12
DIRK BERGEMANN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY ECONOMICS 121 B:I NTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS Problem Set 2: Demand Functions 1/30/12 This problem set is due on Monday, 2/6/12, in class. To receive full credit, provide a complete defense of your answer. 1. In class we defined the notion of a concave function, in particular a concave utility function. We said that a function f : R n R is concave if for all x, x 0 R n , and all λ (0, 1): f ( λx + (1 - λ) x 0 ) λf (x) + (1 - λ) f ( x 0 ) . (1) 1. See Figures 1. If f is a concave function, for every x between z and y, the point (x, f (x)) on the graph of f is above the straight line joining the points (z,f (z )) and (y,f (y)) Figure 1: A concave function 2. If f 00 (x) 0, f 0 (x) is a decreasing function. Suppose f (x) is a utility function representing a decision maker’s preference, decreasing f 0 (x) corresponds to diminishing marginal utility. 3. See Figures 2. If f is a quasiconcave function, for every x between z and y, the point (x, f (x)) on the graph of f is above the minimum of {f (z ),f (y)}. 1

EPARTMENT OF E · 2017-12-22 · DIRK BERGEMANN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY ECONOMICS 121B: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS Problem Set 2: Demand Functions 1/30/12 This problem

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

DIRK BERGEMANN

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

YALE UNIVERSITY

ECONOMICS 121B: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS

Problem Set 2:

Demand Functions

1/30/12

This problem set is due on Monday, 2/6/12, in class. To receive full credit, provide a complete defenseof your answer.

1. In class we defined the notion of a concave function, in particular a concave utility function. We said thata function f : Rn → R is concave if for all x, x′ ∈ Rn, and all λ ∈ (0, 1):

f(λx+ (1− λ)x′

)≥ λf (x) + (1− λ) f

(x′)

. (1)

1. See Figures 1. If f is a concave function, for every x between z and y, the point (x, f(x)) on thegraph of f is above the straight line joining the points (z, f(z)) and (y, f(y))

Figure 1: A concave function

2. If f ′′ (x) ≤ 0, f ′ (x) is a decreasing function. Suppose f (x) is a utility function representing adecision maker’s preference, decreasing f ′ (x) corresponds to diminishing marginal utility.

3. See Figures 2. If f is a quasiconcave function, for every x between z and y, the point (x, f(x)) on thegraph of f is above the minimum of {f(z), f(y)}.

1

Figure 2: A quasi-concave function

4. Let’s start with the definition of concavity:

f (λx+ (1− λ) y) ≥ λf (x) + (1− λ) f (y) .

Since,

f(x) ≥ min {f(x), f(y)}f(y) ≥ min {f(x), f(y)} ,

we have

f (λx+ (1− λ) y) ≥ λmin {f(x), f(y)}+ (1− λ) min {f(x), f(y)}≥ min {f(x), f(y)} ,

which impliesf (λx+ (1− λ) y) ≥ min {f(x), f(y)} ,

the definition of quasi-concavity. Figure 2 also demonstrates that a quasiconcave function is notnecessarily a concave function. We already show that it is a quasiconcave function. For z, y, λ asshown in the figure, we have

f (λx+ (1− λ) y) < λf (x) + (1− λ) f (y) (2)

f (λx+ (1− λ) y) > min {f(x), f(y)} . (3)

This counterexample shows that f(x) as depicted in figure 2 is not a concave function.

2. An equivalent description of a quasiconcave function is the following definition: f : Rn → R is quasi-concave if for all y, the upper contour set U , defined as follows

U (y) = {x ∈ X |f (x) ≥ y} (4)

is a convex set.

2

1. See Figures 3. The circle on the left hand side is a convex set. The shape on the left is not since theconvex combinations of two end points on the right are not in that set.

Figure 3: A concave function

2. See Figure 4. For any z ∈ R, the upper contour set UC(z) is convex, which is the case in figure4. Consider Figure 5 where the upper contour set is not convex as a counterexample. Obviously thisfunction is not quasi-concave.

3. Suppose the consumer’s preferences are represented by function u. For any two bundles x and x′, thefollowing equivalence holds,

x � x′ ⇔ u(x) ≥ u(x′).

