25
Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence B Asami Miketa a , Peter Mulder b, T a Science of Institutional Management of Technology Program, Tokyo Institute of Technology, Tokyo, Japan b Department of Spatial Economics, Free University, Amsterdam, The Netherlands Available online 30 March 2005 Abstract This paper provides an empirical analysis of energy-productivity convergence across 56 developed and developing countries, in 10 manufacturing sectors, for the period 1971–1995. We find that, except for the non-ferrous metals sector, cross-country differences in absolute energy-productivity levels tend to decline, particularly in the less energy-intensive industries. Testing for the catch-up hypothesis using panel data confirms that in all manufacturing sectors energy-productivity growth is, in general, relatively high in countries that initially lag behind in terms of energy-productivity levels. At the same time, cross-country differences in energy- productivity performance seem to be persistent; convergence is found to be local rather than global, with countries converging to different steady states and several failing to catch up. Finally, we find that country-specific factors, such as energy price and investment ratio, do 0140-9883/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2005.01.004 B This paper was mainly written when the authors worked at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Laxenburg, Austria. Peter Mulder gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Netherlands Organisation for Scientific Research (NWO). We wish to thank Henri de Groot and Leo Schrattenholzer as well as an anonymous referee for stimulating and useful comments on an earlier version of this paper. Any remaining errors are our responsibility. T Corresponding author. Department of Spatial Economics, Free University, Boelelaan 1105, 1081HV Amsterdam, The Netherlands. Tel.: +31 20 5986090; fax: +31 20 59846004. E-mail address: [email protected] (P. Mulder). Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429 – 453 www.elsevier.com/locate/eneco

Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453

www.elsevier.com/locate/eneco

Energy productivity across developed and

developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors:

Patterns of growth and convergenceB

Asami Miketaa, Peter Mulderb,TaScience of Institutional Management of Technology Program, Tokyo Institute of Technology, Tokyo, Japan

bDepartment of Spatial Economics, Free University, Amsterdam, The Netherlands

Available online 30 March 2005

Abstract

This paper provides an empirical analysis of energy-productivity convergence across 56

developed and developing countries, in 10 manufacturing sectors, for the period 1971–1995.

We find that, except for the non-ferrous metals sector, cross-country differences in absolute

energy-productivity levels tend to decline, particularly in the less energy-intensive industries.

Testing for the catch-up hypothesis using panel data confirms that in all manufacturing sectors

energy-productivity growth is, in general, relatively high in countries that initially lag behind in

terms of energy-productivity levels. At the same time, cross-country differences in energy-

productivity performance seem to be persistent; convergence is found to be local rather than

global, with countries converging to different steady states and several failing to catch up.

Finally, we find that country-specific factors, such as energy price and investment ratio, do

0140-9883/$ -

doi:10.1016/j.

B This paper

Analysis (IIA

Netherlands O

Schrattenholze

paper. Any rem

T Correspon

Amsterdam, T

E-mail add

see front matter D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

eneco.2005.01.004

was mainly written when the authors worked at the International Institute for Applied Systems

SA), Laxenburg, Austria. Peter Mulder gratefully acknowledges financial support from the

rganisation for Scientific Research (NWO). We wish to thank Henri de Groot and Leo

r as well as an anonymous referee for stimulating and useful comments on an earlier version of this

aining errors are our responsibility.

ding author. Department of Spatial Economics, Free University, Boelelaan 1105, 1081HV

he Netherlands. Tel.: +31 20 5986090; fax: +31 20 59846004.

ress: [email protected] (P. Mulder).

Page 2: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453430

explain the observed cross-country differences in energy-productivity performance, but only to a

very limited extent.

D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

JEL classification: O13; O50; Q43

Keywords: Energy efficiency; Energy intensity; Convergence; Sector analysis; Catch-up

1. Introduction

The changing picture of world energy use illustrates that economic development and

environmental problems have become global issues. Whereas energy consumption used

to be an issue mainly for the developed world, countries that are not members of the

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) are becoming

more and more important in this respect: their share of world primary energy

consumption increased from 33% in 1971 to 42% in 2001 (United Nations, 2001) and

is expected to rise substantially in the coming decades. This global increase in the

scale of energy demand comes at a certain price, including environmental externalities.

Consequently, it is becoming a matter of increasing international concern that economic

growth and environmental pressure should be decoupled, as evidenced by international

agreements on environmental policy such as the Kyoto Protocol that aims for a

worldwide reduction in greenhouse gas emissions. As energy use is a major source of

greenhouse gases, this not only implies a need for renewable energy sources but also

argues for a further improvement in energy efficiency or energy productivity across the

world.

Important questions thus arise concerning the international dimension of energy-

productivity dynamics. Are cross-country differences in energy-productivity perform-

ance decreasing or is the gap between leading and dbackwardT countries widening? Do

relatively energy-inefficient countries catch up with technological dleadersT and, if so,

how quickly and by what means? To answer these questions, this paper addresses two

closely related concepts: dconvergenceT and dcatch-upT. By convergence, we mean the

phenomenon of decreasing cross-country differences in energy-productivity levels. By

catch-up, we refer to the mechanism expressed by the hypothesis that bbeing backward

in level of productivity carries a potential for rapid advantageQ (Abramovitz, 1986).

The rationale behind this hypothesis is that countries lagging behind in terms of

productivity levels can benefit from the experience and technologies developed by

countries operating at the forefront, a process that might, of course, lead to

convergence of cross-country productivity performance. In this paper we provide an

empirical investigation of cross-country energy-productivity convergence and the catch-

up hypothesis, within 10 manufacturing sectors, using a new dataset for the period

between 1971 and 1995 that covers 56 countries, including 32 less industrialised or

developing countries.

The concept of productivity convergence has its roots in the traditional Solow–Swan

neoclassical growth model (Solow, 1956; Swan, 1956) with its central notion of a

Page 3: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 431

transitional growth path toward a steady state. The model postulates convergence of

income per worker driven by the assumption of diminishing returns to capital

accumulation at the economy-wide level. In addition, new or endogenous growth theory

(e.g., Lucas, 1988; Romer, 1986, 1990) stresses the role of international knowledge

spillovers in driving convergence, as this allows less productive countries to catch up with

more advanced economies by exploiting their dadvantage of backwardnessT (Gerschenk-ron, 1952). At the same time, however, new growth theory suggests that growth

differentials may persist, or even increase, because learning effects, externalities, and

market imperfections allow for increasing returns to capital accumulation and the existence

of multiple steady states on an economy-wide basis. These various approaches, in

combination with the availability of new cross-country datasets, have caused the

convergence hypothesis to be subjected to extensive empirical research and debate. In

this literature, the principal focus has been on cross-country convergence of per capita

income (e.g., Baumol, 1986; Abramovitz, 1986; DeLong, 1988; Barro, 1991; Barro and

Sala-i-Martin, 1992, 1995; Mankiw et al., 1992; Islam, 1995) and labour- and total-factor

productivity (e.g., Baumol et al., 1994; Islam, 2003a; van Ark and Crafts, 1996; Miller and

Upadhyay, 2002).1

In spite of many existing cross-country studies on energy-productivity or energy-

intensity developments and their determinants (e.g., Jorgenson, 1986; Howarth et al.,

1991; Miketa, 2001; Schipper and Meyers, 1992; Unander et al., 1999), systematic

analyses of convergence and catching up have, to date, been rare in the field of energy

economics. An example can be found in Mulder and de Groot (2003b) that provides a

comparison of energy- and labor-productivity convergence at a detailed sectoral level for

a number of OECD countries. We follow their approach, but our study is different in

that it includes a range of non-OECD countries,2 an exclusive focus on energy

productivity, and a more elaborate analysis of cross-country energy-productivity

dynamics. Except for its focus on energy productivity, our study differs from most

empirical convergence studies in the economic growth literature in considering a relatively

high degree of sectoral detail. This is important because a convergence analysis of

aggregate productivity developments may mask substantial differences in convergence

patterns at the sectoral level, as has been pointed out by the few detailed sectoral

convergence analyses available (Dollar and Wolff, 1988, 1993; Bernard and Jones,

1996a,b; Mulder and de Groot, 2003b).

The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we give a brief description of the data used

in this study and document some stylised facts regarding the past dynamics of energy

productivities both in developed (OECD) and developing (mostly non-OECD) countries.

In Section 3, we present a statistical analysis to measure the development of cross-country

variation of energy-productivity levels over time. In Section 4, we use an econometric

analysis to test, for each manufacturing sector, the proposition that energy-productivity

1 For more complete surveys of this literature, we refer to Durlauf and Quah (1999), Economic Journal (1996),

and Islam (2003b), among others.2 In this respect, our study also differs from most cross-country studies of energy-intensity developments, which

are mainly confined to OECD countries. An exception is Park et al. (1993).

Page 4: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453432

growth rates are inversely related to initial energy-productivity levels, indicating possible

patterns of catching up. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Data and stylised facts

The analysis presented in this paper is based on a newly constructed database of

manufacturing energy-productivity data covering the period between 1971 and 1995,

and includes 56 countries. Among those countries, we characterise 24 as industrialised

or developed countries and 32 as less industrialised or developing countries. The first

group consists of OECD countries of North America, the Pacific and western Europe,

while the second group includes mostly non-OECD countries. See Table A.1 in the

appendix for a detailed overview of the countries in each sector. Below, we briefly

describe the dataset.3 Furthermore, we distinguish 10 manufacturing industries, classified

according to the International Standard Industry Classification (ISIC) (Rev. 2), as shown in

Table 1.

