36
Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies Chetan Dave y Chetan Ghate z Pawan Gopalakrishnan x Suchismita Tarafdar { April 30, 2018 Abstract We build a small open economy RBC model with nancial frictions to analyze expansionary scal consolidations in emerging market economies (EMEs). We cali- brate the model to India, which we view as a proto-typical EME. When factor income tax rates are low, a contractionary scal shock has an expansionary e/ect on output. The economys debt/GDP ratio falls, and tax revenues rise. When factor income tax rates are high, a contractionary scal shocks has an expansionary e/ect on output if government spending is valued su¢ ciently highly relative to private consumption by households in utility. We identify the mechanisms behind these results, and their implications for actual economies undertaking scal reforms. Keywords : Expansionary Fiscal Consolidations, Fiscal Policy in Small Open Economies, Emerging Market Business Cycles, Financial Frictions. JEL Codes : E32, E62 We thank seminar participants at Virginia Tech and the 13 th Annual Conference on Growth and De- velopment (2017) at ISI Delhi for helpful comments. We are grateful to PPRU (Policy Planning Research Unit) for nancial assistance related to this project. The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the authors and no condential information accessed by Chetan Ghate during the monetary policy deliberations in the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) meetings has been used in this article. y Department of Economics, New York University - Abu Dhabi. Tel: (971)50-831-9256. E-mail: chet- [email protected]. z Corresponding Author: Economics and Planning Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi 110016, India. Tel: (91)-11-4149-3938. Fax: 91-11-4149-3981. E-mail: [email protected]. x Strategic Research Unit, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai 400001, India. Tel: (91)-22-2260-2206. E-mail: [email protected]. { Department of Economics, Shiv Nadar University, Gautam Buddha Nagar, Uttar Pradesh - 201314, India. Tel: (91)-120-266-3801. E-mail: [email protected].

Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies�

Chetan Davey Chetan Ghatez Pawan Gopalakrishnanx

Suchismita Tarafdar{

April 30, 2018

Abstract

We build a small open economy RBC model with �nancial frictions to analyzeexpansionary �scal consolidations in emerging market economies (EMEs). We cali-brate the model to India, which we view as a proto-typical EME. When factor incometax rates are low, a contractionary �scal shock has an expansionary e¤ect on output.The economy�s debt/GDP ratio falls, and tax revenues rise. When factor income taxrates are high, a contractionary �scal shocks has an expansionary e¤ect on outputif government spending is valued su¢ ciently highly relative to private consumptionby households in utility. We identify the mechanisms behind these results, and theirimplications for actual economies undertaking �scal reforms.

Keywords : Expansionary Fiscal Consolidations, Fiscal Policy in Small Open Economies,Emerging Market Business Cycles, Financial Frictions.

JEL Codes : E32, E62

�We thank seminar participants at Virginia Tech and the 13th Annual Conference on Growth and De-velopment (2017) at ISI Delhi for helpful comments. We are grateful to PPRU (Policy Planning ResearchUnit) for �nancial assistance related to this project. The views and opinions expressed in this article arethose of the authors and no con�dential information accessed by Chetan Ghate during the monetary policydeliberations in the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) meetings has been used in this article.

yDepartment of Economics, New York University - Abu Dhabi. Tel: (971)50-831-9256. E-mail: [email protected].

zCorresponding Author: Economics and Planning Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi �110016,India. Tel: (91)-11-4149-3938. Fax: 91-11-4149-3981. E-mail: [email protected].

xStrategic Research Unit, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai � 400001, India. Tel: (91)-22-2260-2206.E-mail: [email protected].

{Department of Economics, Shiv Nadar University, Gautam Buddha Nagar, Uttar Pradesh - 201314,India. Tel: (91)-120-266-3801. E-mail: [email protected].

Page 2: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

1. Introduction

While many countries undertake �scal consolidations to reduce their �scal de�cits, there

is little consensus on the short and long term e¤ects of �scal austerity on public debt and

potential economic growth. The 2010 World Economic Outlook (WEO) published by the

IMF �nds that domestic demand falls by about 1 percent in response to consolidation. It also

�nds that �scal contractions that rely on spending cuts tend to have smaller contractionary

e¤ects than tax based adjustments (IMF WEO, page 95). Building on the seminal work

of Giavazzi and Pagano (1990), another branch of the literature however shows that �scal

retrenchments can stimulate growth in the short run, a phenomenon referred to as the

"expansionary �scal contraction" hypothesis.1 Such expansions happen if the consolidation

is structured in a way that increases con�dence.

Most of the quantitative macroeconomic literature on �scal contractions however is in

the context of advanced economies.2 What is missing is an understanding of the mechanisms

behind �scal consolidations in emerging market economies. Our paper attempts to �ll this

gap. We build a small open economy real business cycle (SOE RBC) model with �nancial

frictions and �scal policy that is more suited to analyzing �scal contractions in EMEs.

Our model builds on the work of Neumeyer and Perri (2005), Ghate, Gopalakrishnan, and

Tarafdar (2016), and Hansen and Imrohoroglu (2016). We calibrate the model to India,

which we view as a proto-typical small open economy, to understand the e¤ects of �scal

contractions in small open emerging market economies.3 Our main result is that when factor

income tax rates are low, a contractionary �scal shock can have an expansionary e¤ect on

GDP. The rise in GDP makes the economy�s debt/GDP ratio fall. In contrast, when factor

income tax rates are high, a contractionary �scal shock has an expansionary e¤ect on output

1See Alesina and Ardagna (2010).2A large literature on �scal consolidation on economic activity in advanced economies (Aiyagari et al.,

1992; Baxter and King, 1993; Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992; Gali, Lopez-Salido, and Valles, 2007)�nds that with in�nitely lived Ricardian households, an increase in (non-productive) government spendingpurchases (�nanced by current or future lump sum taxes) lowers the present value of after tax income andgenerates a negative wealth e¤ect on consumption. The empirical literature on the e¤ects of �scal policy(Blanchard and Perotti (2002), Romer and Romer (2010)) also �nds similar results.

3Neumeyer and Perri (2005), Aguiar and Gopinath (2007), and Chang and Fernandez (2013) provideimportant frameworks for understanding the impact of interest rate shocks in small open economy RBCmodels.

1

Page 3: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

if government spending is valued "su¢ ciently highly" relative to private consumption by

households in utility. If the relative weight on government spending by households in utility

is low, contractionary �scal policy reduces output. Public debt/GDP rises in the transition

to the steady state, and tax revenues falls, thereby worsening macroeconomic outcomes.

Our analysis is policy relevant since in recent years many emerging market economies

have undergone �scal consolidations to reduce their �scal de�cits and public debt/GDP

ratios. Figure 1, which plots the �scal de�cit/GDP ratio of Malaysia since 2009, depicts a

fairly large reduction in the �scal de�cit/GDP ratio approximating 3.7%.

