Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

  • Upload
    1alex2

  • View
    215

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    1/35

    Are Fair Traders Actually Protectionist?

    The Economic and Political Bases of Support for Fair Trade in the European

    Union1

    Sean D. Ehrlich

    Assistant ProfessorDepartment of Political Science

    Florida State University

    559 Bellamy HallTallahassee, FL 32309

    [email protected]

    Abstract: The embedded liberalism thesis argues that governments can build support for

    free trade by compensating economically those hurt by trade, usually with welfare or

    education policies. This strategy depends, though, on opposition to trade being driven by

    economic factors, such as job or income loss because of increased competition. The

    current fair trade movement raises many non-economic criticisms of trade such as

    concerns about the environment and labor standards. Many scholars dismiss these

    concerns as traditional protectionism in disguise. This article argues, instead, that for

    many these concerns are sincere and that this presents a growing challenge to the

    compromise of embedded liberalism. The article demonstrates this by examining survey

    data in the European Union and showing that those who support fair trade tend to have

    characteristics that are opposite those who support economic protection.

    1 I thank Charles Barrileaux, Bill Berry, Justin Esarey, Matt Golder, Cherie Maestas, Will

    Moore, Angela OMahoney, John Scholz, and Jeff Staton for helpful advice and

    comments.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    2/35

    Research on trade policy typically assumes that individuals preferences for free

    trade are largely determined by economic factors. Those who are expected to see an

    increase in income due to increased trade should support free trade while those who are

    expected to lose income should oppose it. As a result of this assumption, most research

    tends to conflate all opponents of free trade as protectionists, who desire to limit trade

    to protect the economy from competition and, thus, protect their job. Recent critics of

    free trade, though, have often focused on other possible downsides of trade, such as

    worsening environmental and labor standards both at home and abroad, a critique often

    labeled fair trade. Economists have largely dismissed these criticisms as repackaged

    protectionism and not as sincere expressions of environmentalism or labor support. In

    other words, fair traders are presumed to be protectionists in disguise.

    This presumption has critical implications for how policymakers should respond

    to the fair trade critics. If they are protectionists in disguise, then the typical policy tools

    discussed in the embedded liberalism literature (Ruggie 1972), such as unemployment

    insurance and job retraining, should suffice to maintain support for free trade. If the

    critics are motivated by sincere environmental and labor concerns, though, then these

    policies are likely not to work. Is the standard presumption correct? Previous research

    on the topic (Ehrlich, 2007) has found that in the United States, fair traders tend to be

    sincere and not protectionists in disguise, thus calling into question the economic

    arguments and suggesting that compensating those who are harmed by trade may no

    longer be sufficient to maintain support for free trade. This article will further support

    this contention by demonstrating that the previous finding is not country-specific but is,

    instead, a general result among developed countries and also by examining the cross-

    2

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    3/35

    country determinants of fair trade support. Thus, this article further calls attention to the

    possibility that the compromise of embedded liberalism may not longer hold and provides

    insight into which countries are most in danger of seeing support for free trade crumble.

    In order to make this case, the rest of this article is organized as follows: First, I

    summarize two distinct literatures: the literature on maintaining support for free trade and

    the emerging literature, mostly in economics, that typically views fair trade as

    protectionism in disguise. Second, I summarize previous theoretical and empirical work

    discussing who supports protection and provide hypotheses to test if protectionists and

    fair traders comprise the same groups of people and discussing what the determinants of

    cross-national support for fair trade should be. Third, I introduce the survey data and the

    statistical methods used to test these hypotheses. Fourth, I present the results of these

    tests, showing that protectionists and fair traders are, in fact, largely, though not entirely,

    different groups of people. Fifth, I conclude by returning to the questions raised by this

    research about the embedded liberalism literature and by discussing future research

    possibilities.

    I. Embedded Liberalism and the Fair Trade Challenge

    Prior to the interwar collapse of the international economy, most countries

    pursued a classically liberal policy of free trade and adherence to the gold standard that

    prioritized international economic stability over domestic economic stability.2

    After the

    experiences of the Great Depression and World War II, countries learned that free trade

    2See Simmons (1994).

    3

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    4/35

    needed to be paired with domestic policies that compensated workers for the increased

    risks that came from openness. Ruggie termed this compromise embedded liberalism,

    in that the classical liberalism of free trade was embedded within policies designed to

    mitigate the negative aspects of free trade. (Ruggie, 1982) The most important element

    of embedded liberalism is that policymakers are concerned about managing public

    support for free trade: the methods to do this have varied between countries and over

    time, and have included unemployment insurance, job retraining programs, and more

    general welfare state programs, but the underlying desire of proponents of free trade to

    increase support for free trade by compensating those who lose from free trade has

    remained the same. This concept of embedded liberalism has been used to explain why

    government size has increased since World War II (Cameron 1978; Rodrik 1998) and

    public opinion studies such as Hays, Ehrlich, and Peinhardt (2005) have found that

    increasing unemployment and education spending can, in fact, increase support for free

    trade even among those most at risk to suffer the negative employment and income

    effects of trade.

    Since the end of World War II, there has, thus, been general consensus among

    policymakers that free trade should be coupled with programs designed to allay the

    concerns of opponents to free trade. Academic debate, in political science and

    economics, has typically centered around the implications or preferred method for

    implementing this compromise or the future of the compromise to changing external

    4

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    5/35

    conditions3

    rather than on the existence or the political desirability of the compromise.

    However, the ability of embedded liberalism to manage public support for trade depends

    crucially on the fact that opposition to trade is caused by the negative effects of trade on

    job or income security. If opposition to trade is driven by other factors, then the

    traditional policies of embedded liberalism will not be able to assuage these opponents.

