108
Financial Services Authority Financial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective Prepared for the Financial Services Authority by David de Meza, Bernd Irlenbusch, Diane Reyniers London School of Economics Consumer Research 69 July 2008

Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

Financial Services Authority

Financial Capability: A BehaviouralEconomics Perspective

Prepared for theFinancial Services Authority by David de Meza, Bernd Irlenbusch, Diane ReyniersLondon School of Economics

ConsumerResearch

69

July 2008

Page 2: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

FSA Foreword Background

The Financial Services Authority (FSA) leads the National Strategy for Financial Capability in partnership with Government, the financial services industry and the third sector. The strategy aims to improve the financial capability of the UK population. The results of the FSA’s major financial capability survey1 showed that in 2005, many UK consumers lacked the confidence and capability to make effective decisions about their money. The FSA launched a seven-point programme2 in March 2006 to improve significantly people’s levels of financial capability and, together with partners, has focused on delivering these priority initiatives. In March 2008, following recommendations of the independent Thoresen Review of Generic Financial Advice3, HM Treasury announced that the FSA will also lead a two-year "Pathfinder" programme to set up a service offering free, impartial information and guidance on money matters. Over time, improving people’s financial capability will not only benefit them directly, but also enable them to exert a stronger influence in the retail markets, creating more effective and efficient markets and reducing the need for regulatory intervention.

Measuring success – the challenge of evaluation The FSA financial capability survey measured different types of financial behaviour and attitudes in five key areas: making ends meet, keeping track of money, planning ahead, choosing products, and staying informed across the UK population. This survey is due to be repeated in 2010 and every four to five years thereafter.

Improvements in the level of financial capability require a long-term change in attitudes, habits and behaviour towards money. The National Audit Office has recognised that measuring those changes is inherently difficult. In a recent report4, the NAO suggested “The FSA may be able to build on its successful record of consumer research by using sophisticated methodologies to demonstrate a clearer link between improved outcomes and its own work". (Section 5.18 National Audit Office Review 2007).

This was also discussed at the Treasury Select Committee, where representatives outlined the need to be able to understand not only how the National Strategy impacts on outcomes and behaviour but also the effectiveness of different ‘types’ of intervention.

With these challenges in mind, and in order to inform further evaluation of financial capability initiatives, the FSA commissioned two academic literature reviews: a review of evidence from policy evaluation of financial capability initiatives around the world; and a review of behavioural economics literature on the likely impact of financial capability

1 Levels of Financial Capability in the UK: Results of a baseline survey, FSA March 2006. Financial Capability in the UK Establishing a Baseline, FSA, March 2006 2 Financial Capability in the UK: Delivering Change, FSA 3 Thoresen Review of Generic Financial Advice: Final Report, HM Treasury, March 2008 4 Review of the Financial Services Authority, National Audit Office, April 2007.

Page 3: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

initiatives on behaviour. These reviews confirm the importance and the unresolved challenges of evaluating robustly the effectiveness of initiatives to improve financial capability.

"Evidence of Impact": Review of policy evaluation literature by Adele Atkinson of the Personal Finance Research Centre, University of Bristol The FSA commissioned Adele Atkinson to review past evaluations of the effectiveness of financial capability initiatives and financial education more broadly, both in the UK and other countries. This was intended to deliver the following:

• An overview of the evidence on the incremental impact of financial capability interventions on people's behaviour and attitudes – i.e. what is the difference compared with the world if initiatives had not been introduced?

• Summaries from the available evidence on the likely impact of different types of financial capability initiative - e.g. school-based learning, one-off seminars, provision of printed information, or advertising via TV/newspapers/radio - and the likely impact on different target groups.

Adele's work has largely confirmed that, not only has there been relatively little work in the past on financial capability in the UK or other countries, but also that rigorous, credible policy evaluation showing the incremental impact of financial capability work is difficult to find. She therefore offered a useful summary of areas where problems have occurred, and what good practice would be to overcome these, which the FSA will take into account in designing future evaluation of financial capability initiatives:

• Clear objectives of the project and the evaluation • Good quality data, including administrative records. • A sample that is broadly representative of the target population • Careful consideration of the sample size, taking into account the analysis that will be

needed to understand the outcomes • Well designed data collection instruments that are appropriate to the target group and

to the initiative under evaluation • A benchmark measure of knowledge, attitude and behaviour (before the initiative) and

a follow up measure to identify change (after the initiative) • A ‘control’ group to show the normal changes that take place in the absence of such

an initiative • Consideration of the time period necessary to identify change, balanced with

consideration of the likelihood of collecting reliable data over extended periods of time.

"Financial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective": Review of behavioural economics literature by Professor David de Meza, Dr Bernd Irlenbusch, and Professor Diane Reyniers (London School of Economics) The FSA commissioned Professor de Meza, Professor Reyniers and Dr Irlenbusch to conduct a review of the behavioural economics literature, examining what this literature has to say about consumer behaviour when making financial management and/or choosing financial products, and in particular, the likely impact of financial capability initiatives, or other

Page 4: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

information provided to consumers with the intention of encouraging better choices about financial products. Drawing on a large and wide-ranging literature on consumer behaviour, this report argues that psychological rather than informational differences may explain much of the variation in financial capability reported in the FSA's financial capability survey, and that people's financial behaviour may primarily depend on their intrinsic psychological attributes rather than information or skills or how they choose to deploy them. In this context, the authors conclude that financial capability initiatives which are designed to inform and educate should be expected to have a positive but modest impact. The FSA recognises that achieving widespread behavioural change will be a long process due to deep seated behavioural biases, and will take the findings of Professor de Meza et al into account in using conservative estimates for the likely behavioural impact of financial capability initiatives in ex ante assessments of cost-effectiveness (e.g. cost-benefit analysis). Professor de Meza draws attention to recent literature which indicates that, in the context of widespread behavioural biases, two modes of financial capability work appear to be the most promising. These are the use of 'norms', which means directing people to a particular action such as higher saving, and the use of active intervention by a councillor and/or individualised advice, rather than passive information or education. The FSA and government's Money Guidance Pathfinder programme will include individualised advice both face to face and over the phone, and evaluation of this programme will provide useful new evidence on these promising modes of delivery.

Page 5: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

Financial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective

David de Meza

Bernd Irlenbusch

Diane Reyniers

London School of Economics

July 2008

Page 6: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

2

Executive Summary

• Financial capability involves knowledge and skills, but attempts to improve these may not lead to better outcomes. What people choose to know and what they do with their knowledge may primarily depend on their intrinsic psychological attributes.

• Behavioural economics has identified a collection of deep seated cognitive biases that influence decisions in both financial and non-financial contexts. There is considerable evidence that these factors are present, though how widespread they are remains controversial. The empirical work is often situated in contexts other than personal finance but there is no reason to think the biases are domain specific.

• Psychological rather than informational differences may explain much of the variation in financial capability reported in the FSA (2006) Baseline Survey. This applies both to differences between individuals and across competence dimensions. The Baseline Survey indicates that in most capability categories, scores improve with age and the level of general education. This is consistent with the importance of attitudes rather than teachable specific knowledge.

• If poor financial capability is mainly a matter of psychology, the information-based approach of the National Strategy for Financial Capability is likely to have only a modest effect in improving outcomes.

• Two links must hold for conventional financial education to be effective. Education must improve relevant knowledge and understanding (financial literacy) and better knowledge must change behaviour. Unscrambling causality from correlation is hard. The best empirical work finds that financial education is not likely to have major lasting effects on knowledge and especially on behaviour. Psychology may be the main driver of what people actually do.

• Some of the principal cognitive biases potentially relevant to the FSA agenda are procrastination, regret and loss aversion, mental accounting, status quo bias and information overload.

• Procrastination is captured by the tendency of many people to have high short-term discount rates but lower long-term discount rates (hyperbolic discounting). Postponing a cost, even one that generates high future benefits, is therefore attractive. So too is advancing a benefit to the present, even if this implies high future costs. This leads to outcomes such as credit card borrowing at high interest rates and unwillingness to engage in painful activities such as financial planning. Nevertheless, people with such preferences might be happy to make a binding commitment, for example to save more in the future. In the absence of commitment opportunities, such intentions will not be realised.

Page 7: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

3

• Procrastination is potentially relevant to all five FSA capability categories and to whether many of the facilities proposed in the National Strategy are widely accessed. There is limited evidence that awareness of the procrastination problem is an effective antidote at the individual level. Many behavioural economists take the view that the best response is not informing consumers of the problem or trying to change them but institutional design and regulation that recognises the psychology. An example is externally set deadlines for pension choice with sensible default options built in.

• People are concerned not only with what they have but how it compares to what they used to have and with what they might have had. That is, loss aversion and regret aversion matter. For example, whether people sell shares is influenced by what they paid for them and some choices may be avoided if it easy to determine subsequently whether a mistake has been made. These considerations have an impact on the choice of financial products and the inclination to stay informed about financial matters.

• Mental accounting is the common tendency to create artificial budgets covering different categories of spending and saving. People use this technique to evaluate and keep track of their finances but it can lead to seemingly irrational decisions such as saving at low interest rates whilst simultaneously borrowing at high rates.

• Status quo bias is the tendency for people to stick with their prior choices. It is therefore relevant to the selection of financial products and the incentive to stay informed. The surprisingly powerful influence of default options is consistent with this bias.

• There is a set of biases involving incorrect information processing that we group under the heading ‘curse of knowledge’. People draw incorrect inferences, focus on inappropriate or unimportant data, are distracted by too much information and choice, may over-deliberate and otherwise misuse information. Unjustified optimism is rife. These errors may affect decision making in all the FSA capability domains. It is though unclear whether people can be educated out of their errors, whether education may sometimes exacerbate problems, or whether the best response is regulation of how information is presented.

• Behavioural economics has been directed more to explaining choices than to changing them. Even if there is a sense in which people can be shown to be making poor decisions it is of course debatable whether it is appropriate to try to intervene. A relatively small literature has looked at remedies for various cognitive biases. Little of this is specifically applied to personal finance.

• A number of the debiasing techniques in the literature involve encouraging thinking that is more critical. “Consider the opposite” encourages people to think why they may be wrong. This counteracts general tendencies to be overconfident and to suppress disconfirming evidence.

Page 8: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

4

• Accountability accentuates the need to think about all aspects of a decision by making people imagine they have to explain their choice to others or really having them explain their choice to others. This has elements of a Weightwatchers or Alcoholics Anonymous approach. It has not been directly tested in the financial domain.

• Training in decision making, whether relatively abstract or applied has had some success, though the extent to which effects endure and are transferable to the financial domain is not known.

• Overall, there is a lack of direct evidence that the National Strategy for Financial Capability will substantially improve long-term financial decision making. The indirect evidence from behavioural economics is that low financial capability is more to do with psychology than with knowledge. Institutional design and regulation are probably far more effective than education, though crisis counselling may be helpful. More research is needed on whether cognitive biases can be overcome in the personal finance domain.

Page 9: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

5

1) Introduction

To promote their long-term interests, people need to identify crucial financial choices and

deal with them in a timely, knowledgeable and coherent fashion. The FSA (2006)

pinpoints five dimensions of financial capability and provides a comprehensive snapshot

of their distribution in the UK population.1 In the light of these findings, a National

Financial Capability Strategy has been formulated to improve decisions. Our paper aims

to draw lessons relevant to this endeavour from the flourishing field of behavioural

economics.

There is no doubt that many people are poorly informed about basic issues in personal

finance and take decisions that are difficult to interpret as rational. For example, some 9%

of tenants buy buildings insurance on the property they live in despite the fact that only

landlords can claim (FSA, 2006). Just as strikingly, the Skipton Building Society reports

that winning the National Lottery is a significant part of the financial planning of one in

seven Yorkshire residents

(http://business.timesonline.co.uk/tol/business/money/article3510234.ece). It is tempting

to assume that the remedy is more and better financial education. This does not follow.

Even highly educated finance specialists make errors.

MBA students at the top ranked Wharton Business School were the subjects in an

experiment by Choi, Laibson, and Madrian (2006). Elementary mistakes were common in

choosing between index-tracking funds that differed only in their administration

expenses. In making their choice, all sorts of irrelevant aspects of the presentation

materials were influential with the subjects. Redesigns of the explanatory materials that

emphasised costs still failed to elicit the strictly dominant choice for many subjects,

despite the experiment providing significant incentives to make correct decisions. If even

1 There is one reasonably similar question in the financial literacy quiz in the US HRS survey (Lusardi and Mitchell, 2007) and the UK survey (FSA, 2006). This concerns the distinction between real and nominal interest rates. Despite the very different education systems in the two countries, about 75% of answers were correct in both places. This could be a pointer to the irrelevance of education. A different US survey of personal finance information is described by Hilgert and Hogarth (2003).

Page 10: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

6

the most financially sophisticated individuals do not take sensible decisions when

confronted with apparently simple choices, the problems may not primarily be due to

financial ignorance and lack of financial education.2

Further food for thought along these lines is provided by an expert in the provision of

financial literacy courses in US high schools:

Perhaps more distressing than low levels of financial literacy is the consistent finding

that those who have taken a high school class designed to improve financial literacy tend

to do no better or little better than those who have not had such a course (Mandell,

2004). We do not doubt that the vast majority of students who take such a course attend

classes, read the textbook and cram successfully for the final. Nor do we doubt that the

teachers are dedicated and educated. We just find no connection between education and

financial literacy, measured, in most cases, within a year after taking such a course.

(Mandell, 2006, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=923557)

Similarly disquieting evidence is provided by Benartzi & Thaler, (2007):

Many employers have tried to educate their employees to make better decisions or

supplied tools to help them improve their choices. The empirical evidence does not

suggest that these methods are, in and of themselves, adequate solutions to the problems.

The same large employer discussed above that offered its employees the chance to switch

from a defined benefit to a defined contribution plan offered its employees a financial

education program free of charge. The employer measured the effectiveness of this

education by administering a before-and-after test of financial literacy. The quiz used a

True/False format, so random answers would receive, on average, a score of 50 percent.

2 FSA (2006) finds that financial capability tends to increase in the level of general education and in age. The former indicates that ability and attitude matter but does not imply that more education would help and has no message regarding the importance of specifically financial education. The age effect may indicate generational effects, that experience is the best teacher, or that older people have more settled financial lives.

Page 11: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

7

Before the education, the average score of the employees was 54; after the education, the

average score jumped to 55. As professors know, teaching is hard'

From a policy perspective, it is crucial to identify whether the reason people behave as

they do is primarily the result of lack of knowledge and mastery of relevant financial

management techniques, or whether it reflects fundamental aspects of human nature.

Only in the former case is conventional financial education an appropriate remedy. Such

education might include topics such as the benefits of diversification, the nature of

compound interest, the implications of tax incentives, pension planning, the management

of credit cards and so forth. At all events, if it is established that the basic problem is

insufficient knowledge, the question is when, where and how to deliver the information.

Is it best to provide formal courses at school, at work, or through evening classes? Are

impartial websites effective? Would television advertising convey information more

efficiently? What is the most helpful way to represent the level of risk implicit in

different financial instruments?

The big challenge though is to show that education does make a difference to how people

behave. Asking people at the end of a seminar whether they will do things differently is

weak evidence. What people say they will do is known to diverge from what they

actually do. “Good resolutions are useless attempts to interfere with scientific laws. Their

origin is pure vanity. The result is absolutely nil.” (Oscar Wilde, The Picture of Dorian

Gray) As we shall note, Choi et al (2006) find Wilde’s dictum is certainly true of pension

planning.

Making people better informed is hard and expensive and is of minimal value if it has no

effect on behaviour. This would be the case if low financial capability is more to do with

psychological factors than lack of knowledge. For example, many people think they

should save more than they do and borrow less. Why this does not happen may be more

to do with the psychology of self control, procrastination and immediate gratification

than ignorance of the relevant opportunities. Benton, Meir and Sprenger (2007) provide

some preliminary evidence that this is indeed the case. If what really matters in financial

Page 12: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

8

capability are personal attributes, the policy implications are major. Perhaps cognitive

behavioural therapy could help, but this approach is very different to most programmes of

financial education. Behavioural economics even suggests that it will be hard to get

people to attend courses if they are voluntary, or pay attention to them if they are

compulsory. The costs are immediate, the benefits deferred. The hyperbolic discounting

that may explain why saving rates are low may also explain failure to invest in education.

Rather than educating people out of error, a more effective approach may be to take the

biases into account when designing policy. A now well known example is to change

defaults, as advocated by Choi et al (2003). Saving rates are much higher if employees

are enrolled in savings schemes from which they can easily opt out than if there is no

automatic deduction but an easy opportunity to opt in. The design of Personal Account

Pensions due to be rolled out in the UK in 2012 has been much influenced by David

Laibson’s work on defaults.

In contrast to the behavioural perspective, the Thoresen Report (2008, http://www.hm-

treasury.gov.uk/media/8/3/thoresenreview_final.pdf ) is implicitly based on the view that

poor financial decisions are to a significant extent due to remediable ignorance. It

advocates that the Government should fund the widespread provision of generic financial

advice (GFA). If this leads to significant changes in behaviour, the benefits would greatly

exceed the costs. According to the Report, the net present value of the gain is of the order

of £15bn. The costs of providing GFA are between £780m and £1.67bn. What is much

more problematic is putting figures on the benefits, especially to consumers. Even if there

were evidence of substantial changes in behaviour (say with respect to saving rate)

converting these into a net benefit would not be straightforward. In fact there are no

reliable predictions of effectiveness. The Deloitte cost-benefit analysis appears to pluck

the key number for the consumer gains from generic financial advice from the air. The

raw data from the FSA Baseline Survey indicates that despite having higher incomes,

those in receipt of professional financial advice do not have higher wealth (see Figure 1).

On the face of it, advice discourages saving or leads to worse investments. Of course, the

effect may disappear if a full set of controls were included. It would be easy enough to

Page 13: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

9

analyse this data further and doing so should be an urgent priority. Another reason for not

reading too much into Figure 1 is that reverse causality might be present. It could be that

people most in distress may be the ones to seek advice. This though seems unlikely given

that the advisers are not crisis counsellors. So even though the evidence cannot be taken

as it stands, it does not provide much basis for expecting gains. As GFA will to some

extent be directed to those in distress it is of course possible that its effects may be more

positive.3 Nevertheless, the benefits claimed by Thoresen are not evidence based.

Figure 1

Our survey aims to cover research regarding the determinants of personal financial

decisions and whether and how they can be influenced. It provides an overview of what is

currently known about the nature versus nurture explanations of financial capability, what

more needs to be known, and the implications for policy. It should be read in conjunction

3 Collins (2005 http://www.policylabconsulting.com/documents/FMF_2005614%20-%20Collins_Paper4_LitReviewCounseling_6_05.pdf ) concludes that the effectiveness of counseling is largely unproven though some recent studies suggest it is helpful.

Page 14: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

10

with Willis (2008a, 2008b) who forcibly and effectively argues that there is little

convincing evidence that financial literacy education has a beneficial effect.

The plan of the paper is that evidence on the effect of financial education and literacy is

first surveyed. Some of the behavioural biases most relevant to financial markets are then

identified and implications for policy are considered. A fuller taxonomy of extant biases

is provided in the Appendix. Finally, debiasing strategies appearing in the literature are

discussed. Unfortunately, there is little work that directly considers whether biases can be

eliminated by appropriate training, especially in a financial context. There is a clear need

for more research in this area.

2) Does financial education deliver?

Providing convincing evidence on the effects of financial education is no easy task. The

most straightforward but least reliable method is to ask people attending a seminar

whether it was useful and whether participation will change their behaviour.4 There are

three main problems. Attendance is self-selected. Those motivated to turn up may have

the greatest interest in financial matters and may already be contemplating making a

change in their finances. That is, as treatment is not random it does not follow that

attending the seminar is the real reason for differences in the behaviour between

attendees and non attendees.

Secondly, self-reports of usefulness and of intentions may not be accurate. Most people

prefer to think they have not wasted their time. So there is a predisposition to want to

value the experience even if it is of little real benefit. Moreover, although participants

may come away from a seminar resolved to act, the proportion actually doing so may be

very low.5 The road to financial ruin is paved with good intentions. Concluding that

4 For example Kratzer et al. (1998); HR Focus (2000); DeVaney et al. (1995); McCarthy and McWhirter (2000); Jacobius (2000).5 See Madrian and Shea (2001), O’Donoghue and Rabin (1999); Diamond and Koszegi (2003); Laibson, Repetto and Tobacman (1998).

Page 15: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

11

education is effective because participants say it will change their financial life may

simply be wishful thinking.

Finally, if there are effects, it is important to know whether they are lasting. Providing

financial education to schoolchildren is pointless unless their adult behaviour changes.

Questionnaires administered immediately after a lesson cannot address the key issue.

Fortunately, there are a few studies sufficiently well designed to minimise these

problems. All find evidence that the effects of financial education on behaviour are

positive but modest. Unfortunately, all the studies relate to the US. There is no particular

reason to think the effect on UK consumers would be different, but there do not appear to

be comparable studies.6 The first set of studies looks at whether financial education raises

saving, wealth and pension plan enrolment. The second set tests whether financial

literacy improves outcomes but does not examine how far financial literacy can be raised

by financial education.

Bernheim, Garrett and Maki (2001) examine the long-term effects of school financial

education on saving behaviour and asset accumulation. This is possible because between

1957 and 1985, different states have adopted compulsory consumer and financial

education at different times and some not at all. A national survey of some 2,000

individuals collected details of personal characteristics, including location of schooling,

current income, wealth, and saving rates. Although the latter three magnitudes may be

biased, this will not distort the results on the effectiveness of financial education unless

the errors with which saving rates are reported themselves depend on financial education.

The main finding is that compared to states that never enacted a mandate, self-reported

saving rates were 1.5% higher for students in states in which financial education has been

compulsory for five years. The difference is statistically significant. It seems that

mandates become more effective the longer they have been in force. This may reflect that

it takes time to develop appropriate curricula and the skills with which to deliver them.

6 FSA (http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/documents/financial_services/financial_capability/fin_cap_fsastrategy.cfm ) describes the various initiatives planned and underway but does not examine effectiveness.

Page 16: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

12

Experience is apparently still building at least seven years after compulsion is introduced.

This is a long period to be learning, bearing in mind that some changes were almost

certainly made in anticipation of enactment. It could be that it is not mandates that are

responsible for the changes but that they are proxying for some other change.

One possibility is that states in which saving rates are highest introduced mandatory

education earlier than others did. The main defence is that a dummy in the individual

savings regression for whether the state ever imposed compulsory education is not

significant. The interpretation of this observation is that states that imposed mandatory

education do not have different intrinsic saving rates relative to the others. This is only

partially convincing in countering the argument that what might matter is not whether a

mandate was imposed but when it was. Perhaps the timing of mandates is correlated with

prior saving rates. In that case financial education is proxying for something else. This is

particularly relevant as fewer than one third of states ever had a mandate. The most

obvious procedure is to use state dummies. When this is done, the effect of the financial

education parameter is only significant at the 7% level. Were state dummies and year

dummies interacted, a ‘years since mandate’ variable might not be significant at all.

A complementary study by Peng et al (2007) is based on an online survey of alumni of a

large mid-western university. It investigates whether those who have taken financial

education courses at school and at university behave differently. Investment knowledge is

found to increase saving but only university courses increases investment knowledge.

There are controls for current income, inheritance and so forth, but there is an obvious

self selection issue. People choose whether to enrol for a university finance course

because they have more interest in financial matters and such types may have a higher

saving propensity.

The remaining studies involve the effects of workplace financial education. Choi et al

(2006) report on the effects of seminars run by a large US company. For both attendees

and non-attendees, data was available on financial choices before and after the seminar.

