25
• Chapter 5 Choice • Budget set + preference → choice • Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A w B for any B in the budget set) ↔ the set of consumption bundles which is strictly preferred to A by this consumer cannot intersect with the budget set. ( 月月月月月 )

Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Fig. 5.1

Citation preview

Page 1: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• Chapter 5 Choice• Budget set + preference → choice• Optimal choice: choose the best one can

afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A w B for any B in the budget set) ↔ the set of consumption bundles which is strictly preferred to A by this consumer cannot intersect with the budget set. ( 月亮形區域 )

Page 2: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• A optimal↔ 月亮形區域為空 .• A optimal → 月亮形區域為空 ? If not,

then 月亮形區域不為空 , that means there exists a bundle B such that B s A and B is in the budget set. Then A is not optimal.

• A optimal ← 月亮形區域為空 ? All B such that B s A is not affordable, so for all B in the budget set, we must have A w B. Hence A is optimal.

Page 3: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 4: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• The indifference curve tangent to the budget line is neither necessary nor sufficient for optimality.

• Not necessary: kinked preferences (perfect complements), corner solution (vs. interior solution) (!!) (intuition)

• Not sufficient: satiation or convexity is violated

Page 5: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• Not necessary: kinked preferences (perfect complements), corner solution (vs. interior solution) (!!) (intuition)

• Not sufficient: satiation or convexity is violated

optimumsufficient

necessary

Page 6: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 7: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 8: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 9: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 10: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• The usual tangent condition MRS1, 2= -p1/ p2 has a nice interpretation. The MRS is the rate the consumer is willing to pay for an additional unit of good 1 in terms of good 2. The relative price ratio is the rate the market asks a consumer to pay for an additional unit of good 1 in terms of good 2. At optimum, these two rates are equal. ( 主觀相對價格 vs. 客觀相對價格 )

Page 11: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• |MRS1, 2| > p1/ p2, buy more of 1• |MRS1, 2| < p1/ p2, buy less of 1• We now know what the optimal choice is,

let us turn to demand since they are related.

• The optimal choice of goods at some price and income is the consumer’s demanded bundle. A demand function gives you the optimal amount of each good as a function of prices and income faced by the consumer.

Page 12: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• x1 (p1, p2, m): the demand function• At p1, p2, m, the consumer demands x1

• Perfect substitutes: (graph) u(x1, x2) = x1 + x2

p1 > p2: x1 = 0, x2 = m/ p2

p1 = p2: x1 belongs to [0, m/ p1] and x2 = (m- p1 x1)/p2

p1 < p2: x1 = m/ p1, x2 = 0

Page 13: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 14: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• Perfect complements: (graph) u(x1, x2) = min{x1, x2} x1 = x2 = m/ (p1+ p2)• Neutrals or bads: why spend money on

them?• Discrete goods (just foolhardily compare)• Non convex preferences: corner solution

Page 15: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 16: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 17: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 18: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• Cobb-Douglas: u(x1, x2) = a lnx1 + (1-a) lnx2

|MRS1, 2| = p1/ p2, so (a/x1)/[(1-a)/x2] = p1/ p2. This implies that a/(1-a) = p1x1/ p2x2, so x1 = am/ p1 and x2 = (1-a)m/ p2. This is useful if when we are estimating utility functions, we find that the expenditure share is fixed.

Page 19: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

Table 5.1

Page 20: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• Implication of the MRS condition: at equilibrium, we don’t need to know the preferences of each individual, we can infer that their MRS’ are the same. (This has an useful implication for Pareto efficiency as we will see later.)

Page 21: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• One small example: butter (price:2) and milk (price: 1)

• A new technology that will turn 3 units of milk into 1 unit of butter. Will this be profitable?

• Another new tech that will turn 1 unit of butter into 3 units of milk. Will this be profitable?

Page 22: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• Choosing taxes: quantity tax and income tax

• Suppose we impose a quantity tax of t dollars per unit of x1. budget constraint: (p1+t) x1 + p2 x2 = m

optimum: (x1*, x2*) so that (p1+t) x1* + p2 x2* = m

income tax R* to raise the same revenue: R* = t x1*

Page 23: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• optimum at income tax: p1 x1’+ p2 x2’ = m - R*, so (x1*, x2*) is affordable at the case of the income tax. hence, (x1’, x2’) w (x1*, x2*). (graph)

Page 24: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A
Page 25: Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A

• Income tax better than quantity tax? two caveats: one consumer, uniform income tax vs.

uniform quantity tax (think about the person who does not consume good 1)

tax avoidance or income tax discourages earning

ignore supply side