We need to show that u is a quasiconcave function if the consumer’s preferences are convex. We firstprove this statement for x, y such that x ∼ y and x 6= y. Since for all λ ∈ (0, 1),

λx+ (1− λ) y % x

λx+ (1− λ) y % y,

we have

u(λx+ (1− λ) y) ≥ min{u(x), u(y)}.

Next we prove the statement for bundles x, y such that x � y. Without loss of generality, we assumethat x % y. In this case, for all λ ∈ (0, 1), we have

λx+ (1− λ) y % y.

Therefore,u(λx+ (1− λ) y) ≥ u(y) = min{u(x), u(y)}.

To sum, we prove that convex preference implies that the utility function is quasiconcave.

3. A consumer’s preferences are represented by the following utility function:

u(x, y) = lnx+ 2lny.

3

Figure 4: Equivalence of the two definitions of strict quasi-concavity

Figure 5: A non-convex upper contour set

4

1. Recall that for any two bundles Z and Z ′ the following equivalence holds

Z � Z ′ ⇔ u(Z) ≥ u(Z ′)

Calculate utility from each bundle.

u(A) = u(1, 4) = ln 1 + 2 ln 4 = 0 + 2 ∗ 1.4 = 2.8

u(B) = u(4, 1) = ln 4 + 2 ln 1 = 1.4 + 2 ∗ 0 = 1.4

Thus, since u(A) > u(B) the consumer prefers bundle A to bundle B.

2. Convex preferences imply that for any three bundles X,Y, and Z, if Y � X and Z � X thenαY + (1− α)Z � X .

From the example above take Y to be bundleA, andX to be bundleB. Since preferences are reflexiveB � B, thus, we can take Z to be bundle B. Thus, convexity of preferences implies

αA+ (1− α)B � B

Notice that C = 1/2A+ 1/2B. Thus C � B. To verify the answer, calculate utility from C

u(C) = u(2.5, 2.5) = ln(2.5) + 2 ln(2.5) = 2.7 > 1.4 = u(B)

3. A bundle Z with consumptions given by (xZ , yZ) is indifferent to the given bundle B when it yieldsthe same utility as bundle B.

Utility that bundle Z yields

u(Z) = u(xZ , yZ) = lnxZ + 2 ln yZ

should be equal to u(B) = 1.4. Thus, an equation for the indifference through the bundle (xB, yB) =

(4, 1) is

lnxZ + 2 ln yZ = ln 4

lnxZy2Z = ln 4

xZy2Z = exp ln 4

y2Z =

4

xZ

yZ =2

x1/2Z

5

4.

MRS(x, y) = −MUxMUy

= −1/x

2/y= − y

2x

MRS(2.5, 2.5) = − 2.5

2.2.5= −1

2

MRS is the rate at which two goods should be exchanges to keep the overall utility constant. Forexample, at a point (2.5 ; 2.5) 1 unit of good x should be exchanged for 1/2 units of good y.

4. Graphically, the function f(x) = a− (x− b)2 look like this:

- x

6

f(x)

b

a

We want to maximize f(x) = a− (x− b)2, or more formally we want to solve:

maxx

a− (x− b)2. (5)

Note that there is no constraint. To find the local maxima/minima we solve ddxf(x∗) = 0. For our

problem we want to solve

d

dxf(x∗) = −2(x∗ − b) = 0 (6)

and so the solution to our first-order condition (FOC) gives us x∗ = b. To make sure that we in fact havea maximum and not a minimum we must check our second-order condition (SOC), or that d2

dx2f(x∗) < 0.

In this case d2

dx2f(x) = −2 < 0 so our SOC is satisfied everywhere and our solution gives us a maximum.

5. Consider the same function f(x) = a − (x − b)2, and suppose now that the choice of the optimal x isconstrained by x ≤ x, where x is an arbitrary number, satisfying

0 < x < b. (7)

1. Adding the constraint x ≤ x̄ to our graph looks like this:

6

- x

6

f(x)

b

a

where everything to the left of the new vertical line at x̄ are feasible choices of x for the constrainedoptimization problem.

2. Our new constrained problem is:

maxx

a− (x− b)2 s.t. x ≤ x̄, (8)

where 0 < x̄ < b. Let us define our Lagrangian as L(x, λ) = a− (x− b)2 + λ(x̄− x).

