Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    1/42

    GO IT ALONE?

    THE EFFECT OF INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTIONS ON

    ECONOMIC SANCTION REGIMESA thesis

    submitted to the Graduate School of Arts & Sciences

    at Georgetown University

    in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

    degree of Master of Public Policy

    in the Georgetown Public Policy Institute

    ByJacqueline Roth Geis, M.P.P.

    Washington, D.C.April 14, 2007

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    2/42

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    3/42

    iii

    ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

    I would like to express my thanks to my advisor, Robert Bednarzik, and my GPPI

    colleagues who have provided me with invaluable support and guidance throughout this

    process.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    4/42

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    5/42

    1

    INTRODUCTION

    The relevance and utility of international organizations is cyclically, if not

    continually, called into question in the United States. Recent discussions on international

    organizations -- including the United Nations, the World Bank, and the International

    Monetary Fund -- have centered on issues of reform, corruption, and effectiveness

    (Helms, 1996; Keohane, 1998). In these discussions on reform, particular attention has

    been paid to the weaknesses and defects of international organizations; little attention,

    however, has been paid to the added value and strengths of these organizations.

    The United States and other nations continue to seek the approval of international

    organizations despite reservations about the effectiveness and necessity of their role in

    the international system. As a look to the recent crises in Iran and North Korea suggests,

    international organizations have a prominent role in enforcing international norms and

    standards. One of the methods of enforcement employed by these organizations is

    sanctioning.1

    Despite the general ambivalence surrounding the effectiveness of economic

    sanctions, their use and the threat of their use continue to be part of the international

    policy repertory. In fact, for the United Nations and other international institutions,

    sanctions are among the strongest possible enforcement measures. Sanctions, however,

    continue to be imposed not only by these institutions, but also by individual states or

    coalitions of states.

    1 In this paper, the word sanction and its derivatives will mean economic sanction unless otherwise stated.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    6/42

    2

    This paper will look at the use of economic sanctions in international affairs and

    analyze whether sanctions implemented with the strong backing and commitment of

    international organizations are more effective than sanctions imposed either unilaterally

    by a national government or multilaterally by an informal coalition of national

    governments. In addition, this paper will determine whether certain types of international

    organizations are more effective sanctioners. Both the threat and the imposition of

    sanctions will be included in the analysis.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    7/42

    3

    LITERATURE REVIEW

    International Organizations

    The struggle between state sovereignty and the developing international

    governance system is ongoing. It is important to note that international organizations

    have few, if any, independent powers. Unlike national governments, they do not have

    treasuries or standing militaries. International organizations are dependent on member

    states to provide them with financial, human, and military resources to accomplish tasks

    set before them. Their ability to secure these resources depends heavily on two

    interdependent factors: effectiveness and legitimacy.

    International organizations serve, among other functions, a convening function.

    They provide structured opportunities for their members to discuss events and goals.

    Given that these organizations often have charters or mandates that provide moral

    authority, they are more likely to be seen as working in the interest of the global order or

    good rather than national self-interest. States seek this moral authority when they request

    that international organizations take action when they have reason to believe that another

    member state is disrupting this order. Even when states are determined to act on their

    own against renegade states, they often seek approval from international organizations in

    order to validate their claims and their actions in other words, to supply legitimacy to

    their causes.

    Keohane (1998) argues that institutions whose members have shared values tend

    to be more effective. The nature of the institutional mandate is also a determining factor

    in its perceived effectiveness. Less controversial mandates, such as setting measurement

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    8/42

    4

    standards, tend to be more effective than mandates whose definitions are not well defined

    and touch at controversial or central value, such as human rights. Effective organizations

    with wide-reaching, controversial mandates are rare.

    Economic Sanctions

    Economic sanctions are most often defined as restrictions or limitations on

    intergovernmental trade intended to alter the political behavior of a given state. They are

    economic measures directed to political objectives and can be imposed by a single state

    or a group of states (Barber, 1979). The effectiveness and effects of sanctions have been

    the subject of extensive scholarly literature. The verdict has been almost uniformly

    negative. Sanctions were determined to be ineffective and, moreover, often had effects

    that were detrimental not to the sanction target, but to the general population of the

    sanctioned country. For example, the Organization of American States (OAS) and UN

    sanctions against Haiti from 1991 to 1994 were characterized by a large majority of

    countries as porous and ineffective; with respect to putting pressure on the Haitian

    government; however, these sanctions did have a negative economic impact on the

    country, particularly the rural poor (Gibbons and Garfield, 1999).

    The idea, and eventual use, of smart sanctions was developed in response to

    episodes such as the 1991-1994 Haiti sanctions. Smart sanctions seek to maximize the

    economic degradation of the regime being targeted by the sanctions while minimizing the

    amount of suffering that the sanctions impose on the countrys population (Cortright and

    Lopez, 2002). In essence, these sanctions try to hit the intended target through methods

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    9/42

    5

    such as freezing financial assets, arms embargoes, and restrictions on commercial trade.

    The sanctions recently implemented by the UN Security Council against North Korea and

    those implemented by the US against Taliban financial assets are examples of smart

    sanction activity. While this amended form of sanction addresses one of the concerns

    raised unintended suffering of the countrys population, Drezner argues that smart

    sanctions are not any more effective than those previously implemented (Drezner, 2003).