    The rhetoric of fair trade suggests that these opponents are not concerned with domestic

    job loss but rather with the effects of free trade on labor and environmental standards

    both domestically and in foreign countries. However, many academics have suggested

    that this is, in fact, only rhetoric and that fair traders are merely masking their

    traditional concern for jobs and incomes with different language. If this view is correct,

    then the bargain of embedded liberalism should still work; if fair trade is really not about

    jobs and income, though, then the compromise may not hold. Thus, it becomes important

    to know who the fair traders are and what they want.

    In general, fair trade means that industries in a countrys trading partners are

    operating under the same rules of the game under which domestic industries are forced to

    operate. In practice, though, fair trade has meant different things at different times. In

    the eighties, calls for fair trade were frequently leveled at Japan because U.S. industries

    believed that the Japanese market was closed to American exports even though the

    American market was open to Japanese imports, thus giving Japanese industries an

    unfair advantage. Similarly, anti-dumping and countervailing duties, which GATT and

    3For instance, the convergence theory argued that capital mobility would make left-

    leaning economic policies, such as unemployment and welfare, harder to maintain. See

    Garrett (1998) for a critical assessment of this theory.

    5

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    6/35

    the WTO allow countries to place on imports when the exporting country is accused of,

    respectively, selling goods below market price or supporting industries with illegal export

    subsidies, are sometimes referred to as fair trade policies as they are designed to force a

    countrys trading partners to eliminate unfair subsidies or predatory pricing practices.

    In the past decade, though, fair trade has taken on a new, though similar,

    meaning: concern that industries located in countries with lower environmental or labor

    standards have an unfair advantage over competitors that adhere to higher standards.4

    This version still stresses the ability of domestic industries to compete fairly with foreign

    industries, but increasingly has also including concerns about how fair the trade is not

    just for the businesses competing but for the workers producing the goods and the

    environment affected by production. Thus, there has been a rise in fair trade products

    which certifies that the product is produced in an environmentally safe manner and with

    high labor standards and that the workers have received a fair share of the profits from

    production. In the United States, the most common fair trade product is coffee, with

    Starbucks specifically marketing a product they call Fair Trade Coffee. In the

    European Union, fair trade bananas as well as tea and coffee have been much discussed

    products. In addition to these agricultural goods, a number of handcrafted goods have

    fallen under the fair trade rubric. In 2002, an international non-governmental

    organization called the Fair Trade Labeling Organizations International (FLO) created a

    4Economists frequently refer to this type of fair trade as a demand for harmonization

    of standards. Much of the economics literature on fair trade is thus about the costs and

    benefits of different standards and of harmonizing those standards between countries.

    6

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    7/35

    fair trade label for products meeting certain standards. FLO claims that over one billion

    Euro worth of products carrying this label were sold in 2005.5

    Fair trade is more than just the labeling of products, though, and also includes

    policy demands. For instance, there have been attempts to create domestic legislation

    banning or restricting trade with countries that violate domestic standards.6

    Also, during

    both the abortive Millennial Round and the current Doha Round of the WTO,

    environmental advocates have pushed for multilateral rules that enable countries to raise

    tariffs on products produced in environmentally unsound ways, a policy sometimes

    referred to as Eco-dumping duties, modeled after the anti-dumping duties discussed

    above. The common thread throughout these policies and activities is concern for the

    effect of trade on the environment, labor standards, and human rights both at home and

    abroad. Thus, in the rest of this paper, I will use the term fair trade specifically to refer

    to supporting limits on trade in order to protect the environment or the rights of foreign

    workers, a definition which is in accord with the self-image of the fair traders.

    Despite the claims of the fair traders themselves, many policymakers, political

    advocates, and academics have argued that fair trade is nothing more than the new

    incarnation of traditional protectionism, a term which usually refers to supporting limits

    on trade in order to protect the domestic economy or domestic jobs. This view is

    particularly common among trade economists. Rodrik probably best summarizes this

    5 See FLOs website, www.fairtrade.net, for more on the labels standards and sales

    claims.

    6For instance, in 2000 the United States passed the Trade and Development Act which

    included requirements that trade partners adhere to international standards for child labor.

    7

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    8/35

    economic conventional wisdom: A common view is that the complaints of

    nongovernmental organizations and labor advocates represent nothing but old

    protectionist wine in new bottles. (Rodrik 1997, 3) For instance, Srinivasan makes this

    argument explicitly: The demand for linkage between trading rights and observance of

    standards with respect to environment or labor would seem to arise largely from

    protectionist motives. (Srinivasan 1995, quoted in Krueger 1996, 4)7

    Other economists suggest only that protectionism is one of several possible

    motives and that a sincere desire to protect the environment and labor rights may be

    another motive. For instance, Bhagwati (1995, 1996) summarizes what he sees as the

    different possible objections to differences between national labor and environmental

    standards. One of these reasons is that protectionists see great value in invoking

    unfairness of trade as an argument for getting protection: it is likely to be more

    successful than simply claiming that you cannot hack it and therefore need protection.

    (1995, 746) Further, Bhagwati fears that if the WTO legitimizes what was referred to as

    eco-dumping dutieswhich would enable countries to put tariffs on imports to

    counteract any price advantage they may have accrued due to lower environmental

    standardsthen this would facilitate protectionism without doubt (1995, 749) because

    protectionists would abuse these duties like they do regular anti-dumping duties.

    Bhagwati does grant that there are other, more sincere reasons, to support fair

    trade. First, people might be concerned with a race to the bottom if lower standards

    abroad can force countries to lower their own domestic standards, though Bhagwati

    discounts the existence of such a race. Second, people might have moral concerns:

    7See also Krugman (1997).