Energy productivity is defined as output divided by final energy use and is thus the

inverse of energy intensity. Final energy-consumption data as well as data on consumption

of various energy types (coal, oil, electricity, natural gas, others) are expressed in tons of

oil equivalents (toe) and are taken from the International Energy Agency (IEA) publication

series, Energy Statistics and Balances. The sectoral output-value data are measured in

1990 U.S. dollars. They have been constructed using 1990 output values in combination

with the production (output) index at sub-industry level (at a three-digit level of ISIC),

subsequently aggregated into 10 manufacturing sectors (at the two-digit level). The

sectoral output data and the production index were taken from the Industrial Statistics

Database at the three-digit classification level, published by the United Nations Industrial

Development Organization (UNIDO). Missing data in this data source have been

estimated at the three-digit level using the physical production quantity data from the

United Nations Industrial Commodity Statistics.

In this paper we also use data on energy prices and investment ratios. Country-

specific, industrial energy end-use price series have been calculated as a weighted

average of aggregate industrial energy prices for the four main energy carriers:

petroleum products, natural gas, coal, and electricity. The country-specific weights of

these energy carriers in total energy consumption in the industrial sector were taken

from Energy Statistics and Balances of the IEA. The price for petroleum products is

calculated as a weighted average of liquefied petroleum gas (LPG), naphtha, gas/diesel

oil and heavy fuel oil. Industrial energy prices for natural gas, coal, and electricity were

taken from the IEA Energy Prices and Taxes series, the Energy Indicators of Developing

Member Countries of ADB published by the Asian Development Bank (ADB) and

Energy, Economic Statistics and Indicators of Latin America and the Caribbean

published by the Latin American Energy Organization (OLADE). Investment data

represent gross capital formation and are taken from the aforementioned UNIDO

3 A separate, unpublished document with a more detailed description of the database is available upon request.

Page 5: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table 1

Sector classification

Sector ISIC Rev. 2 code

1. Food and tobacco FOD 31

2. Textiles and leather TEX 32

3. Wood and wood products WOD 33

4. Paper, pulp and printing PAP 34

5. Chemicals CHE 35

6. Non-metallic minerals NMM 36

7. Iron and steel IAS 371

8. Non-ferrous metals NFM 372

9. Machinery MAC 381+382+383+385a

10. Transport equipment TRM 384

a MAC=fabricated metal products (381)+machinery except electrical (382)+machinery, electrical (383)+pro-

fessional and scientific equipment (385).

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 433

Industrial Statistics Database. Both energy price and investment data series are deflated

using the wholesale price index taken from the International Financial Statistics (IFS)

database of the International Monetary Fund (IMF).

Finally, all currency denominated variables are in constant 1990 U.S. dollars and have

been converted using 1990 market exchange rates taken from the IFS database of the IMF.

Theoretically, the most appropriate conversion factors for productivity comparisons at the

sectoral level are those based on a comparison of output prices by industry of origin (e.g.,

van Ark and Pilat, 1993). The main problem encountered when using this production or

industry-of-origin approach, however, is the limited availability of producer-price-based

purchasing power parities (PPPs), in particular for non-OECD countries (van Ark, 1993;

Pilat, 1996). Hence, expenditure-based PPPs or market exchange rates are commonly used

in cross-country studies, with each having its advantages and disadvantages.4 Market

exchange rates are, theoretically, an appropriate conversion factor, in particular with

respect to tradable goods (as is the case for most manufactured goods) and are available

both for OECD and non-OECD countries. However, they might suffer from the impact of

speculation or other specific peculiarities in the base year, implying a potentially biased

picture of market conditions concerning production and international trade. Therefore, the

results presented in this paper should be interpreted with caution, bearing in mind the

aforementioned issues. In the remainder of this section we document a few stylised facts

derived from our dataset.

The manufacturing sector is characterised by a substantial degree of heterogeneity in

terms of energy intensity. Table 2 gives some descriptive statistics for each sector. To

illustrate the heterogeneity, the first row of the table shows, for each manufacturing sector,

4 The main disadvantages of expenditure PPPs are: they exclude the part of output that is exported, while

including imported goods produced elsewhere; they take account of differences in trade and transport margins and

indirect taxes between countries; and they do not cover intermediate products. See Sørensen (2001) and Bernard

and Jones (2001) for a discussion of this issue in the context of empirical convergence analysis at the sectoral

level.

Page 6: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table 2

Weighted average annual growth rates 1975–1990

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD MAN

Relative level of energy productivity in 1990 (unweighted cross-industry average normalised to 100)

World 36 108 21 221 26 12 49 110 251 165 100

Weighted average annual growth rate 1975–1990a

World 0.86 0.81 2.4 0.63 2.14 0.41 1.45 0.26 0.9 0.88 1.07

Industrialised 1.2 1.22 2.69 0.27 2.26 0.39 1.46 0.07 0.98 1.07 1.16

Rest of world �0.84 �0.95 1.54 3.68 1.7 0.48 1.38 0.83 �3.96 �0.67 0.32

a The average is weighted with each country’s 1990 share of total output per sector. The values for MAN are

unweighted average of all manufacturing sectors.

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453434

an index of the cross-country average energy-productivity levels in 1990, normalised to

the unweighted cross-sector average (=100) in our database.

The table shows that roughly three groups of sectors can be distinguished within

manufacturing: (i) the energy-intensive sectors, non-metallic minerals (NMM), iron and

steel (IAS), non-ferrous metals (NFM), chemicals (CHE) and paper (PAP); (ii) the energy-

extensive sectors, transportation equipment (TRM), machinery (MAC), and wood (WOD);

and (iii) a medium group consisting of food (FOD) and textiles (TEX). These substantial

differences are naturally a consequence of some activities requiring more capital and

higher labor skills and/or technology than others, the result being that some sectors

produce more value added per unit of input than others. For that reason, the impact of a

shift in sectoral distribution of energy consumption (often referred to as structural change)

on aggregate energy-productivity growth can be substantial (e.g., Greening et al., 1997;

Howarth et al., 1991; Eichhammer and Mannsbart, 1997; Unander et al., 1999, Mulder and

de Groot, 2003a). Our sectoral approach implies that the sectoral energy-productivity

growth rates we report below result from technological change and intra-sectoral

structural change only, which implies a closer link with issues concerning international

technology diffusion, as raised in the convergence debate provoked by the new growth

theory.

In the lower part of Table 2 we summarize, for each manufacturing sector, the cross-

country average growth rate of energy productivity for the period between 1975 and 1990,

weighted by each country’s 1990 share of total output per sector. In addition to the cross-

country average growth rate for all countries in the database (dWorldT), we also show it for

industrialised countries (dIndustrialisedT) and less industrialised countries or developing

countries (dRest of WorldT). From the table it can be seen that the sectors differ

substantially also in terms of the dynamics of energy-productivity levels over time. In

general, the highest growth rates of energy productivity are to be found in energy-intensive

sectors rather than less energy-intensive sectors, and within the Industrialised regions

rather than within the Rest of World. In particular, the energy-intensive sectors, iron and

steel (IAS), non-ferrous metals (NFM), and paper (PAP) experienced rapid energy-

productivity growth in both regions. An important exception to this pattern, however, is

the most energy-intensive sector, non-metallic minerals (NMM), which experienced rather

slow energy-productivity growth, particularly in the Industrialised regions. In the sectors,

chemicals (CHE), food (FOD), transport equipment (TRM), and wood (WOD), modest

Page 7: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 435

energy-productivity growth took place in the Industrialised region, and negative-to-almost-

zero growth in the Rest of World. In the textile industry (TEX), energy-productivity

growth has been relatively slow in both regions. Machinery (MAC) is unique in showing

much higher energy-productivity growth in the group of less industrialised or developing

countries than within the Industrialised region. In the remaining part of the paper, we will

explore what these dynamics mean for the development of cross-country differences in

energy-productivity performance.

3. Cross-country differences

Our analysis of cross-country energy-productivity differences builds upon the

methodological framework provided by the convergence analyses in the empirical

growth literature, as briefly discussed in the introduction. From this literature, it

follows that convergence can be understood in terms of levels and growth rates, which

translates into a distinction between so-called r-convergence and b-convergence (e.g.,

Barro, 1991; Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1992). The former refers to a decreasing

variation of cross-country differences in productivity levels, while the latter suggests a

tendency of countries with relatively low initial productivity levels to grow relatively

fast, substantiating the catch-up hypothesis. In this section, we analyse the develop-

ment of the variation of energy-productivity levels across countries within each

manufacturing sector. The variation is measured by r, defined as the cross-country

standard deviation for the log of energy productivity.5 A decreasing cross-country

variation is therefore referred to as r-convergence. Table 3 displays the degree of cross-

country variation in energy-productivity levels per manufacturing sector between 1980 and

1990, again classified by our sample of Industrialised countries and Rest of World,

respectively.6

It can be seen from the table that, in most sectors, the cross-country differences in

absolute energy-productivity levels are declining in the Industrialised region as well as in

5 In the literature on convergence analysis, two measures of r-convergence are used interchangeably: (1) the

SD of the log of productivity ( y) and (2) the SD of productivity ( y) divided by the sample average. They

are defined, respectively, as follows: 1Þffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1n

Pni¼1 log yi � log y

PPPð Þ2q

; log yPPP ¼ 1

n

Pni¼1 log yi 2Þ

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1n

Pni¼1

yi�y

y

� �2r

; y ¼ 1n

Pni¼1 y. The

latter is usually referred to as the coefficient of variation. Dalgaard and Vastrup (2001) have shown that these

measures may lead to different conclusions because they assign different weights to individual countries’

performance. For this reason we also calculated the coefficient of variation to test for the robustness of our

results. We find both measures to yield an overall similar pattern of r-convergence, although there are some

differences in various sectors. Details are available upon request.6 It should be noted that for this analysis the sample of countries is kept the same to avoid a potential bias of

convergence evidence due to change in the list of countries included throughout the period. See Table A.1 in the

appendix for an overview of countries included per sector. The period between 1980 and 1990 was selected here

because this was the period with the highest level of data available for the greatest number of countries. We also

performed the analysis for the period 1975–1990 where we had to drop a number of countries because of

restricted data availability. Moreover, we did the analysis for a somewhat different sample of countries, making a

strict distinction between OECD and non-OECD countries. The results of these analyses revealed that although in

some sectors the level of dispersion is somewhat different as shown in Table 3, the overall pattern is similar.

