British and European industrialization

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    1/66

    BRITISH AND EUROPEAN INDUSTRIALIZATION

    C. Knick Harley

    UN I V E R S I T Y O F OX F O R D

    Discussion Papers inEconomic and Social History

    Number 111, February 2013

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    2/66

    British and European industrialization

    C. Knick Harley

    University of Oxford

    Forthcoming in the Cambridge History of Capitalism, Vol. 1.Edited by Larry Neal and Jeffrey Williamson

    Abstract

    Modern economic growth the simultaneous increase in population and average incomes

    has been capitalisms greatest achievement. This growth first became apparent in Britain in

    the nineteenth century and then spread to continental Europe (and the United States). The

    process is usually associated with the Industrial Revolution in Britain and the spread of

    British-type industrialization to follower economies. This chapter reviews the emergence of

    modern economic growth and suggests that the usual view is misleading in that it focuses is

    too limited both in time and in the technological change it usually emphasizes. On one hand,

    the of famous industries textiles, iron and engineering contributed only modestly to

    growth because they constituted only a small proportion of the economy. Furthermore, the

    emergence of growth was much more gradual than traditionally understood. In new views,

    Britain was already a substantially industrialized economy with relatively high wages before

    the early eighteenth century. The origin of growth appear to lie in the ability of an economy

    in which both product and factor markets were well developed in both the rural and urban

    areas to partially overcome Malthusian constraints. The spread of growth to continental

    Europe is often seen as the spread of new technology of the British Industrial Revolution.

    This too seems somewhat misleading. The industries were small relative to the entire

    economies and their success depended on particular conditions. Furthermore, just as Britains

    early success rested importantly on productive capitalist agriculture, the emergence of

    increased incomes on the continent depended on agricultural reforms that increases in its

    productivity.

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    3/66

    1

    Modern economic growththe simultaneous doubling of income and population in

    fifty or seventy yearshas been capitalism's greatest triumph. It first became apparent in

    Britain in the mid-nineteenth century and spread to America and continental Europe. Modern

    growth did not, however, spread elsewhere and a great divergence developed between

    income per capita in the few leaders and the rest (Figure 14.1).

    It is common to attribute modern growth to the factory-based industrialization that

    emerged from British inventions in textile production and steam power in the later eighteenth

    centurythe Industrial Revolution, represented dramatically by the patents of both Richard

    Arkwright's water frame for the mechanical spinning of cotton thread and James Watt's

    improved steam engine in 1769. These inventions created an explosion of urban factory-

    based industry particularly in textiles that made Britain the workshop of the worldby the

    1850s. By that time British factories provided some two-thirds of the worlds output of new

    technology industries(Bairoch 1982, p.288). Growth seemed to be the product of novel

    urban factory-manufacturing and the social changes that it brought about. Marx and Engels

    starting with the Communist Manifestoin 1848 put forward a forceful theory of economic

    growth in which the class of modern capitalists, owners of the means of social production

    and employers of wage labor,occupy center stage as the agents of disruptive but productive

    change (Marx & Engels 1848, chap.1). The spread of modern economic growth is usually

    seen as the spread of the British factory system to continental Europe and America. Marx

    remarked the country that is more developed industrially only shows, to the less developed,

    the image of its own future. (Marx 1867, p.ix). Economic historians, however, now question

    the closeness of the connection between urban factory industrialization and the emergence of

    modern economic growth. Estimates of overall income show modest connection with the

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    4/66

    2

    famous industrial breakthroughs. Britain was already relatively rich when the Industrial

    Revolution occurred and the innovations that created urban factory industrialization were the

    product of the already advanced economy. Similarly, incomes in continental Europe in the

    nineteenth century are not well explained by adoption or non-adoption of the technology that

    Britain pioneered.

    The emergence of Britains modern economic growth depended more on a long

    history of capitalism than on the Industrial Revolution. British capitalism, involved in large

    measure in enterprises of modest scale and created institutionsparticularly marketsthat

    supported efficient allocation, and reallocation, of resources and provided incentives

    consistent with wealth accumulation and innovation. As Chapter 1 pointed out the

    displacement of custom and command with durable and long lasting markets was potentially

    of key importance. Goods and factors markets were well-established in the late medieval

    Britain and Holland and persisted through the following centuries. These societies developed

    an economic lead that was apparent by the sixteenth century and rested on agricultural

    productivity and efficient service industries as much as on industrialization. The emergence

    of growth in continental Europe in the nineteenth century depended less on the spread of

    British-style industrialization and more on the spread of British-type capitalism and the

    institutions that supported it. Rising productivity across the economy created growth;

    excessive concentration on the spread of factory manufacturing overlooks much of a broader

    process.

    The British Industrial Revolution

    Estimates of aggregate economic activity underlie understanding of the beginnings of

    modern economic growth. Early quantitative analysis of the growth of British national

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    5/66

    3

    income appeared to support the traditional view of late eighteenth century inventions creating

    an Industrial Revolution (Hoffmann 1955; Deane & Cole 1967). Deane and Coles systematic

    use of the early censuses to estimate national income showed per capita income accelerated

    during the Industrial Revolution. Revision of the aggregate estimates since, however, has

    questioned sudden aggregate change arising from great factories of industrial capitalists.

    Some historians, most notably, Sir John Clapham who also drew on census data on

    occupations, had earlier questioned the representativeness of the new factory industries and

    the impact they had on the fundamental issue of raising standards of living. (Clapham 1926).

    Using Deane and Coles income estimates, D. N. McCloskey published a revealing calculation

    that suggested that technological advances in the new technology industries were

    insufficient to explain the acceleration of national income and concluded that technological

    change had become pervasive in early nineteenth century Britain, although it was still slow

    by twentieth century standards (McCloskey 1981, p.114). Views of a broader process of

    change and a revision of the timing of change were strongly supported when scholars

    revisited the pioneering estimates in the mid 1980s and concluded that Hoffmanns and

    Deane and Cole unconsciously exaggerated the discontinuity in the final decades on the

    eighteenth century. Harley pointed out that Hoffmanns estimate of industrial production

    index dealt with the incomplete coverage of manufacturing industries with an implicit

    assumption that other industries, in aggregate approximately the size of cotton textiles, shared

    cottonsexceptional growth following Arkwrights inventions (Harley 1982). Crafts re-

    examined Deane and Coles extrapolation of nineteenth century census data into the

    eighteenth century and their conversion of estimates of income in current prices into real

    income and concluded that aggregate growth was substantially slower between 1770 and

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    6/66

    4

    1840 (Crafts 1976; Crafts 1985). The changes in the aggregate estimates are illustrated in

    Figure 14.2. Slower growth in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth century implied that

    eighteenth century Britain must have already been richer than we had previously thought and

    that nineteenth century income levels depended less on the famous technological

    breakthroughs.

    Research (initially spearheaded by historians of the Asian economies (Pomeranz

    2001; Parthasarathi 1998; Parthasarathi 2011) has also placed British and European economic

    growth in a broader framework. Multinational comparisons of economic performance are

    tricky even if data are extensive and much harder in data scarce historical circumstances.

    However, labor income makes up the majority of national income. It can also be reasonably

    argued that the well-being of ordinary people is the best indicator of societal well-being and

    their income is almost entirely labor income. It is also the case that labor income is the most

    readily available component of historical income because corporate, public and private

    bodies whose archives make up most of the historical record regularly hired wage labor.

    Scholars have collected this material for the earlier developers and increasingly for later

    developing societies. The records are, of course, not perfect indicators of societal well-being

    particularly as in many societies only a small part of labor income passed through organized

    labor markets. Nonetheless, wage data deflated by indicators of the cost of living provide us

    with significant insights into historical economic performance.

    Prior to the nineteenth century, the balance between population and resources was the

    prime determinant of real wages. Figure 14.3 shows this clearly in the case of England. The

    fourteenth century Black Death which killed off over one third of the population resulted in a

    dramatic increase in real wages. Real wages declined to near pre-plague levels when

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    7/66

    5

    population eventual recovered, beginning at the end of the fourteenth century. Slower

    population growth after 1650 led to a rise of wages that ended in the mid-eighteenth century

    when population growth resumed. Only after the first quarter of the nineteenth century did

    increases in real wages accompany continued population growtha transformation to

    modern economic growth which reinforces traditional narratives of transformation at the end

    of the eighteenth century.

