45
Engines of Liberation Jeremy Greenwood, Ananth Seshadri and Mehmet Yorukoglu 1, 2 November 2000, Preliminary Comments Welcome 1 Aliations : University of Rochester, University of Wisconsin and The University of Chicago. 2 Updates : http://www.econ.rochester.edu/Faculty/GreenwoodPapers/engine.pdf

Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Engines of Liberation

Jeremy Greenwood, Ananth Seshadri and Mehmet Yorukoglu1, 2

November 2000, PreliminaryComments Welcome

1Affiliations : University of Rochester, University of Wisconsin and The University ofChicago.

2Updates: http://www.econ.rochester.edu/Faculty/GreenwoodPapers/engine.pdf

Page 2: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Abstract

Electricity was born at the dawn of the last century. Households were inundatedwith a flood of new consumer durable goods. What was the impact of this consumerdurable goods revolution? It is argued here that the consumer goods revolutionliberated women from the home. To analyze this hypothesis, a Beckerian model ofhousehold production is developed. Households must decide whether to adopt thenew technologies or not, and whether a married woman should work. Can such amodel explain the rise in married female labor-force participation that occurred inthe last century? Yes.

Keywords: The second industrial revolution, technology adoption, householdproduction theory, female labor-force participation.

Subject Area: Macroeconomics.

JEL Classification Numbers: E1, J2, N1.

Page 3: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

“The housewife of the future will neither be a slave to servants or

herself a drudge. She will give less attention to the home, because the

home will need less; she will be rather a domestic engineer than a domestic

laborer, with the greatest of all handmaidens, electricity, at her service.

This and other mechanical forces will so revolutionize the woman’s world

that a large portion of the aggregate of woman’s energy will be conserved

for use in broader, more constructive fields.”

Thomas Alva Edison, as interviewed in Good Housekeeping Magazine,

LV, no. 4 (October 1912, p. 436)

1 Introduction

1.1 Facts

The dawning of the last century ushered in the second industrial revolution: the rise

of electricity, the internal combustion engine, and the petrochemical industry. As

this was happening, another technological revolution was beginning to percolate in

the home: the housework revolution. The impact of the housework revolution was

no less than the industrial revolution.

Durable Goods: The housework revolution was spawned by massive investment-

specific technological progress in the production of household capital. This era saw

the rise of central heating, dryers, electric irons, frozen foods, refrigerators, sewing

machines, washing machines, vacuum cleaners, and other appliances now considered

fixtures of everyday life. The spread of electricity, central heating, flush toilets and

running water, through the U.S. economy is shown in Figure 1.1 Likewise, Fig-

ure 2 plots the diffusion of some common electrical appliances through American

1The data for this figure is taken from Lebergott (1976, p. 100) and Lebergott (1993, Tables

II.14 and II.15).

1

Page 4: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

Year

0

20

40

60

80

100

Hou

seho

ld A

dopt

ion,

%

Central Heating

Electricity

Running Water

Flush Toilet

Figure 1: Spread of Basic Facilities Through the U.S. Economy

households.2

Investment in household appliances as a percentage of GDP has almost doubled

over the last century. It represented about 0.5% of GDP in 1988, which was about

2.9% of total investment spending. Likewise, the stock of appliances as a percentage

of GDP has also risen continuously, as Figure 3 illustrates.3

To understand the impact of the housework revolution, try to imagine the tyranny

of household chores at the turn of the last century. In 1890 only 24 percent of houses

had running water, none had central heating. So, the average household lugged

around the home, 7 tons of coal and 9,000 gallons of water per year. The simple

2Sources: Survey of Current Business and Fixed Reproducible Tangible Wealth in the United

States, 1925-89. Washington, D.C., U.S. Department of Commerce.3Sources: (i) Dishwashers, refrigerators, and vacuum cleaners — Electrical Merchandising; (ii)

Dryers and microwaves — Burwell and Swezey (1990, Figures 11.8 and 11.10); (iii)Washers — Leber-

gott (1993, Table II.20)

2

Page 5: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990

Year

0

20

40

60

80

100

Hou

seho

ld A

dopt

ion,

%

refrigerator

vacuum

washer

microwave

dishwasher

dryer

Figure 2: Diffusion of Electrical Appliances in the Household Sector

task of laundry was a major operation in those days. While mechanical washing

machines were available as early as 1869, this invention really took off only with

the development of the electric motor. Ninety-eight percent of households used a 12

cent scrubboard to wash their clothes in 1900. Water had to be ported to the stove,

where it was heated by burning wood or coal. The clothes were then cleaned via a

washboard or mechanical washing machine. They had to be rinsed out after this.

The water then needed to be wrung out, either by hand or by using a mechanical

wringer. The clothes were dried using a clothes line. Then, the oppressive task of

ironing began, using heavy flatirons that had to be heated continuously on the stove.

The electric iron was first patented in 1882 by Henry W. Seely. Westinghouse

launched an advertising campaign to acquaint the public with the benefits of the iron

in 1906. The iron diffused quickly with the spread of electricity. Seventy-one percent

3

Page 6: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000Year

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Appl

ianc

e-In

vest

men

t-to-

GD

P R

atio

, %

0.6

1.1

1.6

2.1

2.6

Appl

ianc

e-to

-GD

P R

atio

, %

Investment

Stock

Figure 3: Household Appliances

of wired homes had them in 1926.4 The first electric washing machine surfaced in

1908. It was invented by Alva J. Fisher and sold by the Hurley Machine Company.

As with many inventions, the initial incarnation of the idea was crude. Clothes were

spun around on a drum driven by an uncovered chain attached to an electric motor.

Maytag introduced an electric washing machine with an agitator in 1922. It was a

great success and by 1927 the company had produced a million of them. Thirty-

six percent of wired homes had an electric washing machine in 1926.5 The early

machines really just replaced the scrubboard. Homeowners still had to use a wringer.

The electric water heater arrived around this time, too. Fully automatic washing

machines with a spin-cycle didn’t appear until about 1940. The clothes dryer didn’t

catch on until the beginning of the 1950s.

4Source: Electrical Merchandising, January 1926, pp. 6002.5Source: Ibid.

4

Page 7: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Time Savings: The amount of time freed by modern appliances is somewhat spec-

ulative. Controlled engineering studies documenting the time saved on some specific

task by the use of a particular machine would be ideal. Unfortunately, these studies

seem hard to come by. The Rural Electrification Authority supervised one such study

based on 12 farm wives during 1945-46. They compared the time spent doing laundry

by hand to that spent using electrical equipment. The women also wore a pedometer.

One subject, Mrs. Verett, was reported on in detail.6 Without electrification, she

did the laundry in the manner described above.7 After electrification Mrs.Verett had

an electric washer, dryer and iron. A water system was also installed with a water

heater. They estimated that it took her about 4 hours to do a 38 lb load of laundry

by hand, and then about 4 and 1/2 hours to iron it using old-fashioned irons. By

comparison it took 41 minutes to do a load of the laundry using electrical appliances

and 1 and 3/4 hours to iron it. The woman walked 3,181 feet to do the laundry

by hand, and only 332 feet with electrical equipment. She walked 3,122 feet when

ironing the old way, and 333 the new way.

In 1900 the average household spent 58 hours a week on housework — meal prepa-

ration, laundry and cleaning — Lebergott (1993, Table 8.1) estimates. This compares

with just 18 in 1975. Sociologists suggest that modern appliances have had little

effect on the total time allocated to housework. This is based on time diary evidence.

