41
Center for Economic Institutions Working Paper Series Center for Economic Institutions Working Paper Series Institute of Economic Research Hitotsubashi University 2-1 Naka, Kunitachi, Tokyo, 186-8603 JAPAN Tel: +81-42-580-8405 Fax: +81-42-580-8333 No. 2009-2 “Law and Economic Change in Traditional China: A Comparative Perspective“ Debin Ma September 2009

Economic Perpestive

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Economic Perpestive

Center for Economic Institutions

Working Paper Series

Center for Economic Institutions

Working Paper Series

Institute of Economic Research

Hitotsubashi University 2-1 Naka, Kunitachi, Tokyo, 186-8603 JAPAN

Tel: +81-42-580-8405 Fax: +81-42-580-8333

No. 2009-2

“Law and Economic Change in Traditional China: A Comparative Perspective“

Debin Ma

September 2009

Page 2: Economic Perpestive

1

Law and Economic Change in Traditional China: A Comparative

Perspective1

Debin Ma Economic History Dept.

London School of Economics Email: [email protected]

Sept. 2009

Abstract This article offers a critical review of recent literature on Chinese legal tradition

and argues that some subtle but fundamental differences between the Western and Chinese legal traditions are highly relevant to our explanation of the economic divergence in the modern era. By elucidating the fundamental feature of traditional Chinese legal system within the framework of a disciplinary mode of administrative justice, this article highlights the contrasting growth patterns of legal professions and legal knowledge in China and Western Europe that would ultimately affect property rights, contract enforcement and ultimately long-term growth trajectories. The paper concludes with some preliminary analysis on the inter-linkages between the historical evolution of political institution and legal regimes.

1 I want to thank comments from and discussion with John Drobak, Tirthankar Roy, Billy So, Oliver Volckart, Patrick Wallis, Jan Luiten van Zanden.

Page 3: Economic Perpestive

2

Western law – its unique features of legal formalism and rule of law – as argued

by Max Webster has laid the foundation of Western capitalism and the eventual of the

West (Trubeck 1972). Crucial to the Western legal system is Weber’s distinction

between formal and substantive justice. Under formal justice, legal adjudication and

process for all individual legal disputes are bound by a set of generalised and

well-specified rules and procedures. Substantive justice, on the other hand, seeks the

optimal realisation of maximal justice and equity in each individual case, often with due

consideration to comprehensive factors, whether legal, moral, political or otherwise.

Formal justice tends to produce legal outcomes that are predictable and calculable, even

though such outcomes may often clash with the substantive postulates of religious,

ethical or political expediency in any individual case. Weber believed that formal justice

is unique to the European legal system, with its highly differentiated, specialized and

autonomous professional legal class, independent from the political authority. Legal

rules were consciously fashioned and rulemaking was relatively free of direct

interference from religious influences and other sources of traditional values. Formal

justice reduces the dependency of the individual upon the grace and power of the

authorities, thus rendering it often repugnant to authoritarian powers and demagoguery.

Above all, the rule of law born out of the Western legal tradition supplied what Weber

termed as calculability and predictability, elements essential for explaining the rise of

Western capitalism and its absence in other civilizations.2

The Weberian synthesis permeated the thinking of generation of sinologists on

the Chinese legal tradition. John King Fairbank remarked that “the concept of law is

one of the glories of Western civilization, but in Chinese, attitude toward all laws has

2 Weber (1978), vol.II, p.812. Unger (1976) and Trubek (1972), p.721.

Page 4: Economic Perpestive

3

been a despised term for more than two thousand years. This is because the legalist

concept of law fell far short of the Roman. Whereas Western law has been conceived of

as a human embodiment of some higher order of God or nature, the law of the legalists

(in China) represented only the ruler’s fiat. China developed little or no civil law to

protect the citizen; law remained largely administrative and penal, something the people

attempted to avoid as much as possible” (1960, p.84).

These sentiments on the relative “backwardness” of Chinese legal tradition have

entered into summary form in a recent book by Chinese legal scholar, Zhang Zhongqiu.

The Chinese legal tradition, according to him, originated in tribal wars, was collectivist,

dominated by public law, oriented towards ethical value, singular and closed,

encapsulated in official legal codes, founded on the rule by man, and aimed for the ideal

of no litigation, as contrasted with Western law which originated in clan conflicts, was

individualistic, dominated by private law, oriented towards religious value, plural and

open, expounded by jurisprudence, founded on the rule of law and aimed for justice

(2006). These broad-brush characterizations, while useful to certain degrees, border

on simplistic stereotypes of different legal cultures which have become the target of

criticism from recent waves of revisionist scholarships. Contrary to the traditional

Weberian synthesis, these recent works on Chinese legal tradition have argued that the

Qing imperial legal system, long regarded as the epitome of arbitrary justice, was in fact

far more rule-bound and predicable in their upholding of private property rights and

enforcement of private contracts that previously recognized (see Philip Huang 1996,

Zelin, Ocko and Gardella 2004). Interestingly, this is in line with another separate but

influential argument advanced by Kenneth Pomeranz in his influential book, “Great

Divergence” that views the property rights or the freedom to contract in traditional

China as no less secure or flexible than in Western Europe. The implication of these

Page 5: Economic Perpestive

4

lines of argument that the roots of economic divergence between China and Western

Europe in the modern era needs to be sought in areas other than ideological and

institutional factors.3

This article offers a critical review of recent literature on Chinese legal tradition

and argues that while the recent revisionist literature make significant contribution to a

lively and timely re-examination of traditional Chinese legal system, it overlooks some

subtle but fundamental differences between the Western and Chinese legal traditions

that are crucial to the origin of the economic divergence in the modern era. By

elucidating the fundamental feature of traditional Chinese legal system within the

framework of a disciplinary mode of administrative justice, this article highlights the

contrasting growth patterns of legal professions and legal knowledge in China and

Western Europe that would ultimately affect property rights, contract enforcement and

ultimately long-term growth trajectories. The paper ends with some preliminary analysis

on the inter-linkages between the historical evolution of political institution and legal

regimes.

The rest of the article is divided into three sections followed by a conclusion.

The first section reviews the major feature and the related debate on the nature of

traditional Chinese legal system. The second section offers a comparative analysis on

legal traditions between China and Western Europe. The third section offers some

preliminary analysis on the linkage between political institutions and legal regimes in

China and Europe.

3 For a summary of the California school, see Ma 2004b. See Pomeranz (2000) on the flexibility of traditional Chinese factor markets. See Philip Huang, Zelin et al for these revisionist studies on traditional Chinese legal system

Page 6: Economic Perpestive

5

I. Law and Legal System in Traditional China: Issues and Debates

We start our review of the Chinese legal tradition with Thomas Stephens’s useful

classification of traditional Chinese legal regime as “disciplinary” versus “adjudicative”

or “legal” in the West. A “disciplinary” legal regime is akin to a military tribunal

system whose overriding interest is the sanctioning of deviant behaviour to ensure

group solidarity and social order at large (p.6). We can trace this “disciplinary”

element of traditional Chinese law to etymology. The Chinese word for law, “fa,” (法)

also means “punishment” (刑) (Liang 2002, p. 36, Su, p. 6). In fact, pre-modern

Chinese legal text makes no distinction between punishment and military conquest (兵

刑不分), a contrast to the Latin etymology of “law”, “jus” which specifically denotes

rights (Liang, 2002, p. 37-38).

In traditional Chinese law (as in Rome law), the emperor is the source of law.

Traditional Chinese legal apparatus had been an integral part of the administrative

system with bureaucracy within the hierarchy – from the county level to the emperor –

acting as the arbiter in criminal cases. But there is a system of checks to ensure

consistency. The Chinese penal code was highly elaborate and systematic. The

compilation of China’s first legal code dated to 629 in the Tang dynasty (revised and

completed in 737), only a hundred years later than the Justinian code (drafted in 529

and promulgated in 533). As pointed out by Japanese scholar, Shuzuo Shiga, almost all

the court rulings on criminal cases were required to cite specific official penal codes and

statures as support. Legal decisions on criminal cases, depending on the severity of

punishments, would need to be reviewed through the administrative hierarchy with

capital punishment reviewed and approved by the emperor himself (Shiga et al p.9).

Officials at the lower level would face punishment if their rulings were found to be

mistaken after review.

Page 7: Economic Perpestive

6

Despite the elaboration and sophistication of this legal system, this is in the end a

bureaucratic law designed for the officials to meter out punishments proportionate to the

extent of criminal violations for the purpose of social control. The official legal codes

were structurally organized along the six ministerial divisions under the imperial

bureaucracy: government, revenue, ceremony, justice, military and works (Liang, 1996,

p.128-9). “More than half of the provisions of the Qing code, as pointed out by

William Jones, are devoted to the regulation of ‘the official activities of government

officials’” (cited in Ocko and Gilmartin, p.60). The meticulous and sophisticated

juridical review process is carried out top-down within the administrative hierarchy.

In the case that the emperor made decisions and rulings outside the purview of

extant legal statutes or contravened existing codes, these decisions became new laws or

sub-statutes to be used as legal basis for future cases (Shiga et al, pp.11-12). In fact, as

emphasized by Shiga and Terada, as the formal legal codes changed little over the

dynasties, the emperor’s legal decisions on individual cases formed the single most

important dynamic changes to China’s formal legal system (Shiga et al pp. 120-121).

Although there are no formal legal or constitutional constraints on the imperial power

(except the informal ones such as the much talked about “mandate of heaven”), the

emperors recognize the value of consistency, fairness and balance in the legal system

(Ocko and Gilmartin, p.61). So a “disciplinary” mode of justice may not necessarily

lead to complete arbitrariness.