    Placing Englandsexperience in the context of other European regions, however,

    reveals a different picture (Allen 2001). The Malthusian fall in real wages of the fifteenth

    century occurred throughout Europe but by the sixteenth century another dynamic appeared.

    In the North Sea economiesthe Low Countries and Englandreal wages declined

    significantly less than elsewhere and in the early seventeenth century wages began to grow.

    This phenomenon, which Allen called the great divergence in European wages and Jan

    Luiten van Zanden the little divergence, (to distinguish it from the great divergence

    between developed economies and the rest) directs attention to a period well before the

    classical Industrial Revolution.

    Wage data are not as extensively available outside Europe and its off-shoots but

    research is beginning to fill the gaps (Allen 2001; Allen et al. 2011). Preliminary results show

    that in the eighteenth century real wages in major Asian cities were comparable to those in

    most of Europe with the important exception of the North Sea economies. European wages

    generally started to trend upwards in the nineteenth century but Asian wages declined until

    mid century and fell behind those in all but the poorest areas in Europe. The wage data

    challenge most economic historianssupposition that European incomes generally were

    superior to those in Asia in the early modern period and who have postulated general features

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    8/66

    6

    of European society as causes of modern economic growth. Perhaps we should not be

    surprised, however. Allen found that in most of Europe an unskilled laborersreal earnings

    fell in early modern times to below levels needed to support a modest family on the cheapest

    diet available (the unit (1) on the vertical axis of Figure 14.4 is the cost of supporting a family

    of a man, a wife and two small children on a bare subsistence diet primarily of oatmeal gruel

    or its equivalent).

    Although long-run comparative data have made it clear that we need to take a longer

    and broader view of the process of industrialization, the Industrial Revolution between 1770

    and 1840 remains important. The famous new technologies did not, in and of themselves,

    transform the economy, but they were early manifestations of the acceleration of the rate of

    technological change that characterizes modern growth. Most inventive activity undoubtedly

    arises from conscious search and successful technological improvement seldom emerges

    fully formed but rather requires expensive continuing research and development. Market

    conditions in late eighteenth century Britain greatly increased the likelihood that new

    technologies that substituted machinery, mechanical power sources and mineral fuels would

    occur there rather than elsewhere.

    First, as we have seen, British workers earned higher wages than workers elsewhere

    (the Low Countries excepted). Second, only in Britain had coal been extensively mined and

    technologies for its use as residential and industrial fuel evolved ((Allen 2009b; Hatcher

    1993; Nef 1932). Consequently, British manufacturers chose cost minimizing techniques that

    used capital and energy to save labor and British research and development had a machinery-

    using, fuel-intensive starting point. Elsewhere there was much less incentive to explore

    possibilities of this sort because firms were not currently employing coal-using and labor-

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    9/66

    7

    saving techniques. In addition, outside of Britain small improvements that used capital and

    fuel to save labor would not lower costs of production. It is hardly surprising, then, that the

    breakthroughs in machine-based cotton spinning, steam engines, and coke-iron production

    were British (Allen 2009b; Allen 2010).

    Of course, the innovations in machine-based cotton spinning, steam engines, and coke

    iron production were not small improvements but massive breakthroughs. Arkwrights water

    framethe most spectacularreduced the price of coarse cotton yarn to about a third of its

    mid-eighteenth century by the early nineteenth century and finer yarn by much more (Harley

    1998); Watts steam engine revolutionized power supply; Corts puddling-furnace and

    rolling-mill made coke production of wrought iron on a large scale profitable. Nonetheless,

    these changes modified existing practices adapted to high wages and cheap energy. While

    there seems to be no a priorireason to think that capital-intensive and energy-using

    techniques were more likely to generate technological breakthroughs than other techniques, it

    appears that for the past two centuries technological change has mostly clustered around

    improvements of techniques used in rich economies that employed capital, energy and raw

    materials intensively(Allen 2012). It is unclear whether this reflects the nature of possible

    technical improvement or identifies technologically advanced societies with advanced

    engineering skills and advanced capacity for innovation, and consequently high income

    levels.

    The argument that machine technology emerged from a conscious search process

    undertaken by entrepreneurs experienced in using capital-intensive methods because they

    operated with expensive labor and cheap energy seems compelling. As an explanation as to

    how and why economies entered into the era of modern economic growth, however, it is

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    10/66

    8

    unsatisfactory. Crudely, Allen argues that Britain became richer in the nineteenth century

    because it was already rich in the eighteenth. This is likely true, but it begs the basic question:

    why was eighteenth century Britain rich? Just as national income estimates and comparative

    real wages drive us to consider earlier developments, so does the search for the sources of the

    technology of the British Industrial Revolution.

    British prosperity: productive agriculture

    Nineteenth century international comparisons provide insights into the sources of

    Britains development leadership. The common perceptionis that economic advancement

    arose from superior productivity in modern manufacturing but when data allow comparison

    in the nineteenth century, Britain, although it pioneered the Industrial Revolution and

    developed a much larger manufacturing sector than its rivals, does not have much higher

    output per worker in manufacturing than France or Germany. Patrick OBrien and C. Keydar

    (Keyder & OBrien 1978)in their reinterpretation of French economic growth, estimated that

    labor productivity in French industry exceeded that in Britain during the first half of the

    nineteenth century by between ten and forty percent. These estimates may overstate the

    French achievement but Britain had little or no lead in industrial labor productivity (Crafts

    1984a). Nonetheless, Maddison estimates of French per capita income for 1830 at barely over

    two-thirds the British level and Allen reports real wages in Paris as between half and three

    quarters of those in London. Similarly, comparison with Germany for later in the century

    yields similar results. Stephen Broadberry estimated that labor productivity in German

    manufacturing in 1871was 93 per cent of British manufacturing productivity even though

    GDP per worker was only 60 percent (Broadberry 1997).

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    11/66

    9

    A main determinant of Britains higherper capita income was much higher

    productivity in agriculture. Low agricultural productivity characterized Europe outside the

    Low Countries. In Britain around 1840 (at a per capita income level of about $550, 1970 US

    dollars) the share of the labor force (25 percent) and the share of income (24.9 percent) in

    agriculture and extraction were very nearly equal. The average European experience at that

    income was an agricultural labor force share of 54 percent and an income share of 37 per

    cent. This implies that while output per worker in British agriculture was about the same as in

    the rest of the economy, the European norm of labor productivity in agriculture was only half

    of that elsewhere (Crafts 1984b; Crafts 1985). Broadberry finds that German agricultural

    productivity was 56 percent of British in 1870. The gap between agricultural productivity in

    Britain and the continent (outside the Low Countries) appeared between the early seventeenth

    century and the mid eighteenth century, well before the Industrial Revolution (Allen 2000).

    The distinctive, highly capitalistic nature of British agriculture appears to have

    generated high productivity. In most of Western Europe the typical farm was a peasant

    operation with customary tenancy and family control of farm operations and labor input. In

    contrast the typical British farmer was an entrepreneur who rented land from a landowner,

    provided the farms working capital and employed hired labor (Shaw-Taylor 2005; Shaw-

    Taylor 2012; Caird 1852). In older views improving landlords and enclosure of the open

    fields drove British agricultural change but research has firmly established that in the

    seventeenth and eighteenth centuries yeoman farmers on modest size farms initiated and

    adopted productivity enhancing changes in open-field villages as well as on enclosed farms

    (Allen 1992; Allen 1999; Allen 2009b, chap.3).Underlying driving forces cannot be firmly

    establishedbut British agricultures high level of market orientation both in selling its

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    12/66

    10

    produce and in organizing its inputs played a key role. This market orientation was

    longstanding, going back to medieval times and reinforced in the aftermath of the Black

    Death.

