Fiscal Policy and Endoge

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    1/32

    # Oxford University Press 2007 Oxford Economic Papers 60 (2008), 5787 57All rights reserved doi:10.1093/oep/gpm018

    Fiscal policy and endogenous growth with

    public infrastructure

    By Pierre-Richard Agenor

    School of Social Sciences, University of Manchester, Manchester, M13 9PL;

    and Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research;

    e-mail: [email protected]

    Optimal tax and spending allocation rules are derived in an endogenous growth modelwhere raw labor must be educated to become productive and infrastructure services

    affect the schooling technology. Growth- and welfare-maximizing solutions are com-

    pared under nonseparable utility in consumption and government-provided services.

    Among other results, it is shown that the optimal share of spending on infrastructure

    depends not only on production elasticities but also on the quality of schooling and the

    degree to which infrastructure services affect the production of educated labor.

    Congestion costs in education raise the optimal share of spending on infrastructure.

    JEL classifications: O41, H54, I28.

    1. Introduction

    The impact of public investment on growth has been the subject of much attention

    in recent academic research and policy debates. As documented by Zagler and

    Durnecker (2003), much academic research (both empirical and analytical) has

    focused, in particular, on the effects of public infrastructure. At the empirical

    level, Easterly and Rebelo (1993) found in an early contribution a positive associa-tion across countries between public investment in infrastructure (namely,

    transportation and communications) and growth. In a re-run of the Easterly-

    Rebelo regressions, Miller and Tsoukis (2001) confirmed this effect.1 Bose et al.

    (2003), using panel data for 30 developing countries and an econometric method-

    ology that explicitly accounts for the government budget constraint and possible

    biases arising from omitted variables, found that the share of government capital

    expenditure in GDP is positively and significantly related to income growth

    per capita, whereas the share of current expenditure is not. Calderon and Serven

    (2004), using also a large sample of countries and panel data covering the period

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    2/32

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    3/32

    economy is endowed only with raw labor, which must be educated to become

    productive. Knowledge is thus embodied in (educated) workers. Unlike Uzawa-

    Lucas type models, where human capital is disembodied and can expand without

    bounds, in the present framework knowledge is defined as a fixed set of skills and it

    is the number of (educated) workers that can grow without bounds (as long as the

    growth rate of the raw labor force is, of course, positive). Moreover, and unlike the

    case considered in Agenor (2005a), in the present setting government-provided

    services have an impact on household utility, and infrastructure has a positive

    effect on the rate of accumulation of educated labor.

    The latter assumption captures the view that infrastructure services (better roads,

    reliable access to electricity, etc.) may enhance the ability of individuals to study

    and acquire skills. This is a particularly important consideration for low-income

    developing countries. In many of these countries, the lack of an adequate networkof roads makes access to schools (particularly in rural areas) difficult; dropout rates

    tend to be higher when children must walk long distances to get to school (see Levy,

    2004). The lack of access to electricity hampers the ability to study, both in the

    classroom and at home. In some countries, the lack of adequate toilet facilities for

    girls in rural area schools has led many parents to deny an education to their

    daughters.4 As it turns out, accounting for the impact of infrastructure on the

    schooling technology has important implications for the determination of the

    optimal allocation of government expenditure.

    Another issue that I address in the paper is the existence of congestion costs ineducation, which have proved to be a particularly important factor in assessing the

    quality of schooling in low-income countries. According to recent data from

    UNESCO and the World Bank, student-teacher ratios in these countries dramati-

    cally exceed average ratios observed in industrial countries. For instance, at 44 to 1,

    the pupil-teacher ratio in Sub-Saharan Africa is on average three times higher than

    that of developed countries; moreover, one in four countries in the region has

    ratios above 55 to 1 (see UNESCO, 2005). Much research in the endogenous

    growth literature has examined the issue of congestion costs in infrastructure, aswell as their implications for private capital formation and the optimal allocation of

    public expenditure (see, for instance, Turnovsky, 1997; Fisher and Turnovsky, 1998;

    and Eicher and Turnovsky, 2000). But almost none has focused on congestion costs

    in education and their implications for human capital accumulation, the optimal

    composition of spending, and growth.5

    The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the basic

    framework, which assumes that utility is separable in consumption and

    ..........................................................................................................................................................................

    4 See Agenor and Moreno-Dodson (2007) for a detailed discussion of the impact of infrastructure on

    education outcomes, as well as a review of the evidence.

    p.-r. agnor 59

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    4/32

    government-provided services. Section 3 solves for the steady-state growth rate in

    the decentralized equilibrium, and examines its dynamic properties. Section 4

    illustrates the functioning of the model by considering a revenue-neutral change

    in the composition of public spending, namely a switch from spending on educa-

    tion to infrastructure services. Section 5 derives the growth-maximizing fiscalstructure. Section 6 considers the case where utility is nonseparable in consumption

    and government services, and compares the growth- and welfare-maximizing

    solutions. Section 7 introduces congestion costs in education in the model, and

    examines the effect of these costs on the optimal allocation of government expen-

    diture. The final section summarizes the main results of the paper and offers some

    concluding remarks.

    2. The basic frameworkConsider an economy populated by a single, infinitely-lived household. It produces

    a single traded good, whose price is fixed on world markets. The good can be used

    for either consumption or investment. The economys endowment consists of raw

    labor, which must be educated (through a publicly-funded schooling system) to be

    used in market production. The government provides infrastructure, education,

    and utility-enhancing services, at no charge. It levies a flat tax on marketed output

    to finance its expenditure.

    2.1 Market activity

    Aggregate marketed output, Y, is produced with private physical capital, public

    infrastructure services, educated labor, using a Cobb-Douglas technology:6

    Y G I EK

    1P AP

    GI

    KP

    E

    KP

    KP, 1

    whereKPis the stock of private capital,GIgovernment infrastructure services,Ethestock of educated labor, 2 0, 1 the proportion of the educated labor force

    employed in goods production, AP 40, and , 2 0, 1. Thus, production

    exhibits constant returns to scale in all factors. As long as GI=KP and E=KP are

    constant (which turns out to be the case in the steady state), output will exhibit

    linearity in the stock of private capital. The production function is then essentially

    an AK-type technology.7

    ..........................................................................................................................................................................

