19
Bconomic Review Federal Reserve Ran.k of San. Fran.cisco Fall 1989 Number 4 Ronald H. Schmidt John P. Judd and Bharat Trehan James A. Wilcox Natural Resources and Regional Growth Unemployment-Rate Dynamics: Aggregate-Demand and -Supply Interactions Liquidity Constraints on Consumption: The Real Effects of "Real" Lending Policies

Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

BconomicReviewFederal Reserve Ran.kof San. Fran.cisco

Fall 1989 Number 4

Ronald H. Schmidt

John P. Judd andBharat Trehan

James A. Wilcox

Natural Resources and Regional Growth

Unemployment-Rate Dynamics:Aggregate-Demand and-Supply Interactions

Liquidity Constraints on Consumption:The Real Effects of "Real" Lending Policies

Page 2: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

Unemployment-Rate Dynamics:Aggregate-Demand and -Supply Interactions

John P. Judd and Bharat Trehan

Vice President and Associate Director of Research, andSenior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of San Fran­cisco. Research assistance was provided by Conrad Gann.We wish to thank the members of the editorial committee,Fred Furlong, Adrian Throop, and Carl Walsh, for valuablecomments on earlier drafts of this paper.

The implications for monetary policy of movements inthe unemployment rate depend upon the nature of theunderlying disturbances that caused those movements.Positive aggregate-demand shocks cause the unemploy­ment rate to fall as inflationary pressures build, whereaspositive aggregate-supply shocks are likely to lead to afallin both the unemployment rate and inflation. In this paper,we employ a recently developed modeling technique todisentangle the effects of aggregate-demand and -supplyshocks on the unemployment rate. The technique is agnos­tic about alternative macroeconomic theories, derivingidentifying restrictions from relatively uncontroversiallong-run, or steady state, relationships.

20

The unemployment rate often plays an important role inmonetary-policy deliberations, not only because policymakers are concerned about unemployment itself, but alsobecause it is viewed as an important indicator of futureinflation. For example, when the unemployment rate de­clined rapidly to a relatively low level in recent years,a number of Federal Reserve officials became concernedthat the economy was developing dangerous inflationarypressures.'

One problem in evaluating the policy implications ofmovements in the unemployment rate (as well as those ofother macroeconomic variables) is that these implicationsoften depend on one's assumptions about the structure ofthe economy. Currently there is little agreement amongeconomists concerning the appropriate paradigm; theKeynesian (both the traditional and "new" versions), real­business-cycle, and monetary-misperceptions paradigmsall have significant followings among different groups ofmacroeconomists.?

These paradigms differ in the emphasis they placeon aggregate-demand versus aggregate-supply shocks ininfluencing economic activity and labor-market condi­tions. Real-business-cycle models ascribe a larger role toaggregate-supply shocks, whereas Keynesian and mone­tary-misperceptions models place greater weight on aggre­gate-demand shocks. This distinction between demandand supply factors is important because the appropriatemonetary-policy response (or lack thereof) to unemploy­ment rate movements depends on the nature of the underly­ing disturbance. Positive aggregate-demand shocks causethe unemployment rate to fall as inflationary pressuresbuild, and such developments could make a tightening ofmonetary policy appropriate. By contrast, positive aggre­gate-supply shocks are likely to lead to a fall in both theunemployment rate and the rate of inflation. Under thesecircumstances, a tighter monetary policy most likelywould be inappropriate.

In this paper, we employ a recently developed modelingtechnique to disentangle the effects of aggregate-demandand -supply shocks on the unemployment rate (as well ason other important macroeconomic variables.) The tech­nique is agnostic about alternative theories, derivingidentifying restrictions from relatively uncontroversial

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 3: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

assumptions about long-run, or steady-state, relationships.Given the current lack of agreement about macroeconomictheory, such models have the advantage that they eschewover-identifying restrictions, and choose not to go beyondthe minimum number of restrictions necessary to achieveidentification.

Our empirical results suggest that for very short hori­zons of a few quarters, shocks to aggregate demand ac­count for nearly all of the variance of unemployment rateforecast errors. However, at longer horizons of twelvequarters and more, aggregate-supply shocks playa signifi­cant role. Moreover, we find that movements in the unem­ployment rate that are caused by supply shocks (as definedby our model) are positively correlated with inflation,whereas those associated with demand shocks are nega­tively correlated with inflation. Thus, decomposing the

sources of unemployment rate movements into demandversus supply shocks can be important in designing effec­tive monetary policy.

The paper is organized as follows. Section I reviews therelevant literature on macroeconomic modeling and dis­cusses the rationale for the approach taken in this paper.Section II sets out the theoretical specification of themodel. In Section III, we discuss econometric issues thatarise .in estimating the model and the results of thisestimation, as well as their implications for the sources ofvariation in important macroeconomic variables, includ­ing the unemployment rate. Also in this section we analyzethe historical evolution of the unemployment rate and therelationship between inflation and the aggregate-demandand -supply components of the unemployment rate. Policyimplications and conclusions are discussed in Section IV.

I. Methodological Considerations andLiterature ReviewAdherents of the main alternative macroeconomic theo­

ries-Keynesian, real-business-cycle, and monetary mis­perceptions-have very different views about the structureof the economy. A major source of controversy concernsthe relative importance of demand and supply shocks. TheKeynesian and monetary-misperceptions theories stressthe role played by aggregate-demand shocks in inducingshort-run movements around long-run trends which areindependent of those shocks. In contrast, real-business­cycle theories emphasize the role played by technology andlabor-supply shocks in producing short-run fluctuations inoutput around changing equilibrium values which arethemselves determined by factors traditionally emphasizedin neo-classical growth models.

These alternative macroeconomic theories have dif­ferent implications for how monetary policy should beconducted. For example, since Keynesians believe thatunemployment rate movements mainly are induced byaggregate-demand factors, inflation will rise (fall) whenthe measured unemployment rate goes below (above) itsnatural rate. Assuming the monetary authority knows thenatural rate of unemployment, Keynesians suggest that theobserved rate of unemployment relative to its natural ratecan be a major source of information in setting policies tocontrol inflation.

In contrast, real-business-cycle theorists believe thataggregate-supply shocks are the predominant sources ofchange in macroeconomic variables. Under these circum­stances, policy mistakes would be made if the central bankinterpreted the unemployment rate as an indicator ofaggregate-demand pressures. Further, existing real-busi­ness-cycle models generally have modeled business cycles

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

as Pareto-optimal responses to exogenous shocks. Thus, inthese models, there is no role for any type of macro­economic policy aimed at stabilizing the economy.

