Economics of Chaos

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/9/2019 Economics of Chaos

    1/32

    The Economics of Chaos or the Chaos of EconomicsAuthor(s): David KelseySource: Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, Vol. 40, No. 1 (Mar., 1988), pp. 1-31Published by: Oxford University PressStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2663252.

    Accessed: 11/06/2014 11:47

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    .JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms

    of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    .

    Oxford University Pressis collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Oxford

    Economic Papers.

    http://www.jstor.org

    This content downloaded from 128.239.218.133 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 11:47:02 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ouphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2663252?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2663252?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup
  • 8/9/2019 Economics of Chaos

    2/32

    Oxford Economic Papers

    40

    (1988),

    1-31

    THE

    ECONOMICS OF CHAOS OR

    THE

    CHAOS OF

    ECONOMICS*

    By

    DAVID KELSEY

    Abstract

    THIS

    PAPER

    gives

    a

    simple

    account

    of

    non-linear

    dynamics, focussing

    on

    cycles

    and

    chaos. There

    is a

    survey

    of economic models which

    involve

    chaos.

    The

    case where a chaotic

    system

    is

    subject

    to

    exogenous

    random

    shocks

    is discussed.

    1.

    Introduction

    Economics and weather

    forecastinghave

    a

    lot in common. When people

    are not

    talking

    about the weather

    they

    talk

    about the economy.

    Both

    weather forecasters and

    economic

    forecasters have a bad name with the

    public.

    The

    similarities

    go

    further:both

    are trying to predict

    the outcomes

    of

    very large systems,

    the

    components

    of which

    mutually

    nteract

    n

    complex

    ways.

    The

    output

    of

    both

    systems

    has a

    seeminglyrandomappearance,

    even

    though

    there

    are certain other

    regularities (e.g., weather

    is hotter in

    summer han

    winter,

    also there is

    higher employment).

    In recent years some mathematicsknown popularlyas the theory of chaos

    has

    been

    studied. This deals

    with

    systems

    of

    equations which are able to

    produce

    motions

    so

    complex

    that

    they appear completely random. It is

    thought

    that

    chaos

    might

    be

    applied

    both within

    fluid mechanics

    (which

    is

    the

    body

    of

    theoretical

    knowledge

    on which

    weather

    forecastingdepends)

    and

    economic

    theory.

    Anyone

    who has

    watched the flow of

    liquid will realize

    how

    complex

    fluid

    motion

    can be.

    Suppose

    that

    water

    is

    flowing

    down

    a

    straight

    channel

    with

    smooth sides. The motion will

    break

    into a

    series of swirls which

    have

    a

    somewhat random appearance. Despite the fact the initial conditions are

    symmetric

    both

    in

    space

    and

    time the flow will be

    symmetric

    n neither.

    Such

    fluid flows are described as

    being

    turbulent.Turbulence s

    caused

    by

    viscosity

    or friction

    within

    the fluid.

    Viscosity

    introduces non-linear terms

    into

    the

    equations

    of

    motion

    which

    allow

    complex

    turbulent

    solutions

    to

    be

    possible.

    As an

    example,

    the

    presence

    of

    viscosity makes aeroplane flight

    possible.

    In

    the absence

    of

    viscosity pressures

    on

    the upper

    and lower

    sides

    of the

    wing

    would be

    equal

    and hence there would

    be

    no

    uplift.

    Because

    of

    the random

    character

    of

    turbulent motion it has been

    suggested

    that the

    mathematics

    of

    chaos can be

    applied

    in

    this area. Similar

    *

    Financial

    support

    from the ESRC

    post-doctoral ellowship

    scheme

    is

    gratefully

    acknow-

    ledged.

    I

    would

    like to thank

    Colin

    Sparrow

    whose

    excellent lectures

    greatly encouragedan

    interest

    n this

    subject.

    I

    am also

    grateful

    or

    comments

    rom

    MargaretBray, David Canning,

    Partha

    Dasgupta, Joy Read,

    Peter

    Read,

    Gene

    Savin,

    Peter

    Sinclairand

    two

    referees of this

    journal.

    (C

    Oxford

    University

    Press 1988

    This content downloaded from 128 239 218 133 on Wed 11 Jun 2014 11:47:02 AM

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/9/2019 Economics of Chaos

    3/32

    2

    THE ECONOMICS OF

    CHAOS OR THE

    CHAOS OF ECONOMICS

    arguments uggest

    that it could be of use to economists. This paper aims

    to

    give an

    introduction o the

    applications

    of chaos

    in

    economics.

    The models in this paper are very simple.

    The reason for this is that a

    detailed mathematical heory

    has

    only been

    constructed or

    one-dimensional

    dynamicalsystems. (That is there is only one dependent variable and the

    system

    of

    equations

    is

    of

    the first

    order

    in

    that

    variable.)