As the fundamentally penal nature of Chinese legal codes render it un-amenable

to dispute resolution of a commercial and civil nature, this led to the long-held view of a

complete absence of Chinese civil and commercial law. However, new research reveals

that the county magistrates, the lowest level bureaucrats, handled and ruled on a vast

amount of legal disputes of civil and commercial nature that did not entail any corporal

Page 8: Economic Perpestive

7

punishment. Is there an implicit or a functional civil and commercial law in traditional

China?4

Shiga argues these county-level trials were something more akin to a process of

‘didactic conciliation’, a term he borrowed from the studies by Western scholars on the

Tokugawa legal system in Japan. The decisions of the magistrates were not legal

‘adjudications’ as in the Western legal order. The magistrate’s ruling was effective and

a legal case was considered as resolved or terminated only to the point that both litigants

consented to the settlement and made no further attempts for appeals. Although not

common, Shiga did point to cases where a legal dispute dragged on indefinitely when

one of the litigating parties reneged – sometime repeatedly - and thus refused to fulfil

his or her original commitment to the settlement. Thus, this kind of ruling lacked the

kind of binding and terminal force as the legal adjudication in the modern sense

Shiga was also interested in the legal basis of magistrate’s rulings and found that

although invoking general ethical, social or legal norms, they rarely relied on or cited

any specific codes, customs or precedents. In accordance with its intermediation

characteristics, the magistrate’s ruling showed less concern for the adoption of a

reasonably uniform and consistent standard than the resolution of each individual case

with full consideration to its own merits. Shiga made a general case that the

magistrates often resorted to a combination of “situation, reason and law” (情,理,法)

as tools of persuasion or threat where it becomes necessary (see Shiga et al 1998, Shiga

1996, 2002).

This can best be illustrated by a specific case used by Shiga:

A widow of over 70-years old, Mrs. Gao, living in 19th century Shandong

4 For the extent of average people utilising the county level civil trial system, see Susumu Fuma’s article in Shiga et al. and also Huang (1996).

Page 9: Economic Perpestive

8

province pawned land to her junior uncle and his two sons at 45,000 cash. Later, Mrs.

Gao wanted her cousins to buy and take over the land by paying an additional 50,000

cash. The cousins refused and the disputes were taken to the court.

The magistrate started his ruling by declaring that the blood relations are far

more important than money matters and the welfare of the old widow needs to be

looked after by her extended family. As there is a local custom that usually sets the

pawning price of land at half of the sale value of the land, the widow should ask for an

additional 45,000 cash rather than 50,000 from the cousins. The magistrate further

advised that the uncle and his two sons could share in their payment to the widow. The

dispute seemed to be resolved with both parties agreeing to the magistrate’s settlement

(Shiga et al, p. 56).

The specific case shows clearly that the magistrate’s ruling goes far beyond

narrow legal spheres. In fact, he was much more interested in influencing the outcome –

rather than the rules - of the game by bringing about what he viewed a socially ethical

and harmonious outcome at the expense of the original terms of the agreement. His

ruling relied on the power of persuasion more than legal basis. Shiga’s particular

interest in this case comes from the fact this is one of the few that specifically cited a

local custom. But clearly, as Shiga points out, the customs cited here was nowhere

implicated as the legal basis of his ruling or a binding social rule. In fact, Shiga pointed

out other cases where local customs were simply ignored or even condemned (Shiga et

all, pp. 57-59).

The flexibility with which magistrates made their rulings is also confirmed by

Mio Kishimoto’s careful case study of land sales (2003). In many regions, sellers of

land often requested post-sales compensation from their buyers especially following the

rise of land prices after sale. This practise led to widespread abuse with sellers

Page 10: Economic Perpestive

9

requesting compensation at amounts and duration far beyond the customary rule or the

original terms of the agreement. Resorting to reasons of sickness, old age, hunger, bad

harvest, and sometimes blatant extortion, some sellers turn this compensation request

into annual affair (often around the Chinese New Year). In fact, as summarized by

Kishimoto, there is a systematic tendency for magistrates’ rule to lean towards

requesting the relatively wealthy land buyers to compensate the poor in spite of the

original agreement. The fact that that law or legal rulings were often mobilized for

redistributive purpose can be substantiated by the statement from one of China’s

legendary iconoclastic late-Ming bureaucrat海瑞 (Hairei): “When in doubt during a

litigation, my ruling would rather err on the side of the poor than the rich, on the side of

the weak than the powerful”5

These features have led scholars to question the fundamental meaning of courts

and contracts in traditional China. Terada argued that the magistrate’s court more often

served as a forum to renegotiate a settlement to replace the old one based on the

changed conditions. “Contract” in traditional China was merely a written proof of a

mutual agreement which may or may not have power binding the future (Terada 2003,

p.95). Others echoed that “…regardless of subject matter, contracts and “documents of

understanding” were more social than legal in nature because they were rooted in and

protected by the social relationship of the parties;” or alternatively put, “the surest

guarantee of one’s rights seems to have been their acknowledgement by the local

community” (by Myron Cohn and Ann Osborne respectively, cited in Ocko and

Gilmartin, p. 74). Ironically, the importance of social relation behind contracts partly

explains the motivation for litigation at the Magistrates’ court. People filed complaints

5 Cited in Li Qin, 2005, p. 47. Liang Ziping also argued that the magistrate would not hesitate to issue rulings that could result in the alteration or simplification of the original agreements between the litigant parties if this would help “quiet both parties” Liang 1996, pp.134-140.

Page 11: Economic Perpestive

10

to enforce a contract and settle a debt and so on, but getting a case accepted for hearing

also made use of courts to intimidate, coerce, and to turn the balance of social power in

favour of the litigants within the social networks. Parties to private agreements utilized

formal litigation as a means to gain advantages in a power relationship over private

agreements, a process more aptly termed as “litinegotiation” (Ocko and Gilmartin, p.

71). As emphasized by Terada, disputes over properties and contracts were in the end

resolved or regulated through the interplay of social norms, power, compromise and

rational recognition of long-term benefit and cost.6

This largely Weberian interpretation of traditional Chinese legal system met

vigorous challenge from China specialists, Philip Huang. Huang’s interpretation of

Qing archival legal cases of civil disputes led him to conclude that the rulings of

magistrates were far from being arbitrary but rather, rooted in formal legal codes and

seemed legally binding for most of the cases. However, as pointed out in a series of

rebuttals by Shiga and Terada, Huang’s somewhat contentious finding hinges on a very

specific methodology that he adopted. Although there was no evidence to show that

the original rulings by the magistrates cited any legal statues or local customs as their

legal basis, Huang matched the contents of the ruling with the what he deemed as the

relevant codes in the formal Qing legal penal code (Shiga 1996 and Terada 1995).

While there is much to be desired about Huang’s methodology of inserting legal

codes ex post to back up legal rulings made by magistrates several centuries earlier, the

6 See Shiga et al, pp.191-279. One such case in point is recorded by a recent study of the commercial disputes in the highly commercialized Huzhou region of Anhui province in Ming and Qing. According to Han Xouyao, a serious and protracted land dispute between two large lineages in the area broke out and lasted across generation for a total of 128 years (from 1423 to 1551), and saw numerous trials and rulings by the county and prefecture courts and incidences of violent conflicts. In spite of the official ruling from the prefecture court, the disputes only ended with the drafting of a “truce” agreement signed by the two lineages and witnessed by middle men and village elder (pp. 93-117).

Page 12: Economic Perpestive

11

idea that magistrates ruled by some general moral and legal concepts and principles

embedded in formal codes does merit attention.7

In fact, Huang’s criticism of Shiga

thus framed actually takes him close to the original position of Shiga who explicitly

stated that magistrate’s ruling appealed to a wide set of moral and ethical values most of

which could be embedded in formal penal codes. If so, are the legal traditions indeed as

divergent as Weber may have made out to be? After all, Western legal rules also partly

formed through the codification of local customs and norms which may be reflective of

general ethical and moral values. In particular, the English Common law system

exemplifies such a process of law-finding and law-making based on the incorporation of

principles embedded in customs and norms.

II. Convergent or Divergent Legal Traditions?

To appreciate the often subtle yet fundamental differences between the Chinese

and Western legal traditions, we need to incorporate a much more systematic and

historic perspective. It is useful for us to start with Harold Berman’s following

characterization of the fundamental features of Western legal tradition which can be

traced back to the Papal Revolution of the Middle Ages, the starting point of the

political separation between church and state and political fragmentation:

• There is a sharp distinction between legal institutions and other types of

institutions. Custom, in the sense of habitual patterns of behaviour, is

distinguished from customary law, in the sense of customary norms of behaviour

that are legally binding;

• The administration of legal institution is entrusted to a special corps of people, 7 Zelin’s argument on strong property rights and contract enforcement is also based on the fact that Qing’s formal criminal code contains statutes relevant for civil and commercial matters. see Zelin 2004, p.19-23.

Page 13: Economic Perpestive

12

who engage in legal activities on a professional basis;

• The legal professionals are trained in a discrete body of higher learning

identified as legal learning, with its own professional literature and in its own

professional schools.

• There is a separate legal science, or a meta-law. Law includes not only legal

institutions, legal commands, legal decisions and the like but also what legal

scholars say about them;

• Law has a capacity to grow and the growth of law has an internal logic;

• The historicity of law is linked with the concept of its supremacy over the

political authorities. The rulers (or the law-makers) are bound by it;

• Legal pluralism – the co-existence and competition within the same community

of diverse jurisdictions and diverse legal systems – is most distinctive

characteristics of the Western legal tradition (Harold Berman 1983, p. 7-8).