Details are available upon request.

Page 8: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table 3

Standard deviation of log energy productivity per sector between 1980 and 1990

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

Standard deviation in 1980

World 1.14 0.91 1.16 1.20 0.91 1.10 1.08 0.75 0.75 1.45

Industrialised 0.65 0.70 0.90 0.49 0.72 0.72 0.83 0.60 0.54 1.05

Rest of world 1.42 1.16 1.45 1.75 1.08 1.12 1.25 0.76 1.62 1.53

Standard deviation in 1990

World 1.21 0.85 1.13 1.04 1.09 1.06 1.02 0.65 0.72 1.34

Industrialised 0.58 0.47 0.87 0.42 0.79 0.51 0.80 0.45 0.43 0.97

Rest of World 1.49 1.02 1.41 1.44 1.36 1.14 1.22 0.78 1.56 1.34

Percentage change between 1980 and 1990

World 6.4 �6.9 �2.6 �13.2 20.1 �3.4 �6.3 �12.8 �3.9 0.88

Industrialised �10.1 �33.8 �3.4 �14.4 10.1 �29.2 �3.9 �25.9 �19.6 �8.1

Rest of World 5.1 �11.6 �2.5 �17.6 25.7 1.8 �2.3 2.4 �4.0 �12.2

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453436

the Rest of World (and thus in the World sample as well). In other words, most sectors

show a pattern of r-convergence. This appears particularly so in less energy-intensive

industries, such as food (FOD), textile (TEX), wood (WOD), and machinery (MAC). The

most important exception is the non-ferrous metals sector (NFM) where cross-country

differences in energy-productivity levels have increased considerably in both regions. The

overall picture for the Industrialised countries in Table 3 accords well with the findings of

Mulder and de Groot (2003b), who conducted the same analysis for a limited number of

OECD countries, although they did, in fact, find a somewhat lower level of cross-country

variation in the Iron and Steel sector. This can be explained from the larger number of

countries included in our sample.

Table 3 also shows that, in all sectors, the cross-country variation in energy productivity

is lower among Industrialised countries than among the countries in the Rest of World.

Moreover, for both the Industrialised region and the Rest of World, the highest cross-

country productivity differentials can be found in the energy-intensive sectors—iron and

steel (IAS), non-ferrous metals (NFM), paper (PAP) and chemicals (CHE), as well as in

the wood sector (WOD).7

Table 3 also reports total percentage change in standard deviation (SD) of the log of

energy productivity during the same decade. In addition to the above-mentioned

conclusions, the table shows that in chemicals (CHE), non-metallic minerals (NMM) and

textiles (TEX), the variation in energy-productivity levels has increased (slightly) among

the developing countries, while in the energy intensive sectors, iron and steel (IAS) and

paper (PAP), the decline in cross-country variation has been relatively small in all regions.

Finally, Table 3 leads to the conclusion that, in spite of the overall pattern of r-convergence in nine manufacturing sectors, substantial cross-country variation in energy-

productivity levels remains in existence, in particular in several energy-intensive sectors

such as chemicals, iron and steel, and paper. In the next section, therefore, we will further

7 We view the high cross-country variation in transport equipment (TRM) for the Rest of World as a special

case as it is based on a sample of two countries only (see Table A.2 in appendix).

Page 9: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 437

explore the mechanisms behind these developments and the apparent lack of absolute

cross-country convergence.

4. Advantage of backwardness

In this section we focus on the catch-up hypothesis by analysing cross-country

convergence of energy productivity in terms of growth rates. Below, we adopt a panel-

data framework to regress, for each sector, average energy-productivity growth rates on

initial energy-productivity levels, generating an estimate of the coefficient b. A negative

coefficient b indicates the existence of so-called b-convergence, suggesting that countries

with relatively low initial energy-productivity levels catch up to more advanced countries,

possibly because they can benefit from the experience and technologies developed by

countries operating at the forefront. In addition to an analysis of r-convergence, therefore,a b-convergence analysis aids comprehension of the driving forces behind convergence

patterns and the cross-country differences in energy-productivity growth. Obviously,

catching up is a necessary condition for convergence to the same productivity level across

countries, i.e. for r-convergence. As has been argued by Quah (1993), however, it is not a

sufficient condition because lagging countries can still catch up where there is a constant

or even an increasing cross-country variation in energy-productivity levels, a statistical

phenomenon known as Galton’s fallacy of regression toward the mean.8

The concept of b-convergence can be refined by distinguishing unconditional (or

absolute) convergence from conditional (or relative) convergence. The first is said to be

present if cross-country productivity exhibits a tendency to converge toward a uniform level,

while the second concerns convergence of (a subset of) different countries toward different

levels, implying that convergence is conditional on similarities in countries’ characteristics.

The idea of conditional convergence has been formalised by Durlauf and Johnson (1992)

and confirmed by several empirical convergence studies, some of which suggest the

existence of convergence clubs: groups of countries converging to different levels of income

per capita (e.g., Barro, 1991; Chatterji, 1992; Chatterji et al., 1993; Quah, 1997). Below we

will apply both concepts to analysing energy-productivity developments across countries.

We start our b-convergence analysis by testing for unconditional convergence,

assuming that energy productivity converges toward the same long-term growth path

for all countries included in the dataset. Subsequently, in Section 4.2, we include

unspecified country-specific factors by allowing the intercept of the regression equation to

vary across countries (fixed-effect model). In doing so, we test for the assumption that

countries converge to country-specific growth paths and analyse whether this supports the

existence of convergence clubs. Finally, in Section 4.3, we include country-specific data

on energy prices and investment ratios as factors that could cause cross-country

productivity differences.

8 This can be the case, for example, if the gap in productivity level between leading and lagging countries is

relatively big, an even higher growth rate in the lagging countries cannot prevent the absolute difference in

productivity levels from increasing. See Quah (1993) and Durlauf and Quah (1999) for a more elaborate

discussion of this point.

Page 10: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453438

4.1. Unconditional convergence

We test for unconditional b-convergence by regressing, for each sector, the average

annual growth rate ( g) of energy productivity ( y) on its initial level (and a constant a),thus generating an estimate of b according to:

git ¼ a þ bln yð Þi;t�1 þ gt þ eit ð1Þ

with i and t denoting, respectively, the cross-country and the time-series dimension of the

panel-data structure, while gt denotes period-specific fixed effects (period dummies) and

eit is the standard error. Following Islam (1995), we divide the total period into several

shorter periods using 5-year time intervals so that the error term is less influenced by

business-cycle fluctuations and serial correlation than it would be in a yearly setup.9 The

estimation results are summarised in Table 4. Note that, in contrast to the r-convergenceanalysis, the analysis presented here was conducted using an unbalanced sample, that is,

the number of countries included in the analysis was not constant over the time period.

Because the r-convergence analysis required a balanced sample for the sake of

consistency, the period of analysis had to be restricted to 1980–1990. The b-convergenceanalysis does not require a balanced sample, and the number of countries per sector

included in the analysis is shown at the end of the results for each sample within the table,

under the heading bncrossestQ.10

The table displays a negative estimate of b in virtually all sectors, for the total sample

as well as for the Industrialised region and the Rest of World, while in most sectors these

estimates are statistically significant. An exception to this result is the non-ferrous metals

(NFM) sector within the Industrialised region, which shows a positive b-coefficient. Itsestimate, however, is statistically insignificant, which also applies to the iron and steel

(IAS) sector in the Industrialised region as well as the paper (PAP) and transport

equipment (TRM) sectors in the Rest of World.

In short, the results of our test for b-coefficient provide evidence of lagging countries

catching up in terms of energy-productivity performance within most industrial sectors. It

may be noted that our estimates are rather similar to the two percent convergence

coefficient reported by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992) in their seminal work on per capita

income convergence. Moreover, on the whole, our results for the Industrialised countries

are in line with the findings of the convergence analysis for 14 OECD countries in Mulder

and de Groot (2003b). These values indicate that the catch-up process is rather slow. Using

the estimated values of b, the speed of convergence k can be calculated according to

k=�[(1/T)]log(b+1)] with T denoting the time interval under consideration (Barro and

Sala-i-Martin, 1992; Mankiw et al., 1992; Islam, 1995).11 A convenient way of expressing

10 Note that the limited data availability of the non-OECD countries for the transportation equipment sector

implies that the results in this sector should be interpreted with caution.11 T=5 in our analysis, as we use 5-year time intervals. The fact that our first period is 4 years will bias b and

thus k. We believe this effect to be very small, however, because in our regression model we use an average

annual growth rate and include period dummies to control period-specific fluctuations in growth. Moreover, it

should be noted that in Islam (1995), k=�[(1/T)ln(b)] as he takes ln( y)it instead of [ln( y)it�ln( y)it�1] as

dependent variable.