Page 17: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

13

For the attendees it is possible to compare intentions and actions. Attendance appears to

have some effect on behaviour. Table 1 summarises the results. Although eight out of

every 100 attendees increased their pension contributions, so did five out of every 100

non-attendees. Even this small difference may overestimate the effect of the seminar due

to self-selection bias. What is most striking is the low proportion of plans actually carried

out. Of seminar attendees intending to start a 401(k) plan only 14% did.

Seminar attendees Non-attendees

% planning to

make change

% actually

made change

%

actually

made

change

Those not in 401(k)

Enrol in 401(k) Plan 100% 14% 7%

Those already in 401(k)

Increase contribution rate 28% 8% 5%

Change fund selection 47% 15% 10%

Change asset allocation 36% 10% 6%

Table 1

Duflo and Saez (2003) provide interesting further light on findings of this sort. Their

experiment involved non-faculty employees of a large US university. All were

encouraged to attend financial information sessions (“benefit fairs”) but the experiment

offered $20 to some employees as an extra incentive. The choice of departments to which

this offer applied was random and within the chosen departments, it was random which

employees received the invitation. This randomisation of treatment should circumvent

selection effects. Though set low, attendance pay had a large effect on attendance. This

was true both of those actually in receipt of the offer and colleagues in the same

Page 18: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

14

department who did not have the incentive. Five to eleven months after the fair, there was

a statistically significant increase in enrolment in targeted pension plans, both for

attendees and non-attendees. Attendance at the fair was some 17% higher in treated

departments and the fraction of employees enrolled in the pension plan was about 1.25%

higher. This is evidence that the information provided by the fairs had an effect on

behaviour, though not a large one. Effects on overall saving were close to negligible.

Interestingly, within treated departments, enrolment rates were no different for those

offered incentives and those who were not. This suggests that there may be social effects

in spreading information or peer group effects in decision-making. It is also possible that

those paid to attend are less motivated to act or that the payment makes them more

suspicious of the information. At all events, there is evidence here that even controlling

for selection effects, information affects decisions and perhaps that education has

spillover effects. It helps not only the direct recipients but their peers too.

Bernheim and Garrett (2003) use cross-sectional data from a large telephone survey to

provide evidence of the effects of workplace financial education. The basic finding is that

when an employer offers financial education, self-reported saving rates rise from 5% to

6% for the median saver. For those already saving higher fractions of their income,

perhaps not surprisingly, education does not appear to have any effect. The use of

employer availability of education rather than take-up avoids the selection bias that those

choosing to attend a courses are more disposed to save. However, it still allows for

another potential selection bias. Firms do not randomly choose whether or not to offer

financial education. Even if they did, employees with a “taste” for saving may find their

way to employers who provide education. Indeed, employers in some sectors may find

that savers are better employees and deliberately seek to attract them by providing

financial education. One way to test for this is to find a proxy for saving proclivity. If

self-selection imparts an upward bias to the estimate of the effect of education, the

inclusion of this proxy should lower the effect of education on saving. Wealth can be

argued to be a measure of taste for saving since it is increasing in past saving decisions.

Including wealth in the regressions causes the estimated effect of educational availability

on saving to rise. Perhaps this is because financial education is more often offered when

Page 19: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

15

employees have low financial competency. The implication of this interpretation is that

financial education is remedial; the employees to whom it is offered have below average

savings rates, controlling for many demographic and economic variables. If this is really

what is happening, Bernheim and Garret underestimate the effects of education. It does

though seem surprising that below average savers become above average on receiving

education.

There is a puzzle in the findings. Though financial education appears to raise saving

rates, there is no significant effect on wealth levels. As wealth depends on past saving,

the expectation is that it would respond to education in the same direction as does saving.

If, as argued earlier, education is provided as a remedy for low saving rates but has only

recently been received by employees, savings might not have been high for long enough

to counteract low wealth. In that case a negative effect of education on wealth might be

expected. Another possibility is that saving is mismeasured. Borrowing is not netted out

(no respondents recorded negative saving) or mortgage repayments are considered to be

saving. If financial education is provided as a remedial measure it could be that those in

receipt of it are more prone to these recording errors. This would question the earlier

positive savings effect. Or it could be that wealth depends more on inheritance and

random capital gains than on savings so there is too much noise to pick up an

accumulated saving effect. However, wealth has a highly significant positive coefficient

on saving suggesting these exogenous factors do not dominate. So the absence of a

financial education effect on wealth remains something of a mystery, thereby casting

some doubt on the savings effect.

Finally, Clancy, Grinstein-Weiss and Schreiner (2001) is of particular interest because it

focuses on the effects of financial education on the poor. The study looks at the take-up

of a government saving program designed for poor people. Different program strands

vary in the hours of financial education offered. There is data on actual saving rates. So it

is possible to estimate the effect of varying hours of education on savings. Effects appear

large. Six extra hours of financial education are associated with a 25% increase in saving.

In interpreting this result, note that not only are there self-selection effects into the

Page 20: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

16

program, but program managers direct people into strands according to background and

need. Standard self-selection estimation techniques are applied but are unlikely to fully

control for these non-random treatment effects. So the impact of education is likely to be

exaggerated.

A related stream of work looks at whether financial literacy matters irrespective of how it

is acquired. The links proposed are that financial literacy leads to better financial

planning which in turn leads to more saving and wealth accumulation. If all these links

are positive then, if financial education does improving financial literacy, it is justified to

provide it (as long as the cost is not too high). This conclusion depends firstly on the

direction of causality. If, for example, wealthier people have more incentives to plan and

acquire financial literacy, the correlations do not of themselves justify educational

provision. Secondly, the propensity to plan and to be financially literate may both reflect

deeper aspects of personality or abilities. Perhaps those with high IQs are good at the

quizzes that test financial literacy and may also tend to engage in planning. If so, there is

no real basis for thinking that training in financial literacy would change behaviour.

The key published paper, incorporating some findings from their other research, is

Lusardi and Mitchell (2007). The data is from a large-scale US survey, the Health and

Retirement Survey. The self-reported propensity to plan is measured by ‘having thought

about retirement a little, some, or a lot’. The idea is that those who have thought about

retirement are more likely to be planners.

Financial literacy is captured by score on the following quiz:

If the chance of getting a disease is 10%, how many people out of 1,000 would be

expected to get the disease?

If five people all have the winning number in the lottery and the prize is 2 million

dollars, how much will each of them get?

Page 21: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

17

For respondents who give the correct answer to either the first or the second question,

the following question is then asked:

Let’s say you have 200 dollars in a savings account. The account earns 10% interest

per year. How much would you have in the account at the end of two years?

Only the last of these questions appears to be specifically financial, raising questions

whether what is measured is closer to numerical competence, general IQ or perhaps

diligence or some other psychological attribute. In fact, Lusardi and Mitchell (2007)

report that success at counting backward, and subtracting seven from 100 five times is

highly correlated with the questions on financial literacy, casting some doubt on whether

the variable really identifies what it is intended to. There is also a political literacy

question. This asks the name of the US President and Vice President, a question of

debatable direct relevance to financial literacy. Political literacy is though correlated with

retirement planning and wealth. The lesson is surely not that teaching political literacy

will improve financial decisions, but that people interested in current events are the type

also likely to be interested in personal finance. The worry is that the same explanation

may underlie the finding of a similar correlation between financial literacy and retirement

planning, so changing the implied policy conclusions.

To defend against the criticism that the wealthy may be more inclined to plan rather than

planning leads to higher wealth, a change in wealth that is clearly outside the individual’s

control is needed. If planning is not higher when wealth of this sort is high, the

implication is that for other components of wealth the causality runs from planning to

wealth and not the reverse. Changes in regional housing prices, plausibly an exogenous

windfall, provide such an “instrument”. Wealth is found to have no significant effect on

planning. The confidence interval is wide though so it cannot be rejected that there is a

large effect. It is also questionable whether people treat housing wealth as similar to other

components of net wealth. It is not very likely that people react in the same way to

knowing that the value of the house they live in rose by $10,000 last year as to winning

the same amount in a lottery.

Page 22: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

18

A further defence to the criticism that both financial literacy and planning are driven by

the same underlying taste parameter is found in Lusardi and Mitchell (2007b). This paper

uses a different (online) survey in which one of the questions asks about the individual’s

exposure to economics courses at high school, college or higher degree level. The

underlying idea is that understanding economic principles highlights the need for

retirement planning and improves individuals’ ability to engage in it. If exposure to

economics courses is random, and taking such courses is associated with greater

retirement planning, this does indeed provide convincing evidence that planning is

fostered by financial literacy.7 Using the appropriate instrumental variable estimation

techniques, financial literacy attributable to attending economics courses is found to be

significantly related to retirement planning. The conclusion that self-selection problems

are avoided is not completely persuasive. University students certainly elect their own

courses, so self-selection bias continues to be an issue. Even at school there may be an

element of choice. Moreover, the matching between students and schools that include

economics in the curriculum is unlikely to be random. Finally, there could be recall bias.

Those who know their financial knowledge is low may be biased against admitting they

studied economics. Even in the absence of conscious suppression, only those for whom

the courses had an impact are likely to remember them, resulting in the effectiveness of

economic education being exaggerated.

Americs, Caplin and Leahy (2003) provide more evidence on the link between wealth

and planning. Using a specially commissioned survey, the wording of the planning

question is more directly relevant. Respondents are asked how far they agree (on a six

point scale) with the statement “I have spent a great deal of time developing a financial

plan”. To provide instruments to test whether financial planning is a cause of wealth

levels, the level of agreement to two questions are used. One is “Before going on a

vacation, I spend a great deal of time examining where I would most like to go and what I

would like to do.” Answers to this question are positively correlated with financial

7 Another qualification is that the content of most economics courses involves little practical financial literacy information.

Page 23: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

19

planning at a high level of statistical significance. Holiday planning is not correlated with

wealth but it is with the financial planning question. So it is a good instrument to test

whether a planning mindset leads to higher wealth. Another statement, “I am highly

confident in my mathematical skills,” was also strongly correlated with financial

planning.8 This is more problematic as an instrument since, not surprisingly,

mathematical ability does enhance earnings. Nevertheless, a number of other variables in

the wealth equation might control for this effect.

The paper also makes some progress in controlling for tastes. There are questions that

relate to the respondents’ time preference and risk aversion. Answers to these are

uncorrelated with the responses to the planning propensity question. This indicates that

the correlation between wealth and planning is not proxying for a common dependence

on these particular aspects of underlying preferences. Though these are two dimensions

of tastes that are emphasised by neoclassical economic theory, there are many other

dimensions of personality that are not tested for. So it could still be that planning matters

because it reflects preferences (other than lack of self control) rather than mastery of a

useful technique.

Overall, the instrumental variable estimate is that a one point increase in the numerical

response to the planning statement leads to a 16-percent increase in net worth. Even if

this can be taken at face value, note that the evidence relates to whether planners are

better at accumulating wealth and not to whether planning skills can be effectively taught.

The stream of work reported here is certainly interesting, but as it stands does not provide

highly convincing evidence on which to conclude that more financial education would

result in better outcomes. To put it starkly, gardening knowledge may well be correlated

with financial literacy and retirement planning. It would be hasty to draw the conclusion

that the way to improve financial decision-making is to make horticulture compulsory in

schools.

8 Rather surprisingly, whether the respondent kept a tidy workspace was not correlated with financial planning.

Page 24: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

20

Most of the education programmes considered in this Section are closer to information

provision than to training in cognitive skills. So a different type of education may be

more effective. There is little evidence on this. Alternatively, if it is “flawed” psychology

that is at fault the most cost effective remedies may be “mechanism design” i.e.

considering behavioural biases in regulating the way financial products are marketed. It is

to these issues we now turn, putting the spotlight on the most established of the

behavioural biases.

3) The challenge of behavioural economics

According to standard economics, there is limited scope to improve financial decision-

making. The theory supposes that individuals rationally process available information to

make optimal saving, borrowing and insurance choices. If people take decisions that

appear to be irrational, there are two reasons. One is that the cost of being rational is

deceptively high. That is, it may take a lot of psychic effort to process rather boring

information. Secondly, the information available to make the decision may be inadequate

or false. So, if there is a role for policy, it is to provide better information in forms that

are easy to work with. Education in how to understand and work with the data is possibly

also justified. Even elimination of any bias (as opposed to falsehood) in what is reported

by information providers should not be needed as rational consumers should not be

fooled, what is left unsaid should speak volumes.

The effects reported in the previous section are largely those attributable to education

conceived in the traditional information provision mode. The approach of behavioural

economics is that psychology also matters. Even if people know and understand the facts,

they may still take poor decisions due to lack of self-control and other personality

characteristics. Moreover, there are ingrained methods of processing information that

lead to systematic bias. These “heuristics” may be better adapted to life on the savannah

than in Surbiton. It is not that people have no idea how to take some decisions. They

Page 25: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

21

think they know, but are “wrong” by the conventional standards of rationality. If they are

to do better, they first have to see the error of their ways. Achieving this may not be an

easy task. For the policy maker it is perhaps easier to require that choices are framed so

as to avoid the deep seated biases. That means rules on marketing financial products that

are sensitive to the psychology of the consumer in an attempt to offset the widespread use

of psychology by sellers.

As an illustration of the kind of issue that may arise, consider the finding that the order in

which items are presented matters for what is bought. For example, according to

Whitney, Hubin, and Murphy (1965), "The interesting thing is that even when a man

enters a clothing store with the express purpose of purchasing a suit, he will almost

always pay more for whatever accessories he buys if he buys them after the suit purchase

than before." Having spent a large amount on the suit, the consumer is desensitised to

large outlays. A spending mood is created and a more expensive jumper will be bought.

When the jumper is sold first and the customer agonises over a small absolute difference

between the high and low quality item, they are going to be consistent by going for a

cheap suit. This is a strategy well known to salesmen. It has been tested on the order in

which car extras are sold. What is the relevance to financial products? A warranty on a

consumer product is easy to sell as a secondary sale after the expensive basic item is

bought. Similarly, overpriced mortgage protection insurance may be easily accepted once

the commitment to major mortgage outlays is made. Firms may trade on this psychology

by discounting the main product to entice the customer in to the office and earning more

than the sacrificed primary profits on the secondary sale.

A possible remedy is to provide better information. For example, customers could be told

that there are large savings to be made from shopping around for mortgage payment

protection. This seems unlikely to be very effective. A message delivered a year or two

earlier is likely to be forgotten and specific information provided at school is unlikely to

be seen as relevant and if it is, to endure. Even were it remembered at the crucial time,

the message might easily be countered by sales pressure. Moreover, the fraction of the

population in the mortgage market at any one time is too low to justify a television

Page 26: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

22

campaign. Could a course that tried to explain the principle rather than the facts of the

particular case be effective? There is no evidence on this that we know of. Such a course

could be time consuming and even if it would ultimately work, it seems unlikely that

many volunteers would enrol. The most obvious policy is not education but to increase

competition at the point of sale. Mortgage providers could be required to offer a choice of

insurance contracts from a variety of companies. An even more effective antidote to

overpricing is to separate the primary and secondary sale by prohibiting the lender from

selling insurance. These policies are far more interventionist than education but could

well be more efficient.

Of course the basis for policy when people take systematically unwise decisions

is controversial. Many behavioural economists think that the appropriate thing to do is to

guide people in the direction they would want to bind themselves after taking expert

advice. This is the agenda of libertarian paternalism (Sunstein and Thaler, 2003).

“Equipped with an understanding of behavioral findings of bounded rationality and

bounded self-control, libertarian paternalists should attempt to steer people's choices in

welfare-promoting directions without eliminating freedom of choice.”

With this in mind we now examine a series of behavioural biases and consider what can

be hoped for from education and other policies that may achieve what education would

ideally do but may not deliver or do so only at prohibitive financial and psychic cost.

4) Procrastination

Definition and evidence

We procrastinate when we delay taking an action in spite of being aware that prompt

action would be better. Why does procrastination occur? Cognitive psychologists claim

that present or immediate costs/benefits are unduly salient or vivid in comparison to

future costs/benefits. This cognitive structure is not something most individuals are fully

Page 27: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

23

aware of, nor are they able to predict they will succumb to it. So, we end up postponing

an unpleasant task until tomorrow, not anticipating that tomorrow we will find another

excuse to postpone it again, only to regret by the end of tomorrow that we still have not

finished (or started) the task. Scores on the FSA Baseline Survey capability ‘planning

ahead (for retirement and unexpected events)’ are clearly affected by people’s tendency

to procrastinate.

Procrastination is characterised by preference reversal over time. Such preference

reversals apply to rewards as well as costs: most people prefer £100 today to £110

tomorrow and at the same time prefer £110 in 31 days to £100 in 30 days. We have high

discount rates for short horizons and low discount rates for long horizons. Far in advance

of time period t, an individual prefers to be patient between t and t + 1 but when time

period t arrives the individual is impatient. This gap between long-term goals and short-

term behaviour was first mentioned by Strotz (1956).

The behavioral economics literature often uses ‘hyperbolic discounting utility’,

introduced by Phelps and Pollak (1986), to capture dynamically inconsistent preferences.

The utility of a consumption stream x = x0, x1, …, xt,… is given by

U(x) = v(x0) + β Σt=1 δt v(xt) 0 < δ < 1, 0 < β < 1

so that today (time t=0) takes on special significance. Animals, including humans, appear

to have such hyperbolic discount functions (Ainslie, 1992, 2001). Numerous authors

report on experiments and simulations supporting hyperbolic discounting. There are

however some dissenters who do not argue against the existence of time inconsistency

but suggest that the hyperbolic utility function is not the best mechanism to capture this

phenomenon (see e.g. Rubinstein, 2003 and Read, 2001).

There is some evidence that actual UK household expenditure patterns are consistent with

hyperbolic discounting. Huffman and Barenstein (2004), using Family Expenditure

Survey data, observe that consumption declines between paydays for a sample of 15,000

Page 28: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

24

households. They report large payday effects for spending on alcohol. It appears,

however, that only cash spending declines; credit card spending is stable between

paydays.

It is not difficult to see that procrastination fundamentally interferes with an individual’s

ability to engage in financial planning. O’Donoghue and Rabin (1998) model

procrastination and show that it is likely to cause severe problems in personal investment

decisions. The urge for instant gratification (consuming immediate benefits or avoiding

immediate costs) leads people to make decisions and take actions (this includes the

decision not to decide and non-action) which are not in their long-term interest such as

overspending on credit cards. According to a survey for the Office of Fair Trading almost

a third of adults said that they had felt pressurised to take up credit when buying goods or

services (http://www.moneystuff.co.uk/debt_statistics.pl?search=2005) and almost 50%

of people who arrange credit while out shopping had not intended to do so before they

went (http://www.creditaction.org.uk/assets/PDF/stats/2005/DebtStatisticsMar05.pdf). It

is not surprising that the growth of ATMs and immediate borrowing possibilities offered

by credit cards and store cards in the last few decades has coincided with reduced saving

and mounting debt. There is a psychological trap set by offering credit cards with no

frontloading of charges, it appears costless to consumers who by and large do not

anticipate that their desire for immediate gratification will result in penalty fees and debt

repayment at high interest rates. Pursuit of immediate gratification regardless of the long

term costs is likely to be a significant factor affecting scores in the FSA Baseline Survey

capability ‘living within one’s means’.

Causes of procrastination

One of the main causes of procrastination is the availability of other activities which

provide instant gratification – ‘why fill out the tax return now when I could be watching

one of my favourite TV shows?’ This suggests that financial decision making is best

organised by setting aside a specific time and location where there are no distractions or

other demands. Rabin and O’Donoghue (1998) suggest financial education seminars in

Page 29: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

25

the workplace which are part of the normal workday. Of course this is not always

possible and could only work where we want to encourage a decision or an action and not

when we want to discourage actions (such as overspending).

Procrastination also results from the desire to avoid emotional distress. It is plausible that

some people fear financial decision making or planning because they anticipate that it

will be a painful experience. So, even when they are fully aware that it is in their interest

to sort out their finances, at any given point in time they will always want to do it later.

A rather extreme example is that of (UK) defined contribution plans which do not require

any employee contributions and are fully paid for by the employer. They do require

employees to take action to join the plan. Data on 25 of these plans shows that only half

of the eligible employees signed up (Benartzi & Thaler, 2007).

We know from neuroscience (see references in Loewenstein & O’Donoghue, 2004) that

both the affective (limbic) system and the cognitive regions of the brain are involved in

intertemporal decision making. The limbic system is designed to ensure survival and

(reproductive) fitness which is why our drives and emotions are inherently myopic. In

normal individuals, the cognitive parts of the brain to some extent override the limbic

system which allows for postponement of gratification. Patients with damage to the

prefrontal regions, however, tend to behave myopically (Camerer et al, 2005).

Psychiatrists who have studied the role of brain chemistry in compulsive behaviour treat

compulsive shoppers with drugs (naltrexone) which block the operation of opiate

receptors (McElroy et al, 1991).

Evidence of the connection between neurological processes and procrastination is

provided by an experiment on intertemporal choice where some rewards are immediate

and others are delayed. The immediate rewards activated mostly the limbic system

whereas the delayed rewards activated the cortex (cognitive system). Greater activity in

the limbic system was associated with more impatience i.e. choosing immediate rewards

more often (McClure et al, 2004).

Page 30: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

26

Why is procrastination a problem?

Economists usually take the view that what people decide to do is what’s best for them –

revealed preferences. Procrastination however almost always involves reversal of

preferences – today I want to fill out my tax return tomorrow but when tomorrow comes I

want to watch TV instead and by the end of tomorrow I regret not having done my tax

return. Our preferences are time inconsistent. People save too little and many spend far

more than they should or, in a sense, ‘want’ to. Of course this raises the issue of which

preferences should be considered from a welfare maximising policy perspective. It is

clear, however, that most people would like help in their attempts to achieve their long-

term goals of saving more and borrowing less.

The ratio of savings, pensions and investments to income was 2.9% in 2007 for the UK,

the lowest since records began in 1960, according to the Office of National Statistics.

Without employer contributions to pension funds, the savings ratio for 2007 was

negative.

(http://www.telegraph.co.uk/money/main.jhtml?view=DETAILS&grid=&xml=/money/2

007/06/30/cnsave130.xml)

Average UK household debt, excluding mortgages, is over £7,500 of which over £4,000

consists of credit cards, motor and retail finance deals, overdrafts and unsecured personal

loans (April 2005). Total credit card debt in the UK (July 2007) was over £53bn of which

£39bn is bearing interest at 17% APR. (http://www.dcmmoney.co.uk/credit-card-

debt/credit-card-debt-statistics.asp) According to Bannister (2004), in the US about 60%

of active credit card accounts are not paid off monthly. Average credit card debt for

American households is $8,400. A typical American family pays about $1,200 a year in

credit card interest (at an average annual interest rate of about 19%). These are alarming

numbers. Perhaps a dose of shame would help: Ariely (2008) proposes a scheme whereby

a borrower can choose to have emails sent to all their friends when their credit card debt

exceeds a specified threshold.

Page 31: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

27

Clearly, the temptation of immediate gratification creates a gap between intentions and

actions. In a 1997 (US) survey, 76% of respondents feel they should be saving more for

retirement (Farkas & Johnson, 1997) and there is evidence that many pensioners regret

not planning well for retirement (Loewenstein et al, 1998). In the UK, the Pensions

Commission estimates that over 12 million people aged 25 and over and in work are not

saving enough for retirement. Of these, 60% are not contributing to a private pension at

all. British pensioners are poor; a third live on under £7,500 per year and nearly one in

five goes back to work after retiring.