Although formal law especially in commercial affairs evolved slowly in the West

partly because commercial disputes tended to be highly specialized and formal legal

litigation and enforcement extremely costly, there occurred an evolution that led to the

rise of an increasingly unified consistent body of laws based on the compilation of

variously urban laws, guilds laws, in particular the well-known merchant law (lex

mercatorie) centred in major trading centres under autonomous local government or

independent city-states. The modern civil law in many ways formed through the

amalgamation and standardization of traditional customary laws and commercial

practices in different territories of jurisdiction. Major intellectual and political

revolutions such as the Reformation and the Enlightenment movement, particularly the

rise of modern nation-states became a major force that propelled the formation of

Page 14: Economic Perpestive

13

modern Civil Law.8

The most illustrative case of this bottom-up process of legal growth is the

historical development of the English legal system as a system distinct from the

Continental civil law regime. As noted by Maitland, what allowed the English case-law

system to develop, was not just the Parliament or the jury system - as the former was

widespread in Europe and the latter originated in France - but the rise of a professional

legal guild of lawyers and judges organized under the system of inns of court and

chancery and their related training methods based on the study of legal case reports (Li

2003, p.20). Originating in the Medieval era, the inns of court grew from a training

institution to become the equivalent of a law school which by the Tudor times would be

termed as the third University of England (outside Cambridge and Oxford) (J.H.Baker

2002, p. 161). Within this legal profession nurtured an independent jurisprudence that

fostered the rise of an English legal tradition based on the commentaries and analysis of

legal cases.

More importantly, with the Royal judiciary appointments being selected from

among the most prominent members of this legal profession, the seeds of judiciary

independent from political control had been sown. It was through the growing

independence of an English judiciary, largely resolved through the political wrangling

of the seventeenth century that laid the foundation for what was to become the hallmark

of an English constitutional tradition rooted in the rule of law (J.H. Baker 2002, pp.

166-8, Li, chapter 6). The rise of an autonomous legal profession allowed the

development of legal rule and procedure based a professional standard relatively free

from extra-legal influences and thus ensured a sufficient degree of consistency and

8 See Berman 1983 for detailed description of this evolutionary process. See Grief 2006, chapter 10 for the evolution of impartial law in Medieval Europe.

Page 15: Economic Perpestive

14

predictability in legal outcomes based on the case-law methods even before the

establishment of the strict doctrine of binding precedents by the nineteenth century

(Duxbury, chapter 2). Or as Weber put it in the characteristically Weberian jargon:

“while not rational this (common) law was calculable, and it made extensive contractual

autonomy possible” (Weber 1951, p. 102).

The evolution of the Chinese legal regime presents a sharp contrast to the

overtime professionalization in the West. Not only did the entire legal system continue

to be a part of the administrative organ of the state, but also, as Shiga aptly put it, all

parties involved in dispute resolution in traditional China, ranging from magistrates,

third-party witnesses to guarantors and contracting parties remained distinctively

“layman” like (Shiga 2002, chapters 4 and 5). The in-depth research by Chiu Pengsheng

(2004) offers a vivid portrayal of a magistrate’s court in action during Ming and Qing

China. The court session was open to the public, often thronged with various

onlookers sometimes unrelated to any parties of the litigation. With an official

qualification based on his success in a state examination system inculcated in Confucian

classics, and appointed under a three-year country-wide rotating system of bureaucratic

posting, the magistrate was often ill-prepared both in legal expertise and in local

knowledge of the county he was serving. As a magistrate could face demotion or even

physical punishment when his legal decisions were reviewed to be mistaken by the

upper level administrative hierarchy or if the discontent litigants appealed to his

superior (an extremely costly process) against his rulings, the effectiveness of his ruling

to satisfy the review from the above and resolve disputes between litigants became

important.9

9 See Ocko 1988 for the appeals procedure. For the very high costs of litigation at magistrate’s court, see Deng Jianpeng, chapter 2.

Page 16: Economic Perpestive

15

As a result, most magistrates came to rely heavily on the legal assistance of the

so-called 幕友, the private legal secretaries hired at their “personal” expenses. These

legal secretaries were not allowed to be physically present at the court and thus operated

from behind the scene based entirely on the written documentation. The magistrates’

dependence on their personal legal secretaries also induced the rise of a profession

equivalent to what would have been lawyers in the West, the so-called “litigation

masters or pettifoggers”(讼师), who used their legal expertise to assist the litigating

parties in legal proceedings. While these factors pushed for professionalization in the

West, they took a different turn in the Chinese political context of a dominant state

bureaucracy. As their legal assistance tended to encourage legal suits which clearly

clashed with the state objective of social stability, litigation master as a profession had

long been stigmatized with various pejorative labels, branded as illegal and subject to

penal punishment. The memoir of Wang Zhuhui, an eminent legal secretary with a long

and successful career serving various magistrates during the late 18th century, told with

pride how he handled these litigation pettifoggers after catching them: they would be

physically tied to a column in the magistrate’ court and set on public display to witness

the litigation which they helped instigate; they would then be caned and made to repent

in public the next day before being finally released. Indeed, a secret guidebook for the

professional litigation masters specifically advised them not to turn up at the court to

avoid being picked out from among the crowd (Chiu 2004, pp. 55-6). Despite the

official ban, litigation pettifogging flourished as an underground profession that

engaged in drafting legal suits as well as conniving with court runners or clerks to

influence the legal outcome.

The rise of litigation pettifogging also induced a lively body of illegally

published and circulated technical guidebooks for the profession under the general title

Page 17: Economic Perpestive

16

of “The Secret Handbook of the Litigation Masters” (讼师密本). If we add these to

various privately published handbooks for the legal secretaries (such as Wang Zhuhui)

and bureaucrats as well as numerous well-known private compilation of legal cases tried

and ruled in the court, we have a substantial body of legal literature in traditional China

(Zheng 2003, p.497-8). There is an official Chinese version of “jurisprudence”

(Lu-Xue 律学) which almost exclusively focused on technical issues on the application,

interpretation and exposition of official legal punishment. In fact, Shiga pointed out the

etymology of the word 律 (Lu) refer to musical notes, which implies that the Chinese

“Lu-Xue” is all about finding the appropriate scale of punishments for crimes (Shiga et

al, p.16). Clearly, these legal publications in China differed significantly from the

Western jurisprudence developed through the formal institutionalization of an

independent and autonomous legal profession and legal education. For that matter,

Shiga and others also questioned the appropriateness of transliterating the term

“Lu-Xue” as “jurisprudence.” (Zhang Zhongqiu chapter 6, Shiga et al, p.13-15).

What is missing in the state-dominated legal regime is the institutional capacity

to generate bottom-up process of law-finding and law-making. Indeed as pointed out by

Zheng Qin, the published compilation of legal cases often led to the use of “rulings by

analogy” (类比) by officials in their legal trial in order to achieve some form of

consistency in their legal decisions, something of a precursor to a doctrine of precedent.

However, in China, except for those rulings approved by the Imperial government, the

practise of ruling by analogy was often discouraged for fear that officials may deviate

too far from the formal codes or imperial instructions (Zheng, p.501-2).

Similarly, as Jerome Bourgon pointed out that the direct transliteration of modern

Western legal terms on traditional Chinese terms could sometime lead to misconception

of the fundamental gap between the two legal traditions. Bourgon pointed out that there

Page 18: Economic Perpestive

17

is no equivalent legal term in Chinese that corresponds exactly to the Western

terminology for “customs.” The direct transliteration of “custom” for the Chinese word

“xiguan” (习惯) could be misleading. “Customs” in the West was not merely a

sociological phenomenon but also a judicial artefact, asserted by witnesses, or

appreciated by the jury, often with a clear territorial delimitation. In contrast, “customs”

in China, according to Shiga and Bourgon, identifies only loose, mostly unwritten social

practices without territorial delineation. They might at times serve as a reference but

almost never formed the specific legal basis upon which the county magistrates made

their decisions or the litigants made their claims. They do not “harden” into law.

This gulf between formal legal rules and private customs has been widely noted.

Deng Jianpeng for example pointed to the clear expressions of private property rights in

various forms could be found in the tens of thousands of private land sale contracts in

traditional China. But there were few attempts of any systematic institutionalization or

codification of these rights in the state legal system whose overriding interest in private

land transactions had remained in the securing of land taxes.10

10 See Deng Jianpeng, chapter 1 for various examples how property rights in land were often identified with the payment of state land taxes. Bourgon 2006 makes similar points. For some recent studies that reveal the highly sophisticated and rational features of private customary practices in land contracts in traditional China, see Long Denggao.

The other illuminating

example is the case of copy rights in traditional China. Contrary to the contemporary

image of an absent tradition in intellectual property rights, Deng argued that the early

invention and diffusion of printing had led to rising demand and repeated attempts by

the publishers to assert and defend property rights of their printed editions, yet none of

these attempts received any clear backing from the state or institutionalization in the

formal legal system. Meanwhile, the state’s own heavy handed regulation of publication

and copy rights were largely motivated by political censorship or the protection of state

Page 19: Economic Perpestive

18

sponsored publications of Confucian classics (Deng, chapter 3).

So, in short, we need to distinguish a legal regime that has the capacity to

transform disparate customs and norms into generalizable and positive legal rules or

precedents as in the West from one that entrusted and embedded similar moral and

ethical principles in the hearts and minds of individual bureaucrats or mediators as in

the case of traditional China. As internalized and intuitive reasoning did not enter into a

sphere of public knowledge subject to debate, reflection, analysis or synthesis, they did

not possess one of the most important dynamic element that Berman emphasized for

European law: its historicity, or its capacity to grow with its own internal logic. This

may be the distinguishing hallmark between the rule of law and rule of man, a point that

could be lost in the type of ex-post “matching exercise” conducted among recent

Chinese legal revisionist scholarship.