    Robert Brennertheory on the origin and nature of British agricultural precocity based

    in theories of capitalism provides a useful framework (Brenner 1976; Aston & Philpin 1987;

    Pamuk 2007). He saw capitalist farming evolve from late medieval class struggles. In Britain,

    the feudal elite became landlords with large land holdings and secure property rights. At the

    same time, all vestiges of medieval servile laborwhere serfs were required to work on the

    lords demesnedisappeared. Markets replaced customary and power relationships.

    Landlords had to compete for tenants to farm their land and tenants depended on the market

    for access to land. A regular agricultural wage labor market developed, particularly for young

    adults. Farmers who increased productivity were able to offer higher rents, hire labor and

    increase the size of their operations while less successful farmers gradually became wage

    laborers without the option of remaining family workers on customary tenancies.

    In contrast, in most of Western Europe, particularly in France and the western

    Germany, late medieval change abolished un-free feudal labor, but failed to provide elites

    with clear property rights. Instead, direct agricultural producers gained control of the land on

    customary tenures from which they could be removed only with difficulty. The elites

    integrated into state structures and extracted resources through taxation. Incentives to

    increased productivity were much weaker than in England. Landowners had little opportunity

    to select successful tenants to increase rental incomes. Less successful farmers did not

    depend on a rental market for access to land. Consequently, it was much more difficult for

    successful farmers to acquire larger holdings and less productive peasants were much less

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    13/66

    11

    likely to be forced into wage labor. Customary relationships remained strong and family

    workers tended to remain on agricultural holding when marginal product fell below wages

    elsewhere in the economy because they had access to a share of the returns of the family

    agricultural holding.

    The dating of the dominance of capitalist agriculture in Britain and its relationship to

    productivity advance is a matter of some dispute. The best documented evidence of the

    evolution of efficiency and agricultural structure comes from R.C. Allens study of the South

    Midlands (Allen 1992; Allen 2009b, chap.3). He shows that the most impressive gains in

    agricultural productivity occurred between 1600 and 1750. Although he argues that these

    were the product of the family farm, his evidence shows the importance of capitalist

    agriculture. He defines three farm categories: peasant farms of less than 60 acres relying on

    family labor; capitalist farms over 100 acres, where hired labor dominated the workforce; a

    transitional category completed the taxonomy. In the South Midlands in the early seventeenth

    century, enclosures occupied about 17.5 per cent of all land and 90 percent of this was in

    farms over 100 acres (although most of this was in very large holding that may have been

    sublet). In open field villages land was approximately evenly divided among the three classes

    of farm size. Overall, farms over 100 acres occupied a little over forty percent of all land and

    the other classes under thirty percent each. By the early eighteenth century the proportion of

    enclosed land had nearly doubled to about a third of the total. The dominance of large farms

    on enclosed land had declined somewhat but they still occupied nearly three quarters of the

    land. Large farms gained ground in open field villages where they now occupied over half the

    land. Overall, large farms occupied nearly sixty percent of the land in the South Midlands

    around 1700. Medium sized farms that employed labor on a continuous basis occupied

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    14/66

    12

    another twenty percent of the land. Peasant families on the French model where the decision

    margin regarding the use of labor was the peasant patrimony and not the labor market farmed

    only the remaining twenty percent of the land (Allen 1992, pp.31, 73).

    Recently, Leigh Shaw-Taylor has examined Allens conclusion. He confirms that the

    data from the South Midlands appears representative of the English heartland although it

    cannot hold for all of England. He also finds capitalist farming reached to smaller farms than

    Allen supposed. The majority of farms between 20 and 30 acres in Buckinghamshire reported

    to the 1851 census that they employed at least one male worker on 31 March, a slack date in

    the agricultural calendar (Shaw-Taylor 2005). He finds that in 1700 small-scale capitalism

    predominated in the south-east with three-quarters of the adult male agricultural workforce

    being proletarian (Shaw-Taylor 2012, p.57).

    It is perhaps strange that capitalist farming arose so strongly in England since in the

    early middle ages (11th and 12th centuries) feudal manorialism, where elites held non-market

    rights to labor of the agricultural population, was particularly strongly entrenched. In

    contrast, in the Low Countries, where capitalist agriculture and high productivity also

    emerged, manorialism was subverted by urban markets (Bavel 2010). Productive agriculture

    in both part of the North Sea economy emerged in conjunction with well-organized markets

    for factors of production (land, labor and capital). Product markets in peasant economies are

    common and developed in most parts of medieval Europe (see chapter by Persson in this

    volume). Markets for occasional labor are also common but very unusually a labor market

    emerged in the North Sea economies that played a primary role in labor allocation.

    The underlying determinants of labor market development are hard to trace but it

    seem associated with another unusual feature of north-western Europethe early emergence

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    15/66

    13

    of the European Marriage Pattern where newly married couples established a new household

    independent of the previous generation. The marriage union was consensual and brides were

    much older than typical in other societies. In late sixteenth century England brides were

    typically about 25 and grooms two or three years older. Elsewhere, marriages were usually

    arranged by parents, new couples integrated into families of the preceding generation and

    teenage brides typically married substantially older men. In late medieval England and the

    Low Countries young men and women left their parental home in their early teens to work

    for wages, usually in agriculture. They accumulated resources for about a decade and

    established independent households on marriage. Wage labor markets became well-

    established with young men and women forming the majority of participants. There is

    uncertainty as to the exact timing and extent of this market. Christopher Dyer has estimated

    that in fourteenth, fifteenth and sixteenth century England just under half the population was

    active in the labor market (and probably more in the most commercialized areas of the

    southeast) (Dyer 2005, pp.21820). In the most advanced parts of the Low Countries

    estimates have up to sixty percent of the population dependent on wage labor (Van Zanden

    2009; De Moor & Van Zanden 2010).

    Markets for the sale and leasing of land also developed in late medieval Europe, first

    in Italy and then in the North Sea economies (although Englands strong manorial tradition

    delayed its emergence somewhat). Modern short-term competitive leasing systems developed

    in parts of the Low Countries in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries and perhaps a century

    later in England (Bavel 2008).

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    16/66

    14

    The precocious allocation of labor to manufacturing

    A substantial portion of the English labor force was employed in manufacturing well

    before the Industrial Revolution. Deane and Colespath breaking quantitative assessment

    relied heavily on social tables Gregory King constructed about 1690 as a starting point. They

    tentatively concluded that agriculture employed somewhere between 60 and 80 percent of the

    labor force (Deane & Cole 1967, p.137). Indispensable as he was as a starting point, King

    painted a misleading picturea nation consisting of just London and a vast, poor

    agricultural hinterland....England and Wales were almost surely more industrial and

    commercial than he has led us to believe(Lindert 1980, p.707). Peter Lindert and Jeffrey

    Williamson modified this view (Lindert 1980; Lindert & Williamson 1982; Lindert &

    Williamson 1983) suggesting that Kings time 56 percent of the labor force was in the

    primary sector (agriculture), 18 percent in the secondary (manufacturing) and 26 percent in

    the tertiary sector.(service). In this picture Britain was still a highly agricultural economy

    (Crafts 1985).

    The Cambridge University Group for the History of Population and Social Structure

    (Shaw-Taylor & E. Wrigley 2008; Shaw-Taylor et al. 2010) are currently re-estimating

    eighteenth century occupational structure on the basis of information in a large number of

    baptismal records. Their preliminary results indicate that considerably fewer English men

    worked in agricultural and considerably more worked in manufacturing than even Lindert

    and Williamsons work suggested. The new estimates for about 1710 show agriculture and

    mining employed about 43 percent of the occupied male population and manufacturing

    employed 39 percent. Over the next century, the share of the labor force in agriculture

    declined only modestly to about 39 percent while the secondary sectors share increased to

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    17/66

    15

    only 42 percent. These results strongly reinforce the conclusion that Britain was already well

    on the way to a modern economy at the beginning of the eighteenth century.

