Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    1/11

    http://cnc.sagepub.com/Capital & Class

    http://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83

    The online version of this article can be found at:

    DOI: 10.1177/0309816801075001072001 25: 83Capital & Class

    Bob JessopState theory, regulation, and autopoiesis: debates and controversies

    Published by:

    http://www.sagepublications.com

    On behalf of:

    Conference of Socialist Economists

    can be found at:Capital & ClassAdditional services and information for

    http://cnc.sagepub.com/cgi/alertsEmail Alerts:

    http://cnc.sagepub.com/subscriptionsSubscriptions:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:

    http://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83.refs.htmlCitations:

    What is This?

    - Jan 1, 2001Version of Record>>

    by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Daniel Silva on November 1, 2013cnc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83http://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83http://www.sagepublications.com/http://www.sagepublications.com/http://www.cseweb.org.uk/http://cnc.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://cnc.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://cnc.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://cnc.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83.refs.htmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83.full.pdfhttp://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83.full.pdfhttp://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/http://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83.full.pdfhttp://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83.refs.htmlhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://cnc.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://cnc.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://www.cseweb.org.uk/http://www.sagepublications.com/http://cnc.sagepub.com/content/25/3/83http://cnc.sagepub.com/
  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    2/11

    83State theory, regulation, and autopoiesis

    This contribution briefly reviews the role of various

    debates in Capital & Class and its predecessor, the

    Bulletin of the Conference of Socialist Economists, in

    the development of my own work over the last years.

    These debates concern Marxist state theory; Fordism

    and post-Fordism; the regulation approach; the

    relevance of autopoiesis to Marxist analysis; and, most

    recently, critical realism. Other issues and problems

    have also influenced my work, of course, but several

    important theoretical turns have been prompted by

    challenges raised by CSE members.

    L claimed there were three major sources

    of Marxism: German philosophy, English economics,

    and French politics. Althusser added that Marxs

    ability to synthesize them derived from his commitment to

    proletarian revolution. My work takes Marxs critique of

    political economy as a primary reference point and is

    therefore imprinted by its three sources too. But it also has

    its own secondary set of sources. These can be described,

    only half-jokingly, as German politics, French economics,

    and Chilean biology. This is certainly how they have been

    (mis)perceived by some critics in Capital & Class. Moreover,

    alongside the various intellectual issues that drew me to these

    State theory, regulation, andautopoiesis: debates andcontroversies

    Bob Jessop

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    3/11

    Capital & Class #7584

    particular sources, I also used them to address the

    peculiarities of postwar Britain. For much of my work over

    years has been driven by the attempt to understand issues

    such as Britains flawed Fordism, its Keynesian welfare

    national state, Thatcherism, and New Labour (for a first

    attempt to address most of these issues, see Jessop ).

    The influence of German politics began indirectly in

    the mid-s through the Bulletin of the Conference of Socialist

    Economists and the seminars on state theory, in which

    John Holloway and Sol Picciotto introduced the German

    state debate to anglophone comrades. From , I also

    pursued this source more directly through German-language

    texts and contacts with German theorists. Their influence is

    clear in my work on the changing forms and functions of

    the capitalist state but it co-existed with the influence of

    Gramsci and Poulantzas (Jessop , ). It was Poulan-

    tzass influence that prompted some critics to attack my

    work for its politicism. This allegedly accords primacy to

    the state without grounding politics in the capital relation

    and/or the unceasing class struggles around that relation.

    Politicism is said to derive from the reification of the various

    fetishised institutional forms of capitalism and to lead to

    voluntarism in theory and practice. Simon Clarke ()

    argued that the Poulantzasian interest in the relative power

    of different fractions of capital in the power bloc tended

    towards instrumentalism and voluntarism and ignored the

    underlying objective, contradictory dynamic of capital

    accumulation. Werner Bonefeld () and John Holloway

    () also criticised treatments of the state as an institutional

    ensemble that is (relatively) autonomous. In particular they

    claimed theories of relative autonomy neglected the deter-

    mining role of the capital relation and failed to see that the

    economic and political actually comprise a dialectical

    separation-in-unity rather than two distinct institutional

    spheres.

    These were important challenges and, whilst not wholly

    convinced, I did wonder how to analyse the economy

    consistently with my strategic-relational approach to the

    state. Initially my ideas developed through reading debates

    on the value form and re-reading Gramscis work on

    Americanism and Fordism. This led to my account of

    accumulation strategies as means of imposing substantive

    unity on different forms of value (Jessop ). At the time I

    thought these reflections could offer a neo-Gramscian

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    4/11

    85State theory, regulation, and autopoiesis

    analysis of the economy corresponding to the insight that

    the state is a social relation. With hindsight, these reflections

    were also politicist, however, because they focused on the

    national states role in formulating accumulation strategies

    and ignored other political scales as well as the role of firms,

    fractions of capital, and other economic, political, and social

    forces. These problems have been addressed in more recent

    work (see below).

