309
The London School of Economics and Political Science Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU: past, present and future Saskia King A thesis submitted to the Department of Law of the London School of Economics for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy, London, January 2015

Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

  • Upload
    vutruc

  • View
    219

  • Download
    3

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

The London School of Economics and Political Science

Agreements that restrict competition by object under

Article 101(1) TFEU: past, present and future

Saskia King

A thesis submitted to the Department of Law of the London School of Economics

for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy, London, January 2015

Page 2: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 1

Declaration

I certify that the thesis I have presented for examination for the MPhil/PhD degree

of the London School of Economics and Political Science is solely my own work

other than where I have clearly indicated that it is the work of others (in which case

the extent of any work carried out jointly by me and any other person is clearly

identified in it).

The copyright of this thesis rests with the author. Quotation from it is permitted,

provided that full acknowledgement is made. This thesis may not be reproduced

without my prior written consent.

I warrant that this authorisation does not, to the best of my belief, infringe the

rights of any third party.

I declare that my thesis consists of 99,345 words.

Page 3: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 2

Acknowledgments

My heartfelt thanks go, of course, to my supervisors, Professor Giorgio Monti and

Dr Andrew Scott for their invaluable advice, time and support over the years. I am

deeply indebted.

This thesis is dedicated to my beloved family: to my wonderful children, Sabella and

Sebastian, my husband Spencer and my parents. Thank you.

Stone-in-Oxney

January 2015

Page 4: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 3

Abstract

This thesis conducts a robust and granular examination of the concept of ‘object’

under Article 101(1) TFEU and its resulting legal and practical implications. To that

end, a methodology focusing on the case law of the European Courts and other

primary sources is adopted. This enables a legal analysis of the meaning,

application and role of restrictions of competition by object to be undertaken. The

case law reveals three key approaches adopted by the European Courts to

restrictions by object: the ‘orthodox approach’, the ‘more analytical approach’ and

an amalgamation of these two approaches, the ‘hybrid approach’. This finding

immediately questions the dominance of the orthodox approach within legal

discourse over the years. The orthodox approach contends that a limited category

of agreements are considered by law to automatically restrict competition by virtue

of their object. This is reflected in the European Commission’s Article 81(3)

Guidelines and is encapsulated by the widely recognised ‘object box’. This thesis

poses a direct challenge to such narrow interpretation of the law. It argues that

this depiction of the law does not fully reflect the jurisprudence of the European

Courts. Rather the case law reveals an alternative interpretation of the concept of

object based on the seminal case of Société Technique Minière concerned more

with determining the aim of the agreement within its legal and economic context as

opposed to its categorisation. Moreover, the ‘more analytical approach’ benefits

from greater judicial support. Having established the three key approaches and

their application under Article 101(1) TFEU, the question of what is the best

interpretation of the law on restrictions of competition by ‘object’ is reflected on.

Based on the case law of the European Courts, it is argued the more analytical

approach provides the best interpretation of the law. This is assessed in relation to

the framework of Article 101 TFEU as a whole. Finally, this thesis briefly explores

whether such conclusion is then consistent with the optimum function of the object

criterion from an enforcement perspective.

Page 5: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 4

Table of Contents

Declaration ...................................................................................................................................... 1

Acknowledgments ........................................................................................................................... 2

Abstract ........................................................................................................................................... 3

Table of Contents ............................................................................................................................. 4

Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 9

1. Introduction............................................................................................................................. 9

2. Background to the thesis ....................................................................................................... 12

3. The research question and methodology ............................................................................... 17

4. Chapter organisation ............................................................................................................. 21

Chapter 1: Establishing the ‘orthodox approach’ ........................................................................... 27

1. Introduction........................................................................................................................... 27

1.1. The object criterion: an overview ........................................................................................ 28

2. The orthodox approach ......................................................................................................... 29

2.1. Restrictions that ‘by their very nature’ distort competition ................................................ 29

2.1.1. Necessary effect ........................................................................................................... 31

2.1.2. US per se offence ......................................................................................................... 31

2.2. Case law ............................................................................................................................... 32

2.3. The Commission................................................................................................................... 34

2.3.1. Guidelines and BER’s: soft law and policy .................................................................... 35

2.3.2. Decisions, submissions and speeches .......................................................................... 39

2.4. Conclusion ........................................................................................................................... 45

3. Problems with the orthodox approach .................................................................................. 46

Chapter 2: The case law of the European Courts ............................................................................ 52

Part I: How the European Courts have interpreted the meaning and application of the object

criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU: establishing the more analytical approach

1. Introduction........................................................................................................................... 52

Page 6: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 5

2. Early case law up until the inception of the GC: the European Court of Justice (1965 – 1989) 54

2.1. Agreements that incorporate a ‘more analytical approach’: the need for a contextual

assessment ................................................................................................................................. 55

2.1.1. Establishing the more analytical approach: STM ......................................................... 55

2.1.2. Confirmation of a more analytical approach ............................................................... 60

2.1.2.1. Consideration of market power and market structure ........................................ 61

2.1.2.2. Taking into account the potential effects of an agreement to prove an anti-

competitive purpose: the importance of the economic context ...................................... 63

2.1.3. Interim Conclusion ....................................................................................................... 68

2.2. Questionable foundations of the orthodox approach: agreements that ‘by their very

nature’ restrict competition: early case law up to 1989 ............................................................ 70

2.2.1. Cases that continue to support the more analytical approach .................................... 71

2.2.2. Origins of the orthodox approach ................................................................................ 72

2.2.3. Necessary consequence/necessary effect ................................................................... 75

2.2.4. Interim conclusion ....................................................................................................... 76

3. The more analytical approach continues to inform the CJEU’s application of the object

concept: 1989 to 2006 ............................................................................................................... 77

3.1. Conclusion: 1989-2006 ........................................................................................................ 83

4. Case law of the General Court ............................................................................................... 86

4.1. ‘Per se’ infringements: a new dimension to agreements that ‘by their very nature’ restrict

competition ................................................................................................................................ 86

4.2. The return to a more analytical approach ........................................................................... 88

4.2.1. GlaxoSmithKline ........................................................................................................... 90

4.3. Conclusion: case law of the General Court .......................................................................... 94

5. Conclusion: Part I ................................................................................................................... 95

Part II: How the European Courts have interpreted the meaning and application of the object

criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU: the metamorphosis of the more analytical approach

1. Introduction........................................................................................................................... 97

2. The European Court of Justice: the dawn of the hybrid approach .......................................... 98

2.1. The Game Changer Cases .................................................................................................... 98

2.1.1. BIDS .............................................................................................................................. 99

2.1.1.1. The judgment ..................................................................................................... 102

2.1.2. T-Mobile ..................................................................................................................... 104

2.1.3. GlaxoSmithKline ......................................................................................................... 107

Page 7: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 6

2.2. Conclusion: the Game Changer Cases ............................................................................... 109

3. Overall conclusion: Parts I and II .......................................................................................... 110

Chapter 3: Identifying the concept of object ................................................................................ 114

1. Introduction......................................................................................................................... 114

2. Universal legal principles of the object criterion .................................................................. 114

2.1. ‘Object’ and ‘effect’ are distinct concepts ......................................................................... 114

2.2. Object does not require the concrete effects of an agreement to be examined .............. 115

2.3. Object must be considered first ........................................................................................ 116

2.3.1. When is the object criterion satisfied? ...................................................................... 119

2.4. Subjective intention is not determinative when assessing object ..................................... 121

2.4.1. Odudu and intent ....................................................................................................... 122

2.4.2. Conclusion .................................................................................................................. 124

2.5. Success and non-implementation of an agreement are extraneous ................................. 124

2.6. An agreement that restricts competition by object can still benefit from an Article 101(3)

TFEU exemption........................................................................................................................ 125

2.7. Burden of proof ................................................................................................................. 125

2.8. Conclusion ......................................................................................................................... 125

3. The definition of ‘object’: what does it mean? ..................................................................... 126

3.1. The more analytical approach ........................................................................................... 126

3.2. The orthodox approach ..................................................................................................... 128

3.3. The hybrid approach .......................................................................................................... 130

3.4. Legal Presumptions ............................................................................................................ 133

3.4.1. Definition of a ‘legal presumption’ ............................................................................ 134

3.4.2. Hardcore restrictions ................................................................................................. 135

3.4.3. Necessary effect/necessary consequence/prior belief .............................................. 137

3.4.3.1. Categorisation .................................................................................................... 141

3.4.4. Rebuttable legal presumptions versus no legal presumptions under Article 101(1)

TFEU ..................................................................................................................................... 143

3.4.4.1. Reversing the burden of proof within Article 101(1) TFEU ................................ 144

3.4.5. Conclusion: presumptions of harm ............................................................................ 147

3.5. The definition of ‘object’: conclusion ................................................................................ 148

Chapter 4: Applying the object concept to agreements in accordance with the MAAP ................ 150

1. Introduction......................................................................................................................... 150

Page 8: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 7

2. Legal and economic context ................................................................................................ 150

2.1. Definition ........................................................................................................................... 152

2.2. Applying the legal and economic context to determine the precise purpose of an

agreement: balancing the positive aims of an agreement against negative ones ................... 155

2.3. Legitimate goals/aims/objectives and objective justifications .......................................... 160

2.4. Object and the ancillary restraints doctrine ...................................................................... 168

2.5. Conclusion: legal and economic context ........................................................................... 173

3. The role of ‘effects’ under the legal and economic context .................................................. 174

3.1. Allianz Hungária ................................................................................................................. 175

3.2. Determining potential effects: the capacity to restrict competition ................................. 180

3.3. Conclusion: The role of effects under the legal and economic context ............................ 185

4. Commentator rationale: explaining the anomalies without abandoning categorisation ...... 186

4.1. Analysis of the commentary .............................................................................................. 198

5. Conclusion ........................................................................................................................... 200

Chapter 5: The implications of adopting the more analytical approach on Article 101 TFEU ........ 202

1. Introduction......................................................................................................................... 202

2. De Minimis: How appreciable is object? .............................................................................. 203

2.1. Introduction ....................................................................................................................... 203

2.2. Expedia: background to the case ....................................................................................... 205

2.3. Opinion of Advocate General Kokott ................................................................................. 206

2.4. Judgment of the Court ....................................................................................................... 210

2.5. Analysis of the judgment ................................................................................................... 214

2.5.1. Appreciable effects .................................................................................................... 215

2.5.2. Effect on trade ........................................................................................................... 224

2.6. Conclusion: not a landmark judgment ............................................................................... 227

3. The impact of the MAAP on the objectives of Article 101 TFEU ........................................... 229

3.1. Introduction ....................................................................................................................... 229

3.2. The objectives of Article 101 TFEU: what is a restriction of competition .......................... 229

3.2.1. Conclusion: the relationship between the object concept and restrictions of

competition .......................................................................................................................... 234

4. The distinction between restrictions by object and by effect ............................................... 237

5. Article 101(3) TFEU: the legal exception .............................................................................. 243

Page 9: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 8

5.1. Introduction ....................................................................................................................... 243

5.2. The relationship between restrictions by object and Article 101(3) TFEU ........................ 244

5.2.1. Application: division of labour between Articles 101(1) and (3) TFEU ...................... 247

5.2.2. The practical implications and practice of applying Article 101(3) TFEU ................... 253

5.2.3. A new order? .............................................................................................................. 255

5.3. Conclusion: the death of Article 101(3) TFEU? .................................................................. 259

Conclusion: The function of the object criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU ................................. 262

1. Introduction......................................................................................................................... 262

2. The role of the object criterion: Commission and Courts ..................................................... 266

3. The ought question: effective enforcement ......................................................................... 267

3.1. How the object criterion should be delineated: criticising the effects-based approach ... 269

3.1.1. US per se offences: s.1 Sherman Act ......................................................................... 271

4. Conclusion ........................................................................................................................... 273

Glossary/Abbreviations ............................................................................................................... 276

Bibliography ................................................................................................................................. 279

1. Books, Chapters, Journal Articles & Conference Papers ....................................................... 279

2. Judgments and Opinions ...................................................................................................... 293

2.1. EU (European Court of Justice / General Court) ................................................................ 293

2.2. UK ...................................................................................................................................... 300

2.3. US ....................................................................................................................................... 300

3. Commission Decisions ......................................................................................................... 302

3.1. UK decisions ....................................................................................................................... 303

4. On-line Resources ................................................................................................................ 304

5. Legislation/Notices/Press releases ...................................................................................... 306

Page 10: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 9

Introduction

1. Introduction

Historically, one of the most neglected aspects of Article 101(1) of the Treaty on the

Functioning of the European Union (TFEU), indeed of EU competition law more

generally, has been the concept of agreements whose ‘object’ is to restrict

competition. Many commentators were in the past willing to accept Professor

Whish’s infamous depiction: the ‘object box’.1 In his terms, the object box

comprises a limited class of ‘particularly pernicious’ agreements, which are

considered by law to have as their object the restriction of competition.2 By

implication, restrictions of competition by object are akin to a form of per se

offence as understood within the context of section 1 of the Sherman Act 1890.3

Although an agreement restricting competition by object could be exempted under

Article 101(3) TFEU, this was seen as highly unlikely. Particular restrictions that fall

within the impugned category are therefore automatically seen as having the

object of restricting competition under Article 101(1) TFEU.4 As such, they involve

an ‘obvious’ infringement of Article 101(1) TFEU.5 Restrictions by object do not

require their anti-competitive effects to be proven; hence they immediately fall foul

of Article 101(1) TFEU.6

This perception and presentation of the law has been challenged only recently.7

This was due in large part to the clear embrace of the object box concept by the

1 (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p124. See (Bellamy & Child, 2008). The object box reflects what is referred

to as the “orthodox approach” within this thesis. See Chapter 1. 2 (Whish, 2009), pp115, 118 and (Whish & Bailey, 2012), pp117, 121. Whish admits his presentation

of the object box “slightly oversimplifies” the law (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p124. Whish is used as an authoritative benchmark as he pioneered the vision of the ‘object box’, which has been followed, not just by scholars, but cited by Advocate Generals (see AG Trstenjak in BIDS infra n14 and 41) and courts such as the Competition Appeals Tribunal. 3 See eg (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, pp658-660; also Case T-148/89 Tréfilunion v

Commission (Welded Steel Mesh) [1995] ECR II-1063. 4 (Whish, 2009), pp115-117.

5 (Whish, 2009), p119 and (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p121: citing the General Court’s judgment in ENS

infra n19. 6 (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p118. The contents of the object box are found at p124.

7 Since 2010 a number of articles on the object criterion emerged, for instance supra n3 (Jones), ‘Left

Behind by Modernisation?’; (King, 2011); (Andreangeli, 2011); (Bailey, 2012).

Page 11: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 10

European Commission (Commission) through its categorisation of restrictions by

object designated as ‘hardcore’ restrictions, evident in its guidelines and Block

Exemption Regulations (BERs).8 This meant that most focus of debate concerning

the object concept centred on whether the Commission correctly categorised

various types of agreement under the object heading and whether the object box

should be ‘thin’ or ‘fat’.9 The associated benefits such categorisation may bring in

terms of legal certainty or ease of administrative burden were also reflected

upon.10 The more pertinent question of whether categorising different types of

agreements as ‘object’ or ‘effect’ was legally correct was rarely considered.

Instead, that the law operated in the terms of an object box was simply and

unreservedly assumed.11

Due to the implementation of modernisation, however, particularly the acceptance

by the Commission of an ‘effects-based approach’ to determining restrictions of

competition by effect under Article 101(1) TFEU, the ‘effect’ criterion had for many

years taken centre stage within legal discourse.12 The object concept was therefore

8 See eg, Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty [2004] OJ C101/97 (the Article

81(3) Guidelines), paras 20-23; Commission Regulation 330/2010 on the application of Article 101(3) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to categories of vertical agreements and concerted practices [2010] OJ L102 1-7; Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2000] OJ C291 1-44; Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer agreements [2004] OJ C101 2-42, para 14; Horizontal Guidelines on the applicability of Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to horizontal co-operation agreements [2011] OJ C11/1, para 74 (the Horizontal Co-operation Guidelines). 9 This was evident at the conference on ‘Object/Effect and Information Sharing – the good, the bad

and the ugly’ 6 October 2010 at the British Institute of International and Comparative Law. Here delegates pressed the panel on precisely which types of agreement fall within the object category and whether the Horizontal Cooperation Guidelines correctly delineated that category. 10

(Bennett & Collins, 2010), pp311, 312-314. See also supra Jones n3, ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p656 and AG Kokott, infra n41 T-Mobile, para 43. 11

Ibid Bennett and Collins pp311, 312-314: “The most difficult thing to do is to determine exactly what kinds of agreement, arrangement or practice should fall within the object category, and hence carry the presumption of harm”. The authors provided no authority or case law supporting the basis on which they stated their view of the law. 12

2004 marked a significant chapter in the Commission’s role as the central enforcer of the EU’s antitrust regime. The ‘modernisation’ of EU competition law under Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 [2003] OJ L1/1 (Regulation 1/2003) meant the notification system was abolished and the application of Article 101 TFEU was decentralised. This meant businesses no longer needed to notify their agreements to the Commission and National Competition Authorities (NCA’s) and National Courts (NC’s) now had the power to grant exemptions to the prohibition, thus ending the Commission’s monopoly over Article 101(3) TFEU. See eg (Marquis, 2007), (Nazzini, 2006), (Wesseling, 2000) and for an in-depth examination of the effects-based approach see (Bourgeois & Waelbroeck, 2013).

Page 12: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 11

not high on the academic or, seemingly, the political agenda. This position no

longer stands: Gerard confirmed that the meaning of the object criterion has

resurfaced as one of the “fundamental legal questions of the day”.13

The shift in the debate from ‘effect’ to ‘object’ can be attributed to a variety of

factors. For instance, a number of important judgments were handed down by

both the General Court (GC) and Court of Justice (CJEU), which firmly drew

attention back to the object concept.14 Additionally, the process of modernisation

meant that the Commission was able to free up its resources to investigating and

uncovering cartels, typically forms of agreement that are restrictive by object.15 A

consequence of this enforcement priority adjustment and the absence of the

notification system has been that nearly every Decision issued by the Commission

under Article 101 TFEU in the past ten years has been framed in object terms.16

In parallel with this development, the application of an ‘effects-based’ approach to

agreements under Article 101(1) TFEU is seen as complex.17 Competition

authorities find it harder to win cases on an effects-based analysis given the level of

economic assessment demanded by the Community Courts. For instance, in O2 the

GC reminded the Commission of the importance of the counterfactual.18 In

Delimitis and ENS, the Courts also asked for more evidence of effects than in

previous effect cases.19 Hence, competition authorities would rather resort to

applying the object criterion, which carries a burden of proof that is easier to

satisfy.20 As the concrete effects of the agreement do not need to be proven under

the object criterion, a rational competition authority will therefore look to stretch

13

(Gerard, 2013), p39. 14

See Chapter 2: Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline Services v Commission [2006] ECR II-2969 and infra n41: C-501/06 P GSK, C-209/07 BIDS and C-8/08 T-Mobile. Note that previously the General Court was known as the Court of First Instance. 15

White Paper on Modernisation of the Rules Implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty Commission Programme No 99/027 [1999] OJ C132/1. 16

(Gerard, 2013), p38. 17

See eg Gerard, supra n13: “The term ‘economic’ approach is often used as a synonym for ‘effects-based’”, p20. 18

Case T-328/03 O2 (Germany) GmbH & Co, OHG v Commission [2006] 5 CMLR 258, 65-117. See (Robertson, 2007), p262; (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p127. 19

C-234/89 Delimitis v Henninger Bräu [1992] 5 CMLR 210; Joined Cases T371, 375, 384 &388/94 European Night Services v Commission [1998] ECR II-3141 (ENS). 20

(Goyder, 2011), III.

Page 13: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 12

the meaning of the object criterion - usually in the guise of expanding the contents

of the object box - as a mechanism for ensuring it is successful in finding an

agreement anticompetitive.21 As a result, there is a growing reliance on the object

criterion by competition authorities within their decision-making. This refocus on

the object criterion has given rise to a concern amongst some commentators that

the economic rationale behind the impetus of the effects-based approach is now

meaningless; because all economic analysis is reserved for restrictions by ‘effect’ as

opposed to those by object.22 This proposition needs testing.

What is certain is that the relevance of the object criterion continues to increase

within the current legal landscape. The debate, that had long been so absent over

its meaning and application, now shows no signs of abating.23

2. Background to the thesis

In September 2006 the GC handed down a controversial judgment, which departed

dramatically from the concept of object as traditionally perceived.24 In GSK, the

Court found on the facts that an intended restriction of parallel trade, a known

‘hardcore’ restriction, did not infringe Article 101(1) TFEU by object. Rather, it held

that the agreement was restrictive by effect. In doing so, it deviated from the

standards employed by the Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines. The

prevalent reaction to the judgment at the time was that the GC was wrong: that its

application of the object criterion to the agreement blurred the line between the

concepts of object and effect.25 The GC’s interpretation of the law was, therefore,

21

Arguably the Commission did this in Lundbeck (Case No. 39226) and in its Horizontal Co-operation Guidelines. 22

(Gerard, 2013), pp38-39. Also noted by (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p650. 23

Numerous conferences on the subject continue to take place, eg, ERA conference “Restrictions of Competition by object after Cartes Bancaires and the Commission’s Initiatives” on 11 December 2014; of many blog posts on this topic see also (Lawrence, 2014), Object Restrictions on the Menu; and, more generally, www.chillingcompetition.com; Lovdahl Gormsen highlights the “considerable debate” over whether the presumption of effects under the object criterion is rebuttable under Article 101(1) TFEU as opposed to being exempted under Article 101(3) TFEU, (Lovdahl Gormsen, 2013), ft23. 24

Supra n14, Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline Services v Commission. See (Goyder & Albors-Llorens, 2009), p120. 25

See eg (Whish, 2009), p121.

Page 14: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 13

regarded as an anomaly.26 Such reaction demonstrated how entrenched the

position, that the law operated in terms of an object box, was within the legal

community. The notion that the law may, in fact, operate in a way not wholly

reflected in the Commission’s guidelines, was largely absent. Hence, an initial

enquiry was to test whether the judgment was, indeed, “surprising”.27

Testing the hypothesis revealed a number of significant findings. Even on a

preliminary reading of the case law of the CJEU, the judgment should not have been

especially surprising.28 In particular, much of the careful application and recounting

of the law on the object criterion by the GC was, in fact, more rather than less,

indicative of the jurisprudence. The GC’s judgment highlighted an alternative, more

analytical means of applying the object criterion, far removed from the deployment

of the object box analogy by the Commission in its decision.29 It was evident from

this early research, that the meaning and application of the object criterion was

considerably more nuanced than the Article 81(3) Guidelines would suggest.30 The

very real prospect was thus raised, that the Article 81(3) Guidelines did not

accurately reflect the law. Moreover, the dearth of in-depth academic research

into the object concept was exposed.31

Many of the leading texts and academic papers published prior to 2010 revealed

the common acceptance of the Commission’s interpretation of the object

criterion.32 Indeed, the object concept was of so little interest that some

commentators ignored it entirely in their critiques of Article 101(1) TFEU.33 For

26

(Whish, 2009), p121. See also (Bennett & Collins, 2010), pp312-314. Many comments voiced at conferences confirmed this perception, eg, at the PhD conference held by QMW at Goodenough College in November 2007. 27

Ibid, Whish, p121. 28

This initial research was undertaken between 2008-2010. 29

Commission Decision, GlaxoSmithKline, 2001/791/EC. 30

For instance, at least 6 different definitions of ‘object’ were found. 31

Cf two papers on the object concept authored by Odudu in 2001, ‘Object as Subjective Intention’ and ‘The Object Requirement Revisited’; (Jones, 2006); a paper written for the Swedish competition authority (Kolstad, 2009) and a short article written on the rule of reason by Lasok QC (Lasok QC, 2008). 32

See eg (Whish, 2009), (Bellamy & Child, 2008), (Faull & Nikpay, 2007), (Chalmers, et al., 2006) who rely heavily on the judgment in ENS; (Goyder & Albors-Llorens, 2009), pp118-122, particularly p119-120. Cf (Odudu, 2006) and (Black, 2005), pp115-127. 33

See eg (Slot & Johnston, 2006).