    The question remains the same. If sanctions are ineffective, why do policymakers

    continue to use them? Recent literature claims that the perceived ineffectiveness of

    sanctions that scholars have quantifiably found to be the case may be the partially caused

    by selection bias. That is, studies conducted prior to the late 1990s only included data

    from events where the sanctions had been implemented. T. Clifton Morgan (2003) has

    argued that these data must be augmented with data from events where sanctions were

    threatened, but not actually imposed. He argues that the exclusion of the data from

    threatened sanction events introduces bias into the results. In other words, implemented

    sanctions and threatened sanctions may have different impacts.

    Multilateral vs. Unilateral Sanctions

    Within the discussion about the forms that sanctions should take, there has also

    been debate about whether multilateral or unilateral sanctions are more effective.

    Unilateral action does provide the sanctioning state (or sender) with the ability to

    sanction a target state (or target) quickly and to deploy the type and breadth of sanctions

    that the state considers appropriate given the targets actions. Working unilaterally,

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    10/42

    6

    however, also subjects the sender to all of the costs, both economically and politically, of

    taking action against the target (Mansfield, 1995; Drezner, 2000). Furthermore, very few

    states have economies large enough to impose effective sanctions regimes against their

    targets (Drezner, 2000).

    Even for states that can impose effective sanctions regimes unilaterally, however,

    there are benefits of seeking multilateral action, including the sharing of both economic

    and political costs. The economic cost burden is spread across the governments and

    citizens of sender countries, which limits the impact of the sanction on the populations of

    the sanctioning countries. Moreover, the larger the multilateral coalition, the greater the

    economic cost to the target. The political cost burden is also shared, creating greater

    legitimacy and moral authority for the effort and thereby protecting senders from

    removing sanctions due to domestic political pressures (Mansfield, 1995; Drezner, 2000;

    Thompson 2006). There is a greater economic cost to the target the larger the multilateral

    coalition.

    While there are benefits, there are also costs to multilateral sanctions. Drezner

    breaks the costs down into three categories: bargaining between the sender and the target,

    bargaining between the initial (or primary) sender and subsequent senders, and

    enforcement. He argues that sender often seeks multilateral support for the most

    sensitive cases: when the stakes are high and there is a real possibility of long-term

    deadlock. In other words, multilateral action is often sought when unilateral action is not

    an option. Bargaining between potential senders in the international arena also tends to

    imply costs to the initial sender since the sender often has to compromise or offer

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    11/42

    7

    concessions in order to gain consensus. As the number of senders increases, enforcement

    also becomes more difficult. An increase in the number of senders leads to an increase in

    the number of possible defectors (Drezner, 2000; Thompson 2006).

    Even though policymakers continue to push for coalitions, the early quantitative

    evidence in the literature has shown that the benefits of multilateral action are not worth

    the costs. There has been substantial evidence that unilateral action is more effective

    than multilateral (Martin, 1993). At the beginning of the decade, however, other scholars

    began to look at the role of international organizations in multilateral sanctions efforts

    and making distinctions between ad hoc multilateral sanctions regimes and those

    structured under an international organization. Using this distinction, Drezner (2000)

    shows (1) that multilateral sanctions with an international organization as the sender are

    more likely to be effective than unilateral sanctions and (2) that multilateral sanctions

    without an international organization as the sender are less likely to be effective than

    unilateral sanctions. Mansfield (1995) argues that international institutions each have

    distinct characters and that some may implement more effective sanctions than others.

    There is a gap in the literature between Mansfields assertion and Drezners

    results that this paper seeks to address. There are various types of international

    organizations that implement sanctions regimes and the effectiveness of these

    organizations has not been studied. Furthermore, neither Drezner nor Mansfield included

    the effectiveness of the threat of sanctions into their analysis. This paper will seek to

    expand upon Drezners results of the importance of international organizations in light of

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    12/42

    8

    the new data and to test Mansfields assertion that distinguishing between international

    organizations is important.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    13/42

    9

    HYPOTHESIS, DATA SOURCE, & METHODOLOGY

    This paper will examine whether sanctions threatened or implemented with the

    strong backing and commitment of international organizations are more effective than

    sanctions threatened or imposed either unilaterally by a national government or

    multilaterally by an informal coalition of national governments. It will further analyze

    whether certain types of international organizations are more effective in threatening or

    implementing sanctions.

    Five hypotheses will be tested:

    H1: Unilateral sanctions are more effective than multilateral

    sanctions.

    H2: Multilateral sanctions with international organization (IO)

    involvement are more effective than unilateral sanctions and

    multilateral sanctions without IO involvement.

    H3: Sanctions with the backing of a regional IO are more effective

    than those with the support of a global IO.

    H4: Sanctions with the support of a UN agency are more effective

    than sanctions with the support of another IO.

    H5: Economic international organizations implement more effective

    sanctions and sanction threats than political international

    organizations.

    The same dependent variable (FINALOUTCOME) will be used in each of the

    hypothesis test. It is defined as the success of the sanction case. The dependent variable

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    14/42

    10

    will be constructed by synthesizing the 10 possible final outcomes in the TIES database

    into four categories: (1) successful, (2) partially successful, (3) stalemate, and (4)

    unsuccessful. Regime success is defined by total acquiescence by the target or successful

    negotiations in either the threat or imposition stage. Partial success is when the target

    only agrees to some of the senders demands. A stalemate is when the sanction regime

    has not been lifted but neither side wants to back down. Failure, or an unsuccessful

    sanction regime, is defined as the removal of sanctions without gaining any concessions

    from the target. This categorization will allow for greater comparison across sanction

    cases.