The optimal conditions include one FOC and one complementary condition

∂xL(x∗, λ∗) = −2(x∗ − b)− λ∗ = 0 (9)

λ∗(x̄− x∗) = 0. (10)

There are two possibilities given our complementary slackness condition, λ∗(x̄ − x∗) = 0. Eitherλ∗ > 0 and x̄− x∗ = 0 or x̄− x∗ > 0 and λ∗ = 0 should be the case. If λ∗ = 0 is the relevant casehere, equation (9) implies that x∗ = b, but this contradicts our assumption that x∗ < x̄ since x̄ < b.Therefore, we have λ∗ = 0 and x∗ = x̄, which gives us our optimal choice of x. Equation (9) impliesthat λ∗ = −2(x∗ − b), which can be combined with our first equation to give us λ∗ = 2(b − x̄) ouroptimal choice of λ.

3. Lagrange multiplier. The value of the Lagrangian evaluated at our solution isL(x∗, λ∗) = L(x̄, 2(b−x̄)) = a− (x̄− b)2. We can find the marginal effect of increasing our bound, x̄, by taking the partialderivative of our value function with respect to x̄. Namely, we are interested in

∂x̄L(x∗, λ∗) = −2(x̄− b) = 2(b− x̄), (11)

and we find that ∂∂x̄L(x∗, λ∗) = λ∗.

4. Interpretation of Lagrangian multiplier. The price we would have to charge in order to get thedecision maker to choose exactly x∗ = x̄, even in the absence of a hard constraint, would be given byλ∗ = 2(b− x̄).

7

6. Comparative Statics. Substituting x∗ = x̄ into function f , we get

y∗ = f(x∗)

= a− (x̄− b)2.

To measure how y∗ varies with b, we simply take the derivative of y∗ with respect to b,

dy∗(b)

db= −2(b− x̄).

We can get the same result using envelope theorem.

We start off with

y∗(b) = f(x∗(b), b),

dy∗

db=∂f

∂x

dx

db+∂f

∂b=∂f (x, b)

∂b.

This is the envelope theorem which states that at the optimal solution, the impact of a marginal changein an exogenous parameter on the value of the objective function is equal to the direct marginal changethat the exogenous variable has on the objective function. The indirect effects, i.e.

∂f

∂x

dx

db|x=x̄ = 0

all cancel out at the optimal solution. In our case dydb = ∂f(x,b)

∂b |x=x̄ = 2(x̄− b).

7. Consider the following utility function (often referred to as quasi-linear utility function as it is linear inthe second element):

u(x, y) = ln (x) + y;

with prices and income given by: px = 1, py ∈ R+ and I ∈ R+.

1. For special case of py = 2 and I = 1, the tangency condition implies that

∂u(x,y)∂x

∂u(x,y)∂y

=pxpy

1

x=

1

2x = 2.

Since pxx+pyy = x+2y ≤ 1, we conclude that there is no positive consumption choice (x∗, y∗) ≥ 0

which satisfies the tangency condition.

Figure 6 shows the green indifference curve is tangent to the budget constraint at point (x, y) =

(2,−12). At the price level (px, py) = (1, 2) the tangency condition can be satisfied only if x = 2

which can not be sustained given that (px, py, I) = (1, 2, 1).

8

Figure 6: Quasi-linear Utility

2. From figure 6 we can see that if we are restricted to bundles weakly positive (graphically, we requirethat we choose bundles above the x-axis), the highest indifference curve which intersects the budgetconstraint area is the red indifference curve. Therefore, the optimal consumption choice is (x∗, y∗) =

(1, 0). Note that at the optimal consumption bundle, the indifference curve is not tangent to the budgetconstraint line.

Analytically, we only need to check two corner solutions (1, 0) and (0, 12), whichever gives the higher

utility is the optimal bundle.

3. Now solve by the method of substitution (using pxx + pyy = I) and do not insist on positive valuesof consumption of either x or y.