(http://www.creditaction.org.uk/assets/PDF/stats/2006/DebtStatisticsFeb2006.pdf)

Hancock et al. (2006) predict, for the period up to 2022, that 25% of older people (age

85+) in the UK will have zero or very low value financial assets.

What makes the procrastination problem worse is that it is subject to a cumulative effect;

the procrastinator may change their self-conception to reduce cognitive dissonance

(Andreou, 2007). Someone who repeatedly fails to save or continues to overspend may

over time decide that they really don’t want to get their finances under control by saving

or curbing their spending. Moreover, people may be reluctant to take actions which, if

they had taken them earlier, would have delivered large benefits. We don’t like to admit

our mistakes, even to ourselves.

Commitment devices

At least some of us are aware of our tendency to procrastinate or overspend and look for

commitment devices which bind us to the ‘right’ course of action e.g. agreeing to give a

conference presentation on a paper which is not yet written or saving in non-interest

bearing Christmas clubs which do not allow withdrawals for a certain period

(Wertenbroch, 1998). Ariely and Wertenbroch (2001) report that students are willing to

self-impose costly deadlines to help them overcome procrastination. Another ‘trick’ we

use is to have separate ‘mental accounts’ for example for ‘money to spend’ versus

‘money to invest’ (Shefrin & Thaler, 1988).

Page 32: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

28

Ashraf et al (2004) conducted an experiment in the Philippines which shows that people

are aware of their self-control problems (in the financial planning area) and when given

an opportunity to solve these problems by binding themselves will do so. The first stage

of the experiment involved a survey to identify people with time inconsistent preferences.

Subjects were then randomly assigned to a control group or a treatment group. Everyone

in the treatment group was offered a ‘commitment saving product’ with restricted access

to funds. Those with time inconsistent preferences were significantly more likely to take

up the offer. Subjects in the treatment group ended up saving 20% more than those in the

control group and for those who opened a commitment account (25% of the treatment

group) savings increased by 80%.

There is evidence that ‘Rotating Savings and Credit Associations’ (ROSCAS) can take on

the role of commitment device. Saving in ROSCAS is particularly popular in Africa but

is also found in developed economies such as Japan. Gugerty (2005) studies data on 70

ROSCAS in western Kenya and finds that participants do not always want to receive

money sooner rather than later. The holiday season is the least favoured time to receive

the ‘pot’ as participants worry that the money they receive at this time of year will be

used up in celebrations. Many participants claim they join a ROSCA to give them the

strength to save.

Thaler and Benartzi (2004) discuss the results of a ‘Save more tomorrow’ plan which

allows employees to commit to increase their contribution (saving) rate in a 401(k)

pension plan whenever they get a raise. The idea here is to delay the salient immediate

cost of foregoing current consumption. After two years, participants in this scheme had

nearly quadrupled their saving rate.

Page 33: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

29

What can be done?

a) Simplification

Complexity and resulting confusion may lead people to passivity. If confusion were the

only reason for procrastination then simplification of information on product attributes

and financial education might be fruitful. However, most of us are less likely to be

confused about materially relevant factors than we are to use ‘confusion’ as an excuse for

procrastination.

Madrian and Shea (2001) provide evidence that people procrastinate when they have to

make complex decisions. This finding is clearly relevant with regard to the FSA Baseline

Survey capability ‘shopping around’. Dealing with complexity and ambiguity is

unpleasant. In certain situations, simplification (e.g. by setting a default) might therefore

help. O’Donoghue and Rabin (2001) show that when an individual decides not to pursue

a choice which improves his financial situation because there is a more attractive choice

which requires (minimal) effort, it is likely that no choice is ever made. Hence, offering

more options can induce procrastination.

Another argument for simplification is that less intelligent people, in addition to being

handicapped by their relative inability to process complex information, are more likely to

have self-control problems - time discounting correlates with IQ (Mischel & Metzner,

1962).

Page 34: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

30

b) Financial education

The extent of financial illiteracy in the general population is staggering e.g. according to

a Mori poll, nearly four out of five people do not know that APR refers to the interest and

other costs of a loan. (http://www.credithelpline.net/personal_debt_stats.html)

There is certainly great scope for increasing knowledge of financial matters but could

financial education alleviate procrastination? If procrastination in financial decision

making is prevalent then education, disclosure and even financial incentives will not have

strong effects on behaviour. This is partly because people will tend to procrastinate with

respect to these remedies as well as with regard to their actual financial decisions; they

will postpone acquiring and absorbing the information. One can always choose to find

out about various choices of financial products later on. It is hard to imagine how

financial education could change individuals’ discount rates, so how could it work?

This not to say that there is no role for providing more information. However, the

presentation of this information is crucial. There are ways of making the long term

problems of debt more salient for example. We know that vivid and personal information

is more effective than statistical information. One could imagine government sponsored

commercials illustrating the dangers of overspending much like the ones warning against

drunk driving or drugs.

c) Defaults

Most of the time maintaining the status quo does not involve (mental) activity and the

easiest option is therefore to stick with the status quo and procrastinate, for example by

keeping savings where they are. This is precisely why setting the ‘right’ default options,

e.g. for pension plans, is such a powerful tool.

Defaults remove the immediate cost of mental anguish involved in decision making and it

is therefore not surprising that they have significant effects on financial choices. When

Page 35: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

31

employees are by default enrolled in their 401(k) plan, only a very small proportion opt

out. But when they have to make a choice to enrol, during their first year of employment

less than half do (Madrian &Shea, 2001; Choi et al. 2002, 2003a).

Another area where defaults could be introduced is in credit-card payments. The default

could be that the balance is automatically deducted from a current account. Customers

could opt out of this arrangement at the cost of some minimal effort.

In some cases it may be difficult to decide what the ‘right’ default is (see e.g. Camerer et

al, 2003); individuals may (if they could overcome their procrastination) choose to have

different saving rates for example. In these circumstances it may still be welfare

enhancing to choose a default and it may be even better to choose a ‘bad’, undesirable

default which forces people to make a decision (Choi et al, 2003b).

A powerful remedy for procrastination is the elimination of the ‘no decision’ option and

use active decision mechanisms. Choi et al (2005) document a scheme where employees

had to check the participation or the non-participation box for a retirement plan. This led

to participation rates almost 25% higher than the standard scheme with a non-enrolment

default.

Commitment devices can help people overcome procrastination. Offering, as a default, a

standard saving plan which transfers a set amount from a current account into a savings

account could be the default option. So rather than incurring costs (in time and hassle) to

set up a savings scheme, a customer would have to incur some costs or apply some effort

to undo the default savings scheme.

Page 36: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

32

d) Regulation

Procrastinators and overspenders appear to be in favour of regulation which protects them

from themselves. Sixty percent of Americans say it is better to keep restrictions on

withdrawing savings from retirement plans (Farkas & Johnson, 1997).

The constant pressure to abandon plans for self restraint and instead succumb to

immediate gratification implied by hyperbolic discounting is facilitated by credit cards.

Temptation could perhaps be held in check if credit card holders were offered the

opportunity of a self imposed spending limit. Were the limit exceeded, the card would be

refused, perhaps for a pre-specified period or until the balance is below the limit. It could

be mandatory for credit card suppliers to offer this facility. Of course, the policy will only

work for people who recognise their own weakness of will and want to do something

about it. Such people do exist; witness those joining a Christmas club. Even more

strikingly, in Illinois people can and do voluntarily sign an agreement that they will be

arrested should they enter a casino

(http://www.igb.state.il.us/whatsnew/sepchange060622.pdf).

Financial institutions clearly take advantage of people’s tendency to procrastinate. Banks

and credit card companies have recently had to face extensive litigation threats due to

overcharging on current account overdrafts and penalties on credit cards which far exceed

the cost of delayed payment. In the UK, during the first half of 2007, over 4m credit card

bills were not paid on time at an average late payment penalty of £12.

(http://www.dcmmoney.co.uk/credit-card-debt/credit-card-debt-statistics.asp) Minimum

repayments on credit cards are now as low as 2%.

(http://www.moneystuff.co.uk/debt_statistics.pl?search=2005)

Another area where banks exploit their customers’ inertia and procrastination is in their

provision of no (or very low) interest current accounts. Savings accounts pay interest and

typically have no restrictions on withdrawals. A ‘sensible’ customer would therefore

Page 37: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

33

transfer any excess funds into a savings account but many don’t. In fact, Rabin and

O’Donoghue (1998) show how procrastination can lead to never transferring money from

a current account, even for a very small transfer cost. Banks deliberately maintain the

distinction between current and savings accounts to create barriers to saving by forcing

customers to act if they want to avoid losing out on interest. Regulation can be helpful

here. Essentially every current account should be a savings account.

Banks also exploit individuals’ tendency to procrastinate when they lower interest rates

on existing savings accounts. Although customers are informed of such changes (and

possibly even advised that they can achieve a higher interest rate by switching to a

different product), the presumption is that most will not take the trouble to go for a better

deal.

Credit card companies also rely on inertia when they make valuable offers only available

to new customers. It is indicative of the forcefulness of inertia that offers, for example to

transfer credit card balances, have to be very attractive to get people to switch. ‘Teaser

rates’, which are sometimes zero for an initial period, are apparently very tempting to

consumers (Bar-Gill, 2004) although most of the borrowing takes place at high post-

teaser rates. Shui and Ausubel (2004) confirm this in an experiment where consumers are

randomly assigned to get different credit card offers. They are more likely to accept a low

introductory offer for a short period even when they would have been better off with a

slightly higher interest lasting for a longer period. Consumers seem reluctant to switch

even after the introductory rate expires, perhaps because they don’t keep track of the

expiry date. Regulation specifying a minimum period for which the teaser rate must be

maintained could be considered.

Insurance companies are also very aware of their clients’ inertia and exploit this tendency

by hiking up premia of existing policy holders to subsidise very attractive offers to new

policy holders. This practice, like the teaser rate offers, is a form of price discrimination

between new and existing customers and regulation in this area is likely to be welfare

improving.

Page 38: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

34

A recent development in the form of ‘payday loans’ i.e. cash advances on salary, paid

back on the day the salary arrives into the bank account, is bound to push many people

into very serious debt problems. Payday loans are very popular in the US and payday

loan firms are increasingly active in the UK. It is very easy to borrow £1,000 instantly as

long as you are over 18 and in employment. Interest rates are exorbitant by any standard

– equivalent to an APR of over 2000%! Clearly payday loan providers prey on people’s

lack of willpower. The problem is exacerbated by the fact that many lenders offer payday

loan rollovers which make it very easy to extend the term of the loan. Some providers go

as far as automatically renewing the loan as the default option so that borrowers have to

make additional efforts to repay the loan. Several US States have banned payday loans.

(http://usgovinfo.about.com/od/consumerawareness/a/paydayloans.htm)

Imposing a different default could be very effective in secondary insurance purchase such

as mortgage or loan payment protection or extended warranties. It is likely that a

requirement to act by, for example, posting in a form if insurance is wanted would

generate much lower take-up rates for these types of insurance. This type of regulation is

particularly attractive for extended warranties where people may make very different

decisions when they are not exposed to sales pressure.

e) Forced saving (for retirement)

The state pension is effectively forced saving for retirement. Extension of this idea could

be beneficial to many people, but there are a number of serious problems. First of all,

how to decide on the saving rate? In Australia, where compulsion was introduced in the

early 1990s, the saving rate actually fell, as most people accepted the compulsory rate as

the new benchmark, and reduced their saving accordingly.

(http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/4404852.stm) Also, compulsory saving could be

perceived as tax and is perhaps not politically viable.

Page 39: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

35

5) Loss aversion

Standard economic theory assumes that all that matters to consumers is the bundle of

goods they consume. Every day experience suggests this is not the whole story. Someone

who expects to earn £60K but actually receives £50K is not as happy as someone

expecting £40K and ending up with £50K. As Adam Smith put it "we suffer more... when

we fall from a better to a worse situation, than we ever enjoy when we rise from a worse

to a better.” Gains and losses matter independently of final outcomes. Loss aversion is the

tendency of individuals to weigh losses about twice as much as gains (Kahneman &

Tversky, 1979; Tversky & Kahneman, 1992). A substantial (experimental) literature

shows that loss aversion is very common. There is some evidence that loss aversion

increases in age, income and wealth and decreases in education (Johnson et al, 2006;

Gächter et al., 2007). Loss aversion leads people to value what they own more than what

they don’t own in the sense that they demand more money to give up an object than they

would be prepared to pay to acquire it (the ‘endowment effect’). This has implications for

the FSA Baseline Survey capabilities ‘choosing products’ and ‘shopping around’.

In prospect theory, a value function v(x), defined on gains and losses with respect to a

reference point replaces the standard utility function of expected utility theory. The

reference point normally corresponds to the current position but may also be determined

by aspirations or norms (Tversky & Kahneman, 1991). The ‘loss side’ of the value

function is steeper than the ‘gain side’ (loss aversion), i.e. v(x) < -v(-x) for x>0. The

value function is concave for gains and convex for losses, indicating declining sensitivity

for larger amounts i.e. v’’(x)<0 for x>0 and v’’(x)>0 for x<0 so that the value function is

S shaped.

Several interesting observations follow from these assumptions. For multiple gains, x and

y, segregation is preferred since v(x)+v(y)>v(x+y). For multiple losses, integration is

preferred since v(-x)+v(-y)<v(-(x+y)). This latter property may explain the popularity of

credit cards (many small losses are pooled into a larger loss) and why it is relatively easy

to sell add-ons in insurance (Thaler, 1985). It could also explain the success of debt

Page 40: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

36

consolidation firms and why those who consolidate their debt end up with the same, if not

higher, amount of debt two years later.

(http://www.bankrate.com/brm/news/cc/20031007a1.asp) In 2007, about 400,000 people

in the UK remortgaged or applied for new credit cards or personal loans to pay off old

loans. An additional 300,000 people chose bankruptcy, debt management plans or IVAs

to resolve their serious debt problems. Of those who enter into an IVA, 45% never

complete their payments (Seib, 2008).

Loss aversion implies that people are reluctant to sell at a loss (the ‘disposition effect’). It

is an empirical regularity in the housing market that when house prices fall, volume also

decreases and houses remain on the market for longer than when prices are rising

(Kahneman et al, 1990; Engelhardt, 2003). More direct evidence of loss aversion in the

housing market is provided by Genosove and Meyer (2001). According to standard

economics, houses are sold for what the market will bear. At any given date, the asking

and transaction prices of houses with the same characteristics should not depend on

prices prevailing when the seller bought. In fact, in downturns, people who bought at the

height of a housing boom ask more, receive more and have their house on the market

longer than those who bought when prices were lower. This is loss aversion in action in a

real market.

The Save More Tomorrow scheme exploits people’s tendency towards loss aversion.

Participants commit to increase their saving rate whenever their income increases so that

they never see their take-home pay go down. They therefore don’t view their increased

401(k) contribution as a loss.

It is possible to manipulate loss aversion by using different frames. Benartzi and Thaler

(1999) offer subjects repeated gambles which are either described in words (N plays of

gamble X) or in terms of the probability distribution of outcomes (after N plays).

Subjects like the gambles more in the second format, perhaps because they overestimate

the probability of loss in the first format. This finding generalises to an investment

context. Subjects are given one year or many year returns for 401(k) plan investments.

Page 41: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

37

Those given the returns over the longer horizon are willing to take more risk. This is

important since most employees are rather bad at allocating assets in 401(k) plans; they

invest in their employer’s stock (bad for diversification reasons) and allocate a large

proportion to fixed income accounts.

Myopic loss aversion is the tendency to see risks in isolation rather than taking the

perspective that life is a sequence of mostly small risks and what matters is the total

outcome, not the outcome of individual small lotteries. The one year returns presentation

in the study mentioned above accentuates the risk of investing in stocks and appears to

induce myopic loss aversion. This will bias people’s investment strategy away from

stocks. Given that losses are felt twice as much as gains and the stock market is equally

likely to move up and down on a daily or weekly basis, frequently checking how your

stocks are doing is bound to make you very miserable indeed.

The myopic loss aversion result is also found by Gneezy and Potters (1997). In their

experiment they manipulate the frequency of feedback on outcomes and the opportunity

to make decisions, i.e. in the low frequency treatment, subjects are told the outcome

every three rounds and make decisions every three rounds whereas in the high frequency

treatment, subjects get feedback about the outcome and make decisions every round. The

risky options were considered more attractive in the low frequency treatment and subjects

in this treatment had higher earnings. Fellner and Sutter (2008) conduct an experiment in

which the investment horizon and the frequency of feedback is varied. Longer horizons

and less frequent feedback lead to higher investment. Setting a long horizon and low

feedback frequency as the default is very effective in inducing higher investment with

higher expected return. A lesson for financial regulators is that investment decisions are

likely to be affected by how risk and return data are presented. Financial advisers should

draw investors’ attention to long term distributions of outcomes.

6) Regret aversion

Page 42: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

38

Regret theory (Loomes & Sugden, 1982; Bell, 1982) assumes that the emotional

consequences of decisions, such as rejoicing and elation but particularly regret, are

anticipated and taken into account when making decisions. People are regret averse and

hope to avoid situations where they appear to have made the wrong decision even if the

decision was the correct one ex ante given the information available. Loomes and Sugden

(1982) show how their theory explains why many people simultaneously gamble and

purchase insurance.

Bar-Hillel and Neter (1996) conduct a series of experiments in which Israeli college

students were given lottery tickets. They are then asked whether they want to exchange

their ticket for another ticket and an expensive chocolate or another small incentive. Their

chances of winning the lottery are unaffected by swapping yet only about 40% exchanged

their ticket. This resistance to exchange is likely to be driven by regret avoidance. In a

follow-up experiment, Maimaran (2003) found that when tickets are concealed in

envelopes (and so it is harder to imagine winning) subjects are more likely to exchange.

In her experiment the rate of exchanging is 80% with the envelopes and 63% without.

There is obviously potential for regret in most financial decisions. If I invest in portfolio

A rather than portfolio B, I can find out about the performance of my rejected option and

experience regret. Zeelenberg and Beattie (1997) show that in a financial decision

making context where subjects have to choose between two investment options, the

expectation of feedback on the outcome of the riskier option can promote risk seeking

choices. Subjects may prefer the less risky option if they are not going to find out the

result of the (rejected) risky choice but reverse their preference if they are going to get

feedback on the risky choice. However, in reality regret aversion is more likely to lead to

underinvestment in risky assets. If I invest in a fixed rate investment, the outcomes of

alternative investment choices are not always very salient. If I invest in stocks, however,

my obvious point of comparison (the fixed rate) is easy to recall.

Page 43: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

39

Choice overload

The possibility or anticipation of regret can have a paralysing influence in financial

decision making. In particular, when there are many options to choose from, especially

when these options are complex, inaction is likely. People lack the confidence to decide.

This phenomenon of ‘choice overload’ has been documented by Schwartz (2005) and

others.

Iyengar and Lepper (2000) describe an experiment which involved displays of Godiva

chocolates. Some participants were offered a limited number (6) of options, others a large

number (30). They selected (and consumed) one chocolate. Participants choosing from

the more limited array were more satisfied and more likely to purchase chocolates again

compared to those who were offered the selection of 30. This experiment illustrates that

dissatisfaction with choice is likely to be more prevalent when the number of possible

choices is larger.

In their famous ‘jam experiment’, Iyengar and Lepper (2000) set up tasting booths which

displayed either six or 24 different flavours of jam. 60% of passing traffic stopped to

sample one of the jams when there were 24 flavours and 40% did when there were six

flavours. However, in the extensive choice condition only 3% bought jam whereas 30%

did in the limited display condition.

In online shopping, where the seller offers the top 50 ‘best matches’, expected to be a

good fit to the consumer’s preferences, rather than the top 10, people choose lower

quality options. Presenting more options encourages investigation of lower quality

options. Since the list is not random but ordered according to fit or quality, the average

quality of options considered decreases for a longer list. Perhaps the cognitive overload

of considering a large number of possible choices leads consumers to make mistakes

(Diehl, 2005).

Page 44: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

40

Iyengar et al (2003) test the ‘choice overload leads to inaction’ theory in a financial

decision making setting. They use a very large data set covering almost 800,000

employees in 69 industries and examine the effect of the number of offered funds in the

401(k) plan on the likelihood of employee participation. Plans offering more funds had

significantly lower participation rates. For the same sample, Iyengar and Kamenica

(2008) find that the more funds in a plan, the greater the allocation to money market and

bond funds. They argue, on the basis of experimental evidence, that it is simplicity

seeking rather than risk avoidance which drives these choices. Faced with large choice

sets, decision makers apparently tend to prefer the simple options.

Another case which illustrates the perils of ‘too much choice’ is that of the Medicare

Prescription Drug Plan which offers drug discount cards. Each card, provided by

Medicare approved organisations, offers savings on medications. The cards, and there are

many, differ in monthly premiums and deductibles. Enrolment in the plan is low since

most senior citizens find the task of choosing a card daunting and fear choosing the

wrong card (Botti & Iyengar, 2006). In the UK, a simple prepayment prescription

certificate is available which entitles the holder to free medicines, no agonising choices

necessary.

There is a lot of product proliferation in financial markets e.g. savings accounts and credit

cards. Given that choice can be debilitating and overwhelming, especially for non-

experts, this is likely to be detrimental to welfare.

The obvious remedy for information overload is to restrict choice rather than to try to

educate consumers to handle excessive variety in a stress-free fashion. An earlier jams

experiment does though find a useful cognitive routine to handle such situations. Wilson

and Schooler (1991) asked subjects to rate jams. Left to their own devices, control

subjects formed preferences for strawberry jams that corresponded well to the ratings of

experts. Subjects asked to think about why they liked or disliked the jams made choices

less in agreement with experts. Subsequent work also shows less regret with spontaneous

choice. Deliberation and planning is not always the right way to make decisions.

Page 45: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

41

7) Mental accounting

‘Mental accounting’ refers to the cognitive methods people use to evaluate and keep track

of transactions, investments, gambles and other financial outcomes (Kahneman &

Tversky, 1984; Thaler, 1985). People tend to group their assets into a number of non-

fungible mental accounts and use these accounts for different purposes. They tend to

spend gamble winnings or unexpected bonuses differently from other money for

example. ‘Not all dollars are created equal’, as Belsky and Gilovich (2000) put it.

Suppose I am saving to buy a house and my savings are in a low interest account. I buy a

car and take out a loan at high interest to pay for the car although I could pay cash out of

my savings account. I might do this because I have separate mental accounts for housing

and car expenses. It is possible that people engage in this type of behaviour to counteract

self-control problems. They may fear that if they withdraw money from their ‘special’

savings account once, they may not be able to force themselves to pay it back into the

account (slippery slope) whereas a loan has to be paid back (Thaler, 1985).

Standard economic theory assumes that people make decisions based on current wealth,

probability distributions of future earnings, etc. but in reality transactions are evaluated

within a much narrower frame. Thaler (1999) suggests that, in their construction of

mental accounts, people engage in ‘hedonic editing’; they choose the set of accounts that

is most attractive to them. In terms of prospect theory’s value function, they choose to

evaluate transactions and corresponding gains and losses (x,y) according to

v(x & y) = Max (v(x+y), v(x) + v(y))

Thaler and Johnson (1990) show that subjects want to separate gain (intertemporally) but

they also want to separate losses, which is inconsistent with prospect theory.

Page 46: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

42

Mental accounting explains why, in contradiction to the life-cycle model, current income

flow is more important in budgeting decisions than present value of lifetime wealth.