    While it is usual when the dependent variable is an ordered measure of

    effectiveness (successful, partially successful, stalemate, and unsuccessful) to use an

    ordered probit regression model, in this instance running both the ordered probit model

    and the OLS regression model showed similar results. For ease of interpretation, the

    OLS results are used. The ordered probit results are appended in Appendix I. The model

    is based on completed studies by Drury (1998), Drezner (2000) and Whang (2006) and

    seeks to determine the success of sanction regimes. Data from the Threat and

    Implementation of Sanctions (TIES) database will be used in this study. The TIES

    database was released by Morgan, Krustev, and Bapat in October 2006. The database

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    15/42

    11

    EXHIBIT 1: VARIABLE DEFINITIONS AND SOURCES

    Variable Name Definition Source

    Final outcome

    The outcome of the sanction event:

    1 = successful2 = partially successful

    3 = stalemate

    4= unsuccessful

    Threat and

    Implementation ofSanctions (TIES)

    Database

    Target cost

    The anticipated costs to the target; higher

    costs to the target would increase the

    incentive to acquiesce; variable =1 when

    costs are moderate or high; =0 if costs arelow

    TIES

    Sender cost

    The anticipated costs to the sender;

    variable =1 when costs are moderate or

    high; =0 if costs are low

    TIES

    Issue

    If the issue at hand is of large consequence,

    political regime change for instance, then

    this variable = 1; variable = 0 if the issue is

    limited in scope.

    TIES

    ThreatIf the sanction event was resolved in the

    threat stage (no sanctions implemented) =1TIES

    USAWhether the USA is the sender; variable

    =1 when USA is senderTIES

    VARIABLES OF INTEREST

    Regional IO If regional IOs are involved, variable =1 TIES

    Global IO If global IOs are involved, variable =1 TIES

    MultiIf multiple countries are involved, but nointernational organizations, variable =1

    TIES

    UnilateralIf only one country and no international

    organizations are involved, variable =1TIES

    UN

    Whether a UN organization was involved

    in the sanction event; constructed dummyvariable; UN involvement = 1

    TIES

    Political IOIf an IO serves a mainly political function,i.e. UN or Arab League involvement = 1

    TIES

    Economic IOIf an IO serve a mainly economic function,

    i.e. WTO or OPEC involvement, =1TIES

    includes 888 sanction cases from 1971 to 2000. A sanction case is defined as a single

    sanction episode or a merged group of sanction episodes, regardless of whether the

    episode ended with a sanction threat or implementation. Sanction cases form the base

    unit of the data (Morgan et al, 2006).

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    16/42

    12

    Key factors in sanction regimes as determine by previous studies and theory are

    presented in Exhibit 1. The expected effects of each variable are summarized in Exhibit

    2. The model is presented in Exhibit 3.

    EXHIBIT 2: HYPOTHESIZED EFFECTS AND BACKGROUND OF SANCTION VARIABLES

    Variable Name Description Prediction Rationale

    X1 Target cost Dummy PositiveDrury (1998), Drezner

    (2000)

    X2 Sender cost Dummy NegativeDrury (1998), Drezner

    (2000)

    X3 Issue Dummy NegativeDrury (1998), Drezner(2000); Whang (2006)

    X4 USA Dummy PositiveDrury (1998), Drezner

    (2000)

    X5 Threat Dummy PositiveDrury (1998), Drezner

    (2000)

    X6 Regional IO Dummy PositiveVariable of interest,Mansfield (1995)

    X7 Global IO Dummy PositiveVariable of interest,

    Mansfield (1995)

    X8 Multi Dummy NegativeVariable of interest,Mansfield (1995)

    X9 Unilateral Dummy NegativeVariable of interest,

    Mansfield (1995)

    X10 UN Dummy Positive

    Variable of interest,

    Mansfield (1995)

    X11 Political IO Dummy NegativeVariable of interest,

    Mansfield (1995)

    X12 Economic IO Dummy PositiveVariable of interest,

    Mansfield (1995)

    EXHIBIT 3: MAIN REGRESSION MODEL

    OUTCOME= 1Targetcost + 2Sendercost + 3Issue + 4Threat +5U SA + 6RegionalIO+ 7GlobalIO +8Multi

    The TARGETCOSTvariable serves as a proxy for the strength of the proposed or

    implemented sanction. As the strength of the sanction increases, the costs to the target

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    17/42

    13

    are also likely to increase. Increased target costs will most likely increase the likelihood

    of the sanctions success.

    SENDERCOSTis a proxy variable to determine the level of commitment of the

    sender. Its effect on sanctions success could be either positive or negative. Senders

    willing to incur high costs to sanction targets are more likely to have strong resolve to

    solve the conflict successfully, increasing the likelihood of sanction success. On the

    other hand, increased costs could raise political pressures to end the conflict sooner,

    potentially decreasing the likelihood of sanction success.

    TheISSUEvariable is predicted to have a negative effect on sanction success.

    The larger or more complex the issue or set of issues that the senders have with the target,

    the more difficult it is for the target to agree to the demands or to negotiate with the

    senders (Whang, 2006). These larger, more complex issues, such as regime change, are

    often not in the best interests of the targeted states current rulers and, therefore, they

    have decreased incentives to back down from their current policies. As such, seminal

    issues, like regime change, lead to the decreased effectiveness of sanctions.

    The THREATvariable illustrates the effectiveness of sanction threats as opposed

    to sanction implementation. Threats provide warnings and that conflicts resolved in the

    threat stage show the initiative of both the sender and target to come to a solution prior to

    sanction implementation. It is predicted that threatening sanctions increases the

    likelihood of that sanction regimes success.