Page 15: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 14

others, the object criterion was clear and straightforward.34 On the whole, the

texts provided limited explanation of the meaning or application of the object

criterion to agreements, or to the case law underpinning it.35 Instead, the

modernisation process meant most commentary focused on the role and

assessment of the effect criterion. Nevertheless, it was acknowledged on occasion,

paradoxically by Whish, that the object concept did present some inconsistencies

and therefore was “confused and confusing”.36 Few at this juncture, however,

chose to unravel and respond to the problems.37

In view of the nature of the object criterion as a substantive element of Article

101(1) TFEU these initial findings were illuminating and unexpected. The

assumption was that the object concept would have been subject to careful

examination, as the importance of the object criterion within Article 101(1) TFEU

was always clear.38 This was underlined by Odudu who opined that:

“economic effects need not be considered when the object is to restrict competition; when an economic effect must be shown is

34

See eg, (Chalmers, et al., 2006) p1000: “object cases are simple: a cartel…has as its object the elimination of competition because the parties monopolise the market and raise prices, as such it is prohibited. The object of an agreement is not determined by the intention of the parties, rather an agreement has its anti-competitive object when the restriction of competition is obvious. If the object is to harm competition, then there is no need to enquire about the effects.” See also (Bourgeois & Bocken, 2005). 35

Arguably many commentators were guilty of this: see eg, (Nicolaides, 2005), pp129-130; also (Bellamy & Child, 2008), para 2/097 who viewed object as a “per se” restriction, which “of their nature” restricted competition, which they claimed was the same approach adopted by the Commission; (Korah, 2006), pp74-84 and (Dabbah, 2004), pp73-76. 36

(Whish, 2003), pp108-115. The statement was made in reference to the amount of market analysis required under the object heading when assessing whether the agreement is appreciable. 37

At the PhD conference at Goodenough College in 2007, David Gerber made an observation that resonated with the impetus behind this thesis. He stated that, despite over 50 years of EU competition law, there was a need for a “back to basics” approach, as the Courts and commentators were still struggling to understand the fundamental elements of Article 101 TFEU, despite the advancement of competition law in terms of economic considerations, policy developments and other deviations. Marquis also acknowledged Article 101(1) TFEU and its “exotic mysteries” (Marquis, 2007). Notably Odudu did advance an alternative view of the object criterion: (Odudu, 2001) “Interpreting Article 81(1): Object as Subjective Intention” and “Interpreting Article 81(1): the Object Requirement Revisited”. 38

Goyder agrees, “...the concept of an ‘object’ restriction has not yet been firmly nailed down, and still gives rise to confusion. It seems even more surprising when one considers that object infringements represent the most serious anticompetitive conduct, and so tend to be enforcement priorities for competition authorities, and to attract significant fines...it is hard to discern clear outlines of the concept of ‘object restriction’ [despite the volume of case law].” (Goyder, 2011), I (Introduction).

Page 16: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 15

determined by the scope and content of the object category. Article [101 TFEU] remains uncertain to the extent that the meaning and functioning of the ‘object’ element is unspecified.”39

The lack of historical research was all the more startling in view of the

acknowledgment, by several prominent scholars such as Marquis and Whish, that

Article 101(1) TFEU lacked clarity as a whole, despite the Commission’s claim that

EU competition law had “clearly established basic principles and well-defined

details”.40 The need for detailed research into the object criterion was further

underscored by three seminal judgments handed down by the CJEU that dealt

specifically with the law relating to the object criterion: GSK, BIDS and T-Mobile.41

These judgments significantly raised the profile of the object concept and

highlighted a more contextual approach to determining an agreement’s object.

The increase in interest surrounding the object criterion has coincided with a

palpable shift in the perception of it in a number of the current editions of leading

texts. Certainly, in contrast with earlier editions, the object concept has been

subject to a more full and balanced appraisal. This, in conjunction with the recent

spate of CJEU judgments, is due to the influence of a number of prominent

academic papers published between 2010 and 2012, which highlighted the

limitations of the orthodoxy.42 Whish & Bailey’s description of the object criterion,

for example, is now more expansive than in previous editions insofar as the authors

recognise that the object concept is more complex than was previously stated.43

The premise of their interpretation of the law still rests on the understanding that

certain agreements can be “classified as having as their object the restriction of

competition since in such cases it is not necessary to prove that anti-competitive

39

(Odudu, 2006), p3. 40

(Odudu, 2006), p97; (Marquis, 2007), p29; White Paper on Modernisation of the Rules Implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty Commission Programme No 99/027 [1999] OJ C132/1, introduction, para 3. See generally (Monti, 2007) and (Gerber, 2008). 41

Joined cases C-501/06P, C-513/06P, C-515/06P, C-519/06P GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission and Others, [2009] ECR I-9291 (GSK); Case C-209/07 Competition Authority v Beef Industry Development Society Ltd and Barry Brothers (Carrigmore) Meats Ltd [2008] ECR I-8637 (BIDS); Case C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands BV and Others v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit [2009] ECR I-4529 (T-Mobile). 42

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, (King, 2011), (Andreangeli, 2011), (Bailey, 2012). 43

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p122, ft 367 citing Jones and King. They acknowledge the object box is not an exhaustive list, p122.

Page 17: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 16

effects would follow”.44 Hence, the categorisation of agreements falling into the

“object box” remains at the heart of their argument.45 They also continue to assert

that any quantitative component to the object analysis lies primarily in the fact that

any restriction of competition must be appreciable.46 How the object criterion is, in

fact, applied to agreements is not elaborated on.47

The shift in the perception of the object concept is most palpable in Bellamy &

Child.48 In contrast to its previous account of the object criterion, though notably

relying on much of the same case law as in its previous edition, Bellamy & Child

provides one of the most comprehensive text-book accounts of the object

criterion.49 Having previously advanced a position sympathetic to the object box

approach and analogous with US-style per se infringements, the 7th edition places

more reliance on determining the precise purpose of the agreement within its legal

and economic context.50 What the text lacks is greater detail and a more granular

account of the various elements that play a role under the object criterion, such as

legitimate objectives and restrictive effects.

What emerges, therefore, from the proliferation of judgments, new guidelines and

commentary in recent years is that the object criterion is currently in a state of flux.

This status is evidenced by the Commission. In September 2013 Alexander

Italianer, the Director General of DG COMP, gave an insightful speech on the object

44

Ibid, p120. 45

Ibid, p120. ENS is cited as authority for this contention, pp121-123. 46

Ibid, p120. Following the judgment in Case C-226/11 Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence, 13 December 2012, nyr (Expedia) this understanding is contentious (see Chapter 5). Bellamy & Child also find that the function of an effects-based analysis under the object heading is limited to (i) the determination of appreciableness, (ii) the level of fine, (iii) the application of Article 101(3) TFEU and (iv) the affect on trade, (Bellamy & Child, 2013), 2.117. This thesis argues that the quantitative component is not only due to these factors. See Chapters 2-4. 47

For instance, there is no examination of the role of the legal and economic context, which is shown in later chapters of this thesis to form a fundamental part of the application of the law under Article 101(1) TFEU. 48

(Bellamy & Child, 2013), 2.111-2.123. 49

(Bellamy & Child, 2013), 2.111-2.123. (Jones & Sufrin, 2014) also provides a comprehensive account, though describes the object concept in terms of the identification of a category of object restraints automatically assumed to restrict competition, p205. However, the exceptions to this general rule are noted: pp212-226, 232. 50

(Bellamy & Child, 2013), 2.111.

Page 18: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 17

criterion.51 He advocated a more contextual approach to ascertaining an

agreement’s object, operating along the lines of a continuum or sliding scale: the

complexity of such assessment being dependent on the circumstances of the case.52

Conversely, in its Guidance on restrictions by object published in June 2014, the

Commission seemingly distances itself from a more in-depth contextual analysis by

re-enforcing its perception of the relationship between the object concept and

hardcore restrictions.53 The judgment in Expedia ostensibly exacerbated this

understanding, which the Commission interpreted to mean that anticompetitive

agreements by object “have by definition an appreciable impact on competition”.54

The truth of this assertion requires careful attention.

Having flirted with the notion that the object criterion is not straitjacketed by an

object box, it would appear in some quarters that the Commission, and indeed

certain commentators, are again favouring a return to formalism.55 It is perhaps no

coincidence that the complexity of analysis involved in determining restrictions by

effect (under the effects-based approach), has reignited the call for ‘bright lines’

under the object condition.56

3. The research question and methodology

In view of these insights the need for comprehensive research into the concept of

object, not just the issue of what constitutes a restriction by object, is long overdue.

Set against the backdrop of modernisation, this thesis casts a probing light on this

substantive element of Article 101(1) TFEU. It asks what the object concept means

if the case law is interpreted carefully and recounted accurately. The thesis is

therefore designed to advance our knowledge and enhance our legal understanding

51

(Italianer, 2013) ‘Competitor Agreements under EU Competition law’, Fordham. 52

Ibid, p5. Even though this thesis does not support all of the proposals made in the speech, it is a notable departure from the Article 81(3) Guidelines. 53

Commission Staff Working Document, Guidance on restrictions of competition ‘by object’ for the purpose of defining which agreements may benefit from the De Minimis Notice’, 2014. 54

Commission Press release, 25 June 2014; Case C-226/11 Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence. 55

See generally (Nagy, 2013), p542 and AG Kokott in T-Mobile and Expedia; (Jones & Sufrin, 2014), p205. However, the judgment in Case C-67/13 P Groupement des Cartes Bancaires v Commission (11 September 2014) (Cartes Bancaires) has re-ignited the debate regarding the object criterion and its relationship with the effects-based approach. 56

See (Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013).

Page 19: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 18

of this provision by focusing on its legal meaning, application and role within Article

101(1) TFEU as determined by the European Courts. The outcome of this

examination will then be considered in the wider context of Article 101 TFEU as a

whole, in terms of the object concept’s relationship with Article 101 TFEU.

Additionally, the Article 81(3) Guidelines, which the Commission issued as part of its

package of guidelines intended to ensure the coherent enforcement of Article 101

TFEU across the EU as well as to clarify its application, are significant in this

research.57 They represent the official account of the Commission’s interpretation

of the object concept and embody the traditional perception of the concept of

object. Consequently, they provide a useful comparative component, which

exemplifies the complexity and nuances of the case law that becomes evident

throughout the body of this thesis.

This thesis is doctrinal in nature and utilises doctrinal restatement techniques.58

Given its focus on undertaking a legal examination of the concept of object under

Article 101(1) TFEU, the key methodological approach employed in this thesis is to

conduct a detailed examination of the jurisprudence emanating from the

Community Courts and to present the evidence. As the ultimate interpreter of the

TFEU the emphasis on the case law of the European Courts is fundamental to this

research.59 Other primary sources and academic research are also considered.60

This methodology not only highlights the questionable origin of the interpretation

of the object concept provided in the Article 81(3) Guidelines and other

commentary, but more importantly provides legal justification for the conclusions

reached in this research.

57

Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty [2004] OJ C101/97 (Article 81(3) Guidelines). Article 81 is now Article 101 under the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU). 58

(Minow, 2006), pp34–5. 59

See (Goyder, 2011), III. 60

Including Advocate General opinions, Commission Guidelines, Regulations, Notices, Decisions, guidance, white and green papers, Commission newsletters, speeches and press releases. Also the case law, decisions, guidelines and other primary sources emanating from the NCA’s and NC’s are examined as appropriate.

Page 20: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 19

The benefit and rationale behind focusing on black letter law is well documented.61

Separating the ‘is’ from the ‘ought’ question is an important component of this

thesis.62 To determine the law on object is an interpretative task and, to this end,

the meaning, application and function of the object concept is examined to reveal

the characteristics, structure, concepts and principles ascribed by the European

Courts. This approach could be criticised as one-dimensional,63 but given the

overwhelming influence of the orthodox approach on legal discourse a return to a

basic premise relying on the jurisprudence of the European Courts is warranted.

This thesis therefore also explores the limits of the application of the law and its

potential application in the future. Once the interpretative task is completed, then

soft law, policy, economic and normative considerations can be re-incorporated to

those findings.

To provide an accurate legal account of the object concept, economic

considerations will be provisionally set to one side. The text of Article 101 TFEU is

enshrined in law and interpreted by judges, not economists, in the European

Courts. The economics of Article 101(1) TFEU has, rightly, been a dominant feature

in legal scholarship over the past 10 years, but this has come at a cost: the legal

interpretation of the law concerning the object concept has been neglected,

particularly as emphasis was generally placed on deciphering restrictions by effect

in accordance with the ‘effects-based’ approach.64 Such focus on economic

considerations and values resulted in questionable assumptions as to the state of

the law being advanced with respect to the object criterion.65 This has been greatly

aided by the general acceptance of the Commission’s legal interpretation of

restrictions by object despite the under-acknowledged existence of a contradictory

61

See (Kelsen, 1934); (Smith, 2004) ‘Contract Theory’, p5. 62

See (Austin, 1832). See also other legal positivists such as Bentham, Kelsen and subsequent criticisms by Hart regards precisely how the ‘is’ question is determined: (Davies & Holdcroft, 1991). 63

Hart argues that identifying what the law is, is not just attributable to what the Courts say: (Hart, 1997). Dworkin takes this proposition further claiming that the law is made up of rules, standards (such as policies) and principles and as such there cannot be a strict separation between law and morality: (Dworkin, 1977), (Dworkin, 1986). 64

See eg (Gerard, 2013). 65

Economists often recount the basic premise of law, as interpreted by the Commission, as being accurate. This is evidenced in papers, texts and at conferences. See eg (Bennett & Collins, 2010).

Page 21: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 20

array of case law.66 Revealing the true legal nature of the object criterion and

reclaiming it for legal discourse ensures that policy and economic considerations

can then be countenanced appropriately as tools to help determine agreements

within a legal framework.

This thesis will therefore develop the conclusions reached from such investigation

into the positive law and engage in a form of legal interpretation.67 The case law

will be reorganised by calibrating it as reflecting an ‘orthodox approach’, a ‘more

analytical approach’ (the MAAP), and a ‘hybrid approach’.68 Ultimately, this thesis

seeks to determine what is the best interpretation of ‘restriction of competition by

object’ based on the case law of the European Courts. The advantages and flaws of

the three approaches will therefore be documented and highlight how the

inconsistent application of a narrow category of agreements seen to be restrictive

by object renders the legal value of any so-called ‘object box’ meaningless.

More fundamentally, this thesis contributes to the literature by advocating an

approach to the object concept that moves away from the notion of categorisation

and from any analogy with the US per se system. Instead, it promotes a return to

the contextual understanding of the law first set out in the seminal case of STM.69

In that case, the Court looked to the “precise purpose” of an agreement

determined within its legal and economic context as opposed to identifying a

category of restraints automatically presumed as being restrictive by object.70

Consequently, such an understanding of the law can be seen as being, in a sense,

neither new nor transformative.71 Having answered the key research question of

66

See NCA’s submissions in cases before the CJEU supporting the orthodox understanding of the law, eg: supra n41, BIDS. NCA’s, particularly those with less sophisticated and newer competition regimes will often support the Article 81(3) Guidelines in their submissions, despite not being obliged to follow the Guidelines (see supra n46 Expedia). AG’s have also used the Article 81(3) Guidelines to justify their interpretation of the law: see AG Cruz Villalón in Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária, 25 October 2012, nyr, para 65 (infra Chapter 4, section 3.1). 67

(Smith, 2004), p5. 68

See generally (King, 2011). 69

Case C-56/65 Société Technique Minière v Maschinenbau Ulm Gmbh [1966] ECR 249 (STM). 70

Ibid, STM, 249. 71

Cf ‘The Object/Effect Distinction in Competition Law Article 101, categorical distinctions and Predictable Enforcement’, New Challenges in Competition Law Enforcement conference, Istanbul, 6 June 2014: (Rodger, 2014).

Page 22: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 21

what is the best interpretation of law on the object criterion, the implications of

adopting the MAAP for Article 101 TFEU are then explored.72

This thesis therefore addresses the gap in the historical literature by presenting a

comprehensive legal account of the object criterion within Article 101(1) TFEU, and

investigating the repercussions of that research on Article 101 TFEU as a whole. As

less attention is paid to the perspectives of the Commission, and greater emphasis

is placed on the jurisprudence of the European Courts, the questionable origins of

the orthodox approach are revealed.

4. Chapter organisation

This thesis is organised as follows: Chapter 1: Establishing the orthodox approach,

sets out the conventional understanding of the law on the object criterion as set

out by the Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines and the ‘object box’ proposed

by Professor Whish. This perception of the law is referred to in this thesis as the

‘orthodox approach’. The essence of the orthodox approach in terms of its

meaning, application and role will be examined with the aid of the Commission’s

policy documents and decisional practice, literature and a summary of the case law

supporting such interpretation. The US per se system under the Sherman Act is

drawn on as an appropriate analogy. Hence the significance of the orthodox

approach as the leading interpretation of the law will be underlined whilst noting it

still attracts many followers. Thereafter, the chapter will identify the problems with

the orthodox approach as highlighted, most prominently, by the seminal judgment

of the GC in GSK.73 This encompasses the inconsistent and contradictory

application of the Article 81(3) Guidelines to cases by the Commission, the

expansion of the ‘object box’, the evolution of approach adopted by the

Commission evidenced in its new guidelines by the clearer adoption of the ‘legal

and economic context’ to cases and hence a more ‘analytical’ application of the

object concept.

72

For instance, in terms of object’s relationship with restrictions by effect, Article 101(3) TFEU and as a tool of enforcement. 73

Supra n14, GSK.

Page 23: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 22

Having mapped out the orthodox approach to the object criterion, established its

significance within legal discourse, in particular to the Commission, and then

identified its anomalies, Chapter 2: The meaning and application of restrictions by

object according to the European Courts tests the accuracy of the orthodox

approach vis-a-vis the case law of the European Courts.74 As such it sets out the

legal foundations underpinning the law relating to the object criterion. Such

analysis thereby provides the authority upon which to critique the object criterion

and the Article 81(3) Guidelines. The purpose of the chapter is to: (i) set out the

development of the case law thereby determining that the Courts have used a

variety of approaches when assessing the object of an agreement, namely, the

more analytical approach (the MAAP) and the hybrid approach in addition to the

orthodox approach, (ii) assess the meaning and application of the object criterion

adopted by the Courts, thereby finding the case law in fact provides greater support

for a more analytical approach; and (iii) prove the orthodox approach lacks judicial

support commensurate with its prominence within EU competition law. Overall,

the chapter demonstrates how the contextual analysis promulgated by the more

analytical approach is not ‘new’, and that the judgment in STM holds the most

influence throughout the case law.

Having identified the three key approaches to the object criterion drawn on by the

Courts, the reconstruction of the case law undertaken in chapter 2 is further

fleshed out in chapters 3 and 4, which probe the features of the object criterion

established by the case law review in more depth. This enables the primary

research question, what is the best interpretation of restrictions of competition by

object based on the case law of the European Courts, to be answered. To this end,

Chapter 3: Identifying the concept of object has two main tasks. First, it sets out the

74

This involved a comprehensive examination of the jurisprudence of the CJEU (including opinions) and GC relating to Article 101(1) TFEU for both object and effect since the 1960’s. Therefore, not only were those cases which were identified as relating to the object criterion in the various texts, articles and Commission’s guidelines scrutinised, but also cases usually considered relevant to ‘effect’ (such as STM). It was noted that ‘effect’ cases often included a general pronouncement by the Court regarding the application of Article 101(1) TFEU to agreements as a whole. Hence, the cases reported in the text of this thesis are those that provide more helpful illustrative examples of such pronouncements.

Page 24: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 23

so-called ‘universal principles’ of the object criterion. These principles are

consistently applied to agreements or upheld by the Courts, regardless of the

approach adopted by the European Courts to the object concept. Secondly, it

establishes the definition of ‘object’ under Article 101(1) TFEU, critiquing the

object/effect distinction advocated in BIDS, and assessing the definitions of the

object concept proposed under each approach.

Chapter 4: Applying the object concept to agreements in accordance with the MAAP

then investigates the application of the object criterion to agreements by focusing

on the MAAP and contrasting this with the hybrid approach. The abundance of

recent case law helps depict how the object criterion is applied to agreements. The

chapter turns, first, to a comprehensive assessment of the application of the legal

and economic context to agreements. Next, it examines how restrictive effects

impact the application of the legal and economic context to agreements that are

prima facie restrictive by object. It then draws on more recent commentary to

ascertain how others have rationalised developments in the case law in this regard.

Finally, the main research question is answered: it is proposed that the MAAP is the

better interpretation of the law in view of its greater and less conflicting judicial

support.75 The MAAP reveals the object concept to be a multi-faceted, complex yet

flexible element of Article 101(1) TFEU that seeks to uncover the ‘primary purpose’

of an agreement. It is able to explain, therefore, why the so-called anomalies

identified in the case law have not followed the orthodox approach. It is noted that

interpreting the law in accordance with the MAAP has garnered increasing support

and recognition in the past few years, though is not without its critics.

Following the detailed examination of the mechanics of the object concept

conducted in chapters 3 and 4 and having chosen the MAAP as the preferred

approach, Chapter 5: The implications of the MAAP on Article 101 TFEU as a whole

explores the wider implications of the MAAP on Article 101 TFEU. It seeks to

explain why the MAAP is a better approach. Given the sheer breadth of such a task,

75

Though it is still acknowledged that the jurisprudence remains confusing, however the application of the MAAP to agreements makes better and more rational sense of it.

Page 25: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 24

this chapter is selective in its scope. It thus tackles what the implications of the

MAAP are for specific aspects of Article 101 TFEU. Given the nature of the MAAP it

will focus on those aspects usually associated with restrictions by ‘effect’, such as

the relationship between the object criterion and the de minimis doctrine (and the

concept of market power) and the ‘effect on trade’ criterion. It also addresses the

relationship between restrictions by object and by effect. This involves a general

consideration of the objectives of Article 101 TFEU and the impact the more

analytical approach has on such objectives. More particularly, it will look at how

the more analytical approach, with its emphasis on the legal and economic context,

slots in with the ‘effects-based’ approach adopted by the Commission post-

modernisation. Finally, the chapter investigates what MAAP means for the

availability of an Article 101(3) TFEU exemption and its relationship with Article

101(3) TFEU.

Having interpreted the case law on the object concept under Article 101(1) TTFEU,

promoted the application of the MAAP and then examined the implications of the

MAAP on Article 101 TFEU as a whole, the final chapter, Conclusion: The function of

the object criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU concludes the thesis. It considers

what this research means for the normative function of the object concept. To this

end, it briefly explores how best the enforcement of Article 101 TFEU is tackled

through the use of the object criterion. The experience gleaned from the US will

aide this discussion. It proposes that a practical solution would be for the

Commission to better articulate its policy in respect of the object criterion and

clearly differentiate its policy approach from the law. Contrary to the Commission’s

assertions, the Article 81(3) Guidelines do not wholeheartedly reflect the

jurisprudence of the European Courts or indeed its own practice. Hence, the

Commission should recast its Article 81(3) Guidelines.

This thesis is intended to provide an authoritative legal account of what constitutes

the concept of object under Article 101(1) TFEU in all its guises. By presenting the

case law in this manner and assessing the impact of that research on Article 101

TFEU as a whole, this thesis makes a substantial contribution to the literature by

promoting an alternative way of perceiving the object criterion based on a faithful

Page 26: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 25

reflection of the jurisprudence of the European Courts. The object concept is

currently one of the most debated and pivotal aspects of Article 101 TFEU. This

thesis reinforces that status by addressing the gap in the literature, providing

detailed analysis and interpretation of the case law, then advocating an approach

removed from the orthodoxy. Ultimately, this thesis maps out the past and

present, with a view to ensuring this body of work will continue to be relevant

(regardless of how the European Courts or Commission go on to interpret the

object criterion) in the future.

Page 27: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 26

Some preliminary matters should be addressed here. In order to provide a focused

account of the object criterion, there are a number of issues that this thesis is

unable to address, though that does not denote they are not significant. For

instance, this thesis does not seek to determine if the outcome of particular

judgments and decisions are necessarily correct. Nor does this thesis aim to

address every aspect of Article 101 TFEU that may be affected by the object

criterion in the wider arena. Rich sources for future research that stem from this

study would therefore include the impact of the MAAP on National Competition

Authorities (NCAs) in light of their obligations under Regulation 1/2003 and the

judgment in Expedia, as well as an examination into any links in terminology and

concepts between Articles 101 and Article 102 TFEU.

This thesis takes account of developments to August 2014.76 Several acronyms are

also used throughout this thesis, which are referenced in the glossary at page 276.

Finally, the focus of this thesis is on the law of the EU contained within the TFEU,

though some comparative work has been done with other jurisdictions such as the

US and UK.

76

Given its importance, the judgment in C-67/13 Cartes Bancaires rendered on 11 September 2014 is referenced. Hence, conferences or blogs reviewing this judgment have also been referenced where appropriate.

Page 28: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 27

Chapter 1: Establishing the ‘orthodox approach’

1. Introduction

A longstanding orthodoxy has informed the general appreciation of the object

criterion in Article 101(1) TFEU. This orthodoxy has been described by leading

scholars of competition law and adopted by the Commission in its guidelines. A

first task of this chapter is to sketch out this traditional or ‘orthodox’ view of the

object criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU by reference to commentators’ views, to

the case law of the European Courts, and to policy statements made by the

Commission.

The orthodox approach continues to provide the bedrock of the Commission’s

interpretation of the object criterion in its Article 81(3) Guidelines. Hence, it carries

great significance under EU competition law, and must be taken seriously.1

Notably, however, the orthodox understanding is not always followed by the

European Courts or, indeed, the Commission. As a result, its value immediately

becomes questionable. While the orthodox understanding of the meaning,

application and role of the object criterion has had many followers, a second aim of

this chapter is to explain that it is unpersuasive. The chapter therefore documents

provisionally a confusion surrounding the application of the object concept.

This exercise provides an appropriate backdrop to the review of case law that is

presented in chapter 2, and which exposes how far the jurisprudence of the

European Courts fails to support the orthodox interpretation of the law. The

depiction offered of the orthodox approach also acts as a useful comparative

benchmark in chapters 3 and 4 when this thesis seeks to ascertain what truly

constitutes the object criterion and its various facets under Article 101(1) TFEU.