Budgeting is done on a month-by-month basis and expenditures are grouped into

categories so that if the ‘entertainment budget’ has run out for example, consumers will

decide to postpone their next movie theatre visit but at the same time they may be willing

to spend money on books, as long as there is money left in the ‘book’ account. Kooreman

(1997) finds that spending on children’s clothing is much more sensitive to changes in

child allowance payments than to changes in other income.

Thaler (1990) provides further evidence of mental accounting. People tend to consume

some types of income or wealth and not others. Money in a current account gets spent but

special retirement accounts remain untouched. Summers et al (1987) show that the

marginal propensity to save for capital gains in the stock market is close to 1. But whilst

paper gains don’t get spent, cash generated in takeovers does increase consumption

(Hatsopoulos et al, 1989). Increases in housing wealth also don’t increase consumption

(Skinner, 1989) but perhaps this could be explained by people wanting to save more as

house prices increase to enable their children to buy a house. However, then we would

see increased saving by non-homeowners too when house prices rise and we don’t.

According to standard theory, savings in the form of pension wealth should reduce other

savings but Cagan (1965) found that the effect of pension saving on other saving is

actually positive. It is possible that there was a bias in this sample if people with a taste

for saving tend to work for employers who offer pension plans or a positive correlation

between pension saving and other saving could be found simply because those with a

taste for saving tend to save more in pensions and in other savings. However, Green

(1981) used a (UK) sample which was restricted to people who had to join an

occupational pension scheme as a condition of taking or remaining in a job with a

particular employer and also found a positive effect on other savings. Venti and Wise

(1987) show that IRA (Individual Retirement Account) contributors do not reduce their

other saving and most of them had not saved much before IRAs were introduced. Pension

wealth does not appear to be a close substitute for other wealth.

Page 47: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

43

In 401(k) plans, employees view company stock as a special asset class (or mental

account). When employer’s stock is not available in the plan, the typical investor

allocates 49% to bonds and 51% to cash but when it is included it attracts 42% and the

remaining 58% is divided equally between bonds and other stocks (Thaler, 1999).

Separate mental accounts are also kept for money already accumulated in the plan and

amounts of money not yet contributed (Benartzi & Thaler, 2007).

Investors also choose when to close a mental account and it appears they are very

reluctant to close an account which is in the red. Suppose you need to raise cash and are

going to sell one of two stocks, one stock has declined and the other has gone up. Which

do you sell? Most people sell the ‘winner’ although (for tax reasons) it is better to sell the

‘loser’. Trading volume for stocks which have declined in price is lower than trading

volume for stocks which have increased in price (Shefrin & Statman, 1985, 1987). In

Odean’s (1998) data set of investors’ trades the same pattern of selling winners and

holding on to losers appears and the stocks sold outperform the stocks bought.

8) Status quo bias

People generally don’t like changing strategies or behaviours. Three of the biases already

discussed may contribute to a preference for the status quo. Change typically involves a

current cost to reap higher benefits in the future, so hyperbolic discounting may result in

the investment never being made despite the returns covering costs many times over.

Loss aversion and regret aversion may also play a role in status quo bias. By sticking

with their existing option, people shield themselves from the regret arising when a new

choice leads to a worse outcome than the original choice. A status quo bias follows

because errors of commission generate more anticipated regret than errors of omission

and because the negative consequences of a change tend to be seen as more painful than

the pleasure associated with the possible positive consequences. This tendency to favour

the status quo was first formally identified by Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988). Their

Page 48: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

44

field evidence concerned the choices of Harvard employees over retirement savings and

health plans. They found that new employees chose significantly different plans from

those of the same age who were continuing. Only 3 percent of employees changed plans

in a year. Similarly, Benartzi and Thaler (2007) find that adjustments in the allocation of

‘old money’ i.e. money already accumulated in a 401(k) plan is rare and suggest that this

may be due to a fear of regret if the new allocation underperforms the old. For new

contributions to 401(k) plans there is no reference point and therefore less potential for

regret.

Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) conducted experiments in which financially

sophisticated subjects were asked to make (hypothetical) choices regarding the

investment of a recent inheritance. Some subjects were told they inherited an amount of

money and were asked which type of investment they would prefer; others were told they

inherited a portfolio of investments. The experiment revealed a significant status quo bias

with those inheriting the portfolio being unlikely to change its composition.

Another manifestation of the status quo bias is the endowment effect (Thaler, 1980). This

refers to the tendency of individuals to be willing to pay less for a good than the

minimum they are willing to accept for the same good once they own it (for a review see

Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1991).

The status quo bias is behind the tendency in financial decisions to follow the path of

least resistance (Choi et al. 2002). The most dramatic evidence is the finding, in a series

of papers by David Laibson and coworkers, that in financial choices defaults are more

influential than (all?) other interventions that have been studied (also a theme of Thaler

and Benartzi 2004). For example, even for important choices that will have major long-

run consequences, it may make a major difference whether subjects must opt in to a

savings scheme or opt out, even if a change from the default merely requires that a phone

call is made. Figure 2 shows participation in a 401(k) pension scheme by employees of a

US company according to whether the default is the employee is enrolled and must call to

cancel (orange) rather than unenrolled and must call to participate (green) (Madrian and

Page 49: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

45

Shea 2001, Choi, Laibson, Madrian, Metrick 2004). The difference is huge and narrows

very slowly. It is not easy to think that the real costs of taking such an important saving

action could account for the difference. As indicated in Section 2, educational seminars

do not have anything like a comparable effect. The reason why many people are so

resistant to change what they are dealt is a matter of speculation. To some extent, it may

be they think the default option is a genuine endorsement of what the company thinks is

the best choice. Or it could be that people find the issues boring and there is a

psychological block to making a start. Our section on procrastination shows how it is

possible people may constantly postpone an important decision when there is no

deadline. Whatever the reason, defaults appear to matter, and it seems by far most

effective and cheapest to set the appropriate default rather than educate consumers to

think through problems from scratch.

Figure 2

401(k) participation by tenure at firm

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

0 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48Tenure at company (months)

Frac

tion

of e

mpl

oyee

s ev

er p

artic

ipat

ed

Hired before automatic enrollment Hired during automatic enrollment Hired after automatic enrollment ended

Page 50: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

46

One way to remove the status quo bias is to require an active decision by some imposed

deadline. These can be surprisingly effective. Ariely and Wertenbroch (2002) conducted

a striking experiment. Though not in a financial context, as we shall see the message has

been translated to such a setting. In the experiment, students had to hand in three papers

for a course. There were three treatments. One class was told that the papers had to be

handed in at the end of term. There were would be a penalty of one mark deducted for

every day that a paper was late. A second treatment set equally spaced deadlines for the

three papers with the same penalty for deadline overdue. In the third class, the students

chose their own deadlines and registered them, but for the self-imposed deadlines the

penalty was still the same. The class with the imposed end-of-term deadline performed

worst, the best performing the class had the equally spaced deadlines, and the class with

401(k) participation by tenure

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

0 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54Tenure at company (months)

Frac

tion

of e

mpl

oyee

s ev

er

parti

cipa

ted

Active decision cohort Standard enrollment cohort

Page 51: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

47

Figure 4

the self-commitment opportunity had grades in the middle. People who set themselves

equally spaced deadlines did as well as students with such a schedule imposed and those

who set all the deadlines at the latest time possible did the same as students in which

those same deadlines were imposed. Some people know their tendency to procrastinate

and if there are self-commitment devices available, they will take advantage of them.

Others fall into a procrastination trap. There is clearly a case for the dictatorial policy in

the interest of the students.

Related ideas have been applied in the financial domain. Choi, Laibson, Madrian, and

Metrick (2007) look at the effects of setting deadlines for an active decision to be made.

Again the decision was participation in a 401(k) pension plan. The new employees given

the active decision scheme were presented with:

• Welcome to the company.

• You are required to submit this form within 30 days of hire, regardless of your

401(k) participation choice.

• If you don’t want to participate, indicate that decision.

• If you want to participate, indicate your contribution rate and asset allocation.

• Being passive is not an option.

The comparison with the regular, passive (no deadline) sign-up scheme is shown in

Figure 5. Just by forcing a decision to be made there is a big effect on behaviour.

Page 52: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

48

Figure 5

The active decision scheme raises the average saving rate by 50 per cent. It does not set a

default but simply requires that there is a choice. Under active decision, employees

choose saving rates that they otherwise would have taken three years to achieve.

In the absence of external forces designed to offset (or exploit) the status quo bias, it may

be helpful if individuals are taught to frame their financial decisions as “if I had to make

the initial choice now, what should I do?” rather than “how should I change from what I

am now doing?”

The status quo bias may also explain why people are often resistant to shopping around

for better deals once they have made their initial choice. As already mentioned, this

tendency not to switch is one that financial service providers often take advantage of by

raising insurance premiums or lowering interest rates after consumers sign up. Even if

this is noticed, people often do not react by cancelling.

401(k) participation by tenure

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

0 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54Tenure at company (months)

Frac

tion

of e

mpl

oyee

s ev

er

parti

cipa

ted

Active decision cohort Standard enrollment cohort

Page 53: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

49

9) The curse of knowledge

Financial education as traditionally conceived supposes that being better informed

improves decision. That does not always apply. One reason that more may not be better is

that attention is a scarce resource and processing power is limited. More information may

deflect attention from what is really important. A pervasive finding (e.g., Kruschke and

Johansen 1999) is that cue competition occurs: more salient cues weaken the effects of

less salient ones, and the presence of irrelevant cues causes subjects to make less use of

relevant cues and base rates (unconditional frequencies). Introducing additional accurate

information may therefore lead to worse outcomes. For example, Lacko and Pappalardo

(2004) show that a particular rewrite of mortgage disclosure information designed to

reveal broker compensation lead to more confusion over the total cost of a mortgage.

Bertrand et al (2005) find in a large-scale field experiment that many factors that are

inconsequential in terms of standard theory had large effects on the decision to take a

loan. For example, providing applicants with the opportunity to win a prize discouraged

loan demand. Less information about the variety of loans available increased take up.

Extra information appears to be distracting and leads to poor decisions.

Education may be counter-productive, not just due to information overload but because it

augments overconfidence in the sense of attaching too much precision to estimates.

People may falsely believe they know what they are doing and in the sense and attach

excessive precision to their beliefs.9 Acquiring a “mental model” may result in random

effects being downplayed and accumulating evidence interpreted through the distorting

lens of confirmatory bias (Griffen and Tversky (1992)). This is particularly the case when

event predictability is low. Then it is easy to ignore counter evidence and find excuses for

error other than the “model” is wrong. Weinstein and Klein (2002) show how difficult it

is to shake false beliefs concerning personal risk.

9 Willis (2008) reports that victims of financial fraud have above average financial literacy!

Page 54: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

50

A problem related to overconfidence is optimism or self serving bias. The tendency to

overestimate the probability of favourable events. As Adam Smith puts it:

“The chance of gain is by every man more or less overvalued, and the chance of loss is by most men under-valued, and scarce by any man, who is in tolerable health and spirits, valued more than it is worth” Adam Smith Wealth of Nations, Book i, Chapter X (p. 107)

Modern psychologists agree;

'... considerable research evidence suggests that overly positive self-evaluations, exaggerated perceptions of control or mastery, and unrealistic optimism are characteristics of normal human thought.' (Taylor and Brown, 1988, p. 193).

Optimism is especially prevalent when people think events are under their own control

(Langer (1975)), an impression that financial education may foster. It certainly applies in

the financial domain. For example a 2008 Natwest survey of 8,500 British teenagers

(http://www.natwestf2f.com/natwest/docs/NatWest_MoneySense_research.pdf) found that they expect

on average to be earning a salary of £31,000 at the age of 25. In contrast, 22 to 29-year-

olds earn on average £17,817 in the Great Britain today. Arabshabani et al. (2000)

compared income forecasts and realisations and found financial optimism applies much

more widely and is especially important for men.

Optimism gives rise to a host of problems relating to financial capability. Overestimating

future income and employment prospects leads to inadequate precautionary saving and

too little pension provision. People are too ready to borrow because they are too

optimistic about their ability to repay. They set up businesses without realistically

factoring in their chance of failure (de Meza and Southey, 1996). Some risks are

uninsured because the chance of loss is underestimated. In short, optimism is a prime

cause of financial incapability.

One ingredient of overconfidence is the law of small numbers; Kahneman and Tversky

(1971). People draw far too strong inferences from small amounts of data. For example,

the performance of unit trusts over the last three years is given far too much weight

relative to the level of management fees. A tendency to believe lessons from insufficient

data is augmented by the availability heuristic whereby people disproportionately weight

Page 55: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

51

salient, memorable or vivid evidence. People rely far too much on personal experience or

that of friends relative to aggregate data in judging risks and returns and evaluating

financial products.

This problem of wrongly evaluating evidence may be worsened by basic mistakes in

inference. The most notable is the base rate neglect bias (Kahneman, Tversky 1973). In

evaluating evidence, people tend to ignore the prior probability that a hypothesis is true.

A striking example is the “Linda” problem. People are told that Linda is 31 years old,

single, outspoken, and very bright. She majored in philosophy. As a student, she was

deeply concerned with issues of discrimination and social justice, and also participated in

anti-nuclear demonstrations. People are asked to rate the likelihood that the following

statements about Linda are true:

a) Linda is active in the feminist movement.

b) Linda is a bank teller.

c) Linda is a bank teller and is active in the feminist movement.

Many people rate (c) more likely than (a) or (b) though this is a logical impossibility.

Their predictions would be better if they knew less about Linda.

Kahneman and Tversky (1982) test whether general knowledge of statistics reduces or

eliminates observed biases with surprisingly negative results. The results by Fong,

Krantz, Nisbett (1986) are more encouraging.

Camerer, Loewenstein and Weber (1989) coined the term “curse of knowledge” to cover

a specific effect according to which better-informed agents are often incapable of

reproducing the judgments of less-informed agents. In their experiment, subjects were

rewarded according to their success in predicting what others would decide. Participants

had the opportunity to buy information that would help predict actual outcomes. Many

bought the information even though those that did so were worse at predicting how the

uninformed would decide. Had the information not been acquired, they would have been

better off, even gross of the purchase price. The problem is that people tend to imagine

everyone knows what they know. This bias may lead to mistakes in stock market

Page 56: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

52

investment. Beating the market involves finding companies that are undervalued. This

involves a theory of mind; appreciating that others may know more or less than you

know.

Even experts may react badly to more information. In a meta-analysis of 136 studies,

Grove and Meehl (1996) and Grove et al (2000) report that in activities such as predicting

individual health outcomes, college grades or criminal recidivism, experts do worse than

simple statistical methods. Moreover, the performance of experts deteriorates when, in

addition to written information being given, the professionals were able to interview the

subjects.

Recent empirical research indicates that professional investors are as prone to irrational,

psychologically motivated biases in their investment decisions (e.g. Glaser et al., 2005,

Haigh and List, 2005, Menkhoff et al., 2006) as amateurs. Professionalism may reduce

biases to some degree but it does not eliminate them entirely (Shapira and Venezia, 2001,

2006, Feng and Seasholes, 2005).

In finance as elsewhere, the overall picture is that “..research does not support the strong

versions of the experts-get-things-right and in the real- world-people-learn hypotheses.”

Rabin (1998)

10) Improving financial capability by debiasing?

Numerous studies from psychology and behavioural economics show that humans are

systematically prone to various kinds of cognitive biases. Biases lead to predictable but

suboptimal decisions. We provide a taxonomy of biases which are likely to be relevant

for financial decision making in the Appendix. Almost all biases originate from the

human tendency to use rules of thumb or heuristics which considerably simplify the

decision process. Heuristics have probably evolved because when dealing with complex

problems they often lead to good decisions – unfortunately, this is not always the case.

Page 57: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

53

The three most prominent heuristics are the availability heuristic, the representativeness

heuristic, and the affect heuristic (Bazerman 2006). The first denotes the observation that

people assess the frequency, probability, or likely causes of an event by the degree to

which instances or occurrences of that event are readily “available” in memory (Tversky

and Kahneman 1973). According to the representativeness heuristic, people look for

characteristics of an individual, an object, or a situation that correspond with previously

formed stereotypes. Judgments that are evoked by genuine subjective feelings and moods

(for example, sadness or disgust) are influenced by the affect heuristic (Cohen, Pham,

Andrade 2008). Some researchers also consider the affect heuristic at work if

subconscious emotional evaluations (Slovic, Finucane, Peters, and Mc Gregor 2002) are

used as the basis of decisions although they occur even before cognitive reasoning takes

place (Kahneman 2003).

Although new biases in judgment and decision making in general are being discovered all

the time, there are relatively few studies that investigate these biases with a specific focus

on financial decision making. Examining these biases in such a context is highly

desirable because the few existing studies yield surprising insights. Kahneman and

Thaler, for example, asked wealthy investors to bring to mind the financial decision they

regretted the most. In line with the omission bias, most investors reported that their worst

regret was about some action they had taken. Interestingly, those individuals who

remembered a regret of omission held an unusually high proportion of their portfolio in

stocks. Kahneman and Riepe (1998) conclude from this that investors who regret the

opportunities they missed tend to take more risk than people who regret actions that

failed. In accordance with the scale bias, Christensen (1989) finds that the more is spent

on a primary purchase the more willing people are to buy additional smaller items.

Apparently, small extra purchases are perceived as minor expenditures when they follow

larger purchases. This might be one of the reasons why mortgage protection insurance

with its seemingly minor fees (compared to the mortgage) are so successfully sold as

secondary products by lenders.

Page 58: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

54

There is even less research on how financial decision makers can be made less vulnerable

to relevant biases. Overviews of generally investigated debiasing approaches can be

found, for example, in Fischhoff (1982), Arkes (1991), Larrick (2004). In the following

we briefly discuss the more prominent of those debiasing techniques which can be

applied by the individual decision maker rather than by institutional design such as

appropriate defaults. We focus on the following approaches: (i) consider-the-opposite, (ii)

accountability, (iii) training in rules, (iv) training in representations, (v) voluntary

cooling-off-periods, and (vi) group decisions. With these techniques in mind one might

hope to be able to tailor and test more effective advice schemes for people who are in the

process of taking decisions on financial matters. As an organising principle we use the

five different aspects of financial capability as identified in the FSA Baseline Survey.

Although it can be argued that some of the debiasing techniques are relevant for several

capabilities, we discuss each technique under the capability for which we consider it most

relevant.

So far little is known on whether mere knowledge about biases reduces their impact.

Thus, it is not immediately clear whether enhancing the awareness of biases really

reduces their consequences. For some biases the answer seems to be negative. For

example, teaching people the existence of the hindsight bias does not make them much

less vulnerable to it (Wood 1978, Fischhoff 1982, Quattrone et al. 1984). More research

is needed regarding the effect of teaching the existence of cognitive biases. One way to

do this might be to let people gain their own experiences with relevant biases. Learning

by doing, with feedback, has the advantage that people are more likely to remember the

consequences of these traps and how difficult it is to avoid them. Such a learning

environment could be implemented by well designed, interactive and incentivised

(online) simulations.

Page 59: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

55

10.1 Managing money / making ends meet

Despite the importance of budgeting for consumers, our knowledge about the budgeting

process is limited. Thaler and Johnson (1990) report evidence that budgeting is highly

dependent on prior outcomes. Prior gains, for example, can induce people to increase

budgets for gambles. They called this tendency the “house money effect”. In contrast,

prior losses can decrease willingness to take risks and outcomes which offer the

opportunity to break even become especially attractive. In a recent study Ülkümen,

Thomas, and Morwitz (2008) analyse how different temporal frames can lead to different

budgeting. They find that estimated budgets for the next year are closer to recorded

expenses than monthly budgets because consumers feel less confident when estimating

the former and therefore adjust them upward. Their interpretation is that the budget-

estimation process entails an anchoring and adjustment mechanism in which initial

estimates are too low, and the amount of upward adjustment depends on the degree of

confidence and the availability of cognitive resources. Consumers’ beliefs about the

accuracy of easily generated budget estimates make them more confident in a next month

frame. Changing these beliefs by informing consumers that feelings of ease do not signal

accuracy leads to a significant increase in the amount of adjustment for next month

budgets. They find that participants persistently underestimate their expenditures for the

next month even when the budget estimates were elicited only seconds after participants

reported their earlier period’s actual expenditures. This observation is consistent with the

finding that people fail to incorporate past experiences into their predictions (Buehler et

al. 1994, Jacoby et al. 1984).

Accountability involves decision makers imagining or really having to explain their

decision to somebody else. It has been shown that such an expectation leads people to

anticipate and take into account potential criticism by employing a kind of pre-emptive

self-criticism. People who think about a decision in the expectation of being held

accountable tend to exert more effort. They spend longer on the task and collect more

information before taking a decision. It is important to guarantee that the decision maker

believes that the person to whom he is held accountable has no preference regarding the

Page 60: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

56

decision outcome. If this is not guaranteed, social issues, such as wanting to please the

other, come into play which might bias the search for information. A potential drawback

of holding people accountable comes from the fact that decisions are perceived as more

difficult if accountability is higher (Lerner, Tetlock 1999, Zhang, Mittal 2005).

The recency bias refers to the tendency to overweight information received later in a

sequence. This clearly has the potential to distort financial decisions, for example, by

generating urgent desires for products one has been informed about recently. It has been

shown that accountability reduces the tendency for recency of information in auditing

tasks. (Kennedy 1993). Accountability also reduces the tendency for recency of

information to influence judgments when predicting a candidate’s success at a job based

on sequential information (Kruglanski, Freund 1983). This remains true if subjects

experience mental fatigue (Webster, Richter, Kruglanski, 1996).

Page 61: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

57

10.2 Keeping track of finances

People often behave as if their money resides in different compartments, so called

“mental accounts” (Thaler 1991). This leads to the illusion that money is not as

“fungible” as it actually is. Mental accounting is helpful in overcoming people’s

impulsiveness or their tendency to neglect the long term. They reserve some money for

retirement, some for food, some for fuel, etc. Thus, mental accounting is an important

means for financial self-control by way of pre-commitment (Thaler, Shefrin 1981, Heath,

Soll 1996). Consumers also use mental accounting to justify purchases by setting up an

account for a transaction, debit the expense, and credit the benefit accrued from

consumption (Prelec, Loewenstein 1998). However, mental accounting may lead to

inconsistent financial decisions. For example, one may borrow at high interest to buy a

consumer item whilst simultaneously saving at lower interest rates for a child’s college

fund.

Another aspect of mental accounting relates to observations that people vary in their

attitudes to risk between their mental accounts. Although in general mental accounts

support self-control, sometimes they can also be used to justify additional spending by

“creative bookkeeping” (Cheema and Soman, 2007). Consumers have flexibility (a) in

classifying ambiguous expenses (and, therefore, in assigning them to different mental

accounts) and (b) in constructing mental accounts to accommodate unclassified expenses.

Soman and Gourville (2001) show that in situations of price bundling (let’s say, for

example, mortgage bundles consisting of the mortgage and a mortgage protection

insurance), the individual typically has flexibility in assigning portions of the total cost to

each of the separate benefits. Soman and Cheema (2001) show that unbudgeted windfalls

introduce flexibility into mental accounts, allowing consumers to allocate the gain to a

mental account at their discretion and helping them write off sunk costs.

Kivetz (1999) finds that the principles of mental accounting often regulate the purchase

and consumption of luxuries. In particular, buying and consuming luxury goods tends to

call for justification and can evoke intra-personal conflict that might be resolved with the

Page 62: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

58

aid of mental accounting. For example, there is evidence that people prefer to pay for

luxurious consumption with “windfall gains” (Thaler 1985).