    6 Throughout the paper, the time subscript tis omitted. A dot over a variable is used to denote its time

    derivative.

    60 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    5/32

    2.2 Household preferences

    The household-producer maximizes the discounted stream of future utility

    V 1

    0

    C1

    1 ln GH

    exptdt, 15 1, 2

    where C is aggregate consumption, GH utility-enhancing government services,

    4 0 the discount rate, 1= the intertemporal elasticity of substitution

    (with 1 corresponding to the logarithmic utility function), and 4 0 a coeffi-

    cient that measures the impact of GH on the households instantaneous utility.

    Thus, as for instance in Turnovsky (1996, 2000, 2004), Chang (1999), and Baier

    and Glomm (2001), publicly-provided services affect the households utility

    directly. However, unlike these authors, and in line with Cassou and Lansing(2003) and Piras (2005), private consumption and public services are assumed to

    be additively separable in this initial specification. This is in line with the empirical

    evidence provided by Karras (1994), McGrattan et al. (1997), Chiu (2001), and

    Okubo (2003), among others.

    Output is taxed at the rate 2 0, 1. The household spends on consumption

    and accumulates capital. It receives teachers pay from the government,

    1 wGE, where wG is the real wage and 1 the proportion of teachers

    in the educated labor force. As noted earlier, education is provided free of

    charge and there are no user fees for infrastructure services used in private produc-

    tion. Thus, the household benefits from an implicit rent associated with public

    spending.

    Abstracting from capital depreciation, the households resource constraint is

    C _KP 1 Y 1 wGE: 3

    2.3 Education technology

    Raw labor, which grows at a constant rate, must be educated before it can be

    used in market production. In turn, the production of educated labor

    requires the combination of teachers, students, and government infrastructure

    services:

    _E Q1 EGIL1

    , 4

    where _E is the flow of newly-educated workers, L the number of students, Q a

    variable that measures the quality of schooling, and 2 0 1 Thus, the educa-

    p.-r. agnor 61

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    6/32

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    7/32

    Using (7), eq. (6) can be rewritten as

    _E

    E AE

    GE

    E

    GI

    E

    , 8

    where AE a11 1. Thus, the growth rate of the stock of educated

    labor depends on public spending on both education and infrastructure services per

    teacher (or educated worker). Note that, in light of (7), it does not matter whether

    the quality of schooling is defined as a function of the ratio of government spending

    per teacher (as in (5)) or per student. In addition, to ensure that the number of

    teachers has a positive effect on the flow supply of educated labor, I assume that

    51.10 Note also that a form similar to (8) can be obtained despite

    Dropping (5) if spending on education is assumed to affect directly the production

    of educated labor (rather than through quality), that is, if for instance (5) takes theform _E Ga1E 1 E

    a2 Ga3I L

    1ai , where ai 2 0, 1. Using (7), it can then be

    shown that _E=E would again be given by (8), with a1 and a3 . In that

    case, no additional restrictions on a1and a2 are necessary.

    2.4 Government

    The government provides infrastructure, education, and utility-enhancing services

    to the household, pays salaries to teachers, and collects a proportional tax on

    marketed output. It cannot issue debt and must maintain a balanced budget con-

    tinuously.11

    Thus, the governments flow budget constraint is given byXhI, E, H

    Gh 1 wGE Y: 9

    Expenditure on all categories of services are taken to be determined as fractions

    of tax revenue, so that Gh hY, with h 2 0, 1, and h I, E, H. Teachers

    salaries are also fixed as a fraction of tax revenue. The government budget

    constraint therefore implies that

    XhI, E, H

    h

    1,10

    which determines residually one of the spending shares.12

    ..........................................................................................................................................................................10 Common empirical estimates of are in the range 0.10.2. Estimates of are more difficult to come

    by; in the numerical exercises performed in Agenor (2005b), values of 0.1 and 0.2 are used. In either

    case, however, the condition 51 appears not to be very restrictive.11 See Turnovsky (1996, 1997) for the case of debt financing in a similar context. Because Ricardian

    equivalence holds in the present framework, excluding borrowing is simply a matter of convenience.

    With government borrowing, agents would foresee that higher taxation is required later in order to

    repay the accumulated debt, and this would need to be accounted for.12 To avoid a corner solution (in which 1), I assume implicitly that educated workers seek employ-

    p.-r. agnor 63

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    8/32

    From (3) and (9), the market-clearing condition for the goods market is

    Y C _KP

    XhI, E, HGh: 11

    3. The decentralized equilibrium

    In the present setting, a decentralized equilibrium can be defined as follows:

    Definition 1 A decentralized equilibrium is a set of infinite sequences for the

    quantities fC, KP, Eg1t0, such that fC, KPg

    1t0 maximize eq. (2) subject to (3), and

    fKP, Eg1t0 satisfy eq. (8), (10), and (11), for given values of the tax rate, , the ratio

    of government wages to output, , and the spending shares on public services, h,with h I, E, H.

    This equilibrium can be characterized as follows. The household-producer

    maximizes (2) subject to (3), taking the tax rate, , government-provided services

    and wage payments as given. The current-value Hamiltonian for this problem can

    be written as

    C1

    1 ln G

    H 1 Y 1 w

    GE C,

    whereis the costate variable associated with constraint (3). Using (1), first-order

    optimality conditions for this problem can be written as, setting s 1

    1 , so that s 2 0, 1:

    d

    dC 0 ) C , 12

    _= d

    dKP sAP

    GI

    KP

    E

    KP

    , 13

    together with the budget constraint (3), the initial condition KP0 K0P, and the

    transversality condition

    limt!1

    KPexpt 0: 14

    Equation (12) equates the marginal utility of consumption to the shadow value

    of private capital, Equation (13) is the standard Keynes-Ramsey consumption

    64 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    9/32

    Combining eqs (12) and (13) yields

    _C

    C sAP

    GI

    KP

    E

    KP

    " #, 15

    whereas substituting (1) in (3) yields

    _KP 1 APGI

    KP

    E

    KP

    KP 1 wGE C: 16

    As shown in Appendix 1, eqs (8), (10), (15), and (16) can be further manipulated

    to lead to a system of two nonlinear differential equations (see eqs (A7) and (A8))

    inc C=KPande E=KP. These two equations, together with the initial condition

    e0 E0=K0P40, and the transversality condition (13), rewritten as

    limt!1

    c1 expt 0, 17

    determine the dynamics of the decentralized economy. The balanced-growth path

    (BGP) can therefore be defined as follows:

    Definition 2 The BGP is a set of sequences fc, eg1t0, spending shares and tax rate

    satisfying Definition 1, such that for an initial condition e0eqs (8), (15), and (16)and the transversality condition (17) are satisfied, and consumption, the stock of

    educated labor, as well as the stock of private capital, all grow at the same constant

    rate _C=C _E=E _KP=KP.