9 As our dataset covers the period 1971–1995 we took the first interval to be a 4-year period.

Page 11: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table 4

Unconditional b-convergence for energy productivity for the period 1971–1995

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

World

b �0.01 �0.02 �0.01 �0.03 �0.02 �0.03 �0.01 �0.03 �0.04 �0.01

(�2.83) (�3.66) (�2.43) (�5.74) (�2.52) (�6.78) (�3.04) (�4.79) (�4.73) (�3.06)

Implied k 0.0029 0.0036 0.0024 0.0058 0.0033 0.0063 0.0026 0.0068 0.0072 0.0027

R2 0.09 0.08 0.03 0.25 0.07 0.22 0.08 0.16 0.24 0.11

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 45 37 52 34 35 42 36 33 22 28

totalobs 205 161 240 147 151 181 158 141 97 120

Industrialised

b �0.02 �0.04 �0.01 �0.05 0.01 �0.06 �0.02 �0.06 �0.05 �0.01

(�2.14) (�4.78) (�1.66) (�5.66) (1.03) (�9.08) (�3.10) (�5.07) (�4.29) (�1.12)

Implied k 0.0043 0.0072 0.0019 0.0110 �0.0014 0.0126 0.0041 0.0115 0.0094 0.0017

R2 0.09 0.22 0.05 0.33 0.07 0.48 0.11 0.25 0.27 0.08

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 23 23 23 23 20 23 22 22 18 20

totalobs 110 103 112 103 91 107 103 100 86 90

Rest of World

b �0.02 �0.02 �0.01 �0.03 �0.04 �0.02 �0.01 �0.02 �0.03 �0.02

(�2.60) (�2.50) (�1.74) (�3.19) (�3.34) (�2.95) (�1.32) (�1.70) (�1.24) (�2.95)

Implied k 0.0036 0.0032 0.0024 0.0057 0.0079 0.0049 0.0018 0.0039 0.0058 0.0038

R2 0.15 0.21 0.05 0.29 0.20 0.16 0.15 0.13 0.55 0.33

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 22 14 29 11 15 20 14 11 4 8

totalobs 95 58 127 44 60 77 55 41 11 30

T-statistics in parenthesis. Estimated values for the constant and the period-specific fixed effects are not reported.

regobs: number of time points included; ncrossest: number of countries included; totobs: total number of

observation.

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 439

this speed of convergence is the time t needed for the energy-productivity level to move its

initial level halfway ( y(0)), and the steady state productivity level y*. This period of time

is commonly referred to as the dhalf lifeT (H), derived from e�kH=fH=log(2)/k. Table 4presents the values of the implied k as they follow from the estimates of b. They confirm

the finding of a slow rate of convergence: the half life that can be derived from these

values varies from 55 years in the non-metallic minerals sector (NMM) to 397 years in the

wood sector (WOD) in the Industrialised region.

A comparison of these results with the patterns of r-convergence, as reported in

Section 3, confirms that those sectors showing evidence of r-convergence also display

evidence of b-convergence. This is obvious because a decreasing cross-country variation

in energy-productivity levels implies that countries with a relatively poor initial

productivity performance tend to grow relatively fast. As we noted previously,

however, the converse does not necessarily hold true; hence, evidence of catching up

can be consistent with increasing cross-country variation in energy-productivity levels.

This can be illustrated by the non-ferrous metal (NFM) sector which, in the previous

section, we found to show increasing cross-country variation in energy-productivity

Page 12: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453440

levels (i.e. r-divergence) but which nevertheless also demonstrates evidence of b-convergence. This can be caused by cross-country differences in energy productivity

being governed not just by the catch-up mechanism alone but also by other (country-

specific) exogenous factors. Moreover, even if we control for the appropriate

exogenous differences, the combination of b-convergence and r-divergence can be

subject to Galton’s fallacy, as discussed earlier. In any case, it should be noted that the

extremely low R2 indicate that the explanatory value of Eq. (1) is very limited,

suggesting the existence of factors determining cross-country differences in energy-

productivity growth other than those included in Eq. (1). In the next section we deal

with these issues by exploring patterns of conditional convergence.

4.2. Conditional convergence

Conditional convergence presumes that countries converge to different energy-

productivity growth paths, depending on country-specific conditions, rather than evolving

toward the same ultimate level of energy-productivity growth. To analyse conditional

convergence, therefore, we allow the intercept (a) of Eq. (1) to vary across countries,

applying a so-called fixed-effect model. We do so by reformulating Eq. (1) into a panel-

data model with individual country effects, according to:

git ¼ bln yð Þi;t�1 þ li þ gi þ eit ð2Þ

with li representing unspecified country-specific (fixed) effects, and all other symbols

identical to Eq. (1). These country effects might include all sorts of country-specific

tangible and intangible factors affecting energy-productivity growth that have not been

included in Eq. (1) or, to put it differently, factors that have been subsumed in the error

term. The model formulation of Eq. (2) enables us to test for the hypothesis that, in the

long run, the energy-productivity growth rates of nations tend to slow down as they

approach their own long-run growth path, thus implying the existence of multiple dsteady-stateT levels of energy productivity. Hence, this formulation accord well with the

possibility that substantial cross-country differences remain in existence, presuming that

determinants of energy-productivity growth may well vary across countries. Table 5

summarises the results of the unspecified conditional convergence estimation according to

Eq. (2).

The results confirm the evidence of b-convergence: except for wood (WOD) in the Rest

of World, all estimated b-coefficients are negative and highly significant.12 Moreover, the

values of the R2 improved considerably, suggesting that country effects indeed play an

important role, and thus making Eq. (2) a much better model for explaining energy-

productivity growth across countries than Eq. (1). From the higher values of the implied kin Table 5, it can be seen that allowing for country-specific effects also leads to a

substantial increase in the speed of convergence. It can be calculated that the resulting half

12 Additional analysis of the relative energy productivity performance of individual countries (see discussion of

Table 6) shows that this lack of evidence of b-convergence for the wood sector is mainly due to the substantial

drop in relative productivity performance of Chinese Taipei (TW) in the period 1985–1995. All other countries in

the wood sector in the Rest of World region display a clear pattern of catching up.

Page 13: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table 5

(Unspecified) conditional b-convergence for energy productivity for the period 1971–1995

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

World

b �0.10 �0.10 �0.12 �0.12 �0.15 �0.14 �0.15 �0.15 �0.10 �0.07

(�7.37) (�6.31) (�9.31) (�7.10) (�9.69) (�12.83) (�10.28) (�8.96) (�5.72) (�3.47)

Implied k 0.0215 0.0219 0.0263 0.0249 0.0315 0.0293 0.0330 0.0326 0.0205 0.0148

R2 0.50 0.41 0.43 0.53 0.62 0.68 0.57 0.53 0.60 0.46

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 45 37 52 34 35 42 36 33 22 28

totalobs 205 161 240 147 151 181 158 141 97 120

Industrialised

b �0.11 �0.12 �0.11 �0.08 �0.15 �0.12 �0.14 �0.13 �0.09 �0.08

(�5.60) (�5.83) (�6.09) (�4.56) (�4.93) (�11.86) (�8.03) (�7.20) (�5.14) (�3.62)

Implied k 0.0239 0.0248 0.0235 0.0162 0.0319 0.0250 0.0307 0.0283 0.0184 0.0167

R2 0.44 0.43 0.41 0.53 0.42 0.79 0.56 0.54 0.60 0.48

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 23 23 23 23 20 23 22 22 18 20

totalobs 110 103 112 103 91 107 103 100 86 90

Rest of World

b �0.11 �0.10 �0.13 �0.17 �0.15 �0.19 �0.18 �0.27 �1.03 0.12

(�5.15) (�3.28) (�6.74) (�4.82) (�7.44) (�7.73) (�6.19) (�6.24) (�1.80) (1.44)

Implied k 0.0240 0.0206 0.0270 0.0377 0.0332 0.0429 0.0387 0.0617 — �0.0230

R2 0.55 0.55 0.45 0.61 0.73 0.61 0.63 0.66 0.85 0.55

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 22 14 29 11 15 20 14 11 4 8

totalobs 95 58 127 44 60 77 55 41 11 30

T-statistics in parenthesis.

regobs: number of time points included; ncrossest: number of countries included; totobs: total number of

observation.

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 441

life (H) decreases to a period that lies between 11 and 47 years (for, respectively, TEX in

the Rest of World region and WOD in the World region).

In short, our results show support for the hypothesis that, in terms of sectoral energy

productivity, lagging countries tend to catch up with advanced nations, with convergence

tending to be conditional on country-specific characteristics rather than unconditional or

absolute. Of course, this raises the question as to which underlying mechanisms cause

dfollowersT to grow faster than dleadersT. It may be recalled from the introduction that there

are various mechanisms; for example, advanced economies may suffer from diminishing

returns, lagging countries may benefit from knowledge spillovers (technology transfer),

production processes may converge because of increasing competition, and so forth. To

date, our results do not provide much information to clarify this. From Table 5 it can be

concluded that, in most sectors, the estimated values for b are higher among less

industrialised or developing countries (the Rest of World region) than for the Industrialised

region. This may be taken as a sign that developing countries are realising their potential

for rapid growth, benefiting from the advantage of backwardness. At the same time,

however, it is again to be noted that these results do not necessarily imply that cross-

Page 14: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453442

country differentials in energy-productivity performance are vanishing, which is also best

illustrated in Table 5 by the non-ferrous metals sector (NFM) which shows robust

statistically significant evidence of b-convergence in combination with a pattern of r-divergence (see section 3). Hence, it is worth taking a closer look at actual energy-

productivity performance per sector and per country. Our panel estimation permits us to

analyse, for each sector, the estimated coefficients of the country-specific intercepts li

themselves. They can be interpreted as a rough measure of a country’s initial energy-

productivity performance in so far as it captures the unspecified country characteristics

within a sector.

As a next step in our analysis, therefore, we analyse the country-specific intercepts

included in Eq. (2). Table 6 shows, for each sector, the top five and bottom five countries

in terms of energy-productivity performance, defined by the estimated values of li relative

to the highest value lmax per sector. Note that numbers of countries included in the

analysis are different for each sector. For an overview of available countries and their

ranking per sector, we refer to Table A.3 in the appendix.