The “disposition bias” is closely related to mental accounting and loss aversion. It

denotes the tendency of sellers of an object to treat its original purchase price as a

reference point for the selling price. According to Weber andWelfens (2006), learning

seems to attenuate the magnitude of the disposition effect. Frequent traders sell their

winners less and their losers more often, resulting in lower disposition effects.

10.3 Planning

A remedy for various cognitive biases is to encourage decision makers to ask themselves:

“What are the reasons that my judgement might be wrong?” The basic mechanism is to

counteract the problem of overly narrow sampling of evidence which mainly results from

the availability heuristic (Tversky and Kahneman 1973, Lord, Lepper, Preston 1984).

Expanding the sample makes it more representative. Interestingly, a similar procedure of

simply listing more reasons for or against making a particular decision is not effective!

Why is this? Again due to the availability heuristic, decision makers tend to generate

reasons which support their view since these reasons come to mind more readily. The

“consider-the-opposite” remedy turns out to be effective in reducing the severity of a

number of biases, for example, anchoring and overconfidence, but is not very effective

with respect to the hindsight bias.

Hoch (1985) investigated the influence of counterfactual reasoning on accuracy when

predicting the outcomes of future personal events – a setting which is quite relevant when

planning ahead and thinking about the right amount of savings or insurance. Graduate

business students made predictions about the results of their job search efforts nine month

in advance (e.g. starting salary). Some subjects were asked to generate pro and/or con

reasons concerning event occurrence before making their predictions. Generating con

Page 63: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

59

reasons increased their predictive accuracy while generating pro reasons had no effect –

the latter suggesting that subjects may have automatically generated supportive reasons.

Hindsight bias involves the error of assuming that what you now know you always knew.

Investors may as a result overweight past success and failure in judging competence of

fund managers, companies and indeed their own skills. People fail to remember how

ignorant they were in the past. This can have serious negative consequences for learning

in financial environments and compromises planning ahead. Biais and Weber (2007)

provide evidence that investment bankers who score highly on hindsight bias have lower

performance. Sanna, Schwarz, Stocker (2002) and Sanna, Schwarz (2003) find that to

force oneself to argue against the inevitability of a reported outcome, that is, to try to

convince oneself that it might have turned out otherwise, might in fact increase the

hindsight bias. Ironically, the strategy may be less effective the more one tries to

convince oneself that it might have turned out otherwise realising along the way that

reasons for an alternate outcome are difficult to bring to mind.

How difficult it is for humans to plan ahead becomes evident from the findings on the

“planning fallacy” which denotes the tendency to underestimate task-completion times

(Buehler, Griffin, Ross 1994, 1995, 2002, Newby-Clark et al. 2000). Buehler et al. (1995)

ask students for times by which they are 50% sure, 75% sure, and 99% sure to finish an

academic project. Only 13% of the participants finished their project by the time assigned

a 50% probability level, only 19% finished by the time assigned a 75% probability, and

45% finished by the time of their 99% probability level. Buehler et. al. (2002) write: "The

results for the 99% probability level are especially striking: even when asked to make a

highly conservative forecast, a prediction that they felt virtually certain that they would

fulfil, students' confidence in their time estimates far exceeded their accomplishments."

Newby-Clark et al. (2000) find that asking subjects for their predictions based on realistic

"best guess" scenarios, and asking subjects for their hoped-for "best case" scenarios,

produces indistinguishable results. When asked for their "most probable" case, people

tend to envision everything going exactly as planned, with no unexpected delays or

unforeseen catastrophes, i.e. the same vision as their "best case". The debiasing

Page 64: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

60

manipulation that has worked best so far is what Buehler et. al. (2002) call the “recall-

relevance” manipulation. Within this manipulation people are asked to describe a

plausible scenario, based on their past experience, that would result in their completing

an assignment at their typical time (Buehler, Griffin, Ross 1994). This manipulation

avoids the “internal approach” to prediction which involves sketching out a scenario that

captures how a future project is likely to unfold. This is, by and large, what planning

means to most people: develop a series of steps that lead from the beginning to a

successful conclusion of the project. Completion estimates for such exclusively plan-

based, future scenarios, however, are likely to be overly optimistic. In contrast the

“recall-relevance” manipulation takes an outside view by referring to experience with

broadly similar projects.

Kahneman and Lovallo (1993) distinguish between two modes of forecasting: the inside

view focuses on the specifics of the case at hand, whereas the outside view focuses on the

statistics of a family of cases similar to the case at hand. The former approach results in

exceedingly optimistic forecasts, and the latter approach results in more accurate

forecasts.

Taking decisions as a group is sometimes a successful debiasing technique because (i)

groups can be an error-checking system, (ii) synergies can emerge if group members have

complementary expertise, (iii) groups can increase the effective sample size of

knowledge. For example, it has been shown that simply averaging forecasts tends to

reduce errors. However, one also has to be careful when taking a decision as a group

because social influence can undermine the effectiveness of the group. In a group, people

often intentionally withhold or misrepresent their private information or they are

unknowingly influenced by the public judgement of other group members.

The aim to make appropriate financial decisions for the future is also likely to be

influenced by unrealistic optimism, i.e., people’s consistent tendency to claim that they

are less likely than their peers to suffer harm (Weinstein 1980). Informing people about

relevant health risk factors in general and requiring them to describe their standing on

Page 65: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

61

these factors had no overall effect on subsequent risk judgement (Weinstein, Klein 2002).

However, if individuals are exposed to lists made by other individuals of factors

improving the other individuals’ chances of positive outcomes reduces unrealistic

optimism (Weinstein 1980). Also offering people information about their own individual

standing on risk factors or information about peers’ standing on these factors has been

shown to decrease optimism Weinstein (1983). Exposing people to a concrete instance of

the occurrence has also been proven to successfully offset optimism. Thus, for instance, a

recent series of studies of smoking behaviour finds that smokers are more likely to

believe that smoking will harm their health if they are aware of specific instances of such

harm (Sloan, Taylor, Smith 2003). The latter is in line with the finding that people

generally tend to respond to concrete, narrative information even when they do not

respond, or respond far less, to general statistical information (Nisbett et al. 1982).

10.4 Making informed decisions about financial products

Our survey of the literature on information overload shows that it is questionable whether

people make better decisions when they have more or better information. Dhar (1997)

finds that the tendency to defer choice is greater when the difference in attractiveness

among the available alternatives is small than when it is large. The percentage of people

who defer choice among comparable alternatives tends to decrease when people first

learn to make trade-offs among the different features. As discussed earlier, increased

introspection can cause subjects to make choices that, compared with control subjects,

correspond less with expert opinions. (Wilson, Schooler 1991).

To be able to make informed decisions about financial products people have to be

familiar with basic mathematical and statistical reasoning. So, is it possible to improve

financial decision making by teaching rules of mathematical and statistical reasoning?

Ideally the rules should be learned in such a way that the trained person can apply them

in a wide range of events. Nisbett et al. (1987) consider two approaches: (i) formal

training in abstract rules in the hope that people can transfer the abstract knowledge to

Page 66: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

62

specific decision domains; (ii) learning the rule in a specific domain in the hope that

people can generalise the knowledge to other domains.

Abstract rule training improved statistical reasoning in:

• Manifestly probabilistic problems

Objectively measurable events such as those involving achievements of some kind

(e.g. performance estimates of graduates from a certain school from a few particular

graduates’ performance)

• Subjective judgments such as those assessing someone‘s sense of humour or kindness

(e.g. subjects should realise that a first impression of a person might not be a good

indication of that individual’s personality)

Training by examples did enable routines to be transferred to very different domains.

The “sunk cost” or “escalation fallacy” denotes the tendency of people not to consider

past actions as “sunk”. They often feel drawn to persue and escalate a previous

unsatisfactory course of action. This may lead to throwing “good money after bad”. In a

study by Larrick, Morgan and Nisbett (1990) students were successfully trained to ignore

sunk costs in financial domains. They were also successful in generalising the rule to

time allocation decisions (i.e., to ignore that they have spent a lot of time on a project in

the past if it does not look promising in the future). They were also able to generalise the

sunk cost rule to financial matters if it was taught in the time domain. In addition, they

could correctly distinguish between sunk cost problems and problems for which the

normative principle implies opposite actions (discontinuing versus continuing

investments, respectively).

There is evidence that people reason more accurately about frequencies than about

probabilities (see Gigerenzer and Hoffrage 1995). At least two possible strategies emerge

from this insight which have been shown successful: (i) regulation to exemplify decision

alternatives by frequencies rather than probabilities; (ii) training people to translate

probabilistic reasoning tasks into frequency formats.

Page 67: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

63

Anchoring refers to the tendency for numerical estimates to be influenced by a previously

considered (and potentially exogenously provided) standard of comparison. It does not

require much imagination to see that this type of bias can easily be exploited, for example

by insurance sellers. The anchoring effect is quite robust and has been shown in many

experiments. For example, Ariely, Loewenstein, and Prelec (2003) showed six products

to subjects and briefly described them without mentioning a market price. Subjects were

asked whether they would buy each good for a dollar figure equal to the last two digits of

their social security number (SS#). This was a simple accept/reject decision. Afterwards,

subjects were asked to state their dollar maximum willingness-to-pay (WTP) for each

product (via an incentive compatible procedure). A random device determined whether

the product would in fact be sold on the basis of the first accept/reject response or the

second WTP response. Subjects understood that both responses had some chance of

being decisive for a potential purchase.

The table above shows that the SS# had a significant impact on WTP, i.e., subjects with

above-median SS# stated values from 57 percent to 107 percent higher than did subjects

with below median numbers. WTPs of top SS# quintile subjects were typically higher by

a factor of three!

Wansink, Kent, and Hoch (1998) provide empirical support for the anchoring effect in an

illustrative field experiment. Imagine you are walking down the supermarket aisle and

Page 68: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

64

you encounter a stack of cans of canned tomato soup, and a sign saying “Limit 12 per

customer.” Their data show that this sign actually causes people to buy more cans of

tomato soup since customers anchor at 12.

To demonstrate the effect of anchoring, Russo and Schoemaker (1989) performed the

following experiment. First, they asked professionals: “What is your best estimate of the

prime interest rate six months from now?” The average guess was 10.9 percent (at that

time the actual prime was around 11 percent). Then they surveyed a second group with

the following two questions: 1. “Do you believe that six months from now the prime rate

will be above or below 8 percent?” and 2. “What is your best estimate of the prime rate

six months from now?” The first question was intended to anchor subjects on 8 percent.

The average guess was now 10.5 (40 basis points below the unanchored group). When

they anchored a third group at 14 percent by an analogous first question the average was

11.2. One can imagine how powerful this subtle manipulation can be if it is used

strategically, i.e. mentioning a statistic to encourage the listener to anchor on it. Consider,

for example, negotiations with a banker or an insurance seller who argues “Generally we

charge customers like you x for this product’.

Mussweiler, Strack and Pfeiffer (2000) designed an experiment to test for the effect of

the “consider-the-opposite” debiasing technique for anchoring. In a car-selling-scenario

subjects were asked to estimate the value of a 10-year-old car. They were given all

relevant information (mileage, year, etc.) and they had the car right in front of them. Four

treatment conditions were employed along two dimensions: (i) anchoring by

experimenter: “I thought that the car should sell for about 2,800 / 5,000 Marks.” (ii) half

the participant were encouraged to “consider the opposite”, i.e., to reason why the anchor

might be inappropriate (“A friend of mine mentioned yesterday that he thought this value

is too high/low”). As expected, it turned out that the high anchor led to higher estimates

for the value of the car than the low anchor. The anchoring, however, was weaker when

participants were instructed to generate anchor-inconsistent arguments.

Page 69: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

65

Overconfidence involves people giving subjective range estimates which are typically too

narrow. Such overconfidence in judgement is quite relevant in financial decision making,

for example in judging whether to hedge investment risk. Soll and Klayman (2004) asked

subjects to answer knowledge questions, for example, “In what year was the first flight of

a hot air balloon?” Ranges for which people are 80 percent confident captured the truth

only 30 percent to 40 percent of the time. They also induced other subjects to “consider-

the-opposite” by asking them to estimate 10th and 90th percentiles in two separate

stages. This increased hit rates to nearly 60 percent by both widening and centering

ranges.

Numerous studies have found that people in good moods make unrealistically optimistic

judgments and choices and that people in bad moods make unrealistically pessimistic

judgments and choices (see Loewenstein et al. 2001, for an overview). Loewenstein

(2000) suggest that “it is probably not an overstatement to say that visceral factors [like

negative emotions, (e.g., anger, fear), drive states (e.g., hunger, thirst, sexual desire), and

feeling states (e.g., pain)] are more basic to daily functioning than the higher level

cognitive processes that are often assumed to underlie decision-making” (p. 427). There

is evidence that people in “hot” states tend to overestimate how long those states will last

(“projection bias”, Loewenstein, O’Donoghue, Rabin 2003). Additionally, it has been

shown that “visceral factors […] are powerfully influenced by temporal proximity”

(Loewenstein 1996, p. 279) indicating that voluntary cooling-off-periods promise to be

quite effective for debiasing.

Zajonc (1980) argues for greater speed and automaticity of affective over cognitive

reactions and showed that people can have an affective reaction to a stimulus before they

know what it is they are reacting to. For example, sudden, unexpected noises can cause

fear well before we determine the source of the noise. Thus, it may well be that "I

decided in favor of X" is no more than "I liked X". Bechara et al. (1997) also find support

for the hypothesis that non-conscious biases guide behaviour before conscious knowledge

does.

Page 70: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

66

Affect in particular influences decisions about whether to purchase insurance. Hsee and

Kunreuther (2000) find that people are willing to pay twice as much to insure a beloved

antique clock against loss in shipment than to insure a similar clock for which “one does

not have any special feeling.” In the event of loss, the insurance paid $100 in both cases.

Judgments about risk may also be the result of subconscious evaluations. People may

have a positive ‘image’ of a market sector and perhaps associate ‘pharmaceuticals’ with

‘healing’, ‘beauty products’, ‘cleanliness’, etc. MacGregor et al. (2000) tested this

hypothesis by asking business students to write the first three images that came to mind

for 40 industry groupings, and then to rate how positive these evaluations were. They

were then asked to say how well these sectors had done in 1994 and how well they would

do in 1995, and indicate their own willingness to buy shares in these sectors. Their

judgements of how well these industry groupings had done in 1994 and would do in

1995, and their willingness to buy were predictable on the basis of how positive their

images were of these sectors. These judgements of sector performance, as well as

willingness to assume risk by buying shares in these sectors, were only weakly related to

indicators of actual performance. Based on subconscious retrieval of positive (or

negative) associations, people may ‘feel good’ (or ‘bad’) about an industry sector and

therefore predict successful (or unsuccessful) performance in that sector.

Choosing the right financial product might also be significantly hindered by the

conjunction error due to which probability is often over-estimated in compound

conjunctive problems. This is nicely demonstrated in Johnson et al. (1993). MBA

students at Wharton are scheduled to travel to Bangkok as part of their degree program.

Several groups of students with similar social and demographical background are asked

how much they are willing to pay for terrorism insurance. One group of subjects is asked

how much they are willing to pay for terrorism insurance covering the flight from

Thailand to the US. A second group of subjects is asked how much they are willing to

pay for terrorism insurance covering the round-trip flight. A third group is asked how

much they are willing to pay for terrorism insurance that covers the complete trip to

Thailand. These three groups respond with average willingness to pay of $17.19, $13.90,

Page 71: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

67

and $7.44 respectively. According to probability theory, adding additional detail onto a

story must render the story less probable Thus, covering the whole trip should be worth at

least as much as covering just part of the trip. However, since the flights from Thailand to

the US or the other way are more representative for a situation prone to a terrorist attack

and therefore make the attack appear more probable, students value these insurance

policies higher. According to Simonson and Nye (1992) accountability is an appropriate

remedy for conjunction error.

10.5 Staying up to date about financial matters

There are three biases that together are likely to inhibit the motivation of people to stay

up to date about financial matters: the confirmation bias, the belief bias, and the

completeness bias. The confirmation bias (also called myside bias) denotes the tendency

to evaluate evidence, generate evidence, and test hypotheses in a manner biased toward

one's own previously held opinions. The belief bias refers to people’s difficulties to

evaluate conclusions that conflict with what one thinks one knows about the world.

According to the completeness bias people tend to stop searching too early if they have

generated one hypothesis to answer an open question. All three biases are forcefully

documented by Wason (1960) in his classic “2-4-6” task experiment. Subjects are asked

to discover a rule, known to the experimenter but not to the subject. Initially subjects are

given the triplet 2-4-6, and told that this triplet fits the rule. Subjects are then asked to

generate own triplets that fit the rule. After coming up with a new triplet the experimenter

gives feedback whether the triplet fits the rule or does not fit the rule. Subjects can

continue testing triplets until they feel sure they know the experimenter's rule, at which

point the subject is asked to announce the rule. While the actual rule is simply “any

ascending sequence”, subjects seem to have a great deal of difficulty in deducing it, often

announcing rules that are far more complex than the correct rule. Subjects seemed to test

only “positive” examples triples that they believe will conform to their rule and confirm

their hypothesis. What they do rarely do is attempt to challenge or falsify their

hypotheses by testing triples that they believe will not conform to their rule. The

Page 72: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

68

experiment also shows that subjects stop far too early once they think they have found the

answer to a problem.

Huber and Seiser (2001) report that in a judgmental task two types of justification

pressure, i.e., the requirement to explain the decision afterwards and the requirement to

convince another person, lead to a distinct increase in the amount of utilised information.

There is also evidence that counterfactual primes – i.e., providing examples that make

subjects aware of both an actual outcome (e.g. getting into an accident; winning a lottery)

and the converse counterfactual outcome (e.g. avoiding the accident; losing the lottery) –

attenuates the confirmation bias in a trait hypothesis testing context. The number of

questions designed to elicit hypothesis-disconfirming answers are increased by such

priming (Galinsky, Moskowitz 2000). Evans et al. (1994) show that teaching in principles

of reasoning (by elaborated verbal instructions) seem to reduce the belief bias in

syllogistic reasoning, but cannot eliminate it. Evans and Curtis-Holmes (2005) show that

the necessity of rapid responding increases the amount of belief bias observed on a

syllogistic reasoning task and it reduces the number of logically correct decisions. Thus,

it is not unlikely that the three biases which make it particularly difficult to stay up to

date with financial matters are amplified by time pressure, information overload,

cognitive busyness, increased introspection, etc.

11) Conclusion

Behavioural economics has identified a host of systematic biases many of which are

evident in the personal finance decisions that many people take. Most people do not act

as fully rational individuals who choose in their self interest. Inertia, complexity, status

quo bias, self-control and hyperbolic discounting are amongst the factors that sway

financial decisions. Rational calculation is a useful benchmark but is not descriptively

accurate. Not surprisingly, the deep-seated psychological traits also at work seem fairly

resistant to conventional information-based financial education and advice. The question

arises what can be done? Most straightforward is to learn about the biases, introduce

Page 73: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

69

regulations that recognize their presence and offset their effects in the least intrusive

fashion possible.

What is largely unexplored territory is whether techniques can be learned that can

effectively neutralise bias itself. A few possibilities have been discussed in this survey.

What should be taught may not be explicit financial capability but thinking skills.

Our skepticism with regard to financial literacy education is shared by Willis (2008a,b).

This leads her to make two interesting policy proposals. The first is norm manipulation.

The idea is that some suitable financial rules of thumb would be inculcated as widely as

possible. Perhaps a norm of scepticism regarding the claims of sellers of financial

products would also be promulgated. The emphasis would not so much be on the reason

behind the advice, but on the delivery of easily digestible slogans that may influence

behaviour at key moments. Examples in other contexts are “don’t drink and drive” and

“safe sex” campaigns. “Save 10%” may be a harder sell. There are fewer vivid images to

exploit though the consequences of high debt could perhaps be effectively dramatised.

Saving norms do appear to differ internationally. It is a challenge to work out how such

norms could be altered. Critics would accuse the state of indoctrination, but further

consideration seems warranted.

The second of Willis proposals is face to face crisis counselling. There is some evidence

from counselling studies that such personalised advice works. Basically, the individual

knows they are in trouble and get specific advice what to do and perhaps help with filling

in forms. This is analogous to curative medicine whereas financial literacy education is

like preventative medicine. Counselling is rather likely to deliver immediate benefits but

it is not clear there are long-term effects in helping people avoid getting into such

situations.

At this point more research should be undertaken on the determinants of financial

decisions in the UK. There is scope for further statistical analysis of the FSA survey and

use of the British Household Panel Study. This would be relatively easy to accomplish.

Page 74: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

70

The problem is that neither survey contains the kind of psychological variables that are

emphasised by behavioural economics. So there is a need to collect more data. Secondly,

there is little convincing evidence on what “therapies”, if any, are effective. Both to

collect more information and to test the effectiveness of different methods of improving

financial competency, we recommend that a large scale online survey and experiment is

conducted. This would involve randomised treatments involving a conventional financial

learning module, an active learning module based on behavioural principles, and a

control group. In addition to an immediate test of the effects of the treatments, the

subjects would be revisited after a year or two to retest and collect data on loan default,

payday borrowing and credit card use over the interval. Working with a bank or subprime

lender may be an even better alternative than online implementation.

A first step in debiasing may be for people to recognise their biases. Doing so will require

that a bias against recognising one’s own biases is overcome. Seeing whether this

approach is feasible and effective seems well worthwhile.

Page 75: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

71

ReferencesAinslie, George W. (1992) Picoeconomics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Ainslie, George W. (2001) Breakdown of will. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Ajzen, Icek (1977) Intuitive theories of events and effects of base-rate information on prediction. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 35(5), 300-314.Amir, On; Ariely, Dan; Cooke, Alan; Dunning, David; Epley, Nicholas; Gneezy, Uri; Koszegi, Boton; Lichtenstein, Donald; Mazar, Nina; Mullainathan, Sendhil; Prelec, Drazen; Shafir, Eldar; Silva, Jose (2005) Psychology, behavioral economics, and public policy. Marketing Letters 16(3/4), 443–454.

Americs, John; Caplin, Andrew; Leahy, John (2003) Wealth accumulation and the propensity to plan. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(3), 1007-1047.

Anderson, Craigh A.; Sechler, Elizabeth S. (1986) Effects of explanation and counterexplanation on the development and use of social theories. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 50(1), 24-34.

Anderson, Christopher J. (2003) The psychology of doing nothing: Forms of decision avoidance result from reason and emotion. Psychological Bulletin 129(1), 139-166.

Andreou, Chrisoula (2007) Understanding procrastination. Journal for the theory of social behaviour 37(2), 183-93.

Arabsheibani, Gholamreza; de Meza, David; Maloney, John; Pearson, Bernard (2000) And a vision appeared unto them of a great profit: Evidence of self-deception among the self-employed. Economic Letters 67(1), 35-41.

Ariely, Dan; Loewenstein, George; Prelec, Drazen (2003) “Coherent arbitrariness”: Stable demand curves without stable preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics118(1), 73-105.

Arkes, Hal R. (1991) Costs and benefits of judgment errors: Implications for debiasing. Psychological Bulletin 110(3), 486-498.

Arkes, Hal R.; Blumer, Catherine (1985) The psychology of sunk cost. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 35, 124-140.

Arkes, Hal R.; Dawes, Robyn M.; Christensen, Caryn (1986) Factors influencing the use of a decision rule in a probabilistic task. Organisational Behaviour and Human Decision Processes 37, 93-110.

Arkes, Hal R.; Christensen, Caryn; Lai, Cheryl; Blumer, Catherine (1987) Two methods of reducing overconfidence. Organisational Behaviour and Human Decision Processes39, 133-144.

