Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    1/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    CREATING WEALTH

    AND COMPETITIVENESS IN MINING

    by

    John E. Tilton1

    The ability of companies and countries to mine copper and other mineral

    commodities competitively and in the process to generate new wealth depends on their

    mineral endowment. Chile, for example, produces and exports copper because it is well

    endowed with high-quality, low-cost deposits. This production creates wealth that

    benefits mining companies and their stockholders, the government, local communities, as

    well as copper consumers around the world.

    The widespread perception that mineral endowment must largely determine

    competitiveness, or what economists call comparative advantage, must be true at any

    particularly moment. Countries with abundant reserves must be competitive. This follows

    from the definition of reservesthe quantity of a mineral commodity found in discovered

    deposits that are profitable to exploit under current conditions. As a result, it is a

    tautology and not particularly interesting. The important question is what causes reserves

    to change over time, producing in the process new wealth and shifts in competitiveness?

    1William J. Coulter Professor of Mineral Economics at the Colorado School of Mines and at the time someof the research for this article was conducted, Visiting Scholar at the Centro de Mineria of the PontificiaUniversidad Catolica in Chile. I am grateful to Rio Tinto plc for kindly providing access to its MineInformation System. This paper is an updated and expanded version of Tilton (2000) and Tilton (2001b). Itwas prepared for the CRU World Copper Conference: Costs and CapitalImproving Performance in theCopper Industry, held March 19-21, 2002, in Santiago, Chile.

    1

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    2/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Three possible answers come readily to mind. First, as mining occurs and the best

    (lowest cost) deposits are depleted, mineral commodity prices may rise, permitting the

    profitable exploitation of the next best set of deposits. Second, the discovery of

    previously unknown deposits may augment reserves. Third, innovation and new

    technology may create reserves by allowing previously known but uneconomic deposits

    to be exploited profitably.

    The prevailing or traditional view of competitiveness and wealth creation focuses

    on the first two possible explanations and for the most part ignores the third. What we

    can call the alternative view, on the other hand, focuses on the third explanation, and

    claims it is as important or more important than the first two, especially over the longer

    term.

    We know that the first explanation at least in recent years is of little relevance,

    because real production costs and prices for copper as well as many other mineral

    commodities have fallen, not risen. While exploration and the discovery of previously

    unknown deposits are important, are they as important as the innovation and new

    technologies that permit the profitable mining of previously known but uneconomic

    resources?

    Studies that several colleagues and I have conducted over the past few years on

    the causes and consequences of labor productivity growth in the copper mining industries

    of the United States and Chile spotlight the importance of innovation and new

    technology.2 They provide considerable support for the alternative view of

    competitiveness and wealth in mining.

    2 See Tilton and Landsberg (1999), Aydin and Tilton (2000), Tilton (2000), Garcia and others (2000),Tilton (2001a), Tilton (2001b), and Garcia and others (2001).

    2

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    3/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    For many closely associated with the mining industry, as well as for a few

    observers outside the industry,3 the importance of innovation and new technology has

    long been recognized. For the most part, however, government officials and the general

    public consider mining to be a mature industry with relatively stagnant technology. In the

    world, as they see it, countries that discover new deposits to replace those being depleted

    maintain their competitiveness. Countries that fail to do so lose their competitiveness and

    the wealth flowing from mining.

    Important and quite different policy implications flow from the traditional and

    alternative views for both mining companies and mineral producing countries. The

    implications of the traditional view are considered next, then the evidence from the

    United States and Chile regarding innovation and new technology, and finally the

    implications of the alternative view.

    The Traditional View

    According to the traditional view, the overriding determinant of competitiveness

    and wealth creation in mining is the geological legacy a country enjoys along with the

    exploration efforts undertaken to uncover that legacy. This view is intuitively quite

    appealing, and over time has accumulated quite a large following. It also has a number of

    important implications.