    I first formulated these ideas by developing analogies

    between Gramscis account of lo stato integrale (the integral

    state) and leconomia integrale(the integral economy). Thus,

    if Gramsci defined the state in its inclusive sense as political

    society + civil society and saw state power in western

    societies as based on hegemony armoured by coercion, a

    regulationist account might interpret the economy in its

    inclusive sense as comprising an accumulation regime +

    social mode of economic regulation and capital

    accumulation as involving the self-valorization of capital

    in and through regulation. Shortly after formulating these

    neo-Gramscian ideas, I became interested in French

    economics in the guise of the Parisian regulation school.

    This is reflected in my work on the crisis of Atlantic Fordism

    and the transition to post-Fordism and the possibilities of

    delineating a post-Fordist form of state analogous to the

    Keynesian welfare national state. Michel de Vroey, who

    provided the first extended overview of this school in Capital

    & Class(),1 reinforced this interest in French economics

    when he invited me to join the organizing committee of the

    International Conference on Regulation (). More

    generally my work on regulation has evolved in dialogue

    not only with French economics but also with some West

    German state theorists whose work on the changing forms

    and functions of the state has also been informed by the

    regulation approach. This engagement with the German

    debate once again provoked the wrath of Holloway and

    Bonefeld, this time for its alleged reformist reformulation

    of Marxist state theory and for naturalizing rather than

    resisting the transition to post-Fordism (Bonefeld a;

    Holloway ).

    Whilst working on regulation I continued to reflect on

    the relative autonomy of the state and the question of

    politicism and began to consider the apparently autonomous

    logic of market forces. This posed interesting issues about

    how the economic and political orders come to be

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    5/11

    Capital & Class #7586

    structurally coupled to produce an historic bloc (Gramscis

    term for the mutually reinforcing correspondence of

    economic base and politico-ideological superstructure) as

    well as about the conditions, if any, under which they can be

    coordinated strategically by a power bloc. As I was attempting

    to combine German politics and French economics I came

    across Chilean biology, if not directly, at least by way of

    German social theorists, especially Niklas Luhmann,

    Gunther Teubner, and Helmut Willke. From them I took

    the concept of autopoiesis or self-production. Transposed

    (some would say illegitimately) from cell biology to

    sociology, autopoietic theory suggests that major societal

    sub-systems (such as law, politics, the economy, and science)

    can be studied as self-referential, self-reproducing, and self-

    regulating. Such systems constitute their own boundaries,

    re-create the conditions for their internal operations, and

    develop according to their own operational logic rather than

    obeying an external logic. Drawing on these ideas suggests

    that historic blocs could be understood in terms of the path-

    dependent structural coupling of two operationallyautonomous

    but substantivelyinterdependentsubsystems, the path-shaping

    efforts of economic and political forces to influence (or

    govern) the nature and direction of this co-evolution, and

    the ecological dominance of the market-mediated, self-

    valorising capitalist economy.2 Needless to say, this flirtation

    with Luhmannian theory incurred the ire of open marxists,

    most notably in Werner Bonefelds critique of the eclecticism

    and conservatism involved in critical realism, Luhmannian

    theory, and work on Fordism and post-Fordism (b,

    ). As my colleague, Colin Hay () wrote an effective

    counter-critique, I decided not to reply directly. Instead I

    chose to respond indirectly in my later work.

    Thus, during the last years, my theoretical work has

    developed in three main directions. First, further rounds of

    theoretical and empirical work have led me back to the value

    form to reground regulationism in Marxs critique of

    political economy. This is my latest attempt to develop state

    theory in response to the problem of politicism and, in

    particular, to reintegrate the analysis of economics and

    politics without conflating them or subsuming them under

    a generic logic of accumulation (see below). Second, I have

    become more interested in problems of scale in analyzing

    the changing economic and political dynamic of capitalism

    especially in the dialectic of globalization-regionalization

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    6/11

    87State theory, regulation, and autopoiesis

    and the future of the national state in an era of globalizing

    capitalism. This is reflected in work on cross-border regions,

    urban politics, the entrepreneurial city, globalization, and

    the post-national state (see Jessop , a, b, a,

    b). This attempts to redress the national focus of my

    previous work on accumulation strategies and to address

    the rescaling of economics and politics. Third, I have explored

    the changing forms and modalities of state intervention in

    reproducing the economic and extra-economic conditions

    for accumulationespecially the shift from imperative

    coordination to public-private partnership, networking, and

    other forms of self-organization and self-regulation. This is

    reflected in work on the emerging significance and limitations

    of governance (self-organization) and the enhanced role of

    states (on different scales) in meta-governance, i.e.,

    organizing the conditions for self-organization. This work

    is a further development of concerns with autopoiesis applied

    on an institutional level to the complexities of the globalizing

    economy (Jessop b, b, c,b).