    The USA variable is included in the regressions where unilateral sanctions (UNI)

    are the reference regime category. Earlier studies separated out the effect of unilateral

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    18/42

    14

    United States sanctions to isolate the effect that being a superpower has on sanctions

    success. The United States, as a hegemonic power, may have sway over targets that other

    states and potential senders do not have. U.S. involvement is expected to increase the

    effectiveness and success of sanction regimes.

    Sanction regime variables are included to determine the effects of multilateral and

    international organization (IO) involvement in sanction cases. The international

    organization variables are broken down into various categories to determine whether

    certain international organizations are more successful with sanctions policies than

    others. There are three sets of dummy indicator variables used (1)REGIONAL IO,

    GLOBAL IO, MULTI, UNI; (2) POLITICAL IO, ECONOMIC IO, MULTI, UNIand (3)

    UN, OTHER IO, MULTI, UNI. Each of these dummy indicator variables was created

    from raw descriptive data on country and organization involvement found in the TIES

    database.

    To compare the likely success of sanctions with regional organization

    involvement, sanctions with global organization involvement, multilateral sanctions

    without organization involvement, and unilateral sanctions, the first set of variables

    (REGIONAL IO, GLOBAL IO, MULTI, UNI) is used in the regression. To identify

    whether international organizations with a primarily political mandate, like the UN and

    the Arab League, are more or less likely than economic institutions, like the WTO and

    OPEC, to increase the success of sanctions, a second set of variables was created

    (POLITICAL IO, ECONOMIC IO, MULTI, UNI). Another set of variables will be used

    to determine whether the UN is more effective than other international organizations

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    19/42

    15

    (UN, OTHER IO, MULTI, UNI). In each regression, one category in the set serves as a

    reference group to which the three remaining groups are compared.

    The international organizational variables are predicted to increase the likelihood

    of success for the sanction regime. The tests intend to show that different types of

    institutions increase the likelihood of success to varying degrees. Using Keohanes

    (1998) logic that larger, more complex institutions are less effective, global institutions

    should show to be less effective at sanction implementation than regional institutions. As

    for political and economic organizations, economic institutions have more ready tools at

    their disposal (trade sanctions, embargoes, etc.) than political organizations and should

    show to be more effective than their political counterparts. The third set takes the UN

    system as a separate dummy variable. Given the UNs size and complexity, it should

    show to be less effective than other international institutions as a sanctioner.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    20/42

    16

    LIMITATIONS

    This model has limitations. Sanction events are partially formed by a set of

    strategic decisions. The sender and target respond to the others last move. A regression

    does not capture the effects of this decision-making on sanction outcomes. The

    regression allows a focus on the impact that international organizations may have in

    determining the success of a sanction case (Whang, 2006).

    There are many other factors that can impact a sanction case or cause a state to

    seek a multilateral sanctions approach. For example, the time that it takes to achieve

    consensus within an international organization is not measured in these data, but is

    included in the effects of having an international institution as a sender.

    Limitations also arise from the data collection. The TIES database was created

    from normative sources2

    and asked its coders to use judgment when entering the data.

    There is no way to determine the personal biases of each of these coders. It is not

    feasible to think that each viewed every sanction case in the same light and it may very

    well be the case that sanction success was determined differently by coders on the

    margins.

    2 The TIES Database collected material from many sources includingLexis-Nexis,Facts on File, Keesings

    Record of Contemporary Events, and the indices ofThe New York Times andLondon Times (Morgan et al,

    2006).

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    21/42

    17

    ANALYSIS

    The data show that the majority of sanction cases are implemented unilaterally.

    In fact, in the TIES dataset, approximately 71 percent or 627 cases are unilateral sanction

    cases. Frequency of the use of a particular type of sanction, however, does not imply the

    greater effectiveness of that type. What frequency does imply, however, is that unilateral

    sanctions were the implementation method of choice for sanctions during the period of

    1971-2000.

    The general question that this study hopes to answer is whether this preferred

    method of implementing sanctions is the one that yields the largest likelihood of success.

    Previous studies (Drezner, 2000) have shown that there are other types of sanctions that

    have a greater likelihood for success than unilateral sanctions, namely multilateral

    sanctions with the involvement of international organizations. As depicted in Chart 1, the

    data analyzed for this study has 259 non-unilateral sanction cases (approximately 29

    percent of the sample). Of these 259 cases, the overwhelming majority (232) included

    the involvement of an international institution. As Chart 2 illustrates, without accounting

    for other factors, the TIES data seem to support Drezners theory that multilateral

    sanctions with international organization involvement have the highest success rate and

    call the relative effectiveness of unilateral sanctions into question. Nearly half of the

    successes or partial successes involved an international organization. This higher success

    rate for IO sanctions is particularly notable since states are more likely to seek

    international organizations assistance when facing tougher, more complex situations

    (Drezner, 2000; Thompson 2006).

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    22/42

    18

    CHART 1: THE FREQUENCY OF UNILATERAL AND MULTILATERAL SANCTIONS (1971-2000)

    70.6%

    (627)

    26.1%(232)

    2.0%

    (18)1.2%

    (11)

    Unilateral Multilateral w/ IO Other Multilateral Missing

    Data Source: Threat and Imposition of Sanctions (TIES) Database; N=888.

    States are more likely to turn to some international organizations than others.

    Chart 3 provides an overview of the international organizations represented in the data.