Figure 1. Fiscal De�cit as % of GDP in Malaysia.

­6­5

.5­5

­4.5

­4­3

.5Fi

scal

 Def

icit 

as %

 of 

GD

P

2010 2012 2014 2016 2018Year

Fiscal Deficit as % of GDP for India

Figure 2. Fiscal De�cit as % of GDP in India.

Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central �scal de�cit/GDP reduction

of a similar order of magnitude. The 2018 IMF Fiscal Monitor notes that many emerging

market countries have already (Brazil, Saudi Arabia) or are in the process of implementing

(Russia, China) �scal consolidation plans. The novel aspect of our framework is that we build

2

Page 4: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

a uni�ed dynamic stochastic general equilibrium framework that identi�es conditions under

which, (i) �scal contractions are contractionary, and (ii) �scal contractions are expansionary.

1.1. Description of Model

Our theoretical framework builds on Neumeyer and Perri (2005), Ghate, Gopalakrishnan,

and Tarafdar (2016), and Hansen and Imrohoroglu (2016). In particular, we add public debt

to the framework of Ghate, Gopalakrishnan, and Tarafdar (2016) along the lines of Hansen

and Imrohoroglu (2016).

The economy consists of �rms, a government, and households. Firm wage payments

are subject to working capital constraints, as in Neumeyer and Perri (2005) and Ghate,

Gopalakrishnan, and Tarafdar (2016). Working capital constraints are the key �nancial

friction in the model. To meet the working capital constraint, �rms borrows from house-

holds domestically and abroad by issuing corporate debt which is priced at the international

interest rate, R�:

In�nitely lived households derive utility over private consumption (Ct) and government

consumption (Gt) which are assumed to be perfect substitutes but with di¤erent weights;

leisure (1�Ht); government bonds (Dt), as in Hansen and Imrohoroglu (2015); and private

bonds (Bt). We assume that households value holding government bonds relatively more

than private bonds since private bonds are assumed to be relatively more riskier compared

to the risk free asset. Consumers form habits in their expenditure formation with utility

depending on current consumption, Ct; relative to a habit reference level, Ct�1: E¤ective

consumption is given by C�t = Ct + �Gt; where � > 0 is the relative weight of government

consumption in utility.4

The government collects tax revenue by imposing time invariant distortionary taxes on

wage and capital incomes, does not balance its budget, and borrows by issuing debt at

a rate RGt > 1. The government allocates Gt of it�s total revenue towards government

consumption. The residual is transferred to households in the form of a lump-sum transfer

(Tt). The sovereign risk premium on public debt depends on the deviation of the period t

4The presence of habits ensures that �scal shocks lead to sluggish adjustments in e¤ective consumptionwhich ensures that steady state consumption, C > 0:

3

Page 5: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

debt-GDP (dt) ratio relative to its steady state value ( �d). If the debt-GDP ratio is higher

than its steady state, than the rate at which the government borrows is higher Thus,

the sovereign risk premia required to borrow in international capital markets depends on

domestic fundamentals in the economy. Finally, the interest rate on corporate debt, Rpt > 1;

is priced o¤ the RGt , as in many emerging market economies, which implies that RPt > R

Gt

(see Caballero, Fernandez, and Park (2016)). Hence, RPt > RGt > R

We calibrate the model using a broad set of parameters representative of the Indian

economy. Using Sims (2002), the solution to the log-linearized system is the state equation

of the model in the form of a VAR (1). We discuss the intuition behind the impulse response

functions generated by three main shocks in the model: government spending shocks, foreign

interest rate shocks, and total factor productivity shocks.

1.2. Main Results

The main insight obtained is to identify the mechanism and conditions under which �s-

cal contractions can be contractionary or expansionary in the short run. We �rst consider

the case when factor income tax rates are low. A reduction in government consumption

leads to a rise in private consumption, but a decline in e¤ective consumption, since govern-

ment consumption and private consumption are substitutes in utility. A decline in e¤ective

consumption increases the marginal utility from e¤ective consumption, which induces the

household to work more. Despite the fall in government spending, low tax collections from

factor incomes leads to a rise in public debt, plus a lump sum tax that is required for the

government budget constraint to hold. The negative wealth e¤ect from higher lump sum

taxes induces households to work more. As a result, employment rises and wages fall. Since

the capital stock is given in time period t; higher hours worked leads to higher GDP. Hence,

on impact, a contractionary �scal shock is expansionary. Higher output also induces house-

holds to buy more government and private bonds, since these enhance utility. Because the

increase in government bonds increases by less than the increase in output, the debt-GDP

ratio falls on impact. The reduction in the debt-GDP ratio relative to its steady state value

reduces the sovereign risk premium, and depresses RGt : Since private sector debt is priced o¤

of RGt ; working capital loan rates fall. Higher output increases the gross marginal product

4

Page 6: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

of capital, Rt: While ordinarily this would depress capital accumulation, higher labor sup-

ply increases the marginal productivity of private capital increasing investment and capital

accumulation overall. This provides a further boost to output in the next period. We �nd

that a �scal contraction increases hours worked, GDP, investment and capital accumulation.

It also reduces the public debt-GDP ratio and which reduces the sovereign risk premium.

Now consider the case when factor income tax rates are high.5 We show that the inci-

dence of a contractionary �scal consolidation being expansionary now depends on the value

of �; the parameter denoting the relative superiority of government consumption vis-a-vis

private consumption in utility.6 When � is low, a negative government spending shock in-

creases private consumption and e¤ective consumption. The marginal utility from e¤ective

consumption falls. Hours worked falls, and wages rise. A reduction in hours worked drives

GDP down which reduces R on impact. A lower R increases investment and capital accu-

mulation in the next period. However, the reduction in the marginal utility from e¤ective

consumption requires a reduction in the marginal utility of holding public and private debt

by households to maintain their marginal rate of substitution conditions. Hence, the de-

mand for private and public debt rises. This raises the public debt-GDP ratio, pushing up

the sovereign risk premium, the government borrowing rate, RGt ; and therefore RPt : When

� is high, the key di¤erence is that a negative government spending shock increases pri-

vate consumption, but reduces e¤ective consumption. Hours work rises, which raises GDP,

investment (because the marginal product of capital rises with higher employment), and

capital, increasing output in the next period as well. Higher GDP implies that households

demand more private and public debt, but because output has risen, the public-debt to GDP

ratio falls. This reduces the sovereign risk premium, implying that both RGt and RPt fall.

To balance its budget, the government lump sum taxes households. These lump sum taxes

impose a negative wealth e¤ect on households which induces the household to work more.