III. Political Institutions, Legal Regimes and Public Knowledge

To understand the roots of this divergence in legal traditions, we may need to go

beyond mere intellectual sphere and venture into the larger historical context of political

structures in a centralized empire in China versus political fragmentation and

independent competing power groups within each polity in Western Europe.11

11 Shiga attributed the non-adjudictive legal regime in traditional China to the absence of “adversary” culture in traditional China as could be seen in ancient Greece. See Shiga 2002, p.368. This cultural explanation seems hard to square with the motto held by victory-driven litigation masters in Ming and Qing China: “to win one hundred legal suits out of one hundred” (Chiu, 2003).

The

peculiar political structure that had fragmented Western European political landscape

since the Medieval era not only made possible a regime of inter-state competition, but

also created autonomous space within a single polity for independent corporate bodies

that embodied commercial or propertied interest. As argued by Greif (2008), the

Page 20: Economic Perpestive

19

existence of elites with administrative powers in Europe constituted an essential

pre-condition for the rise of constitutionalism. In England, the ability of

parliamentarians to mobilize administrative and military counterweight against the King

created space for the growth of these independent corporate bodies such as the legal

community. Indeed, the legal community sided with the parliamentarians to control the

jurisdiction of the King’s prerogative courts in the seventeenth century (Berman 1983,

pp. 214-215). Even as the supreme ruler of the land, King James I was famously

admonished by his own royal chief justice, Edward Coke, that that the power of

adjudicating legal cases did not lie in his hands, but in those of professionally trained

judges guided by the laws and customs of England (ibid p. 464).

In this regard, the precocious rise of a unitary political rule in imperial China

offers a mirror case study. While early elaboration and “rationalization” of a

bureaucratic law that served well the aim of political control and social stability, the

political dominance of a unitary imperial rule founded on the elimination of any

independent contending elites and supported by a highly centralized bureaucratic

machine could have possibly stifled the growth of a civil society which were essential

for the existence of an independent legal profession. Ultimately, a legal system

embedded within this type of political structure remained dependent upon a power

structure.12

12 For a narrative on the political structure in traditional China and non-alignment of the imperial rulers and property class,see Ma 2009 and also Deng.

Often higher level officials and gentries with higher degrees were simply

beyond the laws of the magistrate’s court or courts of any bureaucracy at the lower

hierarchy. Chinese law, as pointed out in Ch’u T’ung-tsu’s classic study, is

fundamentally hierarchical with the senior members in a society (whether defined by

bureaucratic status, age or gender) entitled to lesser punishment to the same crime than

Page 21: Economic Perpestive

20

the junior ones.

In this system, properties or property rights were only derivative to social and

political status of individual members within the power hierarchy. The concentration

of wealth in the distinctively bureaucratic class of Chinese gentry and the massive

investment of Chinese merchant lineage in their offspring’ preparation for China’s Civil

Service Examination are all testimony to the predominance of political posts over

property ownership.13

This dilemma may not be paradoxical in the context of substantive justice as

delineated by Weber. The lack of hard rules and objective standards, while posing risks

for property rights and contracts, gives the authority discretionary power to influence

the outcome of certain actions ex-post in an intended direction. The lack of distinction

between legal and extra-legal, or what Liang Ziping termed as “ethicalization of law”

and “legalization of ethics”, gives the rulers a free hand to intervene where they saw fit

in almost any aspect of Chinese society, public or private, criminal or civil (Liang 2002,

chapters 10 and 11). Meanwhile, given the resource constraint of a traditional empire,

it also gives the rulers the discretion to keep their hands free from areas where no direct

state interest was at stake. Indeed, the states’ long-standing policies on civil and

In the West, the political institution of representation, defined

and endowed the property owners and wealthy elites with political power. In China, the

channel of power went in the opposite direction: from political power emanated the

property. Hence, Deng Jianpeng presented a case of a fundamental dilemma of property

rights in China: the absence of formal legal protection sent property owners to seek

custody under political power, yet property defined and acquired through political

power lacked legality (Deng, p. 69).

13 See Chang Chung-li for the enormous wealth accumulated by Chinese gentry bureaucrats. For widespread practise of buying official titles by wealthy families see Deng, p.68-69.

Page 22: Economic Perpestive

21

commercial disputes were to discourage formal litigation and encourage self-resolution.

In many cases, the state found it expedient to “farm out” coercive violence or

disciplinary duties to non-official elites as a means of social control.14

It is important to note that this disciplinary mode of justice coupled with

community sanctioning mechanism supported a high degree of market exchange and

commercialization as we observed throughout Chinese history. Furthermore, even in the

West, relationship and personal based mechanism of contract enforcement remained

important and functional in the presence or “shadow” of formal justice. In fact, as

pointed out by Greif and others, informal mechanism probably functioned well or even

better than a formal legal system (which is expensive to set up) when the extent of

exchange and the scale of operations remain small and local (Greif 2006 and John Li). It

was when the scale, the extent and frequency of exchange began to stretch across space

and time that the costs and risks tend to grow exponentially. An independent formal legal

system with replicable standard and enforceable rule is a powerful aid to the large scale of

impersonal exchange and complicated commercial and industrial organizations that had

characterized modern capitalism. Indeed, Thomas Stephen’s characterization of Chinese

legal system as a disciplinary mode of justice was constructed in the context of the treaty

port of Shanghai where Western and traditional Chinese legal system came head to head.

It was the rise of exterritorial rights and a Western legal system that underpinned the rise of

In turn the state

would impose a system of collective responsibility over the leaders of these groups and

communities. Judged in this light, substantive justice is very cost-effective and

distinctly rational.

14 Shiga, for example, documented in detail the sanctioning of the power of capital punishment to lineage leaders over their own members subject to official review (2002, chapter 2). For the power of corporeal punishment in villages and guilds, see Han 2004, chapter 2 and Weber 1951, chapters 4.

Page 23: Economic Perpestive

22

large-scale Western and Chinese enterprises to support the phenomenal rise of modern

Shanghai in the early 20th century (see Ma 2008).

There is a dynamic advantage of a formal legal system associated with the

growth of public knowledge in the form of jurisprudence. Indeed, as others have argued

that the logic of legal growth through the derivation of transcendental rules from the

study of practical legal cases and private customs based on jurisprudential reasoning in

many ways paralleled some methodological features that underpinned early modern

scientific revolution. Just as the growth of an autonomous science community had been

essential to the rise of the scientific revolution, the rise and growth of an independent

legal and academic community running from the apprenticeship based training legal

guild to the higher institution of university law school also underpinned the basis of

European legal revolutions.15

In this context, Joel Mokyr’s recent resurrection of the role of the scientific

revolution and industrial enlightenment to the industrial revolution in England is highly

relevant. The significance of the industrial revolution lies in its cumulative and

sustainable effect on growth which is distinguished from earlier growth spurts that

usually peter out after a period. What changed in 18th century Europe is what he

termed an expanded epistemic base resultant from the foundation of scientific

revolution and industrial enlightenment. Key to this argument is that knowledge has the

characteristics of a public good and acts as a fixed input that could generate scale

economies. Furthermore, through a feedback loop between what he termed prescriptive

and propositional knowledge, knowledge itself generates a learning process that creates

15 See again J.H. Baker (2002) for the case of English legal community and Berman (2002, pp. 265-9) for an argument on the methodological linkage between legal jurisprudence and scientific thought in the seventeenth century. Toby Huff (2003) represents a major proponent on the linkage between legal institution and scientific revolution in the West.

Page 24: Economic Perpestive

23

new knowledge (Mokyr 2002).

While much has already been written in the sphere of science technology, future

research should also explore the mechanism that ties together the role of political

institution, legal regime and jurisprudence (as public knowledge) to long-term economic

growth.16

III Conclusion

This thesis might also be highly relevant for explaining long-term economic

and institutional trajectory in traditional China. The process of social and collective

learning – a process which might be the key to cumulative long-term institutional

change – would either falter or truncate when legal knowledge was driven to secret

circulation or legal community turned underground as in traditional China. The lack or

paucity of new ideas theories on political and legal regimes might well explain the

frequent change of political regimes or dynasties marked by violent rebellions and

revolutions throughout Chinese history often degenerated into mere modified

replications of the old order that the rebellion had come to replace.

Our debate on the “Great Divergence” should integrate the divergent traditions in

legal traditions and institutions between China and the West in the early modern period.

To the extent that those institutional and epistemological elements that underpinned the

legal revolution in the 11th and 12th century – the separation of Church and state, the

emergence of an independent territorial jurisdiction, the pursuit of transcendental,

objective and rectifiable standards – were also relevant, as argued by Toby Huff, for the

rise of a scientific revolution in early modern Europe, one needs to take seriously the

linkage between legal institutions and the origins of the industrial revolution.

It is important to note that the relative efficiency hypothesis of divergent legal

16 For a narrative on the feedback loop that runs from the ideas of John Locke, the French enlightenment thinkers and the American federalists and the political events of Glorious Revolution, American Independence and French revolution, see Berman 2003, pp.13-16.