They feel that with the mechanization of the household, societal standards for good

housekeeping have risen to keep women enslaved. Vanek (1973, Tables 14.4 and 14.5)

reports that total amount of time spent on housework in a family with an employed or

non-employed mother seems remarkably constant over the last 70 years or so, about

26 hours a week for the former and 55.4 hours for the later in 1965-1966. Even taking

this pessimistic attitude, this implies that the average amount of total time spent

on housework has fallen as female labor-force participation has risen. The implied

average amount of total time spent on housework (ignoring part-time work) is shown

6This study is reported in Electrical Mechandising, March 1, 1947: pp. 38-39.7She actually had a gas-powered washing machine that replaced the scrubboard.

5

Page 8: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

1910 1930 1950 1970

20

30

40

50

60

Tota

l Hou

rs p

er W

eek

on H

ouse

wor

k

30

50

70

90

Dom

estic

Wor

kers

per

1,0

00 H

ouse

hold

s

Domestics

Housework -- Vanek, implied

Housework -- Lebergott

Figure 4: Housework

in Figure 4. At the same time the number of paid domestic workers declined, presum-

ably in part due to the labor-saving nature of household appliances.8 A reasonable

conclusion is that the time spent on the more onerous household chores, such as those

associated with cooking, cleaning, doing the laundry, etc., declined considerably in

the last century.

Labor-Force Participation: What was the effect of this massive technological ad-

vance in the production of household capital on labor force participation? A case

can be made that it liberated women from the home. As can be seen from Figure 5,

female labor-force participation rose steadily since 1890. At the same time the num-

ber of homemakers continuously declined. Real income per full-time female worker

grew five fold over this period. In 1890 a female worker earned about 50 percent of

a what a male did, and by 1970 this number had risen to only 60 percent. It seems

8Source: Oppenheimer (1969, Table 2.5)

6

Page 9: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980Year

0

20

40

60

Perc

enta

ge

1000

2000

3000

4000

5000

Earn

ings

, $19

67

Homemakers, left

Earnings Ratio, left

Participation, left

Female Earnings, right

Figure 5: Female Labor-Force Statistics

unlikely that the small rise in the relative income of a female worker could explain

the dramatic rise in labor force participation. It is more likely that the rise in overall

real wages, in conjunction with the introduction of labor-saving household appliances,

explains the rise in female labor-force participation.9

A Wrinkle: Now, the data suggests that women from poor households entered the

labor force first. As can be seen, the higher a woman’s husband’s income, the less

likely she was to work. At the same time, the poorer a family, the slower they were

to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

their introduction. Perhaps poor women went to work in order to save up the funds

required to buy the new durable goods at some later date, when their prices would

fall.9Sources: (i) Female earnings, ratio of female to male earnings, and participation — Goldin (1990,

Table 5.1); (ii) Homemakers — Vanek (1973, Table 1.22).

7

Page 10: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Labor Force Participation by Husband’s Income: US, April 1940

No Children under 10 With Children under 10

White Nonwhite White Nonwhite

$1-199 30.4% 44.5 15.4 23.2

200-399 25.5 37.5 12.2 21.0

400-599 24.0 37.2 11.0 19.2

600-999 23.2 33.7 11.2 18.6

1,000-1,499 21.3 25.5 8.7 14.1

1,500-1,999 16.8 20.9 5.5 16.3

2,000 and up 11.1 20.3 3.1 12.1

Source: Durand (1948, Table 17, p. 92)

8

Page 11: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Durable Goods Ownership by Socio-Economic Class: US, 1965

Working Not Working

All Family Income All Family Income

$3,000 $5,000 $8,000 $3,000 $5,000 $8,000

- 4,999 - 7,999 and up - 4,999 - 7,999 and up

Running Water 100% 100 100 100 99 100 99 100

Hot Water 99 100 99 98 98 99 97 100

Flush Toilet 98 96 98 100 98 99 97 100

Bath or Shower 98 91 99 98 98 98 97 100

Furnace 88 74 86 98 87 81 93 93

Telephone 90 65 94 94 92 88 99 100

Refrigerator 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100

Freezer 14 4 13 19 12 8 17 14

Electric or Gas Stove 100 100 100 100 98 98 99 100

Washing Machine 90 78 92 92 98 97 99 100

— Nonautomatic 52 61 60 31 63 73 55 29

— Automatic 40 17 33 63 39 26 51 79

Dryer 60 43 56 75 57 45 70 86

Iron 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100

Vacuum Cleaner 87 78 88 90 89 80 97 100

Sewing Machine 63 48 67 60 68 58 75 100

Source: Vanek (1973, Table 4.21, p. 155)

9

Page 12: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Durable Goods Ownership by Income: Canada, 1957

$2,000-$2,999 $3,000-$3,999 $4,000-$4,999 $5,000-$5,999 $6,000-$7,999

Refrigerator 79% 93 93 95 96

Stove 57 76 82 88 92

Washer 85 90 90 90 92

Television 83 88 90 91 91

Freezer 7 4 5 8 5

Vacuum Cleaner 40 61 67 80 83

Floor Polisher 21 29 42 51 51

Sewing Machine 53 64 61 65 62

Radio 88 91 92 93 95

Source: Day (1992, Table 8, p. 319)

1.2 The Analysis

To address the question at hand, Becker’s (1965) classic notion of household produc-

tion is introduced into a dynamic general equilibrium model. In particular, household

capital and labor can be combined to produce home goods, which yield utility. This

isn’t the first time that household production theory has been embedded into the

neoclassical growth model. Benhabib, Rogerson and Wright (1991) have done so to

study the implication of the household sector for business cycle fluctuations.10 Par-

ente, Rogerson andWright (2000) apply a similar framework to see whether household

production can explain cross-country income differentials. Home production has also

been introduced into an overlapping generations model by Rios-Rull (1993) to exam-

ine its impact on the time allocations of skilled versus unskilled labor.

The analysis undertaken here differs significantly, though, from the above work.

It assumes that over the last century there has been tremendous investment-specific

technological progress in the production of household capital. These new and im-

10This line of research has been recently been extended by Gomme, Kydland, and Rupert (2000).

10

Page 13: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

proved capital goods allow household production to be undertaken using less labor.

The formalization of the labor shedding nature of the new technologies is reminis-

cent of Goldin and Katz’s (1998) description of the effect that continuous-process

and batch methods had on labor demand during the second industrial revolution. It

also resembles Krusell et al ’s (2000) analysis of the impact that biased technological

progress had on the postwar skill premium. At the heart of the developed frame-

work are two interrelated decisions facing each household. First, they must choose

whether or not to adopt the new technology at the going price. Second, they must de-

cide whether the woman in the family should work in the market or not. The upshot

of the analysis is that household production theory is a powerful tool for explaining

the rise in U.S. female labor-force participation over the last century.

2 The Economic Environment

The world is made up of overlapping generations. Each generation lives n periods.

Hence, in any period there are n generations around.

Tastes: Let tastes for an age-j household be given by

nXi=j

βi−j[µ lnmi + ν lnni + (1− µ− ν) ln li],

where mi and ni are the consumptions of market and non-market produced goods

and li is the household’s leisure.

Income: A household is made up of a male and a female. They are endowed

with two units of time, which they split up between market work, home work, and

leisure. Work in the market is indivisible. Set market time at ω. It will be assumed

that males always work in the market. The household can choose whether or not

the female will work in the market. Each household is indexed by an ability level, λ,

shared by both members. This is drawn at the beginning of their life. They make all

decisions knowing the value of λ. Let ability λ be drawn from a lognormal distribution.

