 108 on account of nine missing release dates within the set of available

dates.31 That is, some months in the MMS data set did not report the day on which the

announcement was made, and so, it is assumed no announcement occurred. The

forecast errors/surprises are plotted in Figure 10.

Figure 10 Consumer Sentiment Surprises

31 The missing release dates were for the months July, August, November and December 2004, April,

May and November 2005, July 2009 and February 2012.

-15.00

-10.00

-5.00

0.00

5.00

10.00

15.00

20.00

07/0

4/2

00

4

08/0

9/2

00

4

08/0

2/2

00

5

13/0

7/2

00

5

13/1

2/2

00

5

17/0

5/2

00

6

11/1

0/2

00

6

13/0

3/2

00

7

15/0

8/2

00

7

15/0

1/2

00

8

11/0

6/2

00

8

11/1

1/2

00

8

08/0

4/2

00

9

09/0

9/2

00

9

09/0

2/2

01

0

14/0

7/2

01

0

14/1

2/2

01

0

18/0

5/2

01

1

11/1

0/2

01

1

13/0

3/2

01

2

15/0

8/2

01

2

17/0

1/2

01

3

12/0

6/2

01

3

12/1

1/2

01

3

per cent

Page 107: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 102

All the data observations were plotted, except for the nine missing dates. Casual

observation of the plot does not reveal any bias. Additionally, the forecast over- and

underestimates do not appear to increase in magnitude with the onset of the GFC. The

mean forecast error is -0.22, which is insignificant.

5.3 Control Variables

Crude Oil

A number of oil price benchmarks are available, with Brent and West Texas

Intermediate (WTI) as the two most notable. Brent accounts for around two thirds of

global physical trade in oil, despite only accounting for one per cent of crude oil

production (Dunn & Holloway 2012, p.68). WTI has a strong US focus and recent

developments in the oil and gas market resulted in a preference for Brent as an

indicator of international oil prices. Thus, Brent was selected as the index for oil prices

in the analysis.

I found that some stock returns studies use spot prices for oil as an explanatory

variable, while others use closest to maturity futures prices. Sardosky (2001), Boyer

and Filion (2007), and Hasan and Ratti (2012) used one-month futures prices due to

spot prices being more affected by temporary, random events that introduce noise into

the analysis. I assume market participants place more weight on futures prices, which

is consistent with the recent literature. Accordingly, one-month Brent future contract

prices were sourced from Bloomberg. Missing values were replaced with the last

known price.32

The Australian Dollar contract price per barrel and returns are shown in Figure 11.

32 The Bloomberg ticker for the Brent futures index used is ‘CO1 Cmdty’.

Page 108: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 103

Figure 11 Brent Crude Oil One-Month Futures Prices and Returns

US Stock Market Index

I included the lagged daily US S&P 500 Index returns to control for international

effects on the Australian stock market. The closing index value was acquired from

Datastream and converted to Australian returns using the closing US-Australian dollar

exchange rate on each day.33 Returns were calculated using equation (7) and plotted

in Figure 12.

33 The S&P 500 index code used in data stream was ‘S&PCOMP(RI)’ divided by ‘AUUSDSP’

observations for each day.

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

AUD priceper cent

Page 109: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 104

Figure 12 Lagged US Standard and Poor’s 500 Index Returns

The returns exhibit volatility clustering in similar periods to those evident in the

Australian return series in Figure 1 and Figure 2. This suggests some commonality

may exist and inclusion of this variable is appropriate for this study.

Day of Week and Holidays

Day-of-the-week dummy variables and holiday effect dummy variables are

commonly used as control variables in return studies (see Jaffe 1984, Singh 1993 and

Kim 2003). Australian Stock Exchange holiday dates were sourced from Bloomberg.

Dates that correspond to days with no price changes were deleted from my study, and

the following day, assigned a dummy variable to control for opening price reactions

to information accruing over the holiday period.

All days of the week (except for Wednesday) were assigned their own series and

coded with a dummy variable taking the value of one if it was that particular day-of-

Page 110: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 105

the-week, or zero otherwise. This established Wednesday as the base case, against

which all other days were compared.

Term Spreads

Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002), and Groenewold (2003) included term and

default spreads in their analysis as control variables. The term spread is high on bonds

(upward sloping yield curve) during economic downturns, when future conditions are

expected to improve, also signalling high-expected returns (Fama 1991, p.1585).

Harvey (1989, p.39) explained the role of the term spread in predicting economic

growth. He reasoned that an investor’s marginal value of a dollar is high during

recessions (due to lower consumption) than in affluent times when consumption is

high. Foreseeing this, rational investors sell short-term bonds and buy long-term

bonds as insurance against an expected down turn. Holding all other factors constant,

this raises the yield on short-term bonds (through reduced price) and depresses the

yield on long-term bonds through long-term bonds prices increasing (Harvey 1989).

Stock returns are linked to a firm’s earnings, and thus, real economic growth (Gordon

1962; Fama 1981; Campbell & Shiller 1988; Schwert 1990). The link between term

spreads and economic growth indirectly suggests term spreads are a gauge of expected

returns from equities.

Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002, p.760) used the Treasury term structure

premium, measured as the difference in yield to maturity between ten-year Treasury

bonds and three-month Treasury bills. Groenewold (2003, p.460) used the term spread

between the rates on ten-year Government Bond and three-month Treasury notes.

Three-month Commonwealth Government Treasury Bond data sourced from

Bloomberg contained many missing observations between 2000 and 2013, so I used

Page 111: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 106

one-year bonds to replicate the term spread used by Groenewold for the Australian

market.

The spreads between ten- and one-year Government bonds are shown in Figure 13.34

The term spread becomes negative around the year 2000 ‘Dot-Com’ bubble and in

the years leading up to the 2008 Global Financial Crisis. This indicates the yields on

shorter-term bonds were becoming large in comparison to longer-term bonds at the

onset of economic turmoil, which is consistent with Harvey’s theory outlined above.

Shortly after each of these crises, the spread rapidly becomes positive, which is also

consistent with the view that economic growth and, thus, future returns are expected

to improve.

34 The Bloomberg tickers used for the one and ten year Government bonds are ‘GACGB1 Index’ and

‘GACGB10 Index’ respectively.

Page 112: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 107

Figure 13 Term Spread - Australian Commonwealth Government Bonds

Default Spreads

Fama (1991, p.1585) outlined that during economic downturns default spreads are

high on bonds, while very low stock prices result in relatively high dividend yields.

This implies high-expected returns on bonds and stocks. That is, during persistent

downturns, an investor requires higher compensation if risking depressed levels of

wealth.

Flannery and Protopapadakis (2002, p.760) calculated a default premium, measured

as the difference in yield between Moody’s BAA and AAA seasoned corporate bond

indices.

Groenewold (2003, p.460) measured the default spread between the rates for five-

year Government bonds and five-year New South Wales Treasury Bonds. He noted

that bonds with a greater ‘quality’ difference would have been preferred, but was

restricted to this pair due to data availability.

-1.00

-0.50

0.00

0.50

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.000

3/0

1/2

00

0

09/1

0/2

00

0

16/0

7/2

00

1

22/0

4/2

00

2

27/0

1/2

00

3

03/1

1/2

00

3

09/0

8/2

00

4

16/0

5/2

00

5

20/0

2/2

00

6

27/1

1/2

00

6

03/0

9/2

00

7

09/0

6/2

00

8

16/0

3/2

00

9

21/1

2/2

00

9

27/0

9/2

01

0

04/0

7/2

01

1

09/0

4/2

01

2

14/0

1/2

01

3

21/1

0/2

01

3

per cent

Page 113: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 108

For my research, the longest continuous series of Australian corporate bond yields

available at the time was the Bloomberg 5-year AA fair value curve index. While

other Australian corporate bond series are available from Datastream and UBS, they

do not hold a credit rating or term to maturity constant. This means the default spread

calculated on these bonds is contaminated with term and credit rating variations that

do not reflect the pricing of a given default category. Bloomberg had a variety of other

Australian corporate bond indices, including a BBB band, which would have been

preferable due to the greater premium on these bonds. However, the AA 5-year index

was the only series available with continuous observations from January 2000. The

Bloomberg 5-year Australian Commonwealth Government bond index series was

deducted from the AA fair value curve series to derive a default spread.35 Anomalous

data points were replaced with the preceding day’s value. The resulting series is

shown in Figure 14.

35 The Bloomberg tickers used for the five year Government bond index and AA 5 year fair value

curve are ‘GACGB5 Index’ and ‘C3585Y Index’ respectively.

Page 114: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 109

Figure 14 5-Year Australian Corporate Bond Default Spread

The default spread is relatively stable leading up to the GFC in 2008, fluctuating

within a band of 0.5 to one per cent. The peaks in the series appear to roughly align

with the clustering of increased volatility displayed in Figure 1 and Figure 2. This is

suggestive of a shared relationship between stock market risk and bond returns.

0.00

0.50

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.000

3/0

1/2

00

0

12/0

6/2

00

0

20/1

1/2

00

0

30/0

4/2

00

1

08/1

0/2

00

1

18/0

3/2

00

2

26/0

8/2

00

2

03/0

2/2

00

3

14/0

7/2

00

3

22/1

2/2

00

3

31/0

5/2

00

4

08/1

1/2

00

4

18/0

4/2

00

5

26/0

9/2

00

5

06/0

3/2

00

6

14/0

8/2

00

6

22/0

1/2

00

7

02/0

7/2

00

7

10/1

2/2

00

7

19/0

5/2

00

8

27/1

0/2

00

8

06/0

4/2

00

9

14/0

9/2

00

9

22/0

2/2

01

0

02/0

8/2

01

0

10/0

1/2

01

1

20/0

6/2

01

1

28/1

1/2

01

1

07/0

5/2

01

2

15/1

0/2

01

2

25/0

3/2

01

3

02/0

9/2

01

3

per cent

Page 115: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 110

6 Results

The models outlined in Chapter 4 were estimated using ASX 200 daily returns from

26 October 2005 to 31 December 2013. This period was chosen because the data for

all of the macroeconomic surprises was available between those dates.

To reiterate Chapter 4, two variants of the model were estimated: one using

values/absolute values of macroeconomic surprises (continuous model), and the other

using dummy variables for macroeconomic announcement days separated into good

and bad news days (dummy variable based model). The continuous models’

dependent variables were the forecast errors expressed as a percentage. The

continuous model allowed me to capture the percentage change in stock returns and

stock return volatility per one per cent of error in macroeconomic forecasts. This

provided information on the sensitivity of stock returns and return volatility to

macroeconomic surprises. The details of model fitting are outlined in Appendix B.

6.1 Continuous Model Results

In the mean equation in Table 12, surprises can be negative or positive as they are all

based on the equation (16):

, 1 , ,( )k t t k t k tSurprise E Announcement Announcement

In the variance equation, absolute values of surprises are used, so both good and bad

news is positive and, therefore, summarised into surprises more generally. A positive

coefficient for the macroeconomic variables in the variance equation indicates

surprises in general increase volatility, while a negative coefficient on the variables

indicates surprises, in general, decrease volatility.

Page 116: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 111

The coefficients represent the effect on returns, or return volatility expressed as whole

number percentages. For example, a coefficient of 0.5 would represent a 50 basis

point or a one half a per cent increase in return on a given day.

Table 12 Continuous EGARCH model results based on full period sample

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns: 26 October 2005 - 31 December 2013

Mean Equation

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.1152 0.0282**

Hola Holiday 0.3067 0.0029***

Daya Monday 0.0246 0.6710

Daya Tuesday -0.0408 0.4414

Daya Thursday 0.0182 0.7499

Daya Friday -0.0198 0.7097

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3872 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0251 0.0353**

Controla Term Spread 0.0323 0.1919

Controla Default Spread -0.0674 0.0118**

Surprisea Unemployment 0.4306 0.2373

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.0000 0.8262

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.1850 0.0628

Surprisea Producer Price Index -0.1470 0.6137

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 0.7673 0.0425**

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product -0.1939 0.2954

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 2.1336 0.0838

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0103 0.5302

Page 117: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 112

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.0014 0.9879

ARCH (1) term 0.1084 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1206 0.0000***

GARCH (1) term 0.9662 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0279 0.7677

Dayb Monday 0.1216 0.3596

Dayb Tuesday -0.3193 0.0383**

Dayb Thursday -0.1695 0.2588

Dayb Friday -0.2086 0.0844

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0775 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0007 0.9359

Controlb Term Spread 0.0007 0.8985

Controlb Default Spread 0.0083 0.2192

surpriseb Unemployment -0.2570 0.3307

surpriseb Balance of Trade -0.0002 0.1675

surpriseb Retail Sales 0.0591 0.5428

surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.4262 0.0332**

surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.3685 0.3772

surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -0.1079 0.6353

surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate 0.7953 0.3954

surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0356 0.0241**

Included observations 2070

Adjusted R-squared 0.2603

Log likelihood -2627.7910

Akaike Information criterion 2.5766

Diagnostics

Q(20) [p-value] 14.541 [0.8020]

Q2(20) [p-value] 11.452 [0.9340]

Page 118: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 113

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.6051 [0.9119]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic [p-value] 1.223 [0.2997]

In Table 12 (and the subsequent tables of results for the models that follow), the p-

values are based on Bollerslev-Wooldridge robust standard errors. The p-values given

are based on a two sided test and a null hypothesis of zero consistent with the null

hypotheses outlined in Chapter 3. Two sided tests have been used because they allow

simultaneous testing for negative and positive effects outlined in the alternative

hypotheses in Chapter 3, yet are still more conservative than one sided tests as they

require greater deviation from zero to detect significance. I mainly discuss variables

significant at the five per cent level for the sake of brevity.

To start with, I briefly discuss the effect of control variables. For returns (shown in

the mean equation), the results indicate holidays, US returns and Brent crude oil

futures returns have a positive relationship with Australian stock returns. The result

for US returns is consistent with Kim and In (2002). The relationship between oil

prices and Australian stock market returns are the opposite of that found by Hasan

and Ratti (2012). The default spread shows a negative relationship with returns, which

suggests stock price changes are related to bond price changes. As corporate bond

prices fall, the yields that reflect the coupon payment, as a proportion of the price,

increase which results in an increased default spread. The negative relationship with

stock prices reported in Table 12, therefore, shows that bond and stock prices fall

together. This is consistent with the findings of Fama (1991) who observed that

increased default spreads are related to decreased stock prices during economic

downturns. ASX 200 return volatility shows evidence of a negative relationship with

Tuesdays and US returns. This is consistent with Jaffe (1984) who found that day of

the week effects were unequal. While these results are interesting and reasonable, they

Page 119: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 114

are not the main focus of my research and so I move on to discuss the effect of

macroeconomic surprises.

For returns, only the CPI reports a significant relationship. Good (bad) CPI surprises

report a positive (negative) relationship with returns. That is, stock returns increase

by 76.73 basis points for every one per cent that the CPI is lower than expected.36.

This rejects my null hypothesis of no relationship between CPI surprises and stock

returns. Instead, it appears to support the alternative ‘proxy effect’ hypothesis (H5b)

where inflation acts as a proxy for changes in expected future output (which is

typically positively related to stock market returns) and stock prices.

For volatility, the PPI relates to increased ASX 200 return volatility, reporting a 42.62

basis points increase in returns for every one per cent surprise (or forecast error) of

any sign. This rejects my null hypothesis of no effect and means greater PPI surprises

are associated with greater stock return volatility. This is consistent with alternative

hypothesis H4c and hence the findings of Kim (2003, p.625) in the US market.37 The

CPI, however, was not found to be significant. These results are in contrast to Tiwari

(2012) who found that CPI changes precede PPI changes. If the CPI is a forecaster of

the PPI, one would expect only information in the CPI to be of importance to the stock

market and, therefore, the CPI to be significant instead of the PPI. This result is

examined further for robustness in Section 6.5. Consumer sentiment index surprises

(of any sign) significantly increase volatility, rejecting my null hypothesis of no

relationship. For every one per cent that consumer sentiment differs from that which

was expected, volatility increases by 3.56 basis points. This supports alternative

36 As per equation (1), lower actuals against expectations result in a positive macroeconomic

surprise. 37 It should be noted that the test conducted here cannot isolate the effect of good from bad news on

volatility. Alternative hypothesis H4c specifies that only bad PPI news increases return volatility.

Despite this, the results presented here are not inconsistent with this alternative hypothesis. The

model specification in section 6.2 allows for a more specific test of alternative hypothesis H4c.

Page 120: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 115

hypothesis H8b based on De Long et al’s (1990) hypothesis that the presence of

irrational investors, trading based on sentiment, increases volatility in excess of that

justified by fundamentals. This assumes consumer sentiment is a reasonable proxy

for investor sentiment (Qiu and Welch 2006, Akhtar et al 2011).

6.2 Dummy Variable Based Model Results

The dummy based model captures the average change in stock returns and stock

return volatility in response to good or bad macroeconomic surprises. The definition

of good and bad surprises is outlined in Chapter 3. The results for the full period are

shown in Table 13.