Arkes, Hal R.; Hutzel, Laura (2000) The role of probability of success estimates in the sunk cost effect. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 13, 295-306.

Armor, David. A.; Taylor, Shelley E. (2002) When predictions fail: The dilemma of unrealistic optimism. In: T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, D. Kahneman (eds), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgement. Cambridge University Press, New York.

Page 76: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

72

Arnott, David (2002) A taxonomy of decision biases (Technical Report. No. 2002/01). Decision Support Systems Laboratory. Monash University, Melbourne, Australia. URL: www.sims.monash.edu.au/staff/darnott/biastax.pdfAshraf, Nava; Karlan, Dean S.; Yin, Wesley (2006) Tying Odysseus to the mast: Evidence from commitment savings product in the Philippines. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2), 635-672.

Ashton, Robert H.; Kennedy, Jane (2002) Eliminating recency with self-review: The case of auditor’s “Going concern” judgement. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 15(3), 221-231.

Bannister, Paul (2004) 25 Fascinating facts about personal debt. www.bankrate.com, (http://www.bankrate.com/brm/news/debt/debtguide2004/debt-trivia1.asp).

Bar-Gil, Oren. (2004) Seduction by plastic. Northwestern University Law Review 98(4), 1373- 1434.Bar-Hillel, Maya (1973) On the subjective probability of compound events. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 9, 396-406.

Bar-Hillel, Maya (1980) The base-rate fallacy in probability judgments. Acta Psychologica 44, 211-233.

Bar-Hillel, Maya; Wagenaar, Wileem A. (1991) Perceptions of randomness. Advances of Applied Mathematics 12(11), 428-454.

Bar-Hillel, Maya; Neter, Efrat (1993) How alike is it versus how likely is it: A disjunction fallacy in probability judgments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 65(6), 1119-1131.

Bar-Hillel, Maya; Budescu, David V. (1995) The elusive wishful thinking effect. Thinking and Reasoning 1(1), 71-103.

Bar-Hillel, Maya; Neter, Efrat (1996) Why are people reluctant to exchange lottery tickets? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 70, 17-27.

Baron, Jonathon; Ritov, Ilan (1994) Reference points and omission bias. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 59, 475–498.

Barnett, William P.; Pontikes, Elizabeth G. (2008) The red queen, success bias, and organizational inertia, forthcoming: Management Science.

Bazerman, Max (2006) Judgement in managerial decision making. 6th edition, John Wiley.

Bechara, Antoine; Damasio, Hanna; Tranel, Daniel; Damasio, Antonio, R. (1997) Deciding advantageously before knowing the advantageous strategy. Science 275, 1293-1295.

Bell, David E. (1982) Regret in decision making under uncertainty. Operations Research30(5), 961-981.Belsky, Gary; Gilovich, Thomas (2000) Why smart people make big money mistakes and how to correct them. Lessons from the new science of behavioral economics. Simon & Schuster.

Page 77: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

73

Bentz, Bret G.; Williamson, Donald A.; Franks, Susan F. (2004) Debiasing of pessimistic judgments associated with anxiety. Journal of Psychopathology and Behavioral Assessment 26(3), 173-180.Benartzi, Shlomo; Thaler, Richard H. (1999) Risk aversion or myopia? Choices in repeated gambles and retirement investments. Management Science 45(3), 364-81.

Benartzi, Shlomo; Thaler, Richard H. (2007) Heuristics and biases in retirement savings behavior. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21(3), 81-104.

Benton, M S. Meir and Charles Sprenger (2007) Overborrowing and undersaving: Lessons and policy implications from research in behavioral economics Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, DP 07-4

Bernheim, B. Douglas; Garrett, Daniel M.; Maki, Dean M (2001) Education and saving: The long-term effects of high school financial curriculum mandates. Journal of Public Economics, 80(3), 435-465.Bernheim, B. Douglas; Garrett, Daniel M. (2003) The effects of financial education in the workplace: Evidence from a survey of households. Journal of Public Economics 87, 1487-1519.

Betrand, Marianne; Karlan, Dean; Mullainathan, Sendhil; Shafir, Eldar; Zinman, Jonathan (2005) What’s psychology worth? A field experiment in the consumer credit market. NBER working paper 11892.

Biais, Bruno; Weber, Martin (2007) Hindsight bias and investment performance. IDEI Working Paper, n. 476, January 2007.

Birch, Susan, A.J.; Bloom, Paul (2007) The curse of knowledge in reasoning about false beliefs. Psychological Science 18(5), 382-386.Blanton, Hart; Pelham, Brett W.; DeHart, Tracy; Carvallo, Mauricio (2001) Overconfidence as dissonance reduction. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 37, 373-385.

Botti. Simona; Iyengar, Sheena, S. (2006) The dark side of choice: when choice impairs social welfare. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing 25(1), 24-38.

Brenner, Lyle A.; Koehler, Derek J.; Liberman, Varda; Tversky, Amos (1996) Overconfidence in probability and frequency judgments: A critical examination. Organisational Behaviour and Human Decision Processes 65, 212-219.

Brewer, Noel T.; Chapman, Gretchen B. (2002) The fragile basic anchoring effect. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 15(1), 65-77.Brown, Philip; Chappel, Nick; Da Silva Rosa, Ray; Walter, Terry (2006) The reach of the disposition effect: Large sample evidence across investor classes. International Review of Finance 6(1-2), 43-78.

Budescu, David; Bruderman, Maira (1995) The relationship between the illusion of control and the desirability bias. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 8(2), 109-125.

Page 78: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

74

Buehler, Roger; Griffin, Dale; Ross, Michael (1994) Exploring the "planning fallacy": Why people underestimate their task completion times. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 67, 366-381.Buehler, Roger; Griffin, Dale; Ross, Michael (1995) It's about time: Optimistic predictions in work and love. In European Review of Social Psychology, Volume 6, eds. W. Stroebe and M. Hewstone. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons.

Buehler, Roger; Griffin, Dale; Ross, Michael (2002) Inside the planning fallacy: The causes and consequences of optimistic time predictions. In Gilovich, T., Griffin, D. and Kahneman, D. (eds.) Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

Bukszar, Ed; Connolly, Terry (1988) Hindsight bias and strategic choice: Some problems in learning from experience. Academy of Management Journal 31(3), 628-641.

Cagan, Philip (1965) The effect of pension plans on aggregate savings. National Bureau of Economic Research, New York.

Camerer, Colin (1987) Do biases in probability judgment matter in markets? Experimental evidence. American Economic Review 77(5), 981-997.

Camerer, Colin; Loewenstein, Georg; Weber, Martin (1989) The curse of knowledge in economic settings: an experimental analysis. Journal of Political Economy 97(5), 1232–1254.

Camerer, Colin; Hogarth, Robin M. (1999) The effects of financial incentives in experiments: A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 19(1-3), 7-42.

Camerer, Colin; Lovallo, Dan (1999) Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. American Economic Review 89(1), 306-318.

Camerer, Colin; Issacharoff, Samuel; Loewenstein, George; O’Donoghue, Ted; Rabin, Matthew (2003) Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for ”asymmetric paternalism. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 151(3), 1211–1254.

Camerer, Colin; Loewenstein, George; Prelec, Drazen (2005) Neuroeconomics: How neuroscience can inform economics. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIII, 9–64.

Camerer, Cohn; Fehr, Ernst (2006) When does 'economic man' dominate social behavior. Science 311(5757), 47-52.

Campbell, Jennifer D.; Tesser, Abraham (1983) Motivational interpretations of hindsight bias: An individual difference analysis. Journal of Personality 51(4), 605-620Chapman, Gretchen B.; Johnson, Eric J. (1994) The limits of anchoring. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 7(4), 223-242.

Chapman, Gretchen B.; Johnson, Eric J. (1999) Anchoring, activation and the construction of values. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 79(2), 115–153.

Chapman, Gretchen B.; Johnson, Eric J. (2002) Incorporating the irrelevant: Anchors in judgments of belief and value. In: T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, & D. Kahneman (Eds.),

Page 79: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

75

Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (120-138). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Cheema, Amar; Soman, Dilip (2006) Malleable mental accounting: The effect of flexibility on the justification of attractive spending and consumption decisions. Journal of Consumer Psychology 16 (1), 33-44.

Choi, James J.; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte C. (2005) Are empowerment and education enough? Under-diversification in 401(k) Plans. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 151-213.

Choi, James J.; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte C. (2005a) $100 bills on the sidewalk: Violations of no-arbitrage in 401(k) accounts. NBER Working Paper No. 11554, August 2005.

Choi, James J.; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte C. (2006) Why does the law of one price fail? An experiment on index mutual funds. NBER Working Paper No. 12261, May 2006.

Choi, James J; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte; Metrick, Andrew (2002) Defined contribution pensions: Plan rules, participant decisions, and the path of least resistance. In ed. James Poterba, Tax Policy and the Economy, 16, pp. 67-114.

Choi, James J; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte; Metrick, Andrew (2003) Optimal defaults. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 93(2), 180-185.

Choi, James J; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte; Metrick, Andrew (2004a) Employees’ investment decisions about company stock. In Olivia S. Mitchell and Stephen P. Utkus, eds., Pension Design and Structure, New York: Oxford University Press, 2004, pp. 121-36.

Choi, James J; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte; Metrick, Andrew (2004b) For better or for worse: Default effects and 401(k) savings behavior. In: D. Wise, ed., Perspectives in the Economics of Aging, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, pp. 81-121.

Choi, James J; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte; Metrick, Andrew (2004c) Plan design and 401(k) savings outcomes. National Tax Journal 57(2), 275-98.

Choi, James J; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte; Metrick, Andrew (2005) Optimal defaults and active decisions. NBER Working Paper No. 11074, January 2005.

Choi, James J; Laibson, David; Madrian, Brigitte; Metrick, Andrew (2006) Saving for retirement on the path of least resistance. In: E. McCaffrey and J. Slemrod, eds., Behavioral Public Finance, 304-351.

Christensen, Caryn (1989) The psychophysics of spending, Journal of Behavioural Decision Making 2(2), 69-80.Christensen-Szalanski, Jay J.; Beach, L.R. (1982) Experience and the base rate fallacy. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 29 (2), 270-278

Clancy, Margaret; Grinstein-Weiss, Michal; Schreiner, Mark (2001) Financial education and saving outcomes in Individual Development Accounts. (Working Paper No. 01-2). St. Louis: Center for Social Development, Washington University.

Page 80: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

76

Cohen, Joel B.; Pham, Michel Tuan; Andrade, Eduardo B.(2008) The nature and role of affect in consumer behavior, In Curtis P. Haugtvedt, Paul Herr, Frank Kardes, (eds), Handbook of consumer psychology, 297-348, Erlbaum.Collins, J.M. (2005) Evaluating borrower counselling: review of recent studies policylab http://www.policylabconsulting.com/documents/FMF_2005614%20-%20Collins_Paper4_LitReviewCounseling_6_05.pdf

Conlin, Michael; O'Donoghue, Ted; Vogelsang, Timothy J. (2007) Projection bias in catalog orders. American Economic Review 97(4), 1-33.

Dhar, Ravi (1997) Consumer preference for a no-choice option. Journal of Consumer Research 24, 215–231.

Daniel, Kent; Hirshleifer, David; Teoh, Siew Hong (2002) Investor psychology in capital markets: evidence and policy implications. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(1), 139-209.Davis, Martin, F. (2003) Confirmatory bias in the evaluation of personality descriptions: Positive test strategies and output interference. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 85(4), 736-744.

Diamond, Peter; Koszegi, Boton (2003) Quasi-hyperbolic discounting and retirement. Journal of Public Economics 87, 1839–1872.

Diehl, Kristin. (2005) When two rights make a wrong: searching too much in ordered environments. Journal of Marketing Research XLII, 313-22.

Della Vigna, Stefano; Malmendier, Ulrike (2006) Paying not to go to the gym. American Economic Review 96(3), 694-719.

Deighton, John (1984) The interaction of advertising and evidence. Journal of Consumer Reserach 11(4), 763–770

de Meza, D., and C. Southey (1996): "The Borrower's Curse: Optimism, Finance and Entrepreneurship", The Economic Journal, 106 (435), 375-386.

Denrell, Jerker (2003) Vicarious learning, undersampling of failure, and the myths of management. Organization Science, 14(3), 227-243.

Dror, Itiel, E.; Busemeyer, Jerome, R.; Basola, Beth (1999) Decision making under time pressure: An independent model of sequential sampling models. Memory & Cognition27(4), 713-725.

Duflo, Ester; Saez, Emmanuel (2003) The role of information and social interactions in retirement plan decisions: Evidence from a randomized experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 815-842.

Einhorn, Hillel, J.; Hogarth, Robin M. (1981) Behavioural decision theory: Processes of judgment and choice. Annual Review of Psychology 3, 53-88.

Engelhardt, Gary V. (2003) Nominal loss aversion, housing equity constraints and household mobility: evidence from the United States. Journal of Urban Economics 53, 171-95.

Page 81: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

77

Epley, Nicholas (2004) A tale of tuned decks? Anchoring as accessibility and anchoring as adjustment. In D. J. Koehler, & N. Harvey (Eds.), The Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making (pp. 240–256). Oxford, UK: Blackwell.Epley, Nicholas; Gilovich, Thomas (2001) Putting adjustment back in the anchoring and adjustment heuristic: Differential processing of self-generated and experimenter-provided anchors. Psychological Science 12(5), 391-396.

Epley, Nicholas; Keysar, Boaz; Van Boven, Leaf; Gilovich, Thomas (2004) Perspective taking as egocentric anchoring and adjustment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 87(3), 327-339.

Epley, Nicholas; Gilovich, Thomas (2005) When effortful thinking influences judgmental anchoring: Differential effects of forewarning and incentives on self-generated and externally provided anchors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 18(3), 199-212.

Epley, Nicholas; Gilovich, Thomas (2006) The anchoring-and-adjustment heuristic. Psychological Science 17(4), 311-318.

Epley, Nicholas; Mak, Dennis; Idson, Lorraine Chen (2006) Bonus or rebate? The impact of income framing on spending and saving. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making19(3), 213–227.

Evans, Jonathan, St. B. T.; Curtis-Holmes, Jodie (2005) Rapid responding increases belief bias: Evidence for the dual process theory of reasoning. Thinking and Reasoning11(4), 382−389

Evans, Jonathan, St. B. T.; Newstead, S.; Allen, J.; Pollard, P. (1994). Debiasing by instruction: The case of belief bias. European Journal of Cognitive Psychology, 6, 263−285

Farkas, Steve; Johnson, Jean (1997) Miles to go: A status report on Americans’ plans for retirement. New York, Public Agenda.Fellner, Gerlinde; Sutter, Matthias (2005) Causes, consequences and cures of myopic loss aversion – an experimental investigation. ESI Discussion Paper.Fennema, M.G.; Perkins, Jon D. (2007) Mental Budgeting Versus Marginal Decision Making: Training, Experience and Justification Effects on Decisions Involving Sunk Costs. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making.

Ferrari, Joseph R.; Johnson, Judith L.; McGown, William G. (1995) Procrastination and task avoidance: Theory, research and treatment. New York: Plenum Press.

Ferris, Stephen P.; Haugen, Robert A.; Makhija, Anil K. (1988) Predicting contemporary volume with historic volume at differential price levels: Evidence supporting the disposition effect. Journal of Finance 43(3), 677-697.Fischhoff, Baruch (1982). Debiasing. In: Judgement under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, Kahneman, D., Slovic, P. & Tversky, A. (eds.), (pp. 422-444). Cambridge University Press, New York.

Page 82: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

78

Fischhoff, Baruch (1975) Hindsight is not foresight: The effect of outcome knowledge on judgement under uncertainty. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 1(3), 288-299.Fischhoff, Baruch; Beyth, Ruth (1975) I knew it would happen: Remembered probabilities of once-future things. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance13, 1-16.

Fischhoff, Baruch; Slovic, Paul; Lichtenstein, Sarah (1978) Fault trees: Sensitivity of estimated probabilities to problem representation. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 4, 330–344.

Fong, Geoffrey T.; Krantz, David H., Nisbett, Richard E. (1986) The effects of statistical training on thinking about everyday problems. Cognitive Psychology 18(3), 253-292.

Fox, Craig R; Clemen, Robert T. (2005) Subjective probability assessment in decision analysis: Partition dependence and bias toward the ignorance prior. Management Science51(9), 1417-1432.

Frederick, Shane (2005) Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(4), 25-42.

Frederick, Shane; Loewenstein, George; O’Donoghue, Ted (2002) Time discounting and time preferences: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature 40, 351-401.FSA (2006) ‘Financial Capability in the UK – Establishing a Baseline

Gabaix, Xavier; Laibson, David (2006) Shrouded attributes, consumer myopia, and information suppression in competitive markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2), 505-540.

Gächter, Simon; Johnson, Eric J.; Herrmann, Andreas (2007) Individual level loss aversion in riskless and risky choices. CeDEx Discussion Paper, 2007-02.Galinsky, Adam D.; Moskowitz, Gordon B. (2000) Counterfactuals as behavioral primes: Priming the simulation heuristic and consideration of alternatives. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 36, 384-409.

Galinsky, Adam D.; Mussweiler, Thomas (2001) First offers as anchors: The role of perspective-taking and negotiator focus. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 81 (4), 657-669.

Garland, Howard; Newport, Stephanie (1991) Effects of absolute and relative sunk costs on the decision to persist with a course of action. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 48, 55–69.

Genesove, David, and Christopher Mayer, (2001), Loss aversion and seller behavior: Evidence from the housing market, Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 1233-1260.

Gigerenzer, Gerd (1991) How to make cognitive illusions disappear: Beyond "heuristics and biases." European Review of Social Psychology 2, 83-115.

Gigerenzer, Gerd; Hoffrage, Ulrich (1995) How to improve Bayesian reasoning without instruction: Frequency formats. Psychological Review 102(4), 684–704.

Page 83: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

79

Gigerenzer, Gerd; Hoffrage, Ulrich (1999) Overcoming difficulties in Bayesian reasoning: A reply to Lewis and Keren (1999) and Meilers and McGraw (1999). Psychological Review 106(2), 425-430.Gilbert, Daniel T.; Pelham, Brett W.; Krull, Douglas S. (1988) On cognitive busyness: When person perceivers meet persons perceived. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 54, 733-740.

Gilbert, Daniel T.; Osborne, Randall E. (1989) Thinking backward: Some curable and incurable consequences of cognitive busyness. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57, 940-949.

Gilbert, Daniel T.; Malone, Patrick, S. (1995) The correspondence bias. Psychological Bulletin 117(1), 21-38.

Gilovich, Thomas; Medvec, Victoria Husted (1993) The experience of regret: What, when, and why. Psychological Review 102(2), 379-395.Gilovich, Thomas; Griffin, Dale; Kahneman, Daniel (2002) Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge University Press, New York.

Glaser, Markus; Weber, Martin; Langer, Thomas (2005) Overconfidence of professionals and lay men: individual differences within and between tasks? SSRN-Working Paper No. 712583.

Glaser, Markus; Weber, Martin (2007) Overconfidence and trading volume. The GENEVA Risk and Insurance Review 32, 1-36.

Gneezy, Uri; Potters, Jan (1997) An experiment on risk taking and evaluation periods. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 631-45.

Green, Francis (1981) The effect of occupational pension schemes on saving in the United Kingdom: A test of the life cycle hypothesis. Economic Journal 91(361), 136-144.

Greve, Henrich R. (1999) The effect of change on performance: Inertia and regression toward the mean. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44: 590-614

Griffin, Dale; Tversky, Amos (1992) The weighing of evidence and the determinants of confidence, Cognitive Psychology 24, 411-435.

Grove, William M.; Zald, David H.; Lebow, Boyd S.; Snitz, Beth E.; Nelson, Chad (2000) Clinical versus mechanical prediction: a meta-analysis. Psychological Assessment12(1), 19-30.

Grove, William; Meehl, Paul (1996) Comparative efficiency of informal (subjective, impressionistic) and formal (mechanical, algorithmic) prediction procedures: The clinical-statistical controversy. Journal of Consulting and Clinical Psychology 66(2), 348-362.

Gugerty, Mary Kay (2007) You can’t save alone: commitment in rotating savings and credit associations in Kenya. Economic Development and Cultural Change 55(2), 251–82.

Page 84: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

80

Guilbault, Rebecca L.; Bryant, Fred B.; Howard Brockway, Jennifer; Posavac. Emil J.(2004) A meta-analysis of research on hindsight bias. Basic & Applied Social Psychology 26(2/3), 103-117.Hancock, Ruth; Juarez-Garcia, Ariadna; Wittenberg, Raphael; Pickard, Linda; Comas-Herrera, Adelina; King, Derek; Malley, Juliette (2006) Projections of Owner-Occupation Rates, House Values, Income and Financial Assets Among Older People, UK, 2002-2022. Personal Social Services Research Unit, London School of Economics, PSSRU Discussion Paper, 2373.

Hatsopoulos, George N.; Krugman, Paul R.; Poterba, James M (1989) Overconsumption: the challenge to US economic policy. American Business Conference.

Hawkins, Scott A.; Hastie, Reid (1990) Hindsight biased judgments of past events after the outcomes are known. Psychological Bulletin 107(3), 311-327.

Heath, Chip (1995) Escalation and de-escalation of commitment in response to sunk costs: The role of budgeting in mental accounting. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 62, 38–54Heath, Chip; Soll, Jack B. (1996) Mental budgeting and consumer decisions. Journal of Consumer Research 23, 40-52.

Heath, Chip; Huddart, Steven; Lang, Mark (1999) Psychological factors and stock option exercise. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(2), 601-627.

Hertwig, Ralf; Gigerenzer, Gerd; Hoffrage, Ulrich (1997) The reiteration effect in hindsight bias. Psychological Review 104(1), 194-202.

Hertwig, Ralph; Gigerenzer, Gerd (1999) The 'conjunction fallacy' revisited: How intelligent inferences look like reasoning errors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12(4), 275-305.

Hilton, Denis J. (2001) The psychology of financial decision-making: Applications to trading, dealing, and investment analysis. Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets2(1), 37-53.

Hinds, Pamela J. (1999) The curse of expertise: The effects of expertise and debiasing methods on predictions on novice performance. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied 5(2), 205-221.

Hirt, Edward R.; Markman, Keith D. (1995) Multiple explanation: A consider-an-alternative strategy for debiasing judgments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 69(6), 1069–1086.

Hirt, Edward R.; Kardes, Frank R.; Markman, Keith D. (2004) Activating a mental simulation mind-set through generation of alternatives: Implications for debiasing in related and unrelated domains. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 40, 374-383.

Hoch, Stephen J. (1985) Counterfactual reasoning and accuracy in predicting personal events. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory and Cognition 11(4), 719-731

Page 85: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

81

Hölzl, Erik; Kirchler, Erich (2005) Causal attribution and hindsight bias for economic developments. Journal of Applied Psychology 90(1), 167-174.

Hogarth, Robin M. (1975) Cognitive processes and the assessment of subjective probability distributions. Journal of the American Statistical Association 70(350), 271-289.

Hogarth, Robin, M.; Einhorn, Hillel J. (1992) Order effects in belief updating: The belief-adjustment-model. Cognitive Psychology 24, 1-55.

Hsee, Christopher K.; Kunreuther, Howard C. (2000) The affection effect in insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 20, 141-159.

Hsee, Christopher K.; Zhang, Jiao, Yu, Fang; Xi, Yiheng (2003) Lay rationalism and. inconsistency between predicted experience and decision. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 16, 257-272.

Huber, Oswald; Seiser, Gabriele (2001) Accounting and convincing: The effect of two types of justification on decision process. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 14(1), 69-85.