Page 25: Economic Perpestive

24

traditions is a positive not a normative statement. Nor is it a verdict against the

relative merits of comparative civilizations or multiculturalism. The Western

experience shows that a private social order not only constitutes the evolutionary basis

for public institutions but also continues to play an indispensable role even in modern

economies. In China, the inherited cultural and institutional endowments are essential

to the making of economic miracles. The long experience of social networks,

communities and informal institutions accumulated in China helped reduce transaction

costs and supplied trust to enable economic growth to occur in the 19th and 20th

centuries even before the clarification and reform of formal rules and institutions. The

traditional preference for flexibility over fixed rules may have helped Chinese reform in

the early 1980s to successfully evade much of the ideological rigidities with little social

tension. This may have contributed to the spontaneous emergence of institutional

innovations of a highly experimental and often ad-hoc nature ranging from the

household responsibility system, the township and village enterprise, to the overseas

Chinese networks of FDI to China.

These developments have led to reinterpretation of Chinese economic history

which has taken to task the long-term stagnation thesis and contend for a case of

substantial progress in industrial and agricultural technologies, expansion of regional

trade, growth in urbanization, and perhaps even demographic transition for early

modern China. While both the post-WWII East Asian miracle and post 1980s China

miracle provided the important motivation for the revisionist impulse, it is often too

easy to forget how much political and institutional transformations had transpired in the

last one and half century to enable modern economic growth as achieved today. What

probably distinguished East Asia from the rest of the developing world today, or what

Max Weber had failed to anticipate, is her learning capacity to absorb not only Western

Page 26: Economic Perpestive

25

technology but also formal institutions - from legal system to state-building and to

monetary regimes. One of the pillars of the Meiji reform in Japan was the adaptive

introduction of Western legal institutions ranging from the Constitution to commercial

law, to modern accounting and joint stock corporations. In China, legal reform was

delayed until after the turn of the 20th century when the first set of civil and commercial

codes were being compiled with the aid of Japanese legal specialists.17

Clearly, the administrative nature of Chinese traditional justice continues to exert

a dominant influence on contemporary Chinese legal apparatus under the garb of a

Western Civil Law regime. The fact that economic growth occurred largely in the

absence of rule of law during the last two decades should not be viewed as a vindication

of its irrelevance. On the contrary, Chinese economic reform borrowed and used

ready-made institutions founded on those legal concepts that had taken centuries to

evolve in Western Europe. Eventually to sustain the growth beyond the stage of

institutional adaptation, a transition to the rule of law, one form or another, may become

imperative for China.

But with the

collapse of the Qing empire and the nation thrown into civil disorder after 1911, the

implementation of legal and institutional reform was severely curtailed. As I argued

elsewhere, much of the economic divergence in today’s East Asia could be traced to the

differential patterns of political and institutional response to the Western challenge in

the mid-19th century (2004a).

17 It was also in the 1920s that a government sponsored massive survey of various private customs on private property rights and contracts were conducted with the aim of deriving formal legal rules from private customs. See Liang 1996.

Page 27: Economic Perpestive

26

Baker, J. H. (2002) An Introduction to English Legal History (4th Edition) Butterworths,

LexisNexis.

References:

Berman, Harold (1983) Law and revolution : the formation of the Western legal

tradition. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

____________ (2003) Law and revolution II : The Impact of the Protestant

Reformations on the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge: Harvard University

Press.

Bourgon, Jerome (2002). “Uncivil Dialogue: Law and Custom Did not Merge into Civil

Law under the Qing” Late Imperial China. Vol. 23, No.1 (June 2002): 50-90.

______________ (2007). “Figures in the Carpet: a Discussion about “Customs” and

“Contracts” in Qing Legal Culture” unpublished paper.

Chang, Chung-li (1955) The Chinese Gentry: Studies on Their Role in Nineteenth

Century Chinese Society. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Ch’u T’ung-Tsu (1980) Law and Society in Traditional China. Westport, Conn :

Hyperion Press.

Duxbury, N. (2008) The Nature and Authority of Precedent. Cambridge University

Press.

Greif, Avner (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy. Cambridge

University Press.

_________ (2008) “The Impact of Administrative Power on Political and Economic

Development: Toward Political Economy of Implementation” chapter one in

Institutions and Economic Performance. Edited by Elhanan Helpman.

Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Huang, Philip (1996), Civil Justice in China: Representation and Practice in the Qing.

Page 28: Economic Perpestive

27

Stanford, California: Stanford University Press.

Huff, Toby (2003). The rise of early modern science: Islam, China, and the West. 2nd ed.

Cambridge University Press.

Li, John Shuhe (2003), “Relation-based versus Rule-based Governance: an Explanation

of the East Asian Miracle and Asian Crisis” Review of International Economics,

11(4), 651-673, 2003.

Ma, Debin (2004a) “Why Japan, Not China, Was the First to Develop in East Asia:

Lessons from Sericulture, 1850-1937” Economic Development and Cultural Change

January 2004, volume 52, No. 2, 369-394.

_________ (2004b) “Growth, Institutions and Knowledge, a Review and Reflection on

the Historiography of 18-20th Century China” Vol. 44, Issue 3, Nov. 2004.

Australia Economic History Review (special issue on Asia).

__________ (2008) “Economic Growth in the Lower Yangzi Region of China in

1911–1937: A Quantitative and Historical Analysis” The Journal of Economic

History, Vol. 68, Issue 2, June 2008, pp. 355-392.

__________ (2009). Incentives and Information: An Institutional Interpretation of the

Chinese State and Great Divergence in the Early Modern Era” at

http://www.lse.ac.uk/collections/economicHistory/States%20and%20Growth/ma.

pdf.

Mokyr, Joel (2002) The Gifts of Athena, Historical Origin of the Knowledge Economy.

Princeton University Press.

Ohnesorge, John (2003), “China’s Economic Transition and the New Legal Origins

Literature” China Economic Review, 14(2003) 485-493.

Ocko, J. (1988), “I Will Take It All the Way to Beijing: Capital Appeals in the Qing”

Journal of Asian Studies. No. 2, 291-315 (May 1988).

Page 29: Economic Perpestive

28

Ocko, J. and Gilmartin, D. (2009) “State, Sovereignty, and the People: a Comparison of

the ‘Rule of Law’ in China and India” Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 68, No. 1.

(Feb.) 2009, 55-133.

Pomeranz, Kenneth (2004) The Great Divergence, Europe, China, and the Making of

the Modern World Economy, Princeton University Press.

Stephens, Thomas (1992) Order and Discipline in China, the Shanghai Mixed Court

1911-27. University of Washington Press.

Trubek, David (1972) “Max Weber on Law and the Rise of Capitalism” Wisconsin Law

Review Vol. 1972:720, No.3.

Unger, R. M. (1976), Law in Modern Society: Toward a Criticism of Social Theory. New

York: Free Press.

Weber, Max (1951) The Religion of China, Confucianism and Taoism. Glencoe, IL: The

Free Press.

___________ (1978). Economy and Society, vols. I & II. Berkeley: University of

California Press.

Zelin, M., Ocko, J. and Gardella, R. (eds.) (2004) Contract and property in early modern

China. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.

Chiu, Pengsheng (2003) “以法为名 – 讼师与幕友对明清法律秩序的冲击” (In the

Name of Law – The Impact of Litigation Masters and Legal Secretaries on Ming

and Qing Legal Order). 新史学 Vol. 15, No. 4.

Chinese:

Deng, Jianpeng (2006) 财产权利的贫困 (The Poverty of Property) Beijing: Law

Press.

Han, Xouyao (2004) Civil Disputes and Resolution in Ming and Qing Huizhou, Anhui

Page 30: Economic Perpestive

29

University Press.

Fuma, Susumu (1998) “明清时代的讼师与诉讼制度” (The Litigant Masters and the

Litigation System in Ming and Qing) in Shiga, Shuzo; Terada, Hiroaki;

Kishimoto, Mio; and Fuma, Susumu (1998). 明清时期的民事审判与民间契约

(Civil Trials and Civil Contracts in Ming and Qing China) (edited by Wang

Yaxin and Liang zhiping). Beijing: Law Press, pp. 389-430.

Kishimoto, Mio (2003). “The Problem of ‘Compensation and Repurchase’ in Ming and

Qing” in Yang yifan (ed.) Investigation on Chinese Legal History. Beijing:

Chinese Social Science Press.

Li, Honghai (2003) 普通法的历史解读 (Historical Interpretation of the Common

Law). Beijing: Tsinghua University Press.

Li, Qin (2005) 民国时期的契约制度研究 (A Study on the Contract System in

Republic China). Beijing University Press.

Liang, Ziping (1996) 清代习惯法:社会与国家 (Customary Law in Qing: Society and

the State). Beijing: Zhongguo Zhenfa University Press.

___________ (2002) 寻找自然秩序中的和谐 (In Search of Harmony in Natural

Order). Beijing: Beijing Law University Press.

Long, Denggao (2007) “On the Financial Function of Chinese Land Market”. Chapter

in 中 国 工 商 业 与 金 融 变 迁 (The Evolution of Chinese Industry,

Commerce and Finance, an International Symposium) edited by QiuGeng Liu

and Debin Ma. Shijiazhuang, China: Hebei University Press, 2009.

Shiga, Shuzo; Terada, Hiroaki; Kishimoto, Mio; and Fuma, Susumu (1998). 明清时期

的民事审判与民间契约 (Civil Trials and Civil Contracts in Ming and Qing

China) (edited by Wang Yaxin and Liang zhiping) Beijing: Law Press.

Su, Yegong (2000) Ming Qing Legal Codes and Statures, Beijing: China Law

Page 31: Economic Perpestive

30

University Press.

Zhang, Zhongqiu (2006) 中西法律文化比较研究 (A Comparative Research on Legal

Culture in China and the West). Beijing: China Law University Press.