We compare these results with the propagation mechanism from foreign interest rate

shocks, and TFP shocks. For these cases, the dynamics of the economy respond similarly

5In the experiments we conduct later on, we arbitrarily set factor income taxes to be 10 times higherthan the baseline case.

6 . Consistent with the empirical literature, we restrict 0 < � < 1 ( see Ambler and Paquet (1996), andBarro (1981)).

5

Page 7: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

to the low and high tax cases. A foreign interest rate shock raises RP and RG on impact.

This reduces private consumption and e¤ective consumption, and increases the demand for

public and private debt since these now give higher returns. The reduction in e¤ective

consumption raises hours worked, but in the net hours worked falls, since higher lump sum

taxes are required to balance the government budget constraint. This pushes hours worked

down, and GDP falls.

Our analysis uncovers an interesting point of departure with respect to Neumeyer and

Perri. A reduction in GDP because of a rise in foreign interest rates also obtains in Neumeyer

and Perri (2005). In that paper however, there is no �scal policy. Unlike Neumeyer and Perri

(2005), we also don�t have to assume GHH preferences to obtain this result.

With a TFP shock, both factor prices, wages, and the marginal product of capital, rise.

Households work more, which increases GDP. More employment raises the marginal product

of capital which increases investment and the capital stock in the next period. Higher GDP

raises consumption and e¤ective consumption. The demand for public and private debt falls,

which reduces RP and RG:

2. The Model

2.1. Firms

The economy consists of �rms, a government, and households. At any given time t a

representative �rm produces �nal output using labor employed at time t and capital carried

forward from time period t� 1. However, prior to actual production, the �rm needs to pay

a portion � 2 [0; 1] of its total wage bill. To meet this working capital constraint, the �rm

borrows from households by issuing debt. The �rm issues corporate bonds (Bt) to households

to whom they promise a return of RPt�1 which is considered to be a markup over the domestic

government bond interest rate, RGt�1.

The �rm hires labor (Ht) and uses capital (Kt�1) accumulated in time period t � 1 to

6

Page 8: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

produce the �nal output Yt such that

maxfKt;Htg

Yt �RtKt�1 � (1� �)WtHt � �WtHtRPt�1, (1)

where,

Yt = AtK�t�1H

1��t (2)

and At denotes exogenous total factor productivity (TFP). This yields the following �rst

order conditions for �rms.

(1� �)YtHt

= Wt

�1� � + �RPt�1

�(3)

�YtKt�1

= Rt (4)

The timing of events and decisions is identical to Neumeyer and Perri (2005) and Ghate

et al. (2016). In the beginning of period t, which we denote as t�, �rms borrow �WtHt to

make advance payments to labor prior to actual production (which occurs at t). Firms then

produce output and repay the loan borrowed at the end of time period (t+), with workers

receiving the rest of their wage bill (1 � �)WtHt at time t+. Since the time gap between

t� and t, and between t and t+ is very small, we drop these superscripts and consider the

entire period as time period t.

2.2. Households

The economy is populated by in�nitely lived households with a mass normalized to 1.

The representative household consumes and invests a homogenous good and supplies labor

and capital to �rms. As in the vast literature on habit formation, we assume that consumers

form habits in their expenditure formation with utility, U; depending on current consumption,

Ct; relative to a habit reference level, Ct�1: The representative household has the following

expected discounted lifetime utility

E0

1Xt=0

�tU(C�t ; Ht; Bt; Dt); (5)

7

Page 9: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

where � 2 (0; 1) denotes the households subjective discount factor. We assume that

Ct + �Gt; (6)

where household consumption (Ct) is augmented by government consumption (Gt). The

parameter � captures the weight of public consumption in household utility, where � > 0.

Given our speci�cation in equation (6), Ct and Gt are assumed to be perfect substitutes.7

We assume that agents treat Gt as a given covariance stationary stochastic process (CSSP).

Finally, households also derive utility from holding private and government debt (Bt and

Dt respectively). Our speci�cation of the household deriving utility over public debt follows

Hansen and Imrohoroglu (2016). In the calibration exercise later, we assume that the pref-

erence for holding public debt is higher than private debt since public debt is the risk free

asset.

We adopt a unitary elasticity of substitution speci�cation for instantaneous utility

U(C�t ; Ht; Bt; Dt) = � ln (Ct � �Ct�1 + �Gt) + (1� �� '1 � '2) ln (1�Ht) (7)

+ '1 ln (Dt) + '2 ln (Bt) :

The household faces the following constraint

Ct +Xt +Bt + �1(Bt) +Dt + �2(Dt) (8)

= (1� �w)WtHt + (1� �k)RtKt�1 +RPt�1Bt�1 +R

Gt�1Dt�1 + Tt

where Bt denotes private bond holdings, Xt denotes investment, �w 2 [0; 1] is the tax on

labor income, and �k 2 [0; 1] is the tax on capital income. Agents take the competitive wage

rate (Wt) and return to capital (Rt) as given in deciding optimal choices. For private bond

7In an emerging markets context, an example of Gt can be public health or public transportation serviceswhose quality is typically seen as being superior to private alternatives. See Barro (1981), Christiano andEichenbaum (1992), and Ghate et al. (2016).

8

Page 10: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

holdings the term �(Bt) in (8) is the bond holding cost,

�1(Bt) =�12Yt

�BtYt��B�Y

�2: (9)

Households also invest in government bonds (Dt) and holding these involve an analogous

cost,

�2(Dt) =�22Yt

�Dt

Yt� D�Y

�2: (10)

The term Xt in (8) is the level of private investment

Xt = Kt � (1� �)Kt�1 + �(Kt; Kt�1); (11)

where �(Kt; Kt�1) is the capital adjustment costs such that8

�(Kt; Kt�1) =�

2Kt�1

��Kt

Kt�1

�� 1�2: (12)

Therefore,

Xt = Kt � (1� �)Kt�1 +�

2Kt�1

�Kt

Kt�1� 1�2

(13)

is the law of motion of capital accumulation.

2.3. Government Budget Constraint

The government in our model follows a non-discretionary �scal policy. It collects tax

revenue by imposing time invariant distortionary taxes on wage and capital incomes, does

not balance its budget, and borrows by issuing debt at a rate RGt . The government allocates

Gt of it�s total revenue towards government consumption. The residual is transferred to

households in the form of a lump-sum transfer (Tt). The following is the government budget

constraint, in every time period t.

Gt + Tt = �wWtHt + �kRtKt +Dt �RGt�1Dt�1, (14)

8An investment adjustment cost is required to make the volatility of private investments relative to outputmatch empirically observed values. This is also a standard practice in RBC models.