    8

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    9/35

    they are opposed to labor and environmental abuses regardless of who suffers from them.

    Third, people might have moral concerns about the inherent unfairness of competition

    when one side has a distinct, regulatory advantage over the other. While he

    acknowledges the simultaneous existence of these economic, political, and moral

    concerns, Bhagwati does not provide any suggestions about which one will predominate

    under which circumstances and is highly critical of the validity of the non-protectionist

    reasons.

    Even when acknowledging moral concerns of fair traders, economists have often

    dismissed these concerns. Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1996) liken them to imperialism:

    simply the old, morality-driven desire to spread the values to which one subscribes.

    (180) In impugning the motives of fair traders, Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1996) go so far

    as to suggest that the real reason for calls for harmonization of labor and environmental

    standards is a nefarious plot against developing countries such that they predict we will

    also witness increasing attempts at encouraging population control in these countries

    (165) in order to limit economic competition from these countries. Bhagwati and

    Srinivasan may be right that environmental and labor concerns are culturally specific and

    that forcing other countries to adopt your standards may be more ethically challenged

    than the ethical violations you are charging others of pursuing. However, supporters of

    free trade are unlikely to convince sincere fair traders to abandon their demands by

    pointing out the efficiency gains of free trade or by dismissing their concerns out of hand

    9

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    10/35

    as self-serving or by providing compensation for lost jobs and income, the typical

    strategies suggested in this literature.8

    This view of fair trade can also be seen in political science. For instance, Drezner

    (2006), a review of policy choices available to the U.S. President on trade issues, uses the

    label fair trade to denote the alternative policy orientation to a free trade approach. He,

    thus, consciously conflates many different aspects of trade policy only some of which

    covers what this paper refers to as fair trade. For instance, in addition to labor and

    environmental standards, Drezner also includes anti-dumping measures and concerns

    about the distributional consequences of trade. While Drezner occasionally seems to

    suggest that any opposition to free trade can be carried under the fair trade rubric9

    and,

    thus, fair traders include protectionists, he at other times suggests that support for fair

    trade, including concerns for low labor and environmental standards abroad, only carry

    8Discussions about labor standards are similar to these discussions of environmentalism,

    as exemplified by Brown, Deardorff and Stern (1996) They state that the pursuit of

    international labor standards has taken on a more protectionist tone. In some cases the

    protectionist intent is barely disguised. In fact, it is quite commonly feared that countries

    with below-average labor standards are gaining an unfair advantage in trade. (266)

    9For instance, Drezner states that three political facts of life have caused many

    Americans to shift their support from free trade to fair trade. First, during tough

    economic times or times of economic uncertainty, public suspicion of free trade policies

    explodes into public hostility. Inevitably, foreign trade becomes the scapegoat for

    business-cycle fluctuations that have little to do with trade. (p. 9) This passage seems to

    imply that fair trade includes any opposition to free trade, i.e. including protectionism.

    10

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    11/35

    the danger of being subverted by protectionists rather than directly being protectionist.

    For instance, Drezner states that fair trade carries the danger of mutating into blanket

    protectionism and that because almost any trade barrier can be advocated on grounds of

    fairness to some group, special interests can easily hijack this policy orientation. (pp.

    3-4) Fair trade is, thus, either protectionists in disguise or the possible start of a slippery

    slope towards protectionism.

    Not all academics are so skeptical of the motives of fair traders. For instance,

    Rodrik, though probably best summarizing the conventional wisdom against fair trade as

    quoted above, by no means shares this view. Instead, he argues that we need to take into

    account individual concerns about the procedural fairness of different labor and

    environmental standards. [B]y doing so we can start to make sense of peoples

    uneasiness about the consequences of international economic integration and avoid the

    trap of automatically branding all concerned groups as self-interested protectionists.

    (Rodrik 1997, 5-6) Although acknowledging that there may be legitimate cases in which

    trade is unfair, Rodrik is also concerned that organized interests might abuse fairness

    claims. In other words, not all the new fair-trade bottles contain old protectionist wine,

    but some of them do. Rather than throwing out all the bottles, as others seem to propose,

    Rodrik is interested in creating ways to distinguish the bottles from each other and

    throwing out only the protectionist ones. This view is, thus, similar to argument

    advanced in this article that it is possible to sincerely support fair trade and the results

    presented below can be seen as a way to distinguish between the bottles.

    II. Who Would Fair Traders be if they were Protectionists in Disguise?

    11

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    12/35

    As described above, standard academic views of fair trade tend to fall into two

    major camps: those that view fair trade as the same as protectionism and those that view

    fair trade as a more acceptable disguise for protectionism. This paper offers a third

    possibility sympathetic to Rodriks view: fair trade and protectionism are distinct policies

    and many people will (sincerely) choose to support or oppose only one of them. If the

    standard views are correct, then we would expect the same factors that determine support

    for protection to determine support for fair trade. If, on the other hand, this articles

    argument is correct, then we would expect the same factors that determine support for

    environmentalism and labor rights to determine support for fair trade. Fortunately, these

    factors are very different and often exactly opposite, providing an excellent opportunity

    to test this papers arguments against the standard view of fair trade.

    If the standard view is correct, then those who are hurt economically by trade

    should support fair trade while those who are helped by trade should oppose it.

    Economic theory provides numerous answers on who is helped and who is hurt by free

    trade and protection and recent empirical research has demonstrated that these theoretical

    factors (and other factors not directly derived from theory) are able to predict public

    opinion about trade policy and other aspects of globalization. If the traditional view is

    correct, these same factors should be able to predict (in the same direction) support or

    opposition for fair trade.