First, from Table 6 it can be seen that, not surprisingly, industrialised OECD

countries dominate the top five ranking whereas most bottom five countries are less

industrialised or developing countries. An important exception, however, is the iron

and steel (IAS) sector where all top five countries are developing countries. Second, it

seems that several countries have a similar position in the ranking across different

industrial sectors. According to our analysis, for example, China, Hungary, Poland and

the former Soviet Union do belong to the bottom five category in several sectors,

while Austria, Belgium and Switzerland are listed among the top five countries in

several sectors. This tendency of intercepts across sectors to be correlated with the

relative ranking of countries indicates that country-specific factors affecting energy-

productivity growth, rather than sector-specific factors, seem to be dominant in causing

(the persistence of) cross-country energy-productivity differentials. This confirms our

finding that cross-country differences in energy-productivity growth are driven by

country-specific characteristics, as indicated by the considerable positive impact of

fixed country effects on the panel estimation.

This finding obviously raises the question as to which are these country-specific

factors determining (persistent) cross-country differences in energy-productivity growth.

From classical as well as recent empirical research, it is well known that technological

change, prices and changes in economic structure (sectoral shifts) are key determinants

of aggregate energy-productivity growth (see, for example, Berndt, 1978; Jorgenson,

1984; Schipper and Meyers, 1992). It needs no argument that innovation and diffusion

of energy-saving technologies are complex and costly processes, which accords well

with the finding that rich and advanced economies dominate the top five ranking in

Table 6. Furthermore, energy prices are positively correlated with energy-productivity

growth, as higher energy prices provide an incentive to improve energy efficiency, and

vice versa. The fact that former socialistic countries tend to have lower intercepts across

sectors in Table 6 may indicate some kind of price control by their (former)

governments, thereby discouraging investments in energy-efficiency improvements.

Structural changes as countries get richer might also partly explain the higher energy-

productivity levels in Table 6, but only insofar it consists of shifts away from energy-

Page 15: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table 6

Best and worst performance in energy productivity

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM

Country a i/amax Country a i/amax Country ai/amax Country a i/amax Country a i/amax

1. Kuwait (1.0) 1. Switzerland (1.0) 1. Malaysia (1.0) 1. Thailand (1.0) 1. Chin. Taipei (1.0)

2. Switzerland (0.86) 2. Chile (0.81) 2. Bangladesh (0.96) 2. Belgium (0.99) 2. S. Korea (0.00)

3. Philippines (0.84) 3. USA (0.81) 3. Uruguay (0.96) 3. Japan (0.97) 3. Mexico (0.95)

4. Denmark (0.84) 4. Canada (0.80) 4. Argentina (0.91) 4. Austria (0.97) 4. Austria (0.92)

5. Greece (0.82) 5. India (0.79) 5. Peru (0.86) 5. Ireland (0.97) 5. Belgium (0.90)

41. Mexico (0.50) 33. Hungary (0.45) 48. New Zealand (0.47) 30. Colombia (0.79) 31. Iceland (0.62)

42. Bangladesh (0.47) 34. Poland (0.33) 49. Iceland (0.45) 31. Hungary (0.77) 32. Venezuela (0.61)

43. USSR (0.47) 35. Mexico (0.33) 50. China (0.44) 32. Poland (0.67) 33. USSR (0.54)

44. Trinidad (0.47) 36. USSR (0.27) 51. USSR (0.40) 33. China (0.65) 34. Bahrain (0.49)

45. China (0.30) 37. China (0.20) 52. Venezuela (0.38) 34. USSR (0.54) 35. Ireland (0.33)

NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

Country a i/amax Country a i/amax Country ai/amax Country a i/amax Country a i/amax

1. Switzerland (1.0) 1. Ireland (1.0) 1. S. Africa (1.0) 1. Japan (1.0) 1. UK (1.0)

2. France (0.97) 2. S. Africa (0.99) 2. N. Zealand (0.95) 2. Italy (0.98) 2. Belgium (0.99)

3. Turkey (0.94) 3. Switzerland (0.94) 3. Belgium (0.88) 3. Canada (0.98) 3. Italy (0.99)

4. Austria (0.92) 4. N. Zealand (0.91) 4. Finland (0.86) 4. Finland (0.97) 4. Slovenia (0.99)

5. Ireland (0.91) 5. Denmark (0.90) 5. USA (0.86) 5. France (0.97) 5. Germany (0.98)

38. Colombia (0.59) 32. Canada (0.63) 29. Luxembourg (0.71) 18. Australia (0.85) 24. Poland (0.92)

39. USSR (0.52) 33. Mexico (0.62) 30. Hungary (0.70) 19. Belgium (0.80) 25. Turkey (0.92)

40. China (0.51) 34. China (0.57) 31. India (0.70) 20. Hungary (0.77) 26. China (0.90)

41. Pakistan (0.47) 35. Poland (0.55) 35. Colombia (0.69) 21. Czech Rep. (0.72) 27. USSR (0.90)

42. Poland (0.46) 36. USSR (0.52) 33. China (0.63) 22. Poland (0.67) 28. N. Zealand (0.89)

Relative estimated intercepts for the period 1971–1995.

The ranking of countries is based on the estimated values of li from Eq. (2) in the text. The values in parenthesis denote a country’s values of li relative to the highest

estimated value lmax per sector.

A.Miketa

,P.Mulder

/Energ

yEconomics

27(2005)429–453

443

Page 16: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453444

intensive towards more energy-extensive activities within a sector, for example, from

basic chemicals towards other chemical products. The level of sectoral detail already

takes more aggregate structural changes, such as the shift away from heavy industry into

account. In addition, several authors have stressed the fact that changes in energy mix

are an important source of aggregate energy-productivity developments, because some

energy types (such as natural gas and electricity) are more efficient than others (such as

coal and oil) in terms of available energy (see, for example, Berndt, 1978; Cleveland et

al., 2000; Kaufmann, 2004). Based on information from the IEA Energy Balances we

calculated for the year 1990 the average share of the four main energy carriers in total

final manufacturing energy consumption across the countries listed in Table 6. We found

that the countries in the top five ranking are on average characterised by a lower share

of coal and a higher share of electricity. The share of coal was in 1990 on average 17%

for countries in the top five ranking against 23% for countries in the bottom five

ranking, while for the electricity share these figures are 24% against 17%. However, the

countries in the bottom five ranking are on average characterised by a lower share of oil

and a higher share of natural gas. The share of oil was in 1990 on average 29% for

countries in the top five ranking against 16% for countries in the bottom five ranking,

while for natural gas these figures are 24% and 39%, respectively. In sum, a first look at

the potential impact of fuel mix on manufacturing energy-productivity performance

yields at best mixed evidence: high energy productivity in the countries in the top five

ranking might be driven by relatively low shares of coal and high shares of electricity, it

is also true that countries in the bottom five ranking are characterised by low energy

productivity in spite of relatively low shares of oil and high shares of natural gas.

Obviously, a more detailed and systematic analysis is required to provide a better

understanding of the country-specific factors determining cross-country differences in

energy-productivity performance. Therefore, a final step in our analysis consists of an

attempt to identify these country-specific characteristics, by taking a closer look at the

impact of various factors at the level of manufacturing sectors.

4.3. Conditional convergence: identifying country effects

In this section we test for the hypothesis that cross-country differences in energy

prices, investment ratios and fuel mix are main sources for the observed (persistence

in) cross-country differences in manufacturing energy-productivity performance. We

expect energy prices to be positively correlated with energy-productivity growth, as

higher energy prices provide an incentive to improve energy efficiency. By including

the investment share as an explanatory variable, we test for the so-called embodiment

hypothesis or vintage effect, assuming that higher investment will contribute to

increasing energy-productivity growth via technological change embodied in new

capital goods (e.g., Howarth et al., 1991; Mulder et al., 2003). As previously noted,

changes in energy mix may contribute to energy-productivity growth because some

energy types are more efficient than others in terms of available energy. We expect

increasing shares of electricity and natural gas to have a positive impact on energy-

productivity growth, while the shares of oil and particularly coal are thought to be

negatively correlated with energy-productivity growth.

Page 17: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 445

In line with these hypotheses, one may expect these factors to be among the most

important driving forces of cross-country energy-productivity convergence. Because new

technologies are often embodied in new vintages of capital equipment, investment is an

important channel for knowledge spillovers and international technology diffusion—

possibly facilitated by (increasing) international trade and foreign direct investment. This

may lead to processes of technology catch-up, which in turn can be a potentially

important source of productivity convergence. In a similar vein this may be also true for

decreasing cross-county differences in energy taxation and thus final prices of energy

input, as well as decreasing cross-country heterogeneity in the use of various energy

types. Based on information from the IEA Energy Balances, we have calculated the

cross-country dispersion of the share in total final energy consumption of the various

energy types across the three different regions in our database (measured by the standard

deviation of these shares). Our analysis reveals a clear trend towards decreasing cross-

country variation in the use of the four main energy types (whereby natural gas and

electricity are increasingly substituted for coal and oil). We found that the total cross-

country dispersion of fuel mix decreased with 12–15% over the period 1971–1995,

which was mostly due to decreasing cross-country variation of the shares of coal and oil.