9

Page 11: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

where

RGt = �R�t exp

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�: (15)

RGt is assumed to be a mark-up over the international interest rate R�t .9 The mark-up is the

spread over the international interest rate, to capture sovereign risk, modelled as deviations

from the steady state debt to GDP levels, i.e.,

�t = � exp

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�; where � > 0: (16)

We further assume that the interest rate on private bonds is equal to the interest rate on

government bonds with an additional mark-up, i.e.,

RPt = �RGt : (17)

This re�ects the fact that there is a risk premium in corporate bonds over government bonds.

In light of the above environment, given fAt; R�t ; Gtg1t=0, a vector of �scal policy para-

meters f�k; �w; �g, and initial conditions K�1; B�1; D�1; RP�1; R

G�1; a competitive equilib-

rium for our model is a vector of allocations of fCt; Kt; Dt; Bt; and Htg1t=0 and factor prices

fWt and Rtg1t=0 such that, for the given sequence of factor prices, (i) fKt and Htg1t=0 solves

the �rm�s pro�t maximization problem (1), and FOCs (3-4), (ii) fCt; Kt; Bt; Dt; Htg1t=0 max-

imizes the utility of the representative agent (5) subject to (2), (8), (6), (9), (10), (12), and

(13) together with Ct; Kt > 0, (iii) Tt satis�es (14), (iv) a no-Ponzi associated with the

initial conditions K�1; B�1; and D�1 holds for the representative agent, and �nally, (v) all

markets clear for all time periods. .

Collecting the decision rules and constraints across all economic actors, this de�nition of a

competitive equilibrium results in the following system of nonlinear expectational di¤erence

9We assume R�t to be an exogenous process. Typically in the literature, the international interest rateR�t is assumed to be the US 91 day T-Bill rates (see Neumeyer and Perri (2005), Ghate et al. (2016)).

10

Page 12: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

equations that describe this �cycles only�model10:

�t =�

Ct � �Ct�1 + �Gt� ��

Ct+1 � �Ct + �Gt+1(N1)

(1� �w)�tWt =1� �� '1 � '2

1�Ht(N2)

Et

8><>:��t+1

�1� � � �

2

hKt+1

Kt� 1i2+ �Kt+1

Kt

hKt+1

Kt� 1i+ (1� �k)Rt+1

�= �t

h1 + �

hKt

Kt�1� 1ii

9>=>; (N3)

Et

���t+1R

Pt = �t

�1 + �1

�BtYt��B�Y

��� '2Bt

�(N4)

Et

���t+1R

Gt = �t

�1 + �2

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

��� '1Dt

�(N5)

Ct +Kt � (1� �)Kt�1 +�

2Kt�1

�Kt

Kt�1� 1�2+Bt +

�12Yt

�BtYt��B�Y

�2+Dt (N6)

+�22Yt

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�2= (1� �w)WtHt + (1� �k)RtKt�1 +R

Pt�1Bt�1 +R

Gt�1Dt�1 + Tt

(1� �)YtHt

= Wt

�(1� �) + �RPt�1

�(N7)

�YtKt�1

= Rt (N8)

Yt = AtK�t�1H

1��t (N9)

Gt + Tt = �wWtHt + �kRtKt +Dt �RGt�1Dt�1 (N10)

RGt = �R�t exp

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�(N11)

RPt = �RGt (N12)

Gt � CSSP ( �G; �G; �G) (N13)

At � CSSP ( �A; �A; �A) (N14)

R�t � CSSP ( �R�; �R� ; �R�) (N15)

where CSSP denotes (an exogenous) covariance stationary stochastic process. The assump-

tion that government debt has utility value following Hansen and Imrohoroglu (2016) asserts

itself in the system above. The Euler equations governing private and public debt (equations

10We note that there is no source of deterministic growth in this model and so the log-linearized versionwe analyze next is to be interpreted in terms of Hodrick-Prescott �ltered data analogs.

11

Page 13: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

(N4) and (N5) respectively) are distinct from each other and distinct from that governing

the determination of physical capital (equation (N3)). The working capital friction clearly

introduces a wedge into the equation governing the determination of wages from the �rms�

side (equation (N2)). The remaining equations are standard relative to a baseline RBC

model with real frictions.

3. Calibration

We analyze the log-linearized version of the model, which, for instance following Sims

(2001), can be written as a system of 15 equations in 15 variables:

�0Xt+1 = �1Xt +"t +��t

where; Xt = fCt; Ht; Dt; Kt; Bt; Yt;Wt; Rt; RPt ; R

Gt ; Tt;�t; Gt; At; R

�tg

and the matrices �0, �1, and � are functions of 25 model parameters:

�; �; �; �; '1; '2; �; �; �1; �2; �w; �k; �; �;�; �; �G; �A; �R�; �G; �A; �R� ; �G; �A; �R� ;

with �G = �A = 1, and three new variables re�ecting idiosyncratic rational expectations errors

(�t) have been subsumed in the notation (see DeJong and Dave (2011)). Given the above

representation, any linear solution method including that of Sims (2001) solves a system of

linear expectational di¤erence equations under rational expectations as

Xt+1 = FXt +G"t; E("t"0t) =

26664�2G 0 0

0 �2A 0

0 0 �2R�

37775 ;

which is the state equation of the model in the form of a VAR (1).11

Next, we calibrate the model to India, a proto-typical small open emerging market econ-

omy. Our baseline calibration proceeds as follows. We chose the value of R�to equal 1:0035

11We analyze the model using DYNARE v. 4.5.0.

12

Page 14: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

so that it is close to the long run real interest rate on 91-Day US T-Bill bonds (with f�R� ; �R�g

being (0.7400, 0.0030)). Given that India has a very narrow income tax base and depends

more on generating revenue from indirect taxation, we allow for low income taxes. In par-

ticular, we �x the factor income tax rates at �k = �w = 0:01 following the estimated average

e¤ective tax rates in Poirson (2006). Given data on RPt (Indian commercial paper) and RGt

(91-day Indian T-bill rate) we obtain � and � as 1.01259 and 1.00131 respectively. Since

we have included bond holding costs in our household constraint not just for realism in the

EME context but also to ensure that the corresponding �rst order conditions do not follow

a random walk, we assume them to be small (�1 = �2 = 0:0062). For similar realism in the

Indian context, we set � to be 0.5 and � to be 8.8591. The impulse responses we discuss

below are invariant to these parameter choices.

Our choices for preference parameter values re�ect the following intuition. We set � to be

0.4 to give the highest weight to consumption and '1 and '2 to be 0.2 and 0.15 respectively

to re�ect that due to risk aversion considerations households would give less weight to private

bonds than government bonds. These parameter values then imply a weight of approximately

a third on leisure which corresponds to the notion that households spend approximately

that amount of time on non-employment activity. Table 1 below summarizes our choice of

parameters in our model.

