23
Chapter 10 Circular Economy Policy in Korea Ick Jin National Assembly Budget Office September 2016 This chapter should be cited as Jin, I. (2016), ‘Circular Economy Policy in Korea ’, in Anbumozhi, V. and J. Kim (eds.), Towards a Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways. ERIA Research Project Report 2014-44, Jakarta: ERIA, pp.163-184.

Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

Chapter 10

Circular Economy Policy in Korea Ick Jin National Assembly Budget Office

September 2016

This chapter should be cited as

Jin, I. (2016), ‘Circular Economy Policy in Korea ’, in Anbumozhi, V. and J. Kim (eds.), Towards a Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways. ERIA Research Project Report 2014-44, Jakarta: ERIA, pp.163-184.

Page 2: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

Chapter 10

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

Ick Jin

National Assembly Budget Office

1. Background Information

1.1. Background of Korea’s Circular Economy

The linear approach to industrialisation has been successful in the Republic of Korea

(henceforth, Korea) for decades. Korea’s gross domestic product (GDP) currently ranks

relatively high in the world. It also has a very high Human Development Index (HDI), used as

the common measure of the quality of life in the world. However, because Korea faces

environmental resource constraints, it needs to replace its linear approach to industrialisation

with circular economy, a new economic model. The binding environmental resources of Korea

have become a stringent constraint as a consequence of its accelerated economic growth.

Greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions have rapidly increased in the course of Korea’s

manufacturing-focused industrial development. Between 1990 and 2012, the country’s GHG

emissions more than doubled, from 295.5 million tonnes to 688.3 million tonnes of CO2

equivalent. One of the largest energy consumers in the world, it has also become one of the

largest emitters of CO2. As of 2012, Korea’s CO2 emissions accounted for 4.9 percent of the

OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) total,1 making it the fourth

largest of OECD’s CO2 emitters.

GHG emissions cause climate change,2 which in turn can cause super typhoons, floods, severe

heat waves, intense cold spells, super hurricanes, droughts, desertification, collapse of

ecosystems, food shortages, water resource depletion, contagious disease outbreaks, climate

refugees, etc. Without appropriate mitigation actions, climate change will damage up to 20

percent of the global GDP (Stern, 2006).

1 For more details, see IEA (2014). 2 As much as 97–98 percent of climate scientists believe that GHG emissions cause climate change. For

more details, see Anderegg et al. (2010).

Page 3: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

164

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

Recognising that climate change is taking its toll on the globe, Korea has taken substantial

actions to transit into a circular economy. Selected examples of historical, legislative, and

country-specific actions may be categorised into target management system (TMS), resource

efficiency programme (REP), energy recovery3 programme (ERP), recycling technology

programme (RTP), and emission trading system (ETS).

1.2. Motivation Underlying Policy Intervention

Korea has adopted various policy instruments to transform a linear economy into a circular

one. Although each of the instruments appears independent from one another, all

instruments are underlined by a common motivation. The Kaya identity4 can be used to better

understand the common underlying motivation. It decomposes per capita GHG emissions into

three components,5 generally presented in the form:

C

P=

G

E

C

E (Eq. 1)

where C, P, G, and E represent GHG emissions, population, GDP, and primary energy

consumption, respectively. The identity expresses, for a given time, per capita GHG emissions

as the product of per capita economic output (G/P), energy intensity of the economy (E/G),6

and carbon intensity of the energy mix (C/E). In this analysis, we use CO2 emissions for C, GDP

in 2005 thousand US$ using purchasing power parities (PPP) for G, and total primary energy

supply (TPES) for E.

The rate of change (ROC) of each component could be useful to see how the current quantity

changes in relation to the prior quantity. Because of possible non-linear interactions between

terms, the sum of the percentage changes of the three components would not generally add

up to the percentage change of per capita CO2 emissions. However, ROC of per capita CO2

emissions in time can be obtained from ROCs of three components as follows:

(𝐶 𝑃⁄ )𝑡

(𝐶 𝑃⁄ )𝑠=

(𝐺 𝑃⁄ )𝑡

(𝐺 𝑃⁄ )𝑠×

(𝐸 𝐺⁄ )𝑡

(𝐸 𝐺⁄ )𝑠×

(𝐶 𝐸⁄ )𝑡

(𝐶 𝐸⁄ )𝑠 (Eq. 2)

where t and s represent, for example, 2 different years.

3 Energy recovery includes any technique or method of minimising the input of energy to an overall

system by the exchange of energy from one sub-system of the overall system with another. The energy can be in any form in either subsystem, but most energy recovery systems exchange thermal energy in either sensible or latent form (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Energy_recovery).

4 For more details, see Yamaji et al. (1991). 5 The three components should be considered neither as fundamental driving forces in themselves nor

as generally independent from each other. For more details, see IEA (2014). 6 Energy intensity of the economy (E/G) is a measure of the energy efficiency of a national economy,

and is calculated as units of energy consumption per unit of GDP. High/low energy intensities indicate a high/low price or cost of converting energy into GDP.

Page 4: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

165

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

Table 10.1 shows the ROC of per capita CO2 emissions in Korea, compared with the OECD total.

As of 2012, Korea’s ROC of per capita CO2 emissions was greater than 2. It means that Korea’s

per capita CO2 emissions more than doubled in 2 decades. In contrast, OECD total’s ROC was

less than 1; that is, per capita CO2 emissions in OECD total decreased over the period.

Table 10.1. Rate of Change in CO2 Emissions per Capita

Korea OECD total 1990 (A)

2012 (B)

ROC (C=B/A)

1990 (A)

2012 (B)

ROC (C=B/A)

C/P1 5.34 11.86 2.22 10.41 9.68 0.93 CO2 = carbon dioxide, OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ROC = rate of change. 1 In tonnes of CO2 per head. Source: IEA and authors’ calculations.

The Kaya identity in Eq. 1 would help understand what caused the drastic increase of per

capita CO2 emissions (C/P) in Korea. Table 10.2 shows that the growth of per capita economic

output (G/P) was a driving force behind it. Korea’s ROC of the component outstripped OECD

total’s by a large margin. The force was more than offsetting the reduction of the other two

components. Even more, Korea’s energy intensity of the economy (E/G) decreased less than

OECD total’s.

Table 10.2. Rate of Change in Emission Drivers

Korea OECD total 1990 (A)

2012 (B)

ROC (C=B/A)

1990 (A)

2012 (B)

ROC (C=B/A)

G/P1 10.90 27.99 2.57 22.80 31.25 1.37 E/G2 0.83 0.79 0.95 0.78 0.56 0.72 C/E3 0.59 0.54 0.91 0.59 0.55 0.94

OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ROC = rate of change. 1 In thousand 2005 US$ using purchasing power parities per head. 2 In petajoules per billion 2005 US$ using purchasing power parities. 3 In thousand tonnes of CO2 per petajoules. Source: IEA and authors’ calculations.

