C0809_A2

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    1/15August-September 2008 Conjoncture 13

    During the past 5 years, unemployment has steadily

    declined in the OECD, partly as a result of labour

    market reforms. This favourable development is

    likely to end as the industrial world is entering a major

    economic downturn. Beyond these cyclical developments,

    major structural changes such as globalisation, demographicchange and climate change are posing major challenges.

    Welfare reform is likely to remain at the top the agenda in all

    the major economies. These reforms are often firmly contested

    as they imply changes in acquired rights. However, doing

    nothing is often no solution as it could create substantial

    inequities between generations. In the end, everybody might

    be worse off.

    In particular in continental Europe, many politicians

    fear that their social models will not be able to withstand

    the consequences of globalisation. They consider thesocial models of the Scandinavian countries as an

    alternative for the liberal Anglo-Saxon model. This interest

    comes at an odd moment. In particular in Denmark and

    Sweden, there is growing doubt concerning the long-term

    tenability of their economic models. In both countries, the

    latest parliamentary elections were actually won by the

    parties that campaigned for a slimmer welfare state.

    Three welfare models

    A useful classification of social welfare models has

    been proposed by Gsta Esping-Anderson(1). He

    distinguishes three types of economic models in market

    economies: the liberal-model, the conservative model,

    and the social-democratic model. The liberal model is

    largely based on personal responsibility, and government

    intervention is limited to remedy market failures. The

    social sector has mainly a safety net function. The

    system has strong incentives to look for work and asubstantial part of tax transfers go to working people to

    improve these incentives. Income inequality is relatively

    high and employment protection rather loose. In Europe,

    typical examples of this group are the United Kingdom

    and Ireland.

    In the social-democratic model, the government has a

    much more active role by also aiming at an equalitarian

    society. Government transfers play an important role inachieving a more equal income distribution and promote

    labour market participation. Taxation is relatively high to

    finance a generous social security system. Regular

    consultations between government and the so-called

    social partners, i.e. trade unions and employers

    organisation are an important part of social-economic

    policy. Examples of this model are the Nordic countries

    and the Netherlands.

    The conservative model is similar to the social-

    democratic model. The main difference is in the role ofthe trade unions. Whereas in the social-democratic

    model, one umbrella trade-union dominates, in the

    conservative model trade-unions are organised

    according to religious or political affiliations. These

    organisations tend to defend above all the rights of their

    adherents instead of pursuing more general social-

    economic objectives as in the social-democratic model.

    In this model employment protection is relatively strict

    and minimum wages are high, which protect the rights of

    the insiders. This group includes Austria, Belgium,France and Germany (as well as the southern European

    countries to a lesser extent).

    Sapir assesses the performances of the three models

    by comparing their outcomes in terms of efficiency and

    equity(2). The probability of escaping poverty, defined as

    the percentage of the population receiving income above

    the so-called poverty line, defined as 60% of the median

    income after social transfers, could be considered as a

    measure for equity. Admittedly, this is a rather crude. A

    major objection is that it does not tell us for how longpeople are living below the poverty line and what

    chances they have to improve themselves.

    The Nordic model

    Raymond Van der Putten

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    2/15

    A model is called efficient, if it provides sufficient

    incentives to work. Sapir suggests for this the

    employment rate. However, the use of part-time workerscould make this a misleading measure. To provide a

    better measure of the utilisation of labour, we have

    created an employment rate in full-time equivalents by

    multiplying the employment rate by the hours actually

    worked divided by the hours worked by full-time

    workers.

    As expected, the employment rate in full-time

    equivalents is highest in the liberal model, implying that

    in this model make the best use of the workforce (see

    Chart 1). However, its performance in terms of equity isdisappointing. By contrast, the conservative model

    performs relatively well in terms of equity. However, in

    these countries, the (full-time) employment rate is

    relatively low. In particular, the southern European

    countries perform very badly in terms of equity. The best

    result in terms of equity and efficiency are clearly

    obtained in the social-democratic model.

    A mixed growth performance

    In this article, we will concentrate on the social

    economic models in the Nordic countries(3). These

    models are characterised by relatively high taxes to

    finance a comprehensive welfare system (see Chart 2).

    According to economic theory, high tax rates and

    substantial income transfers are in general associated

    with welfare losses and low incentives to look for work.

    Large welfare programmes often result in substantial

    deadweight losses, as citizens tend to over-useservices for which they do not pay the full price. Using a

    neo-classical growth model, Edward Prescott argues that

    if France were to reduce its effective tax rate on labour

    income from 60 percent to the U.S. 40 percent rate, the

    welfare of the French people would increase by 19 percent

    in terms of lifetime consumption equivalents(4). This

    conclusion could be easily extended to the Nordic

    countries. Nevertheless, the Nordic countries are already

    among the most prosperous in the world. Did the Nordic

    countries find the recipe for expanding the welfare statewithout significant welfare losses? Is the Nordic welfare

    state like a free lunch?(5).

    As it turns out, the welfare state has not come as a

    free lunch. Over the past four decades these countrieshave not really outperformed the other OECD countries.

    (see Chart 3). This is in particular the case for Sweden.

    In 1970, the country was the fourth richest OECD

    member state (after Switzerland, Luxembourg and the

    United States) with GDP per capita 27% above the

    OECD average. By 2006, it had fallen to the 12th place

    and its income advantage had shrunken to 10%. The

    Danish economy performed slightly better, but has also

    experienced a decline in its relative position(6). From this

    perspective, it seems that the Scandinavian model doesnot seem to have much to offer to the other European

    economies.