    First, it suggests that other determinants of competitiveness and wealth creation

    are insignificant compared to geologic endowment. The generation and diffusion of new

    technology along with other innovations, in particular, are of little or no importance.

    3 See, for examples, Adelman (1970) and Trocki (1990).

    3

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    4/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    There are two, quite different rationales for this position. The first contends that the

    technology of mining is mature and stagnant, and that the few changes that do take place

    do not greatly affected costs. The second recognizes that advances in technology occur,

    but argues they diffuse quickly around the world providing particular mines, companies,

    and countries with few opportunities to acquire a cost advantage over other producers.

    The first of these explanations flies in the face of considerable empirical evidence, and

    yet in many circles is still widely accepted.

    Second, the traditional view sees competitiveness and wealth creation in mining

    as largely a transitory gift of nature. Companies and countries with the best deposits are

    the most competitive and generate the most wealth. Once their deposits are exhausted,

    however, competitiveness will shift to those companies and countries with the next best

    set of deposits. New discoveries can also from time to time cause a change in the

    distribution of reserves.

    Third, there is little managers and workers can do to sustain or improve the

    competitiveness of any particular mine. A mine can produce only so long as it has

    reserves. Once these are gone, it will close. To remain competitive over the longer run,

    companies must replace their depleting reserves by new discoveries or by acquiring new

    deposits in other ways.

    Fourth, the ability of governments to promote the competitiveness of their mining

    industries is similarly limited. While policies that encourage domestic exploration may

    delay the inevitable, the depletion of the best deposits and the exploitation of the best

    exploration sites will eventually encourage mining companies to search abroad for new

    reserves. Through taxation and other means, governments can acquire some of the wealth

    4

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    5/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    created from their domestic mineral resources and invest it, thereby ensuring that future

    generations too benefit from the countrys mineral wealth even after it is gone. What they

    cannot do is prevent the depletion of their mineral deposits and the loss of

    competitiveness that follows.

    The United States

    Throughout much of the 20th

    century the United States mined more copper than

    any other country. By the late 1970s and early 1980s, however, its industry was in

    trouble. Between 1970 and 1985, output declined by nearly a third, and its share of

    Western world production fell from 30 to 17 percent. Employment dropped by 70

    percent. Cash costs declined but not enough to keep pace with the drop in market price.

    As a result, very few mines were earning a profit, and many were not even covering their

    variable or cash costs.

    U.S. copper producers petitioned the government for protection from imports in

    1978 and 1984, claiming their survival was at stake. On both occasions, their request was

    denied. The media as well lamented the industrys fortunes.Business Weekin the mid-

    1980s ran a cover story declaring the death of mining in the United States.

    Amoco Minerals, Arco/Anaconda, Cities Service, Louisiana Land and

    Exploration, and other companies left the industry. They sold their mines to other

    companies, spun them off as independent companies, or simply shut them down. Of the

    24 significant copper mines operating in the United States in 1975, six had closed by

    1990 and another five had sharply cut back production.

    5

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    6/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Yet the industry did survive, staging one of the most spectacular turnarounds in

    modern industrial history. By 1995 output was 72 percent above its 1985 level, and even

    21 percent above its 1970 level. Western world market share recovered to 23 percent.

    Imports were down, and profits up as costs continued to fall while prices recovered.

    Innovation, Mineral Endowment, and Competitiveness

    Many factors contributed to the recovery of the U.S. copper mining industry,

    including a decline in real wages, an increase in by-product revenues, a rise in copper

    prices, and the depreciation of the dollar. Among these, however, a dramatic

    improvement in labor productivity was more equal than others. As Figure 1 shows, labor

    productivity more than doubled between 1980 and 1986. So where two workers were

    needed in 1980, one would do six years later. Labor productivity continued to rise after

    1986, though at a more modest pace, and by 2001 was three times its 1980 level.