    Although the great late eighteenth century innovations in textiles and in iron

    contributed to rising real incomes by lowering the costs of these products they do not seem to

    have greatly increased the proportion of the labor force in manufacturing. However,

    manufacturing concentrated geographically. In the early eighteenth century, Britains

    secondary sector employment was widely distributed. The proportion of males in the sector

    in Northern counties (47 percent) was higher than in the agriculturally-advantaged Southern

    counties but the southern proportion was still 39 percent. By the early nineteenth century,

    industrial employment had concentrated on a crescent of counties running from the West

    Riding of Yorkshire through Lancashire then south and west to Glamorgan in South Wales.

    In southern counties, the proportion of manufacturing workers had declined by more than a

    quarter to 28 percent while in the North, principally in Lancashire and the West Riding, they

    had increased by close to 62 percent. The bulk of southern de-industrialization occurred in

    textiles. Male employment in clothing manufacture also declined significantly, presumably

    due to the rise of ready-made clothing manufacture in the East Midlands and a feminization

    of the trade (Shaw-Taylor et al. 2010). A second factor was replacement of charcoal-based

    iron production by coal-based technology that drew the industry to the coal fields.

    Britain was already substantially an industrialized economy by the early eighteenth

    century. Manufacturing was widely dispersed and production units were still small. They,

    nonetheless, clearly produced for the market and were subject to competitive pressure.

    Textiles; clothing; leather processing; food and drink processing; and construction were by

    far the largest sectors, accounting for over three quarters of manufacturing in the mid-

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    18/66

    16

    eighteenth century (Harley 1982). Metal workers produced a wide variety of hardware and

    trinkets for consumer markets as well as tools for agriculture, construction and

    manufacturing. The high level of manufacturing production was a consequence of the

    relatively high income levels. Efficient agriculture released labor and there was consumer

    demandeven building laborers incomes provideda margin above subsistence and artisans

    could afford modest luxuries including imported groceries, particularly sugar, tea and

    tobacco, and modest amounts of manufactured goods. The well-to-do, including a rising

    middle class, probably still constituted the major consumer market for manufactured goods.

    Exports contributed importantly to Britains industrialization. Crafts calculated that

    exports made up about 45 percent of manufactured output in 1801 (Crafts 1985, p.127).

    Exports of woolen cloth to European markets completely dominated British exports until the

    early eighteenth century. Manufactured goods continued to dominate exports during the

    eighteenth century but important diversification occurred. By the third quarter of the

    eighteenth century exports to the Americas nearly equaled exports to Europe and were widely

    diversified with woolen cloth only a little over a quarter while metal products made up nearly

    twenty percent and miscellaneous manufactured goods were nearly as important as woolens

    (Davis 1962; Davis 1979).

    Competitive imperial expansion and mercantilism characterized the eighteenth

    century Atlantic Economy. Britain and France, and to a lesser extent the Netherlands,

    challenged Spains imperial claims and established colonies in the Caribbean and the English

    developed colonies on the North American mainland (chapter by OBrien in this volume).

    The colonial economies revolved around export staples (principally sugar but also tobacco in

    the English Chesapeake Bay) produced by African slaves. Mercantilist regulation reserved

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    19/66

    17

    the trade of each imperial power to its own subjects. In the mercantile contest the English did

    better than their rivals in developing markets for manufactured exports. Success did not arise

    from superior colonies in the Caribbeanthe British islands were high cost sugar producers,

    unable to compete with the rapidly growing output of French Saint Dominique without

    protection and their prosperity depended on English consumers paying higher sugar prices to

    support them. Nor were the English colonies particularly large compared to their rivals. What

    differentiated the British Empire was the large population in the settler colonies of the

    mainland who had been drawn, at least outside the Chesapeake, not by an export staple but

    by the prospect of establishing an independent existence in a new land.

    The settlers succeeded and population grew rapidly. By the third quarter of the

    seventeen century, some sixty percent of English manufactured exports to the Americas went

    to the mainland colonies (Davis 1979). These colonials financed their imports by selling

    temperate agricultural and forest products to the sugar islands and providing mercantile and

    shipping services. In this way the English paid for their sugar imports with manufactured

    goods exports. To what extent, then, did the growth of English manufactured exports depend

    on West Indian slavery? Certainly slave products ultimately financed exports to America.

    However, the answer to the more interesting question: would those exports have not existed if

    slavery had not existed? is less clear. The mainland colonies flourished largely independently

    of slavery. Englishmen probably would have settled and population grown rapidly even if the

    West Indian slave colonies had not existed. They would still have demanded European

    industrial goods. Without opportunities in the West Indies, they would have had to find other

    ways of financing imports that were inferior to those they used and imports would have been

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    20/66

    18

    smaller but it is likely that they would have remained substantial and helped to sustain

    Britains precocious industrialization.

    Conclusions on Britains industrialization

    Britains industrialization had deep roots; produced in an already well-developed

    capitalist economy that had long been mediated by markets. Product markets developed well

    before the Black Death. They may have retreated some with population decline but remained

    substantial and expanded when population recovered in the sixteenth century. More

    importantly and more unusually, late medieval markets for factors of production were also

    well-established. In early modern England most land was held in market contracts. In

    addition, most English men and women experienced a labor market in the countryside or in

    towns. Agriculture was unusually productive, probably because of its capitalist organization.

    The land rental market allowed successful farmers to expand while their less successful rivals

    lost land. In the early seventeenth century family labor remained important on most English

    farms but most of the acreage farmed employed hired labor. Under these circumstances, labor

    decisions were made with reference to a labor market. Feudal relationships had long since

    disappeared. There was not significant class of peasant cultivatorsat least in sense of small

    farms that had customary or ownership rights to their land, who were only tangentially

    involved in the product market, and organized their labor independently of labor markets.

    The penetration of markets resulted in what economic historians have come to refer to

    as Smithian growth following Adam Smiths observation that specialization and

    productivity advance was limited by the extent of the market. Smith recognized three growth

    inducing processes: specialization and exchange that exploits comparative advantage; capital

    accumulation; technological improvement. These can all be seen in Britain by the eighteenth

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    21/66

    19

    century. Agricultural improvement was stimulated by market opportunities, presented most

    conspicuously by the growth of London as a trading, administration, production and

    consumption centre. Modern industrialization is often seen as a process that substitutes

    mineral sources of power for pre-modern sources based on human and animal muscle and

    wood all of which are limited by agricultural resources. Britain developed coal as a source of

    power and fuel long before the late eighteenth century industrialization. Englishmen had been

    learning how to use coal from at least the seventeenth century (Allen 2009a; Allen 2009b;

    Hatcher 1993; Nef 1932). Builders experimented in the use of coal for domestic heating and

    by the eighteenth century Newcastle coal heated London houses. Coal also provided heat for

    many industrial processes from brewing beer to refining copper. Iron masters experimented

    in using coal but chemical problems remained unsolved until the end of the eighteenth

    century. Within textile production, the largest pre-modern manufacturing industry, large

    numbers of merchant manufacturers, many immigrants from warfare in the Low Countries

    and religious intolerance in France and others inspired by continental examples developed

    new techniques and fabrics (the so-called New Draperies).

    In this view of British development, which rests on statistical analysis, long-run

    international comparisons of standards of living and a long view of institutions and

    innovation, it appears inappropriate to overemphasize the famous decades of the 1760s and

    1770s and the achievements of Arkwright, Watt and Cort. There are two perspectives that are

    worth reviewing. First, how much did the inventions contribute to economic growth? Here

    statistical analysis shows that the impact was limited. More importantly, did these

    developments mark the start of an era of faster and more sustained technological change? By

    current standards technological change and growth of living standards before the nineteenth

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    22/66

    20

    century was so slow as to be barely noticeable. Growth, mainly driven by technological

    change, accelerated in the middle of the nineteenth century to eventually reach twentieth

    century levels of about one percent per year (Crafts 2004a; Crafts & Harley 1992; Crafts & T.

    C. Mills 2009). Although the technological change in textiles in the late eighteenth century

    and early nineteenth century was rapid and had the highly visible impact of enlarging an

    already large textile sector and concentrating it in urban factories, its impact on overall

    growth was modest. The innovations of the late eighteenth century can be seen as the result

    of a sustained research and development program that extended existing ideas in a high wage

    environment; the inventions fit within a longer continuum of Smithian growth.