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 14

    Equity versus efficiency

    Chart 1 Source: Eurostat, calculations BNP Paribas

    75

    80

    85

    90

    95

    35 40 45 50 55Employment rate (in full-time equivalents)

    Probabilityofescaping

    poverty

    GER FRA

    ITA

    FIN

    SWE DEN

    UKSP

    SWEDENFRANORFINITAUKSPAGERUSJAP

    60

    50

    40

    30

    20

    10

    0

    Source: OECDChart 2

    Government revenue as % of GDP (2005)

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    3/15

    High employment rate but low hoursworked

    Another characteristic of the Nordic countries is the

    relatively flat income distribution after taxes and socialtransfers (see Chart 4, page 16). However, as the overall

    tax burden is high, marginal tax rates for the average

    income earners are relatively steep (see Table 1, page

    16). In Denmark, the average income earner is already

    facing the highest marginal tax rate of 63%.

    This could easily have a detrimental effect on labour

    market participation. Nevertheless, the employment

    rates in these countries are among the highest in the

    OECD (see Chart 5, page 16). This is one of the puzzling

    aspects of the Nordic model, for which the solution canbe found in the tax-benefit system. One of the reasons

    for the high taxes is the financing of measures to promote

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 15

    Box 1 Nordic countries - diversities and similarities

    The Nordic countries encompass the three Scandinavian countries Norway, Denmark, and Sweden Iceland andFinland, plus their associated territories which include the Faeroe Islands, Greenland (both associated with Denmark) andland (Finland). Their official cooperation is channelled through the Nordic council.

    The logic behind this cooperation is that the region shares much of a common history. As a result, their political, economic,and social institutions are rather similar. The Nordic countries are among the richest in the world. In terms of GDP per head,they are all above the OECD average. The countries have well functioning market economies. Except for Iceland, they are allin the top-10 of the Global Competitiveness Index(7). They have very high tax burdens, related to their comprehensive socialsecurity system.

    Despite these similarities, the Nordic countries have known different economic, social, and political developments. TheDanish manufacturing sector is characterised by small and medium-sized industries with a strong specialisation in the agro-industry. By contrast, the Swedish industrial landscape is dominated by large multinational corporations, operating in transport

    and electronics. Traditionally, Finland was also specialised in timber and paper and pulp industry. However, over the lastdecade, the country has become an important producer of electronics and other high-tech products. Industries in Norway andIceland are heavily dependent on natural resources.

    These differences have also influenced the way of policy making. Denmark has a long tradition of coalition governmentsand consensual politics. By contrast, as a result of the stronger industrialisation, politics in Sweden has been more polarised,with the Social Democratic Party playing a leading role. Only four general elections (1976, 1979, 1991 and 2006) have giventhe centre-right bloc enough seats in Parliament to form a government.

    Up to 1981, Norwegian politics were also dominated by the Social Democrats. However, after 1981, the situation hasbecome more like in Denmark, as governments alternated between minority coalitions led by Labour or centre-right parties.At the moment, almost all Nordic countries are led by centre-right coalitions. Only in Iceland, a broad coalition has been formedbetween the conservative Independence Party and the Social-Democrats.

    Concerning international economic co-operation, Denmark has been a member of the European Union since 1973,

    whereas Sweden and Finland followed their example in 1995. As members of the European Free Trade Association, Norwayand Iceland are part of the European Area, which allows them to join the European Single Market without being member ofthe European Union(8). Only Finland has adopted the euro, whereas Denmark secured an opt-out of the single currency afterthe reaction of the Maastricht treaty in the 1992 referendum.

    0500959085807570

    150

    140

    130

    120

    110

    100

    90

    80

    (OECD=100)

    Source: OECDChart 3

    Denmark

    Sweden

    US

    Eurozone

    GDP per capita

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    4/15August-September 2008 Conjoncture 16

    labour market participation. In particular, the generous

    childcare benefits provide substantial incentives for

    female participation. With the exception of France, the

    Nordic countries are the only European countries that

    offer some form of publicly provided childcare for children

    below 3. In addition, these countries have very generousparental leave benefits(9). However, these benefits are

    conditional on labour market participation. In addition, the

    individual declaration of income taxes has considerably

    reduced the marginal tax rates on earnings of a second

    breadwinner in the family. With the exception of Iceland,

    the tax rate for the second family earner does not differ

    significantly from that of the first income earner.

    In the Nordic countries, measures to stimulate theparticipation of women have been stretched to the limit at

    the costs of the tax regime for the primary breadwinners.

    USITASPAUKJAPGERFRANORFINSWEDEN

    40

    35

    30

    25

    20

    15

    10

    5

    0

    Source: OECDChart 4

    A relatively flat income distribution(Gini coefficient, 2000)

    DENNORSWEUKUSJAPFINGERSPAFRAITA

    80

    70

    60

    50

    40

    30

    20

    10

    0

    Source: OECDChart 5

    A high employment rate(2007, % working-age population)

    Average and marginal tax rates (1)

    Average tax rateSingle

    No childrenOne earner couplewithout children

    One earner couplewith two children

    Top marginaltax rate

    Threshold(multiple AW)

    Nordic countriesDenmark 41.0 35.8 29.3 63.0 1Finland 30.1 30.1 22.9 56.1 1.9Norway 29.9 27.1 21.5 47.8 1.5

    Sweden 27.6 27.6 19.8 56.5 1.4Continental countriesFrance 27.8 23.8 17.5 49.8 2.8Germany 42.8 33.3 23.9 47.5 5.9Italy 28.5 25.6 12.5 50.7 3.5Spain 20.4 16.6 12.4 43.0 2.6English-speakingcountries Australia 23.4 20.5 10.0 46.5 2.6Canada 23.3 18.9 10.6 46.4 2.9United Kingdom 27.0 27.0 20.6 41.0 1.2United States 24.5 19.9 11.8 42.7 8.7

    Table 1 Source: OECD

    (1) All-in tax rate including employeessocial security contributions taking into account standard tax credits and allowancesAW = average worker

    The Gini coefficient measures the income inequality in a country. A lownumber indicates a high degree of income equality.

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    5/15

    The tax wedge on the latter is relatively high by

    international comparison (see Chart 6). This has

    stimulated primary breadwinners to make less hours

    doing paid work (see Chart 7). Instead, they tend to

    devote more time on home work. By contrast, women in

    the Nordic countries tend to be less active at home than

    those in other OECD countries (see Table 2). Althoughthese differences may be partly attributed to cultural

    differences, they have become more pronounced by

    economic incentives.