    The transversality condition (17) is always satisfied along any interior BGP

    because consumption and the stock of private capital grow at the same constant

    rate, implying that the ratio c C=KP is also constant.13 Given the form of the

    utility function used here, a necessary condition to get bounded utility (that is, for

    the integral in (2) to converge) is 41 . This condition imposes no restric-

    tion when41, that is,5 1. When5 1, it imposes an upper bound on admis-

    sible values for the rate of growth. Equivalently, it requires the rate of time

    preference to be sufficiently large.

    From eqs (A4) and (A6) in Appendix 1, is given by the equivalent forms14

    sAPI=1

    ~e=1 , 18

    AE

    =1I

    =1~e!, 19

    ..........................................................................................................................................................................13 _ _ _ _ _

    p.-r. agnor 65

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    10/32

    where ~e denotes the steady-state value ofe, A a constant term, and

    ! 1

    1 50:

    As shown in Appendix 1, the following proposition can be established:

    Proposition 1 Along an equilibrium path with a strictly positive growth rate, the

    BGP is unique. There is only one stable path converging to this equilibrium.

    This proposition implies therefore that the model is locally determinate.

    Its dynamics can be analyzed using phase diagrams, as illustrated in Fig. 1.

    The _e 0 curve (denoted EE in the figure) always has a positive slope in c-e

    space, whereas the slope of the _

    c

    0 curve (denoted CC) can be either upward-or downward-sloping, depending on the size of the elasticity of intertemporal

    substitution, . The upper (lower) panel corresponds to the case where is rela-

    tively high (low), in a sense made precise in Appendix 1. The saddlepath, denoted

    SS, may therefore have either a positive or a negative slope. Following a jump in c

    (as a result, for instance, of a change in the tax rate or one of the spending shares

    parameters),candemay or may not move in the same direction. The reason is that

    the transitional dynamics are driven by the ratio of educated labor to private

    capital, and as this ratio increases (falls), the marginal productivity of private

    capital increases (falls) as well. In turn, this tends to raise (reduce) consumptionand investment over time.

    4. Revenue-neutral spending shift

    The steady-state effects and transitional dynamics associated with revenue-neutral

    changes in spending shares are straightforward to analyse in the present setting.

    In particular, Appendix 1 establishes that an increase in I, offset by a reduction

    in E(that is, with dI dE 0, holding and constant), has an ambiguous

    effect on the steady-state growth rate. This result is summarized in the followingproposition:

    Proposition 2 With the tax rate and the share of government spending on wages

    held constant, a switch in the composition of public expenditure from education

    to infrastructure services has an ambiguous effect on the steady-state growth rate.

    If infrastructure services do not affect the education technology ( 0), the net

    effect depends only on =. With 4 0, the net effect depends also on =.

    To understand the intuition behind these results, consider first the case where

    0. Increasing the fraction of government spending on infrastructure (for a

    given stock of educated labor) increases the marginal product of physical capital,

    66 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    11/32

    Thus, the positive effect of the increase in the share of spending on infrastructure is

    accompanied by a lower supply of educated workers, which tends to lower private

    production and reduce the growth rate. The net effect on output and the growth

    rate depends on how productive the two inputs are in relative terms, that is, on

    the ratio =. As shown in Appendix 1, if= exceeds the elasticity of the steady-

    state value of the educated labor-capital ratio with respect to the share of spending

    in infrastructure, the growth effect (as well as the effect on the consumption-capital

    S

    c

    S

    e

    E

    E

    C

    C

    A

    c~

    e~

    0

    S

    c

    S

    e

    E

    E

    C

    C

    A

    c~

    e~0

    Fig. 1. The balanced growth equilibrium.

    p.-r. agnor 67

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    12/32

    types of services are in the production of goods, but also to how productive they are

    in the production of educated labor, as measured by the ratio =. Even if infra-

    structure services have a small impact on the production of goods, a high value of

    = may still lead to an increase in ~e, ~c, and . In the particular case where 0,

    that is, if education services do not affect the acquisition of skills, the impact on thesteady-state growth rate is unambiguously positive.

    Figure 2 illustrates two possible outcomes, under the assumptions that the

    elasticity of intertemporal substitution is relatively high and the ratio = is not

    too large. In both cases the educated labor-capital ratio falls in the steady state. But

    the consumption-capital ratio and the growth rate may either increase or fall,

    depending on the magnitude of =, as noted earlier. In both panels curve CC

    shifts to the left, but curve EEcan shift either to the right (upper panel) or the left

    (lower panel). In the upper (lower) panel,CCshifts by more (less) thanEEand the

    consumption-capital ratio falls (increases). The steady-state consumption-capital

    ratio falls in the first case and increases in the second.15 As noted earlier, during the

    transition, the fall in the educated labor-capital ratio lowers the marginal produc-

    tivity of capital, leading to a gradual reduction in the stock of physical capital.

    This reduction is large enough to ensure that the consumption-capital ratio

    increases over time.

    5. The growth-maximizing fiscal structure

    To determine the growth-maximizing fiscal structure in the decentralized equili-

    brium involves setting simultaneously the tax rates and expenditure shares so that

    @=@ @=@h 0, 8h. Given the structure of the model, this problem can be

    addressed in two stages, the first of which involves solving for the growth-

    maximizing tax rate, keeping spending shares constant. From (18) and (19), the

    following proposition can be readily established:

    Proposition 3 With all government spending shares held constant, the growth-

    maximizing value of the tax rate is .