    Part of this surge in labor productivity can be attributed to an increase in the

    amount of capital, energy, and other factors available per worker. During the 1980s, for

    example, Bingham Canyon undertook a $400 million modernization program that helped

    the mine quadrupled its labor productivity. Even more important, however, was the

    introduction of new technologies and other innovations.

    One particularly important development was the increasing use of the solvent

    extraction electrowinning (SX-EW) process, which greatly reduced both the operating

    and capital costs of producing copper. A better understanding of rock mechanics allowed

    new mine plans that reduced stripping ratios and so diminished the amount of waste

    generated per ton of ore. Innovative agreements with labor increased the flexibility in

    6

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    7/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    work rules and manning assignments. Better ore handling systems, larger trucks and

    shovels, bigger drills, in-pit mobile crushers with conveyor belts, more cost-effective

    explosives, and the computerization of truck schedules and real time process controls in

    mills are examples of other new technologies and innovations that the U.S. industry

    introduced in its revival efforts.

    Relying on the traditional view of competitiveness and wealth creation in mining,

    we would expect to find behind the revival of the U.S. copper mining industry an

    improvement in the mineral endowment being exploitedeither from raising the cutoff

    grade at existing mines or from shifting production from high cost to low cost mines. One

    looks in vain, however, for much evidence of either.

    Trends in copper head grades do show a rise in the early 1980sfrom 0.59

    percent in 1980 to 0.68 percent in 1984as presumably some mines with poorer deposits

    closed and other mines turned to higher-grade ores to reduce their costs during this

    particularly difficult period. However, the rise in head grades was short lived, and over

    the entire 1971-1993 period that Tilton and Landsberg (1999, Fig. 4.5) examine grades

    drop considerably, from 0.78 percent to 0.60 percent.

    We also know that shifts in mine location did not play a dominant role. The new

    mines brought on stream during the 1975-1990 period, including Flambeau and Cyprus

    Tohono, contributed very little to the countrys total output, under five percent. So the

    revival of the U.S. industry came about because existing mines recovered their

    competitiveness. In particular, Bagdad, Chino, Morenci, Ray, and Tyrone more than

    doubled their output, while Bingham Canyon increased its production by 50 percent.

    7

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    8/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    These substantial increases raise the possibility that the revival of the U.S.

    industry was largely the result of productivity improvements and cost reductions flowing

    from a shift in output away from poor high-cost deposits to the good deposits at these

    mines. However, when we measure how much of the rise in labor productivity for the

    industry as a whole was the result of shifts in output from low to high productivity mines

    and how much was the result of individual mines increasing their productivity, we find

    that the shift in mine location accounted for only a quarter of the rise in industry

    productivity (Aydin and Tilton, 2000). This means that three-quarters of the total increase

    came about as a result of improvements in labor productivity at individual mines, where

    mineral endowments presumably changed little. These findings suggest that changes in

    mineral endowment were of secondary importance compared to innovative activity in the

    recovery of the U.S. industry.

    Technology Diffusion and Competitiveness

    Our research on the U.S. copper mining industry challenges the traditional view

    of competitiveness and wealth creation in yet another way. Earlier we noted that

    proponents of the traditional view claim that innovation and new technology have little or

    no influence on competitiveness because new technology in the global economy diffuses

    rapidly around the world. For example, it is argued, there is little or no difference in the

    time at which a new and more efficient shovel or explosive is available to mines in the

    United States, Chile, Zambia, or elsewhere. So a cost advantage based on new technology

    either will not arise at all or will be extremely short lived.

    8

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    9/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    This conclusion, however, is based on two implicit assumptions. The first is that a

    new process or technique is the result of but one innovation. The second is that the effects

    on all producers are neutral in the sense the impact on costs is the same. As the solvent

    extraction electrowinning (SX-EW) process illustrates, neither of these assumptions may

    hold.

    Ranchers Exploration and Development Company undertook the first commercial

    production of copper using the SX-EW process in 1968 at its Bluebird Mine in Arizona.