    Arkwright transformed and concentrated Britains largest manufacturing sector in a

    manner that caught the attention of contemporaries and historians but did not greatly increase

    aggregate growth. Nonetheless, the successful application of mechanical manipulation

    (clock-work) on a large scale and the development of the factory as a primary locus of

    production marked important steps in the evolution of technology. Cotton factories

    stimulated the development of specialist machine producers who became a locus of improved

    technology (Rosenberg, 1994). That said, however, it is hard to see fundamental changes

    emerging from the textile innovations. For example, we might ask: did the cotton innovations

    make the railway more likely? Probably not. In many ways the breakthrough in cotton was

    not all that different from, say, the expansion of large-scale pottery production in the West

    Midlands by Wedgewood and others. Watts improvements in the steam engine and Corts

    development of improved methods of using coal to produce wrought iron had similar

    characteristics. They were the result of conscious application of resources to already defined

    research and development programs. They both marked stages on the evolution of

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    23/66

    21

    technological change. Both involved, at least at a modest level, the introduction of science

    into industrial research and development.

    During the nineteenth century the success of the industries of the Industrial

    Revolution within the international economy continued to influence Britain. The textile

    industries, highly concentrated in Lancashire and the West Riding of Yorkshire, and the large

    coal-based ironworks on the coal fields captured the most attention. Foreign trade contributed

    the growth of both. Even before the French Revolution, the Lancashire cotton industry

    enthusiastically supported freer trade and the Eden Treaty with France (1786). Competition

    drove down the price of yarn dramatically and low yarn prices in England attracted foreign

    buyers even in the face of severe wartime disruption. By the time peace was restored in 1815

    the British cotton mills were selling to foreign customers as much as to their countrymen.

    Although the technology quickly became available overseas as a result of foreigners copying

    the English practice, hiring British mechanics and, after the 1843 repeal of the British

    prohibition of the export of machinery, buying machinery exported by English makers

    (Jeremy 1981), the British remained the low cost producer of all but the simplest fabrics and

    two-thirds of output was exported until the outbreak of the First World War. Woolen

    manufacturers did not capture world markets to the same extent but exported a large portion

    of their output. Consequently, the textile industries were much larger than they would have

    been if they had depended on domestic markets (Findlay & ORourke 2007).

    Puddling and rolling for wrought iron production also grew in response to Britians

    changed position in the international market. Before Corts inventions nearly sixty percent of

    the wrought iron used in Britain was imported, principally from timber and ore abundant

    Sweden and Russia ((Hyde 1977; Harley 1982; Fremdling 2000). The industry initially grew

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    24/66

    22

    largely by displacing imports. By the early decades of the nineteenth century, however,

    Britain was exporting pig iron and wrought iron. The railways, first in Britain and then

    elsewhere, greatly increased the demand for iron and Britain was the principal international

    provider. Rainer Fremdling calculated that in the late 1840s railway iron consumed a little

    over a quarter of British iron production and about forty percent of that was exported for use

    in the United States and Western Europe. Although the importance of railway iron declined

    in the subsequent decade to a bit over a sixth of output as the pace of British railway

    construction eased and output increased by about seventy percent as other uses of iron

    expanded. Exports continued to increase primarily to meet the demands of the expanding

    railway networks in the United States and Europe (Fremdling 1977). Technological

    leadership also supported the growth of British engineering. In the 1840s the industry

    succeeded in having prohibitions on the exports of machinery repealed and exports expanded

    rapidly. British machine-makers dominated world textile markets and were strong in other

    industries. British engineers and machinery were central to early railway construction on the

    Continent. For example, between 1838 and 1841 the Prussian Railways purchased 48 of its

    first 51 locomotives from British manufacturersthe dominance of British manufacturers

    then declined and locomotives were almost entirely of German manufacture (Fremdling

    1977).

    British technological leadership was enhanced by the isolation engendered by the

    Revolutionary and Napoleonic Warsfor twenty years British firms gained experience in the

    new technologies while potential rivals on the continent had little access to British practice.

    Lower prices from technological leadership led to extensive exports. We should, however, be

    careful not to attribute too much gain to the British from these exports. British competitive

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    25/66

    23

    capitalism eliminated excess profits rapidly. Prices fell as firms entered industries to take

    advantage of lower costs. The benefits from technological improvement took the form of

    cheaper goods enjoyed by consumers and not higher profits for firms. Exports grew because

    prices fell; the foreign consumers of the goods shared the benefits of improved productivity

    with British consumers (Harley 2004).

    In the long run, the steam engine was probably the most important technological

    development of the classical Industrial Revolution. Several points need to be made, however.

    First, Watt clearly drew on earlier developments, particularly Newcomens pumping engine

    that had been in use since early in the eighteenth century. Second, the impact of the steam

    engine depended as much on its further development as on Watts innovations. Third, the

    impact of steam engines, even in cotton manufacturing which dominated its earliest use

    outside of pumping applications, was minor until the 1830s (von Tunzelmann 1978). The

    great contribution of steam to increased efficiency came from its later application to

    transportationrailways and steamships. These innovations impressively lowered costs and

    induced investment that increased the amount of capital per worker (Crafts 2004b; Crafts

    2004a). Crafts calculated that from 1830 to the First World War, steam power and the

    investments it induced in transportation networks generated about a third of a percent per

    year growth in labor productivity, but before 1830 its contribution was barely noticeable at

    one or two tenths of a percent per year. The contributions of the other famous industries were

    much less. The cotton industrys spectacular technological transformation may have

    increased the growth of the economy by a eighth of one percent a year between 1780 and

    1860. Improvements in agriculture (a much larger sector with slower technical change)

    contributed a little more. The other modernized industries together contributed rather less

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    26/66

    24

    than cotton (Harley 1999). The sustained growth in per capita income after 1830 (a little over

    one percent per year, three quarters of which arose from total factor productivity growth)

    resulted from improvements broadly across the economy and cannot be explained mainly by

    changes in the famous industries. No historian has yet carried out an accounting exercise to

    quantify this process but we know changes were widespread. Agricultural productivity

    continued to rise. New, improved and cheaper chemicals and glass appeared. Food processing

    improved with such things as better flour mills, refrigeration and packaged food. The sewing

    machine increased productivity in clothing manufacture and shoe making. Improvements in

    machine making and steel contributed to productivity advance but generally it must be

    concluded that change were broadly spread through the economy. This was the dynamics of

    capitalism at work on a broad scale (Bruland & Mowery 2005).

    During the Industrial Revolution (1770-1830) the average real wage of British male

    workers changed little (Feinstein 1998; Allen 2007; Clark 2005). Wage experiences varied

    rural workers in the south of England suffered as population growth and deindustrialization

    hit their labor market; handloom weavers initially benefited from cheap yarn but then their

    swollen numbers were victims of mechanization. Wages increased in urban factories but

    workers faced an unhealthy environment, loss of freedom and an absence of amenities

    (Williamson 1985). During and after the French Revolution, the state responded to war and

    fear of unrest by suppressing working class rights and political expression. Child labor

    intensified and the economic conditions of working class women probably deteriorated with

    the enclosure of common lands and the decline of manufacturing in the countryside

    certainly the widespread employment in spinning disappeared (Humphries 2011). Optimists,

    however, point out that factors other than industrialization keep wages down: population

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    27/66

    25

    grew at one and a half percent a yeara rate that historically would have been accompanied

    by falling wages; the Revolutionary and Napoleonic Wars were extremely expensive and

    protracted. From the 1830s the real wages of working men clearly trended upwards and were

    about fifty percent higher by 1880. Many working-class families in Britain at the end of the

    nineteenth century remained desperately poor but almost all were less poor than their great-

    grandparents had been at the end of the eighteenth century and few experienced the levels of

    poverty that were common in Italy or eastern Europethe poorer parts of Europe.