1. To solve by substitution we start by rearranging the budget constraint into y = I−pxxpy

and then

substitute this into the quasilinear utility function to obtain u(x) = lnx+ ( I−pxxpy). We could have

just as well solved for x to obtain u(y). To find demand, we solve the following unconstrainedproblem:

maxx

lnx+

(I − pxxpy

). (12)

The FOC is 1x∗ −

pxpy

= 0, which yields the demand function x∗ =pypx

. We can use the budget

constraint to find the other demand function. This yields y∗ =I−pypy

. But note that for the demandfunctions that we have found, there is nothing to guarantee that pxx∗ ≤ I or that y∗ ≥ 0. Wecan plug in our demand functions into these conditions and with a bit of algebra we find that bothconditions imply py

I ≤ 1. So if the parameters are such that pyI > 1, our demand functions do notmake sense (namely, they tell us to purchase negative quantities of y and spend more on x than ourbudget would allow). In this case, it must be that our budget does not allow the purchase of x tothe point that our FOC is satisfied and so the best consumption bundle would be to spend all ourmoney on x and none on y. So the correct and complete demand functions are:

9

x∗ =

{pypx

ifpyI ≤ 1

Ipx

else

y∗ =

{I−pypy

ifpyI ≤ 1

0 else

2. To solve using the Lagrange method we must first set up our Lagrange equation by incorporatingour budget constraint and our nonnegativity constraints, x ≥ 0 and y ≥ 0.The Lagrangean thenformally becomes

L (x, y, λI , λx, λy) = ln (x) + y + λI · (I − pxx− pyy) + λx · x+ λy · y.

This yields the FOCs with respect to x and y as well as complementary slackness conditions,

∂xL(x∗, y∗, λ∗I , λ

∗x, λ∗y) =

1

x∗− λ∗Ipx + λ∗x = 0 (13)

∂yL(x∗, y∗, λ∗I , λ

∗x, λ∗y) = 1− λ∗Ipy + λ∗y = 0 (14)

λ∗I · (I − pxx∗ − pyy∗) = 0 (15)

λ∗x · x∗ = 0 (16)

λ∗y · y∗ = 0. (17)

We start with equation (13). For 1/x∗ to be well defined, it must be the case that x∗ > 0 given thatx∗ is weakly positive. This result is confirmed by checking the marginal utility of x. We can tellby the utility function that the nonnegativity constraint on x will never be binding at the optimumsince ∂

∂xu(0, y) =∞ for all y. Therefore, λx = 0 and x∗ > 0.Substituting λx = 0 and x∗ > 0 into equation (13) we conclude that λIpx > 0, implying thatλI > 0. Combining this condition with equation (15), We know that the budget constraint willbe binding, which should be the case since the utility function is strictly monotonic. So our twopossible cases/solutions involve y∗ > 0 (and thus λ∗y = 0) or y∗ = 0 (and thus λ∗y > 0).

3. We rewrite equations (13) and (14) into pxx∗ = 1λI

and λI =1+λypy

, respectively. Substitutingthese two conditions into budget constraint

(I − pxx∗ − pyy∗) = 0

we haveI = py(

1

1 + λy+ y∗).

We know that either λy = 0 and y∗ > 0 or λy > 0 and y∗ = 0. In the former case, I =

py(1 + y) > py. In the latter case I =py

1+λy< py. This shows that y∗ = 0 if and only if the

method of substitution would have given y∗ < 0 as an answer. In summary, we have the followingsolution.

x∗ =

{pypx

ifpyI ≤ 1

Ipx

else

10

y∗ =

{I−pypy

ifpyI ≤ 1

0 else

λ∗I =

{1py

ifpyI ≤ 1

1I else

λ∗y =

{0 if

pyI ≤ 1

py−II else.

4. The parameter values are px = 2, and py = 1. In order to find the income expansion path for thequasilinear utility function, we have to be mindful of when I − py = 0. So our income expansionpath is given by:

IEP (I) =

{(1

2 , I − 1) if I ≥ 1

( I2 , 0) else

- x

6

y

12

4. With parameter values px = 1, py = 2, I = 10 we are in the case where I > py so demand is givenby x∗ =

pypx

= 21 and y∗ =

I−pypy

= 4. The elasticity of the demand for good i with respect to price j

is defined as εi,j = ∂xi∂pj

pjxi

. So the own price elasticity for x is given by

εx,x =∂x∗

∂px

pxx∗

= −pyp2x

pxx∗

= −pyp2x

p2x

py= −1,

and its cross price elasticity is

εx,y =∂x∗

∂py

pyx∗

=1

px

pyx∗

=1

px

pypxpy

= 1.

11

The own price elasticity for y is given by

εy,y =∂y∗

∂py

pyy∗

= − I

p2y

pyy∗

= −10

1

1

4

= −5

2,

and its cross price elasticity is

εy,x =∂y∗

∂px

pxy∗

= 0pxy∗

= 0.

12