1 In view also of how many NCAs and businesses explain the application of the object concept under

Article 101(1) TFEU in terms of the orthodox approach, in cases that go on appeal to the GC or as preliminary references to the CJEU.

Page 29: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 28

1.1. The object criterion: an overview

As is clear from the text of Article 101(1) TFEU, the provision prohibits agreements

or concerted practices that have either as their ‘object’ or their ‘effect’ the

‘restriction of competition’.2 A close association between object and effect can

therefore be assumed. They are distinct legal terms, however, and the significance

and the consequences of this distinction have not always been clearly or accurately

portrayed. This is due, in part, to the tendency in the past for ‘object’ and ‘effect’

to be referred to collectively not separately in both legal texts and court

judgments.3 The importance of the distinction regained prominence following the

General Court’s (GC) judgment in GSK. The court was widely criticised for blurring

the line between the object and effect analysis and misinterpreting the distinction

between the concepts.4

When determining whether an agreement restricts competition under Article

101(1) TFEU, ‘object’ expresses a true alternative to ‘effect’ and as such requires

separate consideration.5 This principle was established in Société Technique

Minière v Maschinenbau Ulm (STM).6 The European Court of Justice (CJEU) held

that the object of an agreement should be assessed first. Where it is not clear that

2 For the purposes of this thesis, reference to ‘agreement’ is in its widest sense, including concerted

practices and gentlemen’s agreements. 3 See, for example, (Slot & Johnston, 2006), p59; (Bellamy & Child, 2008), 2.096. The CJEU has often

referred to both concepts together in its judgments when deciding whether or not there has been a ‘restriction of competition’, see for example Case C-5/69 Franz Völk v SPRL Ets J Vervaecke [1969] ECR 295; Case C-28/77 Tepea BV v Commission [1978] ECR 1391; Case C-31/80 L’Oréal NV and L’Oréal SV v De Nieuwe AMCK PVBA [1980] ECR 3775; Case C-61/80 Cöoperatieve Stremsell-en Kleurselfabriek v Commission [1981] ECR 811; Case C-107/82 AEG-Telefunken v Commission [1983] ECR 3151. The distinction between ‘object’ and ‘effect’ is considered in greater detail in the following chapters. 4 Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline Services v Commission [2006] ECR II-2969 (GSK). There the GC held

that the object of the agreement was not to restrict competition despite the involvement of an admitted restriction of parallel trade, usually seen as a ‘hardcore’ restriction and thus automatically anticompetitive by object. 5 (Bellamy & Child, 2008), para 2.096. In the Italian version of the text of the Treaty it referred to

object and effect being cumulative by stating the “object and effect”. The Court of Justice in Case C-219/95P Ferrière Nord v Commission [1997] ECR I-4411 rejected this interpretation and confirmed the text ‘object or effect’ was disjunctive. Both elements do not need to be proved in order to establish a restriction of competition. Goyder says that only if the purpose of the agreement does not appear to restrict competition is it necessary to consider the effects: (Goyder & Albors-Llorens, 2009), p118. 6 C-56/65 Société Technique Minière V Maschinenbau Ulm [1966] ECR 235.

Page 30: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 29

the object of an agreement is to restrict competition, then the effect of an

agreement should be considered.7 Moreover, the courts have repeatedly held that

once it has been shown that the object of an agreement is to restrict competition,

‘there is no need to take account of the concrete effects of an agreement’.8 This

distinction is crucial. Having found that the object is to restrict competition, the

assessment under Article 101(1) TFEU can end there. The object criterion clearly

has the scope to be an incredibly useful tool, as to determine the actual effects of

an agreement on competition demands a higher, and thus more intensive and

costly, level of economic and market analysis. The rationale behind this principle is

contentious, as the court, having established the principle in Consten & Grundig,

never clarified the reasoning that underpinned its statement.9 However the

principle has arguably led to the rationalisation of the orthodox approach described

below.

2. The orthodox approach

2.1. Restrictions that ‘by their very nature’ distort competition

The orthodox approach to the object criterion contends that a narrow category of

“serious” agreements, “by their very nature” restrict competition by object due to

their known ‘necessary effect’.10 Such agreements involve an “obvious” restriction

of competition.11 They automatically restrict competition as the case law dictates

that satisfying the object criterion does not require actual restrictive effects on

competition to be determined and, according to the Commission, experience tells

us particular restrictions will harm competition (that is, an agreement’s ‘necessary

7 Ibid, 249.

8 Joined Cases 56 and 58/64 Consten and Grundig v Commission [1966] ECR 299 (Consten &

Grundig). 9 Ibid.

10 Necessary effect also known as ‘necessary consequence’ or ‘prior belief’ refers to the known

anticompetitive effects of particular agreements in view of their “nature”: (Goyder, 2011), II. See also Article 81(3) Guidelines paras 20-23; (Whish, 2009), pp116-122 citing the General Court’s judgment in ENS to support the contention that object restrictions are “particularly pernicious” and infra section 2.1.1. 11

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p121 referencing ENS.

Page 31: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 30

effect’) regardless of the subjective intention of the parties.12 The main premise of

the orthodox approach therefore rests on the categorisation or classification of

particular restrictions of competition, which can then be automatically condemned

as restrictions of competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU.13 That particular

restrictions of competition are presumed anticompetitive by object under Article

101(1) TFEU is an important element of this perception of the law.14 Evidently this

interpretation elicits parallels with the US per se offence.15 There is one obvious

distinction however.16 Unlike US antitrust law, an infringement of Article 101(1)

TFEU by object can potentially be exempted under Article 101(3) TFEU.17

Under the orthodox approach, the identification of those types of restriction falling

within the impugned category is of crucial significance.18 Whish & Bailey identify a

number of such restrictions within their so-called ‘object box’. This includes, price

fixing, market sharing, output limitation, collective exclusive dealing, imposing

minimum or fixed resale prices and the imposition of export bans.19 These

restrictions of competition are synonymous with what the Commission refers to

“hardcore restrictions” in its Guidelines and Regulations.20 As such, the application

of the orthodox approach is apparently straightforward: merely proving the

existence of the agreement is all that is required. A competition authority is “not

required to prove any economic (or other) evidence of likely anticompetitive harm.

It is sufficient to demonstrate that the agreement fits into the object category and

hence breaches Article 101(1) TFEU”.21 Determining the contents of the object

12

Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 20-23. 13

(King, 2011), p269; (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p117. 14

See eg (Bennett & Collins, 2010), p313. 15

Section 1 of the Sherman Act 1890. See (Jones, 2010), pp658-660. Also, Case T-148/89 Tréfilunion v Commission (Welded Steel Mesh) [1995] ECR II-1063. 16

As designated under s.1 Sherman Act; Standard Oil Co (NJ) v United States (1911) 221 US 1. 17

See generally (Jones, 2006). 18

(Bennett & Collins, 2010), pp312-314. 19

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p124. 20

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 23. 21

(Bennett & Collins, 2010), p314.

Page 32: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 31

category is of vital importance as such agreements carry the presumption of

harm.22

2.1.1. Necessary effect

The concept of necessary effect is important as it is intrinsically linked to the idea of

legal presumptions of harmful effects under the object heading.23 Necessary effect

is based on the assertion that under the object heading the concrete effects of an

agreement do not need to be considered, as certain restrictions of competition

automatically infringe Article 101(1) TFEU due to their known negative effects on

competition.24 This is derived from experience. As such, there is a presumption of

anti-competitiveness as agreements have the inevitable consequence of restricting

competition.25 Presumptions of harm play a key role within the orthodox approach

and the desire to make comparisons with the US is therefore understandable.

2.1.2. US per se offence

Under the Sherman Act 1890, the American antitrust law system makes

unequivocal use of presumptions in its set of ‘per se rules’. These rules allow the

US courts to rule on the illegality of certain practices, which prima facie satisfy the

conditions required by such rules without recourse to a detailed examination of all

the relevant facts.26 Kolstad submits that the per se rules are developed on the

basis of experience the Supreme Court has gleaned from its case law and that

covered practices are presumed illegal because of their pernicious effect on

22

Ibid, p314. 23

Also referred to as ‘necessary consequence’ or ‘prior belief’. 24

(Odudu, 2001), ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): the Object Requirement Revisited’, p384. See also (Black, 2005), p118; AG Trstenjak’s Opinions in BIDS and GSK and (Goyder, 2011), I-II. Such restrictions include, price fixing, market sharing etc. See also (Odudu, 2001), ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): Object as Subjective Intention’, pp60-75 (though Odudu does not support this proposition in his paper, he defines the orthodox approach in terms that ‘object’ means ‘necessary effect’); (Jones, 2006), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p691; (King, 2011), p270. Necessary effect is based on the idea of past experience: AG Mazák’s opinion, Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre Dermo-Cosmétique SAS v Président de l’Autorité de la concurrence [2011] ECR I-9419, para 27; Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 21. Justifications for necessary effect are also found in (Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), paras 4.12-4.17. Though much of their analysis is erroneously based on the Commission’s Article 81(3) Guidelines. 25

(Odudu, 2009); AG Kokott, T-Mobile, para 43. 26

(Svetlicinii, 2008), p122(C).

Page 33: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 32

competition.27 Moreover, where there is a per se infringement the parties cannot

then argue that their agreement does not restrict competition.28 This is because,

US law has determined that, by law, a small, limited category of agreements

automatically restrict competition and the parties cannot argue the contrary.29 As

such all that the claimant need prove is that the prohibited practice occurred.

Alongside numerous other commentators, Whish & Bailey find that there is “clearly

an analogy” between the object concept and s.1 of the Sherman Act.30 They also

note, however, the important distinction between the US and EU legal systems,

namely that even if “[an agreement] infringes Article 101(1) TFEU per se, the parties

can still argue that the agreement satisfies the terms of Article 101(3) TFEU”.31 This

possibility is not available under US law.

2.2. Case law

Many commentators continue to subscribe to the understanding of the law on the

object criterion described here as the orthodox approach.32 Chapter 2 subjects the

case law to a detailed critical legal analysis in order to determine more precisely the

law on the object criterion. For the purposes of this chapter, however, this section

provides a brief description of the case law that supports the orthodox approach in

order to illustrate the European Courts’ contribution to the development of the

orthodox approach.33

The clearest embodiment of the orthodox approach is found in European Night

Services (ENS).34 The influence of the GC’s judgment in ENS on the legal

interpretation of the object concept under Article 101(1) TFEU is profound and is

consistently cited as authority for the proposition that the object concept operates

27

(Kolstad, 2009), p5. 28

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p121. 29

(Bailey, 2010), p364, II, 2. 30

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p121. 31

Ibid. 32

See Introduction, section 2. 33

Chapter 2 will therefore highlight those cases that not only support the orthodox approach, but also embody aspects that are pertinent to the other approaches to the object criterion identified in this thesis. 34

Case T-374/94, European Night Services and Others v Commission, [1998] ECR II-3141.

Page 34: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 33

in terms of an object box.35 Even though the case concerned the establishment of a

joint venture and proof of its effects on competition, the GC’s observation on the

object criterion has had lasting implications. The GC found that where an

agreement contained “obvious” restrictions of competition such as price fixing,

market-sharing or the control of outlets, then no economic analysis is required in

terms of assessing the legal and economic context, the structure of the market or

the actual conditions in which the agreement functions.36 This followed similar

judgments in Tréfilunion v Commission and Montedipe SpA v Commission.37 In

Tréfilunion, the GC held that as the case involved a “clear” infringement of Article

101(1) TFEU in particular involving subparagraphs (a) to (c) it “...it must be regarded

as an infringement per se of the competition rules”.38 The GC cited Montepide v

Commission in support of its statement, which articulated the same sentiment.39

Consequently the GC’s approach in Tréfilunion and ENS creates a clear analytical

distinction between object and effect analyses: the former relies solely on whether

the restriction of competition is ‘obvious’; all economic analysis is reserved for the

effects analysis. It is not difficult to see why these cases have been so persuasive

given the attraction of legal bright lines and the associated lowering of the

administrative burden on competition authorities.40

The judgment of the CJEU in Sumitomo v Commission helped confirm the sentiment

that certain types of agreement “in themselves pursue an object restrictive of

competition and fall within a category of agreements expressly prohibited by Article

[101(1) TFEU]”.41 Furthermore “that object cannot be justified by an analysis of the

economic context of the anti-competitive conduct concerned”.42 Hence, the

35

Most prominently in (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p120-121. Though interestingly it is not cited in the Article 81(3) Guidelines. 36

ENS, para 136. See chapter 2 for a more in-depth critique. 37

Case T-148/89 Tréfilunion v Commission [1995] ECR II-1063, para 109; T-14/89 Montepide SpA v Commission [1992] ECR II-1155, para 265. 38

Ibid, Tréfilunion para 109. 39

T-14/89 Montepide, para 265. 40

See generally, (Bennett & Collins, 2010). 41

C-403 & 405/04P Sumitomo v Commission, [2007] ECR I-00729, paras 42-45, 43. 42

Ibid, para 43.

Page 35: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 34

absence of effects of an agreement is of no consequence for a finding by object.43

This builds on the understanding that the actual effects of an agreement do not

require proof in order to determine whether it restricts competition by object.

Finally, in BIDS, the description attributed by the CJEU to the distinction between

object and effect was said to arise “from the fact that certain forms of collusion

between undertakings can be regarded, by their very nature, as being injurious to

the proper functioning of normal competition”.44 This statement was then

replicated in T-Mobile.45 This proclamation tallies with the orthodox approach as it

suggests that there is a category of agreements that automatically restrict

competition by object.

These cases seemingly endorse the understanding advocated under the orthodox

approach; that a particular category of agreements, nominally those contained

within Article 101(1) (a) to (c) TFEU, automatically restrict competition by virtue of

their object regardless of their effects. To determine the object merely requires the

identification of such a restriction within the agreement or concerted practice.

2.3. The Commission

Perhaps the clearest endorsement of the orthodox approach comes from the

Commission.46 The Commission’s interpretation and application of the object

concept to agreements can be discerned through its Guidelines, its Block Exemption

Regulations (BERs) and its decisions. This section involves a particular focus on the

Article 81(3) Guidelines, which following modernisation set out the Commission’s

primary interpretation of Article 101 TFEU.47 The following paragraphs will also

43

Ibid, para 43. 44

Case C-209/07 Competition Authority v Beef Industry Development Society Ltd and Barry Brothers (Carrigmore) Meats Ltd (BIDS) [2008] All ER (D) 235, para 17. 45

Case C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands BV v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit [2009] ECR I-4529 (T-Mobile), para 29. 46

See (Jones, 2010) ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p654. 47

Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty, OJ [2004] C101/9, paras 20-23 (Article 81(3) Guidelines). These were issued in conjunction with the Commission’s modernisation package. For a contemporaneous critique see (Lugard & Hancher, 2004).

Page 36: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 35

reflect on the question of whether the Commission has deviated from the position

set out in its Article 81(3) Guidelines.

2.3.1. Guidelines and BER’s: soft law and policy

Technically, the Commission’s guidelines are not law, nor are they binding on

Member States. There is a legitimate expectation, however, that the Commission

will follow its own guidance.48 Goyder agrees that the guidelines should be viewed

as guidance only as they bind no one except the Commission.49 That the guidelines

in fact take on a more meaningful and significant role is highlighted by the

Commission itself. In the Article 81(3) Guidelines, it is stated that the purpose of

the guidelines is to “set out the Commission’s view of the substantive assessment

criteria applied to the various types of agreements and practices”.50 It is stated

further that they provide “guidance to the courts and authorities of the Member

States in their application of Article 101(1) and (3)”.51 Additionally it is asserted that

“the...guidelines outline the current state of the case law of the Court of Justice’

and set out the Commission’s policy with regard to issues that have not been dealt

with in the case law”.52

Given the Commission’s primary role as enforcer of the competition rules, the fact

that the various Guidelines it issues are not law in its truest sense is irrelevant on a

practical level: the Guidelines demand to be taken seriously.53 What is more, the

guidelines tend to blur the line between law and policy. It is submitted that the

division between policy initiatives and the law (as determined by the European

Courts) has become almost indeterminate for practical purposes within the context

of such guidelines. Therefore the presentation of the law set out in the guidelines is

48

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 4; noted in Case C-226/11 Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence, nyr. 49

(Goyder, 2011), p12 VI. 50

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 3. 51

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 4. 52

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 7. 53

See generally (Stefan, 2008); (Cosma & Whish, 2003). NCA’s and businesses rely on the Article 81(3) Guidelines as demonstrated in numerous NCA decisions and submissions to the European Courts, such as in BIDS, (supra n44). Furthermore there is a legitimate expectation the Commission will follow their guidelines, see Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 4-7. See also AG Kokott’s Opinion of 6 September 2012 in Expedia, supra n48.

Page 37: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 36

often seen to be an accurate reflection of the law, rather than as a combination of

the Commission’s policies together with its subjective interpretation of the case

law.

The premise of the Commission’s approach to the object criterion, as set out in the

Article 81(3) Guidelines, is straightforward: certain restrictions are “by their very

nature” presumed to have the potential to restrict competition by virtue of their

object regardless of their actual or potential effects.54 The Commission claims, as it

provides no judicial support for its reasoning, that this is because of the serious

nature of such restrictions, and the high potential of negative effects on

competition arising from such restrictions based on experience, which allows the

Commission to predict which restrictions will, or are likely to, harm competition.55

As discussed, this “experience” or knowledge that certain agreements harm, or

have the potential to restrict, competition is known as the ‘necessary effect’ of an

agreement.56 According to the Commission, ‘hardcore restrictions’ are synonymous

with restrictions by object.57

The Article 81(3) Guidelines confirm that actual or concrete effects do not need to

be demonstrated where an agreement has a restriction of competition as its

object.58 The Commission references its BERs, guidelines and notices as providing

non-exhaustive guidance on what constitutes restrictions by object.59 These are

typically those restrictions that are black-listed in BER’s or identified as “hardcore”

54

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 21. How this is reconciled with the Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2010] paras 60-64 is questionable. See also Horizontal Cooperation Guidelines, para 24. 55

Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 20-23; (Whish & Bailey, 2012), pp116-122 and cf (Odudu, 2001), ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): Object as Subjective Intention’. 56

(Black, 2005), p119. 57

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 23. See also Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2010], paras 47-64. Note that the Commission allows for some hardcore restraints to fall outside of Article 101(1) TFEU in exceptional circumstances if they are “objectively necessary”, para 60. For instance, if such a hardcore restriction is objectively necessary to ensure a public ban on selling dangerous drugs or where a distributor is making substantial investments in order to gain entry in a new market. The reference to paragraph 18 of the Article 81(3) Guidelines in support of this is curious as upon its reading it appears to only be relevant to restrictions by effect. See commentary on the revised De Minimis Guidelines below. However, the Vertical Guidelines [2010], para 96, suggest that the object criterion is not just limited to hardcore restrictions. 58

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 20. 59

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 23.

Page 38: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 37

in guidelines and notices.60 Such restrictions are therefore presumed to restrict

competition by object.61 It is notable that the Commission reserves to itself the

ability to expand upon the types of restrictions that constitute restrictions by

object.62

The question of how the object of an agreement is in fact determined is recounted

in paragraph 22. According to the Commission whether an agreement has as its

object the restriction of competition rests on a “number of factors”.63 These

“include” the content of the agreement and objective aims pursued by it. It “may

also be necessary to consider the context in which it is (to be) applied and the

actual conduct and behaviour of the parties on the market”.64 It could be deduced

from a reading of the Article 81(3) Guidelines that it is merely optional that the

context of the agreement is considered when determining the object of an

agreement. Additionally, that the context referred to is the ‘legal and economic’

context is not specifically revealed.65

Furthermore, the Commission provides that an examination of the facts underlying

the agreement “may” be required, and that the implementation of the agreement

is more persuasive than the formal agreement, which may not even contain an

express restriction of competition.66 The ease with which the object of an

agreement is found is confirmed by the fact that identifying a ‘hardcore’ restriction

in an agreement labels it automatically as a restriction by object.67 All efforts are

therefore seemingly directed towards identifying restrictions by object in an

60

Ibid. 61

Ibid. 62

Ibid, para 21. The Commission has not been reticent in expanding the category of hardcore restrictions, see for instance its decision in Lundbeck Case No. 39226. 63

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 22. 64

Ibid, emphasis added. References to Joined Cases 29 & 30/83 CRAM and Rheinzink v Commission [1984] ECR 1679 and Joined Cases C-96/82 and others ANSEAU-NAVEWA [1983] ECR 3369 are cited as authority for this proposition. See chapter 2 for a discussion on whether the Article 81(3) Guidelines accurately represent these judgments. 65

As will be demonstrated in chapter 2, this is a fundamental aspect of the application of the object criterion, which is not optional. 66

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 22. The subjective intention of the parties to restrict competition is evidence, but not a necessary condition. 67

Ibid, para 23: “Non-exhaustive guidance on what constitutes restrictions by object”. The same applies to those restrictions that are “blacklisted” in BERs.

Page 39: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 38

agreement, not assessing the agreement itself to determine its object. It can be

readily inferred that an economic analysis of an agreement is not a requirement.

Moreover there is no hint of a suggestion that the presumption that a particular

agreement restricts competition by object is rebuttable within the context of Article

101(1) TFEU.

This understanding of the law has been extremely pervasive throughout the EU.68

Intriguingly the Article 81(3) Guidelines do not reference ENS, though they clearly

draw heavily from it. It can be surmised, therefore, that the Article 81(3) Guidelines

follow the orthodox approach or indeed that the orthodox approach follows the

Commission’s perception of the object criterion.

Other Guidelines and BER’s tend to uphold how the Commission recounts the law

and its policy on the object concept within its Article 81(3) Guidelines.69 As such

the focus is on the categorisation of restrictions whether labelled as hardcore or

blacklisted in BER’s. Consequently, the presumption is that such restrictions fall

foul of Article 101(1) TFEU by virtue of their object and are unlikely to benefit from

an exemption under Article 101(3) TFEU.70 Perhaps importantly, there has been a

subtle shift in some of the Guidelines published subsequent to the Article 81(3)

Guidelines in relation to the necessity of the application of the ‘context’ of an

agreement when determining an agreement’s object.71

68

It is submitted that there has been an over-reliance on cases such as ENS, which arguably form the backbone of the Article 81(3) Guidelines. 69

See eg Commission Regulation 330/2010 on the application of Article 101(3) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to categories of vertical agreements and concerted practices [2010] OJ L 102, 1-7; Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2010] C 130/01 (Guidelines on Vertical Restraints); Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer agreements [2004] OJ C 101 2-42, para 14 (Technology Transfer Guidelines); Horizontal Guidelines on the applicability of Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to horizontal co-operation agreements [2011] OJ C 11, 1 para 74 (Horizontal Guidelines). 70

See eg Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2010], para 47. 71

See eg Horizontal Guidelines, paras 25 and 72-74. Though an agreement’s ‘context’ was ignored in the Technology Transfer Guidelines. See also Guidance on restrictions of competition by object for the purpose of defining which agreements may benefit from the De Minimis Notice, July 2014. The de minimis doctrine will be examined in subsequent chapters.

Page 40: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 39

2.3.2. Decisions, submissions and speeches

It is clearly also important to assess how far the Commission follows its own Article

81(3) Guidelines in its decision-making. Despite the straightforward nature of the

Article 81(3) Guidelines, a cursory review of the Commission’s decisional practice

reveals a diverse approach to its practical application of the object criterion.

Certainly, the Commission has generally employed a formalistic or ‘forms-based’

approach to the object criterion. Indeed, it has often been criticised on precisely

this ground.72 The orthodox approach is formalistic as it does not demand an

economic or market analysis of the agreement to determine if the impugned course

of conduct generates actual or potential anticompetitive effects. Rather, the formal

features of the agreement are given a cursory review and the Commission would

then infer that the agreement, by its nature, is restrictive of competition by object.

The Article 81(3) Guidelines promote a forms-based approach by linking the

identification of hardcore restrictions with restrictions by object.73

An example of the Commission applying its Article 81(3) Guidelines in this manner is

shown in the GlaxoSmithKline decision.74 It considered that as the Community

Courts have consistently found that agreements containing dual pricing systems or

other limitations of parallel trade, which are identified by the Commission as

hardcore restraints, as restrictions by object it was justified in coming to the same

conclusion.75 A more interesting aspect of the decision is that despite

72

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p649. Though it is notable that in many of its decisions the Commission usually provides a detailed account of the parties, the market, market shares and the nature of the restraints before undertaking the legal assessment. 73

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 23. 74

GlaxoSmithKline 2001/791/EC (GlaxoSmithKline) subsequently appealed to the CJEU. Similarly in Commission decision IV/30.658 Polistil/Arbois (1984), paras 37-49 the Commission decided that the absolute territorial protection (ATP) clause and limits on commercial freedom to set prices were automatically restrictive by object. In this case the Commission did not feel compelled to assess actual effects. See also Commission decision Seamless Steel Tubes [2003] OJ L140/1, which found a market sharing agreement to be restrictive by object. Here too the Commission did not describe the agreement’s restrictive effects. 75

Ibid, GlaxoSmithKline, para 124. The Commission was subsequently criticised by the GC for this inference in Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline v Commission. See (Bailey, 2012), pp573-576.