    The disappearance of the skill premium

    The flat income distribution suggests that skill

    premiums are relatively weak in the Nordic countries, in

    particular compared to the English speaking countries.Domeij and Ljungqvist estimate that the average skill

    premium in the US increased by around 8-10 percent

    between 1970 and 1990. During the same period, the

    Swedish skill premium fell by more than 30%, and only

    recovered by 10 percentage points in 2002(10).

    Edin and Topel explain the low returns from schooling

    by non-market conform wage setting(11). During the

    1970s, trade unions pursued egalitarian objectives in

    their wage bargaining policies in centralised wage

    negations. In this way, they achieved high compensationfor low-wage workers in exchange for relatively low

    wages for skilled labour. However, their explanation is

    unlikely to hold for the whole period. Indeed, after 1983,

    wage bargaining moved increasingly to an industry and

    company level, partly because employers argued that the

    underpaying of skilled workers hindered recruiting.

    Domeij and Ljungqvist argue that the decline in the

    Swedish skill premium can be explained by differentiating

    between the private and the public sector. In theiropinion, the decline in the skill premium was related to

    the rapid expansion of the Swedish public sector, which

    involved the disproportionately hiring of unskilled

    workers. In this way, the ratio of skilled to unskilled

    workers available to the private sector was increased,

    which lowered the relative wage for skilled workers. One

    could also argue that the Swedish government became

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 17

    DENGERSWEFINNORUKFRAITAUSJAPSPA

    40

    35

    30

    25

    20

    15

    10

    5

    0

    Source: OECDChart 6

    Total tax wedge (2007)

    JAPUSUKSPAFINITASWEDENFRANORGER

    1900

    1800

    1700

    1600

    1500

    1400

    1300

    1200

    1100

    1000

    Source: OECDChart 7

    Average annual hours worked by employees (2007)

    Home work by gender (Sweden = 100)

    Male Female

    Denmark 85.7 89.7

    Norway 90.5 100

    Sweden 100 100

    US 81 103.4

    Finland 85.7 103.4

    UK 85.7 110.3

    Germany 90.5 113.8

    France 85.7 120.7

    Table 2Source: K.S. Ragan, 2005, Fiscal Policy and the Family: Explaining

    Labour Supply in a Model with Household Production, mimeo,University of Chicago.

    Two-earner married couple, one at 100% of average earnings and theother at 67% with two children.

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    6/15August-September 2008 Conjoncture 18

    the employer of last resort(12). In a similar way, the

    disappearance of low skilled workers into the public

    sector, long-term unemployment, disability or earlyretirement programmes might explain the compression of

    the skill premium in other European countries.

    This could explain why the public sector is relatively

    large in all the Scandinavian countries (see Table 3). The

    relative high level of public expenditure close to 50% of

    GDP is not only related to the substantial income

    transfers but also to the high number of people working

    in the public sector and associated activities(13). In

    Norway, Sweden and Denmark, around 40% of

    employees are working in the public sector comparedwith just over 30% in France and Germany. A study by

    Afonso, Schuknects and Tanzi shows that, in terms of

    inputs, the Swedish public service is the most inefficient

    in the OECD, followed by Finland and Denmark(14).

    According to their calculations, the Swedish authorities

    could decrease their expenditure by 43% to obtain the

    same output(15). The average input inefficiency in the EU

    is 27%. By maintaining public expenditure at the current

    level, the output performance is 18% below what could

    be achieved if productivity were as high as that of themost efficient countries Luxembourg, Netherlands and

    the United States.

    A flexible labour market

    The common factor in the Scandinavian countries isthe important role that trade unions and employers

    organisations are playing an important role in shaping

    social-economic policies. In the three Scandinavian

    countries, most trade unions are members of the umbrella

    organisation LO(16). The trade union membership rate,

    also referred to as the unionisation rate, is close to 80%

    (see Chart 8). This is largely explained by the fact that the

    Public sector performance

    Total government expenditure(as % of GDP) (2007)

    Public sector employee(as % of total) (2006) (1)

    Public sector efficiency(2000) (2)

    Nordic countriesDenmark 51.2 38.1 0.95Finland 48.9 34.2 1.01Norway 51.5* 40.0 1.09Sweden 54.3 40.3 0.82Continental countriesFrance 52.7 33.9 0.83Germany 45.4 30.8 0.97Italy 48.8 28.0 0.80Spain 38.6 24.0 1.06English-speaking countries Australia 34.9 - Canada 39.3 28.6 1.04

    United Kingdom 44.7 35.8 1.06United States 36.6 - 1.26

    Table 3 Source : OECD(1) Employees working in public administration, education, health and social work and other community activities.(2) A. Afonso, L. Schuknecht, and V. Tanzi, 2003, Public Sector Efficiency: an International Comparison, ECB Working Paper 242.(*) Mainland GDP.

    SWEFINDENNORITAUKGERJAPSPAUSFRA

    80

    70

    60

    50

    40

    30

    20

    10

    0

    Source: OECDChart 8

    High unionisation rate (2001)

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    7/15August-September 2008 Conjoncture 19

    unemployment insurance is a voluntary insurance carried

    out by the trade unions. However, the trade unions

    unemployment insurance is also open for non-unionmembers. LOs dominant position and the high degree of

    unionisation imply that the LO is less focused on

    defending the rights of only the employees, but also takes

    into account the macroeconomic consequences for those

    who are outside the labour market.

    Despite the strong presence of the trade unions in

    Denmark, legal employment protection is one of the

    lowest in the OECD. In Denmark, the notice period

    is only 1 month, independent of the job tenure (see

    Chart 9). Given the generous unemployment benefits(see below), one could say that the Danish has given

    greater priority to income security than to job security.