Table 1: Baseline Parameters

13

Page 15: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

Parameters Values Source Parameters Values Source

� 0.4 Arbitrary �1 = �2 0.006 Arbitrary

� < 1 Barro (1981) �G 0.59 Anand and Prasad. (2010)

� 0.4 Arbitrary �A 0.82 Basu et al. (2018)

#1 0.2 Arbitrary �R� 0.74 Authors�Calculation

#2 0.15 Arbitrary �G 0.026 Anand et al. (2010)

� 0.36 Ghate et al. (2016) �A 0.016 Anand et al. (2010)

� 0.98 Gabriel et al. (2012) �R� 0.003 Calculated

� 0.025 Banerjee and Basu (2017) R�

1.0035 Calculated

�w = �k 0.01 Poisron (2006) � 1.01259 Calculated

� 8.8591 Arbitrary � 1.001312 Calculated

� 0.5 Arbitrary G = A 1 Arbitrary

4. Impulse Responses

Our model features three exogenous shock processes, for Gt, R�t and At (all in logarithmic

deviations from steady state). The impulse responses for these shocks are provided below.

The following impulse responses are for our baseline case which is for �w = �k = 0:01 and

� = 0:8:

14

Page 16: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

4.1. G Shock

Figure 3: Impulse responses for a single period bG shock

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08C

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­10

­8

­6

­4

­2

0

2 10­4 cs

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4 10­3 H

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

­0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2 10­5 D

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5 10­3 R

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4

5

6 10­4 K

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­5 RP

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­5 RG

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3 10­3 Y

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­15

­10

­5

0

5 10­4 W

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­3

­2.5

­2

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0 10­3 d

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­2

0

2

4

6

8 10­3 x

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­2

­1

0

1

2

3 10­5 B

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025

0.03LT

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.03

­0.025

­0.02

­0.015

­0.01

­0.005

0G

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.05

­0.04

­0.03

­0.02

­0.01

0FD

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4

5

6 10­3 TR

Figure 3 depicts the case of a negative government spending shock (government consump-

tion falls). A reduction in government consumption leads to a rise in private consumption,

but a decline in e¤ective consumption (cs), since government consumption and private con-

15

Page 17: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

sumption are substitutes in utility. A decline in e¤ective consumption increases the marginal

utility from e¤ective consumption, which induces the household to work more. Since the cap-

ital stock is given in time period t; higher hours worked leads to higher GDP, which directly

increases the return on capital, Rt. Despite a drop in wt, RPt , and RGt , disposable income of

households increase. Hence, on impact, a contractionary �scal shock is expansionary, and

higher output and disposable income also induces households to buy more government and

private bonds, since these enhance utility.

Because the increase in government bonds increases by less than the increase in output,

the debt-GDP ratio falls on impact. The reduction in the debt-GDP ratio relative to its

steady state value reduces the sovereign risk premium, and depresses RGt : Since private

sector debt is priced o¤ of RGt ; working capital loan rates also fall. Finally, higher output

increases the gross marginal product of capital, Rt: While ordinarily this would depress

capital accumulation, higher labor supply increases the marginal productivity of private

capital increasing investment and capital accumulation overall. This provides a further

boost to output in the next period. In sum, a �scal contraction increases hours worked,

GDP, investment and capital accumulation. It also reduces the public debt-GDP ratio, the

�scal de�cit, and therefore the sovereign risk premium.

16

Page 18: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

Figure 4: Impulse responses for a single period bR� shock

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1.5

­1

­0.5

0 10­5 C

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­3

­2.5

­2

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0 10­6 cs

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­15

­10

­5

0

5 10­7 H

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4

5

6 10­8 D

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­10

­8

­6

­4

­2

0

2 10­7 R

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­5

­4

­3

­2

­1

0 10­7 K

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4 10­3 RS

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1 10­5 RP

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1 10­5 RG

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­6 Y

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­5

­4

­3

­2

­1

0 10­6 W

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1 10­6 d

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­4

­3

­2

­1

0

1 10­6 x

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

2

4

6

8 10­8 B

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1.2

­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­7 LT

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.5

1

1.5

2 10­6 FD

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­8

­6

­4

­2

0 10­6 TR

4.2. R� Shock

Figure 4 depicts the case of a positive foreign interest rate, R�; shock. A foreign interest

rate shock on R� raises RP and RG on impact. This reduces private consumption and

e¤ective consumption, and increases the demand for public and private debt since these now

give higher returns. The reduction in e¤ective consumption raises hours worked, but in the

17

Page 19: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

net hours worked falls, since falling lump sum and proportional taxes induces households

to enjoy more leisure. This pushes hours worked down, and GDP falls. The reduction in

GDP is similar to the e¤ect of a rise in foreign interest rates in Neumeyer and Perri (2005).

In Neumeyer and Perri however, there is no �scal policy. The reduction in GDP in our

model obtains because of a �scal policy channel where higher lump sum taxes are required

to balance the government budget constraint.

18

Page 20: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

Figure 5: Impulse responses for a single period bA shock

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02A

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06C

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.002

0.004

0.006

0.008

0.01cs

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­5

0

5

10

15 10­3 H

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­4

­3

­2

­1

0

1 10­5 D

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.005

0

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025R

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

2

4

6

8 10­3 K

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­4 RP

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­4 RG

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025Y

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.002

0.004

0.006

0.008

0.01

0.012W

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.025

­0.02

­0.015

­0.01

­0.005

0d

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04x

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­5

­4

­3

­2

­1

0

1 10­5 B

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4 10­4 LT

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.05

­0.04

­0.03

­0.02

­0.01

0FD

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05TR

4.3. TFP Shock

Figure 5 depicts the case of a positive TFP ( bA shock). With a TFP shock, both factorprices, wages, and the marginal product of capital, rise. Households work more, which

increases GDP. More employment raises the marginal product of capital which increases

investment and the capital stock in the next period. Higher GDP raises consumption and

19

Page 21: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

e¤ective consumption. The demand for public and private debt falls, which reduces RP and

RG:

4.4. Policy Experiments

Finally, as experiments, we consider the case where taxes are high, i.e., �w = �k = 0:112

In this case, we consider two cases �a high value of �; i.e., � = 0:8 and low value of �; i.e.,

� = 0:3. Figure 6a corresponds to the case where � = 0:8: Figure 6b on the other hand

corresponds to the case where � = 0:3:

12We arbitrarily set factor income taxes to be 10 times higher than the baseline case to denote the situationof high taxes.