Macroeconomists have not been able to agree on whichtheory (or combination of theories) most accurately de­scribes the economy. Each theory implies a different set ofidentifying restrictions. Thus, a certain degree of agnosti­cism is warranted in selecting identifying restrictions. Thisagnostic approach increasingly has shown up in macro­economic research in recent years. The use of vectorautoregressions appears to reflect this view. No identifyingrestrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts.Of course, if these forecasts are to be interpreted in termsof economic theory, identifying restrictions must be added.In early applications, these took the form of assuming aspecific recursive structure for the contemporaneous cor­relations in the data.3,4

The Blanchard-Quah Model

Recently, Blanchard and Quah (1989) specified a smallvector autoregression of the macroeconomy that achievesidentification by imposing relatively uncontroversial con­straints on steady-state conditions, thereby avoiding therestrictions associated with alternative theories of thebusiness cycle. Moreover, their model is exactly identified,and thus avoids over-identifying restrictions that may raisetheoretical controversy. Blanchard and Quah (BQ) assumethat supply shocks (those emphasized in real businesscycle models) can have permanent effects on the level ofreal activity, while demand shocks (those emphasized by

21

Page 4: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

where (J~ is the (observed) variance of y, (J~ is thevarianceof u, (Jy" u, is the contemporaneous covariance of u andy,and the othervariances are defined similarly.

So far, there are five conditions from which we mustobtain six coefficients. One more restriction is needed toidentify the model. The traditional approach has been toimpose a recursive structure on the contemporaneouscorrelations in the data (Sims [1980]). For example, onemight assume thatthecoefficient a j = 0,. thatis, shocks tothe unemployment rate do not have a contemporaneous

effect ontherateofgrowth ofoutput. Suchanassumption,however, would be theoretically controversial.

BQ avoid having to assume contemporaneous causalorderings by relying on long-run, or steady-state, restric­tions. Specifically, they assume that v has no long-runeffect on output; that is,

b, + cj = O. (3f)

Thisrestriction, together with the conventional restric­tions onvariances andcovariances, is sufficient to identifythe unobserved shocks from observations ony and u. Therestriction also leads to a straightforward interpretation oftheunderlying structural disturbances: v canbeinterpretedas an aggregate-demand shock since it can have no long­runeffect ony, while e canbeinterpreted asa supply shocksince it is permitted permanently to affect y. In otherwords, the permanent level of real GNP is determined byrealfactors. Although aggregate-demand shocks cancausereal GNP to deviate from this level, it cannot affect thepermanent level itself. By construction, neither demandnorsupply shocks have a permanent impact on the unem­ployment rate.

Using thismethod, BQ found thatdemand disturbanceshada hump-shaped effect onthetimepathofoutput, whilesupply shocks had an effect that increased gradually overtime. They alsofound thatdemand disturbances accountedfor only 35% of the variance of unpredictable changes inreal output in the contemporaneous quarter, leaving 65%for supply disturbances, while demand accounted for 13%at a horizon of eight quarters.> In contrast, demand dis­turbances accounted for 100% of the variance of unpre­dieted changes in the unemployment rate in the currentquarter, and for 50% at an horizon of eight quarters.

The Shapiro-Watson Model

Oneproblem withBQ's analysis is thatit allows foronlytwo underlying disturbances to the economy. If, as seemsplausible, theeconomy isaffected by more than onekindofsupply (or demand) shock, their procedure will tend toconfound the effects of these different shocks. Based onthis reasoning, Shapiro and Watson (1988) useda systemthat comprised real GNP, total labor hours, inflation andtherealinterest rate." Thissetofvariables allowed them toaccount for four different disturbances: two to aggregatesupply, whieh they identified as shocks to laborsupply andtechnology, and two to aggregate demand, which theyreferred to as IS and LM shocks, but did not identifyseparately.

Shapiro andWatson (SW) found thataggregate-demandshocks had a smallerimpact on real output than BQ did.?

(1)

(2)

(3a)

(3b)

(3c)

(3d)

(3e)

Yt = a.e, + b», + CjVt_ j

Ut = a2et + b2vt + C2Vt-j

(J =cby, , u,_) j 2

(j =bcy,_) , u, l 2

the Keynesian and monetary-misperceptions models) canhave only temporary effects. These assumptions are con­sistent with each of the three main macro paradigms.Importantly, they are sufficient to identify certain typesof VARs incorporating important macroeconomic timeseries.

Since theBQ approach is usedin thispaper, albeit on alarger model, it is useful to see how theirmethod works.(A detailed discussion of theirmethod of identification isprovided in Appendix A.) BQ specify a VAR with twovariables: therateof growth of realGNP(Y), andthe levelof the unemployment rate (u). Two types of (unobserved)structural disturbances, v ande, areassumed toaffect thesevariables. (As discussed below, we follow BQ in iden­tifying these disturbances with aggregate-demand andaggregate-supply disturbances.) Equations (1) and (2) aremoving average representations ofy andu interms ofthesetwo disturbances. For simplicity here, we introduce dy­namics intotheBQmodel by including only onelagofv ineachequation, although thefullBQmodel contains severallags.

In order to study the dynamics of this system, it is firstnecessary to obtain estimates of thevarious coefficients inequations (1) and (2). This requires placing certain restric­tions on e and v. In traditional fashion, BQ assume that eand v are uncorrelated with each other and have unitvariance. Inaddition, e andv arealsoserially uncorrelated.Given therepresentations in (1)and(2), these assumptionsimply the following identifying restrictions:

(J~=a]+b]+c]

(J~=a~+~+c~

(Jy" u, = aja2 + bjb2 + CjC2

22 Economic Review / Fall1989

Page 5: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

Specifically, aggregate-demand shocks accounted for just28% of the variance of the output forecast error in thecontemporaneous quarter, and 20% at an eight-quarterhorizon. In addition, they found that labor supply shocksalone accounted for about 45% of the variance of unpre-

dieted changes in output in the contemporaneous quarter.Thesefindings, as wellas those of BQ, sharply contradictthe Keynesian and monetary-misperceptions views thattrend and cycle are neatly separable, with demand shocksplaying the dominant role over the business cycle.

II. Model Specification and Identification

wheres* is the logof the steady-state value of laborsupplyand e* represents (unobserved) technology. Thelaborsup­ply and technology shocks, !J.s and !J.e , are uncorrelated,and the lag polynomials f3s (L) and W(L) describe thetransitory movements in s* and e* as they move to newpermanent levels.

The Underlying Model

We begin by assuming that the production technologycan be described by a neo-classical growthmodel, so thatthe long-run level of output is determined by the capitalstock and labor supply? The capital stock term can beeliminated by assuming a Cobb-Douglas production func­tion and a constantsteady-state capital-output ratio. Thus,the steady-state level of output can be expressed as afunction of the steady-state levels of labor supply andtechnology.

The levels of labor supply and technology may bepermanently affected by labor-supply and technologyshocks, respectively. The evolution of these variables isdescribed by

below, the results obtained when population is used as ameasure of labor supply are much more plausible. Thus,given this paper's policy-driven focus on the unemploy­ment rate, we have opted for working-age population.

We also extend the BQ and SW models by explicitlyincorporating a foreign variable to identify the effects ofshocks originating abroad. Giventhe growing importanceof international trade and capital flows to the U.S. econ­omy, it is desirable to incorporate the independent effectsof shocks from abroad. While inclusion of the exchangerate appears to be an obvious choice, the move fromfixed­to floating-exchange rates in the early 1970s implies achange in the exchange-rate process that precludes sensi­ble estimation results over our 1954-88 period. Instead,we includeas a foreign variable the ratio of real exports toreal imports.