    Economic theory about trade suggests that the main determinants of support for

    free trade or protection are a persons factor endowment, industry of employment, and

    the level of factor mobility in the economy. If factors are mobile, i.e. one can easily

    12

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    13/35

    transfer ones skills or capital from one sector of the economy to another, then the

    Stolper-Samuelson theory predicts that support for free trade and protection should be

    determined by factor ownership: those holding abundant factors should support free trade

    since this will increase exports of products produced intensively with the abundant factor

    while those holding scarce factors should support protection as free trade will increase

    imports of products produced intensively with the scarce factor. Thus, in Europe, owners

    of capital and skilled labor should support free trade while unskilled labor and farmers

    should support protection. On the other hand, if factors are specific, then the Ricardo-

    Viner theory predicts that industry of employment determines trade policy preference.

    Those who work in export industries, regardless of capital ownership or skill level,

    should support free trade while those who work in import-competing industries, again

    regardless of capital ownership or skill level, should support protection. Most of the

    research on public opinion about trade policy has found that both factor-ownership and

    industry matter, although the results are stronger for factor-ownership.10

    Unfortunately, the dataset used in this study does not include a variable for

    industry of employment, so the effect of industry on support for fair trade cannot be

    tested. Variables for skill are included, though, so we can test the effect of factor

    endowment. Typically, skill is indirectly measured by either education levelassuming

    that education imparts job-related skillsor by incomeassuming that increased skills

    increases demand for the worker and, thus, the workers income. According to economic

    10See, for instance, Scheve and Slaughter (2001), Mayda and Rodrik (2002), and Hays,

    Ehrlich, and Peinhardt (2005). Since, as Hiscox (2002) shows, factors are both partly-

    mobile and partly-specific, this finding should not be surprising.

    13

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    14/35

    theory, if fair trade is protectionism in disguise, we should expect low-skilled workers,

    whether measured by education or income, to support fair trade and high-skilled workers

    to oppose it. In addition, a variable is also included for whether the respondent works on

    a farm: given that land is a scarce factor in Europe, we would expect farmers to support

    protection and, thus, also support fair trade if it is protectionism in disguise.

    In addition to these theoretically derived findings, the empirical literature has

    identified a number of other factors that influence support for protection or free trade.

    The studies listed above have found such factors as gender, marital status, age,

    unemployment status, national identity, and ideology to be important predictors of

    support for free trade and protectionism. Women are consistently more supportive of

    protection than men, though the reason for this is still unclear.11

    Older respondents and

    married respondents are also more likely to support protection, although the theoretical

    underpinnings for these findings are also not well specified. Unemployed respondents

    are more supportive of protection because they may blame free trade for the loss of their

    job or they may believe protection might lead to new jobs in their industry. Those who

    express strong levels of patriotism or national identity are less likely to support free trade,

    probably because they want to support domestic industries. Finally, in terms of ideology,

    those on the right tend to be more supportive of free trade and those on the left more

    supportive of protection. This follows from the economic theory above and from the

    11 See Hiscox and Burgoon (2003) for more on the topic of gender and trade policy. In

    particular, they argue that the reason women are more protectionist than men is that men

    are more likely than women to be exposed to economic theory in college and, thus, more

    likely to be exposed to arguments suggesting free trade is beneficial.

    14

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    15/35

    typical concerns of those on the left and right: in a mobile-factor world, free trade in

    developed countries tends to hurt those with lower levels of education and income, i.e.

    the already worse off, and leftists, with their greater concern for economic equality,

    should be more sensitive to these costs. The analyses below include variables for all of

    these factors: if fair trade is the same as protectionism, then we should expect women, the

    old, the married, the unemployed, the nationalistic, and the liberal to support fair trade.

    If, on the other hand, support for fair trade is a sincere expression of belief in the

    value of environmental and labor rights, then the people who support fair trade should

    have the same characteristics as those who support environmental protection and high

    labor standards. Support for these positions, for instance, could all be considered

    elements of post-materialism (Inglehart, 1977, 1997) where people express greater

    concern for quality-of-life issues, such as environmental protection and individual

    freedom and self-expression, rather than economic and physical security issues, such as

    economic growth.12

    Post-materialists are expected to be young, highly educated, and

    wealthy and to have left-wing ideologies. Also, economic security is often a pre-requisite

    for expressing post-materialist values; thus, the unemployed should be less likely to be

    post-materialist and the single should be more likely as they are less likely to have

    dependents to support and, thus, have a lower threshold for security. Women have also

    been found to be less post-materialist (Inglehart, 1977, 90-91) although, again, the reason

    12 If economists are correct that fair trade policies will hurt economic growth or economic

    efficiency, then this further reinforces the link between fair trade and post-materialism.

    Post-materialists will value such things as environmental protection and industrial

    democracy over economic growth.

    15

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    16/35

    for this is not entirely clear.13

    Overall, these characteristics of post-materialists are the

    exact opposite of the characteristics of protectionists. In addition, union members might

    be expected to be more supportive of fair trade especially as collective bargaining rights

    are often considered a core element of labor standards. On the other hand, unionized

    workers often support protection as they view free trade as a threat to their jobs.