Page 41: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 40

acknowledging the fact an assessment of the actual effects of the agreements was

not then required, “for the sake of completeness” it conducted such an analysis.76

There are also, however, a number of notable deviations from this standard mode

of applying the Article 81(3) Guidelines. Examples can be seen in the Visa and

Mastercard multilateral interchange fee (MIF) decisions.77 The agreements fixed

the MIF paid by acquiring banks on each cross-border Visa/Mastercard transaction.

On their face, the agreements arguably did not involve a clear and obvious

‘hardcore’ restriction of competition by object, despite the potential nature of the

restriction concerned, namely horizontal price fixing. Additionally, the cases

demonstrate identical situations of fact, but the Commission uses two diametrically

opposed approaches to the object criterion.78 On the basis of the Article 81(3)

Guidelines, however, the agreements should automatically be seen as having the

object of restricting competition as they concerned what is, in essence, a hardcore

restriction. In Visa, which admittedly was decided prior to publication of the Article

81(3) Guidelines, the Commission concluded that the MIF in the Visa system did not

have the object of restricting competition under Article 101(1) TFEU by virtue of its

pro-competitive attributes.79 Instead, the MIF amounted to an appreciable

76

Ibid, para 125. This questions the value of arguments relating to administrative cost savings when utilising the orthodox approach. In the past the Commission has also found agreements restrict competition by virtue of both their object and effect. See Commission decision Fine art auction houses, IP/02/1585, COMP/E-2/37.784. In Commission decision IAZ/Anseau, IV/29.995 [1982] OJ L167/39 the Commission also looked at the “purpose or effect” of the agreement and in doing so examined the terms and purpose of the agreement, the impact of the agreement in its context and its effects. The Commission often considers the ‘effect’ of an agreement despite a finding that an agreement is restrictive by object. See eg, Commission Decision 86/398/EEC Polypropylene, [1986] OJ L230/1, paras 89 and 90 where the Commission produces evidence of appreciable concrete effects despite finding the concerted practice restricted competition by object and that it was unnecessary to demonstrate such an effect. This can be contrasted with the OFT’s decisional practice, where is does not see the need to subsequently assess the actual effect of an agreement once the object is determined: for example the OFT’s decision of 20 November 2006, ‘Exchange of information of future fees by certain independent fee-paying schools’, Case CE/2890-03. Here the OFT set out its orthodox understanding of the object criterion (paras 1348-1350 and 1387-1388) and, having found the object of the agreement was to restrict competition, specifically stated it made no finding as to the agreement’s effect (para 1388). 77

2002/914/EC Visa International – Multilateral Interchange Fee, [2002] OJ L318/17 (Visa) and COMP/34.579 Europay (Eurocard-MasterCard) [2009] OJ C264/8, 19 December 2007 (Mastercard). Both decisions were appealed. 78

Also noted by (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p665. 79

The Article 81(3) Guidelines were based on already established principles, as demonstrated in the previous version of the Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, OJ C291, 13.10.2000. See to that effect the

Page 42: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 41

restriction of competition by effect, but fulfilled the conditions for an exemption

under Article 101(3) TFEU. Such an exemption was granted despite the Commission

finding that the MIF restricted the freedom of the banks individually to decide their

own pricing policies thereby distorting the conditions of competition on the Visa

issuing and acquiring markets.80 In its reasoning the Commission found that the

MIF was not a restriction of competition by object as the “objective” of the MIF

was:

“To increase the stability and efficiency of operation of that system and indirectly to strengthen competition between payment systems by thus allowing four-party systems to compete more effectively with three-party systems.”81

Regrettably the Commission did not expand further in its analysis of the object of

the agreement. Nonetheless, what is clear is that in this case the pro-competitive

nature of the agreement trumped the fact that the banks were unable freely to

determine their own pricing policies. Even if the Commission was only focusing on

the objective aim of the agreement it would not be irrational to assume that in line

with the Article 81(3) Guidelines it should have found the object of the agreement

was to restrict competition.82 Therefore, the question of the Commission’s

discretion is of relevance as is the impact of such decision-making on legal

certainty.

Conversely in the case of Mastercard the Commission was far more detailed in its

assessment of the object of the agreement, but took a different approach

ostensibly more in-keeping with the Article 81(3) Guidelines.83 Despite

acknowledging its finding in Visa, the Commission added that the concept of a

restriction by object:

accompanying Commission press release of 24 May 2000, which advocated a more economic policy approach as part of the Commission’s modernisation review. 80

Visa 2002/914/EC, para 64. 81

Ibid, para 69. 82

Particularly as the Commission also recognises that restrictions by object can also be achieved by indirect means: see the Vertical Guidelines (1999 and 2010). 83

Supra n77, Mastercard, paras 403-407. Note that the decision was handed down post the GC’s judgment in Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline.

Page 43: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 42

“does not presuppose that the parties to an agreement have the subjective intention of restricting competition. Agreements can be restrictive by object even if the parties to it are able to show that restricting competition was not their (primary) aim, or that they had other laudable motives.”84

Notably, it also rejected the idea of taking the positive attributes of an agreement

into account in such assessment.85 Instead, the Commission argued that such pro-

competitive aims and effects should be considered under Article 101(3) TFEU.86

The Commission seemingly reinforced its position in the Article 81(3) Guidelines by

finding that for an agreement to fall into the category of restrictions by object it

“suffices that an agreement has by its very nature the potential for restricting

competition, for instance, that it has the obvious consequence of fixing prices”.87

Yet, despite these pronouncements the Commission still goes on to determine the

actual effects of the MIF in order to ascertain if it “by its very nature” had the

potential of fixing prices.88 Even though it concluded that the MIF has the

consequence of fixing the fees charged by acquirers to merchants and thus acts like

a minimum price recommendation for transactions on a domestic level, the

Commission decided it was “not necessary to reach a definite conclusion as to

whether the MasterCard MIF is a restriction of object” as it had been established

that the MIF had the effect of appreciably restricting competition.89 This conclusion

is baffling as the logical path would have been to find a restriction by object,

particularly given the wide discretion that the Commission allows itself in its Article

81(3) Guidelines to expand the category of hardcore restrictions if necessary.

Moreover the Article 81(3) Guidelines specifically underline how the effects of an

agreement do not need to be proven if the object is to restrict competition.90

84

Ibid, Mastercard, para 402, citing Joined Cases C-96/82 and others IAZ/ANSEAU, ECR 3369. 85

Supra n77, Mastercard, para 402: citing Cases T-374/94 etc European Night Services v Commission [1998] ECR II-3141, para 136 and Case C-19/77 Miller International Schallplatten v Commission [1978] ECR 131. Arguably this turnabout was as a result of a change in commercial climate. 86

Supra n77, Mastercard, para 402. 87

Supra n77, Mastercard, para 403, citing its Article 81(3) Guidelines and supra n85 C-19/77 Miller International. 88

Supra n77, Mastercard, para 405, see also paras 408-665. See also (Bailey, 2012), p584-585. 89

Supra n77, Mastercard, para 407. 90

Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 20 and 21.

Page 44: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 43

A further example of a decision by the Commission, where it does not specifically

follow the application of the object criterion set out in the Article 81(3) Guidelines,

is that of Lundbeck.91 The decision reflects a careful, more analytical application of

the object criterion by the Commission, which is in direct contrast to the formalistic

position advocated by the orthodox approach.92 The Commission found that

reverse payment settlements (also known as ‘pay-for-delay’ patent settlement

agreements) that Lundbeck entered into with generic manufacturers to prevent

them from competing with it, whilst certain of its manufacturing processes

remained patent protected, infringed Article 101(1) TFEU by object. Lundbeck was

heavily fined as a result.

This development has caused much surprise within the legal community as such

arrangements had never been found in the past to contravene Article 101(1) TFEU

by object. Furthermore, the decision caused alarm as it indicated that the

Commission had expanded the object box as a means to ensure it could condemn

practices using a lower standard of proof. This has also created legal uncertainty.93

As the object concept does not require the actual effects of an agreement to be

proven, the Commission has a far less burdensome task in proving an infringement.

It has therefore been accused of widening the object category in order to condemn

particular agreements rather than risk undertaking an ‘effects’ analysis.94 Many

commentators have not yet seen the text of the decision, however, and therefore

are not aware that in order to condemn the reverse payment settlements the

Commission in fact applied the object concept in a way that supports both the

91

Lundbeck IP/13/563, nyr; http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-13-563_en.htm?locale=en. A confidential version of the decision was seen in order to advise on routes of appeal. The decision is on appeal: Case T-472/13. 92

Lundbeck IP/13/563. Key issues in the appeal may turn on the Commission’s diversion from the Article 81(3) Guidelines, the parties’ legitimate expectations in this regard (as well as its interpretation of the law on the object criterion), and the quality of the evidence used by the Commission to prove the agreement had an anti-competitive object. 93

Newsletters issued by law firms such as Ashurst, Skadden Arps and Baker & Mckenzie argue that the decision marks a shift from the Technology Transfer Guidelines where parties to a settlement agreement are not viewed as competitors where their technologies are in a one-way blocking position. See (Carlin, 2013). 94

See generally (Gerard, 2013).

Page 45: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 44

‘hybrid’ and ‘more analytical’ approaches described in this thesis.95 Certainly, the

assessment of the object criterion was far removed from the application advocated

in the Article 81(3) Guidelines. For the purposes of this thesis, it is the application

of the law rather than the outcome of the decision that is of interest.

These decisions therefore raise the question as to the continued relevance of the

Article 81(3) Guidelines. This is despite the Commission’s subsequent attempts to

rationalise its divergent application of the object criterion in its guidance and new

Guidelines.96 This divergence is also evident in some of its submissions to the CJEU

in preliminary references. For instance, the Commission accepts in the case of BIDS

that regard must be had to the content of the agreement and the legal and

economic context.97 Furthermore, in paragraph 33 of the judgment it concedes

that the concept of object does also apply to restrictions that fall outside the classic

hardcore restrictions. It even recognises that agreements with a legitimate

objective, crisis cartels and restrictions that are not ‘obvious’ can all be regarded as

restrictions of competition by object.98 These aspects of its approach to litigation

are not reflected clearly within the Article 81(3) Guidelines.

Such disconnect between its Article 81(3) Guidelines and the practical application of

the object criterion is also evident in the speech given by Alexander Italianer,

Director General for competition, in 2013, which advocated a more contextual

approach.99 This can be set alongside the revised De Minimis Notice and

accompanying guidance, which at first glance appears to return to a more orthodox

95

However not every aspect of the decision reflects the understanding of the object criterion proposed in the following chapters. For instance, the Commission’s understanding of the relevance of ‘necessary consequence’ bears reflection. The Commission relied heavily on the interpretation of the law by the CJEU in BIDS, whereby each economic operator must be free to independently determine its own commercial policy. 96

See Guidance on restrictions of competition by object for the purposes of defining which agreements may benefit from the De Minimis Notice, 2014, section 1, footnote 10 where the Commission reflects that a restriction of competition by object may in fact come outside Article 101(1) TFEU where it has a legitimate goal or is objectively necessary. See also Vertical Guidelines 2010, paras 60-62 and Horizontal Cooperation Guidelines, para 25. 97

Supra, n44 BIDS, para 23. 98

Ibid. 99

(Italianer, 2013), Fordham, 26 September 2013.

Page 46: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 45

path,100 but in fact the guidance reveals a number of key changes.101 These changes

pertain to the requirement that the legal and economic context “must” be

considered when determining the object of an agreement, and that there are

“exceptional circumstances” where prima facie restrictions by object may come

outside Article 101(1) TFEU if they are objectively necessary or pursue a legitimate

goal.102 Though, the De Minimis Guidance goes further than the Article 81(3)

Guidelines in another respect by stating that when determining if an agreement is

restrictive by object it is unnecessary to demonstrate any actual or potential effects

on the market.103 These aspects are not reflected in the Article 81(3) Guidelines,

despite the Commission’s best efforts to convey the contrary.104

These factors all call into question the influence of the Article 81(3) Guidelines on

the Commission’s own decision-making.105 They also highlight the lack of

consistency in the Commission’s methodology when applying the object criterion

and its evolving framework for applying the object criterion to agreements.106

2.4. Conclusion

This section sought to establish the characteristics of the orthodox approach.

Under the guise of the object box and the Article 81(3) Guidelines the orthodox

approach consists of a narrow category of obvious and serious agreements, which

100

The revised De Minimis Notice relies heavily on the judgment in Expedia, supra n48 which the Commission may come to regret. See chapter 5 for a detailed discussion on the de minimis doctrine. 101

See http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-14-728_en.htm. Notice on agreements of minor

importance which do not appreciably restrict competition under Article 101(1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (De Minimis Notice) OJ 2014/C 291/01; http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/de_minimis_notice_annex.pdf, Guidance on restrictions of competition "by object" for the purpose of defining which agreements may benefit from the De Minimis Notice (De Minimis Guidance), C(2014) 4136 final, 25 June 2014. 102

De Minimis Guidance, 2014, section 1. 103

Ibid, emphasis added. 104

For instance in footnote 10 of the new De Minimis Guidance the Commission references para 18 of the Article 81(3) Guidelines as being the authority for this proposition. Para 18 sets out a descriptive account of how agreements should be assessed under Article 101(1) TFEU. Para 19 of the Article 81(3) Guidelines however suggests that the “analytical framework” set out in para 18 is not applicable to the object criterion and certainly para 22 does not support the application of an “analytical framework”. 105

Contrast this with the obligations on the NCA’s under Regulation 1/2003 to follow the Commission’s rules when determining Article 101 TFEU cases. 106

This could be attributed to a breakdown in its internal communication as it appears the Legal Services division is not always in agreement with DG COMP.

Page 47: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 46

are presumed to restrict competition by object due to their necessary effect. Such

restrictions are labelled as ‘hardcore’ by the Commission. Establishing whether an

agreement restricts competition by object is seemingly straightforward as it

involves, based on the content of the agreement, the identification of those

restrictions set out in the object box or listed as hardcore by the Commission.

Traditionally, there was little place for economic analysis as the negative effects of

such agreements could be presumed.107 This is because such restrictions are taken

automatically to distort competition in view of their serious nature and experience

demonstrating such restrictions are likely to produce negative effects on the

market. It could therefore be assumed that this perception of the law would be

overwhelmingly supported by the jurisprudence given the impact of the orthodox

approach on legal discourse. The orthodox approach continues to have many

followers, though in recent years the more nuanced characteristics of the object

criterion are increasingly acknowledged.108

For instance, the influence of an agreement’s ‘legal and economic context’ is now

seen as a necessary requirement in any assessment of an agreement’s object.109

Though to what end, is not particularly clear. Furthermore, the Commission has

begun to recognise in its more recent guidelines that presumptions of harm under

Article 101(1) TFEU cannot always be absolute.110 These are not the only

anomalies.

3. Problems with the orthodox approach

The Commission’s decisional practice demonstrates that not all restrictions by

object are ‘obvious’ or prima facie pernicious. It is also clear that the Commission

does not always follow its own Guidelines, and has taken the opportunity to expand

107

This is re-enforced by the De Minimis Guidance, section 1. 108

See eg (Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013) and AG Kokott in T-Mobile (supra n45) and Expedia (supra n48) who favour the orthodox approach. 109

“Context” is referred to in the Article 81(3) Guidelines, but not specifically as the ‘legal and economic context’ and it is not seen as a mandatory requirement: para 22. Whish & Bailey endorse the application of the legal and economic context, (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p118. 110

De Minimis Guidance, section 1.

Page 48: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 47

the category of object restraints.111 Even at this juncture the advantage of a limited

category of object restrictions is questionable.112 What is more, judicial support for

the assertion that certain restrictions can be automatically found to constitute

restrictions by object is notably absent within the Article 81(3) Guidelines.113 The

Commission does not therefore seek to prove its categorisation of the object

concept is legally correct by reference to case law. Hence, it could be assumed that

the Commission is citing its policy approach. Having described the orthodox

approach and shown the Commission’s Article 81(3) Guidelines follow it; this

section looks more closely at its perceived problems.

The supposed benefit of the orthodox approach is that it is clear which types of

agreements contain restrictions that have an automatically anti-competitive object

and thus require no analysis of their effects. This is meant to provide undertakings

with a degree of legal certainty, ease the burden on resources and simplify the

process under Article 101(1) TFEU.114 More particularly, the orthodox explanation

of the law does not then expand upon precisely how the object of an agreement is

determined or applied.115 Decisions such as Lundbeck and Visa show that merely

identifying an ‘obvious’ restriction of competition is not enough to taint an

agreement with an anticompetitive object, despite the impression given under the

Article 81(3) Guidelines. This can be contrasted with decisions such as Polistil,

which are faithful to the Article 81(3) Guidelines.116 Consequently, there is no

111

(Goyder, 2011), p2 I, p5 III and p12 VI. Goyder emphasises that the Commission’s power in identifying new object restraints is limited as the category of object restrictions is defined, not by the Commission, but by the CJEU. 112

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p124. 113

The Commission cites no case law for its categorisation of horizontal restraints and references T-62/98 Volkswagen v Commission [2000] ECR II-2707, para 178 (the other being C-279/87 Tipp-Ex GmbH v Commission [1990] ECR I-261), as authority for particular vertical restraints being categorised as restrictions by object. Reading that paragraph does not in fact provide authority for the notion that such vertical restraints always constitute restrictions by object merely that restrictions by object do not require their actual effects to be proved. How the object was determined in that case makes interesting reading as it portrays a more nuanced approach to assessing whether an agreement restricts competition by object in contrast to the Article 81(3) Guidelines: see paras 88-93 of the judgment. 114

See (Bennett & Collins, 2010), p313. See AG Kokott’s Opinion, T-Mobile (supra n45), para 43 and (Bailey, 2012), p567. 115

(Whish, 2009), pp113-122 does not describe in detail precisely how the assessment of object should be carried out. 116

Commission decision IV/30.658 Polistil/Arbois (1984).

Page 49: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 48

consistent approach in the Commission’s own decisional practice as to how the

object criterion will be applied to agreements. Moreover, by adding new

restrictions to the object category, not having previously been found restrictive by

object, undermines the key principal underpinning the orthodox approach.117 It

cannot then be irrefutably stated that experience alone dictates those agreements

that are automatically restrictive by object given their known negative effects on

competition.

Despite the clear benefit of the orthodox approach being that an economic

assessment of an agreement can become superfluous, there is increasing

acknowledgment that some form of analytical component is required in any

determination of whether an agreement restricts competition by object.118 Though

commentators usually limit such instances to when determining whether an

agreement is appreciable, assessing whether it affects trade between Member

States, or deciding the level of fine.119 What is less clearly articulated is the

function of the legal and economic context in this regard, particularly as the

Commission provides scant elucidation in its Article 81(3) Guidelines.120 The

question of whether the orthodox approach over-simplifies the law was brought to

light following judgments in BIDS and T-Mobile due to the way the CJEU expressed

the application of the object criterion.121 Furthermore, the judgments - in

particular the GC’s judgment in GSK - highlighted the importance of the legal and

economic context in any assessment of an agreement’s object. The Commission

has subsequently cited this requirement in its latest Guidelines, Notices and many

of its decisions.122 In practice, it has already been assessing the effects of those

agreements that fall within the object category as demonstrated in its decisions in

117

For instance, new object restrictions were found in Lundbeck and in the Horizontal Co-operation Guidelines for particular types of information exchange. 118

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p120; presentation by Rose on ‘Per se infringements of the competition rules’ at King’s College London (Rose, 24 February 2010). 119

Ibid, (Rose, 24 February 2010); (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p120. 120

As noted by its absence in the Article 81(3) Guidelines. 121

BIDS (supra n44); T-Mobile (supra n45). See (King, 2011). 122

Jones also portrays the limitations of categorisation in the light of the “legal and economic context” requirement, (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, pp663-668.

Page 50: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 49

GSK and Mastercard.123 Such assessment of the effects together with an ill-defined

object category undermines the Article 81(3) Guidelines, and thus also the premise

of the orthodox approach. Ultimately the correctness of the Article 81(3)

Guidelines is powerfully challenged.

An additional concern with the orthodox approach is that it cannot account for a

number of anomalies. For instance, not all agreements falling within the object box

classification have been held consistently to be restrictions by object: neither all

price fixing cases nor all absolute territorial protection cases have been treated as

object cases.124 Instead, some such have been considered as ‘effect’ cases, while

others have been found to fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether.125 As such

not every agreement containing a restriction of competition necessarily has that

object. Additionally, agreements of a type that traditionally lies outside the object

box have been found to be restrictive by object, as was the case in Lundbeck. As

recounted above, the Commission has responded to these anomalies by subtly

altering its latest guidelines and Notices.126 It can be observed, as noted by Gerber

in the past, that modernisation did not just bring about procedural change, but also

substantive change.127 It would appear that the Commission is continuing this

latter practice in relation to the object criterion.

The premise that particular agreements ‘by their very nature’ restrict competition

by object due to their known negative effects, and that they carry a presumption of

harm in consequence is also questionable.128 In its Article 81(3) Guidelines the

Commission provides scant judicial support for its contention that the necessary

effect of an agreement means that certain restrictions are presumed to be

123

Commission Decision GlaxoSmithKline 2001/791/EC; Commission Decision Europay (Eurocard-MasterCard) COMP 34.579 (19 December 2007), para 407. 124

For example, joint selling rights often involve price fixing. See also Commission Decision 2002/914/EC Visa International – Multilateral Interchange Fee, OJ 2002 L318. 125

See chapter 2. Also, inter alia, Case C-309/99 Wouters v Algemene Raad van de Nederlandse Order van Advocaten [2002] ECR I-1577; Case C-262/81 Coditel v Ciné-Vog Films (No.2) [1982] ECR 3381. 126

The same can be said for a number of commentators: see the literature review in the Introduction. 127

(Gerber, 2008). 128

See Horizontal Cooperation Guidelines, para 25.

Page 51: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 50

anticompetitive under Article 101(1) TFEU. Despite its prominent use, the phrase

‘by its nature’ is not defined.129 Indeed, there is no indication whether any such

presumptions of harm are rebuttable within the context of Article 101(1) TFEU.

This in turn questions whether it can be emphatically stated that the meaning,

application and role of the object criterion under the orthodox approach are clear.

The problems identified here would suggest that the object criterion is not as

straightforward as the orthodox approach contends.130 This is exemplified by the

Commission’s failure distinctively to define what is policy and what is law within its

Article 81(3) Guidelines. Policy must play an important role within the Article 81(3)

Guidelines, therefore an unequivocal confirmation regards where the distinction

with the law lies would be welcome.131

Aside from finding that the Commission does not always follow its own Article 81(3)

Guidelines, the above discussion reveals a number of issues that require deeper

reflection. These include: (i) the significance that the Article 81(3) Guidelines lack

detailed, explanatory assessment criteria, in particular the omission of the ‘legal

and economic’ context,132 (ii) the lack of general judicial support and citation, (iii)

the categorisation of restrictions labelled as hardcore or black-listed automatically

constituting restrictions by object,133 (iv) whether restrictions by object must be

appreciable, (v) the fact that any assessment of an agreements’ ‘effect’ for the

purposes of establishing the object of an agreement is superfluous, and (vi) the role

of presumptions.

These aspects are explored in detail in the following chapters. More importantly,

the accuracy of the Article 81(3) Guidelines - and hence the orthodox approach – is

tested against the case law of the European Courts. It will be seen that the

European Courts are also sometimes culpable in fudging the essence of the object

129

See chapter 2. 130

As noted even Whish described the law on the object criterion as “confused and confusing”, (Whish, 2003), pp108-115. 131

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p121. 132

Cf the Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, paras 60-64 which discuss circumstances in which hardcore restrictions may come outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether. 133

Though there is also acknowledgment that such restraints are non-exhaustive leaving open the possibility of future types of by-object restriction being added to the category.

Page 52: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 51

criterion, but that the orthodox approach lacks the legitimacy one would expect to

find from the jurisprudence.

Page 53: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 52

Chapter 2: The case law of the European Courts

Part I: How the European Courts have interpreted the meaning and application of the object criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU: establishing the more analytical approach

1. Introduction

Whether the orthodox approach to the object concept, encapsulated most

prominently within the Commission’s Article 81(3) Guidelines and Whish’s ‘object

box’, comprises a sustainable interpretation has been questioned. Nevertheless,

that approach still permeates much legal discourse and carries great influence. The

argument developed here is that it is also questionable whether the orthodox

approach has ever been a faithful interpretation of the jurisprudence of the

European Courts. This chapter sets out the legal foundations that underpin the

object criterion. It assesses how the European Courts have defined and applied the

object concept over the years.

The aims of Chapter 2 are threefold. First, the case law on the object concept is

mapped out comprehensively, and the reality that the European Courts have in fact

deployed three distinct approaches when determining the object of an agreement

is established. With the ‘orthodox approach’ having been already described, this

chapter identifies the two further approaches used by the Courts, termed the ‘more

analytical approach’ and the ‘hybrid approach’. The second aim is to determine the

essence of the object criterion by focusing on the meaning and application of the

object criterion adopted by the Community Courts. Thirdly, it is confirmed that the

orthodox approach has persistently failed to attract sustained judicial support. This

demonstration provides a basis upon which the Article 81(3) Guidelines can be

critiqued. To this end, the chapter is organised into two parts. Part I focuses on the

more analytical approach and documents the earlier jurisprudence of the European

Courts, whereas Part II is concerned with the advancement of the hybrid approach.