The result points out that Korea has relied on a linear approach to industrialisation. Kaya’s

identity suggests a strong correlation between C/P and G/P with all other factors held

constant. An implicit trade-off exists between emission reduction and economic growth. Any

effective regulation to reduce C/P is likely to hamper G/P in a linear approach. Thus, Korea

should find novel ways of decoupling economic growth from environmental constraints. It is

the underlying motivation why Korea tries pre-emptively to transform a linear economy into

a circular one.

Page 5: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

166

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

1.3. Framework of Analysis

The Kaya identity may serve well as a framework for this analysis. The decomposition points

to the possibility that a well-designed mix of policy instruments would facilitate the shift to a

circular economy. The goal is to search an optimal policy mix that would promote the

transformation into a circular economy at a low cost. It explains why Korea has designed a

national strategy which tries to implement various policy instruments in a cost-effective way.

Corresponding to Kaya’s components, five critical policy instruments can be highlighted: TMS,

REP, ERP, RTP, and ETS. Table 10.3 proposes the correspondence between Kaya’s components

and selected policy categories. TMS may be the most effective measure from the perspective

of global warming. Penalty (or tax) issues in TMS may be an important matter of national

policy. To mitigate the implementation cost of TMS, most countries make an effort to utilise

policy categories addressed in this chapter.

Table 10.3. Correspondence between Kaya’s Components and Policy Instruments

Component Policy Category C/P Target management system

Emission trading system G/P Recycling technology programme E/G Resource efficiency programme C/E Energy recovery programme

Source: Author

2. Description of Policies Adopted

2.1. Target Management System (TMS)

TMS is closely relevant in reducing per capita GHG emissions (C/P) and, thus, is the

groundwork for the overall mitigation efforts. It could also serve to support REP, ERP, RTP,

and ETS instruments.

2.1.1. Goals

A direct goal of TMS is to reduce GHG emissions. TMS first sets the national midterm target,

then sets sectoral reduction targets for emissions-intensive sectors: power generation,

manufacturing, construction, waste management, and transport. It then imposes facility-

specific mitigation targets on preselected large-scale facilities belonging to emissions-

intensive sectors. Companies that fail to meet the targets are subject to penalties.

An ultimate goal of TMS is to engage all parts of society in GHG mitigation efforts. To do so,

TMS tries to advance regulations in collaborating with various stakeholders: agencies,

industries, and civic communities. Conditions of domestic industries would be taken into

account through negotiation with participations.

Page 6: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

167

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

2.1.2. Implementation

The workflow of TMS is subject to the Framework Act on Low Carbon Green Growth and the

Guidelines for the Operation of Target Management Scheme. As a starting point, sectors

accounting for the majority of emissions are identified. Next, controlled entities are

designated for such sectors.7 They submit reports on previous emissions to the controlling

departments. Controlling departments and the Greenhouse Gas Inventory & Research Center

of Korea (GIR) review the reports for double counting or omission. They establish facility-

specific GHG emissions targets. Then controlled entities submit implementation reports to

meet mitigation targets. They also submit emissions reports to show the year’s emissions.

Both emissions and implementation reports are first confirmed by third-party verifying

institutes and then reviewed by controlling departments. Finally, those reports are submitted

to GIR. If their implementation reports do not comply with the monitor-report-verification

standards, controlled entities may be subject to remedial measures. The whole process is

rolled out through the national GHG management system. This system collects data related

to facility-specific GHG statistics. Through the system, controlling departments can access to

GHG emissions data reported by controlled entities.

Table 10.4 shows sectoral GHG reduction targets rate by 2020 for seven sectors.

Table 10.4. Sectoral Reduction Targets by 2020

Sector Reduction

rate (%) Sector

Reduction rate (%)

Industry 18.2 Agriculture, Forestry & Fishery 5.2

Power Generation 26.7 Waste 12.3

Transport 34.3 Public 25.0

Buildings 26.9 Total 30.0

Source: Greenhouse Gas Inventory & Research Center of Korea.

2.1.3. Challenges

As a mandatory regulation, TMS brings in a number of challenges to be carefully dealt with. If

implemented inadequately, it might cause a big burden to controlled entities. Consequently,

economic growth could be hampered because of deadweight loss by poor regulation. For cost-

effectiveness, adequacy of regulation should be ensured. Guidelines related to setting targets

need to be clearly articulated in advance. Double-counting or omission of entities should also

be minutely checked. Implementation plans should be set up as accurately as possible. Since

the role of verifying institutes is critical, they should be quite well disciplined. Controlling

departments should reasonably resolve objections against designations. Altogether, prudent

7 As of 2014, controlled entities included companies with 50,000 tCO2eq of GHG emissions and 200 TJ

of energy consumption. Facilities with 15,000 t2eq of GHG emissions and 80 TJ of energy consumption were designated as controlled entities. For more details, see GIR (2014).

Page 7: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

168

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

responses to challenges would induce the efficient achievement of targets. As spotlighted in

Kaya’s identity, energy efficiency improvement and renewable energy deployment are

significant to reduce emissions. The design of TMS compatible with promoting REP and/or ERP

is another concern.

2.2. Resource Efficiency Programme (REP)

REP tries to manage the quantity of raw materials used to convert energy into GDP. Reducing

resource use can reduce GHG emissions.8 In that sense, REP corresponds to lowering the

energy intensity of the economy (E/G).9 Practically, the energy intensity could be controlled

by saving units of energy consumption per unit of GDP. The fall of E/G would result in the drop

of C/P, with all other factors held constant.

2.2.1. Goals

A direct goal of REP is to reduce the amount of resource required to provide products and

services.10 For that purpose, REP tries to adopt a more efficient production process and/or to

recycle resources. REP tends to facilitate products embodying less resource input. For

instance, energy savings are likely to reduce energy costs, but be accompanied by additional

costs of introducing an energy-efficient process. A financial cost saving to energy users can be

obtained when the former more than offsets the latter. To meet such a condition, REP

provides manufacturers with some incentives to improve their products' efficiency. REP also

induces consumers to purchase more energy-efficient products in the market place.

A more strategic goal of REP is to enhance national security. As resource efficiency is

improved, resource imports from foreign countries would decrease. Moreover, depletion of

domestic resources would be slowed down.