    Nevertheless, it is not true that Danish workers are at the

    mercy of their employer. The strong presence of trade

    unions in the enterprises forms implicit or explicit a

    guarantee against unfair dismissals. In the absence of

    any legal protection against dismissals, the Danish

    Employers Confederation and the trade-union LO have

    agreed on a general rule that employees must not

    dismissed arbitrarily, and that employees that have beenin the company for more than 9 months are entitled to an

    explanation for their dismissal. The flexibility device is

    mainly used in severe downturns or for temporary layoffs,

    to adapt the workforce better to output fluctuations.

    Actually, many unemployment spells terminate by a

    return to the former employer.

    Job volatility is relatively high in the Scandinavian

    countries. Around one fifth of Danish employees is less

    than a year in a job, compared with only 12% in both

    France and Germany. At just above 8 years, the lengthof job tenure in Denmark is the lowest in the OECD (see

    Chart 10). However, it this could be attributed also to

    other factors such as the industry structure with

    relatively many small firms(17). In fact, the average job

    tenure in the other Scandinavian countries with much

    stricter EPL is only marginally longer. Moreover, the high

    level of productivity and the substantial amount of

    expenditure on training are supportive evidence of the

    attachment of the workforce to the firm. Indeed, around

    30% of employees is more than 10 years in the same job, compared with more than 40% in most of

    continental Europe.

    Unemployment and poverty trap

    The Scandinavian countries are often envied for theirremarkable labour market performance. In July 2008, the

    Danish unemployment rate stood at only 2.3%, compared

    with 6.8% for the EU. Also Norway, Finland and Sweden

    have unemployment rates below the EU average.

    The relatively low level of unemployment is largely

    due to the very low level of long-term unemployment (see

    Chart 11, page 20).

    Some have questioned the official unemployment

    data. The management consulting firm McKinsey

    estimates that the real unemployment rate was between15% and 17% in 2004, about three times as high as the

    official rate of 5.4%.They arrive at this number by adding

    SPAFRASWENORGERITAFINDENJAPUKUS

    3.5

    3.0

    2.5

    2.0

    1.5

    1.0

    0.5

    0.0

    Source: OECDChart 9

    High values point to a high degreeof employment protection legislation

    Strictness of employment protection legislation(2003)

    ITAFRAGERSWEFINSPANORUKDEN

    14

    12

    10

    8

    6

    4

    2

    0

    year

    Source: OECDChart 10

    Average job tenure (2007)

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    8/15

    to the official data, discouraged workers, part-time

    workers who are looking for full time jobs, and all those

    at working age and receiving an income replacementbenefit or are employed in special government programs.

    This estimate might be an overestimation. By applying

    the same methodology to the US, Schmitt finds an

    unemployment rate of 15.2%(18).

    In the Nordic countries, low unemployment rates go

    hand in hand with high benefit levels, in particular for

    people at the lower end of the income spectrum (see

    Table 4). Once becoming unemployed, low income

    earners can receive relatively high benefits for a long

    period. The net replacement rate of a single familyworker earning 67% of the wage of an average

    production worker (APW) is 82% in Sweden and even

    87% in Denmark compared with 75% in France and

    around 60% in Germany and the UK. After 5 years,

    Danish jobseekers still receive 82% of their former salary,

    while their Swedish counterparts receive almost 70%.

    Over the same time span, the net replacement rate in

    Germany and France has fallen back to 45% and 48%

    respectively. For higher income earners, the replacement

    rates are more in line with those in other OECDcountries. These results suggest that a generous welfare

    system can coincide with good labour market outcomes.

    It is mainly for this reason that continental European

    countries have become interested in the Nordic model.

    In the Scandinavian countries, low income earners

    have little financial incentives to look for work. To

    stimulate the return of benefit receivers into activity,

    these countries rely on very comprehensive active

    labour market policies (ALMP). Participation in these

    programmes is obligatory, in Denmark after six months forunemployed under 30 and over 60, and nine months for

    all others. In Sweden, unemployed will be enrolled in a

    programme within 28 months. In both countries,

    participants do not qualify anymore for an extension of

    their insurance period. In Denmark and Sweden, around

    0.5% of the labour force is participating in these

    programmes. This is relatively high compared to the

    unemployment rate in these countries. Moreover, the

    costs of these programmes are elevated compared to

    other OECD countries. Both Denmark and Sweden spendmore than 1% of GDP on ALMP compared with around

    0.5% on average in the European Union (see Chart 12).

    Opinions are divided on the usefulness of these kinds

    of programmes. There is always the danger that theycrowd out existing jobs and might lead to unfair

    competition not only between companies but also

    between different kinds of workers. In the Danish case,

    one could ask if the start of these programmes within

    6 month of unemployment for people under 30 is not

    too early. It could be argued that many of the participants

    would have found a job without help. In fact, participation

    could actually slow down the job search. On the other

    hand, the programmes might stimulate the unemployed

    to accept a job before enrolling into these schemes. Inthis way, the ALMP have a similar function as benefit

    sanctions.

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 20

    GERFRASPAFINSWEITAUKUSDENJAPNOR

    109

    8

    7

    6

    5

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

    % labour force

    Source: OECDChart 11

    Long and short-term unemployment (2007)

    Short-term unemployment (1 year)

    DEN*SWEFRAFINGERSPANORITAUKJAPUS

    5.0

    4.5

    4.0

    3.5

    3.0

    2.52.0

    1.5

    1.0

    0.5

    0.0

    Source: OECDChart 12

    (early retirement + unemployment benefits)

    *2004

    Public spending on active labour market policiesas % of GDP (2006)

    Active measuresPassive measures

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    9/15August-September 2008 Conjoncture 21

    An alternative would be to intensify job search

    assistance, as is done in the UK. Between November

    2005 and March 2006, the Danish Labour Market

    Authority carried out a controlled experiment in thecounties Storstrm and South Jutland, by dividing the

    registered unemployed in two groups, depending on their

    date of birth(19). One group received an intensified

    sequence of monitoring, counselling, job search

    assistance, and participation in ALMP. The control group

    followed the normal rules. By intensifying the contacts

    between the unemployed and the public employment

    service, the median unemployment duration of the

    treatment group was reduced to 11.5 weeks compared

    with 14 weeks for the control group.In a study on the Swedish unemployment duration,

    Richardson and van den Berg conclude that the

    individual transition rate from unemployment to

    employment is substantially raised as a result of the

    individuals participation in a vocational training

    course(20). However, when the time spent in the program

    is taken into account, the net effect on unemployment

    duration is about zero. They recommend shortening the

    training courses and prolonging the job search

    assistance after the completion of the course. Moreover,the training programs could become more effective by a

    better selection of potential candidates.