This review of the case law confirms that the concept of object is far more

contested than the Article 81(3) Guidelines suggest. It will illustrate the Courts’

Page 54: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 53

analytical - though at times confusing and unspecific - treatment of the object

concept, which contrasts with the over-simplified per se style approach developed

by the Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines. Hence, in this chapter the

Commission’s interpretation of the notion of a restriction of competition by object

is criticised on account of its adopting, as almost sacrosanct, one narrow view of the

case law.1 It is concluded that, on the contrary the jurisprudence lends far greater

support to a ‘more analytical approach’.

To aid the comparison between the judgments of the CJEU and GC and to help map

the evolution of the concept of object, Part I is divided into three sections. The first

section deals with the CJEU’s early case law up until the inception of the GC in 1989.

This will demonstrate the CJEU’s initial approach to object restrictions, which is still

highly relevant today.2 The second section will examine the CJEU’s application of

the object concept following the inception of the GC up until the judgment in BIDS

(described in Part II).3 This is done to underline the continued prevalence of the

more analytical approach. Finally, the third section looks exclusively at the GC’s

case law. The GC has handed down some of the most incongruent and radical

judgments, which bear a disproportionately significant influence on the

Commission’s interpretation of the law relating to the object criterion.4

1 This is clearly illustrated by its decision in GlaxoSmithKline 2001/791/EC, where the Commission

decided that the object of the agreement was to restrict parallel trade and therefore was automatically prohibited. Conversely, in the ensuing appeal the GC assessed the agreement within its legal and economic context and held that the agreement did not have the object of restricting competition (despite GlaxoSmithKline admitting it intended to restrict parallel trade). See infra section 4.2.1. 2 See eg references to Case C-56/65 Société Technique Minière V Maschinenbau Ulm [1966] ECR 235,

249 (STM) in cases such as Case C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands BV and Others v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit, [2009] ECR I-4529, para 28 (T-Mobile). 3 Case C-209/07 Competition Authority v Beef Industry Development Society Ltd and Barry Brothers

(Carrigmore) Meats Ltd [2008] ECR I-8637 (BIDS). 4 See eg Cases T-374/94 etc European Night Services v Commission [1998] ECR II-3141 (ENS). The GC

has also been viewed as a more specialist competition law court whose judges have greater experience in handling complicated competition law issues: (Wyatt & Dashwood, 2006), p397.

Page 55: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 54

2. Early case law up until the inception of the GC: the European Court of Justice

(1965 – 1989)

The ambiguity and misunderstanding surrounding the concept of object is not

solely attributable to the Commission. The CJEU must also take responsibility. For

example, in this early case law it is possible to count a number of variations of the

definition of ‘object’.5 Furthermore, the CJEU has not been entirely consistent in its

application of object to agreements: it is possible, even during this early stage of

the CJEU’s jurisprudence, to identify two approaches to the assessment of object

under Article 101(1) TFEU. The discrepancy in approach is arguably compounded

by the CJEU’s habit of referring to both ‘object’ and ‘effect’ together when

analysing whether an agreement restricts competition.6 As will be seen, however,

this is because object and effect follow a similar assessment structure. It cannot be

contended therefore that the CJEU introduces the perception of the law in terms of

the classic orthodox approach. Instead, it is possible to discern where the orthodox

approach may have stemmed from, although this is still based on a permutation of

the more analytical approach.

To help illustrate this propensity on the part of the early Court, the following

section is divided into two main parts: those cases where the Court, adopted a

‘more analytical approach’; and those cases in which agreements were held ‘by

their very nature’ to restrict competition.7

5 Including: “precise purpose” (supra n2, STM), “purpose” (Joined cases C-96/82 etc, IAZ v

Commission/ ANSEAU [1983] ECR 3369), “aim” (Joined cases C-29/83, 30/83 CRAM & Rheinzink v Commission [1984] ECR 1679), “intention” (Case C-41/69 ACF Chemiefarma v Commission [1970] ECR 661, Case C-258/78 Nungesser v Commission [1982] ECR 2015), “objective” (Case C-31/80 NV L’Oréal v De Nieuwe AMCK [1980] ECR 3775 (L’Oréal), also arguably Case C-61/80 Cöoperatieve Stremsell-en Kleurselfabriek v Commission [1981] ECR 811) and “objective function” (Case C-250/92 Gøttrup-Klim v Dansk Landbrugs Grovvareselskat AmbA [1994] ECR I-5641 (Gøttrup-Klim), per AG Tesauro, para 16). See chapter 3. 6 See eg Case C-5/69 Franz Völk v SPRL Ets J Vervaucke [1969] ECR 295, Case C-28/77 Tepea BV v

Commission [1978] ECR 1391, Case C-31/80 L’Oréal, Case C-61/80 Cöoperatieve Stremsell-en Kleurselfabriek v Commission, Case C-107/82 AEG-Telefunken v Commission [1983] ECR 3151, C-23/67 Brasserie De Haecht v Wilkin [1967] ECR 407. 7 These headings are not perfect as the CJEU sometimes mixed different approaches when assessing

restrictions by object in its judgments. However, the headings allow the reader to appreciate more readily the basic emerging pattern.

Page 56: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 55

2.1. Agreements that incorporate a ‘more analytical approach’: the need for a

contextual assessment

2.1.1. Establishing the more analytical approach: STM

The CJEU set the bar high in its seminal judgment in Société Technique Minière

(STM) by elucidating how Article 101(1) TFEU should be applied to agreements.8

Despite often being referred to as a case that is pertinent only to restrictions by

‘effect’,9 its influence on the perception of the object criterion is now unparalleled.

This becomes increasingly evident throughout the thesis.10 In this case the CJEU

adopted what this thesis refers to as the ‘more analytical approach’ (the MAAP).

The term ‘analytical approach’ was coined by AG Tesauro in Gøttrup Klim and aptly

summarises the greater analytical component attributed to assessing the object of

an agreement through the consideration of its legal and economic context.11 Given

the significance of STM in revealing a more analytical approach to object cases at

the infancy of the EU’s competition law jurisprudence, it merits separate discussion.

In STM an exclusive right of sale was held to be compatible with Article 101(1)

TFEU. To arrive at this conclusion, the CJEU made some revealing statements about

the interpretation of Article 101(1) TFEU as a whole. The Court considered that in

order for an agreement to be prohibited under Article 101(1) TFEU, it must fulfil

certain conditions depending “less on the legal nature of the agreement than on its

effects…on competition”.12 Therefore, as Article 101(1) TFEU is “based on an

assessment of the effects of an agreement from two angles of economic evaluation

[that of assessing the effects on trade between Member States and its effects on

8 Supra n2, STM.

9 This is largely due to the nature of the restraint in issue, seen more typically as a restriction by

effect. 10

Despite its 50 year age, STM is undisputedly the leading case on restrictions by object, but its status as such was masked for many years, due largely to the unchallenged prominence of the orthodox approach and cases such as ENS (supra n4). STM underlines why cases relevant to the effect criterion may also be highly relevant to understanding the object criterion. Hence the case law reviewed for the purposes of this thesis (not all of which is reported) deals not only with agreements restricting competition by object, but also the general application of Article 101(1) TFEU (and its former incarnations). 11

Supra n5 Gøttrup-Klim, para 16. 12

Supra n2, STM, p248.

Page 57: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 56

competition], it cannot be interpreted as introducing any kind of advance judgment

with regard to a category of agreements determined by their legal nature.”13

Consequently, the prohibition under Article 101(1) “depends on one question

alone, namely whether, taking into account the circumstances of the case, the

agreement, objectively considered, contains the elements constituting the said

prohibition as set out in Article [85](1).”14 It can be deduced from the Court’s

statement that, certainly at this point in time, there were no preconceptions or

presumptions as to the sort of behaviour automatically prohibited under Article

101(1) TFEU by virtue of its object. Moreover, the Court dismisses a form-based

interpretation of the law. It stressed that as object and effect are not cumulative,

but alternative requirements, the first necessary step is for the precise purpose of

the agreement to be considered.15

The judgment in STM sets out a comprehensive test (hereinafter the STM Test) in

which to determine the object of an agreement and prescribes that:

(i) The ‘precise purpose’ of the agreement must be considered.

(ii) The consideration must be in the economic context in which

the agreement is to be applied.16

(iii) Such purpose (interference with competition) must result from

some or all of the actual clauses of the agreement itself.17

(iv) Should this analysis not “reveal the effect on competition to be

sufficiently deleterious, the consequences of the agreement

should then be considered”.18

(v) [When determining the purpose of the agreement] the

competition must be understood within the actual context in

which it would occur in the absence of the agreement in

dispute [the counterfactual].19

(vi) Whether a restriction is prohibited by reason of its object [or

effect], it is appropriate to take account of:

a. the nature and quantity of the products covered by the

agreement,

13

Ibid, p248. 14

Ibid, p248. 15

Ibid, p249. 16

Ibid, p249. 17

Ibid, p249. 18

Ibid, p249. Emphasis added. ‘Consequences’ relates to the ‘effect’ of the agreement. 19

Ibid, p250. This is also relevant for restrictions by effect.

Page 58: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 57

b. the position and importance of the supplier and distributor on

the market for the products concerned,

c. the isolated nature of the disputed agreement or its position

in a series of agreements, and

d. the severity of the clauses intended to protect the restriction

or the opportunities allowed for other commercial

competitors in the same products by way of parallel re-

exportation and importation.20

The first three of these elements comprise the main aspects of the STM Test.

Subsequent judgments have expanded upon these elements over the years and

reveal the object concept to be a nuanced legal provision. STM therefore lays the

foundation for an analytical, economics-based approach towards determining

whether the object of an agreement is to restrict competition. Under this

methodology the standard of proof required to establish if an agreement is

restrictive by object is considerably higher than that of the orthodox approach. The

CJEU is less concerned with identifying types of restriction as infringements by

object per se, but rather in determining the “precise purpose” of the agreement

based on an analysis of the terms of the agreement within its economic context. If

such an assessment reveals a “sufficiently deleterious” effect on competition the

investigation can end there. If not, the “consequences” of the agreement must be

considered to determine if the agreement “in fact” has the effect of restricting

competition “to an appreciable extent”.21

The multi-textured nature of the assessment that the Court demands under the

STM Test, with particular regard to factors pertaining to the market structure, the

position of the parties, the severity of the clauses as well as the use of the

counterfactual is notable. This thesis explores a number of the themes introduced

20

Ibid, p250 21

Ibid, pp249-250. Paragraph 3 of the Operative part of the judgment uses slightly different wording. Here the Court states that when assessing the “consequences” of an agreement (that is, the effects) those consequences must be examined and justify the conclusion that competition is restricted “to an appreciable extent”. It would appear the Court has thereby decided that the actual or concrete effects need be determined only in the context of the analysis of the effect. This is significant as it suggests that the Court recognises that the object criterion carries a lower standard of proof in comparison with restrictions by effect. This can be contrasted with the orthodox approach, which does not account for a contextual analysis and thus makes the standard of proof even lighter.

Page 59: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 58

by the judgment in later chapters, for instance, whether restraints can be ancillary

to a primary pro-competitive purpose.22 At this juncture, however, it is notable

how the Court’s use of wording lends itself to a more fluid dichotomy between

restrictions by object and by effect. For instance, the Court speaks of revealing a

sufficiently deleterious “effect” on competition when determining an agreement’s

object.23 Versions of the judgment in German and French similarly endorse the

English translation of the text. The German version could be directly translated as,

“...if the examination of the provisions do not recognise a sufficient impairment of

competition then the impact of the agreement must be investigated”.24 The French

version likewise states, “If the analysis of these terms do not reveal a sufficient

degree of harm in relation to competition, the effects of the agreement should then

be considered...”.25

What is so interesting about this case is that the Court envisages that object and

effect share a similar analytical effects-based methodology when determining if an

agreement restricts competition. The distinction between object and effect as

envisioned by the Court is that it demands the standard of proof for establishing

the ‘effect’ of an agreement is greater, as the Court requires the actual effect to be

determined. Moreover, such effect must restrict competition to an appreciable

extent. It is therefore arguable that only the potential effects of an agreement

need be found in order to satisfy a finding by object, but that those effects must be

‘sufficiently’ harmful. This is evidently not a precise science and hence the

importance of an agreement’s own context is paramount.

This conclusion is supported by Paul Lasok QC, who considers “that there is one

basic methodology in competition analysis that informs both the object and effect

criteria for identifying an anticompetitive agreement”.26 He notes that the CJEU in

22

See chapters 3 and 4. 23

Supra n2, p249. 24

“Lässt die Prüfung dieser Bestimmungen keine hinreichende Beeinträchtigung des wettbewerbs erkennen, so sind die Auswirkung der Vereinbarung zu untersuchen.” 25

“Qu’au cas cependant au l’analyse des dites clauses ne revelerait pas un degre suffisant de nocivite a l’egard de concurrence, il conviendrait alors d’examiner less effects de l’accord...”. 26

(Lasok QC, 2008), who presented his paper to the Law Society on 8 October 2007.

Page 60: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 59

STM and Consten & Grundig made it clear that the analysis is essentially “free” in

that no assumptions are made about the (anti-)competitive nature of an

arrangement on the basis of the type of agreement.27 The key question is whether

or not “taking into account the circumstances of the case, the agreement,

objectively considered, contains the elements constituting the prohibition set out in

Article 101(1)”.28 He notes further that the exercise is “based on an assessment of

the effects of the agreement”, which is measured by reference to the

counterfactual.29 For Lasok, the object/effect dichotomy “concerns what one looks

at when considering the effect of the agreement on competition”.30 By way of

explanation, he recounts the STM Test, which can be condensed as the following:

based on an analysis of the terms of an agreement within its context, the object of

an agreement determines the potential effects of an agreement, whereas ‘effect’

determines an agreement’s actual effect.31

This position can be contrasted with that of the Article 81(3) Guidelines and its

formalistic approach, which bears little resemblance to this more analytical

understanding of the law. In STM the CJEU makes no mention of obvious or serious

restrictions, nor does it talk about categorising agreements that automatically

restrict competition. Instead, the STM Test places emphasis on determining the

‘precise purpose’ of an agreement; whether the purpose is to restrict

competition.32 Thus, object means purpose. As will be demonstrated below, this

27

Ibid. Joined Cases 56 & 58/64, Etablissements Consten SA and Grundigverkaufs-GmbH v Commission, [1966] ECR 342 (Consten & Grundig). 28

Ibid. 29

Ibid, citing supra n2 STM, 248-250. 30

Ibid. 31

Ibid. Should an analysis of the terms of the agreement reveal a sufficiently deleterious effect on competition bearing in mind its context, the investigation can end there. If not, the “actual effect” of the agreement must be considered. See ft 19, where he notes that in General Motors, para 66, the CJEU found that when determining the object of an agreement “reference may also be made to the ‘aims’ of the agreement...derived from the terms of the agreement and any contextual evidence”. 32

The German text of the judgment calls it “eigentlichen zweck” which translates as the “actual purpose”.

Page 61: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 60

original methodological approach to the object criterion has been subsequently

upheld by numerous judgments and opinions.33

2.1.2. Confirmation of a more analytical approach

Contemporaneous with the judgment in STM, the CJEU in Consten & Grundig

confirmed that the concrete effects of an agreement do not need to be taken into

account once it “appears” that the object of an agreement is to restrict

competition.34 The Court did not expound upon this, though the assertion was

made in the context of whether the pro-competitive effects of an agreement meant

that a restriction will escape the prohibition under Article 101(1) TFEU.35 The CJEU

considered that just because an agreement tends to restrict competition between

distributors of the same make, it does not follow that it automatically escapes the

prohibition because it increases competition between producers. The CJEU decided

that this type of argument is irrelevant, however, because if it “appears” the object

is to restrict competition, the concrete effects do not need to be considered.36

The more analytical approach advocated by STM is supported by the Court when it

says “to arrive at a true representation of the contractual position the contract

must be placed in the economic and legal context in the light of which it was

concluded by the parties”.37 The Court does not thereby imply that certain

agreements are presumed to automatically distort competition by object.38

Nonetheless, the judgment is somewhat incongruous with the sentiments set out in

STM. What is more pertinent is that the CJEU found that the legal and economic

context plays a role in the determination of an agreement’s object. The CJEU thus

33

Though subsequent chapters will show how the emphasis on different elements of the STM Test has shifted over the years, which is why the object concept is seen to be so confusing. 34

Supra n27, Consten & Grundig, p342. 35

Ibid, p342. 36

Ibid, p342. 37

Ibid, p343: “since the agreement thus aims at isolating the French market for Grundig products and maintaining, artificially, for products of a very well-known brand, separate national markets within the Community”. Emphasis added. The goal of preserving the single market was an important aspect of the case and considered as part of the agreement’s legal and economic context. 38

It is possible that the ‘no concrete effects’ rule led to the proposition that object restrictions have ‘necessary effect’, ie: certain restrictions are presumed to have a restrictive effect on competition due to their known anticompetitive effects and thus, by their nature, restrict competition.

Page 62: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 61

builds upon the judgment in STM by referring, not just to the economic, but also to

the legal context. Again, the notion that the object concept is based on the

classification of particular agreements is absent, though the precise delineation of

how the object criterion is applied to agreements is admittedly somewhat vague.

What the judgments in STM and Consten & Grundig attest to, is that the approach

of the European Courts is far more nuanced than the Article 81(3) Guidelines

suggest.

A further series of cases illustrate how the CJEU expands upon and refines aspects

of the STM Test. This can be seen in particular when assessing how it proceeds

when confronted with agreements that, the orthodox approach would

automatically depict as restrictions by object.39 However it is also evident, as aptly

highlighted in STM and Consten & Grundig, that the CJEU has a somewhat

haphazard approach.40 For instance, the Court does not always differentiate

between object and effect despite the clear reference to this requirement in STM.41

Nonetheless, the cases demonstrate how the Court applies an economics-based

approach as opposed to automatically condemning agreements as restrictive by

object per se.42

2.1.2.1. Consideration of market power and market structure

The case of Völk involved an exclusive sales agreement reinforced by absolute

territorial protection (ATP).43 Far from denouncing such an agreement, the Court

held that determining the object or effect of the agreement must be understood by

reference to the “actual circumstances of the agreement”.44 Consequently “even”

39

Such as absolute territorial protection (ATP), price fixing, sharing of markets. See C-5/69 Völk v Vervaecke [1969] ECR 295 (Völk). 40

See eg supra n6 Case C-107/82 AEG-Telefunken v Commission. 41

See for instance supra n5, Joined cases C-96-102 & others/82 IAZ/Anseau where the Court duplicated the analysis by also considering the actual effect of the agreement despite having determined that the object of the agreement was to restrict competition. However, the Court may not always differentiate between the two elements as it recognises that object and effect follow the same basic methodology. 42

See for instance C-5/69 Völk v Vervaecke [1969] ECR 295 (Völk) and Case C-27/87, Louis Erauw-jacquéry Sprl v La Hesbignonne Société Coopérative, [1988] ECR 1999 (Louis Erauw). 43

Ibid, Völk. 44

Ibid, Völk para 5/7.

Page 63: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 62

an agreement containing ATP falls outside Article 101 TFEU when it has “only an

insignificant effect on the markets, taking into account the weak position which the

persons concerned have on the market of the product in question”.45 This endorses

the STM Test as it confirms the importance of context and, that the effect on

competition may not be ‘sufficiently deleterious’ when the parties have a weak

position on the relevant market.

The judgment could be construed to mean that any agreement will not restrict

competition by object if the effect on the market is insignificant. This conclusion is

currently in contention following the CJEU’s judgement in Expedia which has called

into question whether restrictions by object need be appreciable.46 For the

purposes of this section, Völk is an important judgment as it illustrates an economic

rationale behind the competition law rules applicable to both restrictions by object

and by effect. The CJEU does not, however, explain whether those effects need be

concretely proven in respect of the object criterion. The judgment also flags an

important point; to assess the market power of the parties requires a market

definition. It is notable that the Commission chose not to follow this judgment in its

previous and most recent De Minimis Guidelines nor indeed in its Article 81(3)

Guidelines in respect of the object criterion.47

As in Völk, the necessity of a market definition when considering the object of an

agreement was raised in the case of L’Oréal. While this concerned a selective

distribution agreement, which is not typically seen as a restrictive of competition by

object under Article 101(1) TFEU, the judgment is significant.48 It further supports

the requirement of an economic analysis when applying the object criterion. Here,

the Court confirmed the application of the more analytical approach. It held that

whether an agreement is prohibited by reason of the:

45

Ibid, para 5/7. 46

Case C-226/11, Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence, 13 December 2012, nyr. See chapter 5 for an examination of the relationship between the object concept and appreciableness. 47

See chapter 5. Commission Notice on agreements of minor importance that do not appreciably restrict competition under article 81(1) of the Treaty establishing the European Community, OJ 2001 C368/13. These were revised following the judgment in Case C-226/11 Expedia and came into force on 25 June 2014: OJ 2014 C 291/01. 48

C-31/80 NV L’Oréal [1980] ECR 3775.

Page 64: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 63

“...distortion of competition which is its object or effect, it is

necessary to consider the competition within the actual context in

which it would occur in the absence of the agreement in dispute.

To that end, it is appropriate to take into account in particular the

nature and quantity, limited or otherwise, of the products covered

by the agreement, the position and importance of the parties on

the market for the products concerned and the isolated nature of

the disputed agreement or, alternatively, its position in a series of

agreements.”49

This it can be sensibly argued that L’Oréal not only upholds the judgment in STM,

but reaffirms the need for a market definition analysis in every case.50

2.1.2.2. Taking into account the potential effects of an agreement to prove an anti-

competitive purpose: the importance of the economic context

A number of cases that concern the need to assess the market structure in an

object assessment, also draw attention to additional factors that the CJEU reflected

on when contemplating an agreement’s context.

CRAM and Rheinzink reinforces how the focus in any determination of the object of

an agreement centres on uncovering its purpose or aim.51 The CJEU found that:

“...in order to determine whether an agreement has as its object

the restriction of competition, it is not necessary to inquire which

of the two contracting parties took the initiative in inserting any

particular clause or to verify that the parties had a common intent

at the time when the agreement was concluded. It is rather a

question of examining the aims pursued by the agreement as

49

Ibid, para 19. Emphasis added. 50

See also C-262/81 Coditel v Ciné-Vog Films (No.2) [1982] ECR 3381, which assesses exclusive rights under a licence. The CJEU stated that a copyright holder who grants an exclusive right for a specific period is not subject to Article 101 TFEU, unless, “in a given case the manner in which the right is exercised is subject to a situation in the economic or legal sphere the object or effect of which is to restrict the distribution of films or to distort competition within the cinematographic market with regard to its specific characteristics”. 51

C-29&30/83 Compagnie Royal Austrienne des Mines and Rheinzink v Commission [1984] ECR 1679, (CRAM and Rheinzink).

Page 65: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 64

such, in the light of the economic context in which the agreement

is to be applied.”52

This assessment highlights that the subjective intention of the parties is irrelevant

in determining the object of an agreement. It would be easy for parties to argue

that they never intended to restrict competition and thereby excuse their

agreements from the remit of Article 101(1) TFEU. The CJEU gives short shrift to

such arguments. Instead, the aim or purpose of the agreement based on the

objective content of the agreement and viewed in the light of its legal and

economic context is the crucial test.

This position is also reflected in ACF Chemiefarma v Commission where the Court

dealt with a concerted practice involving price fixing and the sharing of markets.53

The CJEU referred to the need to take account of the agreement’s context when

assessing the ‘effects’ of the agreement with regard to restrictions prohibited under

Article 101(1) TFEU.54 To determine the object of the agreement the CJEU took

account of, inter alia, the parties’ conduct, their importance on the market, sales

figures as well as the structure of the market, the duration of the agreements and

the general state of the market in relation to that time.55

The parties argued the agreement was made during a time when there was a

shortage of raw materials and that it had no effect on the market. The Court found,

on the facts of the case, that these factors were irrelevant.56 The Court held that

“such a shortage cannot render lawful an agreement the object of which is to

restrict competition”.57 Based on its assessment of the economic context, the

Court found that the purpose of the agreement was to share markets and fix prices,

which therefore amounted to an intention to restrict competition manifested

through the faithful expression of the parties’ joint intention as to their conduct.

52

Ibid, summary, point 3. Emphasis added. 53

C-41/69 ACF Chemiefarma v Commission [1970] ECR 661. The case raises the interesting question of how object is assessed in respect of a gentleman’s agreement. The main problem is identifying the restriction and proving it. 54

Ibid, paras 110-114. 55

Ibid, also paras 129, 155 onwards. See particularly para 160. 56

Ibid, paras 127, 157. 57

Ibid, para 127.

Page 66: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 65

The Court also found that such an object could not be excused or justified by

arguments that the agreement had no effect or there was a scarcity of raw

materials.58 The Court argued that in order to preserve their territorial protection

the parties had agreed to restrict their freedom of action and therefore the fact the

parties were unable to then act upon such a restriction was deemed irrelevant.59

This reasoning demonstrates to what degree the CJEU is willing to consider whether

economic factors can assuage a proven anti-competitive purpose.