    Figure 1 summarizes the expectations about which factors influence choosing

    protection and choosing fair trade (assuming the latter choice is sincere.) If fair trade is

    protectionism in disguise or the equivalent to protectionism, then the factors in the left-

    most columns should not only explain why respondents support protectionism, but why

    they support fair trade as well. If fair trade support is sincere, then the factors in the right

    most columns should explain their support for fair trade. Thus, Figure 1 lists the

    predictions of what characteristics fair traders should have depending on whether they are

    sincere or protectionists in disguise.14

    The perspectives described above can also be used to determine what national-

    level factors might explain why some countries are more supportive of fair trade than

    others. First, national-level aggregates of the individual-level factors should have the

    same effect. Thus, for instance, if fair trade is protectionism in disguise, wealthy

    13See Hayes, McAllister, and Studlar (2000) for more on gender and postmaterialism.

    14This article does not argue that all fair traders are sincere. Some may be disguising

    their protectionism. If the average fair trader is sincere, though, then the factors listed in

    the right-most columns of Figure 1 should explain their choice. If the average fair trader

    is a protectionist in disguise, then the factors listed in the left-most columns of Figure 1

    should explain their choice.

    16

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    17/35

    countries or countries with low unemployment should oppose fair trade; if fair trade is

    sincere, then wealthy countries or countries with low unemployment should support fair

    trade. Second, if fair trade is sincere, then we would expect countries that tend to support

    environmental and labor protection in other policy areas to also support these concepts in

    trade policy. Thus, countries with strong environmental policies and powerful labor

    unions should also be more supportive of fair trade. Thus, we can examine data at both

    the individual and national level to determine if fair trade is protectionism in disguise or

    sincere.

    III. Research Design

    To test the argument that fair trade support is sincere, we need public opinion data

    asking questions about fair trade support. The 1997 Eurobarometer survey asked a series

    a questions about consumer preferences for fair trade bananas in 15 European Union

    (EU) countries which can provide leverage on support for fair trade. The survey defines

    fair trade products as those that carry a label guaranteeing that the products have been

    produced ensuring fair working conditions for farmers and employees, and respecting the

    environment. Respondents were asked if they were aware of such products, if they had

    every purchased any, and whether they would be willing to buy fair trade bananas if, first,

    they were the same price and quality as regular bananas, and, then, if the fair trade

    bananas were more 10, 20, or 30 percent more expensive than regular bananas. If

    17

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    18/35

    respondent claim to be willing to buy fair trade bananas that are 10 percent more

    expensive then I code them as supporting fair trade.15

    This question only measures consumer preferences but it should, nonetheless,

    serve as a good proxy for policy preferences. This question taps into the willingness of

    respondents to suffer a financial cost for their values and, thus, may be a good measure of

    whether they feel strongly about the issue. Ehrlich (2007) included both fair trade policy

    and consumer preference questions and found consistent results between these questions

    in the United States. This probably should not be surprising given that similar questions

    asked in previous surveys in the United States about the willingness of respondents to pay

    extra to Buy American and, therefore, protect American jobs have found those who

    support protection are also willing to pay more for American-made products. (Scheve

    and Slaughter, 2001) If fair trade is protectionism in disguise, we might expect

    protectionists to similarly answer this question; if fair trade is sincere, we might expect

    labor and environmental advocates to be similarly willing to pay extra for goods that

    conform to their values. Thus, consumer preferences is only a proxy for fair trade policy

    preferences, but these previous results should increase our confidence in the strength of

    the proxy.

    The analysis below therefore investigates why individuals support or oppose fair

    trade based upon whether they are willing to pay extra for fair trade products. Because

    the question has a binary choice, probit methods can be used to determine if the

    15If respondent are not willing to buy fair trade bananas, they are asked why. If they say

    that they do not buy any bananas, I drop them from the sample as it is impossible to tell

    whether they support fair trade or not in this instance.

    18

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    19/35

    independent variables affect this decision in such a way as to support the fair trade as

    protectionism in disguise story or the fair trade as sincere preferences story. The

    model for this analysis is as follows, with expected signs of the independent variables

    detailed in Figure 1:

    Purchase = 0 + 1 Income + 2 Education + 3 Farm + 4 EU Support + 5

    Female + 6 Married + 7 Union + 8 Unemployed + 9 Ideology + 10 Age +

    Income measures in which quartile each respondents household income falls.

    Education measures the age at which the respondent left school. Farmeris a dummy

    variable equal to 1 if the respondent works on a farm and 0 otherwise. EU Support

    measures whether the respondent supports their countrys membership in the EU and can

    be taken as an inverse measure of a respondents level of national identity. Two different

    trichotomous measures are used, one asking if the respondent believes membership in the

    EU is a good thing or a bad thing and one asking if the respondent believes their country

    has benefited from membership or not.16

    Female equals 1 if the respondent is female and

    0 if the respondent is male. Marriedequals 1 if the respondent is currently married and 0

    otherwise. Union is equal to 1 if the respondent is a current union member and 0 if not.

    Unemployedis a dummy variable measuring whether the respondent is currently

    unemployed (out of a job and seeking work) or not. Ideology is a three-point scale equal

    to 1 for those on the left, 2 for those on the center, and 3 for those on the right. Age

    measures the age of the respondent in years. Table 1 provides summary statistics for

    these variables.

    16See Gabel (1998) for a discussion of these different measures.

    19

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    20/35

    To investigate the cross-national determinants of fair trade support, I simply

    calculate the percentage of respondents from each country willing to purchase fair trade

    products, as reported in Figure 2. There is a clear amount of variation in support for fair

    trade across countries: over 60% of Luxemburgers and Swedes support fair trade while

    less than 30% of Portuguese do. Belgium and Spain are below 40% with the other 10

    countries clustered between 40 and 60%. There is no obvious pattern to this data except

    for a possible North-South divide if Belgium is ignored, but other factors may be

    influencing these cross-national results in less obvious ways which the next section will

    determine. Due to the limited sample (15 countries), I only conduct bivariate correlations

    with the factors discussed in the previous section.