20

Page 22: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

Figure 6a: Impulse responses for a single period bG shock for � = 0:8; and �w = �k = 0:1

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.05

0.1

0.15C

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­20

­15

­10

­5

0

5 10­4 cs

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4 10­3 H

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

0

1

2

3 10­5 D

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

5

10

15

20 10­4 R

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4

5

6 10­4 K

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1.2

­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­5 RP

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1.2

­1

­0.8

­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0 10­5 RG

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3 10­3 Y

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­15

­10

­5

0

5 10­4 W

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­3

­2.5

­2

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0 10­3 d

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­2

0

2

4

6 10­3 x

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­2

­1

0

1

2

3

4 10­5 B

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04LT

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.03

­0.025

­0.02

­0.015

­0.01

­0.005

0G

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.05

­0.04

­0.03

­0.02

­0.01

0

0.01FD

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

1

2

3

4

5

6 10­3 TR

Figure 6a depicts the case of a negative government spending shock with high income

tax. A reduction in government consumption leads to a rise in private consumption, but

a decline in e¤ective consumption. The transmission channel in this case is similar to our

baseline case, as corresponding to Figure (3).

21

Page 23: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

Figure 6b: Impulse responses for a single period bG shock for � = 0:3; and �w = �k = 0:1

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03C

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

2

4

6

8

10 10­3 cs

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­2

­1

0

1

2

3 10­3 H

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­2

0

2

4

6

8

10 10­5 D

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

­0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5 10­3 R

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­5

0

5

10

15 10­4 K

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­10

­5

0

5 10­6 RP

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­10

­5

0

5 10­6 RG

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­1

0

1

2

3 10­3 Y

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­6

­4

­2

0

2

4

6 10­4 W

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­3

­2

­1

0

1 10­3 d

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­5

0

5

10

15 10­3 x

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­5

0

5

10

15 10­5 B

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04LT

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.03

­0.025

­0.02

­0.015

­0.01

­0.005

0G

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­0.06

­0.04

­0.02

0

0.02FD

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40­2

0

2

4

6 10­3 TR

Figure 6b depicts the case of a negative government spending shock with high factor

income tax and lower �. A reduction in government consumption leads to a rise in private

consumption, and an increase in e¤ective consumption, since government consumption has

a lower coe¢ cient in utility. An increase in e¤ective consumption decreases the marginal

utility from e¤ective consumption, which induces the household to work less leading to lower

22

Page 24: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

GDP, and lower Interest on capital, Rt. Hence, on impact, a contractionary �scal shock is

contractionary.

These experiments show that the incidence of a contractionary �scal consolidation being

expansionary depends on the value of �; the parameter denoting the relative superiority

of government consumption vis-a-vis private consumption in utility.13 When � is low, as in

Figure 6b, a negative government spending shock increases private consumption and e¤ective

consumption. The marginal utility from e¤ective consumption falls. Hours worked falls, and

wages rise. A reduction in hours worked drives GDP down which reduces R on impact.

A lower R increases investment and capital accumulation in the next period. However,

the reduction in the marginal utility from e¤ective consumption requires a reduction in the

marginal utility of holding public and private debt by households to maintain their marginal

rate of substitution conditions. Hence, the demand for private and public debt rises. This

raises the debt-GDP ratio, pushing up the sovereign risk premium, the government borrowing

rate, RG; and therefore RP . When � is high, the key di¤erence is that a negative government

spending shock increases private consumption, but reduces e¤ective consumption. Hours

work rises, which raises GDP, investment (because the marginal product of capital rises with

higher employment), and capital, increasing output in the next period as well. Higher GDP

implies that households demand more private and public debt, but because output has risen,

the public-debt to GDP ratio falls. This reduces the sovereign risk premium, implying that

both RG and RP fall. To balance its budget, the government lump sum taxes households.

These lump sum taxes impose a negative wealth e¤ect on households which also reinforce

the increase in hours worked from the marginal utility channel.

5. Conclusion

To model �scal consolidations in EMDEs, we develop a simple SOE RBC model with

�scal policy and �nancial frictions to derive conditions under which �scal contractions can

be expansionary. The main result of our paper is show that the incidence of expansionary

13 . Consistent with the empirical literature, we restrict 0 < � < 1 ( see Ambler and Paquet (1996), andBarro (1981)).

23

Page 25: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

�scal consolidations depends crucially on whether factor income tax rates are low or high.

When tax rates are high, we show that the incidence of expansionary �scal contractions

depends on the relative weight that households place on government consumption in utility.

We also show that positive foreign interest rate channels can reduce output in the short run,

but via a channel that does not require assuming that households have GHH preferences as

in Neumeyer and Perri (2005). In the future, we plan to add monetary-�scal interactions to

the model, to derive endogenous responses by the monetary authority to �scal contractions.

It would be interesting to characterize the value of the �scal multiplier in this case.

24

Page 26: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

References

[1] Aguiar, Mark, and Gita Gopinath, 2007, "Emerging market business cycles: The cycle

is the trend", Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 115, No. 1; pp. 69-102.

[2] Aiyagari, S. Rao, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, 1992. "The output,

employment, and interest rate e¤ects of government consumption," Journal of Monetary

Economics, Vol. 30(1), pages 73-86.

[3] Ambler, Steve, and Alain Paquet, 1996, "Fiscal spending shocks, endogenous govern-

ment spending, and real business cycles" Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,

Vol. 20, No. 1-3; pp. 237-256.

[4] Anand, Rahul, and Eswar Prasad, 2010. "Optimal Price Indices for Targeting In�ation

Under Incomplete Markets," IMF Working Papers, Vol 10(200).

[5] Alesina, Alberto, Silvia Ardagna, 2010. "Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes versus

Spending," NBER Chapters,in: Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 24, pages 35-68

National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

[6] Banerjee, Shesadri, Parantap Basu, Chetan Ghate, Pawan Gopalakrishnan, and Sargam

Gupta, 2018. "A Monetary Business Cycle Model for India," CEGAP Working Papers

2018_01, Durham University Business School.

[7] Barro, Robert J., 1981, "Output e¤ects of government purchases" Journal of Political

Economy, Vol. 89; pp. 1086-1121.

[8] Basu, Parantap, and Shesadri Banerjee, 2017. "Technology Shocks and Business Cycles

in India", Macroeconomic Dynamics, Forthcoming.

[9] Baxter, Marianne, and Robert G. King, 1993. "Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium,"

American Economic Review, Vol. 83(3), pages 315-334.

[10] Blanchard, Olivier, and Roberto Perotti, 2002. "An Empirical Characterization of the

Dynamic E¤ects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output," The Quar-

terly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117(4), pages 1329-1368.

25

Page 27: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

[11] Caballero, Julian, Fernandez Andres, and Jongho Park. 2016. On Corporate Borrowing,

Credit Spreads, and Economic Activity in Emerging Economies. IDB Working Paper

Series No 719.

[12] Christiano, Lawrence J., and Martin Eichenbaum, 1992, "Current real business cycle

theories and aggregate labor market �uctuations" American Economic Review, Vol. 82;

pp. 430-450.