11

Page 14: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Normalize the mean of λ at unity. Therefore, assume that lnλ ∼ N(−σ2/2, σ2).

Denote the distribution function for ability by L(λ). The market wage for an efficiency

unit of male labor is given by w. A woman earns the fraction φ of what a man does.

Hence, in a given period, a family of efficiency level λ will earn the amount wλω if

the female stays at home and the amount wλω+wφλω if she works. The family may

also have assets. Denote these by a and let the gross interest rate be r.

Household Production: Home goods are produced according to the following Leon-

tief production function. Specifically,

n = mind, ζh,

where d represents the stock of household durables and h proxies for the time spent

on housework. The variable ζ represents labor-augmenting technological progress in

the household sector. Durables goods are assumed to be lumpy. All housework is

done by women.

The Durable Goods Revolution, A Preview : A household technology is defined

by the triplet (d, h, ζ). Recall that household capital, d, is lumpy, and assume that

housework, h, is indivisible. Let the time price of the technology be q — this is set

in terms of hours of work (at the mean skill level). The cost of the technology is

equal to price of the durable goods, d, needed to operated it. Before the arrival of

electricity suppose that d = δ, h = ρη, and ζ = δ/(ρη), where 0 < ρη < 1 − ω andρ > 1. Using this old technology, n = mind, ζh = δ units of non-market goods canbe produced. The price of the old household technology will be set to zero. Now,

imagine that electricity comes along together with a new set of durable goods. Define

this new technology by the triplet (d0, h0, ζ 0). Here d0 = κδ, h0 = η, and ζ 0 = κδ/η,

where κ > 1. Note that ζ 0 = κρζ, so that technological progress can be broken down

into the additional amount of capital services provided and the amount of household

labor freed up. That is, with the new technology capital services rise by a factor

of κ. The old technology requires more labor, a factor ρ more. The new technology

produces n0 = mind0, ζ 0h0 = κδ > δ units of non-market goods. Should a household

12

Page 15: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

adopt the new technology? This will depend on its price, q0, of course.

Market Production: Market production is undertaken according to the standard

neoclassical production function

y = kα(zl)1−α, (1)

where y is output, k represents the aggregate market capital stock, and l is the

aggregate labor input. Labor-augmenting technological progress is captured by the

variable z. Market output can be used for the consumption of market goods, m,

gross investment in business capital, i, and for gross investment in household capital,

d. Hence

m+ i+ d = y. (2)

The law of motion for business capital is

k0 = χk+ i, (3)

where χ factors in physical depreciation.

3 The Household’s Decision Problem

Asset Accumulation and Labor-Force Participation Decisions: Consider the dynamic

programming problem facing an age-j household. Suppose that the household has

already made its decision about whether or not to adopt the new technology for the

current period. Then the household’s state of the world is summarized by the triplet

(a, τ ,λ). Here τ ∈ 0, 1, 2 is an indicator function giving the state of the householdtechnology. When τ = 0 the household does not use the new technology in the cur-

rent period. When τ = 1 the household purchases and uses the new technology in the

current period. Last, τ = 2 denotes the case where the household has adopted previ-

ously. The lifetime utility for an age-j household with assets, a, state of technology

13

Page 16: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

τ , and ability level λ is represented by V j(a, τ ,λ). It is easy to see that the decisions

regarding female labor-force participation and asset accumulation are summarized by

V j(a, 0,λ) = maxmaxa0µ ln(wλω + φwλω + ra− a0) + ν ln(δ) P(1)

+(1− µ− ν) ln(2− 2ω − ρη) + βmax[V j+1(a0, 0,λ), V j+1(a0, 1,λ)],maxa0µ ln(wλω + ra− a0) + ν ln(δ)

+(1− µ− ν) ln(2− ω − ρη) + βmax[V j+1(a0, 0,λ), V j+1(a0, 1,λ)],

V j(a, 1,λ) = maxmaxa0µ ln(wλω + φwλω + ra− a0 − wq) + ν ln(κδ)

+(1− µ− ν) ln(2− 2ω − η) + βV j+1(a0, 2,λ),maxa0µ ln(wλω + ra− a0 − wq) + ν ln(κδ)

+(1− µ− ν) ln(2− ω − η) + βV j+1(a0, 2,λ). P(2)

and

V j(a, 2,λ) = maxmaxa0µ ln(wλω + φwλω + ra− a0) + ν ln(κδ)

+(1− µ− ν) ln(2− 2ω − η) + βV j+1(a0, 2,λ),maxa0µ ln(wλω + ra− a0) + ν ln(κδ)

+(1− µ− ν) ln(2− ω − η) + βV j+1(a0, 2,λ). P(3)

Denote the female labor-force participation decision that arises from these problems

by the indicator function P j(a, τ ,λ). Here P j(a, τ ,λ) = 1 denotes the event where the

woman works. Likewise, the household’s asset decision is represented by Aj(a, τ ,λ).

The Adoption Decision: Now, suppose that a household currently does not own

the new technology. The household faces a choice about whether to adopt the new

technology in the current period or not. The decision problem facing an age-j house-

hold is

maxτ∈0,1

V j(a, τ ,λ). P(4)

14

Page 17: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Let T j(a,λ) represent the indicator function that summarizes the decision to adopt

the new technology or not. The solution to this problem is simple:

T j(a,λ) =

1, if V j(a, 1,λ) > V j(a, 0,λ),

0, if V j(a, 1,λ) ≤ V j(a, 0,λ).

It only applies to those agents who haven’t adopted previously. The law of motion

for technology must specify that τ j+1 = 2 if either τ j = 1 or τ j = 2.

Decision Rules: Consider generation j. Denote an age-j household’s current asset

holdings by aj and their state of technology by τ j. Now, note that for the first

generation a1 = 0. This implies that aj+1 and τ j+1 can be represented by aj+1 =

Aj(λ) and τ j+1 = Tj(λ). To see that this is the case, suppose that aj = Aj−1(λ)

and τ j = Tj−1(λ). If τ = 2 then either τ j+1 = Tj−1(λ) or τ j+1 = Tj−1(λ) + 1,

and if τ 6= 2 then τ j+1 = T j(Aj−1(λ),λ). Hence, write τ j+1 = Tj(λ). Likewise,

aj+1 = Aj(Aj−1(λ),Tj(λ),λ) ≡ Aj(λ). To start the induction, let T 1(0,λ) ≡ T1(λ)

and A1(0, T 1(λ),λ) ≡ A1(λ). Similarly, an age-j household’s participation decision

can be written asPj(λ). Now, at any point in time some households will have adopted

the new technology while others won’t have. Let λj be the threshold level of λ such

that all households of generation j with λ > λj will have adopted, while those with

λ ≤ λj won’t have.

4 Competitive Equilibrium

Market-Clearing Conditions: At each point in time all factor markets must clear.

This implies that the market demand for labor must equal the market supply of

labor. Therefore,

l = nω

ZλL(dλ) + φω

nXj=1

ZλPj(λ)L(dλ). (4)

The market supply of labor is obtained by summing males’ and females’ labor supplies

across the varying ability levels and generations. Likewise, next period’s market

15

Page 18: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

capital stock must equal today’s purchases of assets so that

k0 =nXj=1

ZAj(λ)L(dλ). (5)

Since the market sector is competitive, factor prices are given by marginal products.

Hence,

w = (1− α)z(zl/k)−α, (6)

and

r0 = α(zl0/k0)1−α + χ. (7)

It is time to define the competitive equilibrium under study.