In this section,wepresentthe specification of themodelestimatedin this paper. We begin with a discussion of thevariables included in the model, followed by a discussionof the equations that constitute the model, and how weachieve identification.

The model includes five variables: the unemploymentrate, real GNP, a nominal rate of interest, a measure oflabor supply, and a variable that measures foreign trade.Thesevariables providebroadcoverage of important typesof activity in the economy, and thus should capture theeconomic relationships that are important in determiningthe behavior of the unemployment rate. Movements in theunemployment rate and the interest rate are likely to behighlycorrelated with two types of underlying aggregate­demand shocks, which can be thought of as being asso­ciated withthe IS and LM curves of textbook macroeco­nomic theory. The interest rate should captureshocks bothto inflation expectations and real interest rates, whilethe unemployment rate should reflect aggregate-demandshocks as theyaffectthe level of economic activity. Follow­ing previous research, we assume that movements in realGNP are correlated with technology shocks, once westandardize for aggregate-demand shocks. 8

Weuse working-age population as our measure of laborsupply. This variable is clearly exogenous, and thereforeguards against the possibility of confounding labor de­mand and supply. However, it has the disadvantage ofomitting the effects on labor supply of changes in par­ticipation rates and average hours worked. One obviousalternative would be to follow SW andusetotallaborhoursas the labor-supply variable. However, our empirical evi­dence suggests that using labor hours to measure supplycausesa seriousbias; weare unablecompletely to separatethe demand-induced changes in labor hours from thoseinduced by labor supply. Specifically, when we includelabor hours in our model, we find that a positive labor­supply shock leads to a large, sustained decline in theunemployment rate, an outcome that suggests a confusionbetween labor supply and demand. Such confusion couldhave a profound effect on conclusions concerning therelative importance of supplyand demand disturbances inmacroeconomic time series. By contrast, as discussed

s*= O'.s + s* + Qs (L) liSt t-1 I-' rrt

e*= O'.e + e* + Qe (L) liet t-1 I-' rrt

(4)

(5)

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 23

Page 6: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

Labor supply is not affected, either in the short or longrun, by any of the other variables in the system. Thisassumption follows from our choice of working-age popu­lation to represent the influences oflabor supply, and yieldsfour of the ten restrictions we need to identify the model. 10

Both labor-supply and technology shocks can causeshort-run movements in output as the level of outputadjusts to a new steady-state value. Short-run movementsin output also can be the result of aggregate-demandshocks. However, the two types of aggregate-demandshocks are permitted to have only temporary effects on thelevel of output. These assumptions yield two more identi­fying restrictions. Foreign shocks cause output to deviatetemporarily from its steady-state value, but are not per­mitted to have a long-run effect on output. 11This assump­tion yields one more identifying restriction.

These considerations suggest the following equationsfor the relationship between observed and equilibriumvalues:

St = si + XS (L) (I-Li) (6)

Yt = Y;+ XY (L) (l-1i, I-1T, f.1f, 1-1:1,1-1:') (7)

where XS(L) and XY(L) are vectors of lag polynomials (inthe indicated variables) that allow for temporary deviationsfrom steady-state levels. Thus, this specification allows theactual level of output to deviate from the level implied bythe Cobb-Douglas production function in the short run. Asdiscussed above, y* itself is a function of s* and e*. f.1fdenotes shocks originating abroad, while 1-1~1 and 1-L~2 arethe domestic demand shocks.

Statistical tests suggest that output and labor supply areboth nonstationary, and thus we take first differences ofequations (6) and (7) (see Appendix B). Substitutingequations (4) and (5) into the results yields:

St - St-I = {XS + W (L) (I-LO + (1-L)XS (L) (I-Li) (8)

Yt Yt-I = {XY + rY' (L) (l-1i, I-LT)+ (1- L)XY (L) (I-Li, I-LT, f.1f, 1-1:1, 1-1:2) (9)

Consider now the specification of the foreign variable.In addition to disturbances originating abroad, this vari­able is affected by all the domestic shocks. However, thetwo aggregate-demand shocks are permitted to affect theforeign variable only temporarily.'? These assumptionsyield two more identifying restrictions. Weassume that thelong-run evolution of the foreign variable can be describedin the same wayas output, so it is included in the model in aform similar to (8) and (9). Thus,

it - h-I = at + [3f (L) (1-1:, I-LT, f.1f)+ (1- L)x! (L)(I-1:, I-LT, f.1f, 1-L:1, 1-L:2)(10)

24

Given that the interest rate appears to be non-stationary(see Appendix B), we specify its equation in differencedform:

. - i-Xi (L) (s e .. f II d 1 II d 2) (11)It t r-L - , f.L t , f.Lt, t"'t' I""t ' I""t

Thus, all the disturbances in the model can have a perma­nent effect on the nominal interest rate.

There is some ambiguity about how the unemploymentrate should be included in the model. On the one hand,there. is a large body of theoretical work in macroeco­nomics to suggest that the unemployment rate is station­ary.13 Tests carried out over long sample periods tend toconfirm this. 14 On the other hand, as shown in AppendixB, unit root tests suggest that the unemployment rate isnon-stationary over shorter sample periods.

This inability to reject nonstationarity in the unemploy­ment rate over the post-war period poses a problem.Different researchers have dealt with this problem indifferent ways. BQ for instance, present results both for thecase where the unemployment rate is assumed to bestationary and where it contains a deterministic trend.Unfortunately, removal of a linear trend is not sufficient tomake the unemployment rate stationary. Evans (1989)allows for an increase in the mean of the unemploymentrate beginning in 1974. As indicated in Appendix B,allowing for this shift in the mean appears to make theunemployment rate stationary.

Acceptance of this "solution" to the nonstationarityproblem implicitly assumes the existence of some well­defined, exogenous change in the economy that is associ­ated with a change in the mean unemployment rate. Whilesome economists have pointed to the change in participa­tion rates of women and teenagers in the labor force overthis period, the issue is by no means resolved. 15 Accord­ingly, we estimated two alternative versions of the model,one that allows the mean unemployment rate to change in1974, and one that holds it fixed over the entire 1954-88period. The results in the two cases are similar, and sowe present only those from the specification that allows fora mean shift. (However, we do point out instances belowin which the results from the two specifications differmaterially.)

Thus, the complete model comprises equations (8)-(11),plus

f.Lt = {XU + XU (L) (f.L:, I-1T, 1JIr, 1-L:1, f.L:2) (12)

where {XU is allowed to shift in 1974Ql. Thus, the unem­ployment rate is affected by all the disturbances in themodel. However, because it is entered as a level, none ofthese disturbances has a permanent effect on it.

