117
Demand & Utility

Demand & Utility

  • Upload
    ziazan

  • View
    68

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Demand & Utility. What is Utility?. Satisfaction, happiness, benefit. Cardinal Utility vs. Ordinal Utility. Cardinal Utility : Assigning numerical values to the amount of satisfaction - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: Demand &  Utility

Demand & Utility

Page 2: Demand &  Utility

What is Utility?

Satisfaction, happiness, benefit

Page 3: Demand &  Utility

Cardinal Utility vs. Ordinal Utility

Cardinal Utility: Assigning numerical values to the amount of satisfaction

Ordinal Utility: Not assigning numerical values to the amount of satisfaction but indicating the order of preferences, that is, what is preferred to what

Page 4: Demand &  Utility

Util

A unit of measure of utility

Page 5: Demand &  Utility

Total Utility

The amount of satisfaction obtained by consuming specified amounts of a product per period of time.

Page 6: Demand &  Utility

Example: TU(X) = U(X) = 16 X – X2

where X is the amount a good that is consumed in a given period of time.

5 units of the product per period of time yields 55 utils of satisfaction

Page 7: Demand &  Utility

Marginal Utility

The change in total utility (TU) resulting from a one unit change in consumption (X).

MU = TU/ X

Page 8: Demand &  Utility

Diminishing Marginal Utility

Each additional unit of a product contributes less extra utility than the previous unit.

Page 9: Demand &  Utility

When the changes in consumption are infinitesimally small, marginal utility is the derivative of total utility.

MU = dTU/dX

Page 10: Demand &  Utility

Calculating MU from a TU FunctionExample: TU(X) = 16 X – X2

MU = dTU/dX = 16-2X

Page 11: Demand &  Utility

In general, the derivative of a total function is the marginal function.

The marginal function is the slope of the total function.

Page 12: Demand &  Utility

X

X

Total Utility

Marginal Utility

TU

MU

X1 X2

X1 X2

Graphs of Total Utility & Marginal Utility

X2 is where total utility reaches its maximum. MU is zero. This is the saturation point or satiation point.After that point, TU falls and MU is negative.

X1 is where marginal utility reaches its maximum. This is where we encounter diminishing marginal utility. The slope of TU has reached its maximum; TU has an inflection point here.

Page 13: Demand &  Utility

Example: If TU = 15 X + 7X2 – (1/3) X3, find (a) the MU function,

(b) the point of diminishing marginal utility, & (c) the satiation point.

a. MU = dTU/dX = 15 +14X – X2

b. Diminishing MU is where MU has a maximum, or the derivative of MU is zero.

0 = dMU/dx = 14 – 2X X = 7c. Satiation is where TU reaches a maximum or its

derivative (which is MU) is zero. How do we determine where MU = 15 +14X – X2 = 0 ?

Page 14: Demand &  Utility

Apply Quadratic Formula to –X2 + 14 X + 15 = 0 .

a2

ac4bbX

2

)(

))(()(

12

15141414 2

2

1614

152

30 X or 1

2

2 X either So

2

25614

Since a negative amount of a product makes no sense, X must equal 15.

Page 15: Demand &  Utility

If the previous example were about eating free cookies at a party, you’d eat 15 of them.

That is where you become satiated.

After 15 cookies, you begin to feel a bit bloated.

Page 16: Demand &  Utility

When you have more than one product, the marginal utility is a partial derivative.

Calculating partial derivatives is no more difficult than calculating other derivatives. You just treat all variables as constants, except the one with which you are taking the derivative.We denote the partial derivative of Z with respect to X as Z/X instead of dZ/dX.

Example: Z = X2 +3XY + 5Y3

To take the partial derivative with respect to X, pretend Y is a constant (like 4). Then,

Z/X = 2X + 3Y .

Similarly, to take the partial derivative with respect to Y, pretend X is a constant (like 4). So,

Z/Y = 3X + 15Y2 .

Page 17: Demand &  Utility

The Connection between Demand and Utility

Instead of thinking in terms of utils, let’s think in terms of dollars.

Suppose the purchase of one unit of a good gives you $10 worth of satisfaction.

In other words, the marginal utility of that first unit of the good is $10.

Then you would be willing to pay up to $10 for it.

Page 18: Demand &  Utility

If a second unit of the good contributes $8 more of satisfaction, the marginal utility of your second unit is $8 and you would be willing to pay up to $8 for it.