    This result generalizes the rule , which was first established by Barro

    (1990) in a flow model, and subsequently in stock models by Futagami et al.

    (1993), Turnovsky (1997), and Baier and Glomm (2001). The Barro rule holds

    only in the particular case where educated labor (or, more generally, human

    capital) has no effect on production, that is, 0. Note also that the growth-

    maximizing tax rate depends only on parameters characterizing the goods

    production technology; it is independent not only of how the revenue is spent

    (that is, the spending shares h and ), but also of the parameters characterizing

    the education technology. As discussed later, this is not generally the case with thewelfare-maximizing solution.

    68 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    13/32

    The second stage involves allocating public expenditure between infrastructure,

    education and utility-enhancing services, with the tax rate and the share of govern-

    ment spending on wages both taken as given. The following proposition can be

    shown to hold:

    Proposition 4 With the tax rate and the share of government spending on wagesheld constant, the growth-maximizing composition of public expenditure is

    S

    c

    S

    e

    E

    E

    C

    C

    Ac~

    e~

    0

    S

    c

    S

    e

    E

    EC

    C

    A

    c~

    e~

    0

    A

    B

    A

    B

    Fig. 2. Shift in the Composition of Government Spending from

    Education to Infrastructure

    p.-r. agnor 69

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    14/32

    That the optimal value ofH is zero is of course a direct implication of assuming

    separability between utility-enhancing government services and private

    consumption. As a consequence, spending on this type of services has no effect

    on growth. To provide a more explicit interpretation of the second result in

    Proposition 4, it is convenient to consider the particular case where 0. Giventhe budget constraint (10), Proposition 4 implies therefore that

    I

    51, 21

    with E 1 I from (10).

    Equation (20) implies that if the production function for educated labor does

    not depend on infrastructure services, that is, with 0, the optimal allocation

    of spending between infrastructure and education would depend only on the

    parameters characterizing the goods production technology not on the education

    technology, as I have shown elsewhere (see Agenor, 2005a). Specifically, from (21)

    the growth-maximizing shares would be I = and E = .

    Combined with Proposition 3, the optimal tax structure implies therefore that

    the shares of spending in output would be I and

    E .

    16 With

    4 0, however, the education technology does matter for the allocation of govern-

    ment spending; the optimal share of spending on infrastructure (education) is

    higher (lower) than otherwise. As can be inferred from (21), the more productiveinfrastructure services are in fostering the acquisition of skills (the higher is), or

    the lower the quality of education (the lower is), the higher should be the optimal

    share of spending on infrastructure services. Note also that an improvement in the

    quality of education has no effect on the optimal allocation of public expenditure if

    infrastructure services do not affect the production of educated labor (that is,

    @I=@ 0 if 0). And in the limit case where ! 0 (so that public spending

    on education has no effect on the schooling technology), I! 1, as could be

    expected.

    Given that the growth-maximizing tax rate is independent of spending shares,and conversely that the growth-maximizing shares are independent of the tax rate,

    the results in Propositions 3 and 4 describe completely the optimal fiscal structure

    in a decentralized economy. The issue to which I turn next is how robust these

    results are if utility is nonseparable in consumption and government-provided

    services.

    6. Nonseparable utility and welfare maximizing rules

    In the foregoing discussion, the utility function of the household was assumed to beadditively separable between private consumption and public services, as suggested

    70 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    15/32

    by some of the empirical evidence. This specification implies that with the tax rate

    and the share of government spending on wages held constant, a switch in the

    composition of public expenditure from utility-enhancing services to the provision

    of either infrastructure or education services is unambiguously growth-enhancing.

    This result is of course due to the fact that the share of spending on utility-enhancing services has no effect on the economys steady-state growth rate, neither

    directly nor indirectlythrough changes in the steady-state value of the ratio of

    educated labor to physical capital.

    However, while separability may be intuitively obvious for some categories of

    utility-enhancing public services (such as security or national defense), this is not

    quite the case for others, such as health or environment services. Better health care,

    for instance, may have a direct impact on the ability of individuals to consume and

    enjoy their free time.17 Greater access to public parks in busy cities may have the

    same effect.

    Accordingly, I now consider a more general utility function, which I take to be

    nonseparable in CandGH:

    maxC

    V

    10

    CGH

    1

    1 exptdt, 22

    where again 4 0 measures the contribution of government-provided services to

    utility and 1= is, as before, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. This

    specification is similar to the one used by Turnovsky (1996), among others.18

    Consider first the growth-maximizing policies. Following the results in Agenor

    (2005c), Agenor and Neanidis (2006), as well as in Appendix 2, the following

    proposition can be established:

    Proposition 5With nonseparable utility as given in (22), the growth-maximizing tax

    rate is the same as given in Proposition 1. If changes in the share of spending on

    infrastructure are offset by an adjustment in the share of spending on education,

    formula (21) remains valid, whereas if the offsetting change results from an adjust-

    ment in spending on utility-enhancing services, the growth-maximizing share of

    spending on infrastructure is equal to unity.

    The first result in this proposition is fairly intuitive; the allocation between

    productive components of public expenditure does not depend on whether

    nonproductive services affect utility if the policymakers objective is to maximize

    growth. The second result is also easy to understand, given that (as can be inferred

    from the results in Appendix 2), neither the share of spending on utility-enhancing

    ..........................................................................................................................................................................17

    p.-r. agnor 71

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    16/32

    services, H, nor the parameter , appear explicitly in the solution of the steady-

    state growth rate.

    Consider now the welfare-maximizing solution, which involves a planner choos-

    ing optimally all quantities and policy instruments so as to maximize (subject to

    appropriate constraints) the households discounted lifetime utility, as given

    in (22).19 Because the government budget constraint (10) must hold at all times,

    one of the spending shares must again be chosen residually. In what follows, I will

    assume thatEis determined through (10), in order to focus on potential trade-offs

    between spending on infrastructure and utility-enhancing services.