Definition: A stationary competitive equilibrium consists of a set of n threshold

values Λ = λ1, ...,λn, a set of allocation rules Aj(λ), Pj(λ), and Tj(λ) for

j = 1, ..., n, and a set of wage and rental rates, w and r, such that

1. The allocation rules Aj(λ) and Pj(λ) solve problem P(1) to P(3), given

w, r, and q.

2. The allocation rule Tj(λ) solves problem P(1) to P(3), given w, r, and q.

3. Factor prices clear all markets, implying that (4) to (7) hold.

Balanced Growth: Represent the pace of labor-augmenting technological progress

by γ so that γ = z0/z. Let z0 = 1 so that zt = γt. Conjecture that y, m, i, d,

and k all grow at this rate too. Also, posit that along a balanced-growth path the

aggregate stock of labor, l, is constant. This conjecture is consistent with the forms

of (1) to (3). This implies from (6) and (7) that r is constant over time, while w

grows at rate γ. It remains to be shown that Ajt+1(λ) = γAj

t(λ), Pjt+1(λ) = Pj

t(λ),

and Tjt+1(λ) = Tj

t(λ). Observe that this solution will be consistent with the factor

market-clearing conditions (4) and (5).

16

Page 19: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Lemma 1 Along a balanced growth path, Ajt+1(λ) = γAj

t(λ), Pjt+1(λ) = Pj

t(λ), and

Tjt+1(λ) = Tj

t(λ).

Proof. Suppose that along a balanced-growth path V j+1(γa, τ ,λ; γw) = V j+1(a, τ ,λ;w)+

[(1 − βn−j)/(1 − β)] ln γ.11 Now, by eyeballing problems P(1) to P(3) it is easy

to see that if Aj(a, τ ,λ;w) and P j(a, τ ,λ;w) are the solutions to these problems

when the state of world is (a, τ ,λ;w), then Aj(γa, τ ,λ; γw) = γAj(a, τ ,λ;w) and

P j(γa, τ ,λ; γw) = P j(a, τ ,λ;w) are the solutions when the state of the world is

given by (γa, τ ,λ; γw). It then follows that V jt (γa, τ ,λ; γw) = Vjt (a, τ ,λ;w) + [(1 −

βn−j+1)/(1− β)] ln γ. Finally, note from problem P(4) that T j(a,λ) = T j(γa,λ; γw).Therefore, if Aj(a, τ ,λ;w), P j(a, τ ,λ;w) and T j(γa,λ; γw) solve problems P(1) to

P(3) today — when the state is (a, τ ,λ;w) — then γAj(a, τ ,λ;w), P j(a, τ ,λ;w) and

T j(a,λ;w) will solve them tomorrow — when the state will be (γa, τ ,λ; γw).

5 Findings

5.1 Some Preliminary Analysis

Calibration: Take the period for the model to be 5 years. Let n = 10 so that a

household has a working life of 50 years. Clearly, ω, η, and ρ can be pinned down

from time-use data. For instance, in a week there are 112 non-sleeping hours available

per adult. If full-time work involves a 40 hour workweek, then ω = 0.36. In 1900

about 58 hours a week were spent on housework, while in 1965 roughly 15 were.

So, set η = 0.13 and ρη = 0.52. Next, pick φ = 0.60, approximately the ratio of

female to male earnings in 1980. This leaves the parameters κ, µ, and ν. In 1929

the stock of appliances was about $5,272 mil. (in 1982$) while in 1959 it was $32,882

mil. Hence, κ = 4.1. The lognormal distribution for λ was discretized so that

11Note that the household’s problem is a function of w and r. Hence, these factor prices should

be entered into the value functions. Since r is constant along a balanced-growth path it has been

suppressed in the value function.

17

Page 20: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

λ ∈ Λ ≡ λ1, ...,λ100. The skill distribution was parameterized by setting σ = 0.70.Now, the two utility parameters µ and ν are set so the model’s balanced growth

displays the two features discussed momentarily. This required picking µ = 0.33 and

ν = 0.20.

The Household Sector, circa 1900 : Imagine that the time is 1900. Virtually no one

owns an electrical appliance. This situation can be obtained in the model by setting

the price of durables high, say q = 20 — this implies that the median person would

have to work 100 years to earn the income required to purchase modern durables.

The annual interest rate for the model is 7.1 percent. This lies above the rate of time

preference. Associated with this interest rate is a market investment to output ratio

of 0.15.

At this time in history, almost all married women stayed at home. In 1890 Goldin

(1987, Table 1) reports that only 5 percent of all married women worked. Sur-

prisingly, female labor-force participation is not a function of income when nobody

adopts the new technology. Hence, female labor-force participation must be some

fraction contained in the set 1/n, 2/n, ..., 1. With the adopted calibration, 10 per-cent (1/10×100%) of women work. The standard deviation (for the ln) of householdincome in the model is 0.70.

Lemma 2 If Tj(λ) = 0 for all j = 1, ..., n and λ ∈ Λ, then Pj(λ) = πj for all j and

λ.

Proof. Take a household of type λ. It’s market consumption decision must satisfy

the Euler equation

1

mj(λ)= βr

1

mj+1(λ), (8)

Using the household budget constraint, this implies that

mj(λ) = (βr)j−1 1− β1− βnΩ(λ),

18

Page 21: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

where Ω(λ) is the present-value of the household’s income — at age 1 — net of the cost

of purchasing consumer durables. Since the household doesn’t adopt, Ω(λ) is given

by

Ω(λ) =nXj=1

wλω + φwλωPj(λ)

(r)j−1= wλω[

1− 1/rn1− 1/r + φ

nXj=1

Pj(λ)

(r)j−1].

It is then easy to calculate that lifetime utility is given by

V 1(0, 0,λ) = µ1− βn

1− β [ln(1− β1− βn ) + lnΩ(λ)] +

nXj=1

(j − 1)βj−1 ln(βr)+ ν 1− βn

1− β ln δ (9)

+(1− µ− ν)nXj=1

βj−1Pj(λ) ln(2− 2ω − ρη) + [1−Pj(λ)] ln(2− ω − ρη).

Now, there are 2n − 1 other possible work combinations. Let P∗j(λ) denote some

other arbitrary work profile and V∗1(0, 0,λ) represent the lifetime utility associated

with this particular participation sequence. To obtain V∗1(0, 0,λ) replace Pj(λ) with

P∗j(λ) in (9). For Pj(λ) to be optimal it must happen that V 1(0, 0,λ) ≥ V ∗1(0, 0,λ).

Observe that V 1(0, 0,λ)−V ∗1(0, 0,λ) is not a function of λ, however.12 Hence, Pj(λ)

cannot be a function of λ.

The Household Sector, circa 1980 : Now, move ahead to 1980. Almost everybody

owns electrical appliances. This situation transpires in the model when q = 0.04.

If a period is 5 years then there are about 8,800 working hours (5 yrs. × 11 mths.

× 4 wks. × 40 hrs.) per adult. Hence, the median male would only need to work

about 350 hours to purchase modern appliances. The steady-state interest rate is

7.01 percent, which lies above the rate of time preference. At this interest rate, the

investment-to-output ratio is 0.15. This is not far off from the postwar average of

0.11. Appliance investment amounts to 0.64 percent of GDP.

About one half of married women work now, in line with Goldin (1987, Table 1).

When everybody adopts the new technology immediately, female-labor participation

is a decreasing function of household income. This is proved in the lemma below.