Page 121: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 116

Table 13 Dummy variable EGARCH model results based on full period

sample

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns: 26 October 2005 - 31 December 2013

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

AR (1) -0.0449 0.0467**

Hola Holiday 0.3425 0.0003***

Daya Monday 0.0913 0.0698

Daya Tuesday 0.0300 0.5314

Daya Thursday 0.0901 0.0916

Daya Friday 0.0607 0.1528

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3932 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0266 0.0268**

Controla Term Spread 0.0364 0.1244

Controla Default Spread -0.0401 0.0556

Surprisea Unemployment 0.1424 0.2043

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.0764 0.5094

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.0700 0.5653

Surprisea Producer Price Index 0.1372 0.3937

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 0.2886 0.1106

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product 0.5838 0.0460**

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 0.1598 0.3958

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index -0.0719 0.5134

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Unemployment -0.0313 0.8877

Bad Newsa Balance of Trade -0.2069 0.1718

Page 122: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 117

Bad Newsa Retail Sales -0.0060 0.9683

Bad Newsa Producer Price Index -0.2582 0.3939

Bad Newsa Consumer Price Index -0.1748 0.5056

Bad Newsa Real Gross Domestic Product -0.6250 0.0594

Bad Newsa Overnight Cash Rate -0.2282 0.2441

Bad Newsa Consumer Sentiment Index 0.1043 0.4957

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.0361 0.7072

ARCH 0.1336 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1253 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9672 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0774 0.4340

Dayb Monday 0.0629 0.6321

Dayb Tuesday -0.3186 0.0470**

Dayb Thursday -0.2381 0.1228

Dayb Friday -0.2796 0.0231**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0775 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0016 0.8714

Controlb Term Spread 0.0006 0.9187

Controlb Default Spread 0.0079 0.1843

Surpriseb Unemployment 0.0816 0.4875

Surpriseb Balance of Trade 0.0054 0.9691

Surpriseb Retail Sales 0.0258 0.8645

Surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.2511 0.2214

Surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.3046 0.1227

Surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -0.6175 0.0032***

Page 123: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 118

Surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate -0.0586 0.7453

Surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0937 0.4539

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Unemployment 0.1175 0.5433

Bad Newsb Balance of Trade -0.1317 0.3936

Bad Newsb Retail Sales -0.0736 0.6035

Bad Newsb Producer Price Index -0.0116 0.9628

Bad Newsb Consumer Price Index 0.2771 0.2389

Bad Newsb Real Gross Domestic Product 0.6848 0.0079***

Bad Newsb Overnight Cash Rate -0.1853 0.2699

Bad Newsb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.3257 0.0170**

Included observations 2070

Adjusted R-squared 0.2570

Log likelihood -2621.5500

Akaike Information criterion 2.5860

Diagnostics

Q(20) 11.1920 [0.9170]

Q2(20) 11.8900 [0.8900]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.6199 [0.9011]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic [p-value] 1.0400 [0.3736]

The results for the mean equation indicate that holidays, US returns and Brent crude

oil futures returns have a positive relationship with ASX 200 returns. This is

consistent with the mean equation results for the continuous model in Table 12.

With respect to the eight macroeconomic variables, returns respond positively to real

GDP surprises, showing an asymmetric response that increases returns by 58.38 basis

points in response to good news, but exhibiting no significant response to bad news.

This rejects my null hypothesis of no relationship between real GDP surprises and

stock returns, indicating good real GDP news is related to increased returns. The

response to good news is consistent with alternative hypothesis H6a and hence the

Page 124: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 119

theories of Jorgenson (1971), Fama (1981) and Campbell and Shiller (1988) who offer

various explanations for a positive relationship between stock returns and expected

future output growth.

The variance equation shows Tuesdays and US returns are related to lower volatility

in ASX 200 returns, which is consistent with the results in Table 12 discussed above.

The dummy based model picks up an additional day-of-the-week effect for Fridays,

which is also related to lower return volatility. Good real GDP surprises appear to

reduce volatility by 61.75 basis points, with an asymmetric bad news response that

increases volatility by 6.73 basis points (-61.75 + 68.48 basis points). This rejects my

null hypothesis of no relationship between real GDP surprises and stock return

volatility. It indicates good real GDP news is associated with decreased return

volatility, while bad real GDP news is associated with increased return volatility and

that the effect of bad real GDP news is slightly stronger than good news. This also

suggests better than expected growth prospects have a ‘calming’ influence on the

stock market, while worse than expected growth has the opposite effect. The good

news effect on volatility is consistent with alternative hypothesis H6c and hence Kim’s

(2003, p.624) observations in the US.

Consumer sentiment index surprises have an asymmetric response to bad news,

decreasing volatility by 32.57 basis points and rejecting my null hypothesis of no

relationship between the consumer sentiment index and stock market volatility. This

asymmetric bad news effect is not intuitively convincing because one would typically

associate bad consumer sentiment with deteriorating business conditions and

increased uncertainty, both of which would be expected to result in increased

volatility. The finding also contradicts Akhtar et al (2011) who found bad consumer

sentiment news decreases returns. Under these circumstances, bad consumer

Page 125: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 120

sentiment news would be more likely to increase (rather than decrease) the volatility

of returns. This result is re-examined in Section 6.5.

6.3 Continuous Model Results: Pre- and Post-Global Financial Crisis

To determine whether the effects differ before and after the onset of the Global

Financial Crisis in 2008, both variants of the model were estimated before and after

(and including) 10 October 2008. Lim, Durand and Yang (2014, p.171) observed the

crises encountered over the period in my study climaxed during October 2008. In

Australian markets, the largest fall in returns was on 10 October, dropping 8.70 per

cent. Two, as opposed to three or more, sub-periods were chosen using this date as

the break point to maximise the number of sub-period observations. The validity of

the results under this structure is tested using alternate dates and three sub-periods

outlined in Section 6.5.

The results for the continuous regression pre- and post-GFC are shown in Table 14.

Table 14 Continuous EGARCH model results: Pre- and Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

AR(1) -0.1495 0.0001*** - -

Hola Holiday 0.4893 0.0055*** 0.2465 0.0309**

Daya Monday 0.2391 0.0017*** -0.0469 0.4783

Daya Tuesday 0.0443 0.5158 -0.0533 0.3969

Daya Thursday 0.2410 0.0025*** -0.0302 0.6373

Daya Friday 0.1076 0.0911 -0.0362 0.5556

Page 126: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 121

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4235 0.0000*** 0.3711 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0185 0.3013 0.0327 0.0263**

Controla Term Spread -0.0092 0.9389 0.0513 0.1167

Controla Default Spread -0.0932 0.0270** 0.0072 0.7593

Surprisea Unemployment -1.0467 0.4404 0.4663 0.2242

Surprisea Balance of Trade -0.0033 0.2583 0.0000 0.9565

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.1771 0.4868 0.1762 0.1420

Surprisea Producer Price Index -0.3933 0.4836 -0.0573 0.8551

Surprisea Consumer Price Index -0.9695 0.1472 1.6623 0.0003***

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product -0.0016 0.9969 -0.2786 0.0824

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 7.5232 0.0028*** 1.3647 0.2473

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0029 0.8875 0.0279 0.2587

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

Intercept 0.0551 0.7299 -0.1622 0.1560

ARCH (1) term 0.1242 0.0131** 0.1417 0.0001***

Asymmetry term -0.1576 0.0000*** -0.1101 0.0000***

GARCH (1) term 0.9105 0.0000*** 0.9560 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0362 0.8553 0.0542 0.6751

Dayb Monday -0.0592 0.7824 0.1820 0.2259

Dayb Tuesday -0.4771 0.0892 -0.2139 0.2268

Dayb Thursday -0.4446 0.0551 -0.0213 0.9031

Dayb Friday -0.4023 0.0511 -0.1024 0.5006

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.1015 0.0036*** -0.0630 0.0020***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0304 0.1668 -0.0024 0.8482

Controlb Term Spread -0.0426 0.4536 0.0294 0.0286**

Controlb Default Spread 0.0653 0.0144** 0.0226 0.1290

surpriseb Unemployment 1.8382 0.2004 -0.2136 0.4943

Page 127: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 122

surpriseb Balance of Trade 0.0041 0.0844 -0.0002 0.3331

surpriseb Retail Sales -0.4835 0.1513 -0.1128 0.3500

surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.5653 0.2626 0.1281 0.5893

surpriseb Consumer Price Index 0.3101 0.6977 -0.2173 0.7039

surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -0.3685 0.5634 -0.1690 0.5190

surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate 1.2663 0.4476 -0.1267 0.9121

surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0040 0.8898 0.0210 0.3656

pre-GFC post-GFC

Included observations 748 1322

Adjusted R-squared 0.306016 0.2344

Log likelihood -946.1024 -1646.0250

Akaike Information criterion 2.62694 2.5516

Diagnostics

pre-GFC post-GFC

Q(20) [p-value] 12.1450 [0.8790] 6.7375 [0.9920]

Q2(20) [p-value] 12.3620 [0.8700] 20.9900 [0.2800]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.6316 [0.8907] 1.0615 [0.3853]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic

[p-value] 0.0779 [0.9719] 0.5121 [0.6740]

Prior to the GFC, holidays, Mondays, Thursdays and US returns were positively

related to returns in the mean equation. The default spread shows a negative

relationship. These results are similar to those for the full period’s continuous

regression.

Post-GFC, the effect of US returns and holidays on the ASX 200 returns remains

significant and of a consistent sign. However, they both have a diminished effect.

Day-of-the-week and default spread effects on ASX 200 returns become insignificant

after the onset of the crisis, while the effect of oil futures returns becomes significant

and positive. With respect to model fitting, the inclusion of an autoregressive lag no

longer results in the most parsimonious fit. These results tend to suggest, after the

Page 128: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 123

stock market euphoria leading up to 2008, there is an increased role for

fundamentals.38

The overnight cash rate is the only macroeconomic announcement to show a

relationship with returns prior to the GFC, strongly increasing returns by 7.5232 per

cent for every one per cent lower the cash rate turned out to be (compared to

expectations). That is, good (bad) cash rate news increases (decreases) returns. This

result rejects my null hypothesis of no relationship and supports alternative

hypothesis H7b which is underpinned by Shiller and Beltratti’s (1992) hypothesis that

investors substitute between dividend paying and interest bearing instruments when

the discount/interest rate changes. The effect becomes insignificant in the post-GFC

period. This result is in contrast to results in the whole period’s regressions in Table

12 and Table 13 above. Both tables did not detect any significant relationship

between cash rates and ASX 200 returns. Reflecting back on Figure 9 in Section

5.2.3, the overnight cash rate fell significantly more than expected on 7 October

2008, which marginally falls within my definition of the pre-crisis period. This could

explain the cash rate’s significance exclusively in the pre-GFC period. The

robustness of this result is tested in Section 6.5.

The coefficient on the CPI surprises becomes significantly positive only after the

GFC. That is, ASX 200 returns increase by 1.6623 per cent for every one per cent the

CPI decreases (compared to expectations). Based on this, it appears good (bad) CPI

news increases (decreases) returns, thus rejecting my hypothesis of no relationship.

The results are consistent with the sign on the CPI in the whole period regression

results in Table 12, but suggest the relationship, detected between CPI and ASX 200

returns over the whole period, stems from the period following the onset of the GFC.

38 The term fundamentals is used here in the same way that Harvey, Liu and Zhu (2014) classify

‘macro’ factors.

Page 129: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 124

This is perhaps due to increased importance placed on fundamentals thereafter.

Fama’s (1981) ‘proxy’ effect hypothesis, where inflation becomes a proxy for

changes in expected future output and stock prices (alternative hypothesis H5b in

Section 3.5), is supported by this result.39

The variance equation shows positive US returns reduce return volatility both before

and after the GFC. Prior to the GFC, increased default spreads are related to increased

stock market volatility, whereas there is no significant default spread effect on returns

reported in the period following the crisis. The term spread coefficient shows no

relationship with ASX 200 return volatility in the pre-GFC period, but reports a

significant positive relationship thereafter. This appears to be counterintuitive because

falling term spreads are associated with an increased risk of recession (Harvey 1989),

and so, one should expect a falling term spread to be associated with increased stock

market risk or volatility. Under these circumstances, a negative relationship between

the term spread and stock market volatility should be observed - not the positive one

reported. The tests in Section 6.5 assess whether this result is robust.

The variance equation reports no significant relationship with any of the

macroeconomic surprises. This is in contrast with the results, for the whole period

regression in Table 12, that report a positive relationship between the PPI and

consumer sentiment index news (of any sign), and return volatility. The finding that

both of these variables are not significant in the sub-periods, pre- and post-GFC, is

possibly a result of the smaller sample sizes within these periods (compared to the

whole period).

39 As noted in the introduction, output is regularly found to be positively related to returns throughout

in the literature.

Page 130: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 125

6.4 Dummy Variable Based Model Results: Pre- and Post-Global Financial

Crisis

The results for the dummy variable variant of the model are shown in Table 15.

Table 15 Dummy variable EGARCH model results: Pre/Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

AR (1) -0.1446 0.0001*** - -

Hola Holiday 0.3717 0.0111** 0.2449 0.0221**

Daya Monday 0.2482 0.0014*** -0.0448 0.5083

Daya Tuesday 0.0732 0.3278 -0.0424 0.5293

Daya Thursday 0.2682 0.0010*** -0.0586 0.3963

Daya Friday 0.1012 0.0904 -0.0437 0.4756

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4372 0.0000*** 0.3710 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0115 0.4976 0.0337 0.0208**

Controla Term Spread -0.0236 0.8385 0.0608 0.0686

Controla Default Spread -0.1203 0.0049*** 0.0027 0.9113

Surprisea Unemployment -0.1400 0.4642 0.3222 0.0170**

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.2526 0.2833 0.0067 0.9581

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.0375 0.8621 -0.0903 0.5312

Surprisea Producer Price Index 0.1403 0.6587 0.2120 0.2545

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 0.0968 0.7008 0.3231 0.1681

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product 0.0173 0.8923 1.0057 0.0024***

Page 131: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 126

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 0.2263 0.1953 0.0203 0.9351

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index -0.0003 0.9981 -0.1754 0.2781

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Unemployment -0.1055 0.8058 0.0238 0.9019

Bad Newsa Balance of Trade -0.2845 0.3183 -0.1838 0.2625

Bad Newsa Retail Sales 0.1070 0.7031 0.1168 0.5146

Bad Newsa Producer Price Index -0.0053 0.9899 -0.4365 0.2555

Bad Newsa Consumer Price Index 0.5976 0.1210 -0.9294 0.0017***

Bad Newsa Real Gross Domestic Product 0.0644 0.8163 -1.1248 0.0024***

Bad Newsa Overnight Cash Rate -0.3822 0.0332** -0.0274 0.9160

Bad Newsa Consumer Sentiment Index -0.1651 0.3794 0.2629 0.1964

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

Intercept 0.1051 0.5306 -0.1318 0.2506

ARCH 0.1831 0.0028*** 0.1200 0.0003***

Asymmetry term -0.2100 0.0000*** -0.1242 0.0000***

GARCH 0.8478 0.0000*** 0.9596 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0285 0.8946 0.0838 0.5320

Dayb Monday -0.2005 0.3130 0.1938 0.1989

Dayb Tuesday -0.6387 0.0113** -0.1901 0.2978

Dayb Thursday -0.6217 0.0064*** -0.0180 0.9183

Dayb Friday -0.7216 0.0002*** -0.0667 0.6608

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0769 0.0298** -0.0660 0.0007***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0242 0.2994 0.0050 0.6655

Controlb Term Spread -0.0077 0.9318 0.0192 0.1070

Controlb Default Spread 0.1397 0.0005*** 0.0150 0.2526

Surpriseb Unemployment 0.4057 0.1159 0.0823 0.5626

Page 132: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 127

Surpriseb Balance of Trade 0.2620 0.3211 -0.1230 0.4620

Surpriseb Retail Sales 0.1242 0.6883 -0.1592 0.3602

Surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.5790 0.3242 0.0505 0.7996

Surpriseb Consumer Price Index 0.2927 0.5835 -0.3253 0.1050

Surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -1.7855 0.0000*** -0.6478 0.0120**

Surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate -0.0308 0.9298 0.1797 0.3762

Surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.2569 0.3032 0.1795 0.2581

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Unemployment -0.1381 0.7497 0.1726 0.4633

Bad Newsb Balance of Trade -0.1298 0.7218 -0.1603 0.3808

Bad Newsb Retail Sales -0.7755 0.0333** 0.1298 0.4856

Bad Newsb Producer Price Index -0.5745 0.3777 0.1603 0.5578

Bad Newsb Consumer Price Index -0.3912 0.5035 0.3304 0.2242

Bad Newsb Real Gross Domestic Product 2.1612 0.0000*** 0.4577 0.1166

Bad Newsb Overnight Cash Rate -0.8529 0.0241** -0.0894 0.6750

Bad Newsb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.3083 0.3781 -0.4113 0.0189**

pre-GFC post-GFC

Included observations 748 1322

Adjusted R-squared 0.3033 0.2457

Log likelihood -928.0526 -1639.7270

Akaike Information criterion 2.6285 2.5624

Diagnostics

pre-GFC post-GFC

Q(20) [p-value] 13.0220 [0.8370] 7.4822 [0.9950]

Q2(20) [p-value] 13.2110 [0.8280] 21.1920 [0.3860]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.6767 [0.8514] 1.0542 [0.3937]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic

[p-value] 0.1899 [0.9033] 0.7210 [0.5394]

For control variables, the dummy variable specification of the model in Table 15

indicates the same relationship with ASX 200 returns as the continuous model in

Table 14. Returns respond positively to holidays, and positively to US returns in both

Page 133: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 128

the pre- and post-GFC sub-periods. Day-of-the-week effects on returns are positive

for Monday and Thursday during the pre-GFC period, but thereafter, report no

significant effects. The default spread reports a negative relationship with returns in

the period preceding the crisis, but reports no relationship after its onset. Post-GFC,

oil returns exhibit a positive relationship with stock returns, while no effects were

found in the period prior to the GFC. The autoregressive lags no longer have a role in

fitting a parsimonious model. As with the continuous model, it appears that after the

GFC, fundamentals play a greater part in explaining stock returns.