    Given the limited space available here, I concentrate on

    the first set of developments. Marx identified a fundamental

    contradiction in the commodity form between exchange-

    and use-value. On this basis he unfolded the complex nature

    of the capitalist mode of production and its dynamic; and

    showed both the necessity of periodic crises and their role

    in re-integrating the circuit of capital as a basis for renewed

    expansion. In turn I have suggested that all forms of the

    capital relation embody different but interconnected versions

    of this contradiction and that they impact differentially on

    (different fractions of) capital and (different strata of) labour

    at different times and places. These contradictions are

    reproduced along with capitalism but do not keep the same

    weight or significance. In addition, the reproduction of these

    contradictions with their contradictory effects and their

    impact on the historical tendency of capitalist development

    depends on the class struggle (Poulantzas , -, italics

    in original). This is the vector that realizes contradictions

    and dilemmas in specific conjunctures. Indeed, as Holloway

    argues, there is no distinction to be made between contradiction

    and struggle: all social contradictions are relations of struggle,

    and therefore undetermined, uncertain, wide open (a:

    ).

    Drawing on these arguments, I have argued that

    capitalism needs regulating because of the indeterminate

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    7/11

    Capital & Class #7588

    but antagonistic nature of the capital relation. This has three

    key aspects: (a) the constitutive incompleteness of the capital

    relation such that its reproduction depends, in an unstable

    and contradictory way, on changing extra-economic

    conditions; (b) the various structural contradictions and

    strategic dilemmas inherent in the capital relation and their

    forms of appearance in different accumulation regimes,

    modes of regulation, and conjunctures; and (c) conflicts over

    the regularization and/or governance of these contradictions

    and dilemmas as they are expressed both in the circuit of

    capital and the wider social formation. The first point refers

    to the inherent incapacity of capitalism to reproduce itself

    wholly through the value form. For accumulation depends

    on an unstable balance between three moments: the extension

    of commodity relations, the reproduction-regulation of

    fictitious commodities (notably land, labour power, money,

    and knowledge), and the maintenance of capitals key extra-

    economic supports. This rules out the eventual com-

    modification of everything and poses major problems of the

    regularization of the capital relation. This is reflected in

    cycles of commodification, de-commodification, and re-com-

    modification as the struggle to extend the exchange-value

    moments of the capital relation encounters real structural

    limits and/or increasing resistance and seeks new ways to

    overcome them. It is also reflected in less frequent but more

    radical crises of specific accumulation regimes and their

    spatio-temporal fixes emerge in and through social struggles

    over the basic forms of the capital relation.

    Second, the various structural contradictions and strategic

    dilemmas inherent in the capital relation all express the basic

    contradiction between exchange- and use-value. For example,

    productive capital is both abstract value in motion (notably

    in the form of realized profits available for re-investment)

    and a concrete stock of time- and place-specific assets in the

    course of being valorized; the worker is both an abstract

    unit of labour-power substitutable by other such units (or,

    indeed, other factors of production) and a concrete individual

    with specific skills, knowledge, and creativity; the wage is

    both a cost of production and a source of demand; money

    functions both as an international currency exchangeable

    against other currencies (ideally in stateless space) and as

    national3 money circulating within national societies and

    subject to state control; land functions both as a form of

    property (based on the private appropriation of nature)

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    8/11

    89State theory, regulation, and autopoiesis

    deployed in terms of expected rents and as a natural resource

    (modified by past actions) that is more or less renewable

    and recyclable; knowledge is both a source of profit in the

    form of intellectual property rights and a collectively

    produced intellectual commons. Likewise, the state is responsible

    for certain key conditions for the valorization of capital and

    the social reproduction of labour power and also has overall

    political responsibility for maintaining social cohesion in a

    class-divided social formation.