    A cursory look at the chart illustrates that when an international institution is involved in

    a sanction regime, it is more likely to be a regional (or selected membership)3

    organization than a global organization. In fact, 77.6 percent of the 232 observations that

    cited involvement of an international organization cited the involvement of a regional

    organization such as the European Union or the Arab League.

    3 For ease of reference, the phrase regional international organization will be used to represent all select

    membership organizations, even when selection is determined based on characteristics other than

    geography. OPEC would be an example.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    23/42

    19

    CHART 2: OUTCOMES OF UNILATERAL AND MULTILATERAL SANCTIONS, 1971-2000

    20.1%

    8.5%7.5%

    20.3%

    15.1%

    3.4%

    10.8%

    37.5%

    22.2%

    27.8%

    16.7%16.7%

    Successful Partially Successful Stalemate Unsucessful

    Unilateral Multilateral w/IO Other Multilateral

    Data Source: Threat and Imposition of Sanctions (TIES) Database; N=888

    Here again, the frequency of regional organizational involvement does not

    provide sufficient information about the success of the sanction. In this instance, the

    preliminary data do not illuminate any patterns either. It does illustrate that sanctions

    threatened or implemented with the assistance of UN organizations can be expected to be

    less successful than those implemented by other international organizations. Nearly 40

    percent of sanctions involving UN organizations ended in failure or a stalemate.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    24/42

    20

    CHART 3: THE DISTRIBUTION OF SANCTIONS WITH INTERNATIONAL ORGANIZATIONALINVOLVEMENT , 1971-2000

    UN Organizations

    15.9%

    WTO/GATT

    4.3%

    EEC

    30.2%

    OPEC

    5.2%

    Arab League

    9.5% Other

    8.6%

    EU

    26.3%

    Organization Key: UN = Any organization in the United Nations System; WTO/GATT = World TradeOrganization/General Agreement on Tariffs and Taxes; EEC = European Economic Community; OPEC = Organizationof Petroleum Exporting Countries; EU = European Union

    Data Source: Threat and Imposition of Sanctions (TIES) Database; N=232

    This preliminary outcome poses a question regarding the tradeoffs of working

    with an international organization. Is there an organizational size, or character, or

    composition at which the benefits of working with a international organization

    minimized costs, fewer political and economic risks are outweighed by the political

    costs and time needed to reach consensus, causing international organization-endorsed

    sanctions to lose their effectiveness edge over unilateral sanctions? The preliminary data

    are inconclusive on this point.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    25/42

    21

    CHART 4: OUTCOMES OF SANCTIONS WITH INTERNATIONAL ORGANIZATION INVOLVEMENT,1971-2000

    40.0%

    26.0%

    16.0%

    6.0%

    36.1%

    11.7%

    2.8%

    10.0%

    35.1%

    29.7%

    8.1%

    13.5%

    Successful Partially Successful Stalemate Unsucessful

    Global IOs Regional IOs UN

    Data Source: Threat and Imposition of Sanctions (TIES) Database; N=232.

    Regression Analysis

    Regression analysis provides more conclusive answers to this question. From the

    base regression outlined in Exhibit 3, five regressions are run to test the five hypotheses.4

    4 The TIES data set does not include effectiveness data for 356 of its observed sanction threats andsanction events. The vast majority of these 356 observations are for unilateral sanction threats or events.

    The reason for this low rate of unilateral effectiveness rates could be that news services may have lost

    interest in long-running sanction threats or events and did not report the results. Given that the data for the356 missing effective observations may skew the results toward underreporting the effectiveness ofunilateral sanctions, the results reported in this paper include only the 532 observations that have

    effectiveness data. Ramsey RESET test shows model misspecification when using all 888 of the TIES

    observations, while it showed no model misspecification when using the 532 observations that had outcome

    data.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    26/42

    22

    Each of the regressions utilizes one of the three sets of sanction regime variables

    described in the Hypothesis, Data Source, & Methodology section. A note detailing

    which sanction regime set is used included with each model. The first, bolded variable

    marks the regime reference group for the model.

    In addition to the five analyses displayed in this section, regressions were run to

    determine whether uniqueness of the European Union as a multinational regional actor

    did not skew the results. To determine this, several regressions were run with the EU as a

    unilateral actor and as a regional actor. In all instances, the results were similar and since

    the EU is still a group of national governments, the entity is characterized as a regional

    organization for the purposes of this paper.

    Hypothesis 1: Unilateral sanctions are more effective than multilateral sanctions.

    Model 1 does not support the hypothesis that unilateral sanctions are more

    effective than multilateral sanctions. In fact, the model shows that multilateral sanctions

    that include international organization involvement are more likely to be successful than

    unilateral sanctions. The model does not support any findings on the likelihood for

    success of multilateral sanctions without organization involvement.

    The two international organization sanction variables were both significant and

    positive, providing evidence that sanction threats and sanctions backed by international

    organizations are more likely to be effective than those implemented unilaterally. This

    model leads to the conclusion that including either regional or global international

    organizations in sanction events increases the likelihood that the sanction events will be

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    27/42

    23

    MODEL 1: MAIN REGRESSION (DEPENDENT VARIABLE: OUTCOME)SANCTION REGIME SET: Unilateral, Global IO, Region IO, Multilateral

    Coefficients (Standard Error)

    Target Cost -.004 (.003)

    Sender Cost -.002 (.003)Issue .101 (.205)USA .244 (.117)***Global IO .519 (.196)***Region IO .780 (.140)***Multi .118 (.290)Threat .748 (.258)***

    Number of Observations 532F (Prob >F) 5.94 (0.0000)Adjusted R2 0.07Ramsey RESET Test F(3,520) =0.53

    PROB>F = 0.66*** = significant at 1% level; ** = significant at 5% level; * = significant at 10% level

    effective. This conclusion will be dissected further in other models to see if it can be

    determined what type of international organizations are the most effective to include in

    sanction situations.