What is emerging from the case law to this point is that the Court seeks to

understand the economic rationale behind the agreement to determine whether its

purpose is indeed to restrict competition, despite the parties’ protestations to the

contrary. Such considerations turn on the facts of the case. The Court therefore

appears to ask itself what the rationale is behind the agreement: is it designed to

restrict competition and therefore pursue an anti-competitive aim?60

Similarly in Anseau/IAZ the case centred on the intent and purpose of the

agreement as the parties denied they knew they were restricting, let alone

intended to restrict, competition.61 The Court took account of the context of the

agreement and its effects on competition when determining whether the use of a

conformity label for washing machines and dishwashers amounted to a restriction

of parallel imports (a hardcore restriction) and thus had as its object the restriction

of competition. The parties contended that the Commission had not met the

requisite legal standard of proof when it found the agreement anti-competitive by

object.62 The Court agreed with the Commission, but noted in its judgment that the

agreement made parallel imports of washing machines more difficult, which was

exacerbated by the high market shares of the parties.63

58

Ibid, paras 156-157. 59

Ibid, para 155-160. This judgment is pertinent when considering the judgment in BIDS supra n3. 60

See eg, STM, Völk, ACF Chemiefarma and CRAM and Rheinzink. 61

Joined cases C-96-102, 104, 105, 108, 110/82 IAZ International Belgium v Commission [1983] ECR 3369 (Anseau/IAZ). See paras 24 and 25. 62

Ibid, para 22 and see paras 23 and 25. 63

Ibid, para 22.

Page 67: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 66

The Court found that the subjective intention of the parties must be objectively

determined when assessing the purpose of the agreement. Any claim that the

parties did not intend to restrict competition must be borne out by an analysis of

the agreement in its context. In this case the parties argued they did not intend to

restrict competition as the agreement’s true purpose was to protect the public’s

health. On analysis, the Court found, based on the agreement’s particular

circumstances, that this alternative purpose was not sufficient to invalidate the

anticompetitive object of the agreement.64 Having regard to the content, origin

and circumstances of the agreement (that is, its terms and the legal and economic

context), the Court held that the agreement had the intention of treating parallel

imports less favourably than official imports.65 By signing the agreement the

parties acted deliberately whether or not they were aware that doing so infringed

Article 101(1) TFEU. These factors were evidenced by the conduct of the parties

and the procedures they implemented.66 This judgment reinforces how any

analysis of the object criterion must be fact specific. The context of an agreement

thus dictates whether a factor is relevant in one case, but not another.67 The

parties also argued the agreement did not affect competition. Even though the

STM Test does not require such effect to be resolved, the Court held that the

agreement did have a restrictive effect given the considerable market shares of the

parties.68

The importance of an agreement’s specific context in determining the purpose of

an agreement is further underlined in Louis Erauw.69 The judgment can be usefully

contrasted with ACF Chemiefarma and Anseau/IAZ as here the Court found that a

positive purpose was in fact sufficient to ensure the agreement was not restrictive

64

Ibid, para 22. See also section 2.1.2 below. This is not to say such a factor may not carry more weight in a different context. 65

Ibid, paras 23-35. 66

Ibid, para 27. 67

For example contrast the views on legitimate objectives: Pierre Fabre vis-a-vis ACF Chemiefarma and BIDS. See also how the CJEU in C-67/13 P Groupement des Cartes Bancaires v Commission, 11 September 2014, nyr explained the judgment in BIDS, para 84. 68

Supra n61, Anseau/IAZ, para 27. The Court held the agreement appreciably restricted competition, notwithstanding its other purpose to protect public health. The question of whether the object criterion must be appreciable is discussed in chapter 5. 69

C-27/87 Erauw-Jacquery v La Hesbignonne [1983] ECR 1919 (Louis Erauw).

Page 68: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 67

by object and, in fact, come outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether. The case

concerned plant breeders’ rights. The agreement (a licence) contained a ‘no

export’ clause and a stipulation that there should be no selling below a minimum

sales price. The Court held, with regard to the no export ban, that - as plant

breeders incur considerable financial costs in developing varieties of basic seed -

such persons must be allowed to protect themselves against any improper handling

of those varieties of seeds. Therefore, the plant breeder was entitled to “restrict

propagation to the growers which he has selected as licensees. To that extent, the

provision prohibiting the licensee from selling and exporting basic seed falls

outside...Article [101](1)”.70

Therefore an argument as to the positive attributes or ‘legitimate goal’ of the

agreement was held to trump a restrictive object. As such the CJEU held, again,

that even absolute territorial protection can come outside the reach of Article

101(1) TFEU. Here, the CJEU was clearly balancing the pro-competitive aim of such

a restriction against the negative aspects.71 This apparent tolerance of the

balancing of the positive attributes of an agreement under Article 101(1) TFEU is

notable. As will be seen throughout this thesis, however, such balancing is fairly

commonplace.72 Yet again, the Court’s approach highlights the individual nature of

each case that comes before it and underlines the importance of assessing the

70

Ibid, para 10-11 (emphasis added). 71

Balancing the aims of an agreement can also be seen in AEG-Telefunken v Commission (supra n6) where the Court considered a selective distribution system. Here the Court looked at the object of the agreement in a positive light, stating that the “object” of the system was to “improve competition”. Moreover, it found there are “legitimate requirements which justify a reduction of price competition in favour of competition relating to factors other than price”. The Court also held that if selective distribution systems did not follow the Metro criteria, they would constitute an infringement of Article 101(1). The Court did not clarify that would constitute a restriction of competition by object or effect. However in para 96 the Court made the point that “effecting parallel imports cannot be regarded as an infringement of the rules of competition, whereas undertaking no longer to effect such imports is manifestly an infringement of community law since it would allow a manufacturer to wall off national markets...” (emphasis added). The interesting issues raised in this judgment are considered in subsequent chapters. 72

See for instance the various selective and exclusive distribution cases; also footnote 34 of the opinion in BIDS (supra n3), the judgment in Case C-238/05 Asnef Equifax v Ausbanc [2006] ECR I-11125 and the Commission’s decision in Visa International – Multilateral Interchange Fee [2002] OJ L318/17. The distinction between positive aims or attributes and a legitimate objective is moot: see AG Mazák’s Opinion in Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre Dermo-Cosmétique SAS v Président de l’Autorité de la concurrence, [2001] ECR I-9419. These issues are discussed further in chapter 4, section 2.

Page 69: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 68

agreement within its context.73 Had the agreement been assessed in accordance

with the Article 81(3) Guidelines, the Commission would not have come up with the

same result. More significantly, the Court held the restriction fell outside Article

101(1) TFEU entirely. Unlike in Völk, this was due to the Court finding a pro-

competitive purpose not because the parties had a low market share.

2.1.3. Interim Conclusion

This section examined the jurisprudence of the CJEU up to the inception of the GC

in 1989. It found that the seminal case of STM outlined a comprehensive test in

order to determine the object of an agreement. The STM Test was further fleshed

out by subsequent judgments, which all focused on uncovering the rationale behind

an agreement drawn from its legal and economic context. Put another way, is the

agreement designed to restrict competition? This approach is referred to as the

more analytical approach (the MAAP). Under the MAAP, to prove the ‘object’ of an

agreement the following factors are taken into account:

a) The key question is: what is the “precise purpose” of the agreement?

b) Such purpose is extrapolated from:

i) the content of the agreement,

ii) the conduct of the parties to the agreement,

iii) an objective determination of the purpose of the agreement only drawing on

the subjective intention of the parties if appropriate, and

iv) the circumstances of the agreement.

c) The purpose is assessed within the agreement’s specific legal and economic

context, which takes account of:

i) The effect of the agreement on competition (both potential and even actual),

ii) The market structure, markets shares, definition of the market,

(1) High market shares can help confirm an anti-competitive purpose whereas

very low markets shares can bring an agreement outside Article 101(1)

TFEU as the effect on competition is not sufficiently deleterious, and

iii) The severity of the clauses needed to protect the (pro-competitive) purpose of

the agreement.

d) If after this analysis it does not “appear” that the agreement has the object, that is,

the purpose of restricting competition then the actual effects of the agreement

73

This point is also highlighted by the GC in Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission [2006] ECR II-2969 (GSK).

Page 70: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 69

must be assessed to determine if an agreement in fact has the effect of restricting

competition under Article 101(1) TFEU.

e) Should an agreement be found to be restrictive by object, then the exemption

under Article 101(3) TFEU is applicable.

It is clear that the objective purpose of an agreement overrides a subjective

intention of the parties not to restrict competition.74 The subjective intention and

conduct of the parties can, however, be relevant in helping determine whether the

purpose of the agreement is to restrict competition. Subjective intention plays a

subordinate role to finding an objective aim to restrict competition. It is also not

relevant whether the parties did not know that what they were doing restricted

competition.75 Furthermore, the CJEU has determined that even if an agreement

was intended to restrict competition, but was not then implemented, this is not

sufficient to remove the agreement from the ambit of Article 101(1) TFEU.76 This is

a significant point as it shows that the competition rules will kick into action even if

a restrictive agreement is not implemented or successful. The case law also makes

clear that the object criterion does not require the agreement to have had an actual

effect on competition as the potential to affect competition is sufficient.

In the above cases, the orthodox approach has little bearing on how the CJEU

applies let alone defines the object criterion. The Court took account those

restrictions specifically named under Article 101(1) TFEU as being ‘restrictions of

competition’, but did not automatically associate them with having a restrictive

object. The foundations of the orthodox approach were thus not apparent at this

juncture. To see whether it is possible to pinpoint the origins of the orthodox

approach, the following section investigates those cases where the CJEU introduces

74

Supra n5 Anseau/IAZ. 75

Ibid, para 6 of the summary: “if the parties to the agreement were aware the agreement as drafted by looking at its terms, the legal and economic context in which it was concluded and to the conduct of the parties, had as its purpose to restrict parallel imports, they acted deliberately by signing the agreement, whether or not they were aware that in doing so they were infringing Article 101(1)”. 76

C-277/87 Sandoz Prodotti Farmaceutici SpA v Commission [1990] ECR 145, para 3 of the summary. Conversely, in T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline (supra n73 discussed below), GlaxoSmithKline admitted it intended to restrict competition, yet in this instance having undertaken an objective analysis of the agreement the GC did not consider this enough to prove that the object was to restrict competition.

Page 71: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 70

the phrase ‘by its nature’ to its jurisprudence. This phrase is significant as the

Commission specifically links it with its interpretation of the object criterion.77

2.2. Questionable foundations of the orthodox approach: agreements that ‘by

their very nature’ restrict competition: early case law up to 1989

The phrases ‘by their very nature’ and ‘of their nature’ play a prominent role in the

determination of restrictions by object under the orthodox approach. The Article

81(3) Guidelines clearly connect both the phrase and the orthodoxy by defining

restrictions by object as those that “by their very nature have the potential of

restricting competition”.78 The use of this phrase also marks, albeit in only a few

specific cases, a shift in approach by the CJEU from the more analytical approach to

an approach that is more analogous with the orthodox approach. What is notable,

however, about the case law of this period is that the CJEU’s reference to ‘of their

nature’ is not always in accord with the Commission’s use of that phrase.79

Despite the prevalent use of the term and its derivatives throughout the Court’s

jurisprudence (both within its earlier and more recent jurisprudence), ‘by their very

nature’ has rarely been defined. One of the few instances is by the GC in GSK,

which it held to mean “independent of any competitive analysis”.80 Such

interpretation is borne in mind when examining the case law below.

77

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 21. The Commission does not cite any case law in support of its contention. This raises the prospect that paragraph 21 reflects the Commission’s policy as opposed to its interpretation of the law. 78

Ibid, paras 21 and 23. 79

See also Case C-238/05 Asnef Equifax (supra n72), which concerned a horizontal credit information exchange agreement. Here the Court of Justice focused on the positive attributes of the information exchange system in determining the object and found that the “essential object of credit information exchange systems is to make available to credit providers relevant information about existing or potential borrowers”. Given the positive attributes of the system the register did not “by its very nature” have the object of restricting competition. Ultimately, the purpose of the agreement was not to restrict competition as it had a positive aim. Also noted by (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p652. 80

Supra n73 GSK, para 120.

Page 72: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 71

2.2.1. Cases that continue to support the more analytical approach

The judgment in Brasserie De Haecht demonstrates how the CJEU has combined the

more analytical approach with the use of the phrase ‘by its nature’.81 The Court

confirmed the methodology in STM by verifying that in order to determine if an

agreement is caught by Article 101(1) TFEU, it must be examined in its ‘legal and

economic context’ and not in isolation.82 The Court found that exclusive supply

agreements are not ‘by their very nature’ incompatible with the Common Market.83

The reference to the phrase implies that certain types of restriction may ‘by their

very nature’ be incompatible with the Common Market. This statement cannot,

however, be interpreted to mean that the object criterion should therefore be

automatically associated with such restrictions. Rather it suggests that particular

restrictions fall foul of the competition rules (such as those restrictions listed in

Article 101(1) TFEU).

Cooperatieve Stremselen endorses this interpretation of Brasserie De Haecht by

illustrating two issues.84 First, it affirms how restrictions not classically categorised

as ‘hardcore’ can, upon a market analysis, still be held restrictive by object.85

Secondly, that a reference to ‘of its nature’ is not an implicit reference to the

orthodox approach. The case concerned the rules of a cooperative and the Court

first looked at the object and effect of the agreement together. It held that the

rules in respect of exclusive purchasing requirements reinforced by payment for

expulsion or resignation “have clearly as their object to prevent members from

obtaining supplies from other suppliers” or from making supplies themselves.86 As

a result, the provisions are “of such a nature as to prevent competition at the level

of the supply of rennet and colouring agents for cheese between producers holding

a large part of the Community market in cheese”.87 Notably, the Court makes this

81

C-23/67 Brasserie De Haecht v Wilkin [1967] ECR 407. See also STM. 82

Ibid, p415. 83

Ibid, Operative Part of the judgment. 84

C-61/80 Coöperatieve Stremsel-en Kleurselfabriek v Commission [1981] ECR 851. 85

Ibid. The agreement may be on a horizontal level, nevertheless, exclusive purchasing obligations are not singled out under the Article 81(3) Guidelines or Article 101(1) TFEU. 86

Ibid, para 12. 87

Ibid, para 13. Emphasis added.

Page 73: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 72

assessment having undertaken an analysis of the market. It considered the market

power of the parties, and thus of the effects of the agreement on the defined

upstream market.

2.2.2. Origins of the orthodox approach

The Court’s judgment in Miller is symbolic as it is consistently cited as supporting

the proposition that, by law, certain restrictions of competition automatically

restrict competition by virtue of their object.88 This is questionable. The judgment

does not, on analysis, offer any such unqualified support. The case concerned

restrictions on exports contained in an exclusive dealing agreement and in the

terms and conditions of sale (therefore a vertical arrangement), which the

Commission found incompatible with Article 101(1) TFEU. The CJEU held that “by

its very nature a clause prohibiting exports constitutes a restriction of

competition”.89 This statement was made, however, in the light of Miller claiming

that it did not have a blameworthy objective, but that the restriction was adopted

at the behest of its customers.90 The Court rejected this stating that by its very

nature prohibiting exports constitutes a restriction of competition “whether [that

clause] is adopted at the instigation of the supplier or of the customer since the

agreed purpose of the contracting parties is the endeavour to isolate a part of the

market”.91 This statement does not therefore specifically link object with the

prohibition of exports rather that such a prohibition is a restriction of competition

under Article 101(1) TFEU. More fundamentally, the Court referred to the objective

purpose of the parties being to restrict competition, which underlines the

interpretation of the object criterion in STM.

88

C-19/77 Miller International Schallplatten GmbH v Commission (1978) ECR 131 (Miller). See for example, (Odudu, 2001), ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): The Object Requirement Revisited’; (Faull & Nikpay, 2007), paras 3.145, 3.150, 3.152; (Bellamy & Child, 2008), para 2.097. Indeed it is also used to demonstrate that object restrictions are akin to per se restrictions: see (Bellamy & Child, 2008), para 2.097 (footnote 391). 89

Ibid, Miller para 7. See also para 3. 90

Ibid, Miller, para 6. 91

Ibid, Miller, para 7. Emphasis added.

Page 74: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 73

Upholding its reasoning in ACF Chemiefarma, the CJEU found arguments that the

parties did not enforce the no-export prohibition did not then denote it had no

restrictive effect.92 It noted that, as customers knew of the prohibition on exports,

a visual and psychological background was created contributing to a division of the

market.93 More pertinently, the case is concerned less with the object of the

agreement and more with whether the agreement affected trade between Member

States. Miller specifically challenged the appraisal of the effects of its behaviour by

the Commission. It contended that the export ban cannot have appreciably affected

trade between Member States due to its insignificant effect on the market.94 This

was despite its acknowledgment that prohibitions on exports are not compatible

with the common market.95 In determining whether the agreement affected trade

between Member States the CJEU conducted an analysis of Miller’s position on the

market so as to dismiss the fact that the parties had an insignificant market share.

Given the focus on the effect on trade element, it is highly questionable whether

Miller should be cited as such strong authority for the contention that export bans

automatically have the object of restricting competition, or indeed, for the more

general proposition that there is a category of agreements which have the object of

restricting competition.96 At best, the judgment provides support for the

proposition that an export ban is a restriction of competition.

A case that probably provides better support for the orthodox approach, though is

not often cited as such, is Bureau National v Guy Clair.97 The case concerned an

inter-trade organisation (BNIC), which fixed the price of cognac and other wines

and spirits in an agreement between its members. The CJEU held that:

92

Ibid, Miller, para 7. 93

Ibid, Miller, para 7. 94

Ibid, Miller, paras 3 and 6. 95

Ibid, Miller, para 6. 96

This alternative analysis is supported by the GC in Case T-148/89, Tréfilunion v Commission, [1995] ECR II-1063 (Tréfilunion) when, at paragraph 103, it cites Miller as the authority for the affect on trade criteria. 97

Case C-123/83 Bureau National Interprofessional Du Cognac v Guy Clair [1985] ECR 391. Note that it is surprisingly cited in the judgment of 11 September 2014, C-67/13 P Groupement des Cartes Bancaires v Commission, nyr (Cartes Bancaires).

Page 75: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 74

“For the purposes of Article 101(1) it is unnecessary to take account of the actual effects of an agreement where its object is to restrict, prevent or distort competition. By its very nature, an agreement fixing a minimum price for a product which is submitted to the public authorities for the purpose of obtaining approval for that minimum price, so that it becomes binding on all traders on the market in question, is intended to distort competition on that market.”98

The passage suggests that, by law, certain restrictions automatically restrict

competition by virtue of their object.99 Through using the word “intended”, which

is taken to refer to the objective intention of the agreement and not the subjective

intention of the parties, the CJEU submits that such agreements automatically

intend to restrict competition regardless of their actual effects. The inference is

that particular restrictions are presumed to restrict competition due to an implied

intention to distort competition. The language of the Court would seem to suggest

that price fixing has the ‘necessary effect’ of always restricting competition as, by

its very nature, fixing minimum prices is intended to restrict competition and should

thus be prohibited. Consequently, the judgment raises more questions than it

answers.

The orthodox approach, as encapsulated in the Article 81(3) Guidelines, does not

refer to an agreement’s ‘intention’. Rather, the Commission claims that particular

restrictions by their very nature have the potential to restrict competition owing to

the high potential of negative effects on competition, the serious nature of the

restriction and on experience showing such restrictions are likely to produce such

negative effects on the market.100 The Commission does not cite any case law in

support of this contention. Hence, determining whether an agreement restricts

competition by object is based upon an identification exercise.101 Guy Clair does

not support all these elements of the orthodox approach.102

98

Ibid, Bureau National v Guy Clair, para 22. Emphasis added. 99

However, the reference to “intention” does not clarify this proposition undisputedly. 100

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 21. 101

Para 23 of the Article 81(3) Guidelines claims, “...what constitutes restrictions by object can be found in Commission block exemption regulations, guidelines and notices”. 102

It is not cited by the Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines.

Page 76: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 75

Despite the passage cited above, there is still a question as to whether, as a result

of this judgment, the phrase ‘by its very nature’ should automatically be associated

with object cases rather than the notion that certain agreements constitute

restrictions of competition. In its answer to the referring court, the CJEU merely

said that “Article [101](1) must be taken to apply to inter-trade agreements fixing a

minimum price for a product concluded by two groups of trades within the

framework of, and in accordance with the procedure of, a body such as BNIC”.103

On balance, however, it is likely that Bureau National v Guy Clair provides the

greatest justification to date for the Commission’s approach to object under its

Article 81(3) Guidelines.

2.2.3. Necessary consequence/necessary effect

The concept of necessary effect has been raised a few times, particularly in the case

of Bureau National v Guy Clair as an element, which encapsulates the ‘by its very

nature’ approach to the object concept. It has been noted the concept plays an

important role in the Commission’s approach to object cases.104 To recap,

necessary effect is based on the assertion that the concrete effects of an agreement

do not need to be considered under the object heading, as certain restrictions of

competition automatically infringe Article 101(1) TFEU due to their known negative

effects derived from experience.105 Impliedly, there is an irrebuttable presumption

of anti-competitiveness.106 That it is therefore safe to assume particular restraints

automatically infringe Article 101(1) TFEU by object, is almost certainly derived

from the principal that ‘actual’ effects do not need to be proven in object cases.107

103

Supra n97 Bureau National v Guy Clair, point 1 of the Operative Part. 104

Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 21, 23. See chapter 1. 105

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 21. (Odudu, 2001), ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): the Object Requirement Revisited’, p379, 384. See also (Black, 2005), p118 and AG Trstenjak’s Opinions in BIDS and GSK (supra n3 and infra n186.) Bailey discusses this issue, see (Bailey, 2012), pp564-565 and 571-572. 106

There is no suggestion in the Article 81(3) Guidelines that such a presumption is rebuttable or even if it were rebuttable which party has the onus of rebutting such presumption, see paras 21-23. 107

Supra n27 above Consten & Grundig. It appears there is a missing link between the propositions that actual effects need not be demonstrated (arguably because the purpose of the agreement is to restrict competition irrespective of effects, though this purpose needs to be ascertained) and no effects need be demonstrated (because it can be assumed that the effect is to restrict competition).

Page 77: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 76

According to Odudu, CRAM and Rheinzink is often cited as supporting the

contention that the actual effects of an agreement do not need to be established

under the object criterion, because the presumption is that they exist.108 Odudu is

right to assert the judgment does not offer any such unqualified support.109 The

case concerned restrictions on parallel trade usually designated by the Commission

as a hardcore infringement. When assessing the agreement, the Court examined

the conduct of the parties, the prices charged and the circumstances surrounding

the contract. It held as a result of this analysis that the export clauses were

“designed” to prevent the re-export of the goods to the country of production so as

to maintain a system of dual prices and restrict competition within the common

market.110 Such analysis does not support the presumption that particular

restrictions automatically have the object of restricting competition. The concept

of necessary effect only requires proof that the restriction is contained within the

agreement. Here, the Court went further than merely identifying the purported

restriction.

2.2.4. Interim conclusion

It has been established that, overall, there is little endorsement by the CJEU of the

orthodox approach within its early jurisprudence. This is evidenced when the case

law that focuses on those agreements that ‘by their nature’ restrict competition do

not wholeheartedly align with the orthodox tradition. Instead, the case law focuses

more heavily on understanding the aim or purpose of the agreement within its

context. One case that bears more resemblance to the Commission’s interpretation

of the object criterion is that of Guy Clair. However, even here the CJEU refers to

the “intention” of the agreement. The value of these cases as precedents for the

orthodox approach is therefore questionable. Conversely, the cases demonstrate

how the CJEU adopts language that can be construed so as to support a more

orthodox meaning. Nevertheless, the Court provides no definition for the phrase

108

(Odudu, 2001), ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): the Object Requirement Revisited’, p384; C-29&30/83 Compagnie Royal Austrienne des Mines and Rheinzink (CRAM) v Commission [1984] ECR 1679. 109

Ibid, (Odudu, 2001), p384. 110

Supra n108, CRAM, para 28.

Page 78: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 77

‘by its nature’. This emphasises the Court’s own shortcomings in terms of clarity of

the law and its contribution to the confusion surrounding the object concept.

The lack of case law that unequivocally supports the orthodox approach is further

confirmed in the next section, which substantiates the proposition that the MAAP

forms the basis of the law on the object criterion.

3. The more analytical approach continues to inform the CJEU’s application of the

object concept: 1989 to 2006

This section documents how the MAAP continues to play a significant role in the

evolution of the object concept within EU competition law after the inception of

the General Court up until 2006. The year 2006 marks a turning point as at that

juncture the ‘hybrid approach’ starts to materialise within the European Courts’

jurisprudence.111 The case law of the period between 1989 and 2006 reinforces the

centrality of the STM Test as the foundation of the Court’s application of the object

criterion and its constituent parts.112 One particular Advocate General (AG) opinion

is pertinent in this respect, that of AG Tesauro in Gøttrup-Klim.113 AGs are not

subject to the same constraints as the CJEU, for example, they do not need to form

a judgment based on a consensus.114 Therefore their opinions can be influential

and helpful in their detail. His opinion is a useful exposition of the judicial thinking

at the time. It is apparent that the object concept as interpreted in accordance

with the MAAP is not a new phenomenon.115 Nevertheless, despite the orthodox

approach lacking the commensurate judicial authority, it is clear just how influential

the Commission’s interpretation of the object criterion is. As the cases below

demonstrate the CJEU has in fact paid very specific attention to the object criterion.