    Since that time literally hundreds of innovations have improved the processenhancing

    the quality of the copper produced, reducing costs, increasing the range of treatable

    copper bearing minerals, and extending the weather and other conditions for successful

    operation. Moreover, these developments will certainly continue into the future. This

    means that companies and countries that stay at the forefront of these efforts can

    indefinitely enjoy a cost advantage over their rivals thanks to technology.

    In addition, the SX-EW process reduces the costs of some producers much more

    than others. Specifically, it favors:

    Companies and countries that historically have been important copper

    producers, as these producers over the years have accumulated substantial

    waste piles of oxide copper minerals. The SX-EW process is particularly

    suited to recover the copper from such low-grade ores.

    Companies and countries where stringent environmental regulations are

    enforced. The sulfur emission recovered from smelting copper provides a low

    cost source for the diluted sulfuric acid used in leaching step of SX-EW

    processing.

    9

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    10/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Companies and countries possessing copper deposits in arid regions. The

    leaching step of the SX-EW process is difficult to control where precipitation

    is heavy.

    Companies and countries with substantial copper reserves that contain few by-

    products of value. So far the SX-EW process has not been able to recover

    economically gold, silver, molybdenum, and other valuable by-products often

    found in copper ores.

    These conditions exist particularly in the United States and Chile. This explains

    why these two countries account for such a large share of the worlds total SX-EW

    copper production, and why in turn the SX-EW process accounts for such a large share of

    their total copper output.

    The SX-EW process is a particularly dramatic example of the impact on

    competitiveness and wealth creation that innovation and new technology can have. At the

    other end of the spectrum, there are thousand of small innovations that can improve the

    performance of individual mines. As every mine is unique, it has its own innovative

    opportunities. Although small innovations may individually have little influence on

    competitiveness and wealth creation, when aggregated they can be of great importance.

    While some of these opportunities extend over several or even many mines, many are

    useful only for a given mine with its unique situation. These innovations do not diffuse

    rapidly around the world.

    10

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    11/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Labor Productivity, Costs, and Mine Survival

    The collapse and revival of the U.S. copper mining industry over the 1970-1995

    period raises yet another intriguing issue: Why did some mines manage to survive and

    even to expand their output over this period, while others shut down?

    Table 1 separates the 24 significant copper mines operating in the United States in

    1975 into three groups. The 10 expanding mines managed not only to survive but to

    increase their output over the following 15 difficult years. The three contracting mines

    survived as significant producers, but suffered a loss in output. The 11 non-surviving

    mines either stopped production completely or cut back to the point where they were no

    longer significant producers.

    Economic theory and common sense leads us to expect the expanding mines to

    have the lowest cash costs and the highest labor productivity at the start of the period, and

    just the opposite to hold for the non-surviving mines. Table 2 provides some support for

    these expectations, though there are anomalies. The non-surviving mines, for example,

    have lower cash costs in 1975 and higher labor productivity than the contracting mines.

    Even more surprising, simple econometric models indicate that the ability of

    mines to reduce their cash costs and to increase their labor productivity after 1975 is

    actually more important in explaining survival than their starting position in 1975 (Tilton,

    2001a). This again suggests that innovative activity played an important role in the

    recovery of the U.S. copper industry.

    Why were certain mines more successful than others in fostering productivity

    growth and in reducing cash costs? While a host of factors were likely involved, Table 2

    indicates that the expanding mines produced more and held substantially larger reserves

    11

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    12/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    than the contracting and non-surviving mines at the beginning of the period. Large mines

    with many employees possess more human capital for innovative efforts. Given the

    greater number of jobs at risk, they may also be more concerned about survival.

    Similarly, mines with many years of reserves are likely to have greater incentives to

    invest in new facilities embodying the latest technology since the expected returns can be

    realized over a longer time horizon.