    IV. Results

    The results strongly support the sincere view of fair trade. Looking first at the

    main model, which includes fixed country effects, listed as Model 1 in Table 2, people

    with higher incomes and education levels are more likely to purchase fair trade products

    while rightists are less likely to purchase these products, all of which we would expect if

    fair trade support is sincere. . Union members are less likely to purchase the products,

    which is a surprising result from either perspective: if fair trade is protectionism, we

    would expect union members to support it to protect their jobs; and if fair trade is sincere,

    we would expect union members to support it because of the increased labor standards

    implied by the fair trade label. The negative coefficient may be a reflection of a desire of

    union members to buy local products rather than any sort of import. Women are more

    20

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    21/35

    likely to buy fair trade products, which is consistent with both the protectionist and

    sincere perspectives. EU support (measured here as whether the respondent believes

    membership is a good thing) is negatively correlated with fair trade purchases, which is

    consistent with the protectionism in disguise perspective if we view those supporting EU

    integration as having lower levels of national identity. On the other hand, the sincere

    perspective makes no prediction about this variable. Where the two perspectives make

    contradictory predictions about the effects of specific variables and where the coefficients

    are significant, the results always support the sincere perspective.

    These results are also remarkably robust. Mode 2 changes the wording of the EU

    support variable to whether the respondents country benefits from membership. As can

    be seen, there are no major changes between the results. The sample size drops in this

    model and the effect of EU support increases, but the size and significance of the rest of

    the variables in the model barely change at all. Models 3 and 4 repeat Models 1 and 2 but

    drop the country-dummies. The results in these models are quite similar to Models 1 and

    2 except that the coefficients on EU support are no longer significant.

    Returning to Model 1, the effects of the important variables can best be seen by

    examining the predicted probability of purchasing fair trade products, as listed in Table 3.

    These probabilities were generating using Clarify and setting all variables at their median

    except for the variables listed in the table which were manipulated one at a time.

    Respondents at the bottom income quartile are only 52% likely to support fair trade,

    while those in the top quartile are 63% likely to support fair trade. Education and

    ideology also have similar effects to income. Those with an education level one standard

    deviation below the mean (left school at age 13) are 54% likely to support fair trade while

    21

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    22/35

    those one standard deviation above the mean (age 23) are 65% likely to support fair trade.

    Left-wing respondents are 64.5% likely to support fair trade with right-wing respondents

    54% likely. Gender and union status have smaller substantive effects: 3 and 8%

    respectively. However, each of these variables are both statistically and substantively

    significant.

    The results are also consistent if Models 3 and 4 are repeated in individual

    country samples rather than in one pooled sample. Doing this cuts the sample size of

    each regression into the hundreds, so the variables are frequently insignificant. However,

    when the variables that are significant in the pooled sample are also significant in the

    country-specific samples, they are in the same direction. In particular, education and

    income, when significant, are always associated with more support for fair trade and

    ideology is always negative when significant. Interestingly, age is significant in four of

    the country-level regressions: it is positively related to fair trade support in the

    Netherlands and Luxembourg and negatively related in Denmark and Greece. Farmers in

    Germany and Ireland are also less supportive of fair trade. For the most part, though,

    these country-specific results support the sincere perspective of fair trade.

    The pattern of support between countries also supports the view that supporting

    fair trade products is a sign of sincere support for environmentalism and labor standards,

    as shown in Table 4. This table examines how country-level characteristics are correlated

    with average support for fair trade products within countries. Due to the small sample

    size (at most 15 countries), I only examine the bivariate correlations, so these results

    should only be seen as suggestive. Economic aggregates are not strongly correlated with

    fair trade support: levels and patterns of trade are not significantly correlated, nor is the

    22

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    23/35

    unemployment rate. GDP per capita is only marginally insignificant, suggesting that

    richer countries are more likely to support fair trade, which is what one would expect

    from a sincere perspective. GDP is positively and significantly correlated with fair trade

    support, which is the only finding that is consistent with the protectionism in disguise

    argument: according to optimal tariff theory, large economies are more likely to support

    protectionism because they have enough market power to influence the terms of trade of

    products that they place tariffs on and can, under certain circumstances, actually benefit

    from some tariffs. Small economies, on the other hand, never benefit from tariffs.

    However, labor and environmental strength within the country are strongly

    correlated with fair trade support. Countries with better environmental conditions, as

    measured by the Environmental Sustainability Index (ESI)17

    , should be expected to have

    stronger environmental movements. As can be seen in Table 4, these countries also tend

    to have high support for fair trade products. Corporatist countries, which have stronger

    labor unions and are traditionally more concerned with labor rights, also are correlated

    with higher support for fair trade, whether measured with Lijpharts (1999) summary

    measure of corporatism or a more focused measure of coordinated-wage bargaining.

    However, union density is not significantly correlated with fair trade support, although

    this may be a result of the small sample size, as there is no data on union density in

    Greece, Luxembourg, Portugal, and Spain. (Luxembourg is the missing observation in

    17 This measure summarizes 76 environmental indicators including measures of natural

    resource protection, pollution levels, and environmental management. It is provided by

    the Center for International Earth Science Information Network and is available at

    http://sedac.ciesin.columbia.edu/es/esi/.

    23

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    24/35

    wage bargaining and ESI.) Thus, countries with stronger environmental and labor

    movements also tend to be more supportive of fair trade, which is what we would expect

    if fair trade support is sincere.