12Note that lnΩ(λ) = ln(wλω) + ln[(1− 1/rn)/(1− 1/r) + φPnj=1 Pj(λ)/rj−1].

19

Page 22: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

10 30 50 70 90

Type -- lowest to highest

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1.0Pa

rtici

patio

n R

ate

Figure 6: Female Labor-Force Participation

Figure 6 illustrates the situation for the case when q = 0.04.Women from more well-

to-do households retire earlier. (Just multiply the participation rate by 10 to get the

period a women retires in.) The standard deviation for (the ln of) household income

is 0.71.

Lemma 3 The present value of labor-force participation,Pn

j=1 pj/rj−1, is nonin-

creasing in type, λ, holding fixed the date of adoption, m. Similarly,Pn

j=1 pj/rj−1 is

nonincreasing in m, holding fixed λ.

Proof (by contradiction). Consider two types of households, λ∗ and λ∗∗

with λ∗ < λ∗∗. Let p∗j denote the optimal participation policy associated with λ∗,

and p∗∗j represent the corresponding policy linked with λ∗∗. Analogously, let B∗1(λ)

and B∗∗1(λ) be the period-1 lefthand sides of the Bellman equations connected with

20

Page 23: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

the policies. These can be obtained by replacing Pj(λ) in (9) with p∗j and p∗∗j,

respectively, and adding [(βm−1 − βn)/(1− β)]ν lnκ.Suppose that the hypothesis is not true. Then, there exists a λ∗ and λ∗∗ such

that B∗1(λ∗) > B∗∗1(λ∗), B∗1(λ∗∗) < B∗∗1(λ∗∗), andPn

j=1 p∗j/rj−1 <

Pnj=1 p

∗∗j/rj−1.

Now, observe from the analogue to (9) that, B∗1(λ) − B∗∗1(λ) = µ[(1 − βn)/(1 −β)]ln[Ω∗(λ)/ lnΩ∗∗(λ)]. Here Ω∗(λ) and Ω∗∗(λ) are the levels of permanent income(net of adoption cost) associated with the p∗j and p∗∗j policies. Now,

d[B∗1(λ)−B∗∗1(λ)]dλ

= µ1− βn1− β

q/rm−1φλω2Pn

j=1[p∗∗j − p∗j]/(r)j−1

Pnj=1[wλω + φwλωp

∗j/(r)j−1]− q/rm−12

Ω∗∗(λ)Ω∗(λ)

> 0.

Consequently, if B∗1(λ∗) > B∗∗1(λ∗), then B∗1(λ∗∗) > B∗∗1(λ∗∗). The desired contra-

diction obtains. The proof for the second part of the hypothesis parallels the first,

mutatis mutandis.

Pursuing Happiness: The second industrial revolution made women worse off, or

so you might believe from reading the sociology literature. The lot of families in

the artificial economy can be examined. Compare the 1900 and 1980 steady states.

As a result of new, more productive household capital, GDP rises by 24 percent.

It may be tempting to conclude that the gain in welfare must be less than this.

After all, the increase in GDP occurs because more women are working. In fact,

welfare increases by 50 percent, when measured in terms of market consumption.

The new technology leads to a 23 percent increase in market consumption, a 50

percent increase in nonmarket consumption, and a 21 percent increase in leisure.13

Now, take a family living in 1980. They will reside at some percentile in the income

13Parente, Rogerson and Wright (2000) show that when household production is incorporated

into the standard neoclassical growth model, cross-country differences in welfare are smaller than

cross-country differences in GDP. In their framework cross-country income differentials are due to

policy distortions. A tax on market activity reduces GDP. Welfare drops by less than GDP, though,

because there is an increase in nonmarket activity. In the current paper, technological progress leads

to a rise in all items in the utility function.

21

Page 24: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

distribution and have an associated level of utility. At what spot in the 1900 income

distribution would a family have to be located in order to realize this same level of

utility? Figure 7 gives the answer. For instance, a poor family at the 20th percentile

in 1980 is as well off as someone living in the 55th percentile in 1900. Trivially, (in

a distortion-free competitive equilibrium) a family wouldn’t adopt a new technology

if it made them worse off; after all, they are pursuing happiness.14 The analysis

here models the household from the perspective that members share a common set

of preferences. Suppose they didn’t. It seems likely that any reasonable bargaining

model would predict that both males and females would share in the gain from the

second industrial revolution.

The Effect of Declining Prices: Between 1900 and 1980 the prices for household

appliances must have dropped dramatically. The time path of prices has a big impact

on adoption and participation decisions. To see this, hold the interest rate fixed at

7 percent and imagine that prices fall 5 percent a year starting from an initial value

of 2.0. Figure 8 tells the story. About 5 percent of households adopt immediately.

14This isn’t the view held by many social historians. On the one hand, they believe that “the

change from the laundry tub to the washing machine is no less profound than the change from

the hand loom to the power loom; the change from pumping water to turning on a water faucet

is no less destructive of traditional habits than the change from manual to electric calculating” —

Cowan (1976, pp. 8-9). On the other hand, they feel that a change in societal tastes, generated

by commercial interests, enslaved women into undertaking new tasks by making them feel guilty

if “their infants had not gained enough weight, embarrassed if their drains clogged, guilty if their

children went to school in soiled clothes, guilty if all the germs behind the bathroom sink are not

eradicated, guilty if they fail to notice the first sign of an oncoming cold, embarrassed if accused of

having body odor, guilty if their sons go to school without good breakfasts, guilty if their daughters

are unpopular because of old-fashioned, or unironed, or — heaven forbid — dirty dressed” – Cowan

(1976, p. 16). To most producing clean clothes for school is a utility generating activity. So, these

sociologists must believe that society has been duped by advertising campaigns, etc. into having

these tastes. Cowan (1976, p. 23) ends with “how long ... can we continue to believe that we will

have orgasms while waxing the kitchen floor.” Well according to Mark Twain, “It isn’t what we

don’t know that kills us, it’s everything we know that ain’t so.”

22

Page 25: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

New Income Distribution -- Fractile

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Old

Inco

me

Dis

tribu

tion

-- Fr

actil

e

Figure 7: A Utilitarian View of Economic Development

23

Page 26: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

The higher a household’s type, the earlier they adopt. In order to acquire consumer

durables the woman in a household may have to go to work. That is, in line with

the lemma, adoption goes hand in hand with increased labor effort.15 In most cases

the woman goes to work before the durables are purchased. As λ rises from λ1 to

λ64 labor effort increases continuously as households adopt at successively earlier

dates. Holding fixed the adoption date, however, labor effort is decreasing in type —

as was proved in the previous lemma. For example, from λ78 to λ100 all households

adopt immediately; hence, the adoption date is fixed here. Labor effort decreases

continuously as the lemma states.

It may seem that theoretically the date of adoption should be a nonincreasing

function of λ. This is difficult to establish, though, given the lumpy nature of the

adopt and work decisions. The lumpy nature of these decisions can be partially

smoothed out by increasing the number of periods that a household lives while holding

fixed its lifespan; i.e., by shortening the length of a period.

Lemma 4 Along a balanced growth path the date of adoption is a nonincreasing

function in type, at least when the length of a period is sufficiently short.

Proof. See Appendix.