In summary, we have identified the model by restricting

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 7: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

certain long-run coefficients to equal zero, and by usingworking-age population, which is strictly exogenous, forour labor-supply variable. As discussed in Appendix A, werequire ten identifying restrictions to separate the influ­ences of each of the five shocks-two domestic demand,two domestic supply, and one foreign-on all the variablesin the system. The assumption that population is ex­ogenous yields four identifying restrictions. Four addi­tional restrictions come from the assumption that the two

aggregate-demand shocks do not have long-run effects onoutput and the foreign variable. One more restrictioncomes from the specification that the foreign shock has nolong-run effect on U.S. output. This gives us a total of ninerestrictions. Following SW, we choose not to identify thetwo aggregate-demand shocks separately. In this way, weare able to eliminate the need for a potentially controver­sial tenth restriction.

HI. Estimation and Empirical Results

In this section we describe the estimation technique andpresent our results. The impulse response functions andthe variance decompositions presented below provide in­formation about the structure of the economy as estimatedby the model. We use this information to analyze thefactors that have contributed to the changes in the unem­ployment rate that occurred over the period from 1955 to1988. Finally, at the end of this section, we show correla­tions between our measures of the aggregate-demand andaggregate-supply components of the unemployment rateand the rate of inflation.

Our model includes the log of the unemployment rateand the first differences of the logs of all other variables.Because population is exogenous, we use ordinary leastsquares to estimate a regression of population growth onsix of its own lags. (A lag-length of six is used in all theequations in the model.)

To illustrate the technique used to estimate the remain­ing equations, we use the real GNP equation. 16 Real GNPis regressed on lags of all the variables in the system pluscontemporaneous values of population, the interest rate,the unemployment rate, and the foreign trade variable. Weimpose the restriction that neither the aggregate-demandshocks nor the foreign shocks has a permanent impact onthe level of GNP by taking the difference of the relevantright-hand-side variables one more time and reducing thelag length by one. Thus the first difference of real GNP isregressed on first differences of population, the seconddifferences of the foreign variable and interest rates, andthe first difference of the unemployment rate (in addition tolags of first differences of real GNP). Two-stage least­squares is used to estimate the equation because it containscontemporaneous values of the three endogenous variables(that is, of interest rates, unemployment, and the foreignvariable). The contemporaneous value of population andlagged values of all variables in the model are used asinstruments.

The remaining equations are estimated in a similar man-

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

nero Following our discussion above, domestic aggregate­demand variables are restricted to have only a temporaryimpact on the foreign variable, while no such restriction isplaced on the domestic supply variables. No restrictionsare placed on the equations for the interest rate and theunemployment rate. As mentioned above, the inclusion ofthe level of the unemployment rate in the model impliesthat no shock to the system has a permanent impact on thatrate.

The Estimated Structure of the Model

Exhibit IA shows the impulse response functions fromthe model. The first two columns of the exhibit show theresponse of the model's four endogenous variables todomestic shocks, while the third column shows the effectsof shocks originating abroad. As discussed above, weidentify labor-supply and technology shocks separately,but we do not disentangle the two underlying demandshocks. Thus, the impulse response functions in the secondcolumn of the exhibit represent responses to a linearcombination of the demand shocks.

Positive aggregate-demand shocks reduce unemploy­ment and raise output and interest rates. By construction,the effects on the unemployment rate and GNP are tempo­rary. The effects of aggregate-demand shocks on the unem­ployment rate die out in about 12 quarters, while those onoutput last eight to 10 quarters. At first, the ratio of U.S.exports to imports reacts negatively to domestic demandshocks; that is, higher domestic demand leads to a rise inimports relative to exports. The impulse response functionthen cycles, becoming positive from five to twelve quar­ters, at which time the effect dampens out.

Positive shocks to technology reduce the unemploymentrate. This effect lasts for about 24 quarters before substan­tially dying out. I? Shocks to labor supply have insignifi­cant effects on the unemployment rate, causing it to cyclearound its original level. Positive shocks to labor supply

25

Page 8: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

ExhibitlA1mpul seRes.ponse.F unet ion s

Domestic Supply Shocks

Labor Supply

Responses of:

Unemployment Rate

31

-1

-3-5-7

-9

- 11 -i-t'''"T''''I""'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''"T''''I""''''''-'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''"T"'T'"14 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Technology

Labor Supply

Real GNP

1.3

1.1

.9

.7

.5

.3

.1

-. 1 -i-t'''"T''''I""'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''"T''''I""''''''-'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''I''''T''''I""T'"'I''"'14 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Technology

Labor Supply

Interest Rate

191715131 1

97531

-1- 3 ....J.of..,..,..'I""'r"'I...,..,......,-,...,....,"T""I"~....,....,....,..,...,..,....I""T""I"""T""I"".,..,...,

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Technology

Labor Supply

4

3

2

1

o~-I-J.~::::============--

-1

- 2 -i-t'''"T''''I""'''''''''1''''''l''"I''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''0''T'''''''''''''''''''''Foreign Variable26

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 9: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

ExhibitlA (conttnued)

Domestic Demand Foreign ShocksShocks

31

-1-3...5

-7 -7-9 -9

-11 -114 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

1.3 1.31.1 1.1

.9 .9

.7 .7

.5 .5

.3 .3

. 1 .1-.1 -.1

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

19 1917 1715 1513 131 1 1 1

9 97 75 53 31 1

-1 -1-3 -3

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

4 4

3 3

2 2

1 1

0 0

-1 -1

-2 -24 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

FederalReserve Bank of San Francisco 27

Page 10: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

and technology permanently raiseoutput, withtheeffectoflabor-supply shocks buildingup somewhat moregraduallythan the effect of technology shocks. Positivi shocks tothese two variables also permanently raise the level ofinterest rates, and the ratio of exports to imports.

Positive foreign shocks temporarily raise output andlower the unemployment rate, although the latter effectsare relatively small. These shocks also permanently raisethe interest rate.

Exhibit IB presents the associatedvariance decomposi­tions, which show the relative importance of the variouskindsof shocksin explaining theerrors made in predictingthe model's variables. At forecast horizons of up tofour quarters, variation in the unemployment rate hasbeendominated by aggregate-demand shocks. Aggregate­supply shocks begin to playa larger role as the forecast ho­rizon lengthens, reaching 15 percent at eight quarters and25 percent at 60 quarters. These results suggest that

28 Economic Review ! Fall 1989

Page 11: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

unemployment has been substantially affected both byaggregate-demand-and -supply shocks duringthepost-warperiod.

Aggregate..demand shocks arethemostimportant factorin.explaining variation in real GNP in the short run(contemporaneously and at forecast horizons of one andtwo quarters), accounting for 50 to 55 percent of thevariation. Technology shocks also are quite important atthese shortlags, accounting for from 28 to 35 percent. Astheforecast horizonlengthens, technology shocks begintodominate, as theseshocks arepermanent, while aggregate­demand. shocks are transitory. By the time the lags reachtwo years, technology shocks dominate demand shocks,with the former factor accounting for 61 percent of thevariation and the latter accounting for only 18 percent.Labor-supply shocks beginto become important only aftertwo years. At the frequency of the average business cycle,ourresultsshow a largerrolefordemand shocks relative tosupply shocks than does earlier research.