2.2.2. Implementation

The Ministry of Commerce, Industry and Energy, through the Korea Energy Management

Corporation (KEMCO), has operated EEPs. First, the Energy Efficiency Standards & Labelling

Program has been in use since 1992. The label on seven target items shows the energy-

efficiency grade of the model from one to five.11 The programme is authorised by the Rational

Energy Utilization Act. Next, the Certification of High Efficiency Energy-using Appliance

Program has been implemented where energy-using products with relatively high level of

8 According to the International Energy Agency, improved energy efficiency in buildings, industrial

processes, and transportation could reduce by one third the world's energy needs in 2050, and help control global emissions of greenhouse gases. For more details, see Hebden (2006).

9 In Korea, various policy instruments have been utilised to improve energy efficiency. For example, tax breaks, loan and subsidy programmes, energy conservation technologies, various pilot projects, energy exhibition and energy service companies, etc. Here, among those programmes, energy efficiency programmes are discussed in detail.

10 For example, the European Union (EU) currently measures resource productivity by European country and for the EU as a whole through the Eurostat system, and these statistics have shown a satisfying increase in resource productivity for the EU since 2000. For more details, see Resource (2015).

11 The seven target items are electric refrigerator, electric air-conditioner, incandescent bulb, fluorescent lamp, self-ballasted lamp, ballast for fluorescent lamp, and passenger car. It is to encourage efficiency in the production and use of energy.

Page 8: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

169

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

energy efficiency are certified. Government organisations should use certified products. The

programme is based on the Rational Energy Utilization Act. The Energy-Saving Office

Equipment & Home Electronics Program, a voluntary partnership between the government

and manufacturers, has also been in use since 1999. Energy-saving products are certified if

they meet the energy-efficiency guideline proposed by KEMCO.12 One of the standards is an

automatic switch to power-saving mode when not in use. Warning labels apply to products

that fail to meet the standard. The programme is based on announcement No. 1998-136 of

the Ministry of Commerce, Industry and Energy. Furthermore, the Average Fuel Economy

regulation on cars has been introduced since 2006 where the average fuel economy of all cars

sold by a manufacturer over 1 year must meet the standards. The required level varies with

engine capacity. It is patterned after the US Corporate Average Fuel Economy system.

2.2.3. Challenges

From a simple engineering perspective, the improvement of energy efficiency (E/G) would

reduce energy consumption all the time. However, energy consumption may not be reduced

by the amount predicted by the model. It is because of the direct rebound effect. As improved

energy efficiency tends to make energy services cheaper, consumption of those services may

increase. Increased consumption offsets some potential energy savings. Actually, an extensive

historical analysis of technological efficiency improvements has conclusively shown that

energy efficiency improvements are almost always outpaced by a net increase in resource

use.13 Considering the limit of REP, ERP catches our attention.

2.3. Energy Recovery Programme (ERP)

ERP has a strong connection with the carbon intensity of the energy mix (C/E). The carbon

intensity could be lowered when energy recovers from wastes. The fall of C/E is likely to cause

the drop of C/P, with all other factors held constant.

2.3.1. Goals

A goal of ERP is to increase the demand and supply of energy from waste. In Korea, 84 percent

of the energy supply comes from fossil-based energy sources. Thus, the deployment of energy

recovery is one of the key priorities to achieve a circular economy. Increasing the use of energy

from waste is the most effective strategy to move beyond oil.14 The National Strategy for

Green Growth has a target of increasing the share of renewable sources in TPES. In addition,

the government plans to increase the use of nuclear power, the least expensive means to

generate electricity and produces almost zero GHG.

12 Manufacturers of selected items can attach energy-saving labels on their products. Examples of

selected items are televisions, microwave ovens, computers, and printers. 13 For more details, see Huesemann and Huesemann (2011). 14 Reflecting such a perspective, worldwide investment in renewable energy reached US$155 billion in

2008. It was a sevenfold increase from 2002. The United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) has pointed out that the investment must more than triple until 2020 as global carbon emissions would have peaked by that time. For more details, see UNEP (2009a).

Page 9: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

170

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

An affiliate goal of ERP is to reduce the generation cost of energy from waste. It would

require substantial and continuous investment to foster renewable industries. The public

sector should execute a significant amount of research and development (R&D) investment.

2.3.2. Implementation

The most exemplary ERP is the Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS). RPS, applied to major

power generators since 2012, obliges electricity companies to produce a certain portion of

electricity from renewable sources. RPS applies to power generators with a capacity of 500

MW or more. Target generators are the Korea Water Resources Corporation and the Korea

District Heating Corporation that cover a total of 13 publicly owned and privately owned

power generators. Retail suppliers are not directly regulated under the RPS scheme.15 The

renewable portfolio of target generators started from 2 percent of all power generated in

2012. It should amount to 10 percent until 2022. Target generators are permitted to borrow

up to 20 percent of the total amount of renewable energy they require for a given year. The

borrowing comes from their renewable portfolios for the following years. They should submit

the reason for borrowing and quantity to be borrowed.

Renewable energy certificates (REC) are awarded to certified eligible facilities. A renewable

energy generator intending to qualify as an eligible facility must apply for the certification.

The generator’s renewable energy facilities should conform to designated standards for any

given renewable resource. Once certified, an eligible facility is automatically registered with

the new and renewable energy RPS management system. REC documents 1 MWh of electricity

generation from an eligible facility. It is used to demonstrate compliance with RPS

requirements.

The Ministry of Trade, Industry and Energy is responsible for announcing the amount of

energy subject to RPS and may adjust the amount every 3 years based on a review of

technology, performance, and other circumstances. RECs are issued by the Korean New and

Renewable Energy Center of the Korean Energy Management Corporation. The issuance,

trading, and tracking of RECs are done through the RPS management system.

2.3.3. Challenges

‘Not-in-my-back-yard’ (NIMBY) concerns may be a significant challenge to overall levels of

renewable energy deployment. NIMBY is mainly stirred by visual and other impacts of

renewable energy facilities and their constructions are likely to be blocked by local residents.16

Some projects might be delayed for years just because of aesthetic concerns. So, NIMBY may

cause variable or intermittent energy production.

15 It is because only one power retail distributor exists in the Korean market. Most big power generators

are still owned by the public sector. 16 For more details, see Schirber (2008).

Page 10: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

171

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

The lack of government support may be another critical challenge. The private market for

renewable energy technologies usually does not stand on its own feet. Government support

has pulled the growth of the renewable energy industry at least in the initial phase. An

exemplary programme is feed-in-tariffs. Under this programme, renewable energy generators

are able to earn a premium in accordance with the price table promulgated by the

government. Such government supports for ERP are likely to go along with the Recycling

Technology Programme (RTP).