111

Though the hybrid approach materialises at the same time as judgments supporting the MAAP are handed down, see eg Asnef Equifax (supra n72). 112

For instance the cases concern indirect means in which to achieve an export ban, the positive attributes of an agreement, the defence of a legitimate objective and the assessment of object in the light of those factors. 113

Case C-250/92 Gøttrup-Klim (supra n5). The AG’s opinion also provides the basis for the term “more analytical approach”. 114

Whish acknowledges the benefits of AG opinions, (Whish, 2009), p113. 115

A number of commentators claim the MAAP is a recent phenomenon, see eg the paper delivered by Barry Rodger at the ‘New Challenges in Competition Law’ conference, UCL, Istanbul, 6 June 2014, (Rodger, 2014).

Page 79: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 78

In Gøttrup-Klim, AG Tesauro’s opinion cements a number of key features identified

in the case law to this point.116 He underlined the importance of the STM Test in

assessing agreements under Article 101(1) TFEU, and reiterated that to establish

whether an agreement is caught by Article 101(1) TFEU a two stage examination is

necessary. First, the object of the agreement must be considered. To that end, the

“aims pursued by the agreement will have to be appraised in the economic context

in which it is to operate. If the agreement seeks to restrict competition, it must be

considered to be prohibited automatically and its effects need not be

considered.”117 Where the object is not anticompetitive, a second stage is

undertaken: “the agreement will be prohibited if it appears likely to restrict

competition appreciably.”118 The AG confirmed that object and effect must be

viewed in the context of how competition would have operated in the market in

question in the absence of that agreement (the counterfactual):

“...according to that analytical approach, agreements which,

viewed objectively and in the abstract, have no other function

than to restrict freedom of competition between parties in a

manner considered incompatible with the common market will be

regarded as prohibited by virtue of their object”.119

Conversely, he considered agreements that are capable of performing more

complex functions are not regarded as having an anticompetitive object.120 As

such, AG Tesauro found the Court usually decides that “no anti-competitive object

is contained in clauses which are found in the abstract to be necessary to ensure

that contract, which is not in itself harmful to competition, can fully discharge the

legal and economic function which it pursues.”121 According to the AG, this explains

why non-compete clauses and exclusive supply clauses are not seen to be

116

Supra n5, Gøttrup-Klim. Opinion of 16 June 1994. The CJEU confirmed the overall stance of the AG. 117

Ibid, para 16. 118

Ibid, para 16. The role of appreciability is discussed in chapter 5. 119

Ibid, para 16. Note the reference to restricting the freedom of the parties. Cf Case C-309/99 Wouters v Algemene Raad van de Nederlandsche Orde van Advocaten [2002] ECR I-1577. 120

Ibid, Gøttrup-Klim, para 16. The statements in para 16 are further examined in chapters 3 and 4. See also Asnef Equifax (supra n72) and the AG’s Opinion in BIDS (supra n3). 121

Ibid, Gøttrup-Klim, para 16.

Page 80: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 79

restrictive by virtue of their object (presumably as the precise purpose of the

agreement is not to restrict competition).

The AG also gave some thought to the reasoning for the distinction between object

and effect. He emphasised that the analysis of object and effect are to be clearly

distinguished, though acknowledged the distinction is usually disregarded by the

Commission, which tends to make an overall assessment for both object and effect,

concluding that a particular agreement does or does not infringe Article 101(1)

TFEU as a whole.122 He consequently recognised that it is not clear the way in

which the principle, that object and effect are distinct, is applied.123 The AG

understood the dichotomy as follows:

“[To determine whether a particular clause is anticompetitive in

intent, the object criterion]...is intended to assess, in the abstract,

the objective function of a particular set of conditions in its

contractual context. The second, on the other hand, is designed

to establish whether, specifically, an agreement whose object is

not anti-competitive is nevertheless liable, in the specific market

context in which it is to operate, appreciably to affect competition

in the common market.’124

This version of the distinction is persuasive, to an extent. It is, however, a vital clue

in the understanding of the functioning of Article 101(1) TFEU as a whole and

underlines the importance of the more analytical approach in legal history. In

accordance with this distinction, every agreement must first be assessed to

determine if the object is to restrict competition. If this is not established, then the

role of effect is to sweep up those agreements that do not intend to restrict

competition, but nevertheless have that effect. However, the notion that the

object concept is viewed in the abstract is somewhat controversial. The AG does

not explain what the term ‘abstract’ means. There is a conflict between assessing

an agreement in the abstract, but within its specific context. A contextual analysis

cannot be deemed abstract. Arguably, the AG is merely referring to the position

122

Ibid, footnote 19 of the Opinion. 123

Ibid, footnote 19 of the Opinion. 124

Ibid, para 16. See also the opinion in Pierre Fabre, para 26 (supra n72).

Page 81: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 80

established in STM; that the analysis undertaken when determining the object of an

agreement is less intensive than when establishing the actual effect of an

agreement. The precise parameters of the object analysis are therefore unclear.

The importance of context is reinforced by AG Tizzano’s opinion in General Motors

v Commission.125 The case involved what the Commission would automatically

consider to be an object restriction: an export ban. The export ban was ‘indirect’

and therefore it was not clear on the face of the documentation that the aim or

purpose of the agreement was to restrict competition.126 The AG held that for

there to be a restriction of competition by object, the agreement does not need to

have a restriction of competition as its sole aim.127 Where an agreement “obviously

has an anticompetitive purpose”, this renders “irrelevant and uninfluential” the fact

that it also pursues other legitimate objectives.128 This position can be contrasted

with earlier case law where, even in the context of a hardcore restriction, such as

the export ban in Louis Erauw, such an agreement was considered to fall outside

the realms of Article 101(1) TFEU due to justifications to the contrary.129 It is

submitted the determinative factor as to whether alternative purposes are able to

justify particular restrictions turns on the context of the agreement.

To then “ascertain whether an agreement is capable of restricting competition” the

agreement must be assessed within the actual context in which it would occur in

the absence of the agreement in dispute.130 Moreover, the AG upheld the principle

125

Case C-551/03 P General Motors Nederland and Opel Nederland v Commission [2006] ECR I-3173. Here the AG looked at a series of agreements and discussions between the parties in order to decide whether the object was to restrict competition. 126

The issue was, inter alia, whether excluding export sales from the dealer’s bonus policy was a restriction of competition. Note, that the Commission recognises that hardcore restrictions can be achieved through indirect means, though the orthodox approach tends to suggest restrictions by object are ‘obvious’. See chapter 1. 127

Supra n125, General Motors, para 67. In AEG-Telefunken the Court found it was irrelevant that the agreement had another legitimate purpose (supra n6). 128

Ibid, para 68 of the opinion. This follows IAZ/Anseau (supra n61). 129

In Louis Erauw (supra n69) the justification was the amount of financial commitment needed to develop the product. See also Völk (supra n42). 130

Supra n125, General Motors, para 74, ie, the counterfactual. Unfortunately the AG references para 33 of Case C-215/96 Bagnasco v Banca Popolare di Novara [1999] ECR I-135, which provides an extremely confused and limited account of the law on Article 101(1) TFEU. Therefore this aspect of the opinion is questionable in its accuracy. The AG should have cited STM. See also Joined cases C-

Page 82: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 81

that the object of an agreement is deduced from the content of its clauses, the

intention of the parties “as it arises from the ‘genesis’ of the agreement or

manifests itself in the circumstances in which it was implemented” and the conduct

of the undertakings concerned.131 Thus, the characteristics of the measure, as well

as the objectives pursued by the manufacturer inferred from its general strategy,

were relevant.132 Finally, it is notable that the AG found it irrelevant that the

objective pursued was not attained and therefore did not produce anticompetitive

effects.133

Notably the CJEU confirmed much of the AG’s opinion. When making an

assessment of object the CJEU held that:

“...account must be taken not only of the terms of the agreement,

but also of other factors, such as the aims pursued by the

agreement in the light of the economic and legal context, in order

to determine whether an agreement has a restrictive object.”134

The CJEU affirmed that such an objective can be achieved through direct and

indirect means.135 The CJEU therefore held that the agreement had the object of

restricting competition even though it was not explicitly obvious that the agreement

had that object.136 In making its assessment, the CJEU looked at the conduct of the

parties and considered what the competitive situation in the market would have

been if, as in this case, export sales had not been excluded from the bonus policy.

Proof of intention was not seen as a necessary factor in determining the object of

the agreement.137 Such intention, however, may be taken into account when

assessing the object of the agreement.

238/99 & others P Limburgse Vinyl Maatschappij v Commission [2002] ECR I-8375 on the relevance of the economic context. 131

Supra n125, General Motors, para 78. 132

Ibid, para 81. 133

Ibid, footnote 52. See also C-235/92 P Montecatini v Commission [1999] ECR I-4539, para 125. 134

Ibid, General Motors, paras 64-66. 135

Ibid, para 68. 136

This can be contrasted with the case law of the General Court in ENS (supra n4). See section 4. 137

Supra n125, General Motors, para 77. The CJEU cited Miller (supra n88) and CRAM (supra n108) in support of this point. This finding upheld the opinion, paras 77-78. Intent could also be attributed to the conduct of the parties.

Page 83: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 82

The need to ascertain the true objective of an agreement and the significance of an

agreement’s context was again reinforced by the judgment in Asnef Equifax.138

Here, the issue concerned a horizontal credit information exchange agreement.

Information exchange systems raise intriguing questions under Article 101(1) TFEU

as they involve a form of collusion. Therefore, the assessment of whether such an

arrangement is a restriction by object is an important and revealing one. Horizontal

agreements to exchange information have been held to constitute restrictions by

object when they concern future pricing intentions or where the commercial

independence of an undertaking is compromised.139 The CJEU focused on the

positive attributes of the information exchange system when dismissing the

suggestion that the object of the agreement was anticompetitive.140 Instead it

found that the “essential object of credit information exchange systems is to make

available to credit providers relevant information about existing or potential

borrowers”.141 The CJEU considered the positive benefits of such credit information

systems, such as the lender being able to foresee the likelihood of repayment, and

decided that they are in principle capable of improving the functioning of the

supply of credit.142 Therefore, the register did not “by its very nature” have the

object of restricting competition.143

The impact that the positive benefits of the agreement had on the outcome of the

judgment is significant. The CJEU weighed, albeit briefly, the positive benefits

(arguably the positive effects and aims) of the agreement against the negative

aspects. As a result of this exercise, it found that the “essential object” of the

agreement was not anticompetitive.144 This supports the view that the object

criterion is concerned with identifying the precise purpose of the agreement by

determining what the rationale behind it is, and specifically whether the agreement

138

Supra n72 Asnef Equifax. Judgment of 23 November 2006. 139

See for example Case C-204/00 P etc Aalborg Portland v Commission [2004] ECR I-123 and more generally see (Whish, 2009), p120. 140

Supra n72 Asnef Equifax, paras 46-48. 141

Ibid, para 46. 142

Ibid, para 47. 143

Ibid, para 48. 144

Ibid, para 46.

Page 84: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 83

is designed to restrict competition. More interestingly, the judgment leads to the

conclusion that the object criterion can accommodate the consideration of the

positive attributes of an agreement. Hence, if an agreement’s purpose is pro-

competitive then it does not have the object of restricting competition.145 This

conclusion was certainly evidenced in Louis Erauw. However, this position is

controversial. Having a legitimate aim or objective, indeed an objective justification

as a reason for entering into a potentially restrictive agreement did not convince

the CJEU in a number of cases.146 Therefore, where the distinction lies between

these concepts requires further reflection.

3.1. Conclusion: 1989-2006

The case law of this period continues to support the application of the MAAP when

determining an agreement’s object. Based on the STM Test, the CJEU assesses

whether the objective aim or purpose of an agreement within its specific legal and

economic context is to restrict competition.147 There is little evidence of the

orthodox approach being applied to agreements. Instead, the AG’s outline more

nuanced aspects of the object criterion. This highlights how the Court seeks to

understand the rationale behind an agreement: whether it seeks to restrict

competition. The case law does, however, expose that the object criterion lacks

absolute consensus and clarity relating to all its aspects. For instance, the defining

factor between a pro-competitive purpose and a legitimate objective is unclear. A

positive purpose is purportedly able to circumvent the application of the object

concept whereas a legitimate objective is not. Additionally, the AG in Gøttrup-Klim

referred to agreements performing more complex functions coming outside the

remit of the object criterion, which are assessed in the abstract. These are all

factors that require further scrutiny.148

145

This approach is also seen in a number of selective and exclusive distribution agreements. 146

See eg IAZ/Anseau (supra n61). 147

This includes considering the conduct of the parties and the circumstances surrounding the contract. 148

See chapters 3 and 4.

Page 85: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 84

This thesis rationalises the law as follows. It is clear that actual effects do not have

to be demonstrated in order to find an anti-competitive object. Rather, the role of

the object criterion is to tease out those agreements that are designed to restrict

competition, hence there being no requirement that an agreement is successful or

in fact has a physical effect on competition.149 STM requires that the effect on

competition is “sufficiently deleterious”, which is conceivably why judgments often

show the Court taking account of the potential and indeed actual effects of a

restriction.150 Nevertheless, the standard of proof under the object heading is less

onerous than when determining an agreement’s actual effect on competition.

What is not resolutely clear from the Court’s perspective is the question of precisely

why no actual effects need be shown under an object analysis. It is contended that

the reason, certainly at this juncture, is less dependent on the necessary effect of

the agreement and more on the fact the agreement itself intends, or has the

‘purpose’ of ‘restricting competition’. Such purpose to restrict competition,

objectively determined based on the agreement’s content and its particular legal

and economic context is sufficient alone to satisfy the object requirement. In

contrast, the effect criterion captures those agreements that may not have the

objective intention to restrict competition, but nevertheless have a restrictive

effect. This interpretation of the case law is consistent with Arved Deringer’s

earliest works deciphering Article 101 TFEU.151

Deringer is one of the early pioneers of EU competition law and therefore drawing

on his insightful early interpretation of the Treaty is helpful in understanding the

competition law rules. The English version of his German text describes Article 101

infringements as those “whose purpose or effect” is to restrict competition.152

Deringer saw the wording “purpose or effect” to indicate that there are “two

independent and equally important possibilities”.153 Accordingly, it is sufficient if an

agreement results in a restraint of competition, even if it was not intended to have

149

Hence why restrictions by object do not have to be ‘obvious’. 150

This is conceivably why agreements that are de minimis may come outside Article 101(1) TFEU. 151

(Deringer, 1968). 152

Ibid, para 130. 153

Ibid, para 130, 17.

Page 86: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 85

this effect. It is also sufficient that the agreement “aimed at” restricting

competition, but fails to achieve that result. As such, it is not necessary that the

agreement expressly states the intention to restrict competition, but that the

content of the agreement conclusively indicates such a purpose.154 The fact that

the agreement pursues other objectives is unimportant.155 It is the illegal purpose

of the agreement that renders an agreement illegal, not the agreement itself.156

Deringer considers that the Court requires the purpose of an agreement to be

determined first. This purpose must be a direct result of the agreement. When

ascertaining this purpose the economic circumstances surrounding the

implementation of the agreement should be taken into account in accordance with

the STM Test. If the result of this examination is that the agreement is “designed”

to restrict competition, there is no need to evaluate its actual effects.157 The

examples listed in Article 101(1) TFEU are thus illustrations of the concept of a

“restraint of competition”.158 They are not necessarily automatically synonymous

with restrictions by object.

Deringer’s assessment of the law is compelling. It lends weight to an interpretation

of the law on the object criterion as following a more analytical approach as

opposed to the orthodoxy. However, certain case law from this period marks an

alternative approach to the object concept, particularly evident in the case of

Bureau National v Guy Clair. These cases contend that the agreement ‘by its very

nature’ restricts competition. The CJEU does not elaborate on this terminology,

though does not subscribe to the orthodox approach as it does not categorise the

object concept as applying only to hardcore or obvious restrictions of competition.

Therefore defining the phrase as ‘independent of any competitive analysis’ appears

wide of the mark. A more appropriate definition is the recognition that actual

effects do not need to be proven. Such terminology does, however, permeate

more profoundly the jurisprudence of the European Courts going forwards.

154

Ibid, para 131. 155

Ibid paras 130-131. 156

Ibid, para 168. 157

Ibid, para 163. 158

Ibid, para 149.

Page 87: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 86

It is apparent at this juncture that the judgment in ENS is not reflective of the

CJEU’s case law to that point. This can be contrasted with the GC’s judgment in

GSK, which looks rather less surprising.

4. Case law of the General Court

The GC assesses the legality of the Commission’s decisions in the first instance. Its

judgments can be appealed to the CJEU on points of law only.159 The GC has taken

a robust approach to EU competition law and its judgments have helped shape the

competition law landscape. That is not to say it has been consistent. Since its

inception in 1989 and in contrast to the CJEU, the GC’s jurisprudence expresses

most clearly the stark dichotomy between the orthodox approach and the MAAP.

Four seminal judgments are selected for review, which best demonstrate this

diversity in approach to the object criterion. It becomes evident from this analysis

that the GC has exerted the most influence on the orthodox approach. However,

the dominance of the orthodox approach is again challenged as the GC subscribes

to the MAAP in two key cases.160 This raises the question of why the orthodox

approach has become so dominant within legal discourse. It may be that the

Commission has given its policy in respect of the object criterion an inflated status

over the law. Certainly, the Commission failed openly to acknowledge the

existence of a more analytical approach in its Article 81(3) Guidelines: it has not

distinguished its policy approach from the law. Hence, the repercussions are that

the MAAP was overshadowed by the orthodox approach. This has had far-reaching

consequences on the legal landscape.

4.1. ‘Per se’ infringements: a new dimension to agreements that ‘by their very

nature’ restrict competition

The GC was evidently keen to adopt a more formalistic approach in its early case

law, but also confirmed a number of principles in respect of the object criterion

established by the CJEU. In Tréfilunion v Commission, the parties to a concerted

159

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p55. 160

Ibáňez Colomo went so far as to claim the orthodox approach is “made up”: LSE lunchtime lecture, 2013.

Page 88: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 87

practice engaged in price fixing amongst other hardcore cartel activity.161 The court

confirmed that even if undertakings participate with others in meetings at which

decisions are taken concerning prices, but do not then observe the agreed prices,

such inaction will not change the fact that the object of those meetings was

anticompetitive. As a result, an undertaking that participated in the agreement has

no defence in saying it did not then implement the agreement.162 This is because

the concrete effects of an agreement do not need to be accounted for where “it

appears” that an agreement has as its object the prevention of competition within

the common market.163 Participation is therefore only relevant to the culpability of

the party.

Moreover, when considering the object of the agreement, the GC stated that as the

infringement of Article 101(1) TFEU - in particular sub-paragraphs (a) to (c) - was

“clear”, it “necessarily precludes the rule of reason since in that case it must be

regarded as an infringement per se of the competition rules”.164 This statement is

fascinating. Aside from the wholly inappropriate use of US antitrust terminology, it

is one of the first times that object has been linked so obviously with the fact

certain restrictions (such as those listed in Article 101(1) (a) to (c) TFEU)

automatically infringe Article 101 TFEU. In this respect, the GC breaks new ground.

Critically, the GC relied on Montedipe SpA v Commission when making this

statement.165 This is because it was unable to rely on a Court of Justice judgment:

there are none supporting such an interpretation. To exacerbate the absence of

judicial support for its reasoning, in Montedipe the GC merely repeated the same

statement utilised in Tréfilunion, though provided no citation supporting its

statement.166 Therefore the GC was relying on its own unsubstantiated

jurisprudence.

161

Case T-148/89 Tréfilunion v Commission (Welded Steel Mesh) [1995] ECR II-1063. 162

Ibid, para 79. 163

Ibid, para 79. 164

Ibid, para 109. 165

Case T-14/89 Montedipe SpA v Commission [1992] ECR II-1155, para 265. 166

Ibid, para 265.

Page 89: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 88

The GC reiterated the same reasoning in European Night Services (ENS).167 While

the case concerned proof of effects of an agreement under Article 101(1) TFEU, the

GC held that when assessing an agreement under Article 101(1) TFEU:

“...account should be taken of the actual conditions in which it

functions, in particular the economic context in which the

undertakings operate, the products or services covered by the

agreement and the actual structure of the market concerned,

unless it is an agreement containing obvious restrictions of

competition such as price-fixing, market-sharing or the control of

outlets [reference to Case T-148/89 Tréfilunion v Commission,

paragraph 109]. In the latter case, such restrictions may be

weighed against their claimed pro-competitive effects only in the

context of Article 85(3) of the Treaty, with a view to granting an

exemption from the prohibition in Article 85(1).”168

This extraordinary statement reveals a number of points. First, the GC was, again,

using its own case law to support a statement of law, without noting the conflict

between its position and that of the CJEU. Secondly, the GC’s approach in

Tréfilunion and ENS creates a clear analytical distinction between object and effect

analyses: the former relying solely on whether the restriction of competition is

‘obvious’, and all economic analysis is being reserved for the effects analysis.

Thirdly, the GC acknowledges that even agreements restrictive by object may be

allowed, on the basis of Article 101(3) TFEU. These two cases provide unequivocal

judicial support for the orthodox approach. Their status is questionable,

nonetheless, in view of the CJEU’s case law described in the previous sections and

the lack of creditable judicial citation.169

4.2. The return to a more analytical approach

Despite its stance in Tréfilunion and ENS, the GC subsequently adopted a more

analytical approach in Volkswagen and GSK. Both cases involved ‘obvious’

restrictions of competition, yet the GC undertook an effects-based approach to the

167

Supra n4 ENS. See chapter 1. 168

Ibid, para 136. 169

Particularly in ENS the comments regards the object criterion are probably obiter dicta.

Page 90: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 89

cases by looking at the market and economic context to determine the agreement’s

object.

In Volkswagen its dealers in Italy were told to sell cars to customers in Italy only. In

addition, Volkswagen implemented a split-margin system on registration of vehicles

and a bonus payment cancellation for cars sold outside Italy.170 The GC held that it

was clear from the documents taken as a whole the Commission was entitled to

conclude that, as a result of the agreements, Volkswagen had the express aim of

hindering re-exportation from Italy and therefore partitioning the Italian market.171

The imposition of the quotas and bonus system was “of such a nature” to induce

Italian dealers to only sell cars in Italy.172

The GC confirmed it is settled case-law that there is no need to take account of the

actual effects of an agreement when the object is to restrict competition. The

Court expressed the rule differently, however, by stating that “it is not necessary to

show actual anticompetitive effects where the anticompetitive object of the

conduct is proved”.173 Previously, the case law focused on whether it ‘appears’ that

the object is to restrict competition or that the effect on competition is ‘sufficiently

deleterious’ before the ‘consequences’ are considered.174

The significance of this divergent terminology is unclear, but could be rationalised

as follows: under the approach in Tréfilunion and ENS, an agreement of a

particularly pernicious type, such as price fixing, automatically restricts competition

by object. In Volkswagen, the GC apparently requires proof of anticompetitive

effects to demonstrate an anticompetitive object. The GC’s proof requirement

seems to rest on two elements. First, the judgment focuses on the aims of the

agreement based on its content in order to satisfy that the object was to restrict

competition. Secondly, the GC considers the agreement in its relevant economic

context. This may be inferred from the Court’s consideration of the need for a

170

T-62/98 Volkswagen AG v Commission [2000] ECR II 2707. 171

Ibid, para 88. 172

Ibid, para 89. 173

Ibid, para 178. 174

See STM and Consten & Grundig (supra n2 and n27).

Page 91: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 90

market definition. The GC held that when applying Article 101 TFEU, the reason for

defining the market, if at all (emphasis added), is to determine whether the

agreement or concerted practice is liable to affect trade and has as its object or

effect the restriction of competition.175 It found the Commission is thus obliged to

define the market where it is impossible without such a definition to determine

whether the agreement has as its object or effect the restriction of competition.176

This appears directly to contradict the judgment in ENS where it was held that

obvious restrictions require no such analysis.177

As a result of the GC’s reasoning, it can be implied that in order to prove the object

of an agreement is to restrict competition, it is not enough to state that certain

restrictions automatically infringe competition by object.

4.2.1. GlaxoSmithKline

In view of the impact that the GC’s judgment in GSK had on the general perception

of restrictions by object, it warrants careful consideration.178 The judgment

triggered an intense, though overdue, academic debate on the legal interpretation

of the object criterion and also encapsulated the GC’s more ambitious assertions.