Interest rate variation is dominated at all forecast hori­zons bydomestic demand shocks, although foreign shockshave a noticeable effect in the long run. Domestic supplyshocks play onlya small role, except at the very long lags.At a lag of 60 quarters, labor supply accounts for 22percent of the variation in the interest rate, while at shorterlags, the role of this variable is quite small (under fivepercent).

Theforeign variable largely isexogenous withrespect tothe otherfour variables in the model-that is, it is deter­mined mainly by its own past behavior-at forecast hori­zons of up to 12 quarters. At long lags, however, laborsupply plays a significant role in the error variance of theforeign variable, reaching 43 percent at 60quarters. Tech­nology and domestic aggregate demand play only smallroles at all forecast horizons.

Theeffects of the foreign variable on theU.S. economyare relatively modest, as would be expected from therelatively small, albeitgrowing, roleof foreign trade in theU.S. economy. Foreign shocks playa significant role inU.S. real GNP at short lags, accounting for 13 percent ofthe contemporaneous variation and then declining in im­portance as the lag lengthens. Foreign shocks also haveplayed a significant role in U.S. interestrate movements,accounting for 10 to 12 percent of the variation in thatvariable at forecast horizons in the range of two to 12quarters.

Federal Reserve Bank of SanFrancisco

Historical Analysis

We how use our estimated structure to carry out twodifferent exercises thatexamine the historical evolution ofthellllemployment rate. First,to understand thefactors thatbave'eaused movements in theunemployment rateoverthecourseofthebusiness cycle, we lookat the sources of ourmodel'sforecast errorsat a forecast horizon of threeyears.

The results of this exercise are shown in Exhibit II. Byconstruction, any error in predicting the unemploymentratehastobe theresultof theunpredicted demand, supply,and/orforeign shocks thattookplacewithin thethree-yearforecasthorizon. We obtain the contribution of each kindof disturbance to the forecast error for any particularquarter by multiplying the coefficients in the impulseresponse functions by the appropriate historical shocks asmeasured by the model.

The•. top panel of Exhibit II shows the total error inpredicting the unemployment rate twelve quarters aheadovertheperiodfrom 1955 to 1988. At thisforecast horizon,themajorerrorsareclosely associated withbusiness cycleswings. The four panels below show the contributions to

Exhibit IIHistorical Analysis: Decomposition

of 12-0uarter-Ahead Forecast Errorsfor Unemployment Rate

TotalErrors

0.0

LaborSupply

Foreign

52 56 60 64 68 72 76 80 84 88

29

Page 12: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

theseforecast errors made bytheindicated shocks. Shadedareasrepresent business cycledownturns.

Themost strikingJeature of this analysis is that aggre­ga.te-<iemand shocks have played by far the largest role inunemployment. rate•movements over the course of thebusiness cycle inthe postwar period. Although technologyshocks. areimportant for the average quarterly variabilityof the unemployment rate over the whole sample, aggre­gate-demand shocks appear to be more closely related tocyclicalswings in the unemployment rate.

TechnologyshocksdO, however, contribute significantlyto thelonger-run swings in the forecast errors. Forexam­pie, the well-known productivity surge in the 1960s ispicked. •up in•• ouranalysis as a succession of positivetieC~~ysbocks that.led to a lower-than-predicted unem­ployment rate over most of the decade. Similarly theslowdowninpr()ductivity growth in theearly to mid1970sis pickedupasa succession ofnegative technology shocks.

The 1980s have been marked by large shocks both toaggregate demand and to technology. Not surprisingly,the second panel of Exhibit II shows large, negativeaggregate-demand shocks (which pushed up the unem­ployment rate) during theperiod from 1980 to 1982, whenthe Federal Reserve oriented monetary policy around themonetary aggregates tocombat thesurge in inflation in thelate 1970s and early 1980s.

Aggregate-demand shocks then turned positive (thuspushing down theunemployment rate)in 1983 asmonetarypolicy became more accommodative in the face of a con­tinuing recession and falling inflation. In addition, fiscalpolicy became highly expansionary from 1983 through

1986, with the high-employment deficitjumping sharplyin 1983 and reaching a peak in mid 1986. From1986through 1988, aggregate demand shocks were relativelysmall, although on average were slightlynegative.

Technology shocks also have been important factors inunemployment rate movements in the1980s.1n fact,theywere about as important as aggregate-demand shocks inraising theunemployment rate. Thiseffectwas substantialby historical standards and lasted from early1980 throughmid 1984. Technology shocks also accounted for a goodpart of the unemployment rate decline-in 1986 and1987,when the unemployment rate moved into a range thatcontributed to the Federal Reserve's concern about futureinflation.

What might beresponsible forthispatternof technologyshocks? Any suggestions would be highly speculative.lfSeveral large studies on thesources of productivity changein the U.S., for example, have failed to come up withspecific explanations for a substantial portion of thatchange.'? Nonetheless, we note that the timing of thenegative technology shocks in theearly1970s andtheearly1980s is close to the two oil price shocks, suggesting thatthis factor may have been important. However, as notedelsewhere, inclusion of oil prices causes problems inexplaining developments after 1985 (see footnote 6).

Unemployment and Inflation

We tum now to the second exercise of our historicalanalysis, namely a decomposition of the unemploymentrate into its aggregate-demand and -supply components,and a comparison of these components with the inflation

Percent1 1

9

7

5

Exhibit IIIThe Unemployment Rate and its

Supply-Induced Component

UnemploymentRate

62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88

*Includes the estimatedmean level of the unemployment rate to allowfor comparisonwith the actual unemployment rate.

Economic Review t Fall1989

Page 13: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

rate. In Exhibit III, theactual unemployment rate isplottedagainst the mean unemployment rate plus thecontributionofaggregat~-supply factors. To obtain this rate, we sub­tractedfromthe unemployment rate both the effects ofaggr~gate-d~mand-induced changes and the effects ofshocks originating abroad.t? The difference between thetwo series plotted in Exhibit III represents the effects ofaggregate-demand. pressures and foreign shocks in thelabor market. (Of the two, the latter are not very impor­tant.)iDemandpressures apparently have reduced theunell1ploymentrate duringmostof the 1965-1981 period,implying the possibility of an inflationary bias in policy.After 1981, these pressures have been more balanced,sometimes positive and sometimes negative.

According to economic theory, there should be a nega­tivecorrelation between our measure of the aggregate­demand component of the unemployment rate and therateQfinflation relative to inflation expectations, if our rneas­ur~jsvalid. This correlation arises in both the KeynesianPhiUipsicurveand the Lucas-Barro, or monetary-misper­ceptions,.· Phillips curve." In the former, an aggregate­demandshockthat reduces theunemployment rate leads tohigh~r inflation. In the latter, a positive aggregate-demandshock that raises inflation above inflation expectations(thatis,createsan inflation surprise) willleadtoa decreaseintheun~mployment rate.