2.4. Recycling Technology Programme (RTP)

RTP focuses on developing cutting-edge, converged recycling technology. It goes beyond a

linear relation between Kaya’s C/P and G/P components. RTP could accelerate the transit into

a circular economy by reconciling the rise of G/P with the fall of E/G or C/E.

2.4.1. Goals

A goal of RTP is to lower the share of resource-intensive industry in GDP. Korea’s economy

heavily relies on resource-intensive industries: steel, petrochemicals, and cement. They

accounted for 12 percent of total value-added as of 2008.17 A way to get away from

dependence on resource-intensive industries is to raise the share of the service sector. For

example, the service sector’s energy intensity is less than one third of the manufacturing

sector’s energy intensity.

A more ultimate goal of RTP is to build the basis for circular growth. The proper management

of electronic waste (or waste electrical and electronic equipment) has become a major

concern due to the large volumes of the waste being generated. Also, rare metals found in

discarded electronic devices can cause potential environmental impacts associated with toxic

chemicals. The potential resource recovery from electronic devices is based on the

development of recycling technology.

2.4.2. Implementation

In Korea, recycling technologies are treated as typical green technologies. The Key Green

Technology Development and Commercialization Strategies, announced in 2009, was

designed as a road map to develop green (including recycling) technologies. In the strategy,

core green technologies are categorised into five groups: (i) climate change, (ii) energy source

technology, (iii) technologies to improve efficiency, (iv) end-of-pipe technology, and (v) R&D

in virtual reality.

More recent recycling efforts in Korea include the recycling target rates, the extended

producer responsibility list, the shared responsibility of distributors with producers, and the

17 The weight is well above the OECD average of 8 percent. Actually, it is the highest in the OECD area.

Page 11: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

172

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

better collection system by local governments. Along with the development of advanced

waste recycling technology, the regulations to encourage its producers to adopt

environmentally sustainable technologies are strengthened.

In addition, the certificates programme has been introduced since 2010 where ‘green

certificates’ are awarded to qualified firms, projects, and technologies. A firm for which

certified green technology accounts for more than 30 percent of sales is certified as a ‘green

firm’. Green firms, projects, and technologies have been funded through green financial

products. Such products invest at least 60 percent of their capital in green firms and projects.

Examples are green bonds, deposits, and investment funds. Also, a green private equity fund

has been launched.18 There are tax incentives for financial instruments. Dividends and interest

from green financial products are tax-exempt up to certain ceilings.

2.4.3. Challenges

A challenge is to suppress government failures which may be brought in by RTP. Initially, RTP

has been introduced to cope with market failures. As the basic recycling technologies are still

too far from commercial viability to attract private investment, policy intervention for

recycling technology is needed. But it often brings in government failure. Unless green

certificates are well designed along with exit strategies, it would result in another disruptive

bubble. Such a risk needs to be managed pre-emptively. To avoid a bubble, RTP should be as

neutral as possible. When RTP concentrates on basic recycling technologies, side effects of

policy intervention would be minimised.

Another challenge is the reallocation of labour and capital resources across sectors during the

shift towards a circular economy. For workers, labour market flexibility to promote the

redeployment of workers is essential.19 Effective training is also critical for the shift to be

successful. In particular, it is important to facilitate the entry of new firms in green industries.

The new entry would account for a large share of radical innovations. At the same time, the

exit of firms in resource-intensive industries needs to be facilitated. Strong global

competitiveness of domestic industries is prerequisite for the adoption of new recycling

technology.

2.5. Emission Trading System (ETS)

ETS could encompass all components of Kaya’s identity. It corresponds to C/P in that it could

serve as the market pricing mechanism to meet the midterm reduction target. It could be

extended to serve as a trading platform for certificates related to other components: E/G and

C/E.

18 For more details, see UNEP (2009b). 19 For more details, see OECD (2010c).

Page 12: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

173

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

2.5.1. Goals

A main goal of ETS is to achieve GHG emissions target in a cost-effective way. ETS is a

distinguishable policy instrument based on the market mechanism. If a company needs higher

cost for voluntary mitigation, it may buy emissions permits in the market. On the other hand,

if a company needs relatively lower cost for mitigation, it may sell extra emissions permits to

gain profits. In this way, ETS helps the national GHG mitigation target to be more efficiently

achieved.

A derived goal of ETS is to relieve the industry from GHG mitigation burdens.20 Companies are

given strategic options to choose through ETS: direct mitigation, permits trading, external

mitigation, and/or permits borrowing. The company may strategically choose the most

advantageous way with the lowest cost. In that way, companies under ETS could flexibly

respond to the changes in the global carbon market.

A more ultimate goal of ETS is to establish a market-based, cost-effective stepping stone to

mutually facilitate GHG reduction and economic growth. ETS could pull a shift to a circular

economy by creating a new growth momentum suitable for a circular economy. Under a

successfully implemented ETS, emissions reduction is likely to be compatible with sustainable

economic growth.

2.5.2. Implementation

Even before the introduction of mandatory ETS, Korea had actively utilised trading

mechanisms and since 2005 has participated in Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). CDM

allows emissions-reduction projects in developing countries to earn certified emission

reduction (CER) credits. Each CER is equivalent to 1 tonne of CO2. CERs can be credited to

projects funded by non-Annex I countries’ own money. Korean investment companies have

owned CERs and sold them to any Annex-1 country in the market. In addition, the Korea

Certified Emissions Reduction (KCER) was introduced in 2005. KCER market is open to firms

that have reduced CO2 emissions by more than 500 tonnes a year. KCERs can also be traded

in the market.

In 2012, the Act on the Allocation and Trading of GHG Emission Permits paved the way for the

introduction of ETS. The mandatory ETS has been implemented since 2015. The Ministry of

Environment supervises the operation of ETS by designating participants, planning emissions

permits allocation, conducting monitoring–reporting–verification of emissions estimates, and

introducing penalties. The Permit Allocation Committee deliberates and adjusts ETS-related

major policies such as allocation plans and market stabilisation measures. GIR supports

facility-specific allocations and registries for emissions permits and offsets. Companies whose

annual emission volumes exceed a quota have to purchase extra emission rights from other

companies. The sum of emission quotas amounts to 1.59 billion tonnes. It is about 21 percent

less than the 2.02 billion tonnes suggested by companies. A quota of 15.98 billion Korean

20 GIR estimates that the mitigation cost under ETS accounts for only 32–57 percent of that under TMS.

Page 13: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

174

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

allowance units (KAUs) is allocated to each company. One KAU is equivalent to a tonne of CO2

gas. KAUs are traded at the Korea Exchange. As of 2015, 502 companies were allowed to trade

KAUs at the Korea Exchange.21

2.5.3. Challenges

A challenge is to operate ETS in a cost-effective way. Too stringent emissions quota would end

up compromising the desperate efforts to boost the sagging economy. Governments usually

encourage big companies to invest because it is one of the most time-efficient ways to

revitalise the economy. Putting a cap on emissions would compromise much of the effect,

unless ETS is operated as intended. Industrial sectors are concerned about the possible

negative impact on their international competitiveness. Manufacturing firms subject to ETS

would be reluctant to make a large-scale investment on their home soil. On the other hand,

excessive quota would cause the price of KAU to converge to zero and make ETS malfunction.