    Industrialization in Continental Europe

    Narratives of the spread of industrialization in Europe have tended, following Marxs

    comment that the country that is more developed industrially only shows, to the less

    developed, the image of its own future, to revolve around the spread of the leading

    industries of Britains Industrial Revolution factory-based textiles; iron; mechanical

    engineeringwith tables of cotton consumption, pig iron output, coal production and railway

    mileage (Pollard 1981; Landes 1969). This provides insights into the particular industries and

    the process of technology transfer but is inadequate for three reasons. First, these industries

    are insufficient to explain Britains success. Second,local conditionsparticularly expensive

    labor and cheap energy from coalstrongly influenced these industries success in Britain

    and affected continental development. Third, Britains industries grew becausefalling prices

    and Britains continuing first-mover advantage supported massive exports markets. Followers

    could hardly have replicated this experience.

    Britains technological achievement, particularly in textiles and iron, significantly

    affected continental industries but there were important national differences in responses.

    Imports from Britain challenged established producers who obtained tariffs protection.

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    28/66

    26

    British technology was copied, particularly in modern textile production, through industrial

    espionage and more importantly through the employment of skilled British workers and after

    the 1843 by the purchase of British machinery, (Bruland 2003). Textiles emulated British

    methods but experience differed from place to place. France adopted heavy tariff protection

    in the face of cheap British imports after the Napoleonic Wars. Consequently, machine

    spinning became established with the aid of British skilled workers but with higher costs than

    in England. (Landes 1969, pp.15863; Milward & Saul 1973, pp. 2707, 31622). In Prussia,

    however, protection was moderate and consequently, imports of British yarn expanded as did

    handloom weaving. In the late 1830s about two thirds of the cotton yarn used in the German

    states was imported (Pollard 1981, p.181).

    The spread of coal-based iron production was more complicated because success

    depended on coal and ore and because the older charcoal-based technology produced superior

    iron that commanded a higher price. Again tariff policy was important. France adopted

    complete protection while the German Zollverein enacted lower tariffs with a structure that

    encouraged the import of pig iron for domestic refining. Continental iron masters adopted

    new iron technologies at different rates and in different combinations depending on resources

    and markets. Charcoal-smelted pig iron persisted but coal was increasingly used for refining

    wrought iron. Even in the highly protected French market, coal-smelted pig iron initially had

    trouble competing. The coming of the railways in the 1840s created a mass demand for lower

    quality iron and coal-based pig iron production finally became established on coal fields in

    France and Belgium and Silesia, and, after deep mines were sunk in the 1840s, in the German

    Ruhr (Fremdling 1977; Fremdling 2000; Evans & Rydn 2005). Elsewhere the absence of

    coal precluded the industrys development.

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    29/66

    27

    The most important transfer of British technology was undoubtedly the railways.

    They stimulated investment and finance and transformed the fortunes of the iron industry.

    More fundamentally they integrated national markets allowing greater specialization in both

    industry and agriculture.

    In narratives that revolve around textiles and iron, Belgium and Germany emerged as

    the principal successes while France disappointed. Belgium maintained its position as highly

    industrialized region with about 30 percent of its national income in the industrial sector in

    1870 (only Britain with 34 percent had more) (Broadberry, Fremdling, et al. 2010, p.170). In

    the mid nineteenth century, factory textile firms took over from traditional textile producers

    (present from medieval times) but not without creating hardship for traditional hand-loom

    weavers. More importantly, engineering firms developed impressive capacity in machine-

    building (although they were slow to turn to new industries in the final years of the century).

    The Belgian iron industry continued to grow with the successful switch to steel production

    and the development of larger firms and plant. It, however, lost its initial continental

    leadership to German rivals (Milward & Saul 1977, pp.15465).

    After the 1848 revolutions, Germany was the great success in this narrative. Building

    railroads and political change began the transformation and the iron and steel industry took

    pride of place. In the final quarter of the century, German iron and steel firms increased the

    size, capital intensity and modernity of their plants and firms like Krupp became

    technological leaders. Germans produced a quantity of steel second only to the United States

    and exported steel, particularly to markets in continental Europe (Landes 1969, pp.24969).

    Along with iron and steel, engineering flourished in the aftermath of the railway. German

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    30/66

    28

    capitalists supplied not only the domestic market but also much of the machinery, outside of

    textile-machines, demand in Europe.

    The conventional narrative delineates the development of some important industries

    but one must question how much insight it provides into the process of modern economic

    growth. Although the title of this essay is European industrialization the process by which

    sustained growth of income per head developed is clearly the important issue. In our

    discussion of Britain we have already seen that the British model of textiles and iron can

    explain only a small proportion of Britains growth. Similar conclusions are appropriate for

    continental Europe. Narratives that assume modern economic growth emerged by emulating

    the leading sectors of mid-nineteenth Britain exaggerates the role and contribution of a few

    new industries.

    First, the industries that are most studied and taken to indicate the emergence of

    economic growth made up only a modest a share of manufacturing and a much smaller

    portion of national income. In Germany, the metal industriesincluding iron and steel and

    engineeringcontributed about 15 percent of the value of manufacturing around 1870. Since

    manufacturing, including mining, construction and utilities, amounted to a little over a

    quarter of national income these industries amounted to less than four percent of national

    output (Broadberry, Fremdling, et al. 2010, pp.16874). The Germany metal industry in 1913

    was about 10 times as large as it had been in 1870. This is impressive growth but some

    simple calculations put it into perspective. First we can exaggerate the sectors effect by

    assuming for simplicity that the growth occurred without increasing the share of resources

    used in the industry (thus not reducing the output of other sectors of the economy). In fact,

    although productivity gains in metal production were impressive at 2.4 percent per year

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    31/66

    29

    (Milward & Saul 1977, p.26), this plus an increase in the labor force equal to population

    growth would have only increased metal output by a little less than four-fold. If all the ten-

    fold growth had been productivity gain it would have increased national income by about

    thirty-five percent. Thirty-five percent appears to be a large increase but is a growth rate of

    somewhat under 1 percent annually. German population was growing at 1.16 percent per year

    so productivity growth of the metal industries alone would have resulted in a decline in per

    capita income. More realistically, if we assume the rest of the economy grew at the same rate

    as population growth, the growth of metal production would have increased per capita

    income about twenty percent or under half a percent per year. Since Germany per capita

    income more than doubled between 1870 and 1913, the contribution of the metal and

    engineering industries was modest. Many will object to placing much weight on the

    preceding calculations. After all, the key story of the geneses of dynamic change is absent

    from the calculation. However, quantitative historians are fond of quoting Samuel Johnson on

    the effect of simple calculations: "That, Sir, is the good of counting. It brings everything to a

    certainty, which before floated in the mind indefinitely" (quoted in (McCloskey 1981,

    p.105)).

    Cotton textiles, which led the introduction of the factory system in Britain, is the other

    industry on which traditional narratives concentrate. Again, unless the goal is to trace

    emulation of Britain, the focus is strange. Factory-based machine-spinning became

    established throughout Europe and the textile industries grew but if we were to carry out an

    exercise like that above we would find a similar result. On average the textile and clothing

    industries were a little over twice the size of the metal industries but grew more slowly. More

    troubling, however, is the fact that textile industries in continental Europe depended on

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    32/66

    30

    protection from the more efficient British industry. This had, of course, also been true of the

    metal industries until the last quarter of the century when Germanys industry became

    competitive. No such growing-up of mass-production textile industries occurred and

    consequently European consumers real incomes were reduced by the growth of their

    domestic textile industry. There were, of course, some exceptions. Silk production grew in

    France and Italy thrived in export markets and was never threatened by British firms. French

    firms successfully held onto high fashion textiles and clothing. The protected cotton

    industries introduced urban factories to the continent, and may have stimulated mechanical

    engineering and generally enhanced the technological capability but most of the industrys

    machinery was imported from Britain. It is hard to sustain a claim that cotton textiles were

    the engine of growth.

    Railways are the third great indicator of industrialization and here the story is

    somewhat different. Transportation services are, of course, location specific and not tradable.