5.2 Some More Evidence

U.S. Evidence: So, what is the relationship between the adoption of appliances and

female labor-force participation? The evidence is scant. Still, here it is. Some

state-by-state data on the quantity of appliances sold is available from Electrical

Merchandising (1957). From this a crude measure of the stock of household appliances

15Take the case where the type distribution is continuous. Consider some threshold value of λ

and a local neighborhood around it. Suppose that above this value of λ the household adopts at

some date ς, while below it they adopt at some later date, say ς + j where the integer j ≥ 1. As thethreshold is crossed the adoption date jumps forward, but λ remains more or less fixed. Hence, the

lemma applies.

24

Page 27: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

0 3 6 9

Period

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

Num

ber o

f Ado

pter

s in

Per

iod

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

Pric

e

Price

Adopters

20 50 80

Type -- lowest to highest

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Labo

r-for

ce P

artic

ipat

ion

Rat

e --

fem

ales

0

2

4

6

8

Perio

d of

Ado

ptio

n

Period

Part.

Figure 8: The Effect of Prices on Adoption and Participation

25

Page 28: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 1800

Stock of Appliances

0.20

0.25

0.30Fe

mal

e La

bor-F

orce

Par

ticip

atio

n

Figure 9: The State-by-State Relationship between Female Labor-Force Participation

and Appliance Ownership

per family can be constructed for each state. In particular, this source presents data

for washers, dryers, refrigerators, electric stoves, freezers, ironers, and electric water

heaters. For each appliance the total numbers of units sold over the twelve year

period 1946-1957 is reported. The resulting numbers can then be summed across

appliances, after multiplying each figure by the price of the appliance. These figures

can be normalized by the number of families in the state, as reported in the 1950

U.S. Decennial Census, to obtain a measure of household capital per family. State-

by-state female labor-force participation numbers can be computed from the 1950

census. The relationship between these two series is plotted in Figure 9. There is

no question that, visually, appliance ownership is positively associated with female

labor-force participation.

To test the robustness of this relationship, female labor-force participation (part)

26

Page 29: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

will be regressed against appliance ownership (appl), plus some additional control

variables. The control variables are the ratio of females with some high school educa-

tion in the state (edu), per-capita income in the state (inc), the extent of urbanization

(urb), and some regional dummies.16 The result obtained is

part = −0.01(0.00032)

+0.000040(0.000023)

× appl+ 0.365869(0.221326)

× edu+ 0.043235(0.071375)

× log(inc)

+ 0.000629(0.000344)

× urb+ dummies,

with r2 = 0.60, σ = 0.024, obs = 48, d.f. = 40.

All coefficients have the expected signs. All are significant, except for the level of per-

capita income in a state. As can be seen, appliance ownership is positively associated

with female labor-force participation. The coefficient, if interpreted literally, implies

that a $1,000 increase in the per-capital stock of appliances in a state will be associated

with a 4.0 percentage point rise in female labor-force participation.

International Evidence: Countries where new durable goods are expensive tend

to have low levels of female labor-force participation. Here is the evidence. The Penn

World Table (Version 5.6) presents some national income account statistics for a

number of countries. By dividing the price of investment goods through by the GDP

deflator, a measure of the relative price of durables can be obtained. Strictly speaking

one would like a measure of the price of household equipment. This isn’t available.

The price of new equipment in the business sector is probably a reasonable proxy

for the price of new equipment in the household sector. The behavior of the relative

price of automobiles, computers, refrigerators, stoves, etc. used in the business sector

across time and space is likely to be similar to the relative price of these goods

used in the household sector. A measure of female labor-force participation can be

computed using data available from the Economically Active Population, 1950-2010,

a publication of the International Labor Office. In particular, the ratio of female

employees to total employees in industry and services will be taken as proxy for16Regions are classified in line with Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995, Table 10.4)

27

Page 30: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

female labor-force participation. This excludes the agricultural sector. Handling the

agricultural sector is a tricky issue. First, the ILO data treats any woman who works

more than one hour a week in agriculture as being employed there. For less-developed

countries this weak restriction will be satisfied by most rural women. The tendency

to count rural adults as agricultural workers, irrespective of the time they allocate

to this sector, has been noted by Parente, Rogerson and Wright (2000). Second, in

less-developed countries a lot of agriculture is really household production, at least

for the purposes here. A panel data set of 128 countries can be complied from these

two data sources. The time interval is a decade, starting with 1950 and ending in

1990. For some countries an observation was not available for each decade.

To judge the significance of the relationship, female labor-force participation

(part) can be regressed against the relative price of durables (price) and some control

variables. The control variables are GDP per worker (inc) and dummy variables for

decades and regions.17 The result is:

part = 0.27− 0.011(0.0036)

× price+ 0.022(0.0121)

× inc+ dummies,

r2 = 0.46, σ = 0.08, obs = 512, d.f. = 499.

The price and income variables take the expected sign. Both are significant18.

The cross-sectional relationship between durable goods prices and female labor-

force participation for 1990 in plotted Figure 10. Here, the relative price of durables

is deflated by GDP per worker to obtain a measure of the time price of durables.

It’s easy to see that higher durable goods prices are associated with a lower level of

female labor-force participation. The figure also graphs the steady-state relationship

between household appliance prices and female labor-force participation predicted by

17The seven regions are Africa (except North Africa), Asia (sans the Middle East), Europe, Middle

East (plus North Africa), North and Central America, Pacific Region, and South America. This

classification is taken from Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995, Table 10.3).18For 1990 there is data on the fraction of the population with a primary or secondary education.

These variables turned out to be insignificant.

28

Page 31: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

-4.5 -4.0 -3.5 -3.0 -2.5 -2.0 -1.5

Ln(q)

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Fem

ale

Labo

r-Fo

rce

Par

ticip

atio

n

Model

Figure 10: The World-Wide Relationship between the Price of New Durables and

Female Labor-Force Participation, 1990

the model.19 The relationship generated by the model is not dissimilar to the one

found in the international data. This exercise heroically assumes that each country

was resting in its steady-state in the last decade. Don’t take this seriously. The

mapping generated by the model is shown just to illustrate how the model can be

used to shed light on some historical and geographical facts.

5.3 The Durable Goods Revolution

The Computational Experiment : The time is 1900. The age of electricity has just

dawned. This era herds in many new household goods: the dryers, frozen foods, hot

water, refrigerators, washing machines, etc. What will be the effect in the artificial

19The price series inputted into the model has been normalized (multiplied by scalar) to make the

price for U.S. in 1990 equal to 0.04.

29

Page 32: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

economy? To answer this, the transition path from the 1900 steady state to the 1980

one will be analyzed. This experiment is in the spirit of King and Rebelo’s (1993)

analysis of the inability of the standard neoclassical growth model to explain the rise

of postwar Japan, Hansen and Prescott’s (1999) study of the pickup in growth from

1800 on, and Caselli and Coleman’s (forth.) research on the catch up of the southern

states.

To do this, a time path for durable goods prices must be inputted into the model.

Hard numbers are hard to come by, but Figure 11 plots several price series for appli-

ances. The NIPA measure for appliances declines at about 2.2 percent a year, relative

to the GDP deflator. This is likely to underestimate the decline in prices because

it doesn’t control for quality improvement in goods. The figure also shows Gordon’s

(1990, Table 7.23) quality-adjusted price index for eight appliances, viz refrigerators,

air conditioners, washing machines, clothes dryers, TV sets, dishwashers, microwaves,

and VCR’s. This series drops at 8.5 percent a year versus only 3.5 percent for the

standard PPI measure. Note that time prices will decline at an even faster clip, since

wages have risen over time. Quality-adjusted time prices for some select appliances

are shown in Figure 12.20 Assume, then, that time prices decline on average at about

5 percent a year for the first 100 years. The analysis also presumes that agents have

perfect foresight; a heroic assumption, for sure.