The expected negative correlation is shown in the toppanel.of Exhibit IV. (We have used annual averages in

Exhibit tVInflation and Unemployment

2

4

6

8

Percent

4

3

2

1

o-1

-2

-3

o .........--r-....-r-.,...,...,..,....,...,........,-.-r-r-,...,...,....,..,...,.-r"'l-.-....-r-.,...,.....-+- 4

Percent

10

62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88

Percent10

8

6

4

2

, Aggregate­SupplyComponent ______

Percent4

3

2

1

o

-1

o """"""""''''''''''''''''''''''''''-'-I'''"''I"".,....,..,...,.....,...,,...,........,....,-,....,...,-.-,....,...,....,.-!-- 262 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 31

Page 14: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

order to reduce the random fluctuations in the data.) Notethat we plot actual inflation rather than the differencebetween actual and expected inflation. In the followingdiscussion, we implicitly assume a positive correlationbetween actual and unexpected inflation. The top panel ofthe exhibit reveals that as the aggregate-demand compo­nent of the unemployment rate fell below zero in mid-1960through 1980, the inflation rate rose, reaching a peak in1981. Since then, the aggregate-demand component hasfluctuated around zero, and inflation has fallen.

The bottom panel of Exhibit IV plots the aggregate­supply component of the unemployment rate and the rateof inflation. As expected, these two series are positivelycorrelated. When there is a positive technology shock, forexample, inflation falls as prices adjust to a new level, andat the same time the unemployment rate falls as firms'demand for labor rises.

The correlations shown visually in Exhibit IV are pre­sented more rigorously in the first two columns of ExhibitV. The first column presents cross correlations betweenpast, present, and future values of inflation, on the onehand, and the aggregate-demand component of the unem­ployment rate, on the other. The correlations between theaggregate-demand component of the unemployment rateand inflation are strongly negative, suggesting that ourmeasure of aggregate-demand pressure is functioning asexpected.

The second column of the exhibit presents the correla­tions between our measure of the aggregate-supply com­ponent of the unemployment rate and past, present, andfuture rates of inflation. These correlations are uniformlypositive, which appears to validate our concept of theaggregate-supply component of unemployment.

In the third column, we show cross-correlations be­tween the unemployment rate minus its mean rate with pastand future values of the inflation rate. The correlationsbetween the aggregate-demand component of the unem­ployment rate and future inflation are noticeably strongerthan those between the (mean-adjusted) unemploymentrate and future inflation. Likewise, the positive relation­ship between past inflation and our measure of the supply­induced changes in the unemployment rate is noticeablystronger than that between past inflation and the unemploy­ment rate.

Notice also that the correlations between past values ofinflation and the unemployment rate are positive. Thus, theraw data tend to support the Keynesian Phillips curve,which has causation running from unemployment to futureinflation, and refutes the monetary-misperceptions Phil­lips curve. The latter relationship implies that there should

32

be a negative correlation between past inflation surprisesand unemployment rates, rather than the positive correla­tion shown in column three. However, the first column ofthe table shows that once the aggregate-supply shocks arestripped away, both directions of causation are supported.There is a negative correlation between past inflationand aggregate-demand-induced unemployment (monetarymisperceptions) and also between future inflation andunemployment (Keynesian).

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 15: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

IV. Policy Implications and Conclusions

The aim of this paper has been to estimate the relative unemployment rate in order to arrive at an estimate ofimportance of different kinds of disturbances in causing future inflation. Since movements in the unemploymentmovements in the unemployment rate. Towardthatend, we rate may be the result of either demand or supply factors,have attempted to keep our model as free as possible of the looking at the level of the unemployment rate alone (or atcontroversial identifying restrictions that are inherent in theunemployment rate relative to some fixed value)can bethe various competing paradigms of the macroeconomy. misleading in particular episodes; instead, it is necessaryWe find that on average both demand and supply shocks first-to determine the relative importance of aggregate-have been important in explaining unemployment rate demand and -supply forces.movements in the postwar period. While demand shocks With this in mind, we consider what the model tells usarerelatively more important in causing cyclical swings in about the conditions that prevailed in 1988 (the last year ofthe unemployment rate, supply shocks playa significant our sample period). As Exhibit III indicates, aggregaterole in inducing longer-term movements. Our finding that demand was mildly stimulatory. The unemployment ratepositive supply shocks are correlated with falling unem- averaged5.5 percent over the year. In the absence of anyployment in subsequent periods casts doubt on Phillips- demand shocks, it would have averaged 5.8 percent. Thecurve analyses, which assume that relative prices and the difference between these two numbers (0.3 percent) pro-unemployment rate move independently of each other. vides a measure of aggregate-demand pressures in the

Our historical analysis suggests that supply shockswere economy. A measure of the net impact of supply shocks isimportant in keeping the unemployment rate low in the obtained as the difference between what the unemploy-1960s, and relatively high in the early- and mid-1970s. Of ment rate would have been in the absence of demandparticular interest right now is the role played by supply shocks and what it would have been in the absence ofshocksin raising the unemployment rate in the firsthalf of shocks of any kind. Our model implies that in the absencethe 1980s, and then lowering it in the second half of the of any shocks to the economy the unemployment ratedecade. The relatively large role played by supply shocks would have settled at 6.0 percent. 22

in the decline in the unemployment rate over the last few Thus, this difference between the actual 5.5 percent rateyearscould be one reason the inflationrate has notacceler- in 1988 and the 6.0 percent mean rate is accounted forated as much as past estimates of the unemployment- about equally by demand and supply shocks. Althoughinflation relationship would have led us to expect. demand pressures do appear to have contributed to labor

The analysis is relevant for policy purposes to the extent market tightness in 1988, the degree of pressure probablythat policy makers take the unemployment rate into ac- is not as intense as would be suggested by comparing thecountin determining policy. Policy makers may lookat the prevailing rate with its 6.0 percent mean.

APPENDIX A

Identification

In this appendix we describe the identificationproblem Let the estimated VAR representation of the model bein terms of the moving average representation of a VAR. given byLet the vector X, = [x., x2t... xnt ] denote the variablescontained in the model, where all the elements are nonsta- B (L) Z, = Vt • (A2)tionary, but are not cointegrated. Assume that the struc- Multiplying both sides of (A2) by C(L) B(L) -lleads totural representation of the model can be written as the moving average representation

z, = A (L) et (AI)

where Z, = JlXt , A(L) = Ao + AlL + A2U + A3V . . . ,and the lag operator L is defined by Let = et- l . Further, itisassumedthat~At< 00, and that thestructuraldisturbanceterm e is serially uncorrelated.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

z, = C (L) Vr (A3)

where E(v t) = 0, and E(vsv/) = n for t = s and is zerootherwise. (A3) is the reduced form representation of (AI),and we have

(A4)

33

Page 16: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

[ZIt]..ZZt .