    Chile

    To what extent can we generalize the finding that innovative activity is as

    important or more than mineral endowment in the creation of wealth and competitiveness

    in mining? There are good reasons to suspect the U.S. situation may be an anomaly.

    While the country is a major producer, the development of most new copper mines has in

    recent years largely taken place abroad, particularly in Chile. One would expect

    exploration and the development of new deposits to play a much more important role in

    competitiveness and wealth creation in the latter countries.

    Our research on Chile was largely motivated by the desire to see if copper mining

    in that county enjoyed a similar jump in labor productivity during the 1980s as in the

    United States. And if so, to what extent innovative activity as opposed to the

    development of new mines drove the increase.

    As Figure 2 shows, labor productivity increased in Chile during the 1980s, but at

    a modest pace.4 Chile did experience a jump in productivity similar to that in the United

    4It is important to note that labor productivity is measured differently in Figures 1 and 2. In Figure 1, laborproductivity is the copper contained in U.S. mine outputper thousand hours of work by copper companyemployees. In Figure 2, for the reasons indicated in footnote 5, labor productivity is the copper contained inChilean mine outputper copper company employee. So the levels of productivity shown in the two curvesshould not be directly compared. As the hours worked per copper company employee in Chile fell during

    12

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    13/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    States, but only in the 1990s, a decade after the jump in the United States.5

    The 1990s was the decade during which many new mines came on stream in

    Chile, suggesting that better deposits rather than innovative activity were largely behind

    the surge in labor productivity in that country. Previously, the state mining company

    Codelco contributed the lions share of the countrys copper output. In 1990, for example,

    its mines accounted for three-quarters of all the copper mined in Chile. Over the decade

    that followed, this figure fell to nearly one-third as Escondida, Candelaria, Cerro

    Colorado, Zaldivar, El Albra, Collahuasi, and other new mines came on stream,

    developed for the most part by private multinational mining corporations.

    Our research indicates that the shift in mine output, particular toward new mines,

    accounts for about two-thirds of the jump in labor productivity during the 1990s (Garcia

    and others 2001). This still leaves a surprisingly large portion of the jumpnearly a

    thirdattributable to increases in labor productivity at old mines. Chiquicamata,

    Salvador, El Teniente, and AndinaCodelcos traditional minesincreased labor

    productivity by 37, 70, 70, and 84 percent respectively between 1990 and 1997. A host of

    different innovative efforts largely created these impressive improvements.

    the 1970-1997 period from over 2000 to under 1500, the labor productivity figures shown in Figure 2 forChile would have to be reduced by 33 to 50 percent to reflect output per copper company employee.5The increasing tendency in recent years for copper producers in Chile to outsource to third parties manyeconomic activities raises the possibility that the growth in labor productivity shown in Figure 2 is

    overestimated. To assess this possibility we corrected the productivity figures shown in the figure for fourknown shortcomingsthe growing use of outsourcing and contract employees, the decline in the averagenumber of hours mining company employees work per year, changes in the quantities of byproductsproduced, and changes in the extent to which ore is processed domestically. The results show that thereadily available measure of output per company employee closely tracks the corrected figures (Garcia andothers 2000). While the errors introduced by outsourcing are significant, they are for the most partcancelled out by the decline over time in the average number of hours that company employees workannually. Errors arising from the other two sources examined are small by comparison. Thus, the almostfour-fold increase in labor productivity in the copper mining industry in Chile over the 1978-1997 period isreal, and not just an artifact of outsourcing or the way productivity is measured.

    13

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    14/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Moreover, when we examine labor growth over a longer periodfrom 1978 to

    1997we find innovative activities at the level of individual mines to be even more

    important. Their contribution to the rise in labor productivity was 45 percent, compared

    to 55 percent for the shift in output from low to high productivity mines.