Adoption and Labor-Force Participation: The new appliances catch on slowly at

first. This can be seen from Figure 13, which plots the diffusion curve. It takes 50

years for half of the population to own the durables. Female labor-force participation

rises along with adoption. This is shown in Figure 13, too. Only wealthy households

— high types — can afford to buy when prices are high. The diffusion curves for three

age-averaged types of households, λ1, λ50, and λ100, are graphed in Figure 14.

Pursuing Happiness, Again: The increase in GDP due to the durable goods rev-

olution is shown in Figure 15. This rise occurs solely because of the increase in

20These are based on series contained in Gordon (1990, Tables 7.4, 7.12, 7.15, and 7.22)

30

Page 33: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990Year

0.1

0.5

0.9

1.3

Pric

e of

App

lianc

es --

NIP

A

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Pric

e of

App

lianc

es --

Gor

don

and

PPI

NIPA, 2.2%

Gordon, 8.5%

PPI, 3.5%

Figure 11: Decline in the Relative Price of Appliances

31

Page 34: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

1950 1960 1970 1980

Year

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Tim

e Pr

ice

of A

pplia

nces

, q

Refridgerators, 8.1%

Microwaves, 12.8%

Dryers, 8.7%

Washers, 5.7%

Dishwashers, 5.7%

Figure 12: Prices for Some Select Appliances

32

Page 35: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

0 40 80 120

Time, years

0

20

40

60

80

100

Perc

enta

ge

0

2

4

6

8

10

Pric

e, q

Diffusion

Participation

Price

Figure 13: Transitional Dynamics — Diffusion and Female Labor-Force Participation

33

Page 36: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

0 20 40 60 80 100

Time, years

0

20

40

60

80

100

Perc

enta

ge

Median

Lowest

Highest

Figure 14: Diffusion by Type of Household

34

Page 37: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

0 40 80 120

Time, years

2.5

2.6

2.7

2.8

2.9

3.0

Gdp

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Com

pens

atin

g Va

riatio

n

c.v.

gdp

Figure 15: The Gain in GDP and Welfare

35

Page 38: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

female labor-force participation. Other than the durable goods revolution there is no

technological progress. The associated rise in welfare — for the flow of new households

into the economy — is also plotted in this figure. Again, the gain in welfare is greater

than the increase in GDP.

Between 1929 and 1999 per-capita real GDP grew at 2.2 percent per annum. Take

this as reflective of the average rate of growth over the last century. In the model

over a 50 year period GDP grows by about 0.35 percent per annum, while for an 80

year period it grows by about 0.22 percent. Therefore, according to the model, the

durable goods revolution can be thought of as accounting for about 15 percent of

growth, say, between 1920 and 1970, or about 10 percent of growth between 1900 to

1980.

6 Conclusions

“For ages woman was man’s chattel, and in such condition progress for

her was impossible; now she is emerging into real sex independence, and

the resulting outlook is a dazzling one. This must be credited very largely

to progression in mechanics; more especially to progression in electrical

mechanics.

Under these new influences woman’s brain will change and achieve

new capabilities, both of effort and accomplishment.”

Thomas Alva Edison, as interviewed in Good Housekeeping Magazine,

LV, no. 4 (October 1912, p. 440)

Did technological progress unlock the manacles chaining women to the home?

That’s the question posed here. Some may argue that the increase in female labor-

force participation was due to a change in social norms, say spawned by the women’s

liberation movement. After reviewing public opinion poll evidence, Oppenheimer

(1970, p. 51) concludes “it seems unlikely that we can attribute much of the enor-

36

Page 39: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

mous postwar increases in married women’s labor force participation to a change in

attitudes about the propriety of their working.”21 Besides without the labor-saving

household capital ushered in by the second industrial revolution it simply would not

have been feasible for many women to spend more time outside of the home, notwith-

standing any shift in societal attitudes. While sociology may have acted as a fertilizer,

the seed of women’s liberation came from economics.

A Appendix

Growth Transformation: Consider the consumption decision for an age-1 household.

It must satisfy the Euler equation

1

mj= βr

1

mj+1, (10)

wheremj is the household’s consumption at age j. The household’s budget constraint

will read

m1 +m2

r+m3

r2+ ...+

mn

rn−1= Ω,

where Ω is the household’s permanent income, net of the cost of purchasing the

consumer durables. The Euler equation (10) implies that mj+1 = βrmj = (βr)jm1.

Therefore,

m1 =1− β1− βnΩ.

21Unfortunately the questions asked are different both across polling organizations and years —

see Oppenheimer (1970, Table 2.10). In 1960 only 34 percent of respondents answered approvingly

to the following question: “There are many wives who have jobs these days. Do you think it is

a good thing for a wife to work or a bad thing, or what? Why do you say so?” A poll in 1937

asked the question “Do you approve a married women earning money in business or industry if

she has a husband capable of supporting her?” Eighteen percent of respondents approved. The

same percentage answered favorably to a similar question in 1945. When questions were qualified

to indicate some sort of financial need — support for children, a new marriage, etc. — the percentage

of favorable responses went up.

37

Page 40: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Adding growth would not seem to change this equation much. All variables that

grow along a balanced path should be transformed to obtain a stationary representa-

tion. Define ajt = ajt/γ

t, bmjt = m

jt/γ

t, bwt = wt/γt, and bΩt = Ωt/γt. Then, the Eulerequation would appear as

1bmjt

= β(r/γ)1bmj+1t+1

.

The household’s budget constraint now reads

bm1t +

bm2t+1

(r/γ)+

bm3t+2

(r/γ)2+ ...+

bmnt+n−1

(r/γ)n−1= bΩt.

Therefore,

bm1 =1− β1− βn

bΩ.Here

bΩt = nXj=1

bwλω + φbwλωP j(λ)− bwqT j(λ)(r/γ)j−1

,

where

bw = (1− α)[r/γ − χα

]α/(α−1), (11)

and

r/γ = α(l/bk)1−α + χ.Last, the market clearing condition for capital would appear as

bk0 = nXj=1

Z bAj(λ)L(dλ).

Transitional Dynamics: Imagine that the economy is resting in some initial steady-

state. Since the electric age hasn’t emerged yet, all households are using primitive

durables at home. Now, suppose that suddenly new household durables are invented.

38

Page 41: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

At the time of the durable goods revolution, the initial state of the economy is de-

scribed by s = (a2(λ), a3(λ), ..., an(λ)). The system will eventually converge to a

new steady state represented by s = (a2∗(λ), a3∗(λ), ..., an∗(λ)), where an asterisk

attached to a variable signifies its value in the new steady state. Assume that this

convergence will take place within e + 1 periods. The time path of prices for these

goods is given by q1 > q2 > ... ≥ qe−m = qe+1 = q∗. The algorithm used to compute

the model’s transitional dynamics can now be outlined.

1. Enter each iteration i with a guess for the interest rate path, or −→r 2 = rte+1t=2 .

Denote this guess by −→r i2 = rite+1t=2 . Using (11) this will imply a guess for wages

−→w i2 = wite+1

t=2 . Note that by assumption re+1 = r∗ and we+1 = w

∗.

2. Using this guess, solve out for−→s 1 = ste+1t=1 . This is done as in the manner

below:

(a) Enter period t with state of world st, which was computed in the previous

period t − 1. For each j and λ solve the household’s decision problemsto obtain Aj

t(λ), Pjt(λ), and Tj

t(λ). Set st+1 = (A2t (λ), A

3t (λ), ..., A

nt (λ)).