Thisis satisfied foranyvt suchthatvt = S*et, andCtl.) =A(L)*S-I. Thus, to recover the structural representationfrom the estimated VAR, we need to obtain the matrix Swhich links the VAR residuals vt with the structuraldisturbances e;

Theexact form ofSwilldepend upon thestructure ofthemodel. Under the usual assumption that the structuraldisturbances areuncorrelated witheachotherandthattheyhave unit variance (that is, E(ete/) = I), the problem ofchoosing the appropriate S reduces to choosing the ele­mentsofS subject to thecondition thatS is a square rootofn (the variance-covariance matrix of the VAR residuals).Sincen has n(n+1)/2 unique elements and S is n*n, weneed n(n-1)/2 (that is, n2 [n(n +1)12]) additionalrestrictions in order to identify a unique S. If n = 2, forexample, n contains three unique elements while S con­tains four. Thus, we need one additional restriction toidentify S.

Sims(1980) suggested choosing S suchthat Sij = 0, forall j > i, which serves tomake thesystemexactly identified.Fora two-variable system, this restriction prevents shocksto the second variable from having any contemporaneouseffectonthe first variable. Sims' restrictions imply thattheunderlying structural model is a recursive, simultaneousequations model (with independent error terms), a repre­sentation thatmay sometimes bedifficult to reconcile witheconomic theory. Blanchard and Watson (1986) imposedrestrictions on contemporaneous correlations that wereexplicitly derived from economic theory, andvariations ofthis technique have beenimplemented byBemanke (1986)and Walsh (1987), among others.

The technique of identification used in this paper hasbeen suggested recently by Blanchard and Quah. In this

technique the restrictions used to identify S can be inter­pretedas restrictions on the long-run effects of the asso­ciatedshocks on certainvariables. Tosee how thisworks,assume that the vector Z, contains only two elements, sothat (A3) becomes

[Cd L) CdL)] [Vlt]

czI(L) cziL) VZt

or

or

rIl = [Cl1(L)Sn + c12(L)s21 cn(L)s12 + CdL)S22] PI]

Ed czlL)sn + cziL)sZI czlL)s12 + cziL)szz ~Zt

As discussed above, if eland e2 are assumed to beindependent of each other, only one more restriction isneeded to identify S. If it isassumed thate2 hasnolong-runeffect onxI (thefirst variable in the model), therestrictiontakes the form

Cll (1) Sl2 + Cl2 (1) S22 = 0

Here, CII (1) is just the sum of the coefficients in the lagpolynomial cll(L). Thus, in this case identification isachieved by choosing an S forwhich a particular weightedsumof theelements of thesecond column ofS is zero. Thecondition that these weights be the sumof thecoefficientsof the estimated lag polynomials for the first variable iswhat ensures that the level of x, is independent of e2 •

Shapiro and Watson (1988) show how this restrictioncan be imposed quite easily in the VAR representation.

Tests for Stationarity

We tested for stationarity using the Said-Dickey test,which is recommended by Schwert (1987). The test in­volves estimating an equation of the form

j

Yt = a + !3Yt-I + .I ~\~Yt-i + e;I=I

Totestwhether theYprocess contains aunitroot we haveto determine whether !3 = 1. However, under the nullhypothesis that the process generating Y contains a unitroot, the ratio of the estimated value of !3 to its standard

APPENDIXB

Data and Preliminary Tests

We use quarterly data over the period 1948Q1-1988Q4for our estimation.

Alldata have beenobtained from theCitibase datatape.For population, we use noninstitutional population, 16years and over, after subtracting armed forces. Theunem­ployment rate is the civilian unemployment rate. Tomakethe GNPdatacomparable, weuse real GNPnet of federaldefense expenditures. The interest rate we use is thesix-month commercial paper rate. Data for U.S. exportsand imports are from the National Income and ProductAccounts.

34 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 17: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

error does not have the usual t-distribution. The criticalvalues to be used in this case are tabulated in Fuller (1976).

Schwert (1987) demonstrates that choosing a large valueof} (as recommended by Said and Dickey) avoids theproblem of falsely rejecting the hypothesis that y contains aunit root. In the table below we present the results for thecases where} = 8 and} = 12. The table shows that we areunable to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root forpopulation, real GNP, the interest rate, or the foreignvariable at the 10%level in either the eight-lag or the 12-lagcase.

the case of the unemployment rate, we present threedifferent sets of results. We are unable to reject the nullhypothesis of a unit root in the unemployment rate whetheror not we allow for a linear trend. The last column showsthe results for the case where we allow for a change in the

mean unemployment rate beginning in 1974Ql. For theeight-lag case, the computed test statistic is significant at5%, while for the 12-lagcase the computed value of - 2.80is justbelow the 5% critical value of - 2.89.

Note, however, that these critical values do not allow fora shift in the mean under the alternative hypothesis. It isuseful to compare these critical values to those reported inPerron (1988). Perron generalizes the null of a unit rootprocess to allow for a one-time change in the structure ofthe series, and compares this to the alternative of astationary series with a discrete change in its mean. (Thus,his null hypothesis is not strictly the same as ours.) It turnsoutthatthecritical values vary with the date at which thebreak occurs. For the case at hand, where the break occursabout two-thirds of the way into the sample, the 5% criticalvalue is - 3.33, while the 10% critical value is - 3.01.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 35

Page 18: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

NOTES

1. See, for example, "Records of Policy Actions of theFederal Open Market Committee," FederalReserve PressRelease, for the eight Federal Open Market Committeemeetings in 1988.2. See, for example, Ball, Mankiw, and Romer (1988),Long and Plosser (1983), Lucas (1973), and Greenwaldand Stiglitz (1988).3. Later applications used restrictions derived from eco­nomic theory. See Blanchard and Watson (1986), Ber­nanke (1986), Sims (1986), and Walsh (1987).4. In another example of theoretical agnosticism, McCal­lum (1988) has investigated the robustness of nominal­income-targeting rules across different macroeconomictheories.5. These results refer to the case where no trend isremoved from the unemployment rate. Blanchard andQuah also present results for the case where they removea linear trend from the unemployment rate. Removal of alinear trend tends to increase the relative importance ofdemand shocks.6. They also included the price of oil as an exogenousvariable, on the grounds that the two recessions duringthe 1970s were the consequence of the oil price shocksduring this period. Inclusion of the oil price variable isproblematic, however, since oil prices fell dramatically in1985 without an obvious effect on real output. Shapiro andWatson estimate their model through the end of 1985only.7. SW also present two sets of results: one where there is adeterministic trend in labor hours and one where the trendin hours is stochastic. The results discussed in the textrefer to the latter case.

8. See, for example, Blanchard and Quah (1989), Longand Plosser (1983), and Shapiro and Watson (1988).

9. The model outlined here closely follows that in Shapiroand Watson.10. As described in Appendix A,once we assume that theunderlying shocks are uncorrelated and have unit vari­ance, we need n(n-1 )/2 additional restrictions to identify amodel that contains n variables. Since n = 5 here, weneed a total of 10 restrictions.