    We had expected the development of new mines to account for all or almost all of

    the growth in labor productivity in Chile, and so were surprised by these figures. They

    indicate that innovation and new technology as well as the discovery and development of

    new deposits have played an important role in enhancing Chiles competitiveness in the

    world copper industry. Without innovation, many of Chiles older mines would no longer

    be producing, Codelco would not be the worlds largest copper producer, and copper

    exports from Chile would be a third or so below their current levels.

    The Alternative View

    According to the traditional view, a countrys geologic legacy and exploration

    determine its ability to compete and create wealth in mining. Aside from finding and

    developing new high quality deposits, there is little government, management, and

    workers can do to reduce the relative costs of their mining activities or to extend the

    working lives of their operating mines. The pressing policy questions that emerge from

    this view are:

    How long will our mineral endowment last?

    How should wealth (or what are commonly called rents) created by mining be

    divided among workers, companies and their shareholders, the state as a

    whole, and other interested parties?

    14

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    15/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    How much of the wealth or rents should the state invest in other forms of

    capital, to ensure that future generations continue to benefit from the countrys

    geologic legacy after the mines are shut?

    These questions lead inevitably to concerns over sustainability, intergenerational equity,

    and the intricacies of green accounting.

    On the other hand, if the traditional view is wrong or incomplete, if innovation

    and new technology are important sources of competitiveness and wealth creation in

    mining as suggested by the alternative view, the set of important policy issues changes.

    The whole process becomes much more internally driven. There is still wealth created

    and rents to be captured, but they are not predetermined gifts of nature, fixed in size, that

    producersfirms and countriescan effortlessly gather up. They are instead created by

    the mining companies that succeed in the global competition to reduce production costs.

    Mining becomes much more of a high tech industry than generally recognized,

    where managers and workers are not helpless bystanders watching external forces

    unravel their predetermined fate. Instead, they are crucial players who through their

    innovative efforts influence their own destinies. While every mine eventually runs out of

    reserves, innovation and new technology may extend the path to extinction by decades.

    The role of government shifts from ensuring that society as a whole gets its fair

    share of the wealth created by mining and that it is used in a manner that achieves

    intergenerational equity, to creating an economic climate conducive to the innovative

    activities of firms and individuals. In short, public policy focuses more on how to

    increase the benefits flowing from mining, and less on how best to divide them.

    15

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    16/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Now, human ingenuity can keep the real costs and therefore prices of copper and

    other mineral commodities falling indefinitely. This in turn reduces concerns about

    sustainability and intergenerational equity.

    The copper industry in the United States provides considerable support for the

    alternative view of the sources of competitiveness and wealth in mining. During its

    dramatic turnaround in the 1980s, it greatly reduced its production costs, not by

    discovering new and better deposits, but by a variety of innovative activities that

    substantially reduced costs and more than doubled labor productivity.

    In Chile, we find, as we expected, that the discovery and development of new

    mines contributed greatly to that countrys rising labor productivity, particularly during

    the 1990s. More surprisingly, we find that innovation and new technology also played an

    important role in sustaining that Chiles competitiveness and in contributing to the wealth

    created by the industry.

    While the stunning revival of the copper mining industry in the United States

    during the 1980s may be exceptional, the experience of the successful copper mining

    firms in that country and Chile is not all that unusual. New technologies have radically

    affected competitiveness and wealth creation in the gold, nickel, and other metal

    industries. Around the world, mining companies are continually searching for new

    technologies and other innovations to reduce costs. The discovery and development of

    new deposits is only one of many possible ways of enhancing competitiveness and wealth

    creation by reducing costs, and often not the most important.

    This, as we have seen, greatly alters the policy agenda for mining.

    16

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    17/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    References

    Adelman, M. A. 1970. Economics of exploration for petroleum and other minerals,Geoexploration 8, pp. 131-150.

    Aydin, H., and J. E. Tilton. 2000. Mineral endowment, labor productivity, andcomparative advantage in mining,Resource and Energy Economics 22, pp. 281-293.