Zheng, Qin (2003). 清代法律制度研究 (A Study on Qing Legal System). Beijing:

Beijing Law University Press.

Japanese

Terada, Hiroaki (1995), “清代民事司法論における‘裁判’と‘調停’“ (“Adjudication”

and “Conciliation” in Qing Civil Justice – a Response to Philip Huang’s recent

works). Chugoku Shigaku vol. 5, (1995) pp. 177-213.

:

____________ (2004) “Agreement and Contract” chapter 4 in Asia in Comparative

Perspective: Ownership, Contracts, Markets, Fairness and Justice. edited by T.

Miura, M. Kishimoto and T. Sekimoto. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.

Shiga, Shuzo (1996) “清代の民事裁判について” (On Civil Adjudication in Qing)

Chugoku Shakai to Bunka 12: 226-32.

Shiga, Shuzo (2002) 清代中国の法と裁判 (Law and Adjudication in Qing China) 2nd.

Edition. Tokyo: Soubunsha.

Page 32: Economic Perpestive

WP-1

Center for Economic Institutions Working Paper Series

2000-1 Jean Tirole, “Corporate Governance,” January 2000.

2000-2 Kenneth A. Kim and S. Ghon Rhee, “A Note on Shareholder Oversight and the

Regulatory Environment: The Japanese Banking Experience,”January 2000. 2000-3 S. Ghon Rhee, “Further Reforms after the “BIG BANG”: The JapaneseGovernment Bond

Market,”June 2000. 2000-4 Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov , Joseph Fan , and Larry Lang, “Expropriation of Minority

Shareholders in East Asia,”July 2000. 2000-5 Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov, Joseph Fan , and Larry Lang, “The Costs of Group

Affiliation: Evidence from East Asia,” July 2000. 2001-1 Masaharu Hanazaki and Akie Takeuchi, “An International Comparison of Corporate

Investment Behavior -Some Implications for the Governance Structure in Japan-,” February 2001.

2001-2 Katsuyuki Kubo, “The Determinants of Executive Compensation in Japan and the UK:

Agency Hypothesis or Joint Determination Hypothesis?” February 2001. 2001-3 Katsuyuki Kubo, “Changes in Directors’ Incentive Plans and the Performance of Firms in

the UK,” March 2001. 2001-4 Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Value: Evidence from

Thailand,” March 2001. 2001-5 Katsuyuki Kubo, “The Effect of Managerial Ownership on Firm Performance: Case in

Japan,” March 2001. 2001-6 Didier Guillot and James R. Lincoln, “The Permeability of Network Boundaries: Strategic

Alliances in the Japanese Electronics Industry in the 1990s,” March 2001. 2001-7 Naohito Abe, “Ageing and its Macroeconomic Implications-A Case in Japan-,” May 2001. 2001-8 Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “The Equity Ownership Structure of Thai Firms,” July 2001. 2001-9 Megumi Suto, “Capital Structure and Investment Behaviour of Malaysian Firms in the

1990s--A study of Corporate Governance before the Crisis--,” August 2001. 2001-10 Naohito Abe, Noel Gaston, and Katsuyuki Kubo, “Executive Pay in Japan : The Role of

Bank-Appointed Monitors and the Main Bank Relationship,” September 2001. 2001-11 Colin Mayer, “The Financing and Governance of New Technologies,” September 2001. 2001-12 Masaharu Hanazaki and Akiyoshi Horiuchi, “Can the Financial Restraint Hypothesis

Explain Japan’s Postwar Experience?” September 2001. 2001-13 Shin-ichi Fukuda, “The Role of Long-term Loans for Economic Development: Empirical

Evidence in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan,” September 2001.

Page 33: Economic Perpestive

WP-2

2001-14 S. Ghon Rhee, “Further Reforms of the JGB Market for the Promotion of Regional Bond Markets,” September 2001.

2001-15 Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov, Joseph P. H. Fan, and Larry H. P. Lang, ”The Benefits

and Costs of Internal Markets: Evidence from Asia’s Financial Crisis,” September 2001. 2001-16 Kenneth A. Kim and John R. Nofsinger, “Institutional Herding, Business Groups, and

Economic Regimes: Evidence from Japan,” September 2001. 2001-17 Mitsuhiro Fukao, “Financial Deregulations, Weakness of Market Discipline, and Market

Development: Japan’s Experience and Lessons for Developing Countries,” September 2001. 2001-18 Akio Kuroda and Koichi Hamada, “Towards an Incentive Compatible Financial System:

Accounting and Managing the Non-Performing Loans,” September 2001. 2001-19 Randall Morck and Bernard Yeung, “Japanese Economic Success and the Curious

Characteristics of Japanese Stock Prices,” September 2001. 2001-20 Miguel A. García-Cestona, “Ownership Structure, Banks and the Role of Stakeholders: The

Spanish Case,” September 2001. 2001-21 Joseph P. H. Fan and T. J. Wong, “Corporate Ownership Structure and the Informativeness

of Accounting Earnings in East Asia,” September 2001. 2001-22 Heather Montgomery, “The Effect of the Basel Accord on Bank Lending in Japan,”

September 2001. 2001-23 Naoyuki Yoshino, Sahoko Kaji, and Ayako Suzuki, “The Basket-peg, Dollar-peg and

Floating---A Comparative Analysis of Exchange Rate Regimes,” September 2001. 2001-24 Colin Mayer, Koen Schoors, and Yishay Yafeh, “Sources of Funds and Investment

Strategies of Venture Capital Funds: Evidence from Germany, Israel, Japan and the UK,” September 2001.

2001-25 Yukinobu Kitamura, Megumi Suto, and Juro Teranishi, “Towards a New Architecture for

the Japanese Financial System: Participation Costs, Intermediated Ownership and Wealth Distribution,”September 2001.

2002-1 Evgeni Peev, “The Political Economy of Corporate Governance Change in Bulgaria:

Washington Consensus, Primitive Accumulation of Capital, and Catching-Up in the 1990,” March 2002.

2002-2 Naohito Abe, “Saving, Capital Flows, and the Symmetric International Spillover of

Industrial Policies,” June 2002. 2002-3 Masaharu Hanazaki and Akiyoshi Horiuchi, “A Review of Japan’s Bank Crisis from the

Governance Perspective,” July 2002. 2002-4 Chutathong Charumirind, Raja Kali and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Crony Lending:

Thailand before the Financial Crisis,” September 2002. 2002-5 Maitreesh Ghatak and Raja Kali, “Financially Interlinked Business Groups,” September

2002. 2002-6 Tarun Khanna, Joe Kogan, and Krishna Palepu, “Globalization and Similarities in Corporate

Governance: A Cross-Country Analysis,” September 2002.

Page 34: Economic Perpestive

WP-3

2002-7 Chongwoo Choe, “Delegated Contracting and Corporate Hierarchies,” September 2002. 2002-8 Tarun Khanna and Yishay Yafeh, “Business Groups and Risk Sharing around the World,”

September 2002. 2002-9 Yitae Kim, Kwangwoo Park, Ronald A. Ratti, and Hyun-Han Shin, “Do Main Banks Extract

Rents from their Client Firms? Evidence from Korean Chaebol,” September 2002. 2002-10 Armen Hovakimian, Edward J. Kane and Luc Laeven, “How Country and Safety-Net

Characteristics Affect Bank Risk-Shifting,” September 2002. 2002-11 Vidhan K. Goyal and Takeshi Yamada, “Asset Price Shocks, Financial Constraint, and

Investment: Evidence from Japan,” September 2002. 2002-12 Clive S. Lennox, “Opinion Shopping and Audit Committees,” September 2002. 2002-13 Seki Obata, “Pyramid Business Groups in East Asia: Insurance or Tunneling? ,” September

2002. 2002-14 Ishtiaq Pasha Mahmood and Will Mitchell, “Two Faces: Effects of Business Groups on

Innovation in Emerging Economies,” September 2002. 2002-15 Kwangwoo Park, “Foreign Ownership and Firm Value in Japan,” September 2002. 2002-16 Adrian van Rixtel, Yupana Wiwattanakantang, Toshiyuki Souma, and Kazunori Suzuki,

“ Banking in Japan: Will “To Big To Fail” Prevail?” December 2002. 2002-17 Stijn Claessens and Leora F. Klapper, “Bankruptcy around the World: Explanations of its

Relative Use,” December 2002. 2003-1 Anya Khanthavit, Piruna Polsiri, and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Did Families Lose or

Gain Control after the East Asian Financial Crisis?” February 2003. 2003-2 Hidenobu Okuda, Hidetoshi Hashimoto, and Michiko Murakami, “The Estimation of

Stochastic Cost Functions of Malaysian Commercial Banks and Its Policy Implications to Bank Restructuring,” February 2003.

2003-3 Masaharu Hanazaki and Liuqun, “Asian Crisis and Corporate Governance, (in Japanese)”

March 2003. 2003-4 Fukuju Yamazaki and Hiroyuki Seshita, ”Economic Analysis of Bankruptcy law in Japan,

(in Japanese)” February 2003. 2003-5 Hirofumi Uchida and Hiroshi Osano, “Bank Monitoring and Corporate Governance in Japan,

(in Japanese)” March 2003. 2003-6 Fukunari Kimura and Kozo Kiyota, “Foreign Ownership and Corporate Performance:

Evidence from Japanese Micro Data, (in Japanese)” March 2003. 2003-7 Yukinobu Kitamura, “Corporate Profit and Debt- Panel Data Analysis of The Japanese

Firms in the 1990s, (in Japanese)” March 2003. 2003-8 Chaiyasit Aunchitworawong, Toshiyuki Soma, and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, "Do

Families Control Banks Prevail after the East Asia Financial Crisis? Evidence from Thailand" March 2003.

Page 35: Economic Perpestive

WP-4

2003-9 Junko Maru, Yasuhiro Yonezawa and Yuki Matsumoto, "Corporate Governance by Foreign

Investors in East Asia Corporations (in Japanese)" March 2003. 2003-10 Sui Qing-yuan, "Declining Firm's Dependence upon Bank Borrowing and Corporate

Performance (in Japanese)" March 2003. 2003-11 Katsumi Matsuura, "Changes in Ownership Structures and Their Impacts upon Corporate

Performance in Japan (in Japanese)" March 2003. 2003-12 Kathy S. He, Randall Morck and Bernard Yeung, “Corporate Stability and Economic

Growth,” May 2003. 2003-13 Robert Dekle and Heajin Ryoo, “Exchange Rate Fluctuations, Financing Constraints,

Hedging, and Exports: Evidence from Firm Level Data,” June 2003. 2003-14 Tsun-Siou Lee, Yin-Hua Yeh and Rong-Tze Liu, ”Can Corporate Governance Variables

Enhance the Prediction Power of Accounting-Based Financial Distress Prediction Models?,” June 2003.

2003-15 Hideaki Miyajima and Yishay Yafeh, “Japan’s Banking Crisis: Who has the Most to Lose? ,”

June 2003. 2003-16 Guifen Pei, “Asset Management Companies in China,” June 2003. 2003-17 Takeshi Nagase, “The Governance Structure of IPO Firm in Japan,” July 2003. 2003-18 Masaharu Hanazaki and Qun Liu, “The Asian Crisis and Corporate Governance ―

Ownership Structure, Debt Financing, and Corporate Diversification ― ,” July 2003. 2003-19 Chutatong Charumilind, Raja Kali and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Connected Lending:

Thailand before the Financial Crisis,” July 2003. 2003-20 Gilles Hilary and Tomoki Oshika, “Shareholder activism in Japan: social pressure, private

cost and organized crime,” August 2003. 2003-21 Sanghoon Ahn, “Technology Upgrading with Learning Cost,” September 2003. 2003-22 Masaharu Hanazaki and Akiyoshi Horiuchi, “Have Banks Contributed to Efficient

Management in Japan’s Manufacturing? ,” November 2003. 2003-23 Chongwoo Choe and In-Uck Park, “Delegated Contracting and Corporate Hierarchies,”

November 2003. 2003-24 Bruno Dallago, ”Comparative Economic Systems and the New Comparative Economics:

Foes, Competitors, or Complementary?,” November 2003. 2003-25 Adrian van Rixtel, Ioana Alexopoulou and Kimie Harada, “The New Basel Capital Accord

and Its Impact on Japanese Banking: A Qualitative Analysis,” November 2003. 2004-1 Masaharu Hanazaki, Toshiyuki Souma and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Silent Large

Shareholders and Entrenched Bank Management: Evidence from Banking Crisis in Japan,” January 2004.

2004-2 Ming Ming Chiu and Sung Wook Joh, “Bank Loans to Distressed Firms: Cronyism, bank

governance and economic crisis,” January 2004.

Page 36: Economic Perpestive

WP-5

2004-3 Keun Lee, Keunkwan Ryu and Jungmo Yoon, “Corporate Governance and Long Term

Performance of the Business Groups: The Case of Chaebols in Korea,” January 2004. 2004-4 Randall Morck and Masao Nakamura, “Been There, Done That –The History of Corporate

Ownership in Japan,” March 2004. 2004-5 Dong-Hua Chen, Joseph P. H. Fan and T. J. Wong, ”Politically-connected CEOs, Corporate

Governance and Post-IPO Performance of China’s Partially Privatized Firms,” March 2004. 2004-6 Jae-Seung Baek, Jun-Koo Kang and Inmoo Lee, “Business Groups and Tunneling: Evidence

from Private Securities Offerings by Korean Chaebols,” March 2004. 2004-7 E. Han Kim, “To Steal or Not to Steal: Firm Attributes, Legal Environment, and Valuation,”

March 2004. 2004-8 Yin-Hua Yeh and Tracie Woidtke, “Commitment or Entrenchment?: Controlling

Shareholders and Board Composition,” June 2004. 2004-9 Hugh Patrick, “Thoughts on Evolving Corporate Governance in Japan,” June 2004. 2004-10 Utpal Bhattacharya and Hazem Daouk, “When No Law is Better than a Good Law”, June

2004. 2004-11 Sanghoon Ahn, Utpal Bhattacharya, Taehun Jung and Giseok Nam, “Do Japanese CEOs

Matter?”, June 2004. 2004-12 Megumi Suto and Masashi Toshino, “Behavioural Biases of Japanese Institutional

Investors; Fund management and Corporate Governance”, July 2004. 2004-13 Piruna Polsiri and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Business Groups in Thailand: Before and

after the East Asian Financial Crisis”, August 2004. 2004-14 Fumiharu Mieno, “Fund Mobilization and Investment Behavior in Thai Manufacturing

Firms in the Early 1990s”, August 2004. 2004-15 Chaiyasit Anuchitworawong, “Deposit Insurance, Corporate Governance and Discretionary

Behavior: Evidence from Thai Financial Institutions”, September 2004. 2004-16 Chaiyasit Anuchitworawong, “Financial fragility under implicit insurance scheme: Evidence

from the collapse of Thai financial institutions”, September 2004. 2004-17 Chaiyasit Anuchitworawong, “Ownership-based Incentives, Internal Corporate Risk and

Firm Performance”, September 2004. 2004-18 Jack Ochs and In-Uck Park, “Overcoming the Coordination Problem: Dynamic Formation

of Networks”, September 2004. 2004-19 Hidenobu Okuda and Suvadee Rungsomboon, “Comparative Cost Study of Foreign and

Thai Domestic Banks 1990–2002: Estimating Cost Functions of the Thai Banking Industry,” February 2005.

2004-20 Hidenobu Okuda and Suvadee Rungsomboon, ”The Effects of Foreign Bank Entry on the

Thai Banking Market: Empirical Analysis from 1990 to 2002,“ March 2005.

Page 37: Economic Perpestive

WP-6

2004-21 Juro Teranishi, “Investor Right in Historical Perspective: Globalization and the Future of the Japanese Firm and Financial System,” March 2005.

2004-22 Kentaro Iwatsubo, “Which Accounts for Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations, Deviations from

the Law of One Price or Relative Price of Nontraded Goods?”, March 2005. 2004-23 Kentaro Iwatsubo and Tomoyuki Ohta, ”Causes and effects of exchange rate regimes (in

Japanese),” March 2005. 2004-24 Kentaro Iwatsubo, “Bank Capital Shocks and Portfolio Risk: Evidence from Japan,” March

2005. 2004-25 Kentaro Iwatsubo, “On the Bank-led Rescues Financially Distressed Firms in Japan,” March

2005. 2005-1 Yishay P. Yafeh and Tarun Khanna, “Business Groups in Emerging Markets: Paragons or

Parasities?,” September 2005. 2005-2 Renee B. Adams and Daniel Ferreira, “Do Directors Perform for Pay?," September 2005. 2005-3 Qun Liu, Shin-ichi Fukuda and Juro Teranishi, “What are Characteristics of Financial

Systems in East Asia as a Region?.” September 2005. 2005-4 Juro Teranishi, “Is the Financial System of Postwar Japan Bank-dominated or Market

Based?,” September 2005. 2005-5 Hasung Jang, Hyung-cheol Kang and Kyung Suh Park, “Determinants of Family

Ownership: The Choice between Control and Performance,” October 2005. 2005-6 Hasung Jang, Hyung-cheol Kang and Kyung Suh Park, “The Choice of Group Structure:

Divide and Rule,” October 2005. 2005-7 Sangwoo Lee, Kwangwoo Park and Hyun-Han Shin, “The Very Dark Side of International

Capital Markets: Evidence from Diversified Business Groups in Korea,” October 2005. 2005-8 Allen N. Berger, Richard J. Rosen and Gregory F. Udell, “Does Market Size Structure

Affect Competition? The Case of Small Business Lending,” November 2005. 2005-9 Aditya Kaul and Stephen Sapp, “Trading Activity and Foreign Exchange Market Quality,”

November 2005. 2005-10 Xin Chang, Sudipto Dasgupta and Gilles Hilary, “The Effect of Auditor Choice on

Financing Decisions,” December 2005. 2005-11 Kentaro Iwatsubo, “Adjustment Speeds of Nominal Exchange Rates and Prices toward

Purchasing Power Parity,” January 2006. 2005-12 Giovanni Barone-Adesi, Robert Engle and Loriano Mancini, “GARCH Options in

Incomplete Markets”, March 2006. 2005-13 Aditya Kaul, Vikas Mehrotra and Blake Phillips, “Ownership, Foreign Listings, and Market

Valuation”, March 2006. 2005-14 Ricard Gil, “Renegotiation, Learning and Relational Contracting”, March 2006.

Page 38: Economic Perpestive

WP-7

2005-15 Randall Morck, “How to Eliminate Pyramidal Business Groups -The Double Taxation of Inter-corporate Dividends and other Incisive Uses of Tax Policy-”, March 2006.

2005-16 Joseph P.H. Fan, T.J. Wong and Tianyu Zhang, “The Emergence of Corporate Pyramids in

China”, March 2006. 2005-17 Yan Du, Qianqiu Liu and S. Ghon Rhee, “An Anatomy of the Magnet Effect: Evidence

from the Korea Stock Exchange High-Frequency Data”, March 2006. 2005-18 Kentaro Iwatsubo and Junko Shimizu, “Signaling Effects of Foreign Exchange Interventions

and Expectation Heterogeneity among Traders”, March 2006. 2005-19 Kentaro Iwatsubo, “Current Account Adjustment and Exchange Rate Pass-Through(in

Japanese)”, March 2006. 2005-20 Piruna Polsiri and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Corporate Governance of Banks in

Thailand”, March 2006. 2006-1 Hiroyuki Okamuro and Jian Xiong Zhang, “Ownership Structure and R&D Investment of

Japanese Start-up Firms,” June 2006. 2006-2 Hiroyuki Okamuro, “Determinants of R&D Activities by Start-up Firms: Evidence from

Japan,” June 2006. 2006-3 Joseph P.H. Fan, T.J. Wong and Tianyu Zhang, “The Emergence of Corporate Pyramids in

China,” August 2006. 2006-4 Pramuan Bunkanwanicha, Jyoti Gupta and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Pyramiding of

Family-owned Banks in Emerging Markets,” September 2006. 2006-5 Bernardo Bortolotti and Mara Faccio, “Reluctant privatization,” September 2006. 2006-6 Jörn Kleinert and Farid Toubal, “Distance costs and Multinationals’ foreign activities”,

October 2006. 2006-7 Jörn Kleinert and Farid Toubal, “Dissecting FDI”, October 2006. 2006-8 Shin-ichi Fukuda and Satoshi Koibuchi, “The Impacts of “Shock Therapy” on Large and

Small Clients: Experiences from Two Large Bank Failures in Japan”, October 2006. 2006-9 Shin-ichi Fukuda, Munehisa Kasuya and Kentaro Akashi, “The Role of Trade Credit for

Small Firms: An Implication from Japan’s Banking Crisis”, October 2006. 2006-10 Pramuan Bunkanwanicha and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Big Business Owners and

Politics: Investigating the Economic Incentives of Holding Top Office”, October 2006. 2006-11 Sang Whi Lee, Seung-Woog(Austin) Kwang, Donald J. Mullineaux and Kwangwoo Park,

“Agency Conflicts, Financial Distress, and Syndicate Structure: Evidence from Japanese Borrowers”, October 2006.

2006-12 Masaharu Hanazaki and Qun Liu, “Corporate Governance and Investment in East Asian

Firms -Empirical Analysis of Family-Controlled Firms”, October 2006. 2006-13 Kentaro Iwatsubo and Konomi Tonogi, “Foreign Ownership and Firm Value: Identification

through Heteroskedasticity (in Japanese)”, December 2006.

Page 39: Economic Perpestive

WP-8

2006-14 Kentaro Iwatsubo and Kazuyuki Inagaki, “Measuring Financial Market Contagion Using Dually-Traded Stocks of Asian Firms”, December 2006.

2006-15 Hun-Chang Lee, “When and how did Japan catch up with Korea? –A comparative study of

the pre-industrial economies of Korea and Japan”, February 2007. 2006-16 Kyoji Fukao, Keiko Ito, Shigesaburo Kabe, Deqiang Liu and Fumihide Takeuchi, “Are

Japanese Firms Failing to Catch up in Localization? An Empirical Analysis Based on Affiliate-level Data of Japanese Firms and a Case Study of the Automobile Industry in China”, February 2007.

2006-17 Kyoji Fukao, Young Gak Kim and Hyeog Ug Kwon, “Plant Turnover and TFP Dynamics in

Japanese Manufacturing”, February 2007. 2006-18 Kyoji Fukao, Keiko Ito, Hyeg Ug Kwon and Miho Takizawa, “Cross-Border Acquisitons

and Target Firms' Performance: Evidence from Japanese Firm-Level Data”, February 2007. 2006-19 Jordan Siegel and Felix Oberholzer-Gee, “Expropriators or Turnaround Artists? The Role of

Controlling Families in South Korea (1985-2003)”, March 2007. 2006-20 Francis Kramarz and David Thesmar, “Social Networks in The Boardroom”, March 2007. 2006-21 Morten Bennedsen, Francisco Pérez-González and Daniel Wolfenzon, “Do CEOs matter?”,

March 2007. 2007-1 Ichiro Iwasaki, “Endogenous board formation and its determinants in a transition economy:

evidence from Russia*”, April 2007, Revised on October 2007. 2007-2 Joji Tokui, Tomohiko Inui, and Katsuaki Ochiai, “The Impact of Vintage Capital and R&D

on Japanese Firms’ Productivity”, April 2007. 2007-3 Yasuo Nakanishi and Tomohiko Inui, “Deregulation and Productivity in Japanese

Industries”, April 2007. 2007-4 Kyoji Fukao, “The Performance of Foreign Firms and the Macroeconomic Impact of FDI”,

May 2007. 2007-5 Taku Suzuki, “The Role of the State in Economic Growth of Post-Communist Transitional

Countries”, June 2007. 2007-6 Michiel van Leuvensteijn, Jacob A. Bikker, Adrian A.R.J.M. van Rixtel and Christoffer

Kok-Sørensen*, “A new approach to measuring competition in the loan markets of the euro area”, June 2007.

2007-7 Sea Jin Chang, Jaiho Chung, and Dean Xu, “FDI and Technology Spillovers in China”, July

2007. 2007-8 Fukunari Kimura, “The mechanics of production networks in Southeast Asia: the

fragmentation theory approach”, July 2007. 2007-9 Kyoji Fukao, Tsutomu Miyagawa, Miho Takizawa, “Productivity Growth and Resource

Reallocation in Japan”, November 2007. 2007-10 YoungGak Kim, “A Survey on Intangible Capital”, December 2007.

Page 40: Economic Perpestive

WP-9

2007-11 Sea-Jing Chang and Jay Hyuk Rhee, “Rapid International Expansion Strategy of Emerging Market Enterprises: The Interplay between Speed and Competitive Risks on International performance”, November 2007.

2007-12 Ishtiaq Mahmood, Will Mitchell, and Chi-Nien Chung, “The Structure of Intra-Group Ties:

Innovation in Taiwanese Business”, January 2008. 2007-13 Kyoji Fukao, Tomohiko Inui, Shigesaburo Kabe and Deqiang Liu, “ An International

Comparison of the TFP Levels of Japanese, Korean and Chinese Listed Firms“, March 2008.

2007-14 Pramuan Bunkanwanicha and Yupana Wiwattanakantang, “Allocating Risk Across

Pyramidal Tiers: Evidence from Thai Business Groups”, March 2008. 2008-1 Rüdiger Fahlenbrach and René M. Stulz, "Managerial Ownership Dynamics and Firm

Value", April 2008. 2008-2 Morten Bennedsen, Kasper Meisner Nielsen, and, Thomas Vester Nielsen, “Private

Contracting and Corporate Governance: Evidence from the Provision of Tag-Along Rights in an Emerging Market”, April 2008.

2008-3 Joseph P.H. Fan, Jun Huang, Felix Oberholzer-Gee, and Mengxin Zhao, “Corporate

Diversification in China: Causes and Consequences”, April 2008. 2008-4 Daniel Ferreira, Miguel A. Ferreira, Clara C. Raposo, “Board Structure and Price

Informativeness”, April 2008. 2008-5 Nicola Gennaioli and Stefano Rossi, “Judicial Discretion in Corporate Bankruptcy”, April

2008. 2008-6 Nicola Gennaioli and Stefano Rossi, “Optimal Resolutions of Financial Distress by

Contract”, April 2008. 2008-7 Renée B. Adams and Daniel Ferreira, “Women in the Boardroom and Their Impact on

Governance and Performance”, April 2008. 2008-8 Worawat Margsiri, Antonio S. Melloy, and Martin E. Ruckesz, “A Dynamic Analysis of

Growth via Acquisition”, April 2008. 2008-9 Pantisa Pavabutra and Sukanya Prangwattananon, “Tick Size Change on the Stock

Exchange of Thailand”, April 2008. 2008-10 Maria Boutchkova, Hitesh Doshi, Art Durnev, and Alexander Molchanov, “Politics and

Volatility”, April 2008. 2008-11 Yan-Leung Cheung, P. Raghavendra Rau, and Aris Stouraitis, “The Helping Hand, the Lazy

Hand, or the Grabbing Hand? Central vs. Local Government Shareholders in Publicly Listed Firms in China”, April 2008.

2008-12 Art Durnev and Larry Fauver, “Stealing from Thieves: Firm Governance and Performance

when States are Predatory”, April 2008. 2008-13 Kenneth Lehn, Sukesh Patro, and Mengxin Zhao, “Determinants of the Size and Structure of

Corporate Boards: 1935-2000”, April 2008.

Page 41: Economic Perpestive

WP-10

2008-14 Ishtiaq P. Mahmood, Hong-Jin Zhu and Edward J. Zajac, “Where Can Capabilities Come From? How the Content of Network Ties Affects Capability Acquisition”, April 2008.

2008-15 Vladimir I. Ivanov and Ronald W. Masulis, “Corporate Venture Capital, Strategic Alliances,

and the Governance of Newly Public Firms”, May 2008. 2008-16 Dick Beason, Ken Gordon, Vikas Mehrotra and Akiko Watanabe, “Does Restructuring Pay

in Japan? Evidence Following the Lost Decade”, July 2008 (revision uploaded on Oct. 2009).

2009-1 Vikas Mehrotra, Dimitri van Schaik, Jaap Spronk, and Onno Steenbeek, “Creditor-Focused

Corporate Governance: Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions in Japan,” August, 2009.

2009-2 Debin Ma, “Law and Economic Change in Traditional China: A Comparative Perspective,” September, 2009.