    Such contradictions and dilemmas can assume different

    forms and primacies. They often find expression in different

    agents, institutions, and systems as the prime bearers of one

    or other of their aspects. They can also prove more or less

    manageable depending on the specific spatio-temporal fixes

    and institutionalized class compromises with which they

    may be linked. However, insofar as these compromises

    marginalize forces that act as bearers of functions or

    operations essential to long-run accumulation, the emergence

    of significant imbalances, disproportionalities, or disunity

    in the circuit of capital will tend to strengthen these

    marginalized forces and enable them to disrupt the

    institutionalized compromises associated with a particular

    accumulation regime, mode of regulation, state form, and

    spatio-temporal fix (Clarke ). Such crises typically act

    as a steering mechanism for the always provisional, partial,

    and unstable re-equilibration of capital accumulation.

    Third, modes of regulation and governance vary widely.

    This follows from the constitutive incompleteness of the

    capital relation and the variety of accumulation regimes and

    modes of regulation. There are different ways to seek to

    close the circuit of capital and compensate for its lack of

    closure. Which of these comes to dominate depends on the

    specific social and spatio-temporal frameworks within which

    these attempts occur. Indeed, notwithstanding the tendency

    for capital accumulation to produce a single world market,

    there are important counter-tendencies and other limits to

    globalization. Specific accumulation regimes and modes of

    regulation are typically constructed in specific social spaces

    and spatio-temporal matrices. This justifies work on

    comparative capitalisms and their embedding in specific

    institutional and spatio-temporal complexes; it also justifies

    exploration of the path-dependent linkages between

    different economic trajectories and broader social

    developments.

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    9/11

    Capital & Class #7590

    Conclusions

    Early debatesin Capital & Classhave continued to shape my

    work for almost years in four main ways: they introduced

    me to state theory, they posed the issue of politicism, they

    challenged me to justify my flirtation with theories of

    autopoiesis, and they have prompted me to justify the critical

    realist approach that informs my analyses (on the last of

    these issues, see Jessop c). The biggest challenge has

    been to respond to the charge of politicism and, in this regard,

    my Capital & Class critics have been constant critical

    members of my imagined intellectual community as I have

    developed my work. I have obviously continued to disagree

    with many of their criticisms but I have not ignored them.

    Without such criticisms I doubt that I would have arrived at

    my current interpretations of: (a) the states role in regulari-

    zing the conditions for accumulation through providing an

    improbable, provisional, and unstable spatio-temporal fix

    for specific accumulation regimes; (b) the many different

    contradictions in the capital relation that are reproduced

    and inflected in specific ways and with specific weights through

    class struggle and institutionalized in specific accumulation

    regimes and modes of regulation; or (c) the ecological

    dominance of the capital relation as a way to rethink the

    problem of economic determination in the last instance.

    These current interpretations have also involved debates and

    discussions in other contexts too (most notably with Stuart

    Hall on the nature of Thatcherism in New Left Review and,

    indirectly, with Laclau and Mouffes post-Marxist discourse

    analysis). They also depend on several other theoretical

    turnsincluding an institutional turn, a narrative turn, a

    governance turn, and a scalar turn. But, in the spirit of an

    open Marxism that I understood rather differently from my

    critics, an often subterranean influence has continued.

    Notes

    1. De Vroey is not himself a Parisian regulationist but a Flemish

    institutional economist.

    2. Ecological dominance refers to the capacity of a given system in a self-

    organising ecology of self-organising systems to imprint its

    developmental logic on other systems operations through structural

    coupling, strategic co-ordination, and blind co-evolution to a greater

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    10/11

    91State theory, regulation, and autopoiesis

    extent than the latter can impose their respective logics on that system.

    I argue that the self-valorization of capital makes the capitalist economy

    ecologically dominant in contemporary societies and that neo-liberal

    globalization reinforces this tendency (Jessop 2000a).

    3. Plurinational monetary blocs organized by states could also be

    included here.

    References

    Bonefeld, W. (1987) Reformulation of State Theory,Capital & Class,

    33, pp.96-127.

    _______ (1993a) Some Notes on the Theory of the Capitalist State,

    Capital & Class, 49, pp.113-21.

    _______ (1993b) Crisis of Theory: Bob Jessops Theory of Capitalist

    Reproduction, Capital & Class, 50, pp.25-48.

    _______ (1994) Aglietta in England: Bob Jessops Contribution to

    the Regulation Approach,Futur antrieur, special issue, pp.299-

    330.

    Clarke, S. (1977) Marxism, Sociology, and Poulantzass Theory of the

    State, Capital & Class, 2, pp.1-31.