    By using eqs (A27), (A29), and (A30) in Appendix 2, and setting 0 for

    simplicity, the social planners problem is to maximize, with respect to

    C, I, H, , KP, and E,

    fCHAPI

    E

    KP 1=1g1

    1

    K 1 APIE

    KP 1=1 C

    n o EA

    EI

    1 2 E1!K!P ,

    where A AEA2P, 1 =1 , 2 =1 , 1 ,

    and Kand Edenote the costate variables associated with eqs (A29) and (A30),

    respectively.Optimality conditions are given by

    GH CG

    H

    K, 23

    CGH 1

    1

    K 1 Y

    1

    EA

    EI1

    2

    E

    1!

    K

    !

    P

    I

    1

    E ,

    24

    CGH

    1H

    EAE

    1I

    2 E1!K!P

    E

    ; 25

    CGH

    1KY 26

    EA

    E

    I1 2 E1!K!

    P

    ,

    72 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    17/32

    _K

    K

    1 1

    Y

    KP

    E

    K

    1 27

    AEI1 2 E1!K!P 1KP

    1K

    CGH

    1

    1 1

    KP,

    _E

    E

    1

    1 A

    EI

    1 2 E1!K!P1

    E28

    K

    E

    1

    Y

    E

    1

    E CG

    H

    11E

    ,

    together with the transversality conditions

    limt!1

    KKPexpt limt!1

    EEexpt 0: 29

    Rewriting (23), taking logs, and differentiating with respect to time yields

    _C

    C

    _K

    K

    _GH

    GH

    , 30

    where 1 1= and _GH=GH _Y=Y. Using (27) and (A22) in Appendix 2,

    eq (30) becomes

    _C

    C

    1 1

    Y

    KP

    E

    K

    1 31

    AEI

    1 2 E1!K!P1

    KP

    1

    K CG

    H

    1 1

    1

    KP

    1

    _E

    E

    1

    _KP

    KP

    :

    Appendix 2 shows how eqs (31), (A29), and (A30), can be further manipulated

    to produce a system of two nonlinear differential equations in c and e. These

    equations, together with the initial condition e040 and the transversality condi-

    tions (29), characterize the dynamics of the centrally-planned economy.

    The steady-state growth rate is given by eq (19) and its equivalent form

    1 1 f 1

    E

    H

    ~C~Y

    !" #32

    p.-r. agnor 73

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    18/32

    Appendix 2 discusses the uniqueness and stability of the BGP. The dynamics of

    the model are qualitatively similar to those derived for the decentralized equili-

    brium and can therefore be analyzed in a diagram similar to Fig. 1.

    More importantly for the purpose at hand, it can be established from (23)(26)

    that

    1 E

    H

    ~C

    ~Y

    ! 0;

    ~C

    ~Y

    ! 1

    " #

    ~C

    ~Y

    !

    " #

    I 1

    E

    0;

    1 EH

    I 1 E

    ~C~Y

    ! 0;

    where E 1 I H. These equations represent a system in ; I, and H.

    Along the BGP, because Cand Ygrow at the same rate, ~C= ~Y is constant and so

    are all fiscal policy instruments. In general, an explicit solution cannot be derived,

    given the high degree of nonlinearity of this system. However, direct inspection

    leads to the following proposition:

    Proposition 6Under non-separable utility as given in (22), and given that from (11)~C= ~Y 1 h = 1

    =~c , the welfare-maximizing values of the tax rate and

    the spending shares along the BGP are not independent of each other and depend

    in general on the sensitivity of household utility to government-provided services.

    In principle, the welfare-maximizing problem of the central planner could also

    be specified in terms of the instantaneous utility function shown in (2), that is, with

    separability between consumption and health services. However, the first-order

    optimality conditions (in the particular case where 1) also give a nonlinear

    system in ; 1 and H for a constant consumption-output ratio, and an explicitanalytical solution cannot be derived either. Exact results are therefore omitted to

    save space, given that their qualitative features are similar to those summarized in

    Proposition 6.

    7. Congestion costs

    As noted earlier, much of the endogenous growth literature on congestion costs

    has focused on two types of congestion costs: those affecting the use of

    infrastructure services (or capital) in the production of goods, and those affecting

    utility-enhancing services 20 In the context of the present paper, a more novel issue

    74 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    19/32

    taking the form of threshold effects. This section examines these issues, with a focus

    on the growth-maximizing solutions.

    Specifically, two alternative ways of modeling congestion costs in education are

    considered. The first approach consists of assuming that the productivity of infra-

    structure services falls with an increase in the flow number of students (or newly-educated individuals), _L:

    _E Q1 E GI_L

    L1, 33

    where 0 measures the degree of congestion (with 1 denoting proportional

    congestion). For instance, too many students using publicly-provided internet

    services may slow the speed of access for everybody, thereby diminishing theusefulness of these services for creating educated labor.

    Given that from (7), _E _L, it is straightforward to show that using equation (33)

    instead of (4) does not affect any of the previous results regarding the

    growth-maximizing fiscal structure (Propositions 3 and 4). The reason is clear

    eq. (33) boils down to a geometric transformation (with all coefficients

    multiplied by 1 1) of the original expression for educated labor flows.

    Although this changes the stability properties of the model and its transitional

    dynamics (and thus the speed of convergence to the BGP), it does not alter

    the optimal allocation rule because it is the ratio = that appears inProposition 4.21

    The second approach to account for congestion in the production of educated

    labor is to assume that quality is subject to threshold effects. In the foregoing

    analysis, it was assumed that the ratio of students to teachers,L=1 E(denoted

    byxbelow) is kept fixed at a by the government. However, whether a is high or

    low does have implications for the quality of schooling. Specifically, suppose that

    the quality of education, Q, has a parameter that can be high or low (Hor L,

    respectively), depending on whether the student-teacher ratio is lower or greater

    than a threshold value, aC:

    Q QH x

    H,

    QL xL

    ,

    if a aC

    if a4aC

    :

    ..........................................................................................................................................................................20 For examples of the former literature, see Turnovsky (1997), Fisher and Turnovsky (1998), and

    p.-r. agnor 75

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    20/32

    This specification implies that the model can generate multiple BGPs, a full

    characterization of which is beyond the scope of this paper. For the purpose at

    hand, it is sufficient to observe that, from Proposition 4 (or more specifically

    eq. (21)), the two regimes would be characterized by different growth-maximizing

    allocations between infrastructure and education services: in the L-regime, theoptimal share E would indeed be lower than in the H-regime. These results

    can be summarized in the following proposition:

    Proposition 7Congestion costs in education (in the form of threshold effects on the

    quality of schooling) raise the growth-maximizing share of public spending on

    infrastructure.