If a third unit of the good contributes $6 more of satisfaction, the marginal utility of your third unit is $6 and you would be willing to pay up to $6 for it.

Page 19: Demand &  Utility

Remember that the demand curve tells you what people are willing to pay for various amounts of a good or, equivalently, how many units of a good they are willing to purchase at various prices.

So, since we just found that the marginal utility tells us what we are willing to pay for a good, the marginal utility provides us with information that we can use to determine our demand curve.

Page 20: Demand &  Utility

In our example, we had the following:

Number of units purchased (Q)

Price you are willing to pay (P)

Marginal Utility

0 - -

1 10 10

2 8 8

3 6 6

Page 21: Demand &  Utility

If we graph that information, we get our demand curve.

Number of units purchased (Q)

Price you are willing to pay (P)

Marginal Utility

0 - -

1 10 10

2 8 8

3 6 6

price

quantity

10 8

6

1 2 3

Demand

Page 22: Demand &  Utility

Notice that by adding our MU values we can determine our total utility at different consumption levels.

Number of units purchased (Q)

Price you are willing to pay (P)

Marginal Utility

Total Utility

0 - - 0

1 10 10 10

2 8 8 18

3 6 6 24

Page 23: Demand &  Utility

Indifference Curve

A set of combinations of goods that are viewed as equally satisfactory by the consumer.

Page 24: Demand &  Utility

Indifference Map

A collection of indifference curves

Page 25: Demand &  Utility

Assumptions

1. The consumer can rank all bundles of commodities.

2. If bundle A is preferred to bundle B and B is preferred to C, then A is preferred to C. (This property is called transitivity.)

3. More is better.

Page 26: Demand &  Utility

Characteristics of indifference curves

Page 27: Demand &  Utility

Indifference curves slope down from left to right.Consider 2 points A & B on the same indifference curve. At point B, you have more food than at point A. If the amount of clothing you had at point B was the same as or more than at point A (like at point C), you would not be indifferent between A and B (since more is better).So A & B could not be on the same indifference curve, which goes against our initial statement that they are. So you must have less clothing at B, which means than B lies below A and the indifference curve slopes downward.

clothing

food

A

B

C

Page 28: Demand &  Utility

Indifference curves to the northeast are preferred.

Point E is preferred to point A because it has more food & more clothing.Since you are indifferent between A & all points on IC1, E must be preferred to all points on IC1.Since you are indifferent between E and all points on IC2, all points on IC2 must be preferred to all points on IC1.

IC2

food

A

E

clothing

IC1

Page 29: Demand &  Utility

Indifference curves can not intersect.Suppose indifference curves could intersect. Let the intersection of IC1 & IC2 be D.Then you must be indifferent between D & any other point A on IC1.Similarly, you must be indifferent between D & any other point B on IC2.

food

A

D

clothing

IC1

B IC2

By transitivity, you must be indifferent between A & B.But A & B are not on the same indifference curve, which they should be if you are indifferent between them.Then, our initial supposition that indifference curves could intersect must be wrong.

Page 30: Demand &  Utility

Indifference curves are convex[the slopes of IC’s fall as we move from left to right, or

we have a diminishing marginal rate of substitution (MRS)]

When we have lots of clothing & not much food (as near A & B), we are willing to give up a lot of clothing to get a little more food.When we have lots of food & not much clothing (as near C & D), we are willing to give up very little clothing to get a little more food.

food

A

C

clothing

B

D

Page 31: Demand &  Utility

Odd special cases that are not consistent with the characteristics

listed previously.

Page 32: Demand &  Utility

Perfect Complements

You need exactly 4 tires with 1 car body (ignoring the spare tire).

Having more than 4 tires with 1 car body doesn’t increase utility.

Also having more than 1 car body with only 4 tires doesn’t increase utility either.

tires

Car bodies1 2

8

4IC1

IC2

Page 33: Demand &  Utility

Perfect Substitutes

Consider two packs of paper; the mini-pack has 100 sheets & the jumbo pack has 500 sheets.No matter how many mini-packs or jumbo packs you have, you are always willing to trade 5 mini-packs for 1 jumbo pack.Since the rate at which you’re willing to trade is the slope of the IC, and that rate is constant, your IC’s have a constant slope.That means they are straight lines.

Mini-packs

Jumbo packs

1 2

10

5

IC1

IC2

Page 34: Demand &  Utility

Goods versus Bads

As you get more of a bad, you need more of a good to compensate you, to keep you feeling equally happy.