    _______ (1988) Overaccumulation, Class Struggle and the

    Regulation Approach,Capital & Class, 36, pp.59-92.

    _______ (1991) New Utopias for Old: Fordist Dreams and Post-

    Fordist Fantasies, Capital & Class, 42, pp.131-53

    Hay, C.S. (1995) Werner in Wunderland,Futur antrieur, special issue,

    pp.331-359.

    Holloway, J. (1988) The Great Bear, Post-Fordism and Class Struggle:

    a Comment on Bonefeld and Jessop, Capital & Class, 36, 93-104

    _______ (1994) Global Capital and the National State,Capital &

    Class, 52, pp.25-30.

    _______ (1993a) Open Marxism, history and class struggle. Some

    comments on Heide Gerstenbergers book Die subjektlose Gewalt:

    Theorie der Entstehung brgerliche Staatsgewalt, Common Sense, 13,

    pp.76-86.

    Jessop, B. (1977) Recent Theories of the Capitalist State,Cambridge

    Journal of Economics, 1 (4), pp.353-373.

    _______ (1980) The Transformation of the State in Postwar Britain,

    in R. Scase, ed., The State inWestern Europe, London: Croom Helm,

    pp.23-94.

    _______ (1982) The Capitalist State: Marxist Theories and Methods,

    Oxford: Martin Robertson.

    _______ (1983) Accumulation Strategies, State Forms, and

    Hegemonic Projects,Kapitalistate, 10, pp.89-111.

  • 8/13/2019 Capital & Class 2001 Jessop 83 92

    11/11

    Capital & Class #7592

    _______ (1988) Regulation Theory, Post-Fordism, and the State: More

    than a Reply to Werner Bonefeld,Capital and Class, 34, pp.147-169.

    _______ (1990) State Theory: Bringing the Capitalist State Back In,

    Cambridge: Polity.

    _______ (1991) Polar Bears and Class Struggle: Much less than a

    Self-Criticism, in W. Bonefeld and J. Holloway, eds.,Post-Fordism

    and Social Form, London: Macmillan, pp.145-169.

    _______ (1992) Fordism and Post-Fordism: a Critical Reformulation,

    in A.J. Scott and M.J. Storper, eds., Pathways to Regionalism and

    Industrial Development, London: Routledge, pp.43-65.

    _______ (1994) The Transition to Post -Fordism and the

    Schumpeterian Workfare State, in R. Burrows and B. Loader, eds.,

    Towards a post-FordistWelfare State?, London: Routledge, pp.13-37.

    _______ (1997) A Neo-Gramscian Approach to the Regulation of

    Urban Regimes, in M. Lauria, ed., Reconstructing Urban Regime

    Theory, London: Sage, pp.51-73

    _______ (1999a) Reflections on the (Il)logics of Globalization, in

    K. Olds et al., eds., Globalization and the Asia Pacific: Contested

    Territories, London: Routledge, pp.19-38

    _______ (1999b) Narrating the Future of the National Economy and

    the National State?, in G. Steinmetz, ed.,State/Culture: State Formation

    after the CulturalTurn, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, pp.378-405.

    _______ (2000a) The Crisis of the National Spatio-Temporal Fix and

    the Ecological Dominance of Globalizing Capitalism,International

    Journal of Urban and Regional Studies, 24 (2), pp.273-310.

    _______ (2000b) From Keynesianism to Workfarism, in G. Lewis,

    ed., RethinkingWelfare Policy, London: Sage, pp.171-184.

    _______ (2000c) The Changing Governance of Welfare: Recent

    Trends in its Primary Functions, Scale, and Modes of Coordination,

    in N. Manning and I. Shaw, eds.,NewWelfare, New Risks: Signposts

    for Social Policy, Oxford: Blackwell, pp.12-23.

    _______ (2001a) What follows Fordism? On the Periodization of

    Capitalism and its Regulation, in R. Albritton et al., Phases ofCapitalist Development: Booms, Crises, and Globalization, Basingstoke:

    Palgrave, pp.282-299.

    _______ (2001b) Time and Space in the Globalization of Capital and

    their Implications for State Power, Rethinking MARXISM(in press).

    _______ (2001c) Capitalism, the Regulation Approach, and Critical

    Realism, in A. Brown, S. Fleetwood, and J. Roberts, eds, Critical

    Realism and Marxism, London: Routledge, pp.88-115.

    Poulantzas, Nicos (1975) Political Power and Social Classes, London:

    New Left Books.de Vroey, M. (1984) A Regulation Approach Interpretation of

    Contemporary Crisis,Capital & Class, 23, pp.45-66.