    Crowson, P. 2001. Mining and public policy: an alternative view: a comment,NaturalResources Forum 25, pp. 67-69.

    Garcia, P., P. F. Knights, and J. E. Tilton. 2000. Measuring Labor Productivity in Mining,Minerals and Energy 15, pp. 31-39.

    Garcia, P., P. F. Knights, and J. E. Tilton. 2001. Labor productivity and comparativeadvantage in mining: the copper industry in Chile,Resources Policy 27, pp. 97-105.

    Tilton, J. E. 2000. Mining and public policy: an alternative view, Natural ResourcesForum 24, pp. 49-52.

    Tilton, J. E. 2001a. Labor productivity, costs, and mine survival during a recession,Resources Policy 27, pp. 107-117.

    Tilton, J. E. 2001b. Mining and public policy: an alternative view: reply,NaturalResources Forum 25, pp. 71-72

    Tilton, J. E., and H. H. Landsberg. 1999. Innovation, productivity growth, and thesurvival of the U.S. copper industry, in R. D. Simpson (ed.)Productivity inNatural Resource Industries: Improvement through Innovation (Washington, DC:Resources for the Future).

    Trocki, L. K. 1990. The role of exploration in iron and copper supply,Resources andEnergy 12, pp. 321-338.

    17

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    18/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Figure 1. Labor Productivity in the U.S. Copper Industry, 1975-2001

    (Tons of copper contained in mine output per thousand man-hours

    by copper company employees)

    0

    15

    30

    45

    60

    75

    90

    Source: U.S. Geological Survey; U.S. Mine Safety and Health Administration.

    18

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    19/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Figure 2. Labor Productivity in the Chilean Copper Industry, 1970 -2001

    (Tons of copper contained in mine output per copper company employee)

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    Note: Figures for 1998-2001 are estimates.

    Source: Comisin Chilena del Cobre, Servicio Nacional de Geologa yMinera, and Consejo Minero.

    19

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    20/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Table 1. Output and Labor Productivity for 24 U.S. Copper Mines, 1975 and 1990a

    Outputb

    Productivityc

    Mines _________________________ _______________________

    1975 1990 Growth 1975 1990f

    Growthf

    Expanding Minesd

    Bagdad 20 136 590 20 102 414Chino 53 145 172 60 91 51Morenci 125 324 158 53 95 78Ray 49 112 129 44 68 55Tyrone 75 155 106 51 95 87Bingham Canyon 247 371 50 31 153 394Pinto Valley 66 88 34 59 77 31San Manuel 109 142 30 22 36 63

    Cyprus Miami 45 57 28 42 52 24Sierrita 132 137 4 35 57 61

    Contracting Minesd

    Butte 91 90 -2 43 123 184Missione 106 79 -26 28 62 122White Pine 71 51 -29 13 24 82

    Non-Surviving Minesd,f

    Silver Bell 19 4 -80 45 44 -1Mineral Park 27 2 -93 34 14 -59

    Superior 44 3 -94 18 15 -18Yerlinton 31 2 -94 35 30 -14Bisbee 13 1 -96 44 35 -20Esperanza 24 0 -99 38 49 30Continental 16 0 -100 32 22 -32Ajo 33 0 -100 42 29 -31Battle Mountain 20 0 -100 30 21 -31Ruth McGill 31 0 -100 16 14 -12Sacaton 20 0 -100 39 45 16

    All Other Minesh 75 98 30 g g g

    Total Industryh

    1542 1995 29

    20

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    21/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Notes:

    aAll U.S. copper mines whose 1975 output equaled or exceeded 10,000 tons or

    more of contained copper equivalent in concentrates are included in this table withthe exception of Twin Buttes. Although Twin Buttes 1975 output was 13,800 tons ofcontained copper, it was excluded because its 1975 production was abnormally low,causing its productivity for that year to be unusually low as well.

    bOutput is measured in thousands of tons of copper equivalent contained inconcentrate production. Output growth is the percent change in output between 1975and 1990.