Huffman, David; Barenstein, Matias (2004) Riches to rags every month? The fall in consumption expenditure between paydays. IZA Discussion Paper, 1430.

Iyengar, Sheena S.; Lepper, Mark R. (2000) When choice is demotivating: can one desire too much of a good thing? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 76, 995-1006.

Iyengar, Sheena S.; Jiang, Wei; Huberman, Gur (2003) How much choice is too much? Contributions to 401(k) retirement plans. Pensions Research Council Working Paper, PRC WP 2003-10.

Iyengar, Sheena S; Kamenica, Emir (2008) Choice proliferation, simplicity seeking and asset allocation. Working Paper, Chicago GSB.

Jacoby, Jacob; Mazursky David; Kuss Alfred; Troutman Tracy (1984) When feedback is ignor12ed: The disutility of outcome feedback. Journal of Applied Psychology 69, 531-545.

Jacowitz, Karen E.; Kahneman, Daniel (1995) Measures of anchoring in estimation tasks. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 21, 1161-1166.

Jonas, Eva; Schulz-Hardt, Stefan; Frey, Dieter; Thelen, Norman (2001). Confirmation bias in sequential information search after preliminary decisions: An expansion of dissonance theoretical research on selective exposure to information. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 80(4), 557-571.Johnson, Eric J.; Hershey, John; Meszaros, Jacqueline; Kunreuther, Howard (1993) Framing, probability distortions, and insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 7(1), 35-51.

Johnson, Eric J.; Bellman, Steven; Lohse, Gerald L. (2002) Defaults, framing and privacy: Why opting in-opting out. Marketing Letters 13(1), 5–15.

Johnson, Eric J.; Goldstein, Daniel (2003) Do defaults save lives? Science 302, 1338–1339

Page 86: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

82

Johnson, Eric J.; Gächter, Simon; Herrmann, Andreas (2006) Exploring the nature of loss aversion. IZA Discussion Paper, 2015.

Kahneman, Daniel (1991). Judgment and decision making: A personal view. Psychological Science 2(3), 142-145.

Kahneman, Daniel (2003) A perspective on judgment and choice – mapping bounded rationality. American Psychologist 58(9), 697-720.

Kahneman, Daniel; Tversky, Amos (1973) On the psychology of prediction. Psychological Review, 80, 237-251.

Kahneman, Daniel; Tversky, Amos (1979) Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2), 263-292.

Kahneman, Daniel; Tversky, Amos (1984) Choices, values and frames. American Psychologist 39(4), 341-50.

Kahneman, Daniel; Knetsch, Jack L.; Thaler, Richard H. (1990) Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy 98, 1325-1348.

Kahneman, Daniel; Knetsch, Jack L.; Thaler, Richard H. (1991) Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives5(1), 193-206.Kahneman, Daniel; Lovallo, Dan (1993) Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive perspective on risk taking. Management Science 39(1), 17-31.

Kahneman, Daniel; Tversky, Amos (1996) On the reality of cognitive illusions. Psychological Review 103(3), 582-591.

Kahneman Daniel; Riepe, Mark W. (1998) Aspects of investor psychology. Journal of Portfolio Management 24, 52-67.

Kahneman, Daniel; Frederick, Shane (2002) Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, and D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (pp. 49-81). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Kempf, Alexander; Ruenzi, Stefan (2006) Status quo bias and the number of alternatives: An empirical illustration from the mutual funds industry. Journal of Behavioral Finance7(4), 204-213.

Kennedy, Jane (1993) Debiasing audit judgment with accountability: A framework and experimental results. Journal of Accounting Research 31(2), 231-245.

Kennedy, Jane (1995) Debiasing the curse of knowledge in audit judgement. Accounting Review 70(2), 249-273.

Kivetz, Ran (1999) Advances on research in mental accounting and reason-based choice. Marketing Letters 10(3), 249-266.

Klauer, Karl Christoph; Musch, Jochen; Naumer, Birgit (2000) On belief bias in syllogistic reasoning. Psychological Review 107(4), 852-884.

Page 87: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

83

Klayman, Joshua (1995) Varieties of confirmation bias. In: J. Busemeyer, R. Hastie, & D. C. Medin (eds.), Decision Making from a CognitivePerspective. The Psychology of Learning and Motivation Vol. 32, Advances in Research and Theory. San Diego: Academic Press.

Klayman, Joshua; Ha, Young-Won (1987) Confirmation, disconfirmation, and information in hypothesis testing. Psychological Review 94(2), 211-228.

Klayman, Joshua; Ha, Young-Won (1989) Hypothesis testing in rule discovery: Strategy, structure, and content. Journal of Experimental Psychology, Learning, Memory, and Cognition 15(4), 596-604.

Klayman, Joshua; Soil, Jack B.; Gonzalez-Vallejo, Claudia; Barlas, Sema (1999) Overconfidence: It depends on how, what, and whom you ask. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 79(3), 216-247.

Kleiter, Gernot D.; Krebs, Marianne; Doherty, Michael E.; Garavan, Hugh; Chadwick, Randall; Brake, Gregory (1997) Do subjects understand base rates? Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 72 (1), 25-61.Koehler, Jonathan J. (1996) The base rate fallacy reconsidered: Descriptive, normative, and methodological challenges. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 19 (1), 1-53.

Kooreman, Peter (2000) The labeling effect of a child benefit system. American Economic Review 90(3), 571-583.

Kruger, Justin; Wirtz, Derrick; Miller, Dale T. (2005). Counterfactual thinking and the first instinct fallacy. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 88, 725-735.

Kray, Laura J.; Galinsky, Adam D. (2003) The debiasing effect of counterfactual mind-sets: Increasing the search for disconfirmatory information in group decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 91, 69-81.

Kruglanski, Arie W.; Freund, Tallie (1983) The freezing and unfreezing of lay-inferences: Effects on impressional primacy, ethnic stereotyping and numerical anchoring. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 19(5), 448-468.

Lacko,J. and J. Pappalardo (2004) The effect of mortgage broker compensation disclosures on consumers and competition: A controlled experiment Federal Trade Commission Bureau of Economics Staff ReportLaibson, David (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2), 443–477.

Laibson, David; Repetto, Andrea; Tobacman, Jeremy (2003) A debt puzzle. In eds. Philippe Aghion, Roman Frydman, Joseph Stiglitz, Michael Woodford, Knowledge, Information, and Expectations in Modern Economics: In Honor of Edmund S. Phelps, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 228-266.

Langer, Ellen J. (1975) The illusion of control. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32(2), 311-328.

Page 88: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

84

Langer, Ellen J.; Roth, Jane (1975) Heads I win, tails it's chance: The illusion of control as a function of the sequence of outcomes in a purely chance task. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32(6), 951-955.Larrick, Richard P. (2004) Debiasing. In D. K. Koehler and N. Harvey (Eds.), Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making (pp. 316-337). New York: BlackwellPublishing.

Larrick, Richard P.; Morgan, James N.; Nisbett, Richard E. (1990) Teaching the use of cost-benefit reasoning in everyday life. Psychological Science 1(6), 362-370.

Larrick, Richard P.; Nisbett, Richard E.; Morgan, James N. (1993) Who uses the normative rules of choice? Implications for the normative status of microeconomic theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 56, 331-347.

Lay, Clarry H. (1986) At last, my research article on procrastination. Journal of Research in Personality 20, 474-495.Lerner, Jennifer S.; Tetlock, Philip E. (1999) Accounting for the effects of accountability. Psychological Bulletin 125(2), 255-275.

Lerner, Jennifer S.; Small, Deborah A.; Loewenstein, George (2004) Heart strings and purse strings. carryover effects of emotions on economic decisions. Psychological Science 15(5), 337–341.

Levin, Irwin P.; Schneider, Sandra L.; Gaeth, Gary J. (1998) All frames are not created equal: A typology and critical analysis of framing effects. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 76(2), 149-188.

Lichtenstein, Sarah; Fischhoff, Baruch (1980) Training for calibration. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 26, 149-171.Loewenstein, George (1996) Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65(3), 272-292.

Loewenstein, George (2000) Emotions in economic theory and economic behavior. American Economic Review 90(2), 426-432.

Loewenstein, George; Prelec, Drazen; Weber, Roberto (1999) What, me worry? A psychological perspective on economic aspects of retirement. In H.J. Aaron (Ed.) Behavioral dimensions of retirement. Brookings Institutions Press, Washington DC, 215-46.

Loewenstein, George; Weber Elke U.; Hsee, Christopher K.; Welch, Ned (2001) Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin 127(2), 267–286.Loewenstein, George; O'Donoghue, Ted; Rabin, Matthew (2003) Projection bias in predicting future utility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 1209-1248.

Loewenstein, George; O’Donoghue, Ted (2004) Animal spirits: affective and deliberative processes in economic behavior. CAE Working Paper, #04-14

Loomes, Graham; Sugden, Robert (1982) Regret theory: an alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty. Economic Journal 92(368), 805-824.

Page 89: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

85

Lord, Charles G.; Lepper, Mark R.; Preston, Elizabeth (1984) Considering the opposite: A corrective strategy for social judgment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology47, 1231-1243.Lusardi, Annamaria; Mitchell, Olivia (2007a) Baby boomer retirement security: The roles of planning, financial literacy, and housing wealth. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 205-224.

Lusardi, Annamaria; Mitchell, Olivia (2007b) Financial literacy and retirement preparedness: Evidence and implications for financial education. Business Economics42(1), 35-44.

Lütje, Torben; Menkhoff, Lukas (2007) What drives home bias? Evidence from fund managers’ views. International Journal of Finance & Economics 12, 21-35.

MacLeod, Colin; Campbell, Lynlee (1992) Memory accessibility and probability judgments: An experimental evaluation of the availability heuristic. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 63(6), 890-902.

Madrian, Brigitte.C.; Shea, Dennis, F. (2001) The power of suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) participation and savings behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(4), 1149–1187.

Mandell, Lewis, (2006) Financial literacy: If it's so important, why isn't it improving? Networks Financial Institute Policy Brief No. 2006-PB-08 Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=923557

Mandell, Lewis, (2004) Financial Literacy: Are We Improving? Results of the 2004 National Jump$tart Survey Washington, D.C.: Jumpstart Coalition

March, James G.; Sproull, Lee S.; Tamuz, Michal (1991) Learning from samples of one or fewer. Organization Science 2, 1-13.

McAfee, R. Preston; Mialon, Hugo M; Mialon, Sue H (2008) Do sunk cost matter? Forthcoming in: Economic InquiryMcClure, Samuel M.; Laibson, David; Loewenstein, George; Cohen, Jonathan D. (2004) Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards. Science, 306(5695), 503-7.

McElroy, S; A. Satlin; H. Pope; P.E. Keck & J.I. Hudson (1991) Treatment of compulsive shopping with antidepressants: a report of three cases. Annals of clinical psychiatry, 3(3), 199-204.

McKenzie, Craig, R.M.; Liersch, Michael. J.; Finkelstein, Stacey R. (2006) Recommendations implicit in policy defaults. Psychological Science 17(5), 414-420.MacGregor, Donald G.; Slovic, Paul; Dreman, David; Berry, Michael (2000) Imagery, affect and financial judgment. Psychology and the Financial Markets 1, 104–110.

Mellers, Barbara; Hertwig, Ralph; Kahneman, Daniel (2001) Do frequency representations eliminate conjunction effects? An exercise in adversarial collaboration. Psychological Science 12(4), 269-275.

Meehl, Paul E. (1954) Clinical versus statistical prediction: A theoretical analysis and review of the evidence. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

Page 90: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

86

Menkhoff, Lukas; Schmidt, Ulrich; Brozynski, Torsten (2006) The impact of experience on risk taking, overconfidence, and herding of fund managers: complementary survey evidence. European Economic Review 50, 1753-1766.Mischel, Walter; Metzner, Ralph (1962) Preference for delayed reward as a function of age, intelligence and length of delay interval. Journal of Abnormal Social Psychology64(6), 425-31.

Moser, Donald V. (1989) The effects of output interference, availability, and accounting information on investors’ predictive judgments. Accounting Review 64(3), 433-448.

Mussweiler, Thomas (2001) The durability of anchoring effects. European Journal of Social Psychology 31, 431-442.

Mussweiler, Thomas; Strack, Fritz; Pfeiffer, Tim (2000) Overcoming the inevitable anchoring effect: Considering the opposite compensates for selective accessibility. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26(9), 1142-1150.Mussweiler, Thomas; Englich, Birte (2005) Subliminal anchoring : Judgmental consequences and underlying mechanisms. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 98, 133-143.

Newby-Clark, Ian R.; Ross, Michael; Buehler, Roger; Koehler, Derek. J.; Griffin, Dale. (2000) People focus on optimistic and disregard pessimistic scenarios while predicting their task completion times. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied 6(3), 171-182.

Nickerson, Raymond S. (1998) Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises. Review of General Psychology 2(2), 175-220.

Nisbett, Richard E.; Zukier, Henry; Lemley, Ronald E. (1981) The dilution effect: Nondiagnostic information weakens the implications of diagnostic information. Cognitive Psychology 13, 248-277.

Nisbett, Richard E.; Borgida, Eugene; Crandall, Rick; Reed, Harvey (1982) Popular induction: Information is not necessarily informative. 101–116. In: Daniel Kahneman, Paul Slovic, and Amos Tversky (eds.) Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Nisbett, Richard E.; Fong, Geoffrey T.; Lehman, Darrin R.; Cheng, Patricia W. (1987) Teaching reasoning. Science 238(4827), 625-631.

Odean, Terrance. (1998) Are investors reluctant to realise their losses? Journal of Finance 53(5), 1775-1798.

O’Donoghue, Ted; Rabin, Matthew (1999) Doing it now or later. American Economic Review 89(1), 103-124.

O'Donoghue, Ted; Rabin, Matthew (2001) Choice and procrastination. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(1), 121-160.

Ofir, Chezy (2000) Ease of recall vs. recalled evidence in judgment: Experts vs. laymen. Organizational Behavior Human Decision Processes 81(1), 28-42.

Ofir, Chezy; Mazursky, David (1997) Does a surprising outcome reinforce or reverse the hindsight bias? Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 69(1), 50-57.

Page 91: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

87

Olsen, Robert A. (1997) Desirability bias among professional investment managers: Some evidence from experts. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 10, 65-72.

Ordóñez, Lisa; Benson, Lehman III (1997) Decisions under time pressure: How time constraint affects risky decision making. Organisational Behaviour and Human Decision Processes 71, 121-140.

Peng, T.M, S. Bartholeme, J.J. Fox, G. Cravener (2007) The impact of personal finance education delivered in high school and college courses Journal of Familly Economic Issues, 28: 265-284

Peters, Ellen; Rothbart, Myron (2000) Typicality can create, eliminate, and reverse the dilution effect. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 26(2), 177-187.

Phelps, Edmund S.; Pollak, Robert A. (1986) On second-best national saving and game-equilibrium growth. Review of Economic Studies 35(2), 201-208.

Pohl, Rüdiger F.; Hell, Wolfgang (1996) No reduction in hindsight bias after complete information and repeated testing. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 67(1), 49-58.

Prelec, Drazen; Loewenstein, George (1998) The red and the black: Mental accounting of savings and debt. Marketing-Science 17(1), 4-28.

Quattrone, G. A., Lawrence, C. P., Warren, D. L., Souza-Silva, K., Finkel, S. E., Andrus, D. E. (1984) Explorations in anchoring: The effects of prior range, anchor extremity, and suggestive hints. Unpublished manuscript. Palo Alto., CA: Stanford University.

Rabin, Matthew (1998) Psychology and economics. Journal of Economic Literature36(1), 11-46.

Rabin, Matthew; O’Donoghue, Ted (1999) Procrastination in preparing for retirement. In Henry Aaron, (Ed), Behavioral Dimensions of Retirement Economics, Brookings Institution Press & Russell Sage Foundation, 125-156.

Rabin, Matthew; Schrag, Joel L. (1999) First impressions matter: A model of confirmatory bias. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1), 37-82.

Rabin, Matthew (2002) Inference by believers in the law of small numbers. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 775-816.

Rachlinksi, Jeffrey J. (2006) Cognitive errors, individual differences, and paternalism, University of Chicago Law Review 73, 207-229.

Rapoport, Amnon; Budescu, David V. (1992) Generation of random series in two-person strictly competitive games. Journal of Experimental Psychology, General 121(3), 352-363.

Rapoport, Amnon; Budescu, David V. (1997) Randomization in individual choice behavior. Psychological Review, 104(3), 603-617.

Read, Daniel (2001) Is time-discounting hyperbolic or subadditive? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 23(1), 5-32.

Read, Daniel (2004) Intertemporal choice. In: D. Koehler and N. Harvey (eds.), Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making. Oxford: Blackwell.

Page 92: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

88

Ritov, Ilana; Baron, Jonathan (1992) Status-quo and omission bias. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5(1), 49–61.

Ritov, Ilana; Baron, Jonathan (1995) Outcome knowledge, regret, and omission bias. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 64(2), 119-127.

Ross, Lee D.; Lepper, Mark. R.; Strack, Fritz; Steinmetz, Julia. (1977) Social explanation and social expectation: Effects of real and hypothetical explanations on subjective likelihood. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 35(11), 817-829.

Rubinstein, Ariel. (2003) ‘Economics and psychology’? The case of hyperbolic discounting. International Economic Review 44(4), 1207-1216.

Russo, J. Edward; Schoemaker, Paul J.H. (1989) Decision traps – ten barriers to brilliant decision-making & how to overcome them. Doubleday/Currency, New York.

Samuelson, William; Zeckhauser, Richard J. (1988) Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1, 7-59.

Sanna, Lawrence J.; Schwarz, Norbert; Small, Eulena M. (2002) Accessibility experiences and the hindsight bias: I knew it all along versus it could never have happened. Memory & Cognition 30(8), 1288-1296.

Sanna, Lawrence J.; Schwarz, Norbert; Stocker, Shevaun L. (2002) When debiasing backfires: Accessible content and accessibility experiences in debiasing hindsight. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, Cognition 28(3), 497-502.

Sanna, Lawrence J.; Schwarz, Norbert, (2003) Debiasing the hindsight bias: The role of accessibility experiences and (mis)attributions. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 39, 287-295.

Schwartz, Barry. (2005) The paradox of choice: why more is less. Harper Collins.

Schweitzer, Maurice (1994) Disentangling status quo and omission effects: An experimental analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 58, 457-476.

Schweitzer, Maurice (1995) Multiple reference points, framing, and the status quo bias in health care financing decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 59, 69-72.

Shapira, Zur; Venezia, Itzhak. (2001) Patterns of behavior of professionally managed and independent investors. Journal of Banking and Finance 25, 1573-1587.

Shapira, Zur; Venezia, Itzhak (2006) On timing and herding: do professional investors behave differentlythan amateurs? Working Paper, European Financial Management Symposium 2006.

Shiv, Baba; Loewenstein, George; Bechara, Antoine; Damasio, Hanna; Damasio, Antonio R. (2005) Investment behavior and the negative side of emotion. Psychological Science 16(6), 435-439.

Shefrin, Hersh; Statman, Meir (1985) The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance 40(3), 777-790.

Page 93: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

89

Shefrin, Hersh; Thaler, Richard H. (1988) The behavioral life-cycle hypothesis. Economic Inquiry 26, 609-643.

Shiller, R.J., 2003. From efficient markets theory to behavioral finance. Journal of Economic

Shui, Haiyan; Ausubel Lawrence M. (2004) Time inconsistency in the credit market. Unpublished Manuscript, University of Maryland.

Sides, Ashley; Osherson, Daniel; Bonini, Nicolao; Viale, Riccardo (2002) On the realityof the conjunction fallacy. Memory and Cognition 30(2), 191-198.

Siegel-Jacobs, Karen; Yates, J. Frank (1996) Effects of procedural and outcome accountability on judgement quality. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65(1), 1-17.

Simonson, Itamar (1989) Choice based on reasons: The case of attraction and compromise effects. Journal of Consumer Research 16, 158-174.

Simonson, Itamar; Nye, Peter (1992) The effect of accountability on susceptibility to decision errors. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 51(3), 416-446.

Simonson, Itamar; Staw, Barry M (1992) Deescalation strategies: a comparison of techniques for reducing commitment to losing courses of action. Journal of Applied Psychology 77(4), 419-426.

Skinner, Jonathan (1989) Housing wealth and aggregate saving. Regional Science and Urban Economics 19(2), 305-324.

Sloan, Frank A.; Taylor, Donald H.; Smith, V. Kerry (2003) The smoking puzzle: information, risk perception, and choice. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Slovic, Paul (1972) Psychological study of human judgement: Implications for investment decision making. Journal of Finance, 27(4), 779-799.

Slovic, Paul (1975) Choice between equally valued alternatives. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 1, 280-287.

Slovic, Paul; Fischhoff, Baruch (1977) On the psychology of experimental surprises. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 3(4), 544–531

Slovic, Paul; Finucane, Melissa; Peters, Ellen; Mac Gregor, Donald, G. (2002) The affect heuristic. In: T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, D. Kahneman (eds), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgement. Cambridge University Press, New York.

Smith, Adam (1759/1892) The theory of moral sentiments. New York: Prometheus Books.

Soll, Jack B.; Klayman, Joshua (2004) Overconfidence in interval estimates. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 30(2), 299–314.Soman, Dilip; Cheema, Amar (2001) The effect of windfall gains on the sunk cost Effect. Marketing Letters 12 (1), 49-60.

Soman, Dilip; Gourville, John T. (2001) Transaction decoupling: How price bundling affects the decision to consume. Journal of Marketing Research 38(1), 30-44.

Page 94: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

90

Soman, Dilip; Ainslie, George; Frederick, Shane; Li, Xiuping; Lynch, John; Moreau, Page; Mitchell, Andrew; Read, Daniel; Sawyer, Alan; Trope, Yaacov; Wertenbroch, Klaus; Zauberman, Gal (2005) The psychology of intertemporal discounting: Why are distant events valued differently from proximal ones? Marketing Letters 16(3/4), 347-360.Staw, Barry M.; Ross, Jerry (1987) Behavior in escalation situations: Antecedents, prototypes, and solutions. In: B. M. Staw, & L. L. Cummings (eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 7, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Staw, Barry M.; Ross, Jerry (1989) Understanding behavior in escalation situations. Science 246(4927), 216-220.

Strack, Fritz; Mussweiler, Thomas (1997) Explaining the enigmatic anchoring effect: Mechanisms of selective accessibility. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 73(3), 437-446.

Strotz, Robert H. (1956) Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization, Review of Economic Studies 23(3), 165-80.Summers, Lawrence; Carroll, Chris; Blinder, Alan S. (1987) Why is US national saving so low? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 607-642.

Tan, Hun-Tong; Yates, J. Frank (1995) Sunk cost effects: The influence of instruction and future return estimate. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes63(3), 311-319.

Teichman, Joel M.H.; Cecconi, Patricia P.; Bernheim, B. Douglas; Novarro, Neva K.; Monga, Manoj; DaRosa, Debra; Resnick, Martin I. (2005) How do residents manage personal finances? American Journal of Surgery 189, 134-139.

Teigen, Karl Halvor; Martinussen, Monica; Lund, Thorleif (1996) Linda versus world cup: Conjunctive probabilities in three-event fictional and real-life predictions. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 9(2), 77-93.

Tetlock, Philip E.; Kim, Jae Il (1987) Accountability and overconfidence in a personality prediction task. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 52(4), 700-709.

Tetlock, Philip E.; Boettger, Richard (1989) Accountability: A social magnifier of the dilution effect. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57(3), 388-398.