    The other two predictors that were significant in Model 1 were U.S. involvement

    and whether the sanction was resolved in the threat stage. Other factors were not found

    to be statistically significant at any level. Both of these predictors were positively related

    to sanction outcomes. Given the size of its economy and its political power, this result

    reflects the common perception that the U.S. is more likely than other nations to be

    successful at implementing unilateral sanctions. The results also show that situations in

    which sanctions are resolved in the threat stage are more likely to be effective than those

    events in which sanctions need to be implemented. This bolsters two points in the

    previous literature: (1) sanction events than are resolved in the threat stage are more

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    28/42

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    29/42

    25

    likely to be effective than those multilateral sanctions that do not have international

    organization involvement.

    Both international organization variables are significant in this model and

    correspond positively with the success of sanction regimes. Here again, the inclusion of a

    regional or global institution increases the chances of the sanction regimes success. The

    results also provide further basis for the claim that sanction events ending in the threat

    stage are more likely to be effective than those involving the implementation of

    sanctions. Indeed, all of the models in this paper bolster this theory.

    Hypothesis 3: Sanctions with the backing of a regional IO are more effective than

    those with the support of a global IO.

    MODEL 3: REGIONAL VS. GLOBAL IOS: OLS REGRESSION

    (DEPENDENT VARIABLE: OUTCOME)SANCTION REGIME SET: Global IO, Unilateral, Region IO, Multilateral

    Coefficients (Standard Error) Coefficients (Standard Error)Target Cost -.004 (.003) -.004 (.003)Sender Cost

    -.002 (.003) -.002 (.003)Issue .179 (.204) .150 (.215)Unilateral -.111 (.163) -.048 (.222)Region IO .488 (.182)*** .551 (236)**Multi -.142 (.316) -.084 (.346)Threat .752 (.260)*** .757 (.260)UN NA .126 (.302)

    Number of

    Observations532 532

    F (Prob >F) 5.57 (0.0000) 4.89Adjusted R2 0.06 0.06

    Ramsey RESET Test F(3,521) =0.44PROB>F = 0.72

    F(3, 520) = 0.57PROB>F = 0.63

    *** = significant at 1% level; ** = significant at 5% level; * = significant at 10% level

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    30/42

    26

    The results for Model 3 depict that hypothesis 3 was supported. That is, it is more

    likely for a sanction episode involving a regional international organization to be

    effective that one involving a global international organization. This relationship remains

    the same even when the UN is pulled out from the general global IO grouping. The

    results appear to be marking a line, albeit not a very clear one, where the chaos of

    multiple players begins to outweigh the economic and political benefits of multiple

    senders. Regional organizations tend to form around a similar ideal or a joint concern,

    meaning there is greater consensus from the beginning an easier environment in which

    to deliberate and determine a course of action in a sanction event. Global organizations

    are formed to instill a sense of order, which makes for a more difficult starting ground

    upon which to build consensus.

    Hypothesis 4: Sanctions with the support of a UN agency are more effective than

    sanctions with the support of another IO.

    MODEL 4: UN EFFECTIVENESS REGRESSION (DEPENDENT VARIABLE: OUTCOME)SANCTION REGIME SET: Other IO, UN, Unilateral, Multilateral

    Coefficients (Standard Error)Target Cost -.003 (.003)Sender Cost -.002 (.003)Issue .161 (.216)UN -.324 (.164)Unilateral -.497 (.112)***Multilateral -.495 (.299)*Threat .738 (.261)***

    Number of Observations 532F (Prob >F) 4.77 (0.0000)Adjusted R2 0.04Ramsey RESET Test F(3,521) =0.77

    PROB>F = 0.51`*** = significant at 1% level; ** = significant at 5% level; * = significant at 10% level

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    31/42

    27

    Model 4 does not show support for the hypothesis that UN agencies are more

    effective than other agencies at sanctions. The results show that UN involvement does

    not necessarily lead to a sanctions episode success. The results show a negative

    correlation between unilateral and multilateral involvement and successful sanctions

    outcomes. This implies that IO support boosts effectiveness, further supporting the

    findings of Model 1. The results also provide further evidence for the effectiveness of

    threats.

    Hypothesis 5: Economic international organizations implement more effective

    sanctions and sanction threats than political international organizations

    Model 5 provides the test results for whether the involvement of economic IOs

    increases the likelihood of effectiveness of sanction regimes as compared to political IOs.

    MODEL 5: POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC INTERNATIONAL ORGANIZATION OLS REGRESSION

    (DEPENDENT VARIABLE: OUTCOME)SANCTION REGIME SET: Political IO, Unilateral, Economic IO, Multilateral

    Coefficients (Standard Error)Target Cost -.003 (.003)Sender Cost -.003 (.003)Issue .055 (.198)Unilateral -.380 (.120)***Economic Organizations .223 (.191)Multilateral -.372 (.303)Threat .764 (.261)***

    Number of Observations 532F (Prob >F) 4.68 (0.0000)Adjusted R

    20.05

    Ramsey RESET Test F(3,521) =1.17PROB>F = 0.32

    `*** = significant at 1% level; ** = significant at 5% level; * = significant at 10% level

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    32/42

    28

    This hypothesis is not supported. However, the results continue to illustrate the likely

    ineffectiveness of unilateral sanction regimes as compared to regimes with the

    involvement of a political international institution and the effectiveness of threats.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    33/42

    29

    POLICY IMPLICATIONS

    State governments have options when it comes to threatening or imposing

    sanctions. It is in the interest of each sender to maximize the sanctions likelihood of

    success while minimizing its economic and political risk. Like many things in politics,

    sanction regimes are about striking the right balance.