The supply–demand discrepancy may set off conflicts between controlled entities and

controlling departments.

3. Outcomes and Impacts

Up to this point, major policy instruments are identified within Kaya’s identity. The goal,

implementation, and challenges of each instrument have been discussed briefly. We now

analyse the performance of policy instruments. For that, the logic model is utilised.

The logic model is useful in evaluating the performance of government programmes whose

intended result is not to achieve a financial benefit. In such situations, a programme logic

model provides indicators in terms of output, outcome, and impact measures of performance.

The output of government programmes can be measured in terms of the amount of money

spent on a programme (e.g. their budgets), and/or the amount of work done (e.g. number of

workers or number of years spent). Often, such as in TMS, REP, ERP, RTP, and ETS, the impact

is long-term mission success far into the future. In those cases, the intermediate or shorter-

term outcome may indicate progress towards the ultimate long-term impact.

Although it is relatively easy to measure the output, it is a poor indicator of goal

achievement.22 On the other hand, the outcome is a better indicator to show that the

programme really meets the intended goals.23 Government programmes are likely to begin by

21 Examples of such companies are Samsung Electronics, Hyundai Motor, POSCO, Hyundai Heavy

Industries, and Lotte Department Store. 22 The workers may have just been 'spinning their wheels' without getting very far in terms of ultimate

results or outcomes. 23 Although outcomes are used as the primary indicators of programme success or failure, they are still

insufficient. Outcomes may easily be achieved through processes independent of the programme and an evaluation of those outcomes would suggest programme success when in fact external outputs were responsible for the outcomes. For more details, see Rossi et al. (2004).

Page 14: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

175

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

declaring grand new programmes and causes. But good beginnings do not guarantee the

success of such programmes. What matters in the end is outcome and impact. Therefore, this

analysis focuses on outcomes to evaluate the performance of government programmes.

It seems still early to verify the short-term outcome or long-term impact of policy

interventions (TMS, REP, ERP, RTP, and ETS). It would take a few more years before outcomes

of such programmes could be clearly recognisable. The logic model used in this analysis can

be regarded as a formative evaluation during implementation to offer the chance to improve

the programme. The short-term outcomes and long-term impacts of each policy instrument

are investigated here within Kaya’s identity.

3.1. Outcomes and Impacts of TMS

Since TMS was established only in 2012, reliable data about the short-term outcome are not

available yet. It may take a few years to confirm that TMS is effective in achieving the midterm

(2020) mitigation target. Although limited, some insights about the short-term outcome can

be identified in terms of per capita CO2 emissions. Table 10.5 shows that Korea’s per capita

CO2 emissions continuously increased between 2008 and 2012. The upward trend is more

clearly displayed through its ROC. On the other hand, OECD’s per capita CO2 emissions slightly

decreased during the period. The difference can be zoomed in through the comparative

indicator, which is calculated as the ratio of Korea’s per capita CO2 emissions over that of

OECD. In sum, Korea’s TMS has not achieved the expected outcome until now.

Table 10.5. Per Capita CO2 Emissions

Year Korea*

(A) OECD*

(B) ROC

(C = At / A2008) Comparative

(D = A / B)

2008 10.3 10.5 1.000 0.982

2009 10.6 9.8 1.025 1.076

2010 11.4 10.1 1.107 1.134

2011 11.8 9.9 1.147 1.198

2012 11.9 9.7 1.149 1.225

OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ROC = rate of change. * In tonnes of CO2 per head. Source: IEA and authors’ calculations.

However, Korea’s TMS has earned positive reviews for long-term impact. Its GHG reduction

efforts have been internationally recognised. For instance, Korea’s climate change policy

ranked second best in the 2010 CCPI evaluation. The pre-emptive policy intervention also

enables Korea to get well prepared for carbon-related international trade barriers. If

mitigation goals are successfully met, Korea could reinforce its international status as one of

the leading countries in GHG mitigation.

TMS has laid the groundwork for sustained reduction of GHG emissions. Cost-effective

mitigation strategies for buildings, transportation means, and industrial sectors have been set

up. It is mandatory for controlled entities to report their GHG emissions. Carbon information

Page 15: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

176

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

is more easily available through the national GHG inventory reporting system. In the end, a

long-term national GHG reduction target from 2020 onwards is about to be established.

3.2. Outcomes and Impacts of REP

The short-term outcome of TMS seems to fall short of the mark. The shortfall may be

accounted by the economic growth. It manifests the importance of controlling resource use

during the economic growth. Most of all, the output of sector-specific energy saving

programme to cut the energy intensity has been more or less effective. For example, AFE

programme boosted average fuel economy from 10.8 km/litre to 11.5 km/litre between 2006

and 2008, and contributed 7.3 percent CO2-emissions reduction.

The short-term outcome of REP can be evaluated in terms of energy intensity of the economy.

Table 10.6 shows how Korea’s energy intensity has dropped since 2008, shown more definitely

through its ROC. However, Korea falls behind OECD with respect to the pace of enhancement

in energy intensity as the comparative indicator distinctly reveals. Even worse, the gap has

been expanded. In sum, the short-term outcome of Korea’s REP can be regarded as

outstanding even though the pace needs to be accelerated.

Table 10.6. Energy Intensity

Year Korea* (A)

OECD* (B)

ROC (C = At / A2008)

Comparative (D = A / B)

2008 8.34 6.90 1.000 1.209

2009 8.41 6.83 1.008 1.231

2010 7.91 5.97 0.948 1.326

2011 7.95 5.75 0.953 1.384

2012 7.88 5.61 0.944 1.406 OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ROC = rate of change. * In petajoules per billion 2005 US$ using purchasing power parities. Source: IEA and authors’ calculations.

The long-term impact of REP would be more evident in the future. The Systematic

Implementation of the National GHG Emissions Reduction Roadmap was announced in 2014.