So IC of a good & a bad slopes upward.

production

pollution

IC1

IC2

Page 35: Demand &  Utility

“Neutral” Good

Your utility is unaffected by consumption of a neutral good.

Neutral good

Desired good

IC1 IC2 IC3

Page 36: Demand &  Utility

Addict

The more substance 1 the addict has the more he/she is willing to give up of substance 2 to get a little more of 1 (& vice versa).

So the IC’s are concave instead of convex.

Substance 1

Substance 2

Page 37: Demand &  Utility

The slope of the indifference curve is the rate at which you are willing to trade off one good to get another good.

It is called the marginal rate of substitution or MRS.

Page 38: Demand &  Utility

What is the MRS or slope of the IC? Suppose points A & B are on the same indifference curve & therefore have the same utility level. Let’s break up the move from A to B into 2 parts.

AD: TU = C (MUC)

DB: TU = F (MUF)AB: 0 = TU = C (MUC) + F (MUF)

C (MUC) = – F (MUF)

C/F = – MUF / MUC

IC1

Food F

A

D

Clothing C

B

IC2

So along an indifference curve, the slope or MRS is the negative of the ratio of the marginal utilities (with the MU of the good on the horizontal axis in the numerator).

MRS = – MUX / MUY

Page 39: Demand &  Utility

For example,Suppose IC1 is the 90-util indifference curve & IC2 is the 96-util indifference curve. Point A is 7 units of food & 6 of clothing. B is 9 units of food & 5 of clothing.Since an additional unit of clothing gives you 6 more utils of satisfaction, the MU of clothing must be 6.Since an additional 2 units of food also give you 6 more utils of satisfaction, the MU of food must be 3.

So, MRS = – MUF / MUC = -3/6 = -0.5 .You’d give up 2 units of food to get 1 units of clothing.

IC1 =90

Food F

A

D

Clothing C

B

IC2 = 96

6

5

7 9

Page 40: Demand &  Utility

Budget Constraint or Budget Line

This equation tells you what you can buy.For example, suppose you have $24, & there are

two goods. The price of the first good is $3 per unit & the price

of the second good is $4 per unit. So, if you buy X units of the first good for $3 each,

you spend 3X on that good.Similarly, if you buy Y units of the second good, you

spend 4Y on that good.Your total spending is 3X+4Y.If you spend all 24 dollars that you have, 3X+4Y=24.That equation is your budget constraint.

Page 41: Demand &  Utility

Example: Budget constraint for $24 of income, and $3 & $4 for the prices of the two goods.

X

Y

(0,6)

(8,0)0

If you spent all $24 on the 1st good, you could buy 8 units.

If you spent all $24 on the 2nd good, you could buy 6 units.

So we have the intercepts of the budget constraint.

The slope of the line connecting these two points is Y/X = – 6/8 = – 3/4 = – 0.75 .

Page 42: Demand &  Utility

Let’s generalize. Keep in mind that income was $24 and the prices of the goods were $3 & $4. The equation of the budget constraint in our example was 3X + 4Y = 24.

X

Y

(0,6)

(8,0)0

So the budget constraint is p1X + p2Y = I

Solving for Y in terms of X, p2Y = I – p1X,

or Y = I /p2 – (p1/p2)X

So from our slope-intercept form, we see that the intercept is I /p2, and the slope is –p1/p2 .

The intercept is income divided by the price of the good on the vertical axis.

The slope is the negative of the ratio of the prices, with the price of the good on the horizontal axis in the numerator.

Page 43: Demand &  Utility

We have the intercept is I /p2, & the slope is –p1/p2 .

What if income increased? The slope would stay the same & the budget constraint would shift out parallel to the original one.Suppose in our example with income of 24 & prices of 3 & 4, income increased to 36. Our new y-intercept will be 36/4 =9 & the new X-intercept will be 36/3=12.

X

Y

(0,6)

(8,0)0

(0,9)

(12,0)

Page 44: Demand &  Utility

Suppose the price of the good on the X-axis increased.

If we bought only the good whose price increased, we could afford less of it.

If we bought only the other good, our purchases would be unchanged.

So the budget constraint would pivot inward about the Y-intercept.

X

Y

(0,6)

(8,0)0 (6,0)

For example, if the price increased from $3 to $4, our $24 would only buy 6 units.

Page 45: Demand &  Utility

Similarly, if the price of the good on the Y-axis increased, the budget constraint would pivot in about the X-intercept.