    Happy Globalisation

    The Nordic countries belong to the most open

    economies in the OECD (see Chart 13). In particularSweden has a relatively large manufacturing sector,

    including some very successful multinational groups

    such as Electrolux, Ericsson, and Volvo. In 2003 (latest

    available data in OECD STAN database), manufacturing

    contributed directly 22% to total value added, with the

    sub-sectors machinery and equipment plus wood and

    paper production making up about half of it.

    Net replacement rates (one-earner married couple, 2 children)

    67% of salary APW 100% of salary APWInitial After 5 years Initial After 5 years

    Nordic countriesDenmark 91 92 75 77Finland 85 91 76 77Norway 74 99 70 73Sweden 89 95 69 70Continental countriesFrance 83 78 67 54Germany 78 79 73 62Italy 64 0 70 0Spain 77 49 75 35English-speakingcountries Australia 77 77 65

    Canada 71 71 78 62United Kingdom 70 79 60 67United States 49 48 56 40

    Table 4 Source : OECDAPW = Average Production Worker

    Exports as % of GDP in 2005

    Chart 13 Source: OECD

    0 20 40 60 80 100

    United States

    Japan

    United Kingdom

    Spain

    France

    Italy

    Finland

    Norway

    Germany

    Denmark

    Sweden

    Netherlands

    Belgium

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    10/15

    As in the rest of the industrialised world, the relative

    importance of manufacturing sector in the Nordic

    countries has steadily diminished. This is partly due to

    the development of the services sector. Moreover, during

    the past decade, enterprises have increasingly offshored

    their activities to low wage countries in East Asia and

    since the disappearance of the Iron Curtain, also to

    central and eastern Europe. The average hourly wage

    costs in the ten EU accession countries are around5 euros compared with 25 euros in Sweden. Swedish

    companies especially invested in Poland and the Baltic

    Republics. The proximity of these areas made it possible

    for the smaller and part of their production.

    The offshoring of part of the labour-intensive production

    process and the expansion of skill-intensive activities such

    as research & development, or downstream processes,

    such as marketing and after sales services, is observed in

    many other countries. They supply the world with a large

    range of products, of which an increasing part is producedelsewhere. According to Sinn (2006) they have become

    bazaar economies(21). The Swedish and Finnish

    manufacturing sectors have the highest R&D intensity in the

    world (see Chart 14). As a result of the unbundling of the

    production process, the import penetration in the

    manufacturing sector has considerably increased, although

    in Sweden less than in most other countries (see Table 5).

    Despite these developments, the decline in the share

    of manufacturing activity in Sweden has been limited

    (Chart 15). This could surprise as Swedish entrepreneurshave been confronted with much sharper increases in

    wage costs than in most other OECD countries. However,

    by offshoring labour intensive activities or outsourcing

    them to foreign suppliers, productivity growth has been

    among the highest (Chart 16). As a result, Swedish unit

    labour costs are one third below their 1992 level.

    There is insufficient information on the employment

    effects of offshoring and outsourcing. According to the

    Swedish Institute for Growth Policy Studies ITPS,

    Swedish groups with subsidiaries abroad have reduced

    their Swedish staff over time, while increasing theirforeign staff. In 2005, these groups employ 1million

    people abroad, or two-third of their total workforces.

    However, as the majority of the Swedish subsidiaries are

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 22

    USUKFRAITAJAPSWEGER

    30

    25

    20

    15

    10

    5

    0

    Source: OECDChart 15

    Share of manufacturing in value added

    1985-19892000-2003

    Import penetration

    yearImport

    penetrationChange

    Spain 1995 272003 36 9

    Germany 1995 30

    2003 39 9UK 1995 39

    2003 48 9France 1995 31

    2003 36 6US 1995 18

    2003 24 6Sweden 1995 41

    2002 46 5Italy 1995 25

    2003 30 5

    Table 5Source: OECD

    Import penetration is defined as imports devidedby total domestic demand

    ITAUKFRAGERDENUSJAPFINSWE

    16

    14

    12

    10

    8

    6

    4

    2

    0

    in % of value added

    Source: OECDChart 14

    R&D intensity of the manufacturing sector (2003)

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    11/15

    in Europe(61%) and the US (28%), it is unlikely that this

    development is largely motivated by expanding market

    share, rather than by seeking cost reductions. On theother hand, the percentage of Swedish employees in

    foreign-owned companies has also rapidly increased and

    is now just under 25%.It is likely that offshoring has in

    particular reduced the amount of work for less skilled

    workers. Indeed, there has been a clear upward trend in

    the wage bill share of workers with tertiary education and

    a downward trend in the wage-bill share of workers with

    lower secondary education(22). However, this trend is also

    due to the increase in the relative supply of workers with

    tertiary education and the increased use of computers.Since the EU enlargement in 2004, firms in the Nordic

    countries have been confronted with increased

    competition from, in particular, the neighbouring Baltic

    Republics and Poland. Increased immigration from these

    countries has helped to ease bottlenecks in the labour

    market and dampen wage demands. Between May 2003

    and June 2007, the Nordic countries issued about 75

    000 work permits for migrants from the new EU member

    states, of which about 50% issued by Norway.