    Given that the growth-maximizing tax rate does not depend on the parameters

    characterizing the education technology, Proposition 3 is not affected by the intro-

    duction of threshold effects on the quality of schooling. But because the welfare-

    maximizing tax rate and spending shares depend on the steady-state ratio of

    consumption to output, they also depend indirectly on the parameters of the

    education technology. As a result, they would both be affected by a threshold

    effect on . However, establishing analytically the effect of a shift in on the

    optimal tax structure is more difficult in this case.

    8. Concluding remarksThe purpose of this paper was to study the determination of optimal taxation andallocation of public resources between utility-enhancing, infrastructure, and educa-

    tion services. The analysis was based on an endogenous growth model with two key

    features: raw labor must be educated to become productive and infrastructure

    services affect the schooling technology. Government spending is financed by a

    tax on output. The balanced growth path was derived, and the transitional

    dynamics associated with a revenue-neutral shift in the composition of public

    spending from education to infrastructure services were analyzed. It was shown

    that, in general, such as shift has an ambiguous effect on the growth rate and thesteady-state values of consumption- and the supply of educated labor (both mea-

    sured in proportion of the private capital stock).

    The third and fourth parts of the paper focused on the determination of the

    optimal tax rate and spending shares, under both separable and nonseparable

    household utility in consumption and government-provided services. In both

    cases, the growth-maximizing tax rate was found to be equal to the sum of the

    elasticities of output with respect to infrastructure services and educated labor,

    and thus to be independent of the schooling technology. With separable utility,

    the growth-maximizing composition of public spending was shown to be a zero

    share for utility-enhancing services, whereas the optimal allocation to infrastruc-

    76 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    21/32

    are not education-enhancing, the growth-maximizing allocation between infra-

    structure and education would depend solely on the parameters characterizing

    the goods production technology. With nonseparable utility, however, it was

    shown that the growth-maximizing solution coincides with the one obtained

    under separable utility only if changes in the share of spending on infrastructureare offset by an adjustment in the share of spending on education. If, on the

    contrary, these changes are offset by an adjustment in spending on utility-enhan-

    cing services, the growth-maximizing share of spending on infrastructure is equal

    to unityeven though spending on education is productive.

    The welfare-maximizing solutions under nonseparable utility were shown to be

    such that the optimal values of the tax rate and the spending shares are constant

    along the balance growth path, and dependent on each other. In addition, it was

    shown that they depend in general on the sensitivity of household utility to gov-

    ernment-provided services. Finally, the last section focused on congestion costs in

    education. It was shown that if these costs take the form of threshold externalities

    associated with the quality of schooling, the optimal share of spending on infra-

    structure (education) is positively (negatively) related to the degree of congestion in

    education.

    The analysis in this paper could be extended in several directions. One area of

    investigation would be to consider the case where it is the stock of public capital in

    infrastructure, rather than the flow of spending on infrastructure services, that

    affects the production technology for goods and educated labor. I have pursuedthis line of research in a companion paper (see Agenor, 2005b), and the results

    indicate that the optimal rules remain qualitatively similar to those derived in the

    present paper. However, transitional dynamics and welfare-maximizing solutions

    cannot be explicitly analysed in that context, and recourse to numerical techniques

    becomes necessary. A second direction would be to consider other forms of dis-

    tortionary taxation, such as a tax on consumption, wages, or capital income, as for

    instance in Turnovsky (1996, 2000). With an endogenous supply of (raw) labor,

    a tax on wages would affect private decisions to allocate time between labor and

    leisure. Similarly, a tax on the return to private capital would affect decisionsbetween consumption and investment. Both taxes are likely to have ambiguous

    effects on growth, because their adverse effect on private investment and labor

    supply would be at least in part offset by the increase in the stock of public capital

    induced by higher revenues. An interesting issue in this context is the extent to

    which collection costs (which can be particularly large for direct taxes in developing

    countries) affect the optimal tax structure.

    Finally, as noted in the introduction, an important difference between the pre-

    sent paper and others in the Uzawa-Lucas tradition is the assumption that knowl-

    edge is embodied in workers. Moreover, it was assumed that all workers (once

    educated) share the same amount of knowledge In practice, it is hard to distinguish

    p.-r. agnor 77

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    22/32

    rate, for instance, may have a significant effect on growth either because the

    number of educated workers acts as a constraint on the expansion of physical

    capital to begin with (as one would expect in low-income countries), or because

    greater literacy increases the economys ability to create knowledge (a more likely

    scenario in high-income countries). It is therefore difficultexcept perhaps byrefining standard growth accounting techniquesto determine whether it is the

    number of educated workers, or changes in the average level of education, that

    affects growth, based on these indicators. A worthwhile extension of the present

    analysis would be of course to combine these two assumptions and assume that

    although knowledge is embodied, the (average) level of skills per worker changes

    over time. Doing so would allow a distinction between two types of education

    expenditurethose aimed at running schools and those aimed directly at creating

    knowledge. But the degree of complexity that would then be added could compli-

    cate the analysis significantly and could require the use of numerical simulation

    methods.

    Acknowledgements

    I am grateful to Kyriakos Neanidis, Devrim Yilmaz, the Editor, and three anonymous

    referees for helpful discussions and comments on a previous version. I bear sole responsi-

    bility, however, for the views expressed here.

    References

    Agenor, P.-R. (2005a) Infrastructure, public education and growth with congestion costs,

    Working Paper No. 47, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research, University of

    Manchester.

    Agenor, P.-R. (2005b) Schooling and public capital in a model of endogenous growth,

    Working Paper No. 61, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research, University of

    Manchester.

    Agenor, P.-R.(2005c) Health and infrastructure in models of endogenous growth, WorkingPaper No. 62, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research, University of Manchester.

    Agenor, P.-R. and Moreno-Dodson, B. (2007) Public infrastructure and economic growth:

    new channels and policy implications, in M. Francese, D. Franco, and R. Giordano (eds)

    Public Expenditure, Banca dItalia, Rome, forthcoming.

    Agenor, P.-R. and Neanidis, K. (2006) The allocation of public expenditure and economic

    growth, Working Paper No. 69, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research, University

    of Manchester.

    Albala-Bertrand, J.M. and Mamatzakis, E.C. (2004) The impact of public

    infrastructure on the productivity of the chilean economy, Review of Development

    Economics, 8, 26678.

    Baier S L and Glomm G (2001) Long run growth and welfare effects of public policies

    78 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    23/32

    Bose, N., Haque, M.E., and Osborn, D.R. (2003) Public expenditure and economic growth:

    a disaggregated analysis for developing countries, unpublished, University of Manchester.

    Calderon, C. and Serven, L.(2004) The effects of infrastructure development on growth and

    income distribution, Policy Research Working Paper No. 3400, World Bank,

    Washington, DC.Cassou, S.P. and Lansing, K.J. (2003) Tax reform with useful public expenditure, unpub-

    lished, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

    Chang, W.-Y. (1999) Government spending, endogenous labor, and capital accumulation,

    Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23, 122542.

    Chiu, R.-L. (2001) The intratemporal substitution between government spending and

    private consumption: empirical evidence from taiwan, Asian Economic Journal, 15, 31324.

    Corsetti, G. and Roubini, N. (1996) Optimal government spending and taxation in endo-

    genous growth models, Working Paper No. 5851, National Bureau of Economic Research,

    Cambridge, MA.

    Dasgupta, D.(1999) Growth versus welfare in a model of nonrival infrastructure,Journal of

    Development Economics, 58, 35985.

    Easterly, W. and Rebelo, S. (1993) Fiscal policy and economic growth, Journal of Monetary

    Economics, 32, 41758.

    Eicher, T. and Turnovsky, S.J. (2000) Scale, congestion, and growth, Economica,67, 32546.

    Fiaschi, D.(1999) Growth and inequality in an endogenous fiscal policy model with taxes on

    labor and capital, European Journal of Political Economy, 15, 72746.

    Fisher, W.H. and Turnovsky, S.J. (1998) Public investment, congestion, and private capitalaccumulation,Economic Journal, 108, 399413.

    Futagami, K., Morita, Y., and Shibata, A.(1993) Dynamic analysis of an endogenous growth

    model with public capital, in T.M. Andersen and K.O. Moene (eds) Endogenous Growth,

    Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

    Glomm, G. and Ravikumar, B. (1997) Productive government expenditures and long-run

    growth,Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21, 183204.

    Gupta S., Clements, B., Baldacci, E., and Mulas-Granados, C. (2005) Fiscal policy,

    expenditure composition, and growth in low-income Countries, Journal of International

    Money and Finance, 24, 44164.

    Hanushek, E. and Kimko, D. (2000) Schooling, labor-force quality, and the growth of

    nations, American Economic Review, 90, 1184208.

    Karras, G. (2004) Government spending and private consumption: some international

    evidence,Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 26, 922.

    Krusell, P., Ohanian, L.E., Ros-Rull, J.-V., and Violante, G.L. (2000) Capital-skill comple-

    mentarity and inequality: a macroeconomic analysis, Econometrica, 68, 102954.

    Lee, J.(1992) Optimal size and composition of government spending, Journal of the Japanese

    and International Economies, 6, 42339.

    Levy, H.(2004) Rural roads and poverty alleviation in Morocco, unpublished, World Bank,

    Washington DC

    p.-r. agnor 79

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    24/32

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    25/32

    From the definition ofGI, and using (1),

    GI IY IAPGI

    KP

    E

    KP

    KP,

    that is, with e E=KP ,GI

    KP IAP

    GI

    KP

    e,

    or equivalently

    GI

    KP IAPe

    1=1

    : A2

    Substituting (A2) in (A1) yields

    _KP

    KP q API

    e

    1=1c

    ,

    A3

    wherec C=KP .

    Similarly, using (A2), equation (15) can be rewritten as

    _C

    C s API

    e 1=1

    h i

    : A4

    From the definition ofGE, and using (1),

    GE EY EAPGI

    KP

    E

    KP

    KP,

    so that, using (A2),

    GE

    KP E API

    e 1=1

    E APIe

    1=1

    : A5

    Equation (8) gives

    _E

    E AE

    GE

    KP

    KP

    E

    GI

    KP

    KP

    E

    AE

    GE

    KP

    GI

    KP

    e,

    so that, using (A2) and (A5),

    _E

    E AE

    EAPIe

    1=1

    IAP=1e=1

    e:

    This expression can be rewritten as

    _E

    E A

    E

    1I

    2 e!, A6

    whereA AEA

    2

    P , 1 =1 , 2 =1 , and

    p.-r. agnor 81

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    26/32

    Combining eqs (A3), (A4), and (A6) yields

    _c

    c I

    e 1=1

    c, A7

    _ee

    AE1I

    2 e! q APIe

    1=1c, A8

    where

    A1=1P s q: A9

    This expression is negative (positive) if is lower (higher) than the ratio q / s:

    sg sg s1q: A10

    To investigate the dynamics in the vicinity of the steady state, the system ( A7)-(A8) can

    be linearized to give_c

    _e

    a11 a12

    a21 a22

    c ~c

    e ~e

    , A11

    where the aijare given by

    a11 ~c, a21 ~e,

    a22 !AE

    1I

    2 ~e! q

    1 API

    ~e

    1=150,

    a12 ~c

    1 I

    =1~e!=,

    where ~e and ~cdenote the stationary values ofe and c , and sga12 sg22

    From (A7), setting _c 0 yields

    ~c I~e

    1=1: A12

    Similarly, from (A8), setting _e 0 yields

    ~c q API~e 1=1AE1I 2 ~e!: A13

    From these two equations, it can be seen that the slopes of the CC and EE curves are

    given by

    d~c

    d~e

    CC

    a12

    a11

    1 I

    =1~e!=,

    d~c

    d~e

    EE

    a22

    a2140:

    Thus, whereas EEalways has a positive slope, the slope ofCC is upward- (downward-)

    sloping if is negative (positive).c is a jump variable, whereas e is predetermined over time. Saddlepath stability requires

    bl ( i i ) T h hi di i h ld h d i f h

    82 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    27/32

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    28/32

    If~e=I50 (which is always the case if 0 or more generally if=is small), the effect

    on growth is positive if =4~e=I. If ~e=I40 the effect on growth is always positive.