X

Y

(0,6)

(8,0)0

(0,4)

Suppose the price of the 2nd good increased from $4 to $6. If you bought only that good, with your $24, your $24 would only buy 4 units of it.

Page 46: Demand &  Utility

Let’s combine our indifference curves & budget constraint to determine our utility maximizing point.

Point A doesn’t maximize our utility & it doesn’t spend all our income. (It’s below the budget constraint.)

X

Y

0

IC1

IC2

IC3

A

Page 47: Demand &  Utility

Points B & C spend all our income but they don’t maximize our utility. We can reach a higher indifference curve.

X

Y

0

IC1

IC2

IC3

B

C

Page 48: Demand &  Utility

Point D is unattainable. We can’t reach it with our budget.

X

Y

0

IC1

IC2

IC3

D

Page 49: Demand &  Utility

Point E is our utility-maximizing point.

We can’t do any better than at E.

Notice that our utility is maximized at the point of tangency between the budget constraint & the indifference curve.

X

Y

0

IC1

IC2

IC3

E

Page 50: Demand &  Utility

Recall from Principles of Microeconomics, to maximize your utility, you should purchase goods so that the marginal utility per dollar is the same for all goods.

If there were just two goods, that means that MU1/P1 = MU2/P2

Multiplying both sides by P1/MU2, we have MU1/MU2 = P1/P2 .The expression on the right is the negative of the slope of the

budget constraint.The expression on the left is the negative of the slope of the

indifference curve.So the slope of the indifference curve must be equal to the slope

of the budget constraint.If at a particular point, two functions have the same slope, they

are tangent to each other.That means your utility-maximizing consumption levels are where

your indifference curve is tangent to the budget constraint.This is the same conclusion we reached using our graph.

Page 51: Demand &  Utility

Example: If TU = 10X + 24Y – 0.5 X2 – 0.5 Y2, the prices of the two goods are 2 and 6, and we have

$44, how much should you consume of each good?

Taking the derivatives of TU we haveMU1 = 10 – X and MU2 = 24 – Y

Since MU1/MU2 = P1/P2 , we have(10 – X) / (24 – Y) = 2 / 6 ,

or 60 – 6 X = 48 – 2Y ,

or 6X – 2Y = 12 .

This an equation with two unknowns.

Our budget constraint provides us with a 2nd equation. Combining the two equations, we can solve for X & Y.

The budget constraint is 2X + 6Y = 44 .

Page 52: Demand &  Utility

So our two equations are 6X – 2Y = 12 and 2X + 6Y = 44

Multiplying the second equation by 3 yields6X + 18Y = 132 .

Now we have 6X + 18Y = 132 6X – 2Y = 12 --------------------

So, 20Y = 120and Y = 6 .Plugging 6 in for Y in the 1st equation yields 6X – 12 = 12,

or 6X = 24. So, X = 4 .

Page 53: Demand &  Utility

Let’s see if all this works.

We had $44, the prices were 2 & 6, and MU1 = 10 – X & MU2 = 24 – Y. We bought 4 units of the 1st good & 6 of the 2nd good.

First, did we spend exactly what we had?

We spent (2)(4) + (6)(6) = 8 + 36 = 44 Good.

Is the marginal utility per dollar the same for both goods?

For the 1st good: MU1/P1 = (10 – X)/2 = (10-4)/2 = 3

For the 2nd good: MU2/P2 = (24 – Y)/6 = (24-6)/6 = 3

So they’re equal and things look fine.

Page 54: Demand &  Utility

What happens to consumption when income rises?

For normal goods, consumption increases.For inferior goods, consumption decreases.What does this look like on our graph?

Page 55: Demand &  Utility

Two Normal Goods

As income increases, the budget constraint shifts out & we are able to reach higher & higher IC’s.

The points of tangency are at higher & higher levels of consumption of both goods.

X

Y

IC1

IC2

IC3

C

B

A

Y3

Y2

Y1

X1 X2 X3

Page 56: Demand &  Utility

Income-Consumption Curve

The curve that traces out these points is called the income-consumption curve.

For two normal goods, the curve slopes upward.

It may be convex (as drawn here), concave, or linear.

X

Y

IC1

IC2

IC3

C

B

A

Y3

Y2

Y1

X1 X2 X3

Page 57: Demand &  Utility

One Normal Good & One Inferior Good

Suppose the good on the horizontal axis is normal & the one on the vertical axis is inferior.