    cProductivity is measured in tons of copper equivalent contained in concentrateproduced per thousand manhours of labor input. Productivity growth is the percentchange in productivity between 1975 and 1990.

    dExpanding mines survived the recession in the copper market during the 1975-

    90 period and even managed to increase their output. Contracting mines survived therecession but suffered a decline in output. Non-surviving mines ceased to besignificant producers in the sense that their output fell below 4,000 tons of copperequivalent.

    eThe Mission mine also includes the Pima mine.

    fLabor productivity reported for non-surviving mines for 1990 is actually for

    their last normal year of operation: 1975 for Ruth McGill and Bisbee, 1976 for BattleMountain, 1977 for Yerington, 1980 for Mineral Park, 1981 for Silver Bell, Superior,Esperanza, and Continental, and 1983 for Ajo and Sacaton.

    gProductivity data for All Other Mines are not available.hOutput for All Other Mines is the contained copper in concentrate production,

    and does not include the copper equivalent of byproduct output. Productivity for AllOther Mines is measured in tons of copper contained in concentrate per thousandmanhours of labor input, and does not take into account the copper equivalence ofbyproduct output. Total Industry Output includes the copper equivalency ofbyproducts for all mines except those included under All Other Mines.

    Sources: Brook Hunt and Associates; Rio Tinto Mine Information System; U.S. MineSafety and Health Administration.

    21

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    22/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Table 2. Average Output, Labor Productivity, and Cost Performance for

    Expanding, Contracting, and Non-Surviving U.S. Copper Mines, 1975-1990a

    Performance Expanding Mines Contracting Mines Non-Survivorsd

    __________________________________________________________________________

    Output Growth 81 -18 -961975-90 (percent). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

    1975 Productivity 36 24 28(tons/1000 hours)

    Productivity Growthd

    125 124 -191975-90 (percent). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

    1975 Cash Costsb 154 165 160(cents per pound)

    Cash Costs Growthb,d -42 -19 231975-90 (percent)

    1975 Breakeven Costsc 116 146 116

    (cents per pound)

    Breakeven Costs Growthc,d -29 -26 -61975-90 (percent). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

    1975 Average Outputa 92 89 25(thousands of tons)

    1975 Average Reserves 558 126 34(millions of tons)

    1975 Average Reserve Life 47 10 9(years)e

    22

  • 8/3/2019 Creating Wealth and Competitivenes in Mining

    23/23

    Draft: December 17, 2002

    Notes:

    aSee Table 1 for an explanation of how output and productivity are measured. Thistable also defines expanding, contracting, and non-surviving mines, and identifies themines in each of these groups.

    b

    Cash costs are in real (1997) U.S. cents per pound. As noted in the text, they coverall the expenses of mining and processing through to the refined metal stage minuscapital costs (specifically, depreciation, amortization, and interest on external debt). Cashcosts typically include expenditures for labor, materials, energy, and contract services ofthird parties.

    cBreakeven costs are also in real (1997) U.S. cents per pound. They are actuallyadjusted breakeven costs, which are cash costs minus any revenues received forcoproducts and byproducts, minus the difference, if any, between a mines reportedrevenues per pound of copper and the world copper price.

    dData for 1990 reported for labor productivity, cash costs, and breakeven costs for

    non-surviving mines are actually for their last normal year of operation: 1975 for Ruth

    McGill and Bisbee, 1976 for Battle Mountain, 1977 for Yerington, 1980 for MineralPark, 1981 for Silver Bell, Superior, Esperanza, and Continental, and 1983 for Ajo andSacaton.

    eReserve life for each mine is calculated by dividing the product of its reserves andthe grade of its reserves by its 1975 output.

    Sources:

    Output and productivity data: Table 1 and the sources cited there.Cash costs, adjusted breakeven costs, reserves, and grade of reserves: Rio Tinto Mine

    Information System.