    Railway technology was quickly adopted across Europe, with some modest delays relating to

    government policy and finance. Technology and finance were readily available

    internationally although modest commercial prospects in more backward regions led to

    government involvement in finance either directly with state debt or by guaranteeing interest

    on railway debt. In either case most of the capital came from foreign investors. The direct

    impact of railways on transportation varied depending on the pre-existing transportation

    network and the level of commercial development. In particular the impact was less in

    regions with well-developed water transportation. Various calculations of the transportation

    cost saving generated by the railways, while somewhat problematic, are in the neighborhood

    of five percent of national income (Broadberry, Federico, et al. 2010, p.81). Unlike iron and

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    33/66

    31

    steel or textiles, transportation improvements brought by the railway almost certainly had

    spill-over that affected growth widely. In particular, cheaper, faster and more reliable

    transportation and communications (aided by the telegraph that accompanied railways)

    integrated national economies allowing greater specialization in both industry and

    agriculture. Efficient producers expanded at the expense of small local and relatively

    inefficient firms and household production. For example, Berlinsituated in a backward

    agricultural area east of the Elbe distant from the main markets in western Germany

    become a major producer of engineering and consumer products for all of Germany.

    Agriculture was profoundly affected. Agricultural historians note that market access was an

    important determinant of investment and technological improvement (Hoffman 1996;

    Grantham 1989; Allen 2003). Railways brought remote areas all across Europe into closer

    contact with urban markets and stimulated productivity advance. Nonetheless, the impact of

    railways was large only when they successfully interacted with wider forces of economic

    change.

    Per capita income and inadequacy of British model

    Historians have constructed estimates of national income for the past. These figures

    should be viewed as work in progress and used with care. The data that modern statisticians

    use are not available before the mid-twentieth century and officials who collected earlier

    statistical material did not think in terms of a concept of national income. Nonetheless it is

    almost impossible to think about economic growth without an estimate of aggregate activity.

    Without them, we rely on impressions that overemphasize the novel, the spectacular and the

    new. Table 14.1 below provides estimates for European countries from the eighteenth century

    to the First World War. They show (as do the long-run real wage figures above) there was a

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    34/66

    32

    gradient of incomes in Europe prior to the nineteenth century industrialization. The highest

    incomes were in the Netherlands and Britain while lower incomes prevailed in the Southern

    and Eastern periphery. The national income figures also correspond with the narrative

    historys conclusion thatGermany was a particular success but that success was primarily in

    overcoming initial backwardness. Even in 1913 Germany does not stand out as having

    achieved high income per capita. National income statistics also highlight the fragility of

    narratives of economic growth based on industrialization driven by textiles and iron. They

    show the success of Germany and Belgium but the companion story of failure of France and

    the Netherlands must be abandoned.

    When we look at the structure of industry in France we are struck almost immediately

    by the small size of the metal and mining sectors which loom large in conventional

    narratives. French economy grew quite slowly in aggregate when compared to Britain and

    Germany (1.6 percent per year in contrast to 1.9 and 2.8 percent for Britain and Germany) but

    during the same period British population increased by two-thirds and German population

    nearly doubled while Frances increased by only fourteen percent. Consequently, as we can

    see from Table 14.1, German growth per capita only slightly exceeds that of France and

    France grew considerably faster than Britain. France grew with a very different economic

    structure than Germany or Britain. Metal and mining were unimportant primarily because

    France had poor coal resources. Industrialization followed a different path and agriculture

    declined relatively more slowly without substantially hurting overall growth. In 1870, France

    and Germany both had half their working population in agriculture; by 1913, the share in

    Germany had fallen to thirty-five percent but in France it remained at forty-one percent.

    French slower population growth put less pressure on rural population.

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    35/66

    33

    Research on the French economy now effectively challenges the failure narrative.

    OBrien and Keyder demonstrated that productivity in French industry was high during the

    eighteenth and nineteenth century. They summarize the difference between French and

    British industry as follows:

    Value added per worker remained high in France because industry specialised in

    higher-value products. For such products, differentiated in quality and style, the

    workshop unit of production, often organized on a family basis, could train

    skilled labor and cater effectively for local and other specific demands (Keyder &

    OBrien 1978, pp.1789).

    Mechanization, large factories and the extensive use of mineral fuels were among the

    changes in industrializing Europe but they were not necessary to generate economic growth.

    In many sectors small-scale capitalist enterprises remained efficient and profitable. By the

    last years of the nineteenth new industries were developing and France performed well,

    achieving leadership in automobile, aviation and electrical engineering, for example. Recent

    detailed examination of comparative income statistics confirms the high levels of

    productivity in French industry in the early twentieth century (Woltjer et al. 2010).

    The national income statistics reveal two other successful economies that did not

    follow the British-Germany modelthe Netherlands and Denmark. The Netherlands is

    covered in detail in another chapter. Here it is only necessary to note that although a story of

    relative failure of growth in the Dutch economy in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries

    has large elements of truth, per capita income remained high despite the failure to adopt the

    so-called key industries. Efficient services, specialized agriculture and associated food

    production and other light industries provided incomes that rivaled those in Britain through

    most of the nineteenth century. The Danish story is even more impressive. The economic

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    36/66

    34

    structure was even more heavily biased towards specialized food production and processing

    than the Dutch but the Danes attained growth rates of per capita income between 1820 and

    1913 that were close to those achieved by Germany by specializing completely differently.

    Gerschenkron, relative backwardness and convergence

    Exploring the development of the industries that were at the forefront of Britain's

    Industrial Revolution provides information about the spread of technology but fails to

    provide an adequate basis for understanding the mechanisms involved in the emergence of

    modern economic growth. In what is probably the most influential essay in European

    economic history in the past two generations, Alexander Gerschenkron suggested a typology

    of the history of European industrialization that gave prominence to initial conditions of

    backwardness at the start of industrialization and focused on systematic substitutions for the

    "prerequisites" of growth that had been present in Britain's industrialization (Gerschenkron

    1962).

    Contemporaries and historians alike were aware that the most advanced economies

    lay in Britain and the Netherlands in the north-west. Moving east across the North European

    Plain gradation of backwardness seemed obvious. France's relative backwardness vis a vis the

    North Sea economieswas perhaps open to debate. The western states of Germany,

    however, were clearly more backward than France or the Low Countries. As one crossed the

    Elbe, the level of backwardness increased and Russia was clearly well behind. Moving from

    north to south a similar gradient appeared although generalization was more tenuous because

    legacies of earlier urban commercial success remained and significant differences in climate

    affected agriculture. The south of France was behind the north; Italy, despite its illustrious

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    37/66

    35

    past, lagged badly. The Balkans, influenced by their troubled history on the periphery of the

    Ottoman Empire, as well as their fragmented geography, lagged even further behind.

    Gerschenkron accepted that backwardness was multi-dimensions but various

    indicators yielded the same ranking. The most obvious indicator was per capita income, or

    general standard of living but the profile of backwardness was also visible in a range of

    institutional features, three, all characteristics of developed capitalism, stand out: the

    organization of agriculture; the extent of commercialization and urbanization and the general

    penetration of commodity markets; the development of factor markets for both labor and

    capital. Capitalist agriculture with well-developed markets in labor and land predominated in

    Britain and, in a different form in the Low Countries; peasant farmers dominated French

    agriculture and western Germany; beyond the Elbe aristocratic landlords farmed under feudal

    relations using forced labor and draft animals of serfs. At the most extreme was Russian

    serfdom. The extent of markets diminished from west to east. Britain and the Netherlands had

    well-developed financial markets; France, although it lagged somewhat behind, also had

    well-developed, if somewhat different, institutions (Hoffman et al. 2001). There was some

    financial development in western Germany but little further east. In Britain and in the

    Netherlands, labor markets dominated the allocation of labor and most of the population had

    labor market experience. In French and western Germany some two-thirds of the labor force

    in the eighteenth century was in agriculture mainly organized on the basis of the custom of

    the peasant family rather than the labor market. The serfdom east of the Elbe was based on

    un-free labor under obligation of providing labor to landlords.