Then X will rise & Y will fall as income increases.

X

Y

IC1 IC2

IC3

CBA

X1 X2 X3

Y1

Y2

Y3

Page 58: Demand &  Utility

Income-Consumption Curve

The result is a downward sloping income-consumption curve.

X

Y

IC1 IC2

IC3

CBA

X1 X2 X3

Y1

Y2

Y3

Page 59: Demand &  Utility

Engel Curve

The Engel Curve shows the quantity of a good purchased at each income level.The graph has income on the vertical axis and the quantity of the good on the horizontal.It slopes up for normal goods & down for inferior goods.X

Income

C

B

A

X1 X2 X3

I3

I2

I1

Page 60: Demand &  Utility

We can also look at consumption levels of two goods when the price of one of them changes.

Suppose there is an increase in the price of the 1st good (the good on the X-axis).

The budget constraint pivots inward.

Here we see X drop & Y increase.

In this case, our 2 goods are substitutes.

X

Y

X3 X2 X1

Y3

Y2

Y1

Page 61: Demand &  Utility

If we connect the points, we have the price consumption curve.

It shows the utility-maximizing points when the price of a good changes.

X

Y

X3 X2 X1

Y3

Y2

Y1

Page 62: Demand &  Utility

If we look at the price of a good & the amount of it consumed, we have the demand curve

for our particular individual.

As the price decreases the quantity demanded increases & vice versa.

X

P

X1 X2 X3

P1

P2

P3

Page 63: Demand &  Utility

We can separate the effect of a change in the price of a good on its consumption level into two parts: the income effect & the substitution effect.

Suppose the price of the first good increases.The budget constraint was originally the blue line and we were at A consuming quantities XA & YA. After the price change, the budget constraint is the red line, and we’re at B consuming XB & YB .

X

Y

ABYB

YA

XB XA

Page 64: Demand &  Utility

We first want to capture the effect of the price change without the effect of the change in income.

X

Y

H

AB

YH

YB

YA

XB XH XA

We draw a line parallel to the new budget constraint and tangent to the old indifference curve.This will reflect the new relative prices, but since we are tangent to the old indifference curve we are just as well off as initially. Under those circumstances we would be at point H (for hypothetical).Since the 1st good is now relatively more expensive compared to the 2nd, we will substitute, increasing Y & decreasing X.

Page 65: Demand &  Utility

The movement from A to H is the substitution effect.

X

Y

H

AB

YH

YB

YA

XB XH XA

As a result of the increase in the relative price of the 1st good, we reduce our consumption of it and consume more of the other good.

Page 66: Demand &  Utility

Now we move from H to B

XX

Y

H

AB

YH

YB

YA

XB XH XA

Our purchasing power has been reduced by the price change. That results in the income effect.In our graph, we now hold the relative prices constant at the new level, but income has fallen. Our budget constraint has shifted inward. If both goods are normal, as a result of the change in income, we reduce our consumption of both goods, and X & Y fall.This is the income effect of the price change.

Page 67: Demand &  Utility

Total Effect of Price Increase

X

Y

H

AB

YH

YB

YA

XB XH XA

The total effect is to move from A to B.X has fallen.Both the substitution & income effects led to a drop in X.Y has increased in this case.The substitution effect increased consumption of the 2nd good, but the income effect reduced it by less than the substitution effect increased it.

Page 68: Demand &  Utility

Let’s do a price decrease.

X

Y

H

B

A

YB

YA

YH

XA XH XB

The budget constraint moves from the blue line to the red line.We draw a line parallel to the new budget constraint and tangent to the old indifference curve.H is the tangency of the hypothetical budget constraint with the old indifference curve.The substitution effect is the movement from A to H. We substitute increasing X & decreasing Y.

Page 69: Demand &  Utility

The movement from H to B is the income effect.

X

Y

H

B

A

YB

YA

YH

As a result of the higher income (greater purchasing power), we consume more of both goods, if they are normal goods.

XA XH XB

Page 70: Demand &  Utility

Total Effect

X

Y

H

B

A

YB

YA

YH

The total effect is to move from A to B.X has increased.Both the substitution & income effects led to an increase in X.Y has also increased in this case.The substitution effect decreased consumption of the 2nd good, but the income effect increased it by more than the substitution effect decreased it.

XA XH XB

Page 71: Demand &  Utility

Income and Substitution Effects, in words

The income effect is the result of the change in purchasing power.