Move onto period t+ 1 (unless t = e, in which case you’re finished).

(b) For age-j agent, with skill level λ, permanent income in period t will be

given by the formula22

bΩjt(λ) = ritaj + n−jXm=0

bwt+m[λω + φλωP j+m(λ)− qt+mT j+m(λ)]Πt+mk=t+1(r

ik/γ)

.

(c) The period−t market clearing wage can be obtained by finding the bwt suchthat (4) holds. Set bwt+m = wit+m for m > 0.

Compute a revised guess for the interest rate path −→r 2, denoted by −→r i+12 , using

the formula

ri+1t+1/γ = α(lt+1/bkt+1)

1−α + χ.

22In this formula, Πtn=t+1 ≡ 1.

39

Page 42: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

It may be better to set

ri+1t+1/γ = ϑ[α(lt+1/bkt+1)

1−α + χ] + (1− ϑ)rit+1/γ, for 0 < ϑ < 1.

Lemma 4: Along a balanced growth path the date of adoption is a nonincreasing

function in type, at least when the length of a period is sufficiently short.

Proof. Consider the continuous-time analogue to the adopt/work problem framed

by P(1) to P(4). Let the date of adoption chosen by the household be represented by

α. The household will choose an interval [σ, ε] ⊆ [0, n] over which to work. Here σdenotes the start date for working and ε denotes the end date. As an example of how

things work, take the case where σ = 0 < α < ε < n. Here the woman in a household

starts working immediately, builds up some resources to purchase durables at age α,

and then retires at ε. A type-λ household’s decision problem is

maxα,εµ1− e

−βn

β[ln(

β

1− e−βn ) + lnΩ(λ)] + µZ n

0

(r − β)je−βjdj

+ν1− e−βn

βln δ + ν lnκ

Z n

α

e−βjdj + (1− µ− ν)[ln(2− 2ω − ρη)Z α

0

e−βjdj

+ ln(2− 2ω − η)Z ε

α

e−βjdj + ln(2− ω − η)Z n

ε

e−βjdj],

subject to

Ω(λ) = wλω1− e−rn

r+ φwλω

Z ε

0

e−rjdj − qwe−ια.

Now, r represents the net interest rate and β is the rate of time preference.

The first-order conditions to this problem are:

µ1− e−βnβ

wqιe−(r−β)α = [(1− µ− ν) ln( 2− 2ω − η2− 2ω − ρη ) + ν lnκ]Ω(λ),

and

µ1− e−βn

βφwλωe−(r−β)ε = (1− µ− ν) ln( 2− ω − η

2− 2ω − η )Ω(λ).

40

Page 43: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

Undertaking the requisite comparative statics exercise gives

dλ= [(1− µ− ν) ln( 2− 2ω − η

2− 2ω − ρη ) + ν lnκ](wω/r)[1− e−rn + φ(1− e−εr)]

× (r − β)µ(1− e−rn)φwλωe−(r−β)ε

β det(H)< 0,

where H is the 2 × 2 Hessian associated with the maximum problem. To sign the

above expression, note that the second-order conditions for a maximum necessitate

that the matrix H is negative semidefinite. Necessary conditions for this to transpire

are that det(H) ≥ 0 and H11,H22 ≤ 0, where H11 and H22 are the entries in upper

left and lower righthand corner of H. When r > β it is easy to see that dα/dλ < 0.

When r < β it can be shown that a maximum cannot obtain, since H11,H22 < 0 then

imply det(H) < 0. There are many other cases to consider, but they all proceed in

the same manner. (Basically, the rest of the proof is a boring taxonomy.)

References

[1] Barro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. Economic Growth. New York: Mc-

Graw Hill, Inc, 1995.

[2] Becker, Gary S. “A Theory of the Allocation of Time.” Economic Journal, 75

no. 299 (September 1965): 493-517.

[3] Benhabib, Jess, Richard Rogerson and Randall Wright. “Homework inMacroeco-

nomics: Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations.” Journal of Political

Economy, 99, no. 6, (December 1991): 1166-1187.

[4] Burwell, Calvin C. and Blair G. Sweezy. “The Home: Evolving Technologies for

Satisfying Human Wants.” In Electricity in the American Economy: Agent of

Technological Progress edited by Sam H. Schurr, Calvin C., Burwell, Warren D.

Devine, and Sidney Sonenblum. New York: Greenwood Press. 1990.

41

Page 44: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

[5] Caselli, Francesco and Wilbur John Coleman II. “How Regions Converge” Jour-

nal of Political Economy, forthcoming.

[6] Cowan, Ruth Schwartz. “The ‘Industrial Revolution’ in the Home: Household

Technology and Social Change in the 20th Century”, Technology and Culture,

17, no. 1 (January 1976): 1-23.

[7] Day, Tanis. “Capital-Labor Substitution in the Home.” Technology and Culture,

33, no. 2 (April 1992): 302-327.

[8] Durand, John D. The Labor Force in the United States, 1890-1960. New York:

Social Research Council, 1948.

[9] Electrical Merchandising, New York: McGraw-Hill Publications.

[10] Goldin, Claudia. “Women’s Employment and Technological Change: A Histor-

ical Perspective.” In Computer Chips and Paper Clips edited by Heidi I. Hart-

mann. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1987.

[11] Goldin, Claudia. Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of

American Women. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990.

[12] Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence F. Katz. “The Origins of Technology-Skill Com-

plementarity.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113 no. 3 (August 1998):

693-732.

[13] Gomme, Paul, Finn Kydland and Peter Rupert. “Home Production Meets Time-

to-Build”. Unpublished paper, Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of

Cleveland, 2000.

[14] Gordon, Robert J. The Measurement of Durable Goods Prices. Chicago: Univer-

sity of Chicago Press, 1990.

42

Page 45: Engines of Liberation - University of Torontohomes.chass.utoronto.ca/~siow/332/liberation.pdf · to purchase durable goods. The relative price of new goods tends to fall rapidly after

[15] Hansen, Gary D. and Edward C. Prescott. “Malthus to Solow.” Staff Report

257, Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1999.

[16] King, Robert G. and Sergio T. Rebelo. “Transitional Dynamics and Economic

Growth in the Neoclassical Model,” American Economic Review, 83, no. 4

(September 1993): 908-31.

[17] Krusell, Per, Lee Ohanian and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull. “Capital-Skill Comple-

mentarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis,” Econometrica 68, no. 5

(September 2000): 1029-1053.

[18] Lebergott, Stanley. The American Economy: Income Wealth and Want. Prince-

ton: Princeton University Press, 1976.

[19] Lebergott, Stanley. Pursuing Happiness: American Consumers in the Twentieth

Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993.

[20] Oppenheimer, Valerie Kincade. The Female Labor Force in the United States:

Demographic and Economic Factors Governing its Growth and Changing Com-

position. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California,

1970.

[21] Parente, Stephen L., Richard Rogerson and Randall Wright. “Homework in De-

velopment Economics: Household Production and the Wealth of Nations”, Jour-

nal of Political Economy, 108, no. 4 (August 2000): 680-687.

[22] Rios-Rull, Jose-Victor. “Working in the Market, Working at Home, and the

Acquisition of Skills: A General-Equilibrium Approach”, American Economic

Review, 83, no. 4 (September 1993): 893-907.

[23] Vanek, Joann. “Keeping Busy: Time Spent in Housework, United States, 1920-

1970.” Ph.D. Dissertation, The University of Michigan, 1973.

43