    V. Conclusions

    The results of this article strongly support the view that fair trade is, at least

    partially, a reflection of sincere support for environmental protection and labor standards

    among the public. Other fair traders may be motivated by economic self-interest, as most

    economists and political scientists have suggested, but this is by no means the dominant

    reason to support fair trade. What are the implications of this finding?

    Most important, this finding changes how academics and policymakers should

    respond to the fair trade movement. The standard approaches, as noted above, have been

    to ignore or belittle the movement as discredited protectionism or, at best, to reiterate the

    economic case for free trade and point out the efficiency costs of any trade barriers. If

    support for fair trade does not rest on economic concerns, though, then this economic

    defense of free trade is unlikely to be convincing.

    This is especially troubling for any supporter of free trade given the embedded

    liberalism literature which has held that the post-War free trade consensus has been

    maintained by increasing the size of the welfare state in order to compensate those who

    lose their jobs or take on increased risk because of free trade. If new opposition to free

    trade is being generated by sincere concerns for environmental protection and labor

    standards both at home and abroad, then the standard technique of increasing

    24

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    25/35

    unemployment insurance or job retraining programs is unlikely to be able to maintain

    support for free trade. In short, without new policy tools, the fair trade movement may

    pose a more serious threat to free trade than previous movements opposed to free trade.

    This is likely to be exacerbated if the sincere fair traders see their concerns

    hijacked by traditional protectionists. Economists sympathetic to the moral concerns of

    fair trade, such as Rodrik, still fear that interest groups like labor unions may be able to

    use fair trade to achieve their protectionists ends. By wrapping up their calls for

    protection in complaints about labor rights abuses, labor unions may be able to increase

    the number of people who support their demands. The results presented here suggest that

    this strategy may be profitable: there is a large pool of people who support fair trade who

    would oppose traditional protectionism. If protectionists can win over these people by

    marketing their protectionism as a tool to achieve fair trade, they may be able to craft a

    large enough constituency to get their measures enacted. The results presented here do

    not demonstrate one way or another whether this strategy would be successful, but it does

    suggest that Rodriks fears are legitimate as the conditions exist that would make success

    possible. Future research is needed, though, to determine whether protectionist interest

    groups are willing or able to exploit this demand.

    For which countries are these issues likely to be most problematic? The fair trade

    movement seems to be strongest in wealthy countries with strong environmental and

    labor movements. In other words, Scandinavian countries like Sweden and Denmark are

    likely to have the largest fair trade movements, but other Northern European countries

    such as Germany. Mayda and Rodrik (2002) have found that these countries tend to be

    the most opposed to protectionism, which might limit the ability of protectionists and fair

    25

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    26/35

    traders to unite in opposition to free trade. However, if the fair trade movement

    continues to grow and if no adequate response to it is implemented, then the support of

    these and other countries for free trade may begin to diminish which could have

    disastrous effects on the global free trade regime.

    Finally, the research presented here suggests that the entire literature on trade

    policy in both political science and economics needs to be expanded. Models of trade

    policy tend to view policy options as residing on a single continuum from complete free

    trade to absolute protection, or autarchy. This papers research suggests that we need to

    move beyond free trade and protection: there is at least one other dimension to the trade

    policy debate that partly, but does not entirely, overlap with the free trade/protection

    dimension. One can oppose free trade without supporting protection and oppose

    protection without supporting free trade. Existing theories about trade policy are ill

    equipped to explain when and why this will be the case or what the results of fair trade

    support will be. As the fair trade movement possibly grows, these theories will become

    increasingly incapable of predicting and explaining trade policy outcomes. Before we

    can devise new theories or revise the old ones, though, we need to come to more fully

    understand what this new movement is, who supports it, and what their demands are, a

    process this article will hopefully start.

    26

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    27/35

    References

    Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1995. Trade Liberalization and Fair Trade Demands: Addressing

    the Environmental and Labor Standards Issues. The World Economy 18 (6): 745-

    759.

    Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1996. The Demands to Reduce Domestic Diversity among Trading

    Nations. In Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert E. Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and

    Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. 1. Cambridge, MA: MIT

    Press. pp. 9-40.

    Bhagwati, Jagdish and T.N. Srinivasan. 1996. Trade and the Environment: Does

    Environmental Diversity Detract from the Case for Free Trade? In Jagdish

    Bhagwati and Robert E. Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and Harmonization:

    Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. 1. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. pp. 159-224.

    Brown, Drusilla K., Alan V. Deardorff, and Robert M. Stern. 1996. International Labor

    Standards and Trade: A Theoretical Analysis. In Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert E.

    Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol.

    1. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. pp. 227-280.

    Cameron, David. 1978. The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative

    Analysis. American Political Science Review 72 (4): 1243-1261.

    Drezner, Daniel W. 2006. U.S. Trade Strategy: Free Versus Fair. New York: Council

    on Foreign Relations.

    Ehrlich, Sean D. 2007. Is Fair Trade Just Protectionism in Disguise? Paper presented at

    the 2007 Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association.

    27

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    28/35

    Gabel, Matthew. 1998. Public Support for European Integration: An Empirical Test of

    Five Theories. Journal of Politics 60 (2): 333-354.

    Garrett, Geoffrey. 1998. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy New York:

    Cambridge University Press.

    Hayes, Bernadette C., Ian McAllister, and Donley T. Studlar. 2000. Gender,

    Postmaterialism, and Feminism in Comparative Perspective. International

    Political Science Review 21 (4): 425-439.

    Hays, Jude C., Sean D. Ehrlich, and Clint Peinhardt. 2005. Government Spending and

    Public Support for Trade in the OECD. International Organization 59 (2): 473-

    494.

    Hiscox, Michael. 2002. International Trade and Political Conflict: Commerce,

    Coalitions, and Mobility. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Hiscox, Michael, and Brian Burgoon. 2003. Trade Openness and Political

    Compensation: Explaining Labor Demands for Adjustment Assistance.

    Unpublished Manuscript.

    Inglehart, Ronald. 1977. The Silent Revolution: Changing Values and Political Styles

    Among Western Publics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Inglehart, Ronald. 1997. Modernization and Postmodernization: Cultural, Economic,

    and Political Change in 43 Societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Krueger, Alan. 1996. Observations on International Labor Standards and Trade.

    Unpublished Manuscript. Princeton, NJ.

    Krugman, Paul. 1997. What Should Trade Negotiators Negotiate About? Journal of

    Economic Literature 35 (1): 113-120.

    28

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    29/35

    Lijphart, Arend. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Governments Forms and Performance

    in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Mayda, Anna M. and Dani Rodrik. 2002. Why Are Some People (and Countries) More

    Protectionist than Others? Unpublished Manuscript. Cambridge, Mass.

    Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, D.C.: Institute for

    International Economics.

    Rodrik, Dani. 1998. Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?

    Journal of Political Economy 106 (5): 997-1032.

    Ruggie, John G. 1982. International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded

    liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization 36(2):

    195-231.

    Scheve, Kenneth and Matthew Slaughter. 2001. Globalization and the Perceptions of

    American Workers Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics.

    Simmons, Beth A. 1994. Who Adjusts? Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Srinivasan, T.N. 1995. International Trade and Labour Standards. Unpublished

    manuscript. Yale University.

    29

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    30/35

    Figure 1: Factors Affecting Support for Trade Policy Dimension

    Support for Protection Support for Fair Trade+

    UnionUnemployed

    AgeFemale

    Married

    Farmer

    -

    IncomeEducation

    Right-wing

    +

    IncomeEducation

    Union

    -

    Right-wingUnemployed

    AgeFemale

    Married

    30

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    31/35

    Figure 2: Average Fair Trade Support by Country

    Austria

    Belgium

    DenmarkFinland

    FranceGermany

    Greece

    Ireland

    Italy

    Lux

    Neth

    Portugal

    Spain

    Sweden

    UK

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    31

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    32/35

    Obs. MeanStandard

    Deviation

    Purchase 12841 0.492 0.500

    Income 11722 2.475 1.096

    Education 15822 18.027 4.747

    Farm 15822 0.043 0.204

    EU Membership 14583 1.662 0.773

    EU Benefit 13050 1.399 0.490

    Female 15822 0.516 0.500

    Married 15821 0.603 0.489

    Union 15822 0.312 0.463

    Unemployed 15822 0.071 0.258

    Ideology 13262 2.011 0.803

    Age 15822 42.846 17.555

    Table 1: Summary Statistics of Independent

    Variables

    32

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    33/35

    Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

    Income 0.097*** 0.092*** 0.088*** 0.084***

    (0.015) (0.015) (0.014) (0.015)

    Education 0.029*** 0.028*** 0.038*** 0.038***

    (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)

    Farm -0.036 -0.051 -0.071 -0.094(0.076) (0.08) (0.074) (0.078)

    EU Support -0.041** -0.064** -0.022 -0.028

    (0.019) (0.032) (0.018) (0.030)

    Female 0.082*** 0.068** 0.082*** 0.067**

    (0.028) (0.030) (0.028) (0.030)

    Married -0.024 -0.027 -0.005 -0.01

    (0.032) (0.033) (0.032) (0.033)

    Union -0.203*** -0.203*** -0.186*** -0.185***

    (0.034) (0.035) (0.033) (0.035)

    Unemployed -0.074 -0.107* -0.071 -0.104*

    (0.057) (0.060) (0.056) (0.059)

    Ideology -0.137*** -0.137*** -0.134*** -0.135***(0.018) (0.019) (0.017) (0.018)

    Age -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001

    (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

    Constant -0.300** -0.188 -0.635** -0.566***

    (0.117) (0.128) (0.109) (0.117)

    N 8286 7542 8286 7542

    Pseudo R-Squared 0.054 0.054 0.037 0.036

    Chi-Squared 620.01 567.9 424.32 376.52

    Notes: ***p

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    34/35

    Mean

    Income

    Bottom Quartile 0.517 0.478 0.554

    Second Quartile 0.555 0.522 0.587

    Third Quartile 0.593 0.564 0.622

    Top Quartile 0.630 0.600 0.660

    Education

    6 Years 0.455 0.408 0.504

    13 Years 0.536 0.503 0.571

    18 Years 0.593 0.564 0.622

    23 Years 0.649 0.619 0.676

    59 Years 0.922 0.881 0.956

    Ideology

    Left 0.645 0.615 0.675

    Center 0.593 0.564 0.622

    Right 0.540 0.506 0.571Union

    Member 0.514 0.480 0.545

    Not Member 0.593 0.564 0.622

    Gender

    Male 0.593 0.564 0.622

    Female 0.624 0.595 0.655

    95% Confidence

    Interval

    Table 3: Predicted Probability of Supporting Fair

    Trade

    34

  • 8/8/2019 Apsa07 Proceeding 209633

    35/35

    Correlation Significance Observations

    GDP 0.659 0.001 15

    GDP per capita 0.437 0.103 15

    Uemployment -0.346 0.207 15

    Imports -0.118 0.676 15

    Exports -0.067 0.811 15Balance of trade 0.244 0.382 15

    Union density 0.428 0.189 11

    Pluralism -0.629 0.012 15

    Wage bargaining 0.622 0.018 14

    Environment 0.712 0.004 14

    Table 4: Correlations with Average Support for Fair Trade