If the price of a normal good increases, you feel poorer, and the income effect is to consume less.

If the price of a normal good decreases, you feel richer, and the income effect is to consume more.

The substitution effect is the result of a change in relative prices.

If the price of a good increases, the substitution effect is to consume less of it & more of the other goods that are now relatively cheaper.

If the price decreases, the substitution effect is to consume more of it & less of the goods that are now relatively more expensive.

Page 72: Demand &  Utility

What if the price changed of an inferior good?

The substitution effect would be the same but the income effect would be the opposite.

Page 73: Demand &  Utility

Price increase for an inferior good

Income effect: Your purchasing power has decreased. You feel poorer.

So you consume more of the inferior good.

Substitution effect:The good is now relatively more expensive than other goods,

so you consume less of it and more of other goods.

Notice the IE & SE are in opposite directions in this case.If the SE is larger than the IE, you will consume less of the

good.If the IE is larger than the SE, you will consume more of the

good.

Page 74: Demand &  Utility

An inferior good for which the IE is larger than the SE is called a Giffen good.

It is a good for which consumption rises when the price increases, and consumption falls when the price decreases.

Page 75: Demand &  Utility

Price decrease for an inferior good

Income effect: Your purchasing power has increased. You feel richer. So

you consume less of the inferior good.

Substitution effect:The good is now relatively more cheaper than other goods,

so you consume more of it and less of other goods.

Again the IE & SE are in opposite directions in this case.If the SE is larger than the IE, you will consume more of the

good.If the IE is larger than the SE, you will consume less of the

good.

Page 76: Demand &  Utility

We previously looked at the demand curve for individuals. How do we get the market demand curve from the demand curve for individuals?

We just horizontally sum up the individual demand curves.

Page 77: Demand &  Utility

Market Demand Curve: 3-person example

Person A Person B Person C Market

P P

Q Q

2

1

2

1

2 4

P P

Q Q

2

1

2

1

4 91 31 2

At a price of $1, person A will buy 4 units of a good, B will buy 2 units, & C will buy 3 units. So at a price of $1, the quantity demanded by the entire 3-person market is 9 units.

Page 78: Demand &  Utility

Market Demand Curve: 3-person example

Person A Person B Person C Market

P P

Q Q

2

1

2

1

2 4

P P

Q Q

2

1

2

1

4 91 31 2

At a price of $2, person A will buy 2 units of a good, B will buy 1 units, & C will buy 1 units. So at a price of $2, the quantity demanded by the entire 3-person market is 4 units.

Page 79: Demand &  Utility

Market Demand Curve: 3-person example

Person A Person B Person C Market

P P

Q Q

2

1

2

1

2 4

P P

Q Q

2

1

2

1

4 91 31 2

Continuing the process, we get the market demand curve.

Page 80: Demand &  Utility

The Demand for a product can be expressed as a function of

1. its price (changes in which lead to movements along the demand curve), and

2. other determinants such as income, prices of related goods, & expectations (changes in which lead to shifts of the demand curve).

So we have QDX = g(PX, Psubst, Pcomp, Inc., Expect.)

A particular demand curve QDX = g(PX) shows the relation between the quantity demanded of a product and its price when we hold all the factors constant. This is also sometimes written as P= f(Q).

Page 81: Demand &  Utility

TR = PQ

Total Revenue

Page 82: Demand &  Utility

Average Revenue

total revenue per unit of output

AR = TR / Q

= (PQ) / Q

= P

AR & P are the same function of Q.

Page 83: Demand &  Utility

Marginal Revenue

The additional revenue associated with an additional unit of output

MR = dTR / dQ

Page 84: Demand &  Utility

Example: Horizontal Demand Curve(price is a constant function)

P

Q

10D

Q

PTRslope = MR = 10

= AR =MR

P = f(Q) = 10

AR = P = 10

TR = PQ = 10 Q

MR = dTR / dQ = 10

So D, AR, & MR are the same horizontal function.

TR is an upward sloping line with a constant slope.

Implications for revenue:Every time you sell another unit of output, revenue increases by

the price, which is constant.

Page 85: Demand &  Utility

Example: linear, downward-sloping Demand curve

P

Q

8

D = AR

Q

P

TR

MR

P = f(Q) = 8 – 3QAR = P = 8 – 3Q

TR = PQ = (8 – 3Q) Q= 8Q – 3Q2

MR = dTR / dQ = 8 – 6QD & MR have the same vertical intercept. MR is twice as steep as D. (The slope of MR is -6;

the slope of D is -3)

Implications for revenue:Revenue increases more &

more slowly & then decreases more & more quickly.