Here the GC reversed the Commission’s decision that GlaxoSmithKline’s general

sales conditions restricted competition by reason of their object, though it upheld

the finding that the agreement was a restriction of competition by effect. The case

concerned the general sales conditions of GlaxoSmithKline in respect of its

wholesalers in Spain. In particular, clause 4 (which was contained within the

general sales conditions) provided for a dual pricing system. This meant that there

was a distinction between prices charged to Spanish wholesalers in the case of

175

Supra n170, Volkswagen, para 230. 176

Ibid, para 230. The GC then cites ENS, paras 93 to 95 and 105 in support. The GC does not refer to para 136 of ENS, which directly contradicts this. Alternatively, the GC may not have intended any real significance to be placed on its use of wording: arguably all it meant was that no actual effects need be taken into account when the object of an agreement is to restrict competition. 177

Supra n170, Volkswagen, para 178. By using the word “proved” the GC raised the bar in terms of the standard of proof required to determine the object of an agreement. This also implies it is imperative that the object element is fully discharged before turning to the effects of an agreement. 178

Supra n73 GSK.

Page 92: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 91

domestic resale and higher prices charged in the case of exports to any other

Member State.179

The GC examined in detail whether clause 4 of the general sales conditions was a

restriction of competition.180 To give a context to its findings, the GC made some

bold assertions. It held that the competition referred to in Article 101 TFEU “is

taken to mean effective competition, that is to say, the degree of competition

necessary to ensure the attainment of the objectives of the Treaty”.181 It

reaffirmed that price competition is not the only effective form of competition or

that to which all absolute priority must be given.182 As such:

“...a restriction of competition within the meaning of Article 101

must take account of the actual framework and, therefore, of the

legal and economic context in which the agreement to which that

restriction is imputed is deployed. Such an obligation is imposed

for the purpose of ascertaining both the object and effect of the

agreement.”183

It went on to say that, when the examination of the clauses within the agreement,

carried out in their legal and economic context, reveals in itself the “alteration of

the existence of competition, it may be presumed that that agreement has as its

object the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition”.184

This context is crucial. Effectively, the GC confirmed the majority of the CJEU’s case

law set out in the sections above. It reaffirmed the need for an examination of the

agreement within its ‘legal and economic context’. The GC also underlines that

assumptions regarding certain types of anticompetitive behaviour, such as hardcore

restrictions, which even the parties themselves acknowledge they intend to impose,

is not enough to ensure that those sorts of restrictions are automatically restrictive

by object. Therefore, any presumption that a particular type of restriction is a

179

Article 1 of Decision 2001/791/EC, OJ L 302 of 17.11.2001. 180

Supra, n73 GSK, para 109 onwards. 181

Ibid, para 109. 182

Ibid, para 109, see also C-26/76 Metro v Commission [1977] ECR 1875, paras 20 and 21. 183

Ibid, para 110. Citing STM, Consten and Grundig (supra n2 and n27), Case C-399/93 Oude Luttikhuis and Others v Verenigde Melkindustrie [1995] ECR I-4515. 184

Ibid GSK, para 111.

Page 93: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 92

restriction by virtue of its object is rebuttable under Article 101(1) TFEU. The GC

explained that:

“...having regard to the legal and economic context, the

Commission could not rely on the mere fact that Clause 4 of the

General Sales Conditions established a system of differentiated

price intended to limit parallel trade as the basis for its conclusion

that that provision had as its object the restriction of

competition.”185

However, the Court’s subsequent requirement that an agreement requires an

analysis to determine whether the object or effect of the agreement is to restrict

competition to the detriment of the final consumer was, correctly, rejected by the

Court of Justice on appeal.186 Notably, the CJEU did not reject the requirement that

regard must be had to the ‘legal and economic context’ within an object

assessment.187

What is so fascinating about the GC’s judgment is that, despite its general reception

as anomalous, within the context of much of the Court of Justice’s case law the GC’s

reasoning is not unusual. The court also proffered an interesting way of describing

the analysis of object stating that, it “may be abridged when the clauses of the

agreement reveal in themselves the existence of an alteration of

competition...[though] must on the other hand, be supplemented, depending on

the requirements of the case, where that is not so”.188

The relevance of the ability to undertake an abridged analysis of object is also

underlined by the judgment in Consten & Grundig. The GC found in GSK that the

Court of Justice in Consten & Grundig never held that an agreement intended to

limit parallel trade must be considered ‘by its nature’ (which, for the first time, is

defined as “independently of any competitive analysis”) to have as its object the

185

Ibid, para 117. 186

Ibid, para 119. See C-501/06 P GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission (GSK) [2009] ECR I-9291, paras 63-64. Lasok QC considers that proof of the anticompetitive nature of an agreement generates a rebuttable presumption of consumer detriment: (Lasok QC, 2008). 187

Ibid C-501/06 P GSK, para 58. 188

Supra n73, GSK, para 119. This is also in line with the judgment in Volkswagen supra n170, para 230.

Page 94: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 93

restriction of competition.189 The GC stated that the Court of Justice in Consten &

Grundig carried out an analysis of the agreement that was “abridged but real”.190

The GC makes clear that it is not enough to presume that certain agreements

automatically restrict competition, though it alludes to the fact there is a rebuttable

presumption of harm.191 Instead, an evaluation of the terms of the agreement,

within its legal and economic context, is required to determine if the object is

indeed to restrict competition. The GC also gave the Commission short shrift for

merely drawing parallels with its previous decisional practice as the basis upon

which it found the agreement restrictive by object.192 Doing so ignores the

elements of a legal and economic context, “which are not present in the decisions

adopted pursuant to Article [101](1) to which the Commission referred”.193

The GC also carried out an analysis of the main characteristics of the legal and

economic context by examining how the medicines were priced and noting the

significant price differentials between Member States due to the lack of

harmonisation.194 The Commission is even criticised by the GC for not examining

the “specific and essential characteristic of the sector, which would show that

medical products are significantly shielded from the free play of supply and demand

unlike the prices of other consumer goods”. This means that it cannot be that

presumed parallel trade has an impact on the prices charged to the final

consumer.195 The examination of the legal and economic context undertaken by

the GC of clause 4 does not therefore reveal in itself that competition is

restricted.196

As a result, the GC found that it could not uphold the Commission’s decision that

clause 4 of the general sales conditions constituted an infringement of Article

189

Ibid, para 120. It has been generally considered that Consten & Grundig is authority for the contention that agreements limiting parallel trade are automatically restrictive by object. 190

Ibid, para 120. 191

Ibid, paras 116-122. 192

Ibid para 138. 193

Ibid para 138. 194

Ibid, paras 124 to 136. 195

Ibid, para 133 to 134. 196

Ibid, para 136.

Page 95: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 94

101(1) by reason of its object.197 It held that due to the nature of the

pharmaceutical market it cannot be taken for granted at the outset that parallel

trade tends to reduce prices and therefore increase the welfare of final consumers.

The GC does, however, add a caveat to its judgment. It states that this is a “largely

unprecedented situation”.198 Thus most agreements intending to restrict parallel

trade are likely still to be found to have the object of restricting competition.

Ultimately, the GC’s judgment in GSK takes the principles set out in the STM Test

and confirms the assessment that should be undertaken when determining the

object of an agreement. It emphasises the application of the legal and economic

context, the importance of uncovering the purpose of the agreement and assessing

each case on its merits. The judgment is a salutary reminder that past precedent

alone cannot condemn an agreement as restrictive by object.

Whether the GC was correct to hold that the agreement did not restrict

competition by object is moot. Rather, the significance of the judgment is that it

legitimately questions the orthodox approach and as such the position taken by the

Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines. Certainly, the GC went out of its way to

hold that the agreement did not restrict competition by virtue of its object, despite

agreeing with the Commission that the agreement had the effect of restricting

competition. This alone stresses the importance of the distinction between object

and effect.

4.3. Conclusion: case law of the General Court

The four GC judgments discussed above clearly illustrate the GC’s divergent

approach to object cases. The GC veers between applying the more analytical and

the orthodox approaches, the latter of which it has apparently devised on its own

accord.199 The reason behind such diversity is unclear, but the judgments leave it

197

Ibid, para 147. 198

Ibid, para 147. 199

The MAAP is also reflected in judgments such as Joined Cases T-68/89 etc Società Italiana Vetro SpA v Commission [1992] ECR II-01403 and T-29/92 SPO v Commission [1995] ECR II-289. In SPO the GC held that when applying Article 101, the reason for defining the market is to determine whether

Page 96: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 95

unsurprising that the object criterion is subject to so much confusion and

misunderstanding. These cases also raise some interesting issues. These relate,

inter alia, to the role of legal presumptions, the significance of the requirement that

concrete effects do not need to be demonstrated (and as such the distinction

between object and effect) as well as the categorisation of ‘obvious’ restrictions.

The judgments in Tréfilunion and ENS, in particular, are anomalous and their legal

basis precarious. Hence, the emphasis placed on these cases is questionable given

their lack of credible judicial support.

What this means for the Commission’s approach in its Article 81(3) Guidelines is

further cause for concern. Although the Commission does not cite any GC case law

in its Article 81(3) Guidelines (aside from an incorrect citation of Volkswagen in

paragraph 23), it would seem clear from its tenor that Tréfilunion and ENS are the

source of the Commission’s stance.200 Furthermore, it is increasingly clear that the

Commission does indeed sympathise with and follow the principles of the more

analytical approach.201 Where this then leaves the Article 81(3) Guidelines is

uncertain. Both the GC and the CJEU, rendered judgments concurrent with the

Commission’s drafting of the Article 81(3) Guidelines that follow the more analytical

path. Hence, the foundations of the Commission’s stance on the object concept are

not obvious. The only sensible answer is that they reflect a policy approach; the

Guidelines are certainly not an accurate reflection of the law.

5. Conclusion: Part I

This review of the jurisprudential back-catalogue of the European Courts

demonstrates that the CJEU devised an analytical approach to the object criterion,

which the GC has largely upheld. The STM Test sets out a clear basis upon which to

determine an agreement’s object and the judgment has constituted a significant

part of the legal landscape since the CJEU’s earliest proclamations on Article 101

TFEU. Furthermore, the case law of both Courts reveals that the MAAP reflects the

the agreement is liable to affect trade and has as its object or effect the restriction of competition: para 74. 200

Demonstrated most prominently in paras 21 and 22 of the Article 81(3) Guidelines. 201

See for eg its submissions to the CJEU in BIDS (supra n3) infra n214.

Page 97: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 96

most prominent interpretation of the law on the object concept. Conversely, the

orthodox approach enjoys less judicial support and what support it does have is

easily challenged. Whether this conclusion still stands in the light of an

examination of the CJEU’s more recent case law, and the subsequent emergence of

the ‘hybrid approach’ to the object criterion is considered in Part II of this chapter.

Page 98: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 97

Part II: How the European Courts have interpreted the meaning and application of the object criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU: the metamorphosis of the more analytical approach

1. Introduction

Part II of chapter 2 undertakes a more focused examination of the jurisprudence of

the CJEU following the judgment of the GC in GSK. It investigates how the concept

of object has evolved and the degree of influence (if any) that the GC imparts on

the CJEU. It will become evident that there is little reliance on the GC’s case law.

Instead, the most influential case in the evolution of the object concept continues

to hark back to the earliest days of the Community’s jurisprudence: Société

Technique Minière (STM).202 The discord between the jurisprudence and the

eminence of the orthodox approach is exemplified by the identification of a third

key approach to the object criterion, which emerges more clearly during this

period. This is the ‘hybrid approach’.

The hybrid approach is a crude amalgamation of the orthodox and more analytical

approaches.203 The case law in Part II therefore confirms a significant finding first

revealed in Part I: that the more analytical approach garners greater support in law

than the orthodox approach. This queries the origins of the orthodox approach as a

legal methodology. The judgments reviewed in Part II continue to emphasise the

concern that the Commission fails to distinguish between its preferred policy

approach and the law in its Article 81(3) Guidelines.204 It is imprudent simply to

dismiss the orthodox approach, however, as it has shaped a key element of the

hybrid approach. A more intriguing issue, therefore, is how far the Commission’s

policy has influenced the CJEU’s interpretation of the law in recent years, given the

CJEU’s increased use of orthodox terminology.

To demonstrate the emergence of the hybrid approach, Part II focuses on three

prominent judgments. These drew long overdue attention to the mechanics and

202

Supra n2, Case C-56/65 STM. 203

It draws on some of the language of the orthodox approach and the methodology of the analytical approach. 204

Equally, that the Commission does not always follow its own Guidelines.

Page 99: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 98

interpretation of the object concept. More particularly, the judgments signalled a

shift in academic debate and a growing consensus that the orthodox approach,

adopted by the Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines, is too limited and

formalistic.205 Hence, these cases are referred to as the ‘Game Changer Cases’.

2. The European Court of Justice: the dawn of the hybrid approach

2.1. The Game Changer Cases

In conjunction with the GC’s judgment in GSK, the CJEU’s judgments in BIDS, T-

Mobile, and GSK signalled a greater appreciation of the nuances of the object

criterion by the academic community. Unlike much previous case law, these cases

revolve specifically around the concept of object. Given the specific need in these

cases for the CJEU to rule directly on ‘object’, the expectation was that the Court

would take the time to clarify the more uncharted and complex areas of this

substantive element of Article 101(1) TFEU.206 Some commentators assumed the

CJEU would confirm the orthodox approach to object restrictions, in particular, by

“rectifying” the General Court’s judgments in GSK.207 To a limited extent, this has

been the case.208 However, the lasting legacy of these cases is to devise a hybrid

approach. In terms of the position adopted in this thesis, the cases reaffirm the

significance of the MAAP adopted in STM. They also accord a certain legitimacy to

the orthodox approach, which consequently continues to linger within the case law.

205

The debate previously centred on the contents of the object category, rather than its application. Note that judgments subsequent to the ones detailed in Part II are examined more appropriately in the ensuing chapters as the function of this Part II is to establish the hybrid approach. 206

In BIDS (supra n3) the following question was referred: “…for the purposes of application of Article 81(1) EC, to have an appreciable effect on trade between Member States, is such arrangement to be regarded as having as its object, as distinct from effect, the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the common market and therefore, incompatible with Article 101(1)?”. In T-Mobile (supra n2), the question was “…when applying Article 101(1), which criteria must be applied when assessing whether a concerted practice has as its object the…restriction of competition?”. 207

This position was extracted from various comments made at the Vertical Block Exemption conference at UCL in 2009. 208

A case in point is the CJEU’s understanding of the distinction between object and effect: T-Mobile (supra n2), para 28. Also the CJEU’s judgment in GlaxoSmithKline (supra n186) would seem to support this position.

Page 100: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 99

Although there was ample scope to conduct a careful assessment of the object

criterion, the level of analysis and clarification undertaken by the CJEU was largely

disappointing, despite detailed opinions being offered by the AGs. This was

compounded by its contradictory handling of the object criterion in so far as the

CJEU appeared to be genuinely confused about what the object concept is there to

achieve.209 By referencing STM, the CJEU demonstrated its recognition of the

analytical approach to object cases, but then used language which seemingly

endorsed and gave legitimacy to the orthodox approach.210 This uneasy tug of war

between the two key approaches to restrictions by object underlines the

importance of uncovering the fundamental essence and constituent elements that

form the object concept.

2.1.1. BIDS

On 4 September 2008, AG Trstenjak handed down a comprehensive and compelling

opinion in Beef Industry Development Society Ltd (BIDS).211 The opinion superbly

demonstrates the complexities, inconsistencies and confusion surrounding the

concept of object in contrast to the simplicity of the orthodox approach, which is

why it is recounted in some detail. The Supreme Court in Ireland made a

preliminary reference to the CJEU and asked the Court to interpret the “notion of

restriction of competition by object”.212 BIDS is an important case as it does not

concern a classic ‘object box’ restriction, but rather a number of what are more

typically seen as restrictions by effect, such as non-compete clauses and other

restrictions on the parties’ freedom to act.213

209

This is evidenced by the way the CJEU describes how object should be applied to agreements versus the reasoning it provides for the distinction between object and effect (see below). This correlates with the question of what competition law is there to protect or achieve. 210

See BIDS, para 17 (supra n3). 211

BIDS (supra n3). The case concerned the Irish beef processing industry, whereby the processors wished to reduce the overcapacity in the Irish processing industry through agreements developed by BIDS (whose members produce about 93% of the beef sold in Ireland). BIDS was set up to implement a market study commissioned by the Irish government. Paras 23 to 33 of AG Trstenjak’s opinion give a flavour of the different opinions on how object should be interpreted. 212

Ibid, para 1 of the opinion. Preliminary references are important as the CJEU must give its interpretation of the law. 213

See eg Wouters (supra n119).

Page 101: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 100

The opinion highlights that the assessment criteria put forward by the Commission

in its Article 81(3) Guidelines are deficient.214 The permeation of the orthodox

approach throughout the various Member States is evident at the outset of the

case. When the Irish Competition Authority challenged the legality of the

agreements devised by BIDS to reduce the over-capacity in the Irish processing

industry, the Irish High Court held that the agreements did not fall under Article

101(1) TFEU because the agreements did not have as their object the restriction of

competition as the agreements were “not aimed at fixing prices, sharing customers,

or limiting production for the purposes of Article 101(1)(a) to (c) TFEU”.215

In stark contrast, AG Trstenjak advocated an analytical and economic approach to

assessing object cases.216 She confirmed that in order to assess whether an

agreement has as its object the restriction of competition, “regard must be had to

the content of the agreement in the light of its legal and economic context”.217 If

the object of an agreement is to restrict competition, then it is irrelevant whether

“it actually has as its effect the restriction of competition”.218

Turning to the meaning and purpose of restrictions of competition by object, she

referred to the “anti-competitive aim or tendency of an agreement”.219 This is

found “in particular” where the “necessary consequence” of the agreement is the

restriction of competition, and “in principle” the parties may not argue they did not

intend any restriction or that the agreement pursed a different aim.220 Significantly,

the AG did not define what she meant by ‘necessary consequence’ though she used

214

Despite the wording of the Article 81(3) Guidelines, this can be contrasted with the Commission’s own submissions in the case. It agreed in paragraph 23 of the opinion that “in examining whether there is a restriction of competition by object, regard must be had not only to the content of the agreement, but also to the legal and economic context” [emphasis added]. It also found that the concept of restriction of competition by object is not limited to hardcore restrictions, but also encompasses agreements which have a “legitimate objective” and that restrictions do not need to be “obvious”. 215

BIDS (supra n3), para 16 of the opinion. 216

Ibid, paras 62 onwards. 217

Ibid, para 43. 218

Ibid, para 37. 219

Ibid, para 44. 220

Ibid, para 44.

Page 102: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 101

Miller as a case citation.221 The choice of wording suggests that the AG recognised

that the object criterion relates to the aim of the agreement. Such aim usually, but

not exclusively, relates to situations where the anticompetitive effects of certain

types of agreement are known. She also recognised that it is not a defence for

parties to contend they did not intentionally infringe the rules. Moreover, the AG

made an interesting analogy: she suggested that object is designed as a form of

inchoate offence and that regard is to be had not solely to the necessary

consequences of an agreement.222 Therefore, the parties to the agreement do not

need to put into practice their restrictive actions in order to infringe Article 101(1)

TFEU by object.

As a result, the AG considered that “it is clear that the category of restrictions of

competition by object cannot be reduced to agreements which obviously restrict

competition”.223 Likewise, there is no exhaustive list of object restrictions. Object

is not limited to restrictions of competition covered in Article 101(1)(a) to (c) TFEU

and is not reduced to price-fixing, market sharing or control of outlets.224 Merely

because the Community Courts have considered hardcore restrictions in many

object cases “does not mean that agreements with another purpose cannot [also]

have as their object the restriction of competition”.225 This was one of the first

times that the categorisation of the object criterion was so obviously rejected.

In order to examine whether an agreement has as its object the restriction of

competition:

“First of all it must be considered whether such agreements have

restrictions of competition as their necessary consequence or are

aimed at limiting the freedom of the parties to determine their

221

The problems with the judgment in Miller (supra n88) were described in section 2.2 of Part I. 222

BIDS (supra n3), para 46. According to the Crown Prosecution Service inchoate offences are those where a substantive offence may not have come to completion, but nevertheless an offence has been committed because of actions or agreements in preparation for the substantive offence. 223

Ibid, para 47. 224

Ibid, paras 48 and 49. 225

Ibid, para 49. The AG also criticised Whish, to an extent, by finding his interpretation of object was “very restrictive” (and stated she considered it doubtful whether a category of restrictions of competition exist per se). She stated her position more firmly in her opinion in GSK, (supra n186) paras 108 and 109.

Page 103: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 102

policy on the market independently and thereby at affecting

market conditions. Subsequently it must be examined as part of

an overall assessment whether the restrictive elements are

necessary in order to achieve a pro-competitive object or a

primary objective which does not come under the fundamental

prohibition contained in Article 101(1).”226

At the time, this was seen as an extraordinary statement. The case law review

shows, however, that AG’s Trstenjak’s interpretation of the law is not without

merit. Moreover, her opinion highlighted the limited role assigned to the object

criterion by the Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines. The value of the legal

context, which includes past precedent and thus its necessary effect, is not

conclusive when determining an agreement’s object in accordance with its actual

legal and economic context.227

2.1.1.1. The judgment

The judgment in BIDS is significant, as it cited STM as authority for the proposition

that first the precise purpose of an agreement must be considered within its

economic context and should “an analysis of the clauses” not reveal the “effect on

competition to be sufficiently deleterious, its consequences should then be

considered”.228 It thus reinforced the need for the object of an agreement to be

determined within its economic context.229 To that end, the CJEU found that based

on the contents of the agreement within its economic context, the essence of the

object criterion goes to determining “the objectives which [the agreement] is

intended to attain”.230 Therefore, finding that the parties lacked the subjective

intention to restrict competition or indeed intended to remedy, in this case, the

failing Irish Beef industry, may be irrelevant if the contents of the agreement within

226

Ibid BIDS, para 60. The AG is possibly drawing on the AG’s opinion in Gøttrup Klim. 227

Ibid, in para 104 the AG states that the content of an agreement must always be examined against the background of its legal and economic context. Comparing agreements is not always the correct approach and may fail to address the question of when a restriction by object exists. 228

BIDS, judgment (supra n3), para 15. 229

Ibid, paras 15-16. 230

Ibid, para 21.

Page 104: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 103

its legal and economic context establishes a restrictive object.231 Repeating the

understanding handed down in General Motors, the CJEU held that “an agreement

may be regarded as having a restrictive object even if it does not have the

restriction of competition as its sole aim but also pursues other legitimate

objectives. It is only in connection with Article 81(3) EC that matters such as those

relied upon by BIDS may, if appropriate, be taken into consideration for the

purposes of obtaining an exemption from the prohibition laid down in Article 81(1)

EC”.232

The CJEU found that as the agreements did not allow each undertaking to

determine independently the policy which it intended to adopt on the common

market, the agreements had the object of restricting competition.233 In reaching

this conclusion, however, the CJEU took account not only of the structure of the

market and the position of the parties on it, but also the potential effects of the

BIDS arrangements.234 For instance, the CJEU considered that as “the investment

necessary for the construction of a new processing plant is much greater than the

costs of taking over an existing plant, those restrictions are obviously intended to

dissuade any new entry of competitors throughout the island of Ireland”.235

One of the most striking elements of the judgment is the CJEU’s interpretation of

the distinction between object and effect, which despite AG Trstenjak’s opinion, it

decided to describe in its own terms. This was said to arise “from the fact that

certain forms of collusion between undertakings can be regarded, by their very

nature, as being injurious to the proper functioning of normal competition”.236 This

contrasts with the view of the AG who argued that the aim of an agreement usually,

231

Ibid BIDS, para 21. Also paras 22-40. The parties argued the aim was to improve the overall profitability of undertakings supplying more than 90% of the beef/veal processing services on the Irish market (note that the market was defined for this purpose, para 32). 232

Ibid, para 21 (emphasis added); General Motors (supra n125), para 64 and the case-law cited. 233

Ibid BIDS, paras 34 and 36. According to the CJEU, this confirms long established case law such as C-96/82 IAZ/Anseau and C-235/92 P Montecatini v Commission (supra n61 and n133). The judgment in BIDS also confirms that it is irrelevant that the parties did not intend to restrict competition (para 21). 234

Ibid BIDS, in particular paras 29-38. 235

Ibid, para 38. 236

Ibid, para 17. The CJEU does not clarify what any of the elements of this statement mean, such as “normal competition”.

Page 105: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 104

but not exclusively, relates to situations where the anticompetitive effects of a

certain type of agreement are known.237 The CJEU did disagree, however, with

BIDS’ submission that:

“...the concept of infringement by object should be interpreted

narrowly. Only agreements as to horizontal price-fixing, or to limit

output or share markets, agreements whose anti-competitive

effects are so obvious as not to require an economic analysis

come within that category.”238

Instead, it held that the types of agreements covered by Article 101(1)(a) to (e)

TFEU do not form an exhaustive list of prohibited collusion.239 The inherent

contradiction, though, between the CJEU’s depiction of the distinction between

object and effect and its rejection of the submission that object should be

interpreted narrowly is ultimately unhelpful and simply fuels speculation. The

Court’s failure to provide judicial support for its understanding of the object/effect

dichotomy means that it is impossible to say definitively how the dichotomy should

be interpreted, particularly as the judgment emphasises the importance of STM.240

2.1.2. T-Mobile

For the purposes of this chapter, the significance of T-Mobile is that