[13] Chang, Roberto, and Andrés Fernández, 2013. "On The Sources Of Aggregate Fluctu-

ations In Emerging Economies," International Economic Review, Vol. 54, pages 1265-

1293.

[14] Fiscal Monitor, April 2018, International Monetary Fund.

[15] Jordi Galí, J. David López-Salido, and Javier Vallés, 2007. "Understanding the E¤ects

of Government Spending on Consumption," Journal of the European Economic Associ-

ation, Vol. 5(1), pages 227-270

[16] Gabriel, Vasco, Paul Levine, Joseph Pearlman, and Bo Yang, 2012. "An Estimated

DSGE Model of the Indian Economy," The Oxford Handbook of the Indian Economy,

Ed. Chetan Ghate, Oxford University Press.

[17] Ghate, Chetan, Pawan Gopalakrishnan, and Suchismita Tarafdar, 2016, "Fiscal Policy

in an Emerging Market Business Cycle Model" Journal of Economic Asymmetries, Vol.

14 (A); pp. 52-77.

[18] Giavazzi, Francesco, and Marco Pagano, 1990, "Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Ex-

pansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries" NBER Macroeconomics Annual

1990, Vol. 5; Blanchard and Fischer. 1990

[19] Hansen, Gary, and Selahattin Imrohoroglu, 2016. "Fiscal Reform and Government Debt

in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective," Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 21, pages

201-224.

26

Page 28: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

[20] Neumeyer, P.A., and F. Perri, 2005, "Business cycles in emerging economies: The role

if interest rates" Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 52; pp. 345-380.

[21] Poirson, Héléne, 2006, "The Tax System in India: Could Reform Spur Growth?" IMF

Working Paper WP/06/93.

[22] Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer, 2010. "The Macroeconomic E¤ects of Tax

Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks," American Economic

Review, Vol. 100(3), pages 763-801.

[23] Sims, Christopher A, 2002. "Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models," Computa-

tional Economics, Vol. 20(1-2), pages 1-20.

[24] Tiryaki, S. Tolga, 2012, "Interest rates and real business cycles in emerging markets"

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 11, No. 1, (Topics), Article 41.

[25] World Economic Outlook, 2010, International Monetary Fund.

27

Page 29: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

Technical Appendix

This appendix provides the derivation of the linear system comprising the model we

analyze, we note that this model is built for use with HP-�ltered data and as such does not

feature deterministic trends.

A.1 The Household Problem

A representative household maximizes utility:

maxfCt;Ht;Bt;Dt;Ktg

E0

1Xt=0

�t

24 � ln (Ct � �Ct�1 + �Gt) + (1� �� '1 � '2) ln (1�Ht)+'1 ln (Dt) + '2 ln (Bt)

35 ,where � 2 (0; 1), Gt � CSSP ( �G; �G; �G) and subject to,

Ct +Kt � (1� �)Kt�1 +�

2Kt�1

�Kt

Kt�1� 1�2+Bt +

�12Yt

�BtYt��B�Y

�2+Dt +

�22Yt

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�2= (1� �w)WtHt + (1� �k)RtKt�1 +R

Pt�1Bt�1 +R

Gt�1Dt�1 + Tt

where CSSP denotes a covariance stationary stochastic process. The Lagrangian of the

problem, where �t is the multiplier on the household budget constraint, is

maxfCt;Ht;Bt;Dt;Ktg

L =

" 1Xt=0

�t [� ln (Ct � �Ct�1 + �Gt) + (1� �� ') ln (1�Ht) + ' ln (Dt)]

#

266641Xt=0

�t�t

26664Ct +Kt � (1� �)Kt�1 +

�2Kt�1

hKt

Kt�1� 1i2+Bt

+�12Yt

hBtYt� �B

�Y

i2+Dt +

�22Yt

hDtYt� �D

�Y

i2��(1� �w)WtHt + (1� �k)RtKt�1 +R

Pt�1Bt�1 +R

Gt�1Dt�1 + Tt

�3777537775

28

Page 30: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

and the FONC are, for Ct, Ht, Kt, Bt and Dt respectively,

�t =�

Ct � �Ct�1 + �Gt� ��

Ct+1 � �Ct + �Gt+1(1� �w)�tWt =

1� �� '1 � '21�Ht

Et

8><>:��t+1

�(1� �)� �

2

hKt+1

Kt� 1i2+ �Kt+1

Kt

hKt+1

Kt� 1i+ (1� �k)Rt+1

�= �t

h1 + �

hKt

Kt�1� 1ii

9>=>;Et

���t+1R

Pt = �t

�1 + �1

�BtYt��B�Y

��� '2Bt

�Et

���t+1R

Gt = �t

�1 + �2

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

��� '1Dt

�:

The household problem therefore delivers the following system of 7 equations:

�t =�

Ct � �Ct�1 + �Gt� ��

Ct+1 � �Ct + �Gt+1(1� �w)�tWt =

1� �� '1 � '21�Ht

Et

(��t+1

"(1� �)� �

2

�Kt

Kt�1� 1�2+ �

Kt+1

Kt

�Kt

Kt�1� 1�+ (1� �k)Rt+1

#= �t

�1 + �

�Kt

Kt�1� 1��)

Et

���t+1R

Pt = �t

�1 + �1

�BtYt��B�Y

��� '2Bt

�Et

���t+1R

Gt = �t

�1 + �2

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

��� '1Dt

�Ct +Kt � (1� �)Kt�1 +

2Kt�1

�Kt

Kt�1� 1�2+Bt +

�12Yt

�BtYt��B�Y

�2+Dt +

�22Yt

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�2= (1� �w)WtHt + (1� �k)RtKt�1 +R

Pt�1Bt�1 +R

Gt�1Dt�1 + Tt

where Gt � CSSP ( �G; �G; �G)

in 15 parameters

f�; �; �; �; '1; '2; �; �; �1; �2; �w; �k; �G; �G; �Gg

and 13 variables

fCt; Gt; Ht; Dt; Kt; Bt; Yt;Wt; Rt; RPt ; R

Gt ; Tt;�tg:

29

Page 31: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

A2. The Firm Problem

The �rm seeks to maximize it�s pro�ts given by,

maxfKt�1;Htg

Yt �RtKt�1 � (1� �)WtHt � �WtHtRPt�1,

subject to

Yt = AtK�t�1H

1��t

At � CSSP ( �A; �A; �A)

This optimization yields 2 FONCs,

(1� �)YtHt

= Wt

�(1� �) + �RPt�1

��YtKt�1

= Rt

The �rm problem therefore delivers the following system of 4 equations:

(1� �)YtHt

= Wt

�(1� �) + �RPt�1

��YtKt�1

= Rt

Yt = AtK�t�1H

1��t

At � CSSP ( �A; �A; �A)

with the addition of 5 parameters f�; �; �A; �A; �Ag and 1 variable (At) to the household

system.