GHG from the transportation sector will be reduced through expansion of ITS, pay-per-mile

car insurance, car-sharing systems, and low-carbon vehicles such as the bus rapid transit. In

addition, the efficiency of various facilities and equipment will be improved. For instance, the

Building Energy Management System and the Home Energy Management System will be

introduced and disseminated. Furthermore, policies will be adopted to reduce GHG in the

areas of public sector, agriculture, forestry, fishery industries, and waste.

Page 16: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

177

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

3.3. Outcomes and Impacts of ERP

The short-term output of ERP can be shown through the contribution of energy recovery to

TPES. As of 2007, Korea’s share of non-renewable waste in TPES was one of the lowest in the

OECD area. Table 10.7 shows the weights of renewable energies and energy from waste in

TPES since 2008. The contribution from renewable energies has continuously increased, but

falls short of initial expectation. The weight of non-renewable waste remained flat until 2010,

but has jumped up since 2011.

Table 10.7. Contribution from Renewable Energies and Energy from Waste

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Renewables* 0.594 0.654 0.712 0.733 0.749

Non-renewable waste* 0.890 0.850 0.874 0.987 1.051 * % contribution to TPES (total primary energy supply). Source: IEA and authors’ calculations.

ERP to increase the demand and supply of non-renewable waste has not shown a tangible

outcome. The short-term outcome of ERP can be shown in terms of carbon intensity of energy

mix. Table 10.8 shows that Korea’s carbon intensity of energy mix presented neither an

upward nor downward trend within a 5-year span. The pattern of its ROC was practically the

same. However, the comparative indicator between Korea and OECD has fallen into a gentle

gradient since 2009, maybe due to the relatively fast uptake of low-carbon technologies in

Korea. For instance, Korea’s use of nuclear energy has been enlarged to reduce CO2 emissions

from power plants.

Table 10.8. Carbon Intensity of Energy Mix

Year Korea* (A)

OECD* (B)

ROC (C = At / A2008)

Comparative (D = A / B)

2008 52.8 55.8 1.000 0.947 2009 53.7 54.9 1.018 0.978 2010 53.9 55.2 1.021 0.976 2011 54.1 55.5 1.025 0.974 2012 53.8 55.3 1.018 0.973 OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, ROC = rate of change. * In thousand tonnes of CO2 per petajoules. Source: IEA and authors’ calculations.

3.4. Outcomes and Impacts of RTP

An output of RTP can be assessed by indicators to show the status of green R&D. Table 10.9

shows Korea’s total R&D, green technology (GT) R&D, and core GT R&D during the first-year

(2009–2013) plan. The GT R&D has increased at the compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of

11.7 percent. It is higher than the total R&D’s CAGR of 8.6 percent. It is noteworthy that the

CAGR of core GT R&D is even higher. The relatively higher CAGR suggests that more R&D

investments have been allocated to green technologies.

Page 17: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

178

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

Table 10.9. Green R&D (trillion ₩)

Year Total R&D Green Technology (GT)

R&D Core GT R&D

2009 12.41 1.95 1.43 2010 13.68 2.24 1.71 2011 14.85 2.55 1.98 2012 15.91 2.71 2.06

CAGR (%) 8.61 11.73 13.00 CAGR = compound annual growth rate, R&D = research and development, ₩ = Korean won. Source: Green Technology Center Korea.

The short-term outcome can be assessed to determine whether RTP has contributed to the

economic growth with GHG emissions controlled. Table 10.10 shows the ROC of each

component of Kaya’s identity. The declining trend in ROC of E/G shows that the short-term

outcome of REP is positive. In contrast, the flat ROC of C/E demonstrates that the short-term

outcome of ERP falls short of its goal. Much less, those outcomes are overwhelmed by

outstanding pace of economic growth (G/P). Altogether, the short-term outcome of RTP is

disputable.

Table 10.10. Rate of Change in Emission Drivers

Year C/P G/P E/G C/E

2008 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 2009 1.025 1.000 1.008 1.018 2010 1.107 1.143 0.948 1.021 2011 1.147 1.175 0.953 1.025 2012 1.149 1.195 0.944 1.018

Source: IEA and authors’ calculations.

3.5. Outcomes and Impacts of ETS

The short-term output of CDM was satisfactory. As of 2010, Korea has 35 CDM projects

registered with renewable energy projects accounting for a third of them. Another 47 projects

are in the process of registration. The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate

Change (UNFCCC) predicts that Korea’s registered projects would reduce CO2 equivalent by

an average of 15 million tonnes per year, a 4.4-percent reduction of the total. Korea ranks

fourth behind China (59 percent), India (12 percent), and Brazil (6 percent).

The short-term output of voluntary carbon market was not satisfactory. In practice, there

were few buyers, given the lack of a domestic reduction obligation. Thus, the government

bought most KCERs to compensate efforts to reduce GHG emissions. As of 2009, 5.6 million

KCERs have been generated from 287 projects. The government purchased 4.7 million of total

KCER for ₩23 billion (US$20 million).

The short-term output of ETS since its launch is disappointing. Trading has been minimal so

far because corporations are uncertain about the volume of GHG that they would emit in the

Page 18: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

179

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

future. On the first trade, KAU trading volume reached 1,190 tonnes. Additional 190 tonnes

were traded in the next 4 days. Since then, there is no trade of KAU because of shortage of

sellers in the market.

To ensure a soft landing of ETS, the offset credit trading was commenced on 6 April 2015. The

GHG emissions reduced by entities other than corporations subject to TMS are certified for

emission allowances. Corporations allotted the emission allowances can request the

conversion of the certified offset credit into Korea Credit Unit (KCU). KCUs can be traded in

the emissions trading market of Korea Exchange Corporations subject to TMS are able to trade

KAUs and KCUs. In the first week, 79,658 tonnes of KCUs were traded. The listing of KCUs is

expected to stimulate more brisk trading in the emissions trading market.

The short-term outcome of ETS is not yet certain. It can be assessed to see whether the

emissions trading market is vitalised. The successful implementation of ETS would construct

the foundation for a market-friendly, cost-effective GHG reduction. The institutional basis for

a linkage with an offset mechanism is already formed. Roles of the market and the private

sector would be broadened by successfully implementing the linkage. Eventually, enhancing

the market function of emissions reductions would spread a circular lifestyle applicable to

everyday life.

4. Implications for ASEAN Countries

Hereafter, a set of policy actions for decision makers in ASEAN are recommended. It aims to

work collectively and beyond them. Future research directions for scholars are also provided.