To estimate the impact of energy prices, investment ratios and fuel mix on energy-

productivity growth we add to the unspecified country-effects li in Eq. (2), specified

fixed-effects xi, according to:

git ¼ bln yð Þi;t�1 þX6j¼1

cj þ xjit þ li þ gt þ eit ð3Þ

with xit1 . . . xit

6 representing, respectively, the country-specific industrial energy price,

investment ratio (i.e., the share of investment relative to output), and the share of oil,

natural gas, electricity and coal in final industrial energy consumption.13

The results of the regression analysis of Eq. (3) are presented in Table 7. It can be seen

that in most sectors the estimated b-coefficients are still negative and statistically

significant, as it was for the unconditional convergence case (Eq. (2)). Moreover, the

values of the R2 suggest Eq. (3) to be an appropriate model to describe cross-country

energy-productivity patterns. Nevertheless, the results also show very limited support for

the hypothesis that energy prices and investment ratios are important determinants of

(cross-country differences in) energy-productivity performance. The expected positive

correlation between energy prices and energy-productivity growth is found in a about half

of the sectors, while it is statistically significant nowhere except for the wood (WOD)

sector in the samples World and Industrialised, and the non-ferrous metals (NFM) sector in

the Rest of World sample. A similar result is obtained for the impact of the investment

ratio, with a statistically significant positive effect in a limited number of sectors, including

the textile (TEX) sector in the World and Rest of World sample, chemicals (CHE) and

transport equipment (TRM) in the Industrialised sample, and non-ferrous metals (NFM) in

the Rest of World sample. In addition, we also found mixed evidence on the effect of

changes in energy mix on energy-productivity growth. The results do not show a clear-cut

13 We refer to Section 2 for a more detailed description of these variables.

Page 18: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table 7

Conditional b-convergence for energy productivity, specifying levels of energy price and investment ratio for the

period 1971–1995

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

World

b �0.16 �0.16 �0.21 �0.11 �0.15 �0.15 �0.15 �0.19 �0.16 �0.09

(�7.35) (�5.68) (�10.51) (�5.06) (�4.20) (�6.53) (�6.37) (�8.42) (�5.07) (�3.12)

Implied kPE 0.05 �0.05 0.01 0.19 0.25 �0.34 �0.10 0.20 �0.08 0.50

(0.31) (�0.20) (0.08) (0.79) (0.57) (�1.42) (�0.41) (0.78) (�0.22) (1.96)

I/Y 0.22 �0.59 �0.04 �0.29 �0.11 �0.05 0.03 0.72 0.15 0.24

(0.27) (�0.79) (�0.61) (�0.56) (�0.35) (�0.45) (0.13) (0.72) (0.37) (0.65)

Share oil 0.44 0.69 0.16 �0.03 �0.05 0.28 0.12 0.53 0.86 0.20

(1.24) (2.12) (0.52) (�0.10) (�0.10) (0.95) (0.39) (1.43) (2.42) (0.53)

Share gas 0.09 0.09 0.07 �0.02 �0.13 0.06 �0.11 0.03 �0.30 0.27

(0.50) (0.54) (0.42) (�0.15) (�0.52) (0.41) (�0.75) (0.14) (�1.61) (1.45)

Share electricity �0.35 0.16 �0.32 0.22 �0.29 �0.13 �0.29 �0.46 �0.60 0.24

(�1.59) (0.77) (�1.54) (1.17) (�0.83) (�0.66) (�1.51) (�1.76) (�2.37) (1.04)

Share coal �0.26 0.02 �0.04 0.08 �0.22 �0.20 0.12 �0.75 �0.78 0.30

(0.73) (0.11) (�0.24) (0.51) (�0.82) (�1.23) (0.71) (�2.51) (�2.75) (1.37)

R2 0.75 0.59 0.82 0.81 0.52 0.73 0.58 0.71 0.72 0.58

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 33 31 33 28 26 32 30 27 19 24

totalobs 102 103 112 98 88 107 104 96 67 82

Industrialised

b �0.17 �0.21 �0.21 �0.12 �0.17 �0.12 �0.16 �0.18 �0.15 �0.12

(�8.00) (�6.19) (�6.64) (�4.42) (�3.91) (�4.75) (�6.21) (�7.83) (�5.97) (�3.94)

Implied kPE 0.10 0.26 �0.28 �0.04 �0.16 �0.26 �0.22 0.48 �0.06 0.70

(0.42) (1.05) (�1.55) (�0.14) (�0.37) (�1.26) (�0.92) (1.58) (�0.22) (2.38)

I/Y 0.32 �0.77 �0.13 �1.03 �0.21 �0.21 0.50 0.85 0.31 0.09

(0.80) (�0.99) (�2.52) (�1.60) (�0.48) (�0.70) (1.19) (1.16) (0.90) (0.21)

Share oil 0.32 �0.05 0.41 0.10 �0.22 �0.06 0.80 0.53 0.88 0.00

(0.98) (�0.17) (1.69) (0.30) (�0.50) (�0.25) (2.56) (1.43) (3.03) (0.00)

Share gas �0.11 �0.17 0.00 �0.16 0.00 0.00 �0.01 0.03 �0.40 �0.01

(�0.60) (�0.97) (0.00) (�0.75) (0.01) (�0.01) (�0.05) (0.14) (�2.53) (�0.03)

Share electricity �0.42 �0.14 0.07 0.04 �0.56 �0.35 �0.17 �0.46 �0.73 �0.10

(�1.66) (�0.62) (0.38) (0.15) (�1.61) (�1.75) (�0.81) (�1.76) (�3.29) (�0.36)

Share coal �0.59 �0.44 0.06 �0.15 0.18 �0.10 0.72 �0.75 �1.01 �0.51

(0.97) (�1.75) (0.25) (�0.60) (0.49) (�0.52) (2.65) (�2.51) (�4.24) (�1.47)

R2 0.85 0.72 0.74 0.72 0.56 0.86 0.66 0.74 0.81 0.58

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

ncrossest 21 22 19 22 19 19 21 21 17 20

totalobs 69 75 70 78 66 72 78 76 62 68

Rest of World

b �0.11 �0.24 �0.21 �0.32 �0.15 �0.21 �0.10 �0.29 NA 0.12

(�1.82) (�4.03) (�5.15) (�2.39) (�4.20) (�3.18) (�2.19) (�5.93) – (0.80)

Implied kPE 0.71 �0.83 0.47 1.34 0.25 �0.66 �0.59 �0.96 NA 0.36

(1.66) (�0.96) (0.75) (1.14) (0.57) (�0.75) (�0.79) (�2.35) – (0.76)

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453446

Page 19: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

I/Y 0.05 0.24 0.16 1.23 �0.11 0.39 0.02 1.10 NA �0.56

(�0.46) (0.08) (0.64) (0.62) (�0.35) (1.32) (0.07) (2.98) – (�0.92)

Share oil 0.71 2.41 �0.78 �6.01 �1.25 �0.01 �2.28 NA NA NA

(1.66) (3.06) (�0.59) (�2.31) (�0.95) (�0.01) (�3.60) – – –

Share gas 0.83 0.06 0.84 0.77 0.69 0.97 1.13 NA NA NA

(0.69) (0.09) (1.45) (1.15) (1.21) (1.63) (2.64) – – –

Share electricity 1.35 0.15 �0.08 3.20 2.06 0.16 �0.19 NA NA NA

(2.31) (0.39) (�0.15) (2.26) (4.16) (0.31) (�0.53) – – –

Share coal �0.63 0.21 �0.04 1.04 0.23 �0.21 0.27

(�1.24) (0.68) (�0.12) (2.06) (1.06) (�0.63) (1.63)

R2 0.85 0.88 0.94 0.98 0.98 0.77 0.94 0.84 – 0.68

regobs 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 4 4

ncrossest 12 9 13 6 7 13 9 8 4 5

totalobs 33 28 37 20 22 35 26 20 5 14

T-statistics in parenthesis.

regobs: number of time points included; ncrossest: number of countries included; totobs: total number of

observation.

Table 7 (continued)

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 447

pattern, with both positive and negative signs and a statistically significant relationship in a

limited number of sectors only, most notably transport equipment (TRM), textiles (TEX),

paper (PAP) and non-ferrous metals (NFM). Additional regression analyses using various

alternative specifications (in different combinations) did not substantially improve the

estimation results reported in Table 7.14

That we find energy prices, investment ratio and fuel mix playing only a very

limited role in explaining energy-productivity growth might, to some extent, be due to

these being estimated at the level of aggregate manufacturing, because of limited data

availability. Consequently, our analysis does not take into account sector-specific

vintage effects, sector-specific mixes of energy carriers used or particular sector-

specific energy prices. Although accounting for these sectoral differences will probably

improve the estimation results to some extent, we do not, however, expect the

additional variation in investment ratio and energy price series to account fully for the

observed cross-country differences. In their convergence analysis for 14 OECD

countries, Mulder and de Groot (2003b) applied sector-specific investment ratios and

energy prices, but found these to have a statistically significant impact on energy-

productivity growth in a few energy-intensive industries only (iron and steel,

chemicals, and paper), although the impact is positive in virtually all manufacturing

sectors. In closing our examination of the country-characteristics driving energy-

14 These specifications include (1) a 3-year moving average for the energy price to avoid capturing the effect of

short-term price fluctuations, assuming that investments in energy- and labor-augmenting technologies do

respond to a structural trend in energy price/wage developments rather than to short-term fluctuations; (2) a

lagged investment share, assuming that it takes some time for new technologies to become effective, for example,

through various learning and adaptation effects; (3) the country-specific explanatory variables (energy price,

investment ratio and fuel mix) in terms of growth rates rather than levels. Details are available upon request.

Page 20: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453448

productivity growth, we therefore emphasize that our analysis points to the role of

country-specific factors other than prices and investment shares being crucial in

determining cross-country productivity differentials.

5. Conclusions

In this paper we examined the dynamics of energy-productivity performance for 56

countries, including 32 less industrialised or developing countries, in 10 manufacturing

sectors, during the period 1971–1995. We calculated average annual growth rates of

energy productivity and performed a convergence analysis to examine patterns of

international energy-productivity developments at a detailed sector level. We found that, in

most sectors, cross-country differences in absolute energy-productivity levels tend to

decline. This appears particularly so in the less energy-intensive industries; the energy-

intensive sector, non-ferrous metals, is a major exception in that it shows substantial

divergence of energy-productivity levels across countries. Testing for the so-called b-convergence hypothesis using panel data confirms that, in all sectors, energy-productivity

growth is relatively high in countries that initially lag behind in terms of energy-

productivity levels. This suggests that lagging countries catch up with advanced

economies. At the same time, however, cross-country differences in energy-productivity

performance seem to be persistent, for convergence is found to be local rather than global,

with countries converging to different steady states that depend on country-specific

characteristics. In a first attempt to identify the country-specific factors determining cross-

country (differences in) energy-productivity growth rates, we found that the energy price,

the investment ratio and the fuel mix affected country-specific energy-productivity growth

rates to a very limited extent only.