Turning to the eight macroeconomic variables, good unemployment surprises are

positively related to ASX 200 returns, causing them to increase by 32.22 basis points

on average. That is, good unemployment news is associated with an increase in returns

in the post-GFC period. The null hypothesis of no relationship is rejected. The result

supports alternative hypothesis H1a which is explained by Boyd, Hu & Jagannathan

(2005, p.650). They highlighted unemployment news may be a proxy of growth

expectations. This is because unanticipated decreases in the unemployment rate may

signal faster future output growth. Higher output growth typically equates to higher

growth in corporate cash flows, and higher stock prices and returns. My results

support this hypothesis, but only in the post-GFC period.

Good real GDP surprises are also positively related to ASX 200 returns in the post

crisis period, causing them to increase, on average, by 1.0057 per cent. During the

same period, bad real GDP news has a negative effect on returns (-1.1248 per cent on

average), at the margin that more than offsets the good news effects. On average, this

results in a negative; effect of -11.91 basis points (100.57-112.48 basis points) on

returns.

Page 134: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 129

These results indicate that post-GFC, good real GDP news is associated with

increased returns, rejecting my null hypothesis of no relationship and supporting

alternative hypothesis H6a; that stock returns are related to output growth expectations

(Jorgenson 1971, Fama 1981). This is one of the most fundamental and regular

empirical findings in the literature. One of the more interesting things about this result

is that this fundamental relationship is found only post-GFC. The sign of the effects

are still consistent with the dummy variable based full period’s regression, which is

an encouraging sign of robustness. In the post-crisis period, bad CPI news has an

asymmetric negative relationship with returns, causing them to decrease by 92.94

basis points on average, while good CPI news reports no significant effect. This

finding rejects the null hypothesis of no relationship and, again, supports Fama’s

(1981) proxy effect hypothesis (outlined in alternative hypothesis H5b). Unexpected

increases in inflation (bad CPI news) may be a sign of a deteriorating outlook for

future real output and stock returns.

Overnight cash rate news has an asymmetric effect, only evident prior to the crisis

when the cash rate tended to be rising. Bad news is associated with a decrease in

returns of 38.22 basis points on average, rejecting the hypothesis that the overnight

cash rate has no relationship with stock prices. These results are consistent with those

in the continuous model in Table 14; however, this regression provides additional

information that indicates the cash rate relationship in the continuous model is an

asymmetric one. The results support alternative hypothesis H7b which reasons that

investors substitute from dividend-paying to interest-bearing instruments, when the

discount/interest rate increases (Shiller and Beltratti 1992), and indicate that

investors are particularly sensitive to interest rate increases in the lead up to the GFC.

Page 135: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 130

The volatility equation in the dummy based model shows that, Tuesdays, Thursdays

and Fridays were associated with reduced volatility prior to the crisis. The effect is

not persistent and disappears after the onset of the GFC. US returns are negatively

related to volatility over the whole period. This result is remarkably consistent

throughout out all of the modelling. It appears that stock market risk in Australia is

strongly linked to the performance of the US economy, regardless of Australian

economic conditions. The default spread is positively related to volatility but only

prior to the GFC. The same result was found in the continuous model and suggests,

leading up to the GFC, increased default risk in the debt market is an indicator of

increased risk in the equity market.

With respect to the eight macroeconomic variables, prior to the GFC, good real GDP

news is associated with decreased volatility (-1.7855 per cent on average), while the

marginal effect of bad real GDP news (2.1612 per cent on average) more than offsets

this. This means that bad news, overall, is associated with an increase in volatility of

37.58 basis points (-178.55 + 216.12 basis points) on average. Only the relationships

with good news persist after the onset of the GFC, and are associated with return

volatility being reduced by 64.78 basis points on average. Both results reject the null

hypothesis of no effect and highlight that real GDP announcements have a significant

asymmetric relationship across the whole period and are consistent with alternative

hypothesis H6c.40 The effect of bad news on return volatility, however, is limited to

the period prior to the GFC. These results appear sensible, with the good news effect

being supported by Kim’s (2003, p.624) US findings. It can be reasoned that the bad

news (lower than expected real GDP) may be seen as a sign of deteriorating business

40 Hypothesis H6c only specifies an effect based on good news, however the additional bad news

effect observed here is consistent with this hypothesis in terms of an inverse relationship existing

between the sign on real GDP surprises and the size of returns volatility. That is, higher than

expected (good) real GDP reduces return volatility and vice versa for lower than expected (bad)

real GDP.

Page 136: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 131

conditions and, therefore, increased uncertainty, risk and heightened volatility in

financial markets. The opposite appears to be the case for good news, or higher than

expected GDP.

Prior to the crisis, bad retail sales have an asymmetric relationship with return

volatility, which decreases on average by 77.55 basis points on bad retail sales’ news

days. This finding rejects the null hypothesis of no relationship with return volatility

and is not consistent with any of the alternative hypotheses postulated. It supports the

possibility that bad, or lower than expected, retail sales news is in fact good news for

the economy and calms the market, reducing volatility. This finding is more closely

examined in Section 6.5 where robustness tests are carried out.

Cash rate news also reports an asymmetric relationship with return volatility prior to

the GFC, with volatility decreasing on average by 85.29 basis points on days where

bad cash rate news is released. This rejects the hypothesis of no relationship between

interest rates and return volatility. There is no intuitive reason why an unexpected

increase in cash rates would dampen market volatility and the result is inconsistent

with the alternative hypotheses postulated. As previously discussed, unexpected

increases in interest rates are defined as bad news. The results are, therefore, showing

an unexpected increase in the cash rate is associated with decreased volatility. This,

if anything, is opposite to what one would expect. The result is tested for robustness

in Section 6.5.

In the period following the onset of the GFC, bad consumer sentiment news has an

asymmetric relationship with return volatility, and it is also associated with a 41.13

basis point decrease in the volatility of returns on average. This result is similar to

that found in the whole period dummy variable based regression shown in Table 13.

As discussed, and in relation to those results, the asymmetric bad news effect is not

Page 137: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 132

intuitively convincing, and it also contradicts the findings of Akhtar et al (2011).

Again, this result is examined more closely for robustness in Section 6.5.

6.5 Robustness Tests

The fourteen results (including the split into pre- and post-GFC regressions) that are

found to be significant are summarised in Table 16.

Table 16 Summary of Results by Macroeconomic Variable

Variable Continuous Model Dummy Variable based Model

Returns

Unemployment not significant post-GFC

Retail Sales not significant not significant

Producer Price Index not significant not significant

Consumer Price Index full period and post- GFC post-GFC

Real GDP not significant full period and post-GFC

Cash Rate pre-GFC pre-GFC

Consumer Sentiment Index not significant not significant

Return Volatility

Unemployment not significant not significant

Retail Sales not significant pre-GFC

Producer Price Index full period not significant

Consumer Price Index not significant not significant

Real GDP not significant full period, pre- and post-GFC

Cash Rate not significant pre-GFC

Consumer Sentiment Index full period full period and post-GFC

To ensure the robustness of these results, three separate robustness tests have been

carried out. Firstly, all of the regression models were re-estimated using the All

Ordinaries index based total returns (instead of the ASX 200). Secondly, all

significant macroeconomic surprises were cross-checked by re-estimating an ASX

200 returns based regression, on each macroeconomic surprise series, in isolation of

the others. Lastly, given that a large number of the findings were significant, as a

result of splitting the sample into pre- and post-October 2008 sub-periods, an

alternative choice of sub-periods was used to check if the results were robust to the

Page 138: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 133

choice of break point. The details and results of these robustness tests are outlined in

Appendix C.

The seven main results (including the split into pre- and post-GFC regressions) that

survived the robustness tests are summarised in Table 17.41

Table 17 Summary of Results Surviving Robustness Tests

Variable Continuous Model Dummy Variable based Model

Returns

Unemployment not significant post-GFC

Consumer Price Index post- GFC post-GFC

Real GDP not significant post-GFC

Cash Rate not significant pre-GFC

Return Volatility

Real GDP not significant full period, pre- and post-GFC42

Consumer Sentiment Index full period not significant

6.6 Summary and Discussion of Results

The overnight cash rate is special because it is the only variable that has a robust

relationship with stock market returns prior to the GFC. The following theories and

evidence offer an insight into why this may be. Flannery and James (1984)

hypothesise the effect of nominal interest rate changes is related to a firm’s maturity

composition of nominal contracts. They found that interest rates were significantly

related to the stock price of deposit taking institutions, and that the sensitivity of the

relationship was related to the extent of the maturity mismatch between assets and

liabilities. In the Australian context, this hypothesis is particularly relevant because

41 With respect to control variables, the positive term spread coefficient observed in the post-GFC

period using the continuous model in Section 6.3 was not robust to using an alternative choice of

sub-periods. 42 The effects of bad real GDP news on return volatility did not survive the test using an alternative

choice sub-periods.

Page 139: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 134

47.6 per cent of the S&P ASX 200 is comprised of financial institutions (as shown in

Figure 15).

Figure 15 ASX 200 Index - Sector Composition

Note. From Standard and Poor’s indices S&P/ASX 200 sector breakdown, July 2015 (S&P 2015)

Faff and Howard (1999) studied the relationship between long-term interest rates and

large Australian bank stock returns, and found a negative relationship during the

period of rapidly rising stock prices between 1978 and 1987. During the period of

relatively subdued stock market growth, between November 1987 and December

1992, no significant relationship was found. Over the period January 1992 to January

2007, Jain, Narayan and Thompson (2011, p.971) found short-term interest rates are

negatively related to the largest four banks stock returns.43

These studies taken with the results of my own study, suggest financial institutions’,

(specifically large banks) stock returns may be sensitive to interest rate changes,

mainly during periods of rapidly rising stock market prices. They also suggest returns

on these stocks are negatively related. This is possibly a result of exacerbated maturity

43 ANZ, Commonwealth Bank of Australian, National Australia Bank and Westpac Banking

Corporation.

Page 140: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 135

mismatches between assets and liabilities. Alternatively, the stock price level of large

banks, rather than operational aspects such as asset maturity mismatches, may be the

determinant of interest rate sensitivity. At lower prices, the greater potential for capital

growth combined with strong dividend yields from bank stocks may require a greater

than usual or continually sustained change in the direction of short-term interest rates

in order to attract funds to interest bearing securities. Further research is required to

test these hypotheses.

Other than the cash rate, no other macroeconomic variables appear to play a part in

explaining returns during the stock market boom leading up to the GFC. Moreover,

the AR(1) or autocorrelation coefficients during this period were highly significant

and in the order of -15 basis points. This may indicate the market was not weak form

efficient during the stock market boom, as the previous days’ returns appear to have

more explanatory power than fundamental factors, such as real GDP, unemployment

and inflation.

It is interesting to note that unemployment, real GDP and the CPI are fundamental

macroeconomic variables, and their relationships with stock market returns only

became significant in the post-GFC period when market volatility (and thus risk) was

at a relatively high level. This is shown in Figure 16 from 2008 onward.

Page 141: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 136

Figure 16 ASX 200 Index - Total Daily Returns

The inclusion of autocorrelation or ‘AR’ coefficients in the post-GFC regressions

resulted in an inferior fit to those specifications that excluded them (see Appendix B

for more details). This may indicate, during times of heightened volatility and stock

market risk, fundamental factors (such as unemployment and real GDP growth) play

a more important role in determining stock prices than the previous days' returns and

overnight cash rates.

One might expect the breakdown in the relationship, between fundamentals and the

stock market in the lead up to the ‘peak’ of the market boom prior to the GFC, may

be attributed to overly high levels of consumer or investor sentiment, or irrational

exuberance (Keynes 1936, Shiller 2003). A casual inspection of the consumer

sentiment data shown in Figure 17 tends to indicate, if anything, the opposite. That is,

consumer sentiment levels were trending down over the period up to 2008.

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

03/0

1/2

00

0

12/0

6/2

00

0

20/1

1/2

00

0

30/0

4/2

00

1

08/1

0/2

00

1

18/0

3/2

00

2

26/0

8/2

00

2

03/0

2/2

00

3

14/0

7/2

00

3

22/1

2/2

00

3

31/0

5/2

00

4

08/1

1/2

00

4

18/0

4/2

00

5

26/0

9/2

00

5

06/0

3/2

00

6

14/0

8/2

00

6

22/0

1/2

00

7

02/0

7/2

00

7

10/1

2/2

00

7

19/0

5/2

00

8

27/1

0/2

00

8

06/0

4/2

00

9

14/0

9/2

00

9

22/0

2/2

01

0

02/0

8/2

01

0

10/0

1/2

01

1

20/0

6/2

01

1

28/1

1/2

01

1

07/0

5/2

01

2

15/1

0/2

01

2

25/0

3/2

01

3

02/0

9/2

01

3

per cent

Page 142: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 137

Figure 17 Westpac-Melbourne Institute Consumer Sentiment Index

Another possibility is that the magnitude of volatility in consumer/investor sentiment

(as opposed to the level of sentiment) is related to the breakdown in the relationship

between fundamentals and the stock market returns. A casual inspection of the

consumer sentiment surprise data in Figure 18 indicates volatility in surprises appears

to be greater during the pre-crisis period where the models fail to detect any

relationship between fundamentals and stock market returns.

-40.00

-20.00

0.00

20.00

40.00

60.00

80.00

100.00

120.00

140.000

7/0

4/2

00

4

08/0

9/2

00

4

08/0

2/2

00

5

13/0

7/2

00

5

13/1

2/2

00

5

17/0

5/2

00

6

11/1

0/2

00

6

13/0

3/2

00

7

15/0

8/2

00

7

15/0

1/2

00

8

11/0

6/2

00

8

11/1

1/2

00

8

08/0

4/2

00

9

09/0

9/2

00

9

09/0

2/2

01

0

14/0

7/2

01

0

14/1

2/2

01

0

18/0

5/2

01

1

11/1

0/2

01

1

13/0

3/2

01

2

15/0

8/2

01

2

17/0

1/2

01

3

12/0

6/2

01

3

12/1

1/2

01

3

Index

Page 143: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 138

Figure 18 Consumer Sentiment Surprises

The AR(1) or autocorrelation coefficients have greater explanatory power during the

pre-crisis period than fundamentals. This is perhaps evidence of a divergence from

fundamental stock values induced by irrational traders, and thus, evidence against

market efficiency. This warrants a closer look at the AR(1) or autocorrelation

coefficients. If the values of these coefficients, (which are around -15 basis points)

are found to be small, when compared to the bid-ask spread of the average stock, the

effect may only be a market microstructure anomaly and, therefore, unlikely to be

evidence against weak form efficiency in the Australian market (Fama 1970 & 1991).

An examination of this is beyond the scope of this thesis, but regardless, consumer

sentiment index surprises exhibit a robust positive relationship with stock market

volatility over the full cycle of stock market activity in the period I examine. The

effect of consumer sentiment surprise volatility on stock market volatility is in the

order of 3 basis points. Although small, one should not totally dismiss the role of

consumer or investor sentiment as a source of stock market risk in Australia.

-15.00

-10.00

-5.00

0.00

5.00

10.00

15.00

20.00

07/0

4/2

00

4

08/0

9/2

00

4

08/0

2/2

00

5

13/0

7/2

00

5

13/1

2/2

00

5

17/0

5/2

00

6

11/1

0/2

00

6

13/0

3/2

00

7

15/0

8/2

00

7

15/0

1/2

00

8

11/0

6/2

00

8

11/1

1/2

00

8

08/0

4/2

00

9

09/0

9/2

00

9

09/0

2/2

01

0

14/0

7/2

01

0

14/1

2/2

01

0

18/0

5/2

01

1

11/1

0/2

01

1

13/0

3/2

01

2

15/0

8/2

01

2

17/0

1/2

01

3

12/0

6/2

01

3

12/1

1/2

01

3

per cent

Page 144: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 139

In terms of magnitude, fundamentals appear to play a much more important role as a

determinant of stock market risk, albeit only in the post-crisis period. Real GDP

surprises have a strong influence on stock market volatility, decreasing it by around

65 basis points if the news is good. Prior to the GFC, the effect of good news appears

much stronger reducing volatility by around 180 basis points. These results indicate

good real GDP news is linked to decreased uncertainty and risk, and the calming

influence of good real GDP news is particularly strong when pre-existing levels of

volatility and, thus, market risk are already low. The real GDP effects support the

view that variation in returns is based on fundamentals and, therefore, rational. This

is evidence in favour of Australian markets being strong-form efficient.

Some final points to note concern the relationships between Australian stock market

returns and control variables. In the post-crisis period, the effect of holidays on ASX

200 returns is diminished. Additionally, day-of-the-week effects, default spreads and

autocorrelation coefficients no longer have any explanatory power. This supports the

idea that macroeconomic fundamentals succeed financial market anomalies (in terms

of explanatory power) in more subdued periods of stock market growth and/or

heightened volatility. Brent oil futures returns have a significant positive relationship

with stock returns in the post-crisis period. Oil, and thus oil prices, can be viewed as

a fundamental macroeconomic factor for the Australian economy from both a

consumption and production point of view (Narayan & Wong 2009, p.2772). The

post-crisis significance of oil returns is, therefore, additional evidence that, during

times of subdued stock market growth and/or heightened volatility, fundamental

macroeconomic variables become a more important determinant of stock prices.

US returns are highly significant in all regressions, playing a major role as

determinant of Australian stock market returns. Australian stock returns increase in

Page 145: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 140

the order of 40 basis points, while return volatility decreases around 8 basis points for

every one per cent increase in US returns.

Page 146: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 141

7 Conclusion

The use of the Sharpe-Lintner-Black capital asset pricing model in Masters of

Business Administration and other managerial finance courses highlights the

importance of understanding macroeconomic risk in economic and financial decision-

making (Jagannathan & Wang 1996, p.4). The more recent work of Chen, Ross and

Roll (1986), Chan, Karceski and Lakonishok (1998), and Flannery and Protopapdakis

(2002) has turned attention to the identification of macroeconomic variables as risk

factors. In an informationally efficient market, the returns on a broad market portfolio

of firms should respond quickly to announcements pertaining to macroeconomic

variables if these variables are risk factors. As equity market indices (such as the S&P

ASX 200) are constituted from individual stocks, any macroeconomic variable that

affects the expected future cash flows, and/or the required or expected future rates of

return to a significant proportion of individual stocks in an economy, should also

affect the broad market index (Gordon 1962, Ross 1976, Fama 1981, Campbell &

Shiller 1988, Schwert 1990).

7.1 Thesis Contribution

While most research, to date, has focused on the relationship between macroeconomic

data values and stock market prices over long time horizons, this study examines the

relationship between macroeconomic news and stock market prices at a daily level,

using an event study within a regression framework. Previous Australian studies that

examine the effects of macroeconomic news have tended to focus on a limited number

of macroeconomic variables (Singh 1993; Singh 1995; Brooks et al 1999; Kim & In

2002) and have found no evidence of a relationship between macroeconomic

variables and stock market returns.

Page 147: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 142

I use eight macroeconomic variables and examine the effect of macroeconomic

surprises (news) on Australian stock market returns, over the period October 2005 to

December 2013, in order to identify if any of the variables are risk factors. The

surprises are measured as the unexpected component of the variable’s

announcements. The eight macroeconomic variables are unemployment, balance of

trade, retail sales, the producer and consumer price index, real GDP, the overnight

cash rate and consumer sentiment index. The unexpected component of these

announcements is separated from the expected component by using MMS surveys of

expectations, ARIMA forecasts, and forecasts derived from futures contracts, to

measure and deduct the expected component from the announcements. I measure the

sensitivity of returns/return volatility to the change in magnitude of these

macroeconomic surprises. I also decompose surprises into good and bad news, and

measure the average effect of each to test if responses differ or are ‘asymmetric’.

The study period is split into pre- and post-2008 GFC sub-periods to test whether

relationships between macroeconomic news and stock market returns are different

during these contrasting phases of stock market activity. Three different tests of

robustness are carried out on the results. Firstly, the dependent variable is changed

from the S&P ASX 200 index based returns to the All Ordinaries index based returns.

Secondly, regressions are estimated using only one macroeconomic variable at a time.

Thirdly, alternate break points are chosen to analyse the sub-periods (pre- and post-

GFC) within the study period. The results that are robust to these various tests are

summarised below.

7.2 Main Results

Bad (higher than expected) overnight cash rate news is the only variable to exhibit a

robust relationship with stock market returns prior to the GFC, and is associated with

Page 148: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 143

a decrease in returns. This indicates Australian investors are particularly sensitive to

rises in interest rates in the lead up to the GFC. The rational expectations present value

model theoretically supports the sign of the relationship. This model predicts that

investors substitute from dividend paying shares to interest bearing instruments when

the discount rate (typically reflecting the cash rate) and bond yields increase (Shiller

& Beltratti 1992).

Aside from the cash rate, no other macroeconomic variables play a part in explaining

returns during the period of rapidly increasing stock prices leading up to the GFC.

The AR(1) or autocorrelation coefficients during this period, however, were highly

significant and in the order of -15 basis points. This is perhaps evidence against weak

form market efficiency because it indicates, during this period, previous days’ returns

have greater explanatory power than fundamental macroeconomic factors, such as

real GDP, unemployment and the CPI.

Fundamental factors only became significant in the post-crisis period, where growth

was relatively subdued and stock market volatility was at a relatively high level.

Additionally, the inclusion of autoregressive or ‘AR’ coefficients, in the post-GFC

regressions, resulted in an inferior fit of model to those specifications that excluded

them.

Good (lower than expected) unemployment news has a significant positive

relationship with ASX 200 returns in the post-crisis period. This is consistent with

Boyd, Hu & Jagannathan (2005, p.650) who suggest unemployment news is a proxy

for expectations of higher future output growth. Lower than anticipated

unemployment may signal firms are experiencing, or are expecting to experience, an

increase in demand and, so, hire additional staff in order to increase output. Stock

prices, and thus returns, may therefore be increasing in anticipation of higher output,

Page 149: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 144

corporate cash flows and earnings. Bad (higher than expected) unemployment news

has no significant effect on returns.

The S&P ASX 200 based returns significantly increase (decrease) in reaction to good

(bad) CPI news in the post-crisis period. The dummy variable based model suggests

the effect is asymmetric with only bad (higher than expected) CPI news, decreasing

returns and good news having no effect. The CPI surprises have the strongest

relationship with returns out of all of the macroeconomic variables included in this

study - the sensitivity of the effect is in the order of one for one if not greater. This

relationship supports the ‘proxy’ hypothesis (Fama 1981, p.563) that the negative

relationship between inflation and stock returns is a proxy for the positive relationship

between expected future real output and stock returns.44 Put another way, unexpected

increases (bad CPI news) may be a sign of a deteriorating outlook for future real

output, which is detrimental to stock returns. The significance of the CPI, and

insignificance of the PPI found in this study, is consistent with Tiwari’s (2012,

p.1577) finding that, in Australia, CPI changes precede PPI changes. This is because

the result supports the idea that stock market participants use the consumer price in

place of the producer price index to inform their trading on account of the CPI leading

changes in the PPI.

Real GDP surprises have an asymmetric relationship with returns. Only good (higher

than expected) real GDP news is found to effect returns (positively) during the post-

crisis period. This positive relationship with returns has strong intuitive appeal,

empirical and theoretical support. An abundance of foreign literature exists that

explains and finds evidence to support the positive relationship between output and

44 Given that inflation targeting has been one of the objectives of monetary policy in Australia over

the period observed, the CPI surprises could also be a proxy for the relationship between the

overnight cash rate and stock market returns.

Page 150: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 145

stock returns. The absence of a relationship during the pre-GFC stock market boom

adds support to the findings of Binswanger (2004). In Canada, Japan and an aggregate

economy consisting of four European G-7 countries, Binswanger (2004, p.248) found

the fundamental relationship between stock returns and real GDP disappeared during

the stock market boom of the 1980s. He concluded there is support for the hypothesis

that speculative bubbles in the stock market were an international phenomenon

affecting major economies during the 1980’s and 1990’s. The findings of Binswanger

(2004) are consistent with the Australian based results of Groenewold (2003 & 2004).

In his 2003 study, he detected a weak relationship between real GDP growth and

Australian stock returns, prior to 1983, which deteriorated in the period thereafter. I

note that the period thereafter included the stock market boom leading up to 1987, as

well as the boom leading up to 2001. In his later (2004) Australian study, he found

stock market prices were not too far from fundamental values over the period of

relatively subdued stock market price growth from 1988 to 1993; however, they

departed substantially from fundamentals (based on real GDP) in the period prior

(from around 1970 to 1987) and from around 1994 to 1999 when stock market price

growth was strong.

Consumer sentiment index surprises exhibit a positive relationship with stock market

volatility, but only over the full cycle of stock market activity in the period I examine.

Consumer sentiment surprises, whether good or bad, increase volatility in stock

market returns in the order of 3 basis points. The effect is small but robust, indicating

sentiment is a risk factor in returns. This could be interpreted as evidence to support

behaviour-driven systematic mispricing (Hirshleifer & Jiang 2010), but the evidence

also shows macroeconomic fundamentals (real GDP) play a much more important

role as determinant of stock market volatility in terms of magnitude.

Page 151: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 146

Real GDP surprises decrease stock return volatility by around 65 basis points if the

news is good. Prior to the GFC, the effect of good news appears much stronger,

reducing volatility by around 180 basis points. This indicates good real GDP news is

linked to decreased stock market uncertainty and risk, and the calming influence of

good real GDP news is stronger when pre-existing levels of market volatility/risk are

already low. The strength and consistency of real GDP news effects, across the sub-

periods vis-à-vis consumer sentiment, supports the view that variation in returns is

based on fundamentals and is, therefore, rational. In turn, this lends support to the

view that the Australian market is efficient.

The control variables tend to corroborate the idea that fundamental macroeconomic

variables become a more important determinant of stock returns than financial market

anomalies during times of subdued stock market growth and/or heightened volatility.

In the post-crisis period, the effect of holidays on ASX 200 returns are diminished,

while day-of-the-week effects, default spreads and autocorrelation coefficients no

longer have any explanatory power.45 On the other hand, Brent oil futures returns,

which can be viewed as gauging a fundamental macroeconomic factor (oil prices),

have a significant robust positive relationship with stock returns in the post-crisis

period. US returns continue to play a major role as determinant of Australian stock

market returns. This is consistent with the strong and long standing correlation

between the business cycles of the US and Australia, confirming it is still the case that

‘when the US sneezes Australia catches a cold’ (Crosby & Bodman 2005, p.226).

The increased importance of fundamentals in Australian stock market returns post-

GFC is mirrored in the findings of Velinov and Chen (2015, p.16) in France,

Germany, Italy, Japan, the UK and the US where stock prices were found to fall back

45 These variables no longer have any explanatory power when using the best fit of model according

to the Akaike Information Criteria.

Page 152: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 147

into line with their fundamentals (approximated by industrial production) after the

GFC. The failure of macroeconomic fundamentals to explain stock returns during the

pre-GFC stock market boom appears to be a phenomenon also observed in the US,

UK and Japan during the stock market boom of the 1980’s (Binswanger 2004). As

Binswanger (2004, p.249) suggested, this may be a result of stock market bubbles or

irrational exuberance, which in turn, would suggest that the Australian stock market

was not efficient in the lead up to the GFC (Shiller 2003). The autocorrelation in

returns, exhibited in my results (in the order of -15 basis points), adds support to the

view that the market may have been informationally inefficient during this period.

The evidence against the Australian stock market being informationally inefficient in

the lead up to the GFC may be attributed to consumer sentiment. Consumer sentiment

appears to be particularly volatile in the lead up to the GFC, but relatively less so

thereafter.

7.3 Limitations and Possible Extensions

Alternative methods of data preparation and model specifications have been noted in

their respective chapters. Andersen et al (2007, p.258) implement an alternative data

preparation technique in calculating macroeconomic announcement surprises where

the surprise is divided by the standard deviation of the surprise component. The

volatility equations used in this study are limited to controlling for the potentially

differing effects of negative and positive values of the control variables on volatility.

Using the absolute magnitude of movements in the control variable returns would

allow the absolute size effects of control variables on volatility to be captured. An

evaluation of these alternative methods is beyond the scope of this study, but may

prove to be a fruitful extension to the research on modelling the effect of

macroeconomic announcement surprises on asset prices.

Page 153: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 148

The significance of the interest rate-stock return relationship, during periods of

rapidly rising stock prices, is suspected to stem from the prevalence of financial

institutions in the S&P ASX 200 and the negative relationship observed between

interest rates and financial institution stock returns during these periods (Flannery and

James 1984, Faff and Howard 1999, Jain, Narayan and Thompson 2011). Further

research is required to better establish and explain the relationship between interest

rates and financial institutions’ stock prices over contrasting periods of stock market

activity. The suspected relationship between interest rates, financial institutions’ stock

prices and the Australian stock market itself also requires more rigorous investigation

in order to confirm the proposed rationale behind the interest rate-stock market return

relationship identified in this study.

Hasan and Ratti (2012, p.1) found an increase in oil returns significantly reduced

overall stock market returns, which is directly counter to my findings in the post-GFC

period. This could indicate increased Australian economic dependence on

commodities, energy and materials-based sectors, since the GFC, as Hasan and Ratti’s

(2012, p.7) study was predominantly based on the period prior to the GFC.46 Further

research would be required to ascertain whether this is so.

The results of my study corroborate the existing literature and indicate interest rates

matter most for stock returns during booms, whereas real GDP, the CPI and

unemployment matter more during periods of subdued stock price growth. The reader

must keep in mind this study is focussed on stock market returns over a period of one

day - not stock market price levels over long horizons. The reader must also keep in

mind only the effect of surprises in macroeconomic variable announcements is

examined - not the effect of the levels of macroeconomic variables. The findings of

46 Specifically, March 2000 to December 2010.

Page 154: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 149

my study could be quite different if stock price movement over the long run and levels

of the announced macroeconomic variable data were used. For example, theory

suggests investor/consumer sentiment may explain divergences in stock prices away

from fundamentals (De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann 1990), but the

framework in this study cannot determine whether the stock market index price level

is justified by levels of the macroeconomic fundamentals or explained by other factors

such as sentiment. The lack of a significant relationship between the stock market

index and macro fundamentals prior to the GFC, therefore, remains unexplained. A

more detailed analysis of the relationship, between investor/consumer sentiment and

the deviation of Australian stock market returns from fundamentals, is a topic for

further research. The most obvious extension of this study, to investigate such effects,

would be to employ a GARCH-X framework (as used by Ratanapakorn & Sharma

(2007)), which includes the error correction term from a cointegrating model of long-

run relationships while simultaneously accounting for short-term effects.

From the perspective of Fama (1970 & 1991), the autocorrelation effects observed in

the pre- GFC period could possibly be a market microstructure anomaly, and in that

case, unlikely to be evidence against weak form efficiency in the Australian stock

market. Determining whether the magnitude of these effects are small enough to be

passed off as a market microstructure anomaly is beyond the scope of this study and,

thus, a topic for further research.

7.4 Final Conclusion

In summary, I have tested the reaction of daily returns to the surprise component of

Australian macroeconomic variable announcements (or news) in order to identify

potential macroeconomic risk factors. The results show the relationship between

macroeconomic variable news and stock market returns differs between ‘boom’

Page 155: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 150

periods in the stock market and periods of relatively subdued growth. This finding is

reflected in earlier-dated Australian studies and studies on foreign markets.

In the stock market boom leading up to the GFC, higher than expected overnight cash

rate news was found to have a negative relationship, with stock returns, that

disappears in the subsequent period of subdued stock market price growth. Lower

than expected cash rate news has no effect. The appearance of an interest-rate rate

relationship with stock returns, during stock market booms and disappearance in other

periods, is consistent with earlier Australian studies. Additionally, in the pre-GFC

period, stock market returns exhibit a negative relationship with the previous days'

returns, which appears to be evidence against market efficiency in terms of returns

being predictable. This may, however, be a market microstructure anomaly.

Macroeconomic fundamentals matter after the onset of the GFC. News of low

unemployment rates is associated with increased returns. News of high real GDP

growth is associated with increased returns. The CPI has the strongest relationship

with returns, out of all of the variables observed, with news of high (low) inflation

decreasing (increasing) returns. US returns maintain their historically strong positive

relationship with Australian stock market returns.

Over the whole period, consumer sentiment and real GDP surprises are the only

macroeconomic variables to impact market risk in terms of stock market volatility.

The findings for Australian stock market returns/return volatility and macroeconomic

surprises are summarised in Table 18 and Table 19.

Page 156: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 151

Table 18 Summary of Results - Returns

Variable Results

Continuous Model Dummy Variable Model

Unemployment No relationship

Post-GFC, good unemployment

news associated with increased

returns

Consumer Price Index

Post-GFC, good (bad) CPI news

associated with increased

(decreased) returns

Post-GFC, bad CPI news

associated with decreased returns

Real Gross Domestic Product No relationship Post-GFC, good real GDP news

associated with increased returns

Overnight Cash Rate No robust relationship Pre-GFC, bad cash rate news

associated with decreased returns

Table 19 Summary of Results - Return Volatility

Variable Results

Continuous Model Dummy Variable Model

Real Gross Domestic Product No relationship

Good real GDP news is

associated with decreased

return volatility over the entire

sample

Bad real GDP news is

associated with increased return

volatility over the entire sample

Pre-GFC, good real GDP news

is associated with decreased

return volatility

Pre-GFC, bad real GDP news is

associated with increased return

volatility

Post-GFC, good real GDP news

is associated with decreased

return volatility

Consumer Sentiment Index

Consumer sentiment index

surprises are associated with

an increase in return volatility

over the entire sample

No relationship

Page 157: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 152

8 References

Akhtar, S Faff, R & Subrahmanyam, A 2011, ‘The power of bad: The negativity

bias in Australian consumer sentiment announcements on stock returns’, Journal of

Banking and Finance, vol.35, no.5, pp.1239-1249.

Andersen, T Bollerslev, T Diebold, F & Vega, C 2003, ‘Micro effects of macro

announcements: Real-time price discovery in foreign exchange’, The American

Economic Review, vol.93, no.1, pp.38-62.

Andersen, T Bollerslev, T Diebold, F & Vega, C 2007, ‘Real-time price discovery

in global stock, bond and foreign exchange markets’, Journal of International

Economics, vol.73, no.2, pp.251-277.

Asprem, M 1989, ‘Stock prices, asset portfolios and macroeconomic variables in ten

European Countries’, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol.13, no.4, pp.589-612.

Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014a, 6202.0 – Labour Force, Australia. Available

from: <http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/mf/6202.0>. [30 April 2014].

Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014b, 5368.0 - International Trade in Goods and

Services, Australia. Available from:

<http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/mf/5368.0>. [30 April 2014].

Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014c, 8501.0 - Retail Trade, Australia. Available

from: <http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/mf/8501.0>. [30 April 2014].

Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014d, 6427.0 - Producer Price Indexes, Australia.

Available from: < http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/mf/6427.0>. [30 April

2014].

Page 158: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 153

Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014e, 6401.0 - Consumer Price Index, Australia.

Available from: < http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/mf/6401.0>. [30 April

2014].

Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014f, 5206.0 - Australian National Accounts:

National Income, Expenditure and Product. Available from:

<http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/mf/5206.0/>. [30 April 2014].

Australian Securities Exchange 1999, ASX Media Release. Available from:

<http://web.archive.org/web/20050718012702/http:/asx.com.au/about/shareholder/

media_releases/MR020999_AS3.htm >. [19 September 2015].

Baker, M & Wurgler, J 2007, ‘Investor sentiment in the stock market’, Journal of

Economic Perspectives, vol.21, no.2, pp.129-151.

Becker, K Finnerty, J & Friedman, J 1995, ‘Economic news and equity market

linkages between the US and UK’, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol.19, no.7,

pp.1191-1210.

Binswanger, M 2004, ‘Stock returns and real activity in the G-7 countries: did the

relationship change during the 1980s?’, The Quarterly Review of Economics and

Finance, vol.44, no.2, pp.237-252.

Black, F 1972, ‘Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing’, The Journal

of Business, vol.45, no.3, pp.444-455.

Bollerslev, T 1986, ‘Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity’,

Journal of Econometrics, vol.31, no.3, pp.307-327.

Page 159: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 154

Bomfim, A 2003, ‘Pre-announcement effects, news effects, and volatility: Monetary

policy and the stock market’, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol.27, no.2, pp.133-

151.

Boyd, J Hu, J & Jagannathan, R 2005, ‘The stock market’s reaction to

unemployment news: Why bad news is usually good for stocks’, The Journal of

Finance, vol.60, no.2, pp.649-672.

Brenner, M Pasquariello, P & Subrahmanyam, M 2009, ‘On the volatility and

comovement of U.S. financial markets around macroeconomic news

announcements’, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, vol.44, no.6,

pp.1265-1289.

Brooks, R Berman, G Davidson, S & Tan, T 1999, ‘Announcements and revisions

of Australian macroeconomic data and their news content for Australian financial

markets’, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, vol.9,

no.2, pp.192-215.

Boyer, M & Filion, D 2007, ‘Common and fundamental factors in stock returns of

Canadian oil and gas companies’, Energy Economics, vol.29, no.3, pp. 428-453.

Campbell, J 1987 ‘Stock returns and the term structure’, Journal of Financial

Economics, vol.18 , no.2, pp.373-399.

Campbell, J & Shiller, R 1988, ‘Share prices earnings and expected dividends’, The

Journal of Finance, vol. 43, no.3, pp.661-676.

Carroll, D Fuhrer, J & Wilcox D 1994 ‘Does Consumer Sentiment Forecast

Household Spending? If So, Why?’, The American Economic Review, vol.84, no.5,

pp.1397-1408.

Page 160: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 155

Carter, B 2007, ‘Australian share market expected to open higher’, Australian

Associated Press Financial News Wire 22 April. Available from: Factiva. [27 June

2015].

Cauchi, S 2015, ‘ASX lower for fourth day, but Asia gives lift’, The Australian

Financial Review 16 January. Available from: Factiva. [27 June 2015].

Chan, L, Karceski, J & Lakonishok, J 1998, ‘The Risk and Return from Factors’,

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, vol.33, no.2, pp.159-188.

Chaudhuri, K & Smiles, S 2004,’Stock market and aggregate economic activity:

evidence from Australia’, Applied Financial Economics, vol.14, no.2, pp.121-129.

Chen, N, Roll, R & Ross, S 1986, ‘Economic forces and the stock market’, The

Journal of Business, vol.59, no.3, pp.383-403.

Cheung, Y & Ng, L 1998, ‘International evidence on the stock market and aggregate

economic activity’, Journal of Empirical Finance, vol.5, no.3, pp.281-296.

Crosby, M & Bodman, P 2005, ‘When the US Sneezes, Do We Need to Catch a

Cold? Historical and Future Linkages between the Australian and US Business

Cycles’ The Changing Nature of the Business Cycle: Reserve Bank of Australia

Conference 2005, pp.226-254. Available from: Reserve Bank of Australia

Publications: Conferences 2005. [9 August 2015].

De Long, J Shleifer, A, Summers, L & Waldman, R 1990, ‘Noise trader risk in

financial markets’, The Journal of Political Economy, vol.98, no.4, pp.703-738.

Dunn, S & Holloway, J 2012, The pricing of crude oil, Reserve Bank of Australia,

Sydney.

Page 161: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 156

Available from: <http://www.rba.gov.au/publications/bulletin/2012/sep/8.html>. [6

January 2015].

Enders, W 2004, Applied econometric time series, 2nd ed., John Wiley & Sons,

Hoboken, N.J.

Faff, R & Howard, P 1999, ‘Interest rate risk of Australian financial sector

companies in a period of regulatory change’, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, vol.7,

no.1, pp.83-101.

Fama, E 1970, ‘Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work’,

The Journal of Finance, vol.25, no.2, pp. 383-417.

Fama, E 1981, ‘Stock returns, real activity, inflation and money’, The American

Economic Review, vol.71, no.4, pp.545-565.

Fama, E 1991, ‘Efficient capital markets: II’, The Journal of Finance, vol. 46, no.5,

pp. 1575-1617.

Fama, E & French, K 1992, ‘The cross section of expected stock returns’. The

Journal of Finance, vol. 47, no.2, pp.427-465.

Fama, E & Schwert, W 1977, ‘Asset returns and inflation’, Journal of Financial

Economics, vol.5, no.2, pp.115-146.

Fisher, I 1930, The Theory of Interest, Macmillan Company, New York

Flannery, M & James, C 1984, ‘The effect of interest rate changes on the common

stock returns of financial institutions’, The Journal of Finance, vol.39, no.4,

pp.1141-1153.

Flannery, M & Protopapadakis, A 2002, ‘Macroeconomic factors do influence

aggregate stock returns’, The Review of Financial Studies, vol.15, no.3, pp. 751-782.

Page 162: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 157

Friedman, M 1957, ‘The Permanent Income Hypothesis’ in A Theory of the

Consumption Function, eds M Friedman, Princeton University Press, New Jersey,

pp.20-37.

Gordon, M 1962, ‘The savings investment and valuation of a corporation’, The

Review of Economics and Statistics, vol.44, no.1, pp.37-51.

Groenewold, N 2003, ‘Financial deregulation and the relationship between the

economy and the share market in Australia’, Australian Economic Papers, vol.42,

no.4, pp.454-477.

Groenewold, N 2004, ‘Fundamental share prices and aggregate real output’, Applied

Financial Economics, vol.14, no.9, pp.651-661.

Gultekin, B 1983, ‘Stock market returns and inflation: Evidence from other

countries’, The Journal of Finance, vol.35, no.1, pp 49-65.

Harvey, C 1989, ‘Forecasts of Economic Growth from the Bond and Stock

Markets’, Financial Analyst Journal, vol.45, no.5, pp. 38-45.

Harvey, C, Liu, Y & Zhu, H 2014, ‘…and the cross section of expected returns’,

NBER Working Paper Series. Available from:

<http://www.financialinnovators.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/05/Harvey-et-al-

2014.pdf>. [20 September 2015].

Hasan, M & Ratti, R 2012, ‘Oil price shocks and volatility in Australian stock

returns’ Paper presented at the Global Accounting, Finance and Economics

Conference, Melbourne, Vic.

Page 163: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 158

Haver 2013, MMS Survey Medians & As First Reported Data (MMSAMER,

MMSEUR, MMSASIA). Available from:

<http://www.haver.com/databaseprofiles.html#forecasts>. [31 December 2013].

Hirshleifer, D & Jiang, D 2010, ‘A financing-based misvaluation factor and the

cross-section of expected returns’, The Review of Financial Studies, vol.23, No.9,

pp.3401-3436.

Humpe, A & Macmillan, P 2009, ‘Can macroeconomic variables explain long-term

stock market movements? A comparison of the US and Japan’, Applied Financial

Economics, vol.19, no.2, pp.111-119.

Jaffe, J 1984 ‘The weekend effect in common stock returns; The international

evidence’, Working paper no.3-85, The Wharton School, University of

Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA. pp.1-33.

Jagannathan, R & Wang, Z 1996, ‘The conditional CAPM and the cross-section of

expected returns’, The Journal of Finance, vol.51, no.1, pp.3-53.

Jain, A, Narayan, P & Thomson, D 2011, ‘The relationship between exchange rates,

interest rates and Australian bank returns’, Applied Economic Letters, vol.18, no.10,

pp.967-972.

Jorgenson, D 1971, ‘Econometric studies of investment behaviour: A survey’,

Journal of Economic Literature, vol.9, no.4, pp.1111-1147.

Kearney, C & Daly, K 1998, ‘The causes of stock market volatility in Australia’

Applied Financial Economics, vol.8, no.6, pp.597-605.

Kearns, P & Pagan, A 1993, ‘Australian stock market volatility: 1987-1987’, The

Economic Record, vol.69, no.205, pp.163-178.

Page 164: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 159

Keynes, J 1936, ‘The general theory of employment interest and money’, Macmillan

Press, London.

Kim, S 2003, ‘The spillover effects of US and Japanese public information news in

advanced Asia-Pacific stock markets’ Pacific-Basin Journal, vol.11, no.5, pp.611-

630.

Kim, S & In, F 2002, ‘The influence of foreign stock markets and macroeconomic

news announcements on Australian financial markets’, Pacific Basin Journal,

vol.10, no.5, pp. 571-582.

Levine, R 1997, ‘Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda’,

Journal of Economic Literature, vol.35, no.2, pp.688-726.

Lim, D, Durand, R & Yang, J 2014, ‘The microstructure of fear, the Fama-French

factors and the global financial crisis of 2007 and 2008’, Global Financial Journal,

vol.25, no.3, pp 169-180.

Lintner, J 1965, ‘The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments

in stock portfolios and capital budgets’, The Review of Economics and Statistics,

vol.47, no.1, pp 13-37.

Matsusaka, J & Sbordone, A 1995 ‘Consumer confidence and economic

fluctuations’, Economic Inquiry, vol.33, no.2, pp.296-318.

Mukherjee, T & Naka, A 1995, ‘Dynamic relations between macroeconomic

variables and the Japanese Stock Market: An application of a vector error correction

model’, The Journal of Financial Research, vol.18, no.2, pp.223-237.

Narayan, P & Wong, P 2009 ‘A panel data analysis of the determinants of oil

consumption: The case of Australia’ Applied Energy, vol.86, no.12, pp.2771-2775.

Page 165: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 160

Rangel, J 2011, ‘Macroeconomic news, announcements, and stock market jump

intensity dynamics’, Journal of Banking & Finance, vol.35, no.5, pp.1263-1276.

Ratanapakorn, O & Sharma 2007, ‘Dynamic analysis between the US stock returns

and the macroeconomic variables’, Applied Financial Economics, vol.17, no.5,

pp.369-377.

Reserve Bank of Australia 1999, ‘Six years of inflation targeting’, Address to the

Economic Society of Australia,

Available from:

<http://www.rba.gov.au/speeches/1999/sp-ag-200499.html#f1> [12 July 2015].

Reserve Bank of Australia 2012, Data for Research Discussion Paper 2012-07.

Available from: <http://www.rba.gov.au/publications/rdp/2012/2012-07-data.html>.

[6 November 2015].

Reserve Bank of Australia 2013, Monetary Policy Changes - A2 - Reserve Bank of

Australia. Available from: <http://www.rba.gov.au/statistics/tables/xls/a02hist.xls>.

[31 December 2013].

Sadique, S & Silvapulle, P 2001, ‘Long-term memory in stock market returns:

international evidence’, International Journal of Finance and Economics, vol.6, pp.

59-67.

Sardorsky, P 2001, 'Risk factors in stock returns of Canadian oil and gas companies’

Energy Economics, vol.23, no.1, pp. 17-28.

Schwert, W 1990, ‘Stock returns and real activity: A century of evidence’, The

Journal of Finance, vol.45, no.4, pp.1237-1257.

Page 166: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 161

Sharpe, W 1964, ‘Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under

conditions of risk’, vol.19, no.3, pp.425-442.

Shiller, R & Beltratti, A 1992, ‘Stock prices and bond yields: Can their

comovements be explained in terms of present value models?’, Journal of Monetary

Economics, vol.30, no.1, pp.25-46.

Shiller, R 2003, ‘From efficient markets theory to behavioural finance’, Journal of

Economic Perspectives, vol.17, no.1, pp.83-104.

Singh, R 1993, ‘Response of stock prices to money supply announcements:

Australian Evidence’, Accounting and Finance, vol.33, no.2, pp. 43-59.

Singh, R 1995, ‘Response of financial markets to announcements of the Australian

current account balance’, Accounting and Finance, vol.35, no.2, pp. 155-174.

Solow, R 1956, ‘A contribution to the theory of economic growth’, The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, vol.70, no.1, pp.65-94.

Standard and Poor’s 2015, Indices S&P ASX 200 sector breakdown, June 2015

Available from:

<http://www.au.spindices.com/indices/equity/sp-asx-200>. [12 July 2015].

Stock, J & Watson, M 1989 ‘The new indexes of coincident and leading economic

indicators’ in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, Volume 4, eds O Blanchard & S

Fischer, MIT Press, Massachusetts, pp.351-409.

Swan, T 1956 ‘Economic growth and capital accumulation’, Economic Record,

vol.32, no.2, pp.334-361.

Page 167: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 162

Tiwari, A 2012, ‘An empirical investigation of causality between producers’ price

and consumers’ price indices in Australia in frequency domain’, Economic

Modelling, vol. 29, no.5, pp.1571-1578.

Tulip, P & Wallace, S 2012, Estimates of uncertainty around the RBA’s forecasts,

Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney. Available from:

<http://www.rba.gov.au/publications/rdp/2012/pdf/rdp2012-07.pdf> [6 January

2015].

Velinov, A & Chen, W 2015, ‘Do stock prices reflect their fundamentals? New

evidence in the aftermath of the financial crisis’, Journal of Economics and

Business, vol.80, pp.1-20.

Worthington, A 2009, ‘All Ordinaries Index’ in Encyclopedia of Business in

Today’s World, ed Wankel, C 2009, Sage Publications, California, pp. 45-47.

Wasserfallen, W 1989, ‘Macroeconomic news and the stock market: Evidence from

Europe’, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol.13, no.4, pp. 613-626.

Wurgler, J 2000, ‘Financial markets and the allocation of capital’, Journal of

Financial Economics, vol.58, no.1, pp.187-214.

Qiu, L & Welch, I 2006, ‘Investor Sentiment Measures’, Social Science Research

Network, Rochester.

Page 168: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 163

9 Appendices

9.1 Appendix A – Structure of Macroeconomic Announcement Data and

Dates

The announcement day date for a macroeconomic variable is distinct from the

observation date for the same variable. This is because the announcement for the

variable usually occurs sometime after the period in which it is observed, due to the

time it takes for the information underlying the announced value to be collected and

processed. For example, the unemployment figure for the observation period

December 2003 is announced on 15 January 2004. Exceptions to this are the cash rate

and consumer sentiment index announcements. Cash rate announcements are made

the day before the intention to implement. Consumer sentiment index announcements

are made during the month in which the underlying survey was carried out.

Announcement dates are required to match unrevised macroeconomic announcement

data values with the appropriate stock return date. ABS announcement day dates are

manually retrieved from the ABS’s ‘Past and Future Releases’ page and paired with

announced values. The availability of these announcement dates on the ABS website

is one of the main constraints on utilising the full series of announced data values.

Announcement day dates for the cash rate are the first Tuesday of every month, except

for January. Announcement day dates for the consumer sentiment index are sourced

from MMS. The announcement dates, found and used to pair this macroeconomic

data to stock returns, are outlined in Table 20.

Page 169: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 164

Table 20 Macroeconomic Announcement Date Structure

Announcement Date Range Number of

announcements Missing Dates

Announcement

Delay

Unemployment January 2004 –

December 2013 120 0 1 month

Balance of Trade August 2005–

December 2013 101 0 2 months

Retail Sales August 2005–

December 2013 101 0 2 months

Producer Price Index October 2005–

November 2013 33 0 1 month

Consumer Price Index October 2005–

October 2013 33 0 1 month

Real GDP January 2000–

December 2013 55 0 3 months

Overnight Cash Rate September 2003

– December 2013 109 0 None

Consumer Sentiment April 2004 –

December 2013 117 9 None

The structure of the macroeconomic data series in their raw form is outlined in Table

21.

Table 21 Raw Macroeconomic Announcement Data Series Structure

Announcement Format Frequency Observation Span Missing

Values

Unemployment Per cent level Monthly December 2003 –

November 2013 1

Balance of Trade $ Billion Monthly June 2005–

October 2013 0

Retail Sales Per cent change from

previous month Monthly

June 2005–

October 2013 0

Producer Price Index Per cent change from

previous quarter Quarterly

September 2005–

September 2013 0

Consumer Price Index Per cent change from

previous quarter Quarterly

September 2005–

September 2013 0

Real GDP Per cent change from

last quarter Quarterly

March 2000–

December 2013 0

Overnight Cash Rate Per cent level Monthly September 2003 –

December 2013 0

Consumer Sentiment Index level Monthly April 2004 –

December 2013 0

Page 170: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 165

All macroeconomic announcement data are downloaded from the MMS database with

the exception of the overnight cash rate and consumer sentiment index (Haver 2013).

The data are values as first reported; that is, they are not revised values. Data on cash

rate announcements are sourced from the RBA. Their Monetary Policy Changes Table

A02 contains a history of new target cash rates that (from 2000) take effect on the

Wednesday after the announcement (Reserve Bank of Australia 2013). The

announcement occurs on the first Tuesday of every month, except January. For

months that were absent from table A02, I record the last available cash rate. This is

because a missing date means there was no change in monetary policy. Announced

Westpac-Melbourne Institute consumer sentiment index values are sourced from

Bloomberg using the ticker WMCCCONS Index. The index is never revised, so it is

not necessary to source unrevised announcement data.47 Nine of the announcement

dates for the consumer sentiment index are unavailable through MMS, resulting a in

a paring back of useful observations from 117 to 108.

All announcement dates were checked to ensure that they fell only on weekdays,

which was the case.

47 M.Best (personal communication, 7 May 2013) confirmed this.

Page 171: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 166

9.2 Appendix B – Model Fitting

9.2.1 Fitting ARMA for Stock Market Return Modelling

The EGARCH specification appeared to be a good candidate for modelling returns as

discussed in Section 2.3.2. Before resorting to this more complicated specification,

various ARMA specifications were estimated using Eviews 7 statistical software’s

non-linear least squares and ARMA regression function, and based on what was

outlined in Chapter 4.4, using Eviews 7 statistical software’s non-linear least squares

and ARMA regression function. Each specification was ranked according to the

Akaike Information Criteria (AIC). The AIC is preferred to the residual sum of

squares because it not only takes account of the fit to the data but also penalises the

use of additional variables, mitigating the possibility of selecting an over-fitted

specification.

In Table 22, I focus on the intercept, autoregressive lag order p, and moving average

term order q, for the purposes of determining the best ARMA (p,q) fit.

Table 22 AIC - All Ordinaries Total Returns ARMA Regression

ARMA (p,q) Akaike Information Criterion

(0,0) 2.9231

(0,1) 2.9223

(0,2) 2.9227

(1,0) 2.9222

(1,1) 2.9216

(1,2) 2.9225

(2,0) 2.9226

(2,1) 2.9225

(2,2) 2.9234

(1,1) (No Intercept) 2.9219

Number of Observations 2070

Page 172: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 167

The ARMA (1,1) specification that includes an intercept (in bold) exhibits the lowest

AIC (2.9216), and according to the criteria, it is the most parsimonious fit on the 2070

observations of stock returns.

Diagnostics on the standardised residuals of the ARMA (1,1) fit indicate the model

does not adequately capture serial correlation in the standardised residuals. The Q

statistics on the squared standardised residuals in Table 23 reject the null hypothesis

of no autocorrelation at all lags, indicating the conditional variance is time varying –

that is, autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (ARCH) effects are present.

Table 23 Q-Statistics on ARMA Model Squared Standardised Residuals

p-value

Lag 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

- - <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001***

Lag 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

<0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001*** <0.001***

The ARCH LM test of the squared residuals in Table 24 confirms the presence of

ARCH effects.

Table 24 ARCH LM Test on ARMA Squared Residuals

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

Test Lags Chi Squared p-value

ARCH LM 1 216.0102 <0.001***

The ARCH LM test was conducted at one lag. If the test indicates ARCH effects are

present at one lag, and the true lag structure is longer than this, it can be concluded an

ARCH effect exists (Enders 2004, p.146). That is, the variance is time varying and

requires a model that captures the effect of time on the residuals.

Page 173: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 168

9.2.2 Fitting GARCH/EGARCH for Stock Market Return and Time Varying

Volatility Modelling

If the return volatility is time varying, the coefficients and standard errors from the

fitted ARMA model could vary significantly from that of simultaneously estimated

mean return, and also the return volatility model (Enders 2004, p.145). In light of this,

I consider a GARCH specification that models both returns and return volatility

simultaneously to be more appropriate for this study.

There has been a proliferation of GARCH models since Tim Bollerslev formalised

the original specification in 1986. Some of the newer variations, such as TARCH and

EGARCH, account for asymmetric volatility responses to shocks.

As see in the Section 2.2, Kearns and Pagan (1993, p.169) found evidence that

Australian stock returns exhibit asymmetric volatility responses. To test for the

presence of asymmetric volatility responses, I fitted a standard GARCH model (using

the AIC) to select the best fit. A GARCH specification with an AR(1) mean equation

gave the most parsimonious fit. The residual diagnostics still indicated the presence

of serial correlation with results identical to those shown in Table 23. Additionally,

Engle and Ng’s (1993) Sign Bias test strongly rejected the joint hypothesis test of no

sign bias with an F distribution p-value of less than 0.0001.

These results suggest that a model, which allows for asymmetric responses in

volatility to return shocks, is more appropriate than a standard GARCH model.

An EGARCH specification was considered the most appropriate because it ensures

the estimated conditional variance is always positive, while allowing the coefficients

on the explanatory variables in the GARCH model to be negative. Based on this

analysis, the model ultimately settled upon for use in Chapter 6 is an EGARCH model.

Page 174: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 169

What follows is an outline of the fitting process for the continuous model in Section

6.1. The basic process outlined is repeated for the remainder of the models. A

summary of diagnostic results is shown at the bottom of their respective tables. For

example, the diagnostics for the first model are shown at the bottom of Table 12 in

Section 6.1.

The most parsimonious fit was an EGARCH (1,1) model, simultaneously estimated

with a mean model using an intercept. There were, however, no lagged autoregressive

or moving average terms.

Diagnostics on the standardised residuals indicated the model satisfactorily captured

serial correlation and sign bias. The Ljung-Box Q statistics out to 20 lags on the

standardised residuals indicated no serial correlation was present, and reported a p-

value of 0.8020. The ARCH LM test out to 20 lags was 0.9119, indicating no ARCH

effects. The Engle-Ng sign bias test indicated no sign bias, reporting an F-distributed

p-value of 0.2997.

Quantile plots of the standardised residuals were constructed to assess whether the

normal distribution for residuals was an appropriate assumption. Figure 19 shows,

despite a slightly skewed pattern, most of the empirically observed standardised

residuals from the fitted model (above) closely match the theoretical quantiles (down

to the second negative standard deviation). Only below the second standard deviation

(positive and negative) do they begin to fall away from the black line. This suggests

that the assumption of normally distributed standardised residuals is appropriate. I

only present the diagnostic for the first model because plots for the other models were

very similar. Plots for other models can be presented on request.

Page 175: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 170

Figure 19 EGARCH Normal Distribution Quantile Plot

Page 176: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 171

9.3 Appendix C – Robustness Tests

9.3.1 All Ordinaries Index Based Regressions

To test robustness, all regressions in the results section above were re-run using the

All Ordinaries index based total returns (over and above the regression using the ASX

200). Differing results are highlighted in the output tables in the following way:

Results in this section that were significant in the ASX 200 based regressions

but not in the All Ordinaries based regressions are emboldened.

Results in this section that were not significant in the ASX 200 based

regressions but found to be significant in the All Ordinaries based regressions

are in italics.

The All Ordinaries based regressions indicate some additional relationships that were

not evident in the ASX 200 based regressions. These relationships might suggest

firms with lower market capitalisation react differently to certain types of news than

firms with relatively high capitalisation. This is because as the All Ordinaries index

includes more firms with lower capitalisation than the ASX 200. The exploration of

this possibility, however, is outside the scope of this paper and maybe a subject for

further research.

Page 177: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 172

Full Period Continuous Regression

Table 25 Continuous Model using All Ordinaries Index based Returns

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

All Ordinaries Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.1226 0.0152**

Hola Holiday 0.3040 0.0021***

Daya Monday 0.0246 0.6572

Daya Tuesday -0.0461 0.3672

Daya Thursday 0.0202 0.7158

Daya Friday -0.0127 0.8035

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3738 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0293 0.0116**

Controla Term Spread 0.0307 0.1936

Controla Default Spread -0.0695 0.0065***

Surprisea Unemployment 0.3875 0.2780

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.0000 0.9402

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.1792 0.0468**

Surprisea Producer Price Index -0.1227 0.6640

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 0.6889 0.0547

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product -0.1872 0.3381

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 2.0089 0.0846

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0104 0.5024

Page 178: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 173

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.0000 0.9999

ARCH (1) term 0.1225 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1253 0.0000***

GARCH (1) term 0.9616 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0218 0.8235

Dayb Monday 0.0921 0.4952

Dayb Tuesday -0.3422 0.0316**

Dayb Thursday -0.1973 0.2007

Dayb Friday -0.2279 0.0642

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0826 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0004 0.9673

Controlb Term Spread 0.0029 0.6298

Controlb Default Spread 0.0096 0.1858

surpriseb Unemployment -0.1892 0.4918

surpriseb Balance of Trade -0.0003 0.1091

surpriseb Retail Sales 0.0220 0.8273

surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.4330 0.0403**

surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.3904 0.3687

surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -0.0821 0.7326

surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate 0.8038 0.4088

surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0353 0.0293**

Included observations 2070

Adjusted R-squared 0.2653

Log likelihood -2542.5750

Akaike Information criterion 2.4943

Diagnostics

Q(20) [p-value] 11.8210 [0.9220]

Q2(20) [p-value] 11.2400 [0.9400]

Page 179: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 174

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.5953 [0.9187]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.6000 [0.6150]

Table 25 includes results across the whole study period. The mean equation (in the

continuous regression) reports that retail sales have a significant relationship with All

Ordinaries based returns. This was not evident in ASX 200 returns based regression.

Additionally, the CPI, which was significant in the ASX 200 based regressions, is not

significant in the All Ordinaries based regression. This indicates the CPI relationship

with returns, found across the whole period, is dependent on the type of index used. I

therefore consider this non-robust.

Page 180: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 175

Full Period Dummy Variable Based Regression

Table 26 Dummy Variable Model using All Ordinaries Index

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

All Ordinaries Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.1207 0.0257**

Hola Holiday 0.3231 0.0003***

Daya Monday 0.0277 0.6407

Daya Tuesday -0.0370 0.5060

Daya Thursday 0.0179 0.7738

Daya Friday -0.0022 0.9672

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3759 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0291 0.0150**

Controla Term Spread 0.0347 0.1356

Controla Default Spread -0.0766 0.0027**

Surprisea Unemployment 0.1303 0.2301

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.0628 0.5669

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.0375 0.7475

Surprisea Producer Price Index 0.1609 0.2851

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 0.2021 0.2410

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product 0.4951 0.0830

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 0.1369 0.4442

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index -0.0974 0.3594

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Unemployment -0.0022 0.9920

Page 181: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 176

Bad Newsa Balance of Trade -0.1419 0.3258

Bad Newsa Retail Sales 0.0174 0.9032

Bad Newsa Producer Price Index -0.2874 0.3228

Bad Newsa Consumer Price Index -0.1611 0.5239

Bad Newsa Real Gross Domestic Product -0.5879 0.0706

Bad Newsa Overnight Cash Rate -0.2076 0.2686

Bad Newsa Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0880 0.5453

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.0271 0.7881

ARCH 0.1392 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1373 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9621 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0710 0.4822

Dayb Monday 0.0454 0.7355

Dayb Tuesday -0.3228 0.0486**

Dayb Thursday -0.2639 0.0978

Dayb Friday -0.2950 0.0181**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0809 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0038 0.7117

Controlb Term Spread 0.0026 0.6770

Controlb Default Spread 0.0146 0.0507

Surpriseb Unemployment 0.0917 0.4439

Surpriseb Balance of Trade -0.0181 0.8987

Surpriseb Retail Sales 0.0515 0.7353

Surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.2663 0.2128

Surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.3222 0.1089

Page 182: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 177

Surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -0.5930 0.0049***

Surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate -0.0409 0.8281

Surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0862 0.4989

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Unemployment 0.1519 0.4467

Bad Newsb Balance of Trade -0.1197 0.4475

Bad Newsb Retail Sales -0.0997 0.4977

Bad Newsb Producer Price Index -0.0028 0.9912

Bad Newsb Consumer Price Index 0.2726 0.2498

Bad Newsb Real Gross Domestic Product 0.6610 0.0123**

Bad Newsb Overnight Cash Rate -0.1980 0.2568

Bad Newsb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.3397 0.0159**

Included observations 2070

Adjusted R-squared 0.2614

Log likelihood -2536.4600

Akaike Information criterion 2.5038

Diagnostics

Q(20) 12.9900 [0.8780]

Q2(20) 12.9890 [0.8780]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.6903 [0.8395]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic

[p-value] 0.6883 [0.5591]

Table 26 reports the All Ordinaries based dummy variable regressions for the whole

period. The mean equation results indicate the real GDP figures are not significant in

the All Ordinaries based mean equation. This, again, indicates the real GDP results,

found across the whole sample, are sensitive to the chosen returns index. I therefore

consider this result non-robust.

Page 183: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 178

Pre- and Post-GFC Period Continuous Regression

Table 27 Continuous Model using All Ordinaries Index: Pre- and Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

All Ordinaries Index Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

AR(1) -0.1193 0.0019*** - -

Hola Holiday 0.4234 0.0093*** 0.2250 0.0408**

Daya Monday 0.2284 0.0013*** -0.0465 0.4608

Daya Tuesday 0.0411 0.5195 -0.0669 0.2716

Daya Thursday 0.2263 0.0031*** -0.0496 0.4247

Daya Friday 0.1087 0.0810 -0.0389 0.5109

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4012 0.0000*** 0.3599 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0220 0.2077 0.0365 0.0118**

Controla Term Spread 0.0098 0.9323 0.0603 0.0539

Controla Default Spread -0.0667 0.1030 0.0098 0.6665

Surprisea Unemployment -0.7767 0.5475 0.3890 0.2844

Surprisea Balance of Trade -0.0026 0.3677 0.0000 0.5423

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.2506 0.2811 0.1832 0.1006

Surprisea Producer Price Index -0.9275 0.0167** -0.0993 0.7278

Surprisea Consumer Price Index -0.6791 0.3226 1.4573 0.0026***

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product -0.1529 0.6666 -0.2451 0.0961

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 5.4656 0.0508 1.3678 0.2148

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index -0.0007 0.9707 0.0309 0.1774

Page 184: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 179

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

Intercept 0.0858 0.6094 -0.1678 0.1465

ARCH (1) term 0.0982 0.0494** 0.1311 0.0001***

Asymmetry term -0.1719 0.0000*** -0.1230 0.0000***

GARCH (1) term 0.8999 0.0000*** 0.9545 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0124 0.9471 0.0888 0.4852

Dayb Monday -0.0915 0.6728 0.2067 0.1736

Dayb Tuesday -0.5223 0.0637 -0.2187 0.2393

Dayb Thursday -0.4602 0.0678 0.0077 0.9643

Dayb Friday -0.4498 0.0287** -0.0860 0.5793

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.1037 0.0032*** -0.0759 0.0001***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0278 0.1825 0.0036 0.7614

Controlb Term Spread -0.0464 0.4068 0.0249 0.0429**

Controlb Default Spread 0.0740 0.0016*** 0.0206 0.1545

surpriseb Unemployment -0.3566 0.7701 0.0671 0.8058

surpriseb Balance of Trade 0.0022 0.3624 -0.0003 0.0429**

surpriseb Retail Sales -0.8912 0.0002*** 0.0674 0.4913

surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.7779 0.1954 0.0208 0.9197

surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.2253 0.7580 -0.0356 0.951

surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product 0.6263 0.2290 -0.1753 0.4708

surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate 2.1466 0.0742 0.1102 0.9164

surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0191 0.4153 -0.0402 0.0356**

pre-GFC post-GFC

Included observations 748 1322

Adjusted R-squared 0.2791 0.2545

Log likelihood -900.6437 -1602.7340

Akaike Information criterion 2.5124 2.4822

Page 185: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 180

Diagnostics

pre-GFC post-GFC

Q(20) [p-value] 13.3870 [0.8180] 7.7163 [0.9940]

Q2(20) [p-value] 9.4784 [0.9650] 22.2730 [0.3260]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.4711 [0.9767] 1.1260 [0.3150]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic [p-

value] 0.8964 [0.4426] 0.3227 [0.8090]

Table 27 shows the continuous All Ordinaries regression, splitting the whole period

sample into pre- and post-GFC sub-periods.

Prior to the GFC, the All Ordinaries based mean equation indicates the overnight cash

rate relationship with returns (which were significant when using the ASX 200 based

returns) is not significant. I therefore consider this result to be non-robust.

Prior to the GFC, the All Ordinaries based regression results report the PPI has a

significant effect on returns, while the ASX 200 based regression shows no

relationship. In the same sub-period, the variance equation also reports retail sales

surprises have a significant effect. In the period following the onset of the GFC, the

balance of trade surprises and consumer sentiment index surprises show a significant

relationship not detected using the ASX 200 index.

Page 186: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 181

Pre- and Post-GFC Period Dummy Variable Based Regression

Table 28 Dummy Variable Model using All Ordinaries Index: Pre- and Post-

GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

All Ordinaries Index Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

AR (1) -0.1212 0.0015*** - -

Hola Holiday 0.3633 0.0094*** 0.2520 0.0164**

Daya Monday 0.2462 0.0009*** -0.0433 0.5052

Daya Tuesday 0.0714 0.3085 -0.0558 0.3902

Daya Thursday 0.2638 0.0007*** -0.0680 0.3065

Daya Friday 0.1028 0.0803 -0.0419 0.4834

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4142 0.0000*** 0.3603 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0168 0.3051 0.0366 0.0100***

Controla Term Spread -0.0434 0.7022 0.0660 0.0394**

Controla Default Spread -0.1138 0.0060*** 0.0048 0.8348

Surprisea Unemployment -0.1467 0.4099 0.3094 0.0170**

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.2171 0.3266 0.0128 0.9139

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.0339 0.8671 -0.0669 0.6284

Surprisea Producer Price Index 0.1663 0.6025 0.1934 0.2733

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 0.0718 0.7558 0.2613 0.2507

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product 0.0181 0.8806 0.9701 0.0023***

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 0.2043 0.2354 -0.0016 0.9944

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0030 0.9785 -0.1767 0.2565

Bad News Announcements

Page 187: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 182

Bad Newsa Unemployment -0.0720 0.8653 0.0350 0.8494

Bad Newsa Balance of Trade -0.2270 0.4013 -0.1698 0.2712

Bad Newsa Retail Sales 0.0815 0.7587 0.1082 0.5225

Bad Newsa Producer Price Index -0.1469 0.7244 -0.4075 0.2775

Bad Newsa Consumer Price Index 0.5862 0.1080 -0.8464 0.0029

Bad Newsa Real Gross Domestic Product 0.0306 0.9114 -1.0913 0.0023

Bad Newsa Overnight Cash Rate -0.3637 0.0438 -0.0169 0.9454

Bad Newsa Consumer Sentiment Index -0.2051 0.2654 0.2562 0.1892

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

Intercept 0.0800 0.6364 -0.1254 0.2716

ARCH 0.1912 0.0017*** 0.1238 0.0002***

Asymmetry term -0.2170 0.0000*** -0.1251 0.0000***

GARCH 0.8497 0.0000*** 0.9569 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0226 0.9161 0.0979 0.4674

Dayb Monday -0.1994 0.3158 0.1733 0.2457

Dayb Tuesday -0.6496 0.0109** -0.2211 0.2270

Dayb Thursday -0.6200 0.0076*** -0.0239 0.8908

Dayb Friday -0.6684 0.0006*** -0.0901 0.5495

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0839 0.0179** -0.0688 0.0004***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0206 0.3891 0.0052 0.6538

Controlb Term Spread -0.0005 0.9952 0.0210 0.0832

Controlb Default Spread 0.1346 0.0005*** 0.0158 0.2394

Surpriseb Unemployment 0.3969 0.1204 0.0650 0.6469

Surpriseb Balance of Trade 0.2567 0.3286 -0.1671 0.3160

Surpriseb Retail Sales 0.1213 0.6933 -0.1555 0.3780

Surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.5856 0.3300 0.0724 0.7137

Page 188: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 183

Surpriseb Consumer Price Index 0.1963 0.7154 -0.3409 0.0881

Surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -1.7874 0.0000*** -0.6195 0.0153**

Surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate -0.0348 0.9227 0.1879 0.3546

Surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.2501 0.3162 0.1606 0.3137

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Unemployment -0.0964 0.8251 0.1901 0.4235

Bad Newsb Balance of Trade -0.1055 0.7715 -0.1137 0.5323

Bad Newsb Retail Sales -0.7448 0.0365** 0.1365 0.4616

Bad Newsb Producer Price Index -0.5301 0.4270 0.1641 0.5555

Bad Newsb Consumer Price Index -0.3429 0.5613 0.3212 0.2480

Bad Newsb Real Gross Domestic Product 2.1619 0.0000*** 0.4287 0.1416

Bad Newsb Overnight Cash Rate -0.7765 0.0441** -0.0871 0.6859

Bad Newsb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.2927 0.4087 -0.4036 0.0208**

pre-GFC post-GFC

Included observations 748 1322

Adjusted R-squared 0.2754 0.2528

Log likelihood -892.3771 -1593.5880

Akaike Information criterion 2.5331 2.4926

Diagnostics

pre-GFC post-GFC

Q(20) [p-value] 13.5420 [0.8100] 8.3430 [0.9890]

Q2(20) [p-value] 10.7090 [0.9330] 21.4840 [0.3690]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 0.5442 [0.9478] 1.0765 [0.3682]

Engle-Ng Joint Sign Bias Test F-Statistic

[p-value] 0.1424 [0.9345] 0.3926 [0.7583]

The All Ordinaries returns based dummy variable specification of the model, split into

pre- and post-GFC periods in Table 28, shows very similar results to the specification

regressed on the ASX 200 returns.

Page 189: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 184

9.3.2 Single Macroeconomic Variable Regressions

As an additional test of robustness, all the significant relationships between

macroeconomic variables and returns/return volatility (found in Chapter 6) were

cross-checked. This was achieved by re-running each ASX 200 returns based

regression on one macroeconomic variable announcement at a time. The results are

classified by macroeconomic variable below.

Page 190: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 185

Unemployment

Table 29 Unemployment Dummy Variable based Regression: Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.2422 0.0372**

Daya Monday -0.0423 0.5218

Daya Tuesday -0.0491 0.4356

Daya Thursday -0.0479 0.4861

Daya Friday -0.0368 0.5459

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3710 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0338 0.0205**

Controla Term Spread 0.0557 0.0876

Controla Default Spread 0.0023 0.9207

Surprisea Unemployment 0.2883 0.0272**

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Unemployment 0.0405 0.8242

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.1452 0.1979

ARCH 0.1406 0.0002***

Asymmetry term -0.1155 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9546 0.0000***

Page 191: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 186

Holb Holiday 0.0749 0.5454

Dayb Monday 0.1843 0.2145

Dayb Tuesday -0.2357 0.1972

Dayb Thursday -0.0748 0.6700

Dayb Friday -0.1175 0.4468

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0650 0.0008

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0005 0.9666

Controlb Term Spread 0.0255 0.0487**

Controlb Default Spread 0.0213 0.1340

Surpriseb Unemployment 0.0810 0.5482

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Unemployment -0.0295 0.8965

Included observations

1322

Q(20) [p-value]

-0.0280 [0.9950]

Q2(20) [p-value]

0.0150 [0.4620]

The mean equation in Table 29 gives a statistically significant coefficient for good

unemployment news, which has a sign consistent with the results shown in Table 15

in Chapter 6. I therefore consider this finding to be robust.

Page 192: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 187

Retail Sales

Table 30 Retail Sales Dummy Variable based Regression: Pre-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

AR(1) -0.1359 0.0005***

Hola Holiday 0.4764 0.0061***

Daya Monday 0.2440 0.0014***

Daya Tuesday 0.0420 0.5250

Daya Thursday 0.2114 0.0077***

Daya Friday 0.0998 0.1148

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4193 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0102 0.5805

Controla Term Spread -0.0061 0.9595

Controla Default Spread -0.1016 0.0211**

Surprisea

Retail Sales 0.1502 0.4651

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Retail Sales -0.0036 0.9892

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.0356 0.8165

ARCH 0.1176 0.0213**

Asymmetry term -0.1963 0.0000***

GARCH 0.8948 0.0000***

Page 193: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 188

Holb Holiday 0.0196 0.9225

Dayb Monday -0.0487 0.8177

Dayb Tuesday -0.4213 0.1221

Dayb Thursday -0.3791 0.1080

Dayb Friday -0.4319 0.0347**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0969 0.0075***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0246 0.2730

Controlb Term Spread -0.0312 0.6273

Controlb Default Spread 0.0892 0.0034***

Surpriseb Retail Sales 0.1878 0.4370

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Retail Sales -0.8430 0.0038***

Included observations 748

Q(20) [p-value]

0.0190 [0.8000]

Q2(20) [p-value]

-0.0300 [0.8460]

Page 194: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 189

Producer Price Index

Table 31 Producer Price Index Continuous Regression

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation48

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.3416 0.0009***

Daya Monday 0.0850 0.0899

Daya Tuesday 0.0127 0.7738

Daya Thursday 0.0985 0.0446**

Daya Friday 0.0418 0.3317

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3930 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0246 0.0433**

Controla Term Spread 0.0329 0.1823

Controla Default Spread -0.0322 0.1248

Surprisea Producer Price Index -0.1318 0.6691

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.0015 0.9868

ARCH 0.1414 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1236 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9650 0.0000***

48 The intercept was removed as the original specification displayed serial correlation in the first lag.

The model excluding the intercept was the second most parsimonious fit after a model including

both an intercept and an autoregressive lag; however, the autoregressive lag was not statistically

significant at the 5 per cent level in this specification.

Page 195: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 190

Holb Holiday 0.0557 0.5533

Dayb Monday 0.1014 0.4301

Dayb Tuesday -0.3113 0.0456**

Dayb Thursday -0.1821 0.2262

Dayb Friday -0.2475 0.0453**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0782 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0038 0.6988

Controlb Term Spread 0.0007 0.9098

Controlb Default Spread 0.0038 0.5370

surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.3563 0.0644

Included observations 2070

Q(20) [p-value]

-0.0140 [0.7060]

Q2(20) [p-value]

0.0020 [0.8850]

Table 31 does not report any significant relationships between the PPI and return

volatility. I therefore consider the finding that PPI surprises are associated with

increased volatility (reported in Table 12 in Chapter 6) non-robust.

Page 196: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 191

Consumer Price Index

Table 32 Consumer Price Index Continuous Regression

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation49

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.3406 0.0008***

Daya Monday 0.0871 0.0827

Daya Tuesday 0.0133 0.7630

Daya Thursday 0.1014 0.0392**

Daya Friday 0.0392 0.3630

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3905 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0243 0.0468**

Controla Term Spread 0.0338 0.1738

Controla Default Spread -0.0321 0.1288

Surprisea Consumer Price Index

0.6184 0.1131

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.0156 0.8672

ARCH 0.1481 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1254 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9650 0.0000***

49 The intercept was removed as the original specification displayed serial correlation in the first lag.

The model excluding the intercept was the second most parsimonious fit after a model including

both an intercept and an autoregressive lag; however, the autoregressive lag was not statistically

significant at the 5 per cent level in this specification.

Page 197: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 192

Holb Holiday 0.0655 0.4874

Dayb Monday 0.1250 0.3361

Dayb Tuesday -0.3050 0.0525

Dayb Thursday -0.1632 0.2824

Dayb Friday -0.2522 0.0425**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0792 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0039 0.6956

Controlb Term Spread 0.0003 0.9577

Controlb Default Spread 0.0053 0.4064

surpriseb Consumer Price Index 0.0069 0.9863

Included observations 2070

Q(20) [p-value]

-0.0140 [0.6940]

Q2(20) [p-value]

0.0040 [0.9090]

The mean equation in Table 32 shows the CPI relationship on returns in the

continuous regression over the full period was insignificant. I therefore consider this

finding in the results section to be non-robust.

Page 198: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 193

Table 33 Consumer Price Index Continuous Regression: Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.2637 0.0227**

Daya Monday -0.0439 0.5021

Daya Tuesday -0.0584 0.3498

Daya Thursday -0.0176 0.7839

Daya Friday -0.0333 0.5823

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3718 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0320 0.0289**

Controla Term Spread 0.0573 0.0774

Controla Default Spread 0.0027 0.9085

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 1.6729 0.0003***

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.1787 0.1079

ARCH 0.1469 0.0002***

Asymmetry term -0.1146 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9535 0.0000***

Page 199: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 194

Holb Holiday 0.0775 0.5366

Dayb Monday 0.2066 0.1644

Dayb Tuesday -0.2077 0.2516

Dayb Thursday 0.0004 0.9982

Dayb Friday -0.1004 0.5099

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0658 0.0010***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0006 0.9597

Controlb Term Spread 0.0272 0.0437**

Controlb Default Spread 0.0216 0.1363

surpriseb Consumer Price Index 0.0489 0.9336

Included observations 1322

Q(20) [p-value]

-0.0290 [0.9940]

Q2(20) [p-value]

0.0120 [0.4890]

Table 33 indicates good CPI news is positively related to returns (and vice versa),

based on the significance of the coefficients. The sign is also the same as that shown

in the original results (Table 12 in Chapter 6). I therefore consider this result to be

robust.

Page 200: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 195

Table 34 Consumer Price Index Dummy Variable based Regression: Post-

GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.2600 0.0216**

Daya Monday -0.0466 0.4802

Daya Tuesday -0.0551 0.3768

Daya Thursday -0.0186 0.7733

Daya Friday -0.0383 0.5313

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3718 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0309 0.0346**

Controla Term Spread 0.0571 0.0796

Controla Default Spread 0.0048 0.8376

Surprisea

Consumer Price Index 0.2948 0.2305

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Consumer Price Index -0.9384 0.0031***

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.1840 0.1034

ARCH 0.1476 0.0002***

Asymmetry term -0.1124 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9533 0.0000***

Page 201: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 196

Holb Holiday 0.0849 0.4953

Dayb Monday 0.2133 0.1567

Dayb Tuesday -0.1981 0.2779

Dayb Thursday -0.0041 0.9813

Dayb Friday -0.0949 0.5370

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0643 0.0011

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0014 0.9078

Controlb Term Spread 0.0265 0.0460**

Controlb Default Spread 0.0228 0.1268

Surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.1338 0.4903

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Consumer Price Index 0.2509 0.3221

Included observations 1322

Q(20) [p-value] -0.0280 [0.9950]

Q2(20) [p-value] 0.0120 [0.5800]

The mean equation in Table 34 indicates bad CPI news decreases returns (and vice

versa) based on the significance of the coefficients. The sign is also the same as that

shown in the original results (Table 15 in Chapter 6). I therefore consider this result

to be robust.

Page 202: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 197

Real GDP

Table 35 Real GDP Dummy Variable based Regression

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

AR(1) -0.0419 0.0634

Hola Holiday 0.3464 0.0004***

Daya Monday 0.0903 0.0690

Daya Tuesday 0.0208 0.6388

Daya Thursday 0.1102 0.0239**

Daya Friday 0.0458 0.2781

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3946 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0249 0.0414**

Controla Term Spread 0.0353 0.1414

Controla Default Spread -0.0331 0.1111

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product 0.6341 0.0366**

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Real Gross Domestic Product -0.6932 0.0413**

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.0060 0.9513

ARCH 0.1454 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1184 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9659 0.0000***

Page 203: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 198

Holb Holiday 0.0561 0.5725

Dayb Monday 0.1037 0.4403

Dayb Tuesday -0.3393 0.0369**

Dayb Thursday -0.1870 0.2259

Dayb Friday -0.2564 0.0428**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0798 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0048 0.6273

Controlb Term Spread -0.0009 0.8804

Controlb Default Spread 0.0060 0.3373

Surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -0.6807 0.0011***

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Real Gross Domestic Product 0.6113 0.0164**

Included observations 2070

Q(20) [p-value] -0.1500 [0.8660]

Q2(20) [p-value] 0.0040 [0.8850]

The mean equation in Table 35 reports a statistically significant coefficient for good

real GDP news, which has a sign consistent with the result in shown in Table 13 in

Chapter 6. However, when the All Ordinaries based returns are used as a dependent

variable, there is no significant relationship (see Table 26). I therefore consider this

result to be non-robust.

The variance equation gives statistically significant coefficients for good and bad real

GDP news, which have signs consistent with the result in shown in Table 13 in

Chapter 6. I therefore consider these findings to be robust.

Page 204: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 199

Table 36 Real GDP Dummy based Regression: Pre- and Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

AR(1) -0.1413 0.0003*** 0.2399 0.0382***

Hola Holiday 0.4620 0.0022*** -0.0432 0.5148

Daya Monday 0.2416 0.0017*** -0.0422 0.5043

Daya Tuesday 0.0187 0.7786 -0.0112 0.8631

Daya Thursday 0.2030 0.0079*** -0.0297 0.6291

Daya Friday 0.0750 0.2438 0.3737 0.0000***

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4253 0.0000*** 0.0293 0.0465**

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0097 0.5871 0.0547 0.0973

Controla Term Spread -0.0488 0.6988 0.0023 0.9223

Controla Default Spread -0.0873 0.0575 0.2399 0.0382**

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product 0.0170 0.9101 1.0164 0.0019***

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Real Gross Domestic Product -0.0516 0.8757 -1.1367 0.0020***

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

Intercept -0.0447 0.7876 -0.1249 0.2700

ARCH 0.1890 0.0031*** 0.1392 0.0001***

Asymmetry term -0.2103 0.0000*** -0.1048 0.0000***

GARCH 0.8597 0.0000*** 0.9592 0.0000***

Page 205: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 200

Holb Holiday 0.0543 0.7999 0.0596 0.6434

Dayb Monday -0.0560 0.7925 0.1765 0.2522

Dayb Tuesday -0.5105 0.0623 -0.2525 0.1788

Dayb Thursday -0.3832 0.0953 -0.0317 0.8568

Dayb Friday -0.4983 0.0116** -0.1265 0.4130

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.1126 0.0026*** -0.0631 0.0009***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0240 0.3205 0.0007 0.9544

Controlb Term Spread -0.0639 0.4750 0.0219 0.0583

Controlb Default Spread 0.1162 0.0020*** 0.0173 0.1760

Surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -1.7141 0.0000*** -0.7410 0.0050***

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Real Gross Domestic Product 2.1116 0.0000*** 0.4484 0.1194

pre-GFC post-GFC

Included observations 748 1322

Q(20) [p-value] 0.0250 [0.7590] -0.0320 [0.9870]

Q2(20) [p-value] -0.0250 [0.8630] 0.0150 [0.3980]

The mean equation in Table 36 yields statistically significant coefficients for good

and bad real GDP news in the post-GFC sub-period, and have signs consistent with

the result in shown in Table 15 in Chapter 6. I therefore consider these findings to be

robust.

The variance equation results report statistically significant coefficients for good and

bad real GDP news in the pre-GFC sub-period and good real GDP news in the post-

GFC sub-period. The signs are consistent with the results in shown in Table 15 in

Chapter 6. I therefore consider these findings to be robust.

Page 206: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 201

Cash Rate

Table 37 Overnight Cash Rate Continuous Regression: Pre-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

AR(1) -0.1334 0.0007***

Hola Holiday 0.5121 0.0034***

Daya Monday 0.2170 0.0050***

Daya Tuesday 0.0366 0.5919

Daya Thursday 0.1868 0.0199**

Daya Friday 0.0846 0.1918

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4226 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0147 0.4184

Controla Term Spread 0.0354 0.7679

Controla Default Spread -0.0661 0.1399

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 6.7545 0.0103**

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.0303 0.8461

ARCH 0.1095 0.0291**

Asymmetry term -0.1762 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9091 0.0000***

Page 207: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 202

Holb Holiday -0.0079 0.9679

Dayb Monday 0.0203 0.9258

Dayb Tuesday -0.4473 0.1136

Dayb Thursday -0.3071 0.1971

Dayb Friday -0.4174 0.0424**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.1005 0.0051***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0293 0.1871

Controlb Term Spread -0.0458 0.4157

Controlb Default Spread 0.0694 0.0115**

surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate 1.5265 0.4168

Included observations 748

Q(20) [p-value] 0.0160 [0.9090]

Q2(20) [p-value] -0.0300 [0.7930]

The result for the mean equation in Table 37, reports a statistically significant

coefficient for good cash rate news in the pre-GFC sub-period and has a sign

consistent with the result in shown in Table 14 in Chapter 6. When the All Ordinaries

based returns are used as the dependent variable, no significant relationship is reported

(see Table 27). I therefore consider this result to be non-robust.

Page 208: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 203

Table 38 Overnight Cash Rate Dummy Variable based Regression: Pre-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

AR(1) -0.1387 0.0003***

Hola Holiday 0.5138 0.0029***

Daya Monday 0.2093 0.0066***

Daya Tuesday 0.0251 0.7364

Daya Thursday 0.1838 0.0277**

Daya Friday 0.0909 0.1515

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4267 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0153 0.3926

Controla Term Spread 0.0116 0.9245

Controla Default Spread -0.0804 0.0707

Surprisea

Overnight Cash Rate 0.4341 0.0325**

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Overnight Cash Rate -0.4977 0.0209**

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept 0.0552 0.7209

ARCH 0.1230 0.0107**

Asymmetry term -0.1821 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9093 0.0000***

Page 209: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 204

Holb Holiday 0.0693 0.7025

Dayb Monday 0.0159 0.9399

Dayb Tuesday -0.4459 0.1050

Dayb Thursday -0.3099 0.2027

Dayb Friday -0.5188 0.0093***

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0980 0.0040***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0274 0.2193

Controlb Term Spread -0.0135 0.8214

Controlb Default Spread 0.0750 0.0060***

Surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate -0.0463 0.8796

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Overnight Cash Rate -0.4500 0.1808

Included observations 748

Q(20) [p-value] 0.0130 [0.9390]

Q2(20) [p-value] -0.0360 [0.7250]

The variance equation in Table 38 finds no significant relationship between the cash

rate and return volatility. I therefore consider the finding that bad cash rate

announcements are associated with decreased volatility (reported in Table 15 in

Chapter 6) to be non-robust.

Page 210: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 205

Consumer Sentiment Index

Table 39 Consumer Sentiment Index Continuous Regression

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation50

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.3300 0.0011***

Daya Monday 0.0862 0.0839

Daya Tuesday 0.0180 0.6815

Daya Thursday 0.0995 0.0393**

Daya Friday 0.0428 0.3160

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3882 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0254 0.0339**

Controla Term Spread 0.0351 0.1553

Controla Default Spread -0.0311 0.1373

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0125 0.4447

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.0192 0.8362

ARCH 0.1340 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1186 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9666 0.0000***

50 The intercept was removed as the original specification displayed serial correlation in the first lag.

The model excluding the intercept was the second most parsimonious fit after a model including

both an intercept and an autoregressive lag, however, the autoregressive lag was not statistically

significant at the 5 per cent level in this specification.

Page 211: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 206

Holb Holiday 0.0864 0.3391

Dayb Monday 0.1465 0.2546

Dayb Tuesday -0.3156 0.0435**

Dayb Thursday -0.1549 0.2999

Dayb Friday -0.2331 0.0577

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0802 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0014 0.8769

Controlb Term Spread 0.0009 0.8799

Controlb Default Spread 0.0049 0.4144

surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0346 0.0286**

Included observations 2070

Q(20) [p-value] -0.0130 [0.6980]

Q2(20) [p-value] 0.0020 [0.9430]

The variance equation in Table 39 reports that consumer sentiment index surprises

are positively related to return volatility. This is consistent with the finding reported

in Table 12 in Chapter 6 and therefore it appears to be robust.

Page 212: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 207

Table 40 Consumer Sentiment Index Dummy Variable based Regression

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.3320 0.0007***

Daya Monday 0.0834 0.1004

Daya Tuesday 0.0168 0.7033

Daya Thursday 0.0967 0.0506

Daya Friday 0.0391 0.3626

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3889 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0250 0.0388**

Controla Term Spread 0.0357 0.1472

Controla Default Spread -0.0304 0.1534

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index -0.0846 0.4436

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsa Consumer Sentiment Index 0.1251 0.4021

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.0049 0.9586

ARCH 0.1399 0.0000***

Asymmetry term -0.1268 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9691 0.0000***

Page 213: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 208

Holb Holiday 0.0741 0.4105

Dayb Monday 0.1255 0.3416

Dayb Tuesday -0.3139 0.0457**

Dayb Thursday -0.1586 0.2954

Dayb Friday -0.2558 0.0372**

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0807 0.0000***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0011 0.9054

Controlb Term Spread 0.0001 0.9812

Controlb Default Spread 0.0039 0.5195

Surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.1197 0.3031

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.2489 0.0575

Included observations

2070

Q(20) [p-value] -0.0140 [0.6640]

Q2(20) [p-value] 0.0020 [0.9230]

The variance equation in Table 40 shows no statistically significant relationship

between consumer sentiment index surprises and return volatility. This is not

consistent with the original finding (reported in Table 13 in Chapter 6), that indicates

bad consumer sentiment index surprises decrease return volatility. I therefore consider

the original finding to be non-robust.

Page 214: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 209

Table 41 Consumer Sentiment Index Dummy Variable based Regression:

Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient p-value

Hola Holiday 0.2350 0.0371**

Daya Monday -0.0474 0.4778

Daya Tuesday -0.0455 0.4665

Daya Thursday -0.0217 0.7416

Daya Friday -0.0399 0.5188

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.3707 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0293 0.0478**

Controla Term Spread 0.0571 0.0822

Controla Default Spread 0.0067 0.7756

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index -0.1938 0.2337

Bad News Announcement Days

Bad Newsa Consumer Sentiment Index 0.2741 0.1716

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient p-value

Intercept -0.1269 0.2626

ARCH 0.1335 0.0002***

Asymmetry term -0.1120 0.0000***

GARCH 0.9620 0.0000***

Page 215: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 210

Holb Holiday 0.0930 0.4312

Dayb Monday 0.1889 0.2063

Dayb Tuesday -0.2334 0.1987

Dayb Thursday -0.0081 0.9626

Dayb Friday -0.1294 0.3906

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.0674 0.0003***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0059 0.5843

Controlb Term Spread 0.0205 0.0680

Controlb Default Spread 0.0126 0.3153

Surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.1404 0.3498

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.3200 0.0648

Included observations

1322

Q(20) [p-value] -0.2700 [0.9770]

Q2(20) [p-value] 0.0170 [0.5630]

The variance equation in Table 41 shows no significant relationship exists between

the consumer sentiment index and return volatility. I therefore consider the finding

that bad consumer sentiment index announcements decrease return volatility

(reported in Table 15 in Chapter 6) to be non-robust.

9.3.3 Alternate Break-Point Regressions

To test whether the sub-period regression results were robust to a change in the choice

of break point (10 October 2008), the sample was split into sub-periods using an

alternative dating method. Fry-McKibbin, Hsiao and Tang (2014, p.525) observed

there is seldom consensus on the dating of a particular crisis, and they reviewed a

number of studies that had attempted to date the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). Their

study indicated the GFC was often viewed as two periods: the sub-prime crisis and

Page 216: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 211

the great recession. Based on their analysis, they dated the start of the sub-prime crisis

to 26 July 2007 and the end of the great recession as 31 December 2009. I have used

these two dates to define the GFC as the combination of both the sub-prime crisis and

great recession, resulting in three sub-periods: the pre-GFC period from 26 October

2005 to 25 July 2007, the GFC from 26 July 2007 to 31 December 2009, and the post-

GFC period from 1 January 2010 to 31 December 2013. For the sake of brevity, the

tables are not presented here, but can be produced upon request. All results withstood

the robustness test, with the exception of the pre-GFC retail sales result.

Differing results are highlighted in the output tables in the following way:

Results that were significant in the original regression, but are not significant

here, are emboldened. These results are not considered robust to choice of

break point.

Results that become significant here, but were not significant in the original

regression, are italicised.

Table 42 Continuous Model Results using Alternate Breakpoints: Pre- and

Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation51

, , , , , ,( ) +

Fri TS CSI

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t k Surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t Hol Day Control SurpriseR M a a a a

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

AR(1) -0.2666 0.0000*** - -

MA(3) 0.1488 0.0001*** - -

Hola Holiday 0.5337 0.0000*** 0.2164 0.0402**

51 The original specification that only had an AR(1) coefficient exhibited serial correlation in the

standardised residuals at various lags. The specification including an MA(3) term was the most

parsimonious fit controlling for this serial correlation.

Page 217: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 212

Daya Monday 0.2035 0.0083*** -0.0149 0.8308

Daya Tuesday -0.0351 0.6991 -0.0520 0.4432

Daya Thursday 0.2429 0.0091*** -0.0274 0.6881

Daya Friday 0.0720 0.3305 -0.0085 0.8981

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4154 0.0000*** 0.3902 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0218 0.1401 0.0324 0.0686

Controla Term Spread 0.0260 0.8056 0.0045 0.9183

Controla Default Spread -0.0384 0.7226 0.0114 0.6614

Surprisea Unemployment -2.3885 0.0210** 0.3331 0.3112

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.0007 0.5020 0.0000 0.8119

Surprisea Retail Sales 0.0256 0.9125 0.1059 0.4404

Surprisea Producer Price Index 0.1888 0.6800 0.0201 0.9668

Surprisea Consumer Price Index -0.5781 0.3821 1.8411 0.0059***

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product 0.1904 0.4293 -0.3012 0.4315

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 5.9780 0.0374** 1.5050 0.2841

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index -0.0075 0.6770 0.0255 0.2744

Variance Equation

, , , ,

2

, ,( ) ln( )Fri TS CSI

Hol t i t i t k surprise k t

i Mon j US k Unem

t i Day j ControlHol Day Control SurpriseV b b b b

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

Intercept 0.6243 0.0003*** -0.0086 0.9573

ARCH (1) term -0.2252 0.0029*** 0.1185 0.0024***

Asymmetry term -0.1913 0.0000*** -0.1263 0.0000***

GARCH (1) term 0.9106 0.0000*** 0.9515 0.0000***

Holb Holiday -0.0861 0.5948 -0.0261 0.8726

Dayb Monday 0.1557 0.5711 0.1215 0.5519

Dayb Tuesday -0.2258 0.4021 -0.2933 0.2256

Dayb Thursday -0.3397 0.1877 -0.0844 0.7392

Dayb Friday -0.5642 0.0188** -0.1502 0.4685

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.2123 0.0000*** -0.0829 0.0078***

Page 218: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 213

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0551 0.0049** 0.0031 0.8771

Controlb Term Spread -0.0790 0.1104 -0.0060 0.7378

Controlb Default Spread -0.5509 0.0029*** -0.0073 0.6820

surpriseb Unemployment 4.8613 0.0000*** -0.4844 0.3235

surpriseb Balance of Trade -0.0082 0.0034*** -0.0002 0.4704

surpriseb Retail Sales 0.3039 0.4211 -0.1797 0.5292

surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.0301 0.9634 0.0972 0.8687

surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.0939 0.8780 -0.8259 0.3871

surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -2.0001 0.0025*** -0.5387 0.1284

surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate 2.2260 0.2945 0.0736 0.9669

surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0324 0.2620 0.0226 0.4615

pre-GFC post-GFC

Included observations 440 1011

Adjusted R-squared 0.2748 0.2514

Log likelihood -405.8986 -1120.4040

Akaike Information criterion 2.0268 2.2916

Diagnostics

pre-GFC post-GFC

Q(20) [p-value] 23.1380 [0.1850] 15.2000 [0.7650]

Q2(20) [p-value] 19.4070 [0.3670] 17.0780 [0.6480]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 1.1652 [0.2812] 0.7823 [0.7372]

Page 219: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 214

Table 43 Dummy Variable Model Results using Alternate Breakpoints: Pre-

and Post-GFC

* 5 per cent level of significance

** 1 per cent level of significance

*** 0.1 per cent level of significance

tests are two sided based on a null hypothesis of zero

ASX 200 Daily Total Returns

Mean Equation

, , , ,

, ,

, ,

( ) +

Fri TS

t Hol t i Day i t j Control i t

i Mon j US

CSI CSI

k Surprise k Bad News

k Unem k Unem

Surprise Bad News

k t k t

t Hol Day Control

D D

R M a a a

a a

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

AR (1) -0.3076 0.0000*** - -

MA(3) 0.1322 0.0002*** - -

Hola Holiday 0.5317 0.0000*** 0.2154 0.0530

Daya Monday 0.2032 0.0088*** -0.0067 0.9256

Daya Tuesday -0.0050 0.9559 -0.0275 0.6919

Daya Thursday 0.3569 0.0003*** -0.0492 0.4928

Daya Friday 0.0560 0.4705 -0.0079 0.9042

Controla US Returns (Lagged) 0.4079 0.0000*** 0.3925 0.0000***

Controla Oil Returns (Lagged) 0.0099 0.4760 0.0359 0.0316**

Controla Term Spread 0.0152 0.8796 0.0131 0.7333

Controla Default Spread -0.1026 0.3630 0.0021 0.9335

Surprisea Unemployment -0.3700 0.0244** 0.2868 0.0364**

Surprisea Balance of Trade 0.1401 0.5532 0.0708 0.5937

Surprisea Retail Sales -0.0996 0.5499 -0.0558 0.6967

Surprisea Producer Price Index 0.5483 0.1314 0.1401 0.4955

Surprisea Consumer Price Index 0.0223 0.9379 0.4882 0.0146**

Surprisea Real Gross Domestic Product -0.1094 0.5598 1.0904 0.0009***

Surprisea Overnight Cash Rate 0.3299 0.0109** 0.0043 0.9880

Surprisea Consumer Sentiment Index 0.0277 0.7795 -0.1276 0.4551

Bad News Announcements

Page 220: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 215

Bad Newsa Unemployment 0.3653 0.1002 0.0548 0.7974

Bad Newsa Balance of Trade -0.0588 0.8208 -0.2368 0.1797

Bad Newsa Retail Sales 0.1015 0.6496 0.0579 0.7587

Bad Newsa Producer Price Index -0.4733 0.2104 -0.5432 0.1414

Bad Newsa Consumer Price Index 0.0343 0.9216 -1.0381 0.0000***

Bad Newsa Real Gross Domestic Product -0.2001 0.4722 -1.2222 0.0009***

Bad Newsa Overnight Cash Rate -0.3498 0.0140** 0.0255 0.9316

Bad Newsa Consumer Sentiment Index -0.1597 0.3145 0.2562 0.2177

Variance Equation

, ,

2

, ,

, , , ,

( ) ln( )

Fri TS

Hol t i t i t

i Mon j US

t i Day j Control

CSI CSISurprise Bad News

k Surprise k t k Bad News k t

k Unem k Unem

Hol Day ControlV b b b

D Db b

Variable Coefficient

(pre-GFC) p-value

Coefficient

(post-GFC) p-value

Intercept 0.8000 0.0004*** 0.0062 0.9594

ARCH -0.2634 0.0038*** 0.1105 0.0046***

Asymmetry term -0.2643 0.0000*** -0.1370 0.0000***

GARCH 0.8961 0.0000*** 0.9582 0.0000***

Holb Holiday 0.0182 0.9318 -0.0149 0.9219

Dayb Monday -0.0788 0.7598 0.1200 0.4354

Dayb Tuesday -0.1087 0.7288 -0.3456 0.0793

Dayb Thursday -0.1930 0.5242 -0.0828 0.6793

Dayb Friday -0.7236 0.0043*** -0.1280 0.4455

Controlb US Returns (Lagged) -0.2525 0.0000*** -0.0757 0.0069***

Controlb Oil Returns (Lagged) -0.0390 0.0269** 0.0036 0.8258

Controlb Term Spread -0.1009 0.0814 -0.0064 0.7152

Controlb Default Spread -0.7152 0.0113** -0.0078 0.6229

Surpriseb Unemployment 0.8113 0.0020*** 0.1638 0.3010

Surpriseb Balance of Trade 0.5747 0.0442** -0.1787 0.3247

Surpriseb Retail Sales 0.1989 0.4441 -0.1808 0.3711

Surpriseb Producer Price Index 0.6882 0.0635 0.0526 0.8295

Page 221: Identifying macroeconomic determinants of daily equity

10 August 2016 216

Surpriseb Consumer Price Index -0.8624 0.0757 -0.3846 0.0866

Surpriseb Real Gross Domestic Product -1.2677 0.0016*** -0.6218 0.0166**

Surpriseb Overnight Cash Rate -0.7870 0.0036*** 0.2648 0.2402

Surpriseb Consumer Sentiment Index -0.7413 0.0037*** 0.1637 0.3828

Bad News Announcements

Bad Newsb Unemployment -0.3392 0.4098 -0.3884 0.0952

Bad Newsb Balance of Trade -0.7726 0.0065*** -0.0400 0.8389

Bad Newsb Retail Sales -0.2935 0.2477 0.1276 0.5613

Bad Newsb Producer Price Index -2.0116 0.0003*** 0.1357 0.6658

Bad Newsb Consumer Price Index 1.1594 0.0314** 0.5271 0.1402

Bad Newsb Real Gross Domestic Product 0.9040 0.0614 0.0783 0.7961

Bad Newsb Overnight Cash Rate -0.0953 0.7960 0.0437 0.8462

Bad Newsb Consumer Sentiment Index 0.2785 0.3303 -0.3656 0.0532

pre-GFC post-GFC

Included observations 440 1011

Adjusted R-squared 0.2583 0.2589

Log likelihood 0.2583 -1110.2750

Akaike Information criterion 2.0587 2.3032

Diagnostics

pre-GFC post-GFC

Q(20) [p-value] 20.9600 [0.2810] 14.6550 [0.7960]

Q2(20) [p-value] 21.2790 [0.2660] 25.5900 [0.1800]

ARCH LM Test F-Statistic [p-value] 1.5415 [0.0642] 1.0825 [0.3621]