Page 86: Demand &  Utility

Example:quadratic, downward-sloping Demand curve

P

Q

20D = AR

Q

P

TR

MR

P = f(Q) = 20 – Q2

AR = P = 20 – Q2

TR = PQ = (20 – Q2) Q= 20Q – Q3

MR = dTR / dQ = 20 – 3Q2

MR is a quadratic; TR is a cubic.

Page 87: Demand &  Utility

Elasticity

Responsiveness or sensitivity of one variable to a change in another variable

(% change in X)ε = ------------------------ (% change in Y)

Page 88: Demand &  Utility

Price Elasticity of Demand

(% change in quantity demanded)ε = ------------------------------------------------ (% change in price)

Page 89: Demand &  Utility

Two methods of calculating elasticity

Arc elasticity: measures responsiveness between 2 points

Point elasticity: measures responsiveness at a single point for an infinitesimally small change

Page 90: Demand &  Utility

Arc Elasticity

ΔQ/(avg Q) [Q2 – Q1] / [(Q1+Q2)/2]--------------- = --------------------------------ΔP/(avg P) [P2 – P1] / [(P1+P2)/2]

Page 91: Demand &  Utility

Arc Elasticity ExampleCalculate the price elasticity of demand if in response to a increase in

price from 9 to 11 dollars, the quantity demanded decreases from 60 to 40 units.

P: 9→11 Q: 60→40

ΔQ/(avg Q) [Q2 – Q1] / [(Q1+Q2)/2]ε = --------------- = -------------------------------- ΔP/(avg P) [P2 – P1] / [(P1+P2)/2]

[40 – 60] / [(60+40)/2] -20 / 50 -0.4 = ------------------------------ = ------------ = ------- = -2.0 [11 – 9] / [(9+11)/2] 2 / 10 0.2

The negative sign indicates that price & quantity move in opposite directions.

The negative sign is sometimes dropped with the understanding that price & quantity are still moving in opposite directions.

Page 92: Demand &  Utility

Point Elasticity

dQ / Q dQ Pε = ---------- = ----- ---- dP / P dP Q

Page 93: Demand &  Utility

Point Elasticity Example

If the demand function is Q = 245 – 3.5 P, find the price elasticity of demand when the price is 10.

When P = 10, Q = 245 – 3.5(10) = 210

The derivative dQ / dP = = – 3.5

dQ / Q dQ P 10ε = ---------- = ----- --- = - 3.5 ------ = - 0.167 dP / P dP Q 210

Page 94: Demand &  Utility

Categories of Price Elasticity of Demand

Demand is elastic if |ε| > 1

Demand is inelastic if |ε| < 1

Demand is unit elastic if |ε| = 1

Page 95: Demand &  Utility

What is the relationship between elasticity & the slope of the demand curve?

dQ / Q dQ P 1 Pε = ---------- = ----- ---- = -------- ---- dP / P dP Q dP/dQ Q

= (1/slope) (P/Q)

So, if 2 demand curves pass through the same point (& therefore have the same values of P & Q at that point), the flatter curve (curve with the smaller slope) has the greater elasticity at that point.

Page 96: Demand &  Utility

Example

At point E, D1 has greater elasticity than D2 .

P

Q

E

D2

D1

Page 97: Demand &  Utility

Elasticity on a Linear Demand Curve

At the midpoint, |ε| = 1 (unit elasticity)

Above the midpoint, |ε| > 1 (elastic)

Below the midpoint, |ε| < 1 (inelastic)

P

Q

Page 98: Demand &  Utility

Let’s show in an example that |ε| = 1 at the midpoint of a linear demand curve.

P

Q

D MR

|ε| = 1

24

63

demand curve: P = 24 – 4QWhen Q = 0, P = 24. So that’s our vertical intercept.When P = 0, Q = 6. That’s our horizontal intercept.The midpoint then is (3,12).The slope is dP/dQ = – 4 .We found earlier that ε = (1/slope) (P/Q)

So ε = (1/-4) (12/3) = (1/-4) (4) = -1 12

Page 99: Demand &  Utility

Relationship between Elasticity & Total Revenue

Price increase:

|ε| > 1: P Q TR

|ε| < 1: P Q TR

|ε| = 1: P Q TR unchanged

Page 100: Demand &  Utility

Relationship between Elasticity & Total Revenue

Price decrease:

|ε| > 1: P Q TR

|ε| < 1: P Q TR

|ε| = 1: P Q TR unchanged

Page 101: Demand &  Utility

The most profitable place to be is in the elastic portion of the demand curve.