    Gerschenkron put forward a number of hypotheses regarding the influence of relative

    backwardness, some of which have survived critical examination better than others. His

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    38/66

    36

    predictions include the hypothesis that industrialization in a more backward economy started

    with a more rapid spurt than had characterized more advanced economies. This rapid growth

    arose out of several related ideas. First, there was a gap between the technological

    possibilities demonstrated by the advanced economies and the current economy. If the

    institutional forces preventing development could be overcome, there was a potential for

    rapid catch-up growth. Second, in backward economies, the majority of the population in low

    productivity agriculture and organized on the basis of either family or servile labor (or some

    combination of both) demanded few goods on the market and so could not provide the basis

    for development of consumers' goods industries. For growth to occur it was necessary to

    achieve a development blocof producersgoods industries that could provide each other

    markets. Consequent, growth began with a big spurt.

    In conditions of backwardness, markets for finished goods and factors of production

    were poorly developed and consequently, entrepreneurs could not rely on wide-spread

    competition among buyers and sellers to insure that products could be readily sold at

    competitive prices or that inputs and intermediate goods could be readily purchased in

    required quantities. In Industrial Revolution Britain broad markets existed permitting firms to

    develop on a small scale and concentrate on a production niche confident that inputs could be

    readily purchased and output, even intermediate goods in a longer production chain, could be

    sold. In backward economies, firms found that it was necessary to adopt hierarchical

    organization within the firm to overcome market limitations. As a result, larger firms

    emerged that often integrated the entire process from raw material supply to final product

    sale under managerial control (Harley 1991).

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    39/66

    37

    Finance also was less market-oriented in more backward economies. In Britain, small

    firms had been able to finance development by a variety of means because financial

    transactions were well-developed. Firms generally grew from funds accumulated in pre-

    existing mercantile-manufacturing, personal contacts, the existing network of trade credit and

    the short-term financing that British commercial banks were willing to offer. Behind these

    arrangements, well-developed financial markets in bills of exchange, and a stock exchange

    supported the development of diversified portfolios for investors. For more capital intensive

    infrastructure like turnpikes and canals, trusts and companies were organized to tap more

    extensive sources of funds (Harris 2000, sec.2). When railways demanded exceptionally large

    amounts of capital in a short period of time, they were able to borrow directly on the stock

    exchange. In conditions of moderate backwardness, in Gerschenkron's narrative primarily

    Germany but also France and Italy, commercial sources and financial markets did not have

    the capacity to provide the same financing and substitutes developed in the form of the large

    universal banks beginning with the Crdit Mobilier in France and then dominating finance in

    Germany. These institutions accepted deposits and made commercial loans but were also

    willing to take longer-term positions in the financing of large firms and to act as

    intermediaries in the issuing and distribution of stock to investors. In conditions of extreme

    backwardness, exemplified by Russia, conditions were too backward even to support this sort

    of bank and the state played an important role in industrial finance with public debt proving

    an instrument that investors, particularly the richer west, were willing to hold.

    Backwardness also influenced the choice of techniques by firms in newly established

    industries. Backwardness provided a tension for entrepreneurs between employing the latest

    technology that had been developed in more advanced economies to suit their high wage

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    40/66

    38

    conditions and the cheap labor of the backward economy. In fact, however, the dilemma was

    to a large extent false. To be sure raw brute labor was cheap but skilled labor and even

    disciplined labor suitable for factory production was scarcer than in advanced economies.

    Consequently, and apparently paradoxically, industries like steel the backward economy

    installed the most advanced labor-saving technology in key parts of production while using

    cheap unskilled, or brute, labor as much as possible in auxiliary operations.

    Backward agriculture played a major role in Gerschenkron's thinking and was the

    subject of two of his major works (Gerschenkron 1943; Gerschenkron 1966). He concluded

    that the contribution of agriculture to the growth process declined with backwardness because

    the poverty of agriculture and the tenuous connection of agricultural workers to the market

    limited the sectors contribution to demand. Because of its institutional nature the agricultural

    sector did not release labor and create a market-oriented work force as happened in Britain.

    Gerschenkron's schema provides substantial insight into the variation within European

    industrialization, particularly when combined with an awareness of the importance of coal for

    the development on industry on the British model. It is particularly useful in illuminating

    differences in institutional structure that emerged in different countries. It is hardly surprising

    that the generalizations have proven too sweeping to be a totally reliable guide to the

    complex economic history of modern Europe. Gerschenkrondespite his avowed aim to

    replace Marx's great generalization that more backward countries follow the path of

    industrialization carved out by the first examplestill thought in terms of emulating the

    British experience of large urban factories and a vibrant iron industry. The substitutions of

    prerequisites that he identifiedlarge hierarchical firms, a key role for banks and the state in

    finance, the adoption of the most advanced technology to overcome the shortcomings of

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    41/66

    39

    labor in backward economieswere largely relevant for the big industriesand like other

    discussions with similar focus, it is less helpful in understanding less spectacular

    development of other sectors.

    Gerschenkron's big spurtat the start of industrialization has proven hard to find in

    aggregate statistics (Crafts et al. 1991). However, there is connection with the idea of

    convergence of income levels among economies is particular growth clubsin which

    economies that have initially lower incomes tend to grow more rapidly and converge towards

    income levels of initially richest economies. Convergence certainly occurred in Western

    Europe by the late twentieth century although in the European periphery it was little in

    evidence until the midtwentieth century. Convergence is, of course, by no means

    guaranteed. On a global scale the history of the nineteenth and twentieth century has been

    one of divergence, big timewith a small club of successful economies in western Europe

    and its offshoots growing much faster than poorer economies elsewhere, increasing global

    inequality.

    Agriculture

    When we shift our focus from the greatindustries to a more holistic view of

    economies and the levels of income that they generated, backwardness and its implications

    for growth across European return our attention to agriculture. High agriculture productivity

    was a leading determinant of Britain's relatively high incomes at an early date. Allens recent

    estimates of comparative output per worker in agriculture for some key European countries

    are presented in Table 14.3 along with estimates for the years just before the First World

    War.

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    42/66

    40

    The high productivity of the Netherlands (shared with Belgium) in the late eighteenth

    century is apparent but low productivity elsewhere is more striking. Contemporaries did not

    see these data but the relative backwardness of continental agriculture was apparent and

    associated with agricultural institutions. In England capitalist agriculture had proceeded to its

    limit. In France, and to a somewhat lesser extent in western Germany, peasant proprietors

    with secure title to land farmed with family labor. In France, peasant security of title was

    enhanced by the Revolution and as Patrick OBrien notes, [b]y abolishing seigniorial dues

    and suppressing tithes, the Revolutionaries also transferred agricultural income back to those

    who farmed the land. At a stroke, the tax and judicial reforms of the 1790s lightened burdens

    on the peasantry and enhanced their capacity to prosper on small plots of land(OBrien

    1996, p.228).

    In Germany east of the Elbe a more backward feudal system of estate agriculture

    Gutsherrschaftpredominated. Aristocrats farmed their estates to the largest possible degree

    using enforced serf labor of which there were two classes. More substantial peasants with

    property rights were required to provide draft animals and stipulated labor services. Lesser

    peasants without legal property provide only labor. The extent of labor required from a

    peasant farmstead was considerable:

    As a rule of thumb, one can say that enforced serf labor did not exceed 2-3

    days a week for peasants with property in their land. As for peasants without

    property, it depended entirely on the requirements of the estates. There were

    quite often 4, 5 or even 6 days of enforced labor per peasant-farmstead. As the

    great majority of the peasants had no property rights in their land we can

  • 7/24/2019 British and European industrialization

    43/66

    41

    quite confidently say that enforced labor for more than 3 days a week was

    very widespread in these areas. (Harnisch 1986, p.45)

    The system provided cheap labor, draft animal capital and serf-built structures that

    underpinned a profitable system for the landowning aristocracy. Harnish quotes a prominent

    Pomeranian official who wrote that managing an estate with enforced labor might not lead

    to the highest possible yields and would certainly cause a lot of irritation and annoyance,...but

    it was convenient and cheap (Harnisch 1986, p.45). In Russia serfdom was even more

    strongly entrenched with heavier peasant obligations and even less freedo