    In

    higher

    dimensions

    there is

    no

    general theory. There

    have been theories developed

    of

    particularequations,

    two

    commonly

    studied examples

    are

    the Lorenz

    equations (Sparrow (1982),

    Guckenheimer and Holmes

    (1983))

    and the

    Henon map (see

    Henon

    (1976)). Higher

    dimension

    systems

    have also been

    studied by

    means

    of

    computer

    simulations.These

    systems

    can

    display

    all the

    kinds

    of

    behavior discussed

    in this

    paper

    and

    other forms of

    complex

    behavior

    as well. Those

    systems

    studied to date have

    largely

    been motivated

    by applicationsof dynamicsystems theoryin the physicalsciences.

    Thus

    economic models

    involving

    chaos are

    not

    always particularly

    realistic.

    The

    reason

    is,

    as

    explainedabove,

    our

    research s as

    yet

    in

    its

    early

    stages.

    The

    simple

    models studied here are

    interesting

    for

    the

    following

    reasons. Most important

    s

    that

    they

    tell us the

    kinds of

    behavior,

    of

    which

    an economic system

    is

    capable. Before

    this

    literature,

    t

    was largelyassumed

    that

    in

    the

    long run,

    an

    economy

    would

    be

    in

    a

    stationary tate (or

    balanced

    growth). Cycles were considered,

    but

    were

    under-emphasizedgiven

    the

    considerable amount

    of

    empirical

    evidence to

    support the

    view that the

    economy

    is

    cyclic. Aperiodic

    motion

    was

    essentially

    not

    considered.

    Economic

    data is

    clearly aperiodic. This,

    however, was put

    down to the

    superposition

    of random shocks onto an

    essentially stationary

    economic

    system.

    Non-linearities

    in

    economic

    systems

    cannot

    be

    denied.

    Little

    attention, however,

    was

    paid

    to

    them. Here we

    give

    an

    account

    of some

    aspects

    of

    the behavior

    of

    non-linear

    systems.

    2.

    Some results from non-linear dynamics

    2.1.

    Linear and non-linear difference equations

    The

    simplest

    difference

    equation is linear

    and first order:

    xt+l

    =

    axt

    (2.1)

    to

    which the solution

    is

    xt

    =

    x0at.

    This

    grows

    exponentially

    f

    laI

    >

    1.

    When

    O

    a

  • 8/9/2019 Economics of Chaos

    4/32

    D.

    KELSEY

    3

    Xt+ll

    XI

    I

    Xt

    XI

    X(

    1/2

    Xt

    1

    FIG.

    1

    first-order,

    but

    are non-linear

    then

    the behavior

    we find is

    very

    different.

    Equation

    (2.2)

    like

    equation

    (2.1)

    is a

    first-order

    difference

    equation.

    Xt+i=fr(xt)

    where

    fr(x)=rx(1-x):

    O

    -r

    e

    -4.

    (2.2)

    Equation

    (2.2)

    is

    often known

    as the

    logistic equation.

    While equation (2.2)

    is also

    of

    the

    first order it is quadratic,

    and hence non-linear.

    Quadratic

    behavior s the

    most

    simple

    kind of

    non-linearity.

    Hence one might expect

    (2.2)

    to behave

    in

    a fairly simple manner as (2.1)

    does. In fact

    as we shall

    see the

    solutions to

    (2.2)

    can

    be extremely

    complex.

    As shown in Fig. 1, fr

    has the

    following properties: fr(O)

    =

    fr(l)

    =

    0.

    fr has

    a unique

    maximum at

    _

    1

    X

    -

    A

    stationary

    solution

    of

    equation

    (2.2) is a sequence

    (xt)

    which is a

    solutionof

    (2.2)

    and is such that

    Vt,

    xt

    =

    x

    for some

    xc

    such that 0

    -x c

    1.

    Graphically

    a

    stationary

    solution

    occurs at a

    point

    where the graph

    of

    fr

    crosses the 450

    line

    (e.g.,

    at

    Yr

    in

    Fig. 2).

    It is

    easily

    seen

    that

    0

    is a

    stationary

    olution

    for

    all

    values

    of

    r.

    Figure

    1

    can also be used to illustrate the

    dynamics of the

    system.

    Suppose

    we start at xo. The

    height

    of

    f(xo)

    =

    x1

    gives

    the second state

    of

    the

    system.

    We

    can

    find

    the

    point corresponding

    o

    x1

    on

    the horizontal

    axis by

    reflecting

    n

    the

    450

    line.

    A

    similar process of going

    up to the function

    and

    reflecting

    n

    the

    450

    line gives the next state of the system x2. Further

    points

    in

    the evolution

    of

    the

    system

    can

    be

    found in

    a

    similar

    manner. The

    successive

    points

    in

    the solution,

    path

    xO,

    x1,

    x2,...

    are

    getting

    closer and

    closer

    to

    the

    origin.

    This will

    happen

    for

    any

    starting point. In Fig. 1 the

    unique

    stationary

    tate at

    the

    origin

    is

    (globally)

    stable.

    Now

    imagine

    that

    we are

    gradually ncreasing

    the parameter

    r,

    and we

    This content downloaded from 128.239.218.133 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 11:47:02 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/9/2019 Economics of Chaos

    5/32

    4 THE ECONOMICS

    OF CHAOS OR THE CHAOS OF ECONOMICS

    xt?1

    XO

    xI

    x2

    Yr

    1/2

    xt

    1

    FIG. 2

    wish

    to observe how

    this affects the

    properties

    of

    the solution.

    The function

    fr

    has a

    single hump.

    As

    r is increased the

    height

    of this

    hump

    increases.

    When

    r

    is

    greater

    than 1

    the

    diagram

    will

    look like Fig.

    2. The graph of fr

    crosses the

    450

    line at two points-the origin and

    Yr

    =

    (r

    -

    1)/r. In fact for

    1

    -

    r

    -

    4, these

    are

    the

    only two stationary solutions of the equation. A

    change

    in the

    dynamics

    of the

    system has occurred. Starting from a typical

    point x0, subsequent

    values

    of

    x

    no

    longer

    tend to the origin but instead

    converge

    on the

    stationary point

    at

    Yr.

    For

    1

    -

    r

    -

    3 the origin is unstable

    and

    Yr

    is

    stable.

    Indeed

    it

    can be shown

    that from

    almost every

    initial

    value

    the

    path

    will

    converge

    to

    Yr

    =

    (r

    -

    1)/r.

    The

    exceptions

    are the

    origin

    which

    is also

    a

    stationary point,

    and

    1,

    which is

    mapped

    to

    the

    stationary point

    at

    the

    origin

    (fr(1)

    =

    0).

    Thus if

    0

    x'

    (0)

    =

    1/zj-'(0)

    =

    1/0

    which

    proves (ii).

    Now

    zj-1(y)

    >

    0

    whenever

    y

    > 0 hence

    using

    (A.4)

    xAM)

    0 which

    proves

    (iii).

    Lemma

    A.2: For

    all

    sufficiently

    large

    a

    we can find

    i(a)

    ?

    y*(a)

    such that:

    (i) U2(M*)>Ul(ft)

    or

    X(j*)>ft

    (ii)

    u2(ft)

    U1(0p*)

    or

    X(ft)

    0p*

    provided

    that

    e1

    +

    e2

    >

    1/e2

    and

    e2

    l/e2

    it

    follows that

    el

    +

    e2

    >

    1.

    Hence we can

    choose

    f

    such

    that 1

    -

    e2

    1/e2

    ande2

  • 8/9/2019 Economics of Chaos

    31/32

    30

    THE ECONOMICS OF

    CHAOS

    OR

    THE

    CHAOS OF

    ECONOMICS

    BRAY,

    M.

    (1982) Learning,

    Estimation and the

    Stability

    of

    Rational

    Expectations,

    Journal of

    Economic Theory 26, 318-339.

    CITANOVIC,

    .

    (1984a) Universality

    in

    Chaos

    (or Feigenbaum

    for

    Cyclists) ,

    Acta Physica

    Polonica A65, 203-239. (Reprinted

    in

    Citanovic (1984b).)

    CITANOVIC,

    P.

    (1984b) Universality

    in

    Chaos,

    Adam

    Hilger,

    Bristol.

    COLLET,

    P. and

    ECKMAN,

    J. P. (1980), Iterated Maps on the Interval as Dynamical Systems,

    Birkhauser Boston.

    CRUTCHFIELD,

    .

    P., FARMER,

    . D. and

    HUBERMAN,

    B. A.

    (1982)

    Fluctuations and

    Simple

    Chaotic Dynamics, Physics Reports

    92,

    45-82.

    DAY,

    R.

    H.

    (1982) Irregular

    Growth

    Cycles,

    American

    Economic

    Review

    72,

    406-414.

    DAY, R. H. (1983)

    The

    Emergence

    of

    Chaos

    from

    Classical

    Economic Growth, Quarterly

    Journal of

    Economics

    98,

    201-213.

    DAY,

    R.

    H. (1986) Unscrambling

    the

    Concept

    of Chaos

    Through Thick and

    Thin

    Reply ,

    Quarterly Journal of

    Economics

    101,

    425-426.

    DENECKERE,

    R. and

    PELIKAN,

    S.

    (1986) Competitive Chaos, Journal of Economic

    Theory

    40, 13-25.

    DIXIT,A. K. (1976) The Theory of Equilibrium Growth, Oxford University Press; Oxford.

    FEIGENBAUM,

    M. J.

    (1980)

    Universal

    Behavior in

    Non-linear

    Systems , Los Alamos

    Science

    1, 4-27. Reprinted

    in Citanovic

    (1984b).

    FRIEDMAN,

    M.

    (1953)

    The

    Methodology

    of

    Positive

    Economics,

    in

    Essays

    in Positive

    Economics, University

    of

    Chicago

    Press, Chicago.

    GAERTNER,

    W.

    (1984)

    Periodic and

    Aperiodic

    Consumer

    Behavior, unpublished.

    GAERTNER, W. (1986) Zyklische

    Konsummester, Jahrbucher fur Nationalokonomie und

    Statistik 201:

    54-65.

    GRANDMONT,

    . M.

    (1983)

    Periodic and

    Aperiodic

    Behavior

    in Discrete

    One-dimensional

    Dynamical Systems,

    CEPREMAP D.P. No.

    8317. Also

    available as a Technical Report

    of EHEC, University of Lausanne.

    GRANDMONT,

    .

    M.

    (1985)

    On

    Endogenous

    Competitive Business Cycles, Econometrica 53,

    995-1045.

    GUCKENHEIMER,

    J. and

    HOLMES,

    P.

    (1983)

    Non-linear

    Oscillations Dynamical Systems and

    Bifurcations of

    Vector

    Fields, Springer-Verlag,

    New

    York, Heidelberg, Berlin.

    HENON,

    M.

    (1976)

    A

    Two-dimensional

    Mapping

    with a

    Strange Attractor, Communications

    in Mathematical

    Physics 50,

    69-77. Reprinted in Citanovic (1984b).

    HIRSCH,

    M. W.

    and

    SMALE,

    S.

    (1974) Differential Equations, Dynamical Systems

    and Linear

    Algebra,

    Academic

    Press,

    New York.

    JAKOBSON,

    M. V.

    (1981) Absolutely

    Continuous

    Invariant Measures for One-Parameter

    Families

    on

    One-Dimensional

    Maps,

    Communications

    in

    Mathematical

    Physics 81,

    39-88.

    LUCAS,

    R. E.,

    JR.

    (1975) An Equilibrium Model of the Business Cycle, Journal of Political

    Economy 83,

    1113-1144.

    LI,

    T. and

    YORKE,

    J.

    A.

    (1975)

    Period Three

    Implies Chaos,

    American

    Mathematical

    Monthly 82,

    985-992.

    MELESE,

    F. and

    TRANSUE,

    W.

    (1986)

    Unscrambling

    Chaos

    Through

    Thick and

    Thin,

    Quarterly

    Journal

    of

    Economics

    101,

    419-424.

    MONTRUCCHIO,

    L.

    (1984) Optimal

    Decisions Over

    Time and

    Strange Attractors, Unpubl-

    ished,

    Politecnico

    di Torino.

    PRESTON,

    C.

    (1983)

    Iterates

    of Maps

    on

    an

    Interval, Springer-Verlag,

    Berlin.

    RAND,

    D.

    (1978)

    Exotic

    Phenomena in

    Games

    and

    Duopoly Models, Journal of

    Mathemati-

    cal Economics 5, 173-184.

    SAMUELSON,

    P.

    (1939)

    Interactions Between

    the

    Multiplier Analysis

    and the

    Principle

    of

    Acceleration,

    Review

    of Economic

    Statistics

    21, 75-78.

    SARGENT,

    T.

    J.

    (1979)

    Macroeconomic

    Theory,

    Academic

    Press,

    New York.

    SEN,

    A. K.

    (1979)

    The Welfare Basis

    of

    Real

    Income

    Comparisons:

    A

    Survey, Journal of

    Economic

    Literature

    XVII,

    1-45.

    This content downloaded from 128.239.218.133 on Wed, 11 Jun 2014 11:47:02 AMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/9/2019 Economics of Chaos

    32/32

    D. KELSEY 31

    SIMON,

    H.

    A.

    (1979)

    Rational

    Decision-Making

    in

    Business Organizations,

    American

    Economic

    Review

    79,

    493-513.

    SINGER, D. (1978)

    Stable

    Orbits and Bifurcations of Maps

    of

    the Interval,

    SIAM

    Journal of

    Applied

    Mathematics

    35, 260.

    SNOWER,

    D.

    (1984)

    Rational

    Expectations,

    Non-linearities

    and

    the

    Effectiveness of

    Monetary

    Policy,

    Oxford Economic

    Papers 36, 177-199.

    SPARROW,C. (1982)

    The Lorenz Equations, Springer-Verlag,

    New

    York, Heidelberg, Berlin.

    ZARNOWITZ,

    V. (1985)

    Recent Work on Business

    Cycles

    in Historical Perspective,

    Journal of

    Economic Literature

    23, 523-580.