In the inelastic portion of the demand curve, marginal revenue is negative (additional units of output lower total revenue).

While this is true in general, we can demonstrate it in the linear demand case.

Page 102: Demand &  Utility

Recall that for a linear demand curve, marginal revenue is twice as steep as the demand curve.

Q

TR

So MR reaches the horizontal axis when the demand curve is only halfway there.

From the graph, we can see that above the midpoint where |ε| > 1, MR > 0 & TR is increasing.

So when MR = 0 at the midpoint, |ε| = 1.

Below the midpoint, where |ε| < 1 , MR < 0 & TR is decreasing.

P

Q

D

P

MR

|ε| > 1

|ε| = 1

|ε| < 1

Page 103: Demand &  Utility

Special Elasticity Cases

Page 104: Demand &  Utility

|ε| = Infinite ElasticityPerfectly Elastic

P

Q

D

Page 105: Demand &  Utility

|ε| = 0Zero Elasticity

Perfectly Inelastic

P

Q

D

Page 106: Demand &  Utility

|ε| = 1Unit Elasticity

P

Q

D

P = k / Q where k is a constant

Page 107: Demand &  Utility

Facts about Price Elasticity of Demand

1. The more substitutes there are for a product, the more elastic the demand.

2. An individual firm’s product has a more elastic demand than the entire industry’s product.

3. The longer the time period, the greater the elasticity of demand, because the greater the adjustments that are possible.

4. Products (like salt) that are a small part of the budget have low elasticities of demand.

Page 108: Demand &  Utility

Some examples of estimated price elasticities of demand

Commodity Price Elasticity of Demand

wheat 0.08

cotton 0.12

potatoes 0.31

beef 0.92

haddock 2.20

movies 3.70

Notice that the demands for wheat & cotton are not very responsive to price changes, whereas the demands for haddock and movies are very responsive.

Page 109: Demand &  Utility

So far the only elasticity that we have discussed is price elasticity of demand.

There are other types of elasticities.

Each type can be computed as arc elasticity or point elasticity.

Page 110: Demand &  Utility

Income Elasticity of Demand

(% change in quantity demanded)εI = ------------------------------------------------ (% change in income)

Page 111: Demand &  Utility

Categories of Income Elasticity of Demand

Normal Goods:

εI > 1 income elastic

εI = 1 unit income elastic

0 < εI < 1 income inelastic

Luxury items have high income elasticities of demand, while necessities have low income elasticities of demand.

Inferior Goods:

εI < 0

Page 112: Demand &  Utility

Some examples of estimated income elasticities of demand

Commodity Income Elasticity of Demand

flour -0.36

margarine -0.20

milk 0.07

butter 0.42

books 1.44

restaurant consumption

1.48

Note that flour & margarine are inferior goods, milk is not very responsive to income changes, & books & restaurant consumption are income elastic.

Page 113: Demand &  Utility

Cross Elasticity of Demand

(% change in quantity demanded of Y)εYX = --------------------------------------------------- (% change in price of X)

Page 114: Demand &  Utility

Categories of Cross Elasticity of Demand

Substitutes: εYX > 0The price of X & the quantity demanded of Y move in the same direction. When the price of X increases, you consume less of X and more of the goods that you can use in place of X.

Complements: εYX < 0 The price of X & the quantity demanded of Y move in opposite directions. When the price of X increases, you consume less of X and less of the goods that you use with X.

Page 115: Demand &  Utility

Some examples of estimated cross elasticities of demand

CommodityCross Elasticity with

respect to price ofCross elasticity

Pork Beef +0.14

Beef Pork +0.28

Butter Margarine +0.67

Margarine Butter +0.81

Notice that the cross elasticity of demand for Y with respect to the price of X is not necessarily equal to the cross elasticity of demand for X with respect to the price of Y.

Page 116: Demand &  Utility

Price Elasticity of Supply

(% change in quantity supplied)εS = ------------------------------------------------ (% change in price)

Page 117: Demand &  Utility

Categories of Price Elasticity of Supply

Supply is elastic if εS > 1

Supply is inelastic if εS < 1

Supply is unit elastic if εS = 1