4.1. Setting Pre-emptive Target

Korea ratified the Kyoto Protocol to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change

(UNFCCC) as a non-Annex I country. Thus, it has no obligation to set a specific GHG-reduction

target. However, it has been pre-emptively involved in the CDM since unilateral projects were

allowed. Unilateral CDMs are funded by developing countries’ money and not by Annex-1

countries.

Finalising the national midterm target shows that Korea has pursued a pre-emptive strategy

to transit towards a circular economy. The business-as-usual scenario (BAU) was a rise of 36.9

percent in GHG emissions between 2005 and 2020. Three initially considered options were to

cut emissions by 21 percent, 27 percent, or 30 percent relative to the BAU. Those options

implied an 8-percent increase in emissions, no change, or a cut of 4 percent relative to 2005,

respectively. Each option was analysed based on Korea’s capacity to make reductions and the

subsequent macroeconomic impact. Finally, the most ambitious option of a 30-percent

reduction was selected as the national midterm target.

Page 19: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

180

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

The midterm target of Korea is thus positioned between the advanced countries and

developing countries. The 2020 targets for Japan, the US, and the EU are approximately 30-

percent, 17-percent, and 13-percent reductions relative to 2005, respectively. Those targets

still require larger emissions reductions. Mexico has also pledged to reduce emissions by up

to 30 percent relative to its BAU baseline by 2020 on the condition of adequate financial and

technology transfer mechanisms from developed countries. In contrast, Korea’s target is not

conditional on international agreements and support. Although not legally binding, the target

is guiding Korea’s climate change policy framework.

The target under TMS is highly significant as it provides a foothold prior to post-2012 climate

change negotiations. In 2015, the Korean government announced it will reduce GHG

emissions by 37 percent from the previous projected emission levels for 2030.

4.2. Comprehensive Framework

The shift to a circular economy may require a national strategy that encompasses various

policy instruments in a comprehensive framework. Individual policy instruments tend to focus

on certain aspects of the transition. The effect of an instrument might be offset by the effect

of another. Thus, it is important that policy instruments be orchestrated within a

comprehensive framework. The national strategy based on Kaya identity could be used as a

cornerstone.

Korea has made intensive efforts to develop a comprehensive strategy at the national level.

In 2008, Low Carbon/Green Growth was proclaimed as the nation’s vision to guide its

development during the next 50 years. In 2009, the first Five-Year (2008–2013) Plan for Green

Growth was announced along with the National Strategy for Green Growth to expedite policy

implementation at the central government level. Also, the midterm target for national GHG

reduction was announced. In 2010, the Framework Act on Low Carbon/ Green Growth was

enacted, covering the economy, industry, national territory, environment, and public conduct.

In 2011, the Act on the Creation and Facilitation of Use of Smart Grids was enacted as the legal

basis for building smart grids. In 2012, the Act on the Allocation and Trading of Greenhouse-

Gas Emission Permits was legislated to establish the institutional foundation of the ETS. In

2014, the second Five-Year (2014–2018) Plan for Green Growth was announced to actively

use the institutional foundation built during the past 5 years.

Developing countries like those in ASEAN may be willing to begin the shift to a circular

economy through various policy instruments. When strategically approached, it would be

helpful to derive an optimal policy mix at the national level. For instance, they may use the

national strategy and/or the 5-year plan encompassing all major policy interventions: TMS,

REP, ERP, RTP, and ETS. The successful transit towards a circular economy may require a socio-

economic system. Focused efforts through national initiatives would be essential for the

settlement of a sound institutional foundation. An example of such an initiative may be the

recycling of resources throughout the entire manufacturing process: factor input, production,

use, disposal, and recycling. The governing principle is to firmly establish 3R (reduce–reuse–

Page 20: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

181

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

recycle). ETS could easily be extended to a more comprehensive certificate trading about

resources recycling, and the twin pillars of sustainable energy policy: REP and ERP.

4.3. Taking Practical Actions

The national strategy to pursue circular economy needs to be developed. The impact of the

industry sector may be evident in a decomposition of final resource consumption by sector.

Compared with developed countries, a developing country would rely more heavily on its

industry sector. Nevertheless, the service sector’s energy intensity is generally less than that

of the manufacturing sector. Thus, a strategy to the share of service sector in total value-

added would help a developing country follow the growth path towards a circular economy.

The practical approach to dealing with oppositions from the private sector would be critical.

As mentioned, NIMBY (not-in-my-backyard) concerns are likely to be severe obstacles against

deployment of renewable energy. A national strategy to particularly develop cooperative

structures may be essential as it would help the overwhelming majority of locals believe that

renewable energy resources can enhance the neighbourhood.24 It is obvious that projects are

generally more likely to succeed if they have broad public support and the consent of local

communities. To do that, a say and a stake need to be given to communities. It is noteworthy

that many renewable energy projects are owned by communities in countries such as

Germany and Denmark.25

Policy instruments relevant to daily living activities are fundamental. Korea uses a system to

effectively collect garbage waste and reuse natural resources.26 Under the system, recycling

is mandatory, and garbage must be separated accordingly as common garbage, food waste,

recyclable, and large waste objects. Such policies exist throughout the country. Recycled items

can be disposed of in any clear plastic bag or divided by items and bound. Containers should

be rinsed or washed before disposal. Recyclable waste should be placed in designated areas

outside the building. Because some items such as batteries, cell phones, unused medicine,

etc. require careful disposal, a separate container for such items should be in place. It is

recommended that unused medicines be taken to the nearest drug store for proper disposal.

Most large apartment complexes have marked boxes for recyclables. Houses and small

apartments/villas should place in position net bags for recyclables.

4.4. Global Cooperation

A key obstacle to the implementation of ETS is concern about its impact on the international

competitiveness of domestic industries. A strict ETS may successfully reduce emissions

domestically but cause an increase in emissions in neighbouring countries, a phenomenon

called carbon leakage. If ETS of a country raises local costs, then another country without ETS

24 For more details, see Gourlay (2008). 25 For more details, see http://www.korea4expats.com/article-waste-disposal-recycling-korea.html 26 For more details, see http://www.korea4expats.com/article-waste-disposal-recycling-korea.html

Page 21: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

182

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

may have a trading advantage. If demand for these goods remains the same, production may

move offshore to the cheaper country without ETS, the reason companies seem to be overly

anxious about the burden of ETS.

Although there is yet no consensus on the magnitude of long-term leakage effects, it manifests

the importance of global cooperation. Carbon leakage is a type of spillover effect, which can

be positive or negative. For example, ETS might lead to technological developments that aid

global reductions. To amplify positive externalities, carbon leakage may be controlled through

changes in trading patterns. An exemplary case is to measure the balance of emissions

embodied in trade.