The task ahead is to identify what accounts for the observed persistence in cross-

country energy-productivity differentials. Our results suggest that international flows,

associated mostly with manufacturing, may not be contributing substantially to

convergence of energy productivity across countries in different parts of the world. It

may be that patterns of international specialization and relocation of industries,

accommodated by increasing international trade, or all sorts of market imperfections,

outweigh the influence of increasing competition, capital accumulation, technology

transfer, and knowledge spillovers in driving international patterns of energy-productivity

developments. Another possible explanation is that countries lagging too far behind are

not able to catch up with advanced economies because the technology gap (distance to

technology leader) proves to be too large to actually exploit the advantage of

backwardness through, for example, knowledge spillovers or technology transfer

(Gomulka, 1971; Chatterji, 1992, 1993). This suggestion is very much in line with the

Abromivitz notion of dsocial capabilitiesT (Abromivitz, 1986) required for successful

catching up. Finally, there is some reason to believe that technology diffusion and

knowledge spillovers are local rather than global (Keller, 2002). As technological change

is a major source for energy-productivity growth, this suggests that there is a need to pay

specific attention to the spatial dimension of technology gaps and technology diffusion in

driving energy-productivity patterns in different world regions.

Page 21: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 449

Appendix A

Table A.1

Industrialised countries included in the r-convergence analysis 1980–1990 per sector

Country Code CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

1. Austria AT � � � � � � � � � �2. Australia AU � � � � � � � � � �3. Belgium BE � � � � � � � � �4. Canada CA � � � � � �5. Switzerland CH � � � � �6. Germany DE � � � � � � � � � �7. Denmark DK � � � � � � � � �8. Spain ES � � � � � � � � �9. Finland FI � � � � � � � � � �10. France FR � � � � � � � � � �11. United Kingdom GB � � � � � � � � � �12. Greece GR � � � � � � � � � �13. Ireland IE � � � � � � � �14. Iceland IS � �15. Italy IT � � � � � � � � � �16. Japan JP � � � � � � � � �17. S. Korea KR � � � � � � � �18. Luxembourg LU � � � � � �19. Netherlands NL � � � � � � � � � �20. Norway NO � � � � � � � � �21. New Zealand NZ � � � � � �22. Portugal PT � � � � � � � � � �23. Sweden SE � � � � � � � � � �24. United States US � � � � � � � � � �

Table A.2

Rest of World (developing)countries included in the sigma-convergence analysis 1980–1990 per sector

Country Code CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

1. Argentina AR � �2. Bangladesh BD � � � �3. Bahrain BH �4. Brazil BR � � � � � � �5. Chile CL � � � � �6. China CN � � � � � � �7. Colombia CO � � � � � � � �8. Czech Republic CZ � � �9. Algeria DZ �10. Egypt EG � � �11. Hungary HU � � � � � � � � � �12. Indonesia ID � �13. Israel IL �14. India IN � � � � � � � �15. Kuwait KW �16. Malaysia MY � �

(continued on next page)

Page 22: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table A.2 (continued)

Country Code CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WOD

17. Mexico MX � � �18. Peru PE �19. Philippines PH � � �20. Pakistan PK � � �21. Poland PL � � � � � � � � �22. Slovenia SI

23. Thailand TH � � � � � �24. Tunisia TN � �25. Trinidad and Tobago TT �26. Chinese Taipei TW � � � � � � � �27. USSR (former) USSR � � � � � � � �28. Uruguay UY �29. Venezuela VE � � �30. South Africa ZA � � � � � �31. Turkey TR � � � � � � � �32. Zimbabwe ZW �

Table A.3

Estimated country effects per sector for different countries (ranking in parenthesis)

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WODCountry

code a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax ai/amax ai/amax a i/amax a i/amax

AR 0.79 (8) 0.91 (4)

AT 0.77 (9) 0.71 (9) 0.71 (23) 0.97 (4) 0.92 (4) 0.92 (4) 0.75 (24) 0.84 (12) 0.89 (15) 0.97 (9)

AU 0.68 (24) 0.47 (32) 0.68 (26) 0.91 (17) 0.64 (30) 0.81 (19) 0.78 (18) 0.80 (21) 0.85 (18) 0.97 (13)

BD 0.47 (42) 0.96 (2) 0.60 (36)

BE 0.68 (23) 0.66 (19) 0.66 (29) 0.99 (2) 0.90 (5) 0.74 (26) 0.88 (8) 0.88 (3) 0.80 (19) 0.99 (2)

BH 0.49 (34)

BR 0.69 (20) 0.61 (27) 0.63 (36) 0.67 (25) 0.82 (18) 0.78 (19) 0.78 (25)

CA 0.64 (30) 0.80 (4) 0.64 (35) 0.93 (13) 0.66 (26) 0.89 (9) 0.63 (32) 0.86 (6) 0.98 (3) 0.97 (10)

CH 0.86 (2) 1.0 (1) 0.97 (7) 1.0 (1) 0.94 (3)

CL 0.81 (2) 0.62 (37) 0.86 (7) 0.77 (24) 0.76 (23)

CN 0.30 (45) 0.20 (37) 0.44 (50) 0.65 (33) 0.65 (27) 0.51 (40) 0.57 (34) 0.63 (33) 0.90 (26)

CO 0.69 (22) 0.50 (31) 0.66 (31) 0.79 (30) 0.65 (28) 0.59 (38) 0.66 (30) 0.69 (32) 0.94 (23)

CZ 0.57 (42) 0.80 (21) 0.72 (21)

DE 0.70 (19) 0.65 (22) 0.73 (16) 0.94 (11) 0.81 (12) 0.87 (10) 0.82 (14) 0.83 (14) 0.89 (14) 0.98 (5)

DK 0.84 (4) 0.63 (24) 0.73 (17) 0.91 (16) 0.83 (15) 0.90 (5) 0.85 (7) 0.91 (9) 0.97 (12)

DZ 0.65 (33)

EG 0.62 (33) 0.61 (38)

ES 0.70 (18) 0.68 (15) 0.72 (18) 0.91 (18) 0.77 (15) 0.80 (22) 0.83 (13) 0.80 (22) 0.89 (16) 0.98 (8)

FI 0.67 (25) 0.67 (16) 0.72 (20) 0.90 (21) 0.88 (6) 0.83 (16) 0.72 (28) 0.86 (4) 0.97 (4) 0.94 (21)

FR 0.72 (15) 0.67 (17) 0.75 (11) 0.91 (20) 0.83 (10) 0.97 (2) 0.88 (7) 0.81 (17) 0.97 (5) 0.98 (6)

GB 0.73 (14) 0.64 (23) 0.72 (19) 0.88 (25) 0.77 (16) 0.91 (7) 0.89 (6) 0.81 (18) 0.89 (12) 1.0 (1)

GR 0.82 (5) 0.65 (21) 0.76 (9) 0.94 (12) 0.67 (24) 0.69 (30) 0.80 (16) 0.84 (11) 0.89 (13) 0.98 (7)

HU 0.58 (37) 0.45 (33) 0.59 (40) 0.77 (31) 0.73 (18) 0.68 (32) 0.74 (26) 0.70 (30) 0.77 (20) 0.95 (19)

ID 0.54 (39) 0.78 (7) 0.68 (31)

IE 0.80 (7) 0.75 (8) 0.77 (8) 0.97 (5) 0.33 (35) 0.91 (5) 1.0 (1) 0.83 (15) 0.95 (18)

IL 0.72 (16)

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453450

Page 23: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

Table A.3 (continued)

CHE FOD IAS MAC NFM NMM PAP TEX TRM WODCountry

code a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax a i/amax ai/amax ai/amax a i/amax a i/amax

IN 0.58 (36) 0.79 (5) 0.57 (44) 0.86 (28) 0.73 (19) 0.64 (34) 0.66 (31) 0.70 (31)

IS 0.60 (35) 0.45 (49) 0.62 (31)

IT 0.69 (21) 0.66 (18) 0.75 (12) 0.87 (27) 0.85 (9) 0.78 (23) 0.84 (12) 0.84 (10) 0.98 (2) 0.99 (3)

JP 0.73 (12) .79 (6) 0.75 (13) 0.97 (3) 0.86 (8) 0.91 (8) 0.88 (9) 0.82 (16) 1.0 (1)

KR 0.64 (29) 0.59 (28) 0.72 (22) 0.88 (24) 1.0 (2) 0.76 (25) 0.79 (17) 0.74 (27) 0.96 (16)

KW 1.0 (1)

LU 0.73 (10) 0.77 (7) 0.66 (30) 0.87 (26) 0.87 (11) 0.71 (29)

MX 0.50 (41) 0.33 (35) 0.61 (39) 0.95 (3) 0.65 (33) 0.62 (33)

MY 1.0 (1) 0.80 (20)

NL 0.61 (34) 0.62 (25) 0.65 (34) 0.91 (19) 0.74 (17) 0.85 (14) 0.87 (10) 0.79 (24) 0.90 (10) 0.96 (15)

NO 0.63 (32) 0.69 (12) 0.57 (43) 0.90 (22) 0.69 (22) 0.85 (13) 0.75 (25) 0.84 (13) 0.87 (17) 0.94 (20)

NZ 0.69 (11) 0.47 (48) 0.97 (6) 0.91 (4) 0.95 (2) 0.89 (28)

PE 0.86 (5)

PH 0.84 (3) 0.70 (25) 0.61 (35)

PK 0.58 (38) 0.67 (28) 0.47 (41)

PL 0.54 (40) 0.33 (34) 0.56 (45) 0.67 (32) 0.73 (20) 0.46 (42) 0.55 (35) 0.85 (9) 0.67 (22) 0.92 (24)

PT 0.67 (26) 0.62 (26) 0.72 (21) 0.94 (10) 0.79 (14) 0.73 (28) 0.76 (22) 0.80 (19) 0.90 (11) 0.96 (14)

SE 0.73 (13) 0.68 (14) 0.76 (10) 0.88 (23) 0.83 (11) 0.85 (12) 0.67 (29) 0.79 (23) 0.91 (8) 0.94 (22)

SI 0.69 (13) 0.71 (24) 0.85 (29) 0.67 (23) 0.73 (27) 0.80 (20) 0.99 (4)

TH 0.80 (6) 0.65 (20) 0.82 (6) 1.0 (1) 0.82 (17) 0.78 (21)

TN 0.73 (14) 0.85 (8)

TR 0.73 (11) 0.54 (29) 0.68 (27) 0.92 (14) 0.70 (21) 0.94 (3) 0.81 (15) 0.73 (28) 0.92 (25)

TT 0.47 (44) 0.54 (46) 0.60 (37)

TW 0.67 (27) 0.70 (10) 0.66 (32) 0.92 (15) 1.0 (1) 0.74 (27) 0.78 (20) 0.76 (26) 0.94 (7) 0.96 (17)

US 0.71 (17) 0.81 (3) 0.73 (15) 0.95 (9) 0.81 (13) 0.91 (6) 0.84 (11) 0.86 (5) 0.96 (6) 0.97 (11)

USSR 0.47 (43) 0.27 (36) 0.40 (51) 0.54 (34) 0.54 (33) 0.52 (39) 0.52 (36) 0.90 (27)

UY 0.96 (3)

VE 0.64 (31) 0.38 (52) 0.61 (32)

ZA 0.64 (28) 0.53 (30) 0.50 (47) 0.95 (8) 0.64 (29) 0.73 (29) 0.99 (2) 1.0 (1)

ZW 0.58 (41)

amax 0.97 0.52 1.05 1.15 1.20 0.98 1.31 1.42 0.93 3.32

amin 0.29 0.11 0.40 0.62 0.40 0.45 0.69 0.89 0.62 2.97

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 451

References

Abramovitz, M., 1986. Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind. Journal of Economic History 47, 385–406.

Barro, R.J., 1991. Economic growth in a cross-section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 407–443.

Barro, R.J., Sala-i-Martin, X., 1992. Convergence. Journal of Political Economy 100, 223–251.

Barro, R.J., Sala-i-Martin, X., 1995. Economic growth. McGraw Hill, New York.

Baumol, W.J., 1986. Productivity growth, convergence and welfare: what the long-run data show. American

Economic Review 76, 1072–1085.

Baumol, W.J., Nelson, R.R., Wolff, E.N., 1994. Convergence and Productivity; Cross-National Studies and

Historical Evidence. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Bernard, A.B., Jones, C.I., 1996a. Comparing apples to oranges: productivity convergence and measurement

across industries and countries. American Economic Review 86, 1216–1238.

Page 24: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453452

Bernard, A.B., Jones, C.I., 1996b. Productivity across industries and countries: time series theory and evidence.

Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 135–146.

Bernard, A.B., Jones, C.I., 2001. Comparing apples to oranges: productivity convergence and measurement

across industries and countries: reply. American Economic Review 91, 1168–1169.

Berndt, E.R., 1978. Aggregate energy, efficiency, and productivity measurement. Annual Review of Energy 3,

225–273.

Chatterji, M., 1992. Convergence clubs and endogenous growth. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 8, 57–69.

Chatterji, M., Gilmore, B., Strunk, K., Vanasin, J., 1993. Political economy, growth and convergence in less-

developed countries. World Development 21, 2029–2038.

Cleveland, C.J., Kaufmann, R.K., Stern, D.I., 2000. Aggregation and the role of energy in the economy.

Ecological Economics 32, 301–318.

Dalgaard, C.-J., Vastrup, J., 2001. On the measurement of r-convergence. Economics Letters 70, 283–287.

DeLong, J.B., 1988. Productivity growth, convergence and welfare: comment. American Economic Review 78,

1138–1154.

Dollar, D., Wolff, E.N., 1988. Convergence of industry labour productivity among advanced economies,

1963–1982. Review of Economics and Statistics 70, 549–558.

Dollar, D., Wolff, E.N., 1993. Competitiveness, Convergence, and International Specialization. MIT Press,

Cambridge MA.

Durlauf, S.N., Johnson, P.A., 1992. Local versus global convergence across national economies. NBERWorking

Paper, vol. 3996. NBER, Cambridge, MA.

Durlauf, S.N., Quah, D., 1999. New empirics of economic growth. In: Taylor, J.B., Woodford, M. (Eds.),

Handbook of macroeconomics vol. 1. North Holland Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, pp. 235–308.

Economic Journal, 1996. Controversy on the convergence and divergence of growth rates’. Special Issue

Economic Journal 106, 1016–1069.

Eichhammer, W., Mannsbart, W., 1997. Industrial energy efficiency: indicators for a European cross-country

comparison of energy efficiency in the manufacturing industry. Energy Policy 25, 759–772.

Gerschenkron, A., 1952. Economic backwardness in historical perspective. In: Hoselitz, B. (Ed.), The Progress of

Underdeveloped Areas. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 5–30.

Gomulka, S., 1971. Inventive Activity, Diffusion, and the Stages of Economic Growth, Monograph, vol. 24.

Institute of Economic, Aarhus.

Greening, L.A., Davis, W.B., Schipper, L., 1997. Comparison of six decomposition methods: application to

aggregate energy intensity for manufacturing in 10 OECD countries. Energy Economics 19, 375–390.

Howarth, R.B., Schipper, L., Duerr, P.A., Strøm, S., 1991. Manufacturing energy use in 8 OECD countries.

Energy Economics 13, 135–142.

Islam, N., 1995. Growth empirics: a panel data approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 4, 1127–1170.

Islam, N., 2003a. Productivity dynamics in a large sample of countries: a panel study. Review of Income and

Wealth 49, 247–272.

Islam, N., 2003b. What have we learnt from the convergence debate? Journal of Economic Surveys 17, 309–362.

Jorgenson, D.W., 1984. The role of energy in productivity growth. Energy Journal 5, 11–26.

Jorgenson, D.W., 1986. The great transition: energy and economic change. Energy Journal 7, 1–13.

Kaufmann, R.K., 2004. The mechanisms for autonomous energy efficiency increases: a cointegration analysis of

the US energy/GDP ratio. Energy Journal 25, 63–86.

Keller, W., 2002. Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. American Economic Review 92,

120–142.

Lucas, R.E., 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 3–42.

Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., Weil, D.N., 1992. A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly

Journal of Economics 107, 407–437.

Miketa, A., 2001. Analysis of energy intensity developments in manufacturing sectors in industrialized and

developing countries. Energy Policy 29, 769–775.

Miller, S.M., Upadhyay, M.P., 2002. Total factor productivity and the convergence hypothesis. Journal of

Macroeconomics 24, 267–286.

Mulder, P., de Groot, H.L.F., 2003a. International comparisons of sectoral energy- and labour productivity

performance: stylized facts and decomposition of trends. CPB Discussion Paper, vol. 22. CPB, The Hague.

Page 25: Energy productivity across developed and developing countries in 10 manufacturing sectors: Patterns of growth and convergence

A. Miketa, P. Mulder / Energy Economics 27 (2005) 429–453 453

Mulder, P., de Groot, H.L.F., 2003b. Sectoral energy- and labour productivity convergence. CPB Discussion

Paper, vol. 23. CPB, The Hague.

Mulder, P., de Groot, H.L.F., Hofkes, M.W., 2003. Explaining slow diffusion of energy-saving technologies, a

vintage model with returns to diversity and learning-by-using. Resource and Energy Economics 25, 105–126.

Park, S.H., Dissmann, B., Nam, K.Y., 1993. A cross-country decomposition analysis of manufacturing energy

consumption. Energy 18, 843–858.

Pilat, D., 1996. Labour productivity levels in OECD countries: estimates for manufacturing and selected service

sectors. OECD Economics Department Working Paper, vol. 169. OECD, Paris.

Quah, D., 1993. Galton’s fallacy and test of the convergence hypothesis. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95,

427–443.

Quah, D., 1997. Empirics for growth and distribution: polarization, stratification, and convergence clubs. Journal

of Economic Growth 2, 27–59.

Romer, P.M., 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94, 1002–1037.

Romer, P.M., 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98, S71–S102.

Schipper, L., Meyers, S., 1992. Energy Efficiency and Human Activity: Past Trends and Future Prospects.

Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Solow, R.M., 1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 65–94.

Sørensen, A., 2001. Comparing apples to oranges: productivity convergence and measurement across industries

and countries: comment. American Economic Review 91, 1160–1167.

Swan, T.W., 1956. Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record 32, 334–361.

Unander, F., Karbuz, S., Schipper, L., Khrushch, M., Ting, M., 1999. Manufacturing energy use in OECD

countries: decomposition of long term trends. Energy Policy 27, 769–778.

United Nations, 2001. United Nations Statistical Yearbook. United Nations, New York.

van Ark, B., 1993. International comparisons of output and productivity. Monograph Series, vol. 1. Growth and

Development Centre, Groningen.

van Ark, B., Crafts, N., 1996. Quantitative Aspects of Post-War European Growth. Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge.

van Ark, B., Pilat, D., 1993. Productivity level in Germany, Japan, and the United States: differences and causes.

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics 2, 1–46.