11. This assumption implies symmetric treatment of for­eign and domestic aggregate-demand shocks; that is,neither have permanent effects on output. However, theforeign shock also is designed to include the effects offoreign supply disturbances. One drawback of our modelis that we are treating foreign and domestic supply shocksasymmetrically; that is, domestic supply shocks can havepermanent effects, while foreign supply shocks cannot.

36

12. The assumption that an aggregate-demand shockinduced by monetary policy does not have a long-runeffect on the foreign variable is uncontroversial. The as­sumption that a fiscal-policy shock does not have a long­run effect on real exports and imports is less clear cut. SeeKrugman (1985) and Mussa (1985) for discussions ofthese issues and other references.13.See Phelps (1978). For a contrary view, see Summersand Blanchard (1986).14.See, for instance, Nelson and Plosser (1982).15. See, for instance, Gordon (1982) and CongressionalBudget Office (1987).16. The reader interested in more detail is referred toShapiro and Watson (1988).17. As noted earlier, we also estimated a model with nomean shift in the unemployment rate, even though underthis specification unit root tests suggest that the unem­ployment rate is non-stationary. The impulse responsefunctions and variance decompositions for this model arenearly identical with those presented in the text, with oneexception. The model without a mean shift in the unem­ployment rate ascribes a larger role to technology shocksand a smaller role to demand shocks in determining theerror variance of the unemployment rate. Moreover (con­sistent with our findings in the unit root tests), the effectsof different kinds of shocks on unemployment dissipatemore slowly in the model without a mean shift than in themodel discussed in the text.18. The list of real shocks considered by Boschen andMills (1988), for instance, contains changes in the price ofoil, marginal tax rates, real government purchases, work­ing-age population, and real exports.19. See Jorgenson, et aI., (1987).20. More specifically, to obtain the supply component ofthe unemployment rate for any given quarter, we subtractthe effect of all demand and foreign shocks that occurredas long as 40 quarters ago. The impulse response func­tions in Exhibit 1A show that this is more than long enoughfor the effects of these shocks to die out.21. See Gordon (1982), Barro (1977), and Lucas (1973).22. Prior to 1974,when we assume a mean shift, this rate isestimated to be 4.8 percent. Also, in the model where themean is not allowed to shift, the mean rate of unemploy­ment is estimated to be 5.0 percent.

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 19: Federal Reserve Ran.k ofSan. Fran › economic-research › files › 89-4_20-37.pdf · restrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts. Of course, if these forecasts are

REFERENCESBall, Laurence, N. Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer.

"The New Keynesian Economics and the Output­Inflation Trade-off," Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 1988:1.

Barra, Robert J. "Unanticipated Money, Output, and thePrice Level in the United States," Journal of PoliticalEconomy, Vol. 86, 1977.

Bernanke, BenS. "AlternativeExplanations for theMoney­Income Correlation," Carnegie-Rochester Confer­ence Serieson Public Policy, 25: 1986.

Blanchard, Olivier J. and Danny Quah. "The DynamicEffects of Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturb­ances," The American Economic Review, September1989.

Blanchard, OlivierJ. and MarkW Watson. "Are All CyclesAlike?", in RobertJ Gordon, ed., The American Busi­ness Cycle. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,1986.

Boardof Governors of the Federal Reserve System. "Rec­ords of Policy Actions of the Federal Open MarketCommittee," Federal Reserve Press Release, for theeight Federal Open Market Committee meetings in1988,

Boschen, John F, and Leonard O. Mills, "Tests of theRelation Between Moneyand Output in the Real Busi­ness Cycle Model," Journal of Monetary Economics,22,1988.

Congressional Budget Office. Congress of the UnitedStates, The Economic and Budget Outlook: An Up­date. August, 1987.

Evans, George W, "Output and Unemployment Dynam­ics in the UnitedStates: 1950-85," Journal ofAppliedEconometrics, Vol. 4, 1989,

Fuller, Wayne A. Introduction to Statistical Time Series.New York: John Wileyand Sons, 1976,

Gordon, Robert J. "Inflation, Flexible Exchange Rates,and the Natural Rate of Unemployment," in Martin N,Bailey, ed. Workers, Jobs, and Inflation. WashingtonD.C,: The Brookings Institution, 1982,

Greenwald, Bruce C. and Joseph E, Stiglitz. "ExaminingAlternative MacroeconomicTheories," Brookings Pa­pers on Economic Activity, 1988:1,

Jorgenson, Dale W, Frank M, Gollop, and Barbara M,Fraumeni. Productivity and US, Economic Growth.Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard UniversityPress: 1987.

King, Robert, Charles Plosser, James Stock, and MarkWatson, "Stochastic Trends and MacroeconomicFluctuations," unpublished paper, University of Roch­ester, 1987,

Federal Reserve Bankof San Francisco

Krugman, Paul R. "Is the Strong Dollar Sustainable?," inThe US. Dollar-RecentDevelopments, Outlook, andPolicy Options, Proceedings of a Symposium Spon­sored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 21-23,1985.

Long, John B. and Charles I. Plosser. "Real BusinessCycles," Journal of Political Economy, 91, 1983.

Lucas, RobertE. "SomeInternational Evidenceof Output­Inflation Tradeoffs," American Economic Review, 63,1973.

McCallum, BennettT "RobustnessProperties ofa RuleforMonetary Policy," Carnegie-Rochester ConferenceSerieson Public Policy, 29, 1988.

Mussa, Michael L. "Commentaryon "Is the Strong DollarSustainable?," in The US, Dollar-Recent Develop­ments, Outlook, and Policy Options, Proceedingsof aSymposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bankof Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August21-23,1985.

Nelson, Charles R, and Charles I. Plosser. "Trends andRandom Walks in MacroeconomicTimeSeries: SomeEvidenceand Implications,"Journal of Monetary Eco­nomics, 10, 1982,

Perron, Pierre. "Testing for a Unit Root in a Time SeriesWith aChanging Mean," mimeo, Princeton University,1988.

Phelps, Edmund S. Microeconomic Foundations of Em­ploymentand Inflation. NewYork: W W Norton, 1970,

Schwert, G. William, "Effects of Model Specification onTests for UnitRoots in Macroeconomic Data,"Journalof Monetary Economics, 20, 1987.

Shapiro, Matthew D. and Mark W Watson. "Sources ofBusiness Cycle Fluctuations," NBER Macroeconom­ics Annual 1988, Cambridge, Massachusetts: M.l.TPress,

Sims, Christopher A. "Macroeconomics and Reality,"Econometrica, 1980.

____. "Are Policy Models Usable for Policy Analy­sis?,"Quarterly Review, FederalReserve Bankof Min­neapolis, 1986.

Summers, Lawrence and Olivier Blanchard. "Hysteresisand European Unemployment," NBER Macroeco­nomics Annual 1986, Cambridge, Massachusetts:M.I.T Press,

Walsh Carl E, "Monetary Targeting and Inflation: 1976­1984," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank ofSan Francisco, Winter, 1987.

37