    Major problems have appeared in the import of servicesfrom these countries, i.e. for posted workers and self-

    employed offering temporary services, mainly in the

    construction sector. The problem is in the implementation of

    the Posted Worker Directive, which requires firms to observe

    a nucleus of mandatory rules for minimum protection. In the

    Nordic countries, labour market regulations are often

    negotiated between trade unions and employers. In

    Denmark and Sweden, the social partners have always

    strongly opposed state interference in this area. As a result,

    foreign supplier can either enter a collective agreement with

    the trade union in the host country or apply the collective

    agreement of its home country. Recently, the EuropeanCourt of Justice decided that industrial actions to force

    foreign suppliers to enter a collective agreement with trade

    union were illegal (see Box 2).

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 23

    060504030201009998979695949392

    280260

    240

    220

    200

    180

    160

    140

    120

    100

    1992=100

    Source: US Bureau of Labor StatisticsChart 16

    Labour productivity in the manufacturing sector

    SwedenUSFranceGermanyUK

    Box 2: The Laval case

    In May 2004, the Latvian construction company Laval un Partneri posted workers on Swedish building sites run by itssubsidiary L&P Baltic Bygg AB. The Swedish construction trade union demanded that these workers would be paid inaccordance to the Swedish collective agreement. The Latvian firm refused this, arguing that it had entered into an agreementwith the Latvian building sector trade union. Workers would receive almost twice the pay that was customary in Latvia, inaddition to board, lodging and transport.

    Following the breakdown of the negotiations, the Swedish construction trade union, initiated a blockade of the building site.The action was later joined by the Swedish Electricians Union. As a result of the action, Baltic Bygg filed for bankruptcy in2005, and the posted workers returned to Latvia.

    Laval asked the Swedish Labour Court to declare the blockade illegal, as it would violate the European Posting WorkersDirective. The Labour Court rejected this demand, but decided to request a statement from the European Court of Justice,which delivered its verdict in December 2007. The Court declared that trade unions had the right to take collective action toprotect workers of the host State against social dumping. However, in the specific case, the action was not justified as thetrade unions had asked for pay rates in line with the average market level of pay in the Stockholm region, whereas theDirective on posted workers only requires firms to observe a nucleus of mandatory rules for minimum protection. In Sweden,no legal minimum wage exists. The labour market is largely regulated by collective agreements negotiated between tradeunions and employers organisations. The Court argued that the trade unions demand could not replace the lack of a minimumwage provision in Swedish labour law. In addition, the Court stated that the Swedish labour laws failed to take into account

    that the Latvian workers were also bound to the collective agreements in their home country.The Swedish government has announced that amendments to its labour legislation might be necessary to avoid future

    problems. A government report will be published by mid December 2008.

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    12/15

    Nordic lessons

    The Nordic countries have a good record in terms ofreduction of poverty reduction, labour market participation

    and the return the unemployed to the regular labour

    market. On the other hand, the costs of the model are

    very high. Government expenditure (in % of GDP) is

    among the highest in the OECD. This has undoubtedly

    led to substantial welfare losses. As marginal income tax

    rates are high, employees work on average much less

    than in the rest of the OECD. At the latest elections, both

    the Danish and the Swedish have already expressed their

    preference for a slimmer welfare state, without affectingthe fundamentals of their social models. A lower tax

    burden might stimulate workers to increase their number

    of hours worked. In this way, the Nordic countries could

    improve their welfare substantially.

    In all the Nordic countries, the regular dialogues

    between the trade unions and employers organisations

    play an important role in the shaping of social economic

    policies. Recently, the labour market model has come

    under double pressure. In the first place, to remain

    competitive, companies have been offshoring labourintensive activities. The trade unions have not opposed

    this development. On the contrary, they have understood

    that this in combination with the upgrading of skills of the

    domestic workforce is essential for the survival of the

    manufacturing sector. In addition, technical developments

    have increased the scope for outsourcing and offshoring.

    In the services sector, all work that is suitable for electronic

    delivery can in principle be offshored. This could lead to

    the loss of service jobs to foreign competitors. At the same

    time, Nordic services firms should also be able to profitfrom this development by exporting their products.

    The second threat is coming from the free movement

    of services and the posting of workers in the European

    market. As the Laval case showed, the Nordic traditions

    of negotiated agreements between employers and trade-

    unions have clashed with European legislation, which is

    based on the continental tradition of the legal extension

    of collective agreements and minimum standards. The

    adoption of more European style minimum labour

    standards seems inevitable. The experiences in Norwayand Finland show that it is probably less than a threat

    than most actors fear at the moment.

    The good performance of the Nordic models in

    comparison to some of the continental models has raised

    the question what the European countries can learn. It isgood to underline first that the Nordic models are

    outcomes of a historical process. When the Danish social

    partners concluded their first agreement in 1899, they did

    not have a blueprint of a social model in mind. For this

    reason, elements of these models are difficult to

    implement in isolation. The Nordic countries are also

    relatively small and have rather homogeneous

    populations. That could also be an element that explains

    the functioning of their models.

    It is in the field of labour market policies that thecontinental countries could probably learn most. If the

    Continental European countries do not want to adopt the

    more incentive-based policies to improve the functioning

    of their labour markets, they could find inspiration in the

    active labour market policies of the Nordic countries.

    Lastly, the strength of the Nordic model is in its adaption

    to changing circumstances, in which the negotiations

    between social partners play a central role. However,

    such policies only work if social partners can be

    persuaded not to pursue the interest of their members byadopting anti-competition measures or strengthening the

    position of those who are already in the labour market,

    but keeping the interest of the whole society in mind.

    [email protected]

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 24

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    13/15

    NOTES

    (1) G. Esping-Andersen, 1990, The three worlds of

    welfare capitalism, Princeton University Press. Someauthors have later added the Mediterranean model asseparate category. See f.e. Sapir, A. (2005),Globalisation and the Reform of European SocialModels, Bruegel Policy Brief, issue 2005/01.(2) See Sapir op. cit.(3) The term Scandinavian model is often reserved todescribe the way the Nordic countries organise andfinance their social security, health and educationsystems.

    (4) E. Prescott, 2004, Why Americans work so much,Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly ReviewVol. 28, No. 1.(5) P.H. Lindert, 2003, Why the welfare state looks likefree lunch, NBER Working Paper 9869.(6) Only Norway improved its position considerably byclimbing up to the 2nd place, after Luxembourg.However, this development is narrowly connected withthe finding of oil on its continental shelf.(7) The Global Competitiveness Index is constructed by

    the World Economic Forum. In the 2007 ranking,Denmark, Sweden and Finland ended on the third, fourthand sixth place, respectively. Iceland came in at the 23rd

    position.(8) The other members of the European Free Trade

    Association are Switzerland and Liechtenstein.(9) In Sweden, parental benefit is payable for up to480 days, of which 390 days at 80% of the parentsincome. The generosity of the parental leave isdepending on how many days the woman has worked

    before giving birth. This has given young women strongincentives to establish themselves firmly in the labourmarket before starting a family.(10) D. Domeij and L. Ljungqvist, (2006) Wage structureand public sector employment: Sweden versus theUnited States, 1970-2002, CEPR Discussion Paper5921.(11) Per-Anders Edin and Robert Topel, 1997, WagePolicy and Restructuring: The Swedish Labor Marketsince 1960, in The Welfare State in Transition:

    Reforming the Swedish Model Richard B. Freeman,Robert Topel, and Birgitta Swedenborg, editors, (p. 155 -202), NBER published in January 1997.

    (12) A. Lindbeck, 1997, The Swedish Experiment,

    Journal of Economic Literature, Vol 35, no.3.(13) Defined as employees in public administration,education, health and social work and other communityactivities.(14) A. Afonso, L. Schuknecht, and V . Tanzi, 2003,Public Sector Efficiency : An International Comparison,ECB Working Paper 242.(15) Public sector output performance is calculated byusing several indicators indicators for public sectoroutcomes concerning administration, education, health

    and infrastructure. These are complemented withindicators concerning the three tradition funtions forgoverment, i.e. income distribution, stabilisation andeconomic performance.(16) LO stands for Landsorganisationen i Sverige,Landsorganisationen i Danmark, andLandsorganisasjonen i Norge.(17) Torben M. Anderson and Michael Svarer, 2007,Flexicurity - labour market performance in Denmark,Economics Working Paper 2007-9, University of Aarhus.

    (18) John Schmitt, 2007, Is the unemployment rate inSweden really 17 percent?, Center for Economic andPolicy Research, Issue Brief, June 2007.(19) B.K. Graversen and J.C. van Ours, 2006, How tohelp unemployed find jobs quickly: ExperimentalEvidence from a mandatory activation program, IZADiscussion Paper 2504.(20) Katherina Richardson and Gerard van der Berg,2006, Swedish labour market training and the durationof unemployment, CEPR Discussion Paper 5895.

    (21) Hans-Werner Sinn, 2006, The Pathological ExportBoom and the Bazaar Effect, CESifo Working Paper1708. He studies in particular the industrialdevelopments in Germany.(22) Karolina Ekholm and Katarina Hakkala, 2008,International Production Networks in the Nordic/BalticRegion, OECD Trade Policy Working Paper 61.

    August-September 2008 Conjoncture 25

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    14/15August-September 2008 Conjoncture

    ECONOMIC RESEARCH DEPARTMENT economic-research.bnpparibas.com

    Philippe dARVISENET 33 1.43.16.95.58 [email protected]

    Chief EconomistOECD COUNTRIES

    Philippe dARVISENET 33 1.43.16.95.58 [email protected]

    Eric VERGNAUD 33 1.42.98.49.80 [email protected] of OECD CountriesStructural issues, Single European Financial Market

    Caroline NEWHOUSE-COHEN 33 1.43.16.95.50 [email protected] economics

    UNITED STATES, CANADAJean-Marc LUCAS 33 1.43.16.95.53 [email protected]

    JAPAN, AUSTRALIA, NEW ZEALANDCaroline NEWHOUSE-COHEN 33 1.43.16.95.50 [email protected]

    EURO ZONE, ITALY, EU ENLARGEMENTClemente De LUCIA 33.1.42.98.27.62 [email protected]

    FRANCE, EURO ZONE LABOUR MARKETMathieu KAISER 33 1.55.77.71.89 [email protected]

    GERMANY, AUSTRIA, SWITZERLAND,PUBLIC FINANCESFrdrique CERISIER 33 1.43.16.95.52 [email protected]

    SPAIN, PORTUGAL, GREECEPhilippe Sabuco 33 1.43.16.95.54 [email protected]

    UNITED KINGDOM, NORDIC COUNTRIES,BENELUX, PENSIONS, LONG TERM FORECASTSRaymond VAN DER PUTTEN 33 1.42.98.53.99 [email protected]

    BANKING ECONOMICSLaurent QUIGNON 33 1.42.98.56.54 [email protected]

    Cline CHOULET 33.1.57.43.02.91 [email protected]

    Philippe SABUCO 33.1.43.16.95.54 [email protected]

    COUNTRY RISK

    Guy LONGUEVILLE 33 1.43.16.95.40 [email protected]

    Franois FAURE 33 1 .42.98.79.82 [email protected] flows to emerging markets,Turkey

    ASIA

    Delphine CAVALIER 33.1.43.16.95.41 [email protected] PELTIER 33 1.42.98.56.27 [email protected]

    LATIN AMERICASylvain BELLEFONTAINE 33 1.42.98.26.77 [email protected] PERRACINO 33 1 42 98 74 26 [email protected]

    AFRICAStphane ALBY 33 1.42.98.02.04 [email protected] GUIEZE 33 1.42.98.43.86 [email protected]

    EASTERN EUROPECentral Europe, Baltic countries, Balkan countriesAlexandre VINCENT 33 1.43.16.95.44 [email protected]

    RUSSIA, FORMER SOVIET REPUBLICSAnna DORBEC 33 1.42.98.48.45 [email protected]

    MIDDLE EAST SCORINGPascal DEVAUX 33 1.43.16.95.51 [email protected]