Thaler, Richard H. (1980) Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1, 39-60.

Thaler, Richard H. (1985) Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science4(3), 199-214.

Thaler, Richard H. (1990) Saving, fungibility and mental accounts. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4(1), 193-205.

Thaler, Richard H. (1994) Psychology and savings policies. American Economic Review84(2), Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Sixth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1994), 186-192.

Page 95: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

91

Thaler, Richard H. (1999) Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12(3), 183-206.

Thaler, Richard H.; Shefrin, Hersh (1981) An economic theory of self control. Journal of Political Economy 89(2), 392-410.

Thaler, Richard H.; Johnson, Eric J. (1990) Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: the effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science 36(6), 643-660.

Thaler, Richard H.; Benartzi, Shlomo (2004) Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase employee savings. Journal of Political Economy 112(1), S164-S187.

Thoresen Review of Generic Financial Advice: Final Report (2008)

Trotman, Ken T.; Wright, Arnold (2000) Order effects and recency: Where do we go from here? Accounting & Finance 40(2), 169-182.

Tubbs, Richard, M.; Gaeth, Gary, J.; Levin, Irvin P.; Van Osdol, Laura A. (1993) Order effects in belief updating with consistent and inconsistent evidence. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 6(4), 257-269.

Turner, Marlene E.; Pratkanis, Anthony R. (1998) Twenty-five years of groupthink theory and research: Lessons from the evaluation of a theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 73(2/3), 105-115.

Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1971) Belief in the law of small numbers. Psychological Bulletin 76(2), 105–110.

Tversky, Amos, Kahneman, Daniel (1973) Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology, 5, 207–232

Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1974) Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science 185(4157), 1124–1131.

Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1981) The framing of decisions and the psychology of frames. Science 211(4481), 453-463.Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1983) Extensional versus intuitive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability judgment. Psychological Review 90(4), 293-315.

Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1991) Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(4), 1039-1061.

Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1992) Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk & Uncertainty 5(4), 297-323.

Ülkümen, Gülden; Thomas, Manoj; Morwitz, Vicki G. (2008) Will I spend more in 12 months or a year? The effect of ease of estimation and confidence on budget estimates. forthcoming Journal of Consumer Research.

Van den Steen, Eric (2004) Rational overoptimism (and other biases). American Economic Review 94(4), 1141-1151.

Page 96: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

92

Venti, Steven F.; Wise, David A. (1990) Have IRAs increased US saving? Evidence from Consumer Expenditure Surveys. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(3), 661-698.

Waller, William S.; Zimbelman, Mark F. (2003) A cognitive footprint in archival data: Generalizing the dilution effect from laboratory to field settings. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 91(2), 254-268.

Wansink, Brian; Kent, Robert J.; Hoch, Stephen J. (1998) An anchoring and adjustment model of purchase quantity decisions. Journal of Marketing Research 35, 71-81.

Wason, Peter C. (1960) On the failure to eliminate hypotheses in a conceptual task. Quarterly Journal of. Experimental Psychology 12(3), 129 -140.

Weber, Martin; Camerer, Colin (1998) The disposition effect in securities trading: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 33, 167-184.

Weber, Martin; Welfens, Frank (2006) An individual level analysis of the disposition effect: Empirical and experimental evidence. Discussion Paper, University of Mannheim.

Webster, Donna, M., Richter, Linda; Kruglanski, Arie W. (1996) On leaping to conclusions when feeling tired: Mental fatigue effects on impressional primacy. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 32(2), 181-195.

Weinstein, Neil D. (1980) Unrealistic optimism about future life events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 39(5), 806-20.

Weinstein, Neil D. (1983) Reducing unrealistic optimism about illness susceptibility. Health Psychology 2, 11-20.

Weinstein, Neil D.; Klein, William M. (2002) Resistance of personal perceptions to debiasing interventions. In: T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, D. Kahneman (eds), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge University Press, New York.

Whitney, Robert A.; Hubin, Thomas; Murphy, John D. (1965) The new psychology of persuasion and motivation in selling. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

Wilson, Timothy D.; Schooler, Jonathan W. (1991) Thinking too much: Introspection can reduce the quality of preferences and decisions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 60(2), 181-192.

Willis, Lauren E (2008a) Evidence and ideology in assessing the effectiveness of financial literacy education, Journal of Consumer Affairs. May

Willis, Lauren E. (2008b) Against consumer financial literacy education. Iowa Law Review, 94(1) (forthcoming).

Wood, Gordon (1978) The knew-it-all-along effect. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 4(2), 345-353.

Zajonc, Robert B. (1980) Feeling and thinking - preferences need no inferences. American Psychologist 35(2), 151-175.

Zeelenberg, Marcel; Beattie, Jane (1997) Consequences of regret aversion 2: additional evidence for effects of feedback on decision making. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 72(1), 63-78.

Page 97: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

93

Zhang, Yinlong; Mittal, Vikas (2005) Decision difficulty: Effects of procedural and outcome accountability. Journal of Consumer Research 32, 465-472.

Zukier, Henry (1982) The dilution effect: The role of the correlation and the dispersion of predictor variables in the use of nondiagnostic information. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 43(6), 1163-1174.

Page 98: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

Taxonomy of cognitive biases likely to be relevant for financial decision makingBias Description and potential relevance Reference (Non-)Remedies

MemoryCurse of knowledge

Knowledge of an event's outcome can compromise the ability to reason about another person's beliefs about that event.

Wood (1978), Camerer, Loewenstein, Weber (1989), Birch, Bloom (2007)

Individuals cannot ignore private information even when monetary incentives and feedback are provided. However, a market setting reduces (but does not eliminate) this bias. Camerer, Loewenstein, Weber (1989)Entreating subjects to work hard and warning them about the bias have been largely ineffective. Fischhoff (1982), Wood (1978)The curse of knowledge is not mitigated by accountability defined as the requirement to justify one's judgments when called upon (but it encourages people to exert additional cognitive effort). Counterexplanation, i.e., explicitly considering evidence that would not support or lead one to expect the outcome that occurred, helps (because it addresses the cognitive nature of this bias and weakens causal connections between evidence and the actual outcome). Alternative outcomes are made more salient with counterexplanation. Kennedy (1995)

Hindsight[3]

Outcomes that are considered improbable ex ante are often overestimated ex post.

Fischhoff (1975), Fischhoff, Beyth (1975), Slovic, Fischhoff (1977), Campbell, Tesser (1983),Hawkins, Hastie (1990), Sanna, Schwarz, Small (2002), Guilbault et al (2004), Hölzl, Kirchler (2005), Biais, Weber (2007)

Advanced students of strategy analyzing a complex business case systematically distort their evaluations of initial decisions and projections for the future. Bukszar, Connolly (1988)The amount of hindsight bias in a knowledge question task is not reduced by having received information about the bias in advance or by having received feedback about their individual performance before being subject to the same

Page 99: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

95

procedure a second time. Pohl, Hell (1996)When surprise levels are moderate or low, judgments are consistent with the hindsight bias, whereas highly surprising outcomes lead to the reversal of the bias. Subjects under these conditions seek explanations to the outcome and “effortless assimilation,” the most accepted theoretical account for the hindsight bias, is less likely. Ofir, Mazursky (1997)To force oneself to argue against the inevitability of the reported outcome, that is, to try to convince oneself that it might have turned out otherwise might in fact increase the hindsight bias. Ironically, the strategy may be less effective the more one tries to convince oneself that it might have turned out otherwise realising along the way that reasons for an alternate outcome are difficult to bring to mind. Sanna, Schwarz, Stocker (2002)Sanna, Schwarz (2003)

Mental accounting[2]

Mental accounting is the set of cognitive operations used by individuals and households to organize, evaluate, and keep track of financial activities. People are assumed to group their assets into a number of non-fungible mental accounts.

Thaler (1985), Thaler (1990), Heath (1995), Heath, Soll (1996), Thaler (1999), Prelec, Loewenstein (1998), Kivetz (1999), Cheema, Soman (2006)

Procastination[3]

Postponing things one knows one should do today. A psychological reason might be that present or immediate costs/benefits are unduly salient or vivid in comparison to future costs/benefits.

Lay (1986), Ferrari, Johnson, McGown (1995), Rabin, O’Donoghue (1999), O'Donoghue, Rabin (2001), Andreou (2007)

The tendency to defer choice is greater when the difference in attractiveness among the available alternatives is small than when it is large. However, the percentage of people who defer choice among comparable alternatives decreases when the subjects first learn to make trade-offs among the different features. Dhar (1997)

Recall, Imaginability

An event or class may appear more numerous or frequent if its instances are more easily

Tversky, Kahneman (1974, 1981) Financial accounting information only mildly mitigates investors’ tendency to judge those

Page 100: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

96

[3, 4] recalled than other equally probable events. outcomes more probable for which they are able to generate the most supporting reasons. Moser (1989)

Naïve StatisticsBase rate neglect, stereotyping[1, 3, 4]

The base-rate fallacy is people's tendency to ignore base rates in favour of, e.g., individuating information (when such is available), rather than integrate the two.

Kahneman, Tversky (1973), Ajzen (1977), Bar-Hillel, Maya (1980), Camerer (1987), Kleiter et al (1997)

Conjunction[1, 4]

Probability is often over-estimated in compound conjunctive problems.

Tversky, Kahneman (1983), Teigen, Martinussen, Lund (1996), Hertwig, Gigerenzer (1999), Mellers et al (2001), Sides et al (2002)

Statistical training tends to improve reasoning. Fong, Krantz, Nisbett (1986)Bayesian reasoning can be improved by representing information in frequency formats rather than in probabilities. Tversky, Kahneman (1983), Gigerenzer, Hoffrage (1995, 1999), Kahneman, Tversky (1996)Accountability has a positive effect. Simonson, Nye (1992)

Correlation[1, 3, 4]

The probability of two events occurring together can be overestimated if they can be remembered to have co-occurred in the past.

Tversky, Kahneman (1973)

Disjunction[1, 4]

Probability is often under-estimated in compound disjunctive problems.

Bar-Hillel, Neter (1993)

Small number[1, 4]

Believers in the law of small numbers tend to over- infer the outcome of a random process after a small series of observations. People tend to believe that small samples replicate the probability distribution properties of the population.

Tversky, Kahneman (1971, 74), Kahneman, Tversky (1973), Hogarth (1975), Bar-Hillel, Wagenaar (1991), Rapoport, Budescu (1992, 1997), Rabin (2002)

AdjustmentAnchoring[4]

Assimilation of a numeric judgement to a previously considered standard

Jacowitz, Kahneman (1995), Strack, Mussweiler (1997), Galinsky, Mussweiler (2001), Mussweiler (2001), Brewer, Chapman (2002), Chapman, Johnson (2002), Ariely, Loewenstein, Prelec (2003), Epley (2004), Epley, Keysar, Van Boven, Gilovich

Implausibly extreme anchors have a proportionally smaller effect than anchors close to the expected value of the lotteries evaluated. Anchoring occurred only if the anchor and preference judgment are expressed on the same

Page 101: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

97

(2004), Mussweiler, Englich (2005), Epley, Gilovich, (2001, 2006)

scale. Chapman, Johnson (1994)Prompting subjects to consider features of the item that are different from the anchor reduces anchoring, while increasing consideration of similar features has no effect. Chapman, Johnson (1999)Anchoring can be reduced by applying a consider-the-opposite strategy. Mussweiler, Strack, Pfeiffer (2000)One can distinguish between externally provided (by another person, e.g., by the experimenter) and “self-generated” anchors. The latter are invented by oneself as part of a heuristic process and function as a short-cut and therefore they are known from the beginning to be wrong. Responses to “self-generated” anchors are found to be influenced by monetary incentives for precise judgment and by forewarning regarding an anchoring bias. Responses to externally provided anchors are not. Epley, Gilovich, (2005)

Default[3, 5]

People tend to stay with the default. Johnson et al. (1993), Madrian, Shea (2001), McKenzie, Liersch, Finkelstein (2006), Camerer, Issacharoff, Loewenstein, O’Donoghue, Rabin (2003), Johnson, Goldstein (2003)

Disposition[2]

The original purchase price of an item is treated as the reference point (closely related to mental accounting and loss aversion).

Shefrin, Statman (1985), Weber, Camerer (1998), Heath, Huddart, Lang (1999), Brown, Chappel, Da Silva Rosa, Walter (2006), Genesevo, Mayer (2001)

Learning seems to attenuate the magnitude of the disposition effect. Frequent traders sell their winners less and their losers more often, resulting in lower disposition effects. Weber, Welfens (2006)

Endowment[2, 3, 5]

The value of an item increases when it becomes a part of a person’s endowment. The person demands more to give up an object then they would be willing to pay to acquire it.

Kahneman, Knetsch, Thaler, (1990, 1991)

Page 102: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

98

Loss aversion[2, 3, 5]

Tendency of individuals to weigh losses about twice as much as gains.

Kahneman, Tversky(1979), Kahneman, Knetsch, Thaler (1991), Odean (1998), Tversky, Kahneman, (1991, 1992), Engelhardt (2003), Fellner, Sutter (2005), Johnson, Gächter, Herrmann, (2006), Gächter, Johnson, Herrmann, (2007)

Projection[3]

People exaggerate the degree to which their future tastes will resemble their current tastes.

Loewenstein, O'Donoghue, Rabin (2003), Conlin, O'Donoghue, Vogelsang (2007)

Regression to mean

Consider two variables X and Y which have the same distribution. If one selects individuals whose average X score is higher than the mean of X by k units, then the average of their Y scores will usually deviate from the mean of Y by less than k units. Often people do not take this into account in their judgments. For example, investments that have been extraordinary profitable yesterday are likely to regress back to their mean today.

Tversky, Kahneman (1974), Greve (1999)

Regret aversion[3, 5]

Tendency to avoid taking an action due to a fear that in hindsight it will turn out to have been suboptimal.

Loomes, Sugden (1982), Bell (1982), Ritov, Baron (1995), Bar-Hillel, Neter (1996), Zeelenberg, Beattie (1997)

There seems to be a temporal pattern to the experience of regret. Actions, or errors of commission, generate more regret in the short term; but inactions, or errors of omission, produce more regret in the long run. Gilovich, Medvec (1993)

Omission[3]

Tendency to judge harmful actions as worse or less moral than equally harmful omissions (inactions), especially in the short run.

Ritov, Baron (1992, 1995), Baron, Ritov (1994), Schweitzer (1994), Anderson (2003)

Bias towards omission tends to be higher when potential regret or knowledge of outcome is expected. Ritov, Baron (1995)

Status quo[3, 5]

People like things to stay the same. An alternative may be chosen only because it was used before (habit).

Slovic (1975), Samuelson, Zeckhauser (1988), Kahneman, Knetsch, Thaler (1991), Ritov, Baron (1992), Johnson et al. (1993), Baron, Ritov (1994), Schweitzer (1994, 1995), Anderson (2003), Thaler, Benartzi (2004)

ConfidenceBelief[3, 4, 5]

Difficulty evaluating conclusions that conflict with what one thinks one knows

Klauer, Musch, Naumer (2000) Rapid responding increases the amount of belief bias observed on a syllogistic reasoning

Page 103: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

99

about the world. task and it reduces the number of logically correct decisions Evans, Curtis-Holmes (2005)Elaborated verbal instruction in principles of reasoning seem to reduce the belief bias in syllogistic reasoning, but cannot eliminate it, Evans et al. (1994)

Completeness[3, 4, 5]

Perception of an apparently complete or logical data presentation of information base can stop the search process too early.

Wason (1960), Fischhoff, Slovic, Lichtenstein (1978)

Confirmation, Myside[3, 4, 5]

Tendency to evaluate evidence, generate evidence, and test hypotheses in a manner biased toward one's own previously held opinions.

Wason (1960), Deighton (1984), Klayman, Ha (1987, 1989), Klayman (1995), Nickerson (1998), Rabin, Schrag (1999), Jonas et al. (2001), Davis (2003)

Counterfactual primes – examples that makesubjects aware of both an actual outcome (e.g., getting into an accident; winning a lottery) and the converse counterfactual outcome (e.g., avoiding the accident; losing the lottery) –attenuated the confirmation bias in a trait hypothesis testing context by increasing the selection of questions designed to elicit hypothesis-disconfirming answers Galinsky, Moskowitz (2000)In a judgmental task two types of justification pressure, i.e., the requirement to explain the decision afterwards and the requirement to convince another person, lead to a distinct increase in the amount of utilised information Huber, Seiser (2001)

Unrealistic optimism, desire, wishful thinking[3]

The probability of desired outcomes is assessed to be greater than actually warrants.

Einhorn, Hogarth (1981), Bar-Hillel, Budescu (1995), Olsen (1997) Armor, Taylor (2002)

Offering people information about their own standing on risk factors or information about peer’s standing on these factors decreased optimism. Weinstein (1983)Counterfactual reasoning tends to increase accuracy when predicting the outcomes of future personal events. Hoch (1985)The desirability bias tends to be reduced in the case of repetitive events. Budescu, Bruderman (1995)

Page 104: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

100

Generally informing people about relevant health risk factors and requiring them to describe their standing on these factors had no overall effect on subsequent risk judgement. Weinstein, Klein (2002)

Illusion of control[4]

The expectancy of a personal success probability of an outcome often increases (normally above the objective one) when one has some control over the outcome.

Langer (1975) Langer, Roth (1975), Budescu, Bruderman (1995)

Planning fallacy[3]

Refers to the tendency to underestimate task-completion times.

Buehler, Griffin, Ross (1994, 1995, 2002) Pessimistic-scenario generation is unlikely to be an effective debiasing technique for personal completion predictions. Newby-Clark et al. (2000)The “recall-relevance” manipulation is more promising. Within this manipulation people are asked to describe a plausible scenario – based on their past experience – that would result in their completing an assignment at their typical time. (Buehler, Griffin, Ross 1994)

Overconfidence[3]

The ability to solve difficult or novel problems and the accuracy of our own judgements is often over-estimated.

Weinstein (1980), Brenner, Koehler, Liberman, Tversky (1996); Klayman, Soil, Gonzalez-Vallejo, Barlas, (1999), Blanton, Pelham, DeHart, Carvallo (2001), Soll, Klayman (2004), Van den Steen. (2004), Della Vigna, Malmendier (2006)

Calibration is improved after intensive training in the task. Lichtenstein, Fischhoff (1980).In a preexposure-accountability condition of a personality prediction task (subjects learned of the need to justify their responses before seeing the test-takers’ responses) subjects reported more integratively complex impressions of test-takers, made more accurate behavioural predictions, and reported more appropriate levels of confidence in their predictions than did either no-accountability or postexposure-accountability subjects. Tetlock, Kim (1987)Subjects who have received five apparently “easy” practice questions and then have been given feedback on the accuracy of their answers are underconfident on the final 30 questions. Subjects who anticipate a group

Page 105: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

101

discussion of their answers to general knowledge questions take longer to answer the questions and express less overconfidence in their answers than does a control group. Arkes, Christensen, Lai, Blumer, (1987)

Success Often failure is associated with poor luck and success with the abilities of the decision maker.

March, Sproull, Tamuz (1991), Denrell (2003), Barnett, Pontikes (2008)

PresentationDilution[4, 5]

The weakening of a belief by providing irrelevant neutral information.

Nisbett, Zukier, Lemley (1981), Zukier (1982), Peters, Rothbart (2000), Waller, Zimbelman (2003)

Framing[3, 4, 5]

Alternative wordings of the same objective information can significantly alter the decision, though differences between frames (e.g., as losses or gains) should have no effect on the rational decision.

Kahneman, Tversky (1979), Tversky, Kahneman (1981), Levin, Schneider, Gaeth, (1998), Bertrand et al. (2005), Epley, Mak, Idson (2006)

Linear Decision makers are often unable to extrapolate a non-linear growth process.

Bar-Hillel, Maya (1973)

Information order, recency[4]

The first item presented or the last may be over-weighted in judgment. Decision makers derive different conclusions depending on the order in which they receive information

Hogarth, Einhorn (1992), Tubbs, Gaeth, Levin, Van Osdol (1993)

Accountability reduced tendency for recency of information to influence judgments when predicting a candidates’ success at a job based on sequential information. Kruglanski, Freund (1983) This is still true if subjects experience mental fatigue. Webster, Richter, Kruglanski (1996)Accountability reduced tendency for recency of information to influence judgments in auditing tasks. Kennedy (1993)In auditing task-specific experience tends to reduce the recency bias. Trotman, Wright (2000)

Pruning bias, partition dependence

Bias in probability assessment due to which the particular choice of events into which the state space is partitioned does affect the

Fischhoff, Slovic, Lichtenstein, (1978), Ofir (2000), Fox, Clemen (2005)

Page 106: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

102

assessed probability distribution over statesScale[4]

The perceived variability of data can be affected by the scale of the data. This might cause that small extra purchases are perceived as minor expenditures when they follow larger purchases.

Tversky, Kahneman (1981), Christensen (1989)

SituationAttribution Tendency to draw inferences about a person's

unique and enduring dispositions from behaviours that can be entirely explained by the situations in which they occur.

Gilbert, Malone (1995)

Complexity[4, 5]

Time pressure, information overload, cognitive busyness, increased (internal) inspection and other factors that increase the perceived complexity of the task can lead to worse decisions.

Gilbert, Osborne (1988), Gilbert, Pelham, Krull (1989), Ordóñez, Benson (1997), Dror, Busemeyer, Basola (1999)

Increased introspection caused people to make choices that, compared with control subjects', corresponded less with expert opinion. Wilson, Schooler (1991)

Escalation, sunk cost[1]

Commitment to follow or escalate a previous unsatisfactory course of action. This leads to throw “good money after bad”.

Arkes, Blumer (1985), Staw, Ross (1987, 1989),Garland, Newport (1991), Arkes, Hutzel (2000),McAfee, Mialon, Mialon (2008)

Professional training in economics is positively correlated with cost-benefit reasoning and naïve subjects who have been given brief training in the sunk-cost rule (i.e., only future costs and benefits should be considered in current decisions) subsequently use the rule outside the laboratory. Larrick, Morgan, Nisbett (1990, 1993)Simonson, Staw (1992)Accountability (expectation that at some point in the future one might be required to justify ones decision to other people) do not necessarily reduce the sunk cost bias. This is consistent with the notion that accountability effects in decision making are driven by the desire to be favourably evaluated and avoid criticism by others. Simonson, Nye (1992)Sunk cost effects are mitigated by explicit

Page 107: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

103

estimating the future returns the given options might yield. Tan, Yates (1995)Observing the budgeting process suggests that people are only likely to escalate commitment when they fail to set a budget or when expenses are difficult to track. Heath (1995)The level of training, as measured by the number of college courses in managerial accounting, is found to be positively correlated with performance (by making less use of sunk cost information), while the level of experience, as measured by years of financially-related work, is not. Justification is found to improve decisions only for those participants with significant work experience. Fennema, Perkins (2007)

Numbers in brackets [ ] indicate (most) likely relevance for different characteristics of financial capability [1] being able to manage money; [2] keeping track of finances; [3] planning ahead; [4] making informed decision about financial product; [5] staying up to date about financial matters;

The Taxonomy is in parts structured according Arnott (2002).

Page 108: Consumer research: Financial Capability: A Behavioural ... · PDF fileFinancial Capability: A Behavioural Economics Perspective ... successful record of consumer research by ... "Financial

The Financial Services Authority25 The North Colonnade Canary Wharf London E14 5HSTelephone: +44 (0)20 7066 1000 Fax: +44 (0)20 7066 1099Website: http://www.fsa.gov.ukRegistered as a Limited Company in England and Wales No. 1920623. Registered Office as above.