Moreover, as more countries take ETS, the positive externalities would get larger. Fortunately,

ETS has been successfully introduced in many countries and the market-based environment

policy is currently being executed in over 30 countries. In EU, ETS has been implemented since

2005. In New Zealand, a national-level ETS has been implemented since July 2010. In the US,

a state-level ETS has been implemented in California. In addition, ETS implementation has

been prepared in developing counties such as China, Taiwan, Chile, and Turkey.

Even before ASEAN member states establish ETS domestically, they could participate in CDM

projects. CDM constitutes the official international carbon market together with ETS and the

Joint Implementation under the Kyoto Protocol. CDM allows emission-reduction projects in

developing countries to earn CER credits. Non-Annex I countries owning CERs can sell them to

any Annex-1 country in the market. Annex I countries can use CERs to meet a part of their

emissions-reduction targets under the Kyoto Protocol. It would be helpful to set up the

National GHG Management System. Its role may be to operate ETS, allocating allowance unit

across sectors, and verify ETS-related statistics. The role to cooperate with international

organisations is also played by the National GHG Management System.

4.5. Maintaining Balance between Penalties and Incentives

The cost-effective implementation of policy instruments would serve as the groundwork for

national GHG mitigation efforts. For that purpose, the balance between penalties and

incentives needs to be strategically maintained.

As for the penalty, fines under TMS and taxes in energy prices can be managed. The ratio of

environmental taxes over total tax revenue may be a key indicator. Tax reforms to raise the

ratio may be considered and the share of taxes in energy prices may be another indicator. For

example, the government can raise the tax on fossil fuel–based energy sources such as diesel,

gasoline, LPG butane, light fuel, and heavy oil. The higher prices would help slow down the

consumption growth of such energy sources. Closing the gap between domestic and

international fossil fuel prices could cut GHG emissions in ASEAN countries (Burniaux et al.,

2009). Generally, feed-in-tariffs could be assessed on each energy source. The renewable

energy generators earn a premium in accordance with the price table promulgated by the

government. It usually represents the difference between the market price of electricity and

Page 22: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

183

Circular Economy Policy in Korea

the power production cost using renewable resources. Feed-in-tariffs would promote the

distribution of renewable energy technology.

As for the incentive, voluntary emissions-reduction targets may work well. The firms may be

eligible for low-interest-rate loans on energy-saving facilities, tax benefits, and technical

support. Although voluntary approaches are not cost-effective in addressing environmental

externalities, they can reveal information about abatement costs and environmental damage

at an early stage (de Serres et al., 2010).

Under the mandatory scheme, the government needs to flexibly respond to voices from

controlled entities. During the initial stage, companies under TMS and/or ETS would receive

carbon allowances for free. Revenues generated from ETS operation (fees, fines, etc.) should

be spent to advance circular economy. A couple of options can be used for TMS to operate

more smoothly. For instance, voluntary mitigation outside ETS may count towards mitigation

targets under ETS. Borrowing from future permits and banking of permits may be allowed.

Companies that overachieve mitigating targets can earn rewards by selling or banking extra

permits. Overall, public–private partnerships can be invigorated.

References

Anderegg, W., J. Prall, J. Harold, and S. Schneider (2010), ‘Expert Credibility in Climate Change’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, Vol. 107, No. 27. Available at: http://www.pnas.org/content/107/27/12107.full.pdf

Burniaux, J., J. Chateau, R. Dellink, R. Duval, and S. Jamet (2009), ‘The Economics of Climate Change Mitigation: How to Build the Necessary Global Action in a Cost-Effective Manner?’, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 701, Paris: OECD.

CGG (2014), Green Growth Korea: Now & the Future. The Committee on Green Growth. Available at: http://www.greengrowth.go.kr/wp-content/uploads/2014/12/green-eng-bro.pdf

de Serres, A., F. Murtin, and G. Nicoletti (2010), ‘A Framework for Assessing Green Growth Policies’, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 774, Paris: OECD.

DTI (2004), ‘Co-operative Energy: Lessons from Denmark and Sweden’, Global Watch Mission Report, Department of Trade and Industry (UK). Available at: http://www.uk.coop/sites/storage/public/downloads/36247mr_0_0.pdf

GIR (2014), 2014 National Greenhouse Gas Inventory Report of Korea. Greenhouse Gas Inventory & Research Center of Korea (in Korean).

Page 23: Circular Economy Policy in Korea (Ick Jin)

184

Towards Circular Economy: Corporate Management and Policy Pathways

Gourlay, S. (2008), ‘Wind farms are not only beautiful, they're absolutely necessary’, The Guardian (UK). Available at: http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2008/aug/12/windpower.alternativeenergy (accessed 30 April 2015).

Huesemann, M. and J. Huesemann (2011), ‘Technofix: Why Technology Won’t Save Us or the Environment’, in In Search of Solutions II: Efficiency Improvements. Canada: New Society Publishers.

IEA (2013), Energy Balances of OECD Countries. IEA Statistics.

IEA (2014), CO2 Emissions from fuel combustion: Highlights. IEA Statistics.

Hebden, S. (2006), ‘Invest in clean technology says IEA report’. Scidev.net. Available at: http://www.scidev.net/global/biofuels/news/invest-in-clean-technology-says-iea-report.html (accessed 30 April 2015).

OECD (2010c), OECD Economic Survey of Korea, Paris: OECD.

PCGGK (2009), Road to Our Future Green Growth: National Strategy and the Five-Year Plan (2009~2013). Presidential Commission on Green Growth Republic of Korea. Available at: http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/resource/road-our-future-green-growth-national-strategy-and-five-year-plan-2009-2013

Resource (2015), Circular Economy – State of the Nations. Available at: http://www.resource-event.com

Rossi, P., W. Lipsey, and E. Freeman (2004), Evaluation: A systematic approach (7th ed.). Thousand Oaks. CA: Sage.

Schirber, M. (2008), ‘Whatever Happened to Wind Energy?’. LiveScience. Available at: http://www.livescience.com/2211-happened-wind-energy.html (accessed 30 April 2015).

Stern, N. (2006), The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge University Press.

UNEP (2009a), Global Trends in Sustainable Energy Investment 2009. UNEP. New York.

UNEP (2009b), Overview of the Republic of Korea’s Green Growth National Vision: An Interim Report. UNEP: New York.

Yamaji, K., R. Matsuhashi, Nagata, and Y. Kaya (1991), ‘An integrated system for CO2/Energy/GNP analysis: case studies on economic measures for CO2 reduction in Japan’, In Proceedings from Workshop on CO2 reduction and removal: measures for the next century. International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis.