ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    1/10

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    2/10

    Work and living standards Do rising living standards cause people to work more or less?

    It will be very difficult to gather and interpret data on this

    question.

    An increase in the real wage (everything else constant) will

    have a substitution effect that increases the labour supply,

    and a substitution effect that reduces the labour supply.

    Over time, as people get richer, they have more non-labour

    income, which reduces the labour supply.

    Over time (as they get richer), people tend to live longer,

    which increases the labour supply.

    Over time, the participation rate tends to increase; raising

    both the labour force and the labour supply.

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    3/10

    Some data

    Stiglitz and Walsh show the average weekly hours worked in

    manufacturing fell from 59 hours in 1900 to 42 hours in 2000.

    It is not clear if this data relates to individual workers or

    manufacturing positions. It might be that the number of part-

    time manufacturing positions has increased.

    The US has a higher real GDP per capita than Europe because

    Americans work more (productivity is roughly the same in

    both regions). The take-home wage rate is higher in the US

    due to lower taxes (and fewer social services). Surveys tend to suggest that rich people work more than poor

    people; the higher your wage rate, the more hours you work.

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    4/10

    More data

    It is estimated that, in 1880, the average male US household

    head worked 8.5 hours a day (seven days a week?), while in

    1995 they worked only 4.7 hours a day.

    See Table 5

    http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/whaples.work.hours.us

    Since 2003, the US Bureau of Labor Statistics has conducted

    the American Time Use Survey. In 2003, a full-time male

    employee worked 8.72 hours on an average weekday. By

    2009, this number had risen to 8.75. For these few years, atleast, it appears that full-time workers did not work less.

    http://www.bls.gov/tus/#tables

    http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/whaples.work.hours.ushttp://www.bls.gov/tus/http://www.bls.gov/tus/http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/whaples.work.hours.us
  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    5/10

    Labour supply

    The number of hours worked per week does not tend to

    respond too much to the real wage. A full-time job tends to

    be about 40 hours a week.

    The main impact comes from the timing of exiting and

    entering the labour market.

    When wages are high, I will be reluctant to exit the market (go

    overseas, have children, retire), and keen to enter (come back

    from overseas, having children, being retired).

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    6/10

    An experiment

    Suppose you are currently employed for 40 hours a week, at

    $20/hour. Suppose your employer allows to specify how many

    hours you will work each week (from 0 to 60 hours). At

    $20/hour, you choose to work 40 hours.

    Suppose your wage is doubled, with all other prices fixed.

    How many hours will you choose to work?

    Suppose the wage is really increased, to $20,000/hour (all

    other prices fixed). How may hours will you work now? My

    guess is you would work at least 40 hours a week for the firstfew months. Once you have a few million in the bank, then

    you will start to work less, maybe just ten hours a week.

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    7/10

    Experiment (contd)

    If the wage increases enough, I will eventually start working

    less. However, because I may be uncertain about how long the

    high wage will last forit could be a mistakeI will work a lot

    to begin withto build up my wealthand then work less.

    We may see an increase in labour in the first few months,followed by a decrease.

    Does it make a difference if all wages rise, rather than just

    yours? Some people argue it is relative wages that matter, not

    absolute wages. If all wages double (with goods prices fixed),everyone preserves their relative position and so we may see

    no change in the labour supply.

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    8/10

    Working in the USA

    40

    42

    44

    46

    48

    50

    52

    54

    56

    58

    60

    1900 1909 1919 1929 1940 1950 1960 1970 1978

    Hoursworked

    Year

    Average weekly hours worked in the US (non-student males, from

    Robert Whaples' web article)

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    9/10

    Possible interpretations

    In the US, from 1900 (and most likely earlier) till 1940, the

    average hours worked per week fell significantly.

    From 1940, on, hours worked have done very little, maybe

    even increased a bit.

    For a specific country, hours worked, plotted against time

    could very well be U-shaped; early industrial development

    causes hours worked to fall (and may well be connected to the

    political strength of the union movement), while the later

    development of service industries (as the country becomesricher) causes hours worked to increase a bit.

  • 8/14/2019 ECON 130 Lecture 20(2).pptx

    10/10

    Keywords

    Hours worked

    Hours worked per full time employee