    Given that there is risk associated with threatening or implementing a sanction

    regime, potential senders should use caution when deciding their course of action.

    Preliminary evidence from cross-tabs reveals that states should collaborate and involve

    international organizations in their proposed sanction regimes. In particular, cross-tabs

    indicate that regional IO involvement in sanction regimes decreases the likelihood of

    failure most significantly, while maintaining a high success rate. The regression results

    support these findings, inclusion of an international organization in a sanction regime

    increases that regimes likelihood for effectiveness.

    These results provide a strong case that it is in the self-interest of the potential

    sender state to seek the consensus of a regional body and seek to jointly threaten or

    impose sanctions. The governments of potential senders would then be able to not only

    lessen their political and economic risk, but limit the amount of sanction management

    that would need to be done by the states bureaucrats. This could lead in a shift in the

    prevailing policies in sanctions.

    There are mitigating factors to this shift. The time that it takes to build consensus

    varies by international organization and, in some instances, this time lag may prevent the

    potential sender state from seeking consensus. By attempting to quantify which types of

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    34/42

    30

    international organizations are most effective at threatening and imposing sanctions,

    potential senders can better determine which organizations to engage in various

    circumstances.

    The results form Model 3 may illustrate the trade off between effectiveness and

    timeliness. These results show that regional organizations are more likely to be effective

    sanctioners than global organizations. Members of regional organizations as

    organizations formed around a specific collective interest tend to have more common

    interests than members of global organizations, making their decisions more prompt and,

    as the data show, effective. However, the results for the hypotheses about the

    effectiveness of political and economic organizations and the UN did not provide

    additional support for determining certain types of international organization sanctioners.

    The RAND Cooperation recently published a report on the success of UN and

    U.S. peacekeeping missions since World War II showing that the UN had a comparative

    advantage over the U.S. in peacekeeping (Dobbins et al, 2005 and 2003). The

    comparison is particularly relevant since international peacekeeping missions face similar

    time lag problems in consensus-building as sanctions do. In the past decade, there has

    been a remarkable increase in the number of UN peacekeeping missions deployed

    (Dobbins et al, 2005). A similar shift should happen in the realm of sanctions, since

    international organizations are shown to have a comparative advantage in threatening and

    imposing sanctions.

    Determining that international organizations, particularly regional organizations,

    have a comparative advantage over unilateral orad hoc multilateral efforts provides new

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    35/42

    31

    relevance to the international governance regime. Qualitative and quantitative

    assessments illustrating the successes of international organizations should give

    opponents of international organizations pause and cause them to rethink the overarching

    negativity they associate with these institutions.

    Continuing to decipher where international organizations work better than

    individual states will begin to mitigate the tension between the international governance

    regime and states about sovereignty. Once international organizations are seen as

    partners and not as rivals to states, consensus may be easier to achieve. Moreover, the

    comparative advantages of using international organizations as part of a states foreign

    policy toolkit may also increase. Most importantly, however, determining where

    international organizations are most useful to states will only help in securing their future

    and preventing their demise.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    36/42

    32

    CONCLUSION

    The presented analysis is not intended to answer the question whether sanctions

    are a good policy decision. The analysis starts from the point that sanctions continue to

    be a primary element of foreign policy and, as such, the most effective way to implement

    sanctions should be determined. The data provide strong support for seeking

    international institution support for sanction regimes as opposed to pushing sanctions

    unilaterally or with an ad hoc group. There is also support for using regional institutions

    instead of global institutions to strengthen sanction effectiveness, when such a policy is

    politically feasible. The strong coalitions that make up international organizations

    provide steady administrative and political support for sanctions.

    Sanctions remain an imperfect foreign policy instrument. However, by seeking

    the participation of international organizations, and especially regional organizations,

    these imperfections can be softened and the likelihood for success increased.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    37/42

    33

    APPENDIX I

    ORDERED PROBIT REGRESSION RESULTS (DEPENDENT VARIABLE: OUTCOME)

    Unsuccessful Stalemate PartiallySuccessful

    Successful Sign of ProbitCoefficient

    Targetcost -.185

    (.034)

    -.023

    (.006)

    .091

    (.020)

    .117

    (.022)-

    Sendercost .168

    (.053)

    .021

    (.008)

    -.082

    (.028)

    -.106

    (.034)-

    Issue -.033

    (.076)

    -.005

    (.012)

    .015

    (.033)

    .022

    (.055)+

    USA -.080

    (.043)

    -.010

    (.006)

    .038

    (.021)

    .052

    (.029)+

    UN .296

    (.152)

    -.001

    (.018)

    -.180

    (.101)

    -.115

    (.036)-

    GlobalIO -.246(.061)

    -.065(.028)

    .028(.043)

    .283(.125)

    +**

    RegionIO -.210(.393)

    -.041(.012)

    .068(.014)

    .184(.047)

    +**

    Multi .014

    (.106)

    .001

    (.011)

    -.007

    (.054)

    -.008

    (.063)+

    Threat .042

    (.038)

    .005

    (.005)

    -.020

    (.019)

    -.026

    (.024)-**

    SenderComm -.0003

    (.0004)

    -.00004

    (.00006)

    .0001

    (.0002)

    .0003

    (.0003)+

    Reported values are the dy/dx values provided by the ordered probit regression

    * = significant at the 10% level; ** = significant at 1% level

    LINKTEST RESULTS

    COEFFICIENT SE Z P >|Z|

    _hat 1.10 .313 3.53 0.000

    _hatsq -.142 .374 -0.38 0.704

    The link test shows that the ordered probit model is correctly specified.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    38/42

    34

    OLS REGRESSION (DEPENDENT VARIABLE: OUTCOME)

    Coefficients (SE)Targetcost -.004 (.003)Sendercost -.003 (.003)

    Issue .197 (.214)USA .237 (.117)**UN -.553 (.375)GlobalIO .858 (.324)***RegionIO .750 (.142)***Multi -.001 (.290)Threat -.917 (.306)***SenderComm .001 (.001)

    Number of Observations 532F (Prob >F) 5.11 (0.0000)Adjusted R2 0.07

    ` *** = significant at 1% level; ** = significant at 5% level

    The OLS results are comparable to the ordered probit results, which led to the use of the

    OLS results in analyzing the hypotheses in the paper.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    39/42

    35

    CHART 8: SCATTERPLOT OF DEPENDENT VARIABLE (OUTCOME) RESIDUALS

    -2

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    Residuals

    2 2.5 3 3.5Fitted values

    The scatter plot shows that within the four outcome possibilities (see page 11), the resultswithin each category are distributed randomly.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    40/42

    38

    36

    SIMPLECORRELATIONS

    outcome

    multi

    glob

    alIO

    regionIO

    UN

    USA

    issue

    threat

    outcom

    e

    1.00000

    0.04023

    0.2311

    0.15

    055

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    41/42

    37

    REFERENCES

    Barber, James (1979). Economic Sanctions as a Policy Instrument. International Affairs,

    55(3), 367-384.

    The Carter Center. (1996) Notes from the Meeting on the Viability of InternationalEconomic Sanctions. Retrieved on November 29, 2006, from

    http://www.cartercenter.org/documents/1218.pdf.

    Dashti-Gibson, Jaleh, Davis, Patricia, & Radcliff, Benjamin. (1997). On theDeterminants of the Success of Economic Sanctions: An Empirical Analysis.

    American Journal of Political Science, 41(2), 608-618.

    Dobbins, James et al. (2003). Americas Role in Nation-Building: From Germany toIraq. RAND Corporation.

    Dobbins, James et al. (2005). The UNs Role in Nation-Building: From the Congo to

    Iraq. RAND Corporation.

    Drezner, Daniel W. (2000). Bargaining, Enforcement, and Multilateral Sanctions: WhenIs Cooperation Counterproductive? International Organization, 54(1), 73-102.

    Drury, A. Cooper. (1998). Revisiting Economic Sanctions Reconsidered. Journal of

    Peace Research, 35(4), 497-509.

    Eaton, Jonathan & Engers, Maxim. (1999). Sanctions: Some Simple Analytics. The

    American Economic Review, 89(2), 409-414.

    Fearon, James D. (1998). Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation.

    International Organization, 52(2), 269-305.

    Helms, Jesse. (1996). Saving the U.N.: A Challenge to the Next Secretary-General.Foreign Affairs, September/October 1996, 2-6.

    Keohane, Robert. (1998). International Institutions: Can Interdependence Work?

    Foreign Policy, 110, 82-97.

    Mansfield, Edward D. (1995). International Institutions and Economic Sanctions. WorldPolitics, 47(4), 575-605.

  • 8/6/2019 Go It Alone the Effect of International Institutions on Economic Sanction Regimes

    42/42

    3838

    Martin, Lisa L. (1993). Credibility, Costs, and Institutions: Cooperation on EconomicSanctions. World Politics, 45(3), 406-432.

    McLean, Elena V. & Whang, Taehee. (2006). International Cooperation and the Success

    of Economic Sanctions. Retrieved on November 27, 2006 fromhttp://troi.cc.rochester.edu/~twng/TaeheeWhang-Writing3.pdf.

    Morgan, T. Clifton & Bapat, Navin. (2003). Imposing Sanctions: States, Firms, and

    Economic Coercion. International Studies Review, 5(4), 65-79.

    Morgan, T. Clifton, Bapat, Navin, Krustev, Valentin, & Vonnahme, Greg (2004). WhenEnough Is Enough: Ending Economic Sanctions. Retrieved on October 10, 2006,

    from http://www.allacademic.com/meta/p74274_index.html.

    Morgan, T. Clifton, Krustev, Valentin, Bapat, Navin (2006). Threat and Imposition of

    Sanctions (TIES) Data Users Manual Case Level Data. Retrieved on October 10,2006, from http://www.personal.psu.edu/nab12/TIESUSERSMANUAL.pdf.

    Rowat, Colin. (2006). Written Evidence: the Impact of Economic Sanctions. Submissionto the UK Parliament. Retrieved on December 1, 2006 from

    www.parliament.uk/documents/upload/EA296%20CRowat.pdf.

    Thompson, Alexander. (2006). Coercion Through IOs: THe Security Council and theLogic of Information Transmission. International Organization, 60, 1-34.

    Whang, Taehee. (2006). Unifying Theory and Testing of Economic Sanctions Outcomes.

    Retrieved on December 1, 2006 from troi.cc.rochester.edu/~twng/TaeheeWhang-Writing2.pdf.