A.3 Government Budget Constraint

The government budget constraint is given by

Gt + Tt = �wWtHt + �kRtKt +Dt �RGt�1Dt�1,

30

Page 32: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

where

RGt = �R�t exp

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�RPt = �R

Gt

R�t � CSSP ( �R�; �R� ; �R�)

The speci�cation for government behavior therefore delivers 4 additional equations to the

system so far:

Gt + Tt = �wWtHt + �kRtKt +Dt �RGt�1Dt�1

RGt = �R�t exp

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�RPt = �R

Gt

R�t � CSSP ( �R�; �R� ; �R�)

with the addition of 5 parameters f�;�; �R�; �R� ; �R�g and 1 variable (R�t ) to the system given

by the household and �rm problems.

31

Page 33: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

A.4 The Nonlinear System

Collecting across economic actors, the system of expectational di¤erence equations is

�t =�

Ct � �Ct�1 + �Gt� ��

Ct+1 � �Ct + �Gt+1(N1)

(1� �w)�tWt =1� �� '1 � '2

1�Ht(N2)

Et

(��t+1

"1� � � �

2

�Kt+1

Kt

� 1�2+�Kt+1

Kt

�Kt+1

Kt

� 1�+ (1� �k)Rt+1

#= �t

�1 + �

�Kt

Kt�1� 1��)

(N3)

Et

���t+1R

Pt = �t

�1 + �1

�BtYt��B�Y

��� '2Bt

�(N4)

Et

���t+1R

Gt = �t

�1 + �2

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

��� '1Dt

�(N5)

Ct +Kt � (1� �)Kt�1 +�

2Kt�1

�Kt

Kt�1� 1�2+Bt +

�12Yt

�BtYt��B�Y

�2+Dt +

�22Yt

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�2(N6)

= (1� �w)WtHt + (1� �k)RtKt�1 +RPt�1Bt�1 +R

Gt�1Dt�1 + Tt

(1� �)YtHt

= Wt

�(1� �) + �RPt�1

�(N7)

�YtKt�1

= Rt (N8)

Yt = AtK�t�1H

1��t (N9)

Gt + Tt = �wWtHt + �kRtKt +Dt �RGt�1Dt�1 (N10)

RGt = �R�t exp

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�(N11)

RPt = �RGt (N12)

Gt � CSSP ( �G; �G; �G) (N13)

At � CSSP ( �A; �A; �A) (N14)

R�t � CSSP ( �R�; �R� ; �R�) (N15)

which is a nonlinear system of 15 equations in:

� 25 parameters f�; �; �; �; '1; '2; �; �; �1; �2; �w; �k; �; �;�; �; �G; �A; �R�; �G; �A; �R� ; �G; �A; �R�g

32

Page 34: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

and,

� 15 variables fCt; Ht; Dt; Kt; Bt; Yt;Wt; Rt; RPt ; R

Gt ; Tt;�t; Gt; At; R

�tg.

A.5 The Nonstochastic Steady State

Assume that the steady state values �A, �G and �R� are in hand, then �RG is in hand from

equation 11 above:

RGt = �R�t exp

�Dt

Yt��D�Y

�! �RG = � �R�:

Equation (3) above yields the expression for �R:

Et

8><>:��t+1

�1� � � �

2

hKt+1

Kt� 1i2+ �Kt+1

Kt

hKt+1

Kt� 1i+ (1� �k)Rt+1

�= �t

h1 + �

hKt

Kt�1� 1ii

9>=>;! �R =1� �(1� �)�(1� �k)

;

and �nally equation (12) above yields the expression for �RP :

RPt = �RGt ! �RP = � �RG

The remaining (9) equation system in the steady state is

�� =�(1� �)

(1� �) �C + � �G

(1� �w)�� �W =1� �� '1 � '2

1� �H

� �� �RP = ��� '2�B� �� �RG = ��� '1�D

�C + � �K + �B + (1� �RG) �D = (1� �w) �W �H + (1� �k) �R �K + �RP �B + �T

(1� �) �Y(1� � + � �RP ) �H

= �W $�W �H�Y

=1� �

1� � + � �RP� �Y�K= �R

�Y = �A �K� �H1��

�G+ �T = �w �W �H + �k �R �K + �D � �RG �D

33

Page 35: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

from which we need to determine the steady state values for Ct, Ht, Dt, Kt, Yt, Wt, Tt, Bt

and �t. Combining the 5th and 9th equations in the above system eliminates

�T = �w �W �H + �k �R �K + �D � �RG �D � �G

and yields

�� =�(1� �)

(1� �) �C + � �G

(1� �w)�� �W =1� �� '1 � '2

1� �H

�� ='2

�B(1� � �RP )�D =

'1(��� � �� �RG)

�G+ (1� �RP ) �B = �W �H + ( �R� �) �K � �C

�W =(1� �) �Y

(1� � + � �RP ) �H� �Y�K= �R

�Y = �A �K� �H1��

Next, we can eliminate �K = ��Y�R

�Y = �A

���Y�R

���H1�� (18)

�Y =��A���R

��� 11�� �H (19)

�Y = #1 �H; #1 =��A���R

��� 11��

(20)

34

Page 36: Fiscal Austerity in Emerging Market Economies · Figure 2. Fiscal De–cit as % of GDP in India. Figure 2, which depicts the Indian case, also shows a central –scal de–cit/GDP

yielding

�� =�(1� �)

(1� �) �C + � �G

(1� �w)�� �W =1� �� '1 � '2

1� �H

�� ='2

�B(1� � �RP )�D =

'1(��� � �� �RG)

�G+ (1� �RP ) �B = �W �H + ( �R� �) �K � �C

�W =(1� �)#1

(1� � + � �RP )= #2

Then letting #3 = 1� �� '1 � '2

�C =���� � �G

1� �

�H =(1� �w)#2��� #3(1� �w)#2��

�B =(1� � �RP )

'2��

�D =(1� � �RG)

'1��

#6��2 � #5�� + #4 = 0

�� =#5 �

p#25 � 4#4#62#6

#4 = �R#2(1� �)'2#3 + (1� �)'2( �R� �)�#1#3 + �R#2�(1� �w)(1� �)'2

#5 =

24 �R#2(1� �)'2#2(1� �w) + (1� �)'2( �R� �)�#1(1� �w)#2+ �R#2(1� �w)'2� �G� �R#2(1� �w)(1� �)'2 �G

35#6 = �R#2(1� �w)(1� �)(1� �RP )(1� � �RP ):

35