  • 8/3/2019 C0809_A2

    15/15

    Prepared by Economic Research - BNP Paribas

    Registered Office: 16 boulevard des Italiens - 75009 Paris

    Tel. +33 (0) 1 42 98 12 34 - Internet: www.bnpparibas.com

    Publisher : Michel PbereauPrinted in France by: Ateliers J. Hiver SA - Dpt lgal: August-September 2008

    ISSN 0224-3288 - Copyright BNP Paribas

    BNP Paribas is regulated by the FSA for the conduct of its designated investment business in the UK and is a member of the London Stock Exchange.The information and opinions contained in this report have been obtained from public sources believed to be reliable, but no representation or warranty, express

    or implied, is made that such information is accurate or complete and it should not be relied upon as such. This report does not constitute a prospectus or otheroffering document or an offer or solicitation to buy any securities or other investment. Information and opinions contained in the report are published for theassistance of recipients, but are not to be relied upon as authoritative or taken in substitution for the exercise of judgement by any recipient, they are subject tochange without notice and not intended to provide the sole basis of any evaluation of the instruments discussed herein. Any reference to past performance shouldnot be taken as an indication of future performance. No BNP Paribas Group Company accepts any liability whatsoever for any direct or consequential loss arisingfrom any use of material contained in this report. All estimates and opinions included in this report constitute our judgements as of the date of this report. BNP Paribasand their affiliates ("collectively "BNP Paribas") may make a market in, or may, as principal or agent, buy or sell securities of the issuers mentioned in this report orderivatives thereon. BNP Paribas may have a financial interest in the issuers mentioned in this report, including a long or short position in their securities, and oroptions, futures or other derivative instruments based thereon. BNP Paribas, including its officers and employees may serve or have served as an officer, directoror in an advisory capacity for any issuer mentioned in this report. BNP Paribas may, from time to time, solicit, perform or have performed investment banking,underwriting or other services (including acting as adviser, manager, underwriter or lender) within the last 12 months for any issuer referred to in this report. BNPParibas, may to the extent permitted by law, have acted upon or used the information contained herein, or the research or analysis on which it was based, beforeits publication. BNP Paribas may receive or intend to seek compensation for investment banking services in the next three months from an issuer mentioned in thisreport. Any issuer mentioned in this report may have been provided with sections of this report prior to its publication in order to verify its factual accuracy.

    This report was produced by a BNP Paribas Group Company. This report is for the use of intended recipients and may not be reproduced (in whole or in part)or delivered or transmitted to any other person without the prior written consent of BNP Paribas. By accepting this document you agree to be bound by the foregoinglimitations.

    Analyst Certification

    Each analyst responsible for the preparation of this report certifies that (i) all views expressed in this report accurately reflect the analyst's personal views aboutany and all of the issuers and securities named in this report, and (ii) no part of the analyst's compensation was, is, or will be, directly or indirectly, related to thespecific recommendations or views expressed herein.

    United States: This report is being distributed to US persons by BNPParibas Securities Corp., or by a subsidiary or affiliate of BNP Paribas that is not registeredas a US broker-dealer, to US major institutional investors only. BNP Paribas Securities Corp., a subsidiary of BNP Paribas, is a broker-dealer registered with theSecurities and Exchange Commission and is a member of the National Association of Securities Dealers, Inc. BNP Paribas Securities Corp. accepts responsibilityfor the content of a report prepared by another non-US affiliate only when distributed to US persons by BNP Paribas Securities Corp.

    United Kingdom: This report has been approved for publication in the United Kingdom by BNP Paribas London Branch, a branch of BNP Paribas whose headoffice is in Paris, France. BNP Paribas London Branch is regulated by the Financial Services Authority ("FSA") for the conduct of its designated investment businessin the United Kingdom and is a member of the London Stock Exchange. This report is prepared for professional investors and is not intended for Private Customersin the United Kingdom as defined in FSA rules and should not be passed on to any such persons.

    Japan: This report is being distributed to Japanese based firms by BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited, Tokyo Branch, or by a subsidiary or affiliate of BNPParibas not registered as a securities firm in Japan, to certain financial institutions permitted by regulation. BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited, Tokyo Branch,a subsidiary of BNP Paribas, is a securities firm registered according to the Securities & Exchange Law of Japan and a member of the Japan Securities Dealers

    Association. BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited, Tokyo Branch accepts responsibility for the content of a report prepared by another non-Japan affiliate onlywhen distributed to Japanese based firms by BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited, Tokyo Branch.

    Hong Kong: This report is being distributed in Hong Kong by BNP Paribas Hong Kong Branch, a branch of BNP Paribas whose head office is in Paris, France.BNP Paribas Hong Kong Branch is regulated as a Licensed Bank by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority and is deemed as a Registered Institution by the Securitiesand Futures Commission for the conduct of Advising on Securities [Regulated Activity Type 4] under the Securities and Futures Ordinance Transitional Arrangements.

    Singapore: This report is being distributed in Singapore by BNP Paribas Singapore Branch, a branch of BNP Paribas whose head office is in Paris, France.BNP Paribas Singapore is a licensed bank regulated by the Monetary Authority of Singapore is exempted from holding the required licenses to conduct regulatedactivities and provide financial advisory services under the Securities and Futures Act and the Financial Advisors Act.

    BNP Paribas (2008). All rights reserved.

    Our publications economic-research.bnpparibas.com

    Conjoncture focuses each month both on the main economic issues and structural problems.

    Economic Market Monitorprovides a detailed follow-up of the economic situation whilst analysing developments of interest andexchange rates in OECD countries (8 issues per year). EcoWeek focuses on specific economic issues (every Friday).

    EcoFlash comments and analyses the main economic events (data releases, economic policy decisions) in the hours following theirrelease).

    ECOTV the monthly broadcast programme from BNP Paribas economists. Each month, Philippe d'Arvisenet and his teams will helpyou to make sense of the economic and financial news in both French and English. These interviews are available on our website:

    To receive directly our publications, please subscribe on our website