    Graphically, it can be verified from (A12) and (A14) that a rise in Ialways leads to a shift in

    CCto the left (given that 4 0), whereas the shift in EEcan be either to the right (upper

    panel of Fig. 2) or the left (lower panel).The impact effect of a rise in I on the consumption-private capital ratio, given that

    de0=d 0, is

    @c0

    @I

    @~c

    @I

    a12

    ~c

    @~e

    @I

    , A16

    which is also ambiguous in general, given that @ ~c=@Iis ambiguous. If@ ~e=@I50 , given that

    a1240 , then @c0=@I50 if@~c=@I50 , as shown in the upper panel of Fig. 2.

    Appendix 2Dynamic form with nonseparable utility

    Suppose that the households discounted utility is given by (22), which is repeated here for

    convenience:

    maxC

    V

    10

    CGH1

    1 exptdt, 40: A17

    In the decentralized economy, the household solves problem (A17) subject to (1) and (3),taking the tax rate, , and government-provided services, GH, as given. The current-value

    Hamiltonian for this problem can be written as

    CG

    H

    1

    1 1 AP

    GI

    KP

    E

    KP

    KP S C

    ( ),

    where is the costate variable associated with (3) and S 1 wGE .

    From the first-order condition d=dC 0 and the costate condition_

    d=dKP , optimality conditions for this problem can be written, withs 1 , where 1 , as

    GHCGH

    , A18

    _= sAPGI

    KP

    E

    KP

    , A19

    together with the budget constraint (3) and the transversality condition

    limt!1

    KPexpt 0: A20

    84 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    29/32

    Equation (A18) can be rewritten as

    C G11=H :

    Taking logs of this expression and differentiating with respect to time yields

    _C

    C

    _

    _GH

    GH

    , A21

    where 1 1=.

    Given that the tax rate is constant, _GH=GH _GI=GI _Y=Y. From (1),

    _Y

    Y

    _GI

    GI

    _E

    E

    1

    _KP

    KP ,

    that is,

    _Y

    Y

    1

    _E

    E

    1

    _KP

    KP

    : A22

    Substituting this expression, together with (A19), in (A21) yields

    _C

    C sAP

    GI

    KP

    E

    KP

    ( )

    1

    _E

    E

    _KP

    KP

    : A23

    The next step is to eliminate _KP=KP and _E=E in (A23). From (A3) in Appendix 1,

    _KP

    KP q API

    e

    h i1=1c, A24

    wherec C=KP and q 1 I E H. Similarly, from (A6),

    _EE

    AE1I

    2 e!, A25

    where again A AEA2P, 1 =1 , 2 =1 , and !

    1=1 250.

    Substituting (A24), and (A25) in (A23) and using (A2) yields

    _C

    C s API

    e

    h i1=1 A26

    1

    AE1I

    2 e! q APIe

    h i

    1=1c

    :

    p.-r. agnor 85

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    30/32

    Combining (A24), (A25), and (A26) yields a dynamic system in c and e, which can be

    analyzed along the lines of Appendix 1. With 51, the qualitative properties of the model

    (uniqueness and stability) are the same as before.23 The growth-maximizing policies

    (as summarized in Proposition 5) can be derived directly from (A25) and (A26), setting

    c ~cand e

    ~e .Consider now the welfare-maximizing policies. To specify the social planners problem,

    note first that, from (1), given that GI IY,

    Y APIE

    KP

    h i1=1: A27

    From (11), the economys consolidated budget constraint can be written as

    Y C _KP X

    hI, E, H

    Gh, A28

    that is, using (A27),

    _KP q APIE

    KP

    h i1=1C: A29

    Using Gh hYand (A27), eq. (8) becomes

    _E AEI1 2 E1!K!P: A30

    To get an expression for E=K, use (23) and (25) to obtain

    E

    K

    EY

    HA

    E

    1I

    2 E1!K!P 1 C

    Y

    : A31

    Substituting (A31) in (31) yields, using (23), (A29), (A30), and setting 0;

    _C

    C API

    e

    h i1=1

    A32

    1 AE

    1I

    2 e!

    1 c ,

    where

    1 1

    E

    Hg

    C

    Y

    40:

    Divide (A29) byKPyields

    _KP

    KP q API

    e

    h i1=1c: A33

    86 fiscal policy and endogenous growth

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    31/32

    Subtracting (A33) from (A32) yields

    _c

    c API

    e

    1=1

    A34

    1 A

    E

    1I

    2 e!

    1 1

    c ,

    where q. The sign of this expression depends on the size of ; as before, it is

    negative for sufficiently small.

    Now, dividing (A30) byEyields

    _E

    E A

    EI

    1 2 e!: A35

    Subtracting (A33) from (A35) implies

    _e

    e AE

    1I

    2 e! q APIe

    h i1=1

    c, A36

    which is identical to (A8). Equations (A34) and (A36) represent a system of two nonlinear

    differential equations inc C=KPande E=KP. Uniqueness and stability properties of this

    system can be established along the lines of Appendix 1 (see also Agenor and Neanidis,

    (2006, Appendix C). It can readily be shown that Fig. 1 represents again the phase diagram of

    the centrally-planned economy.

    p.-r. agnor 87

  • 8/12/2019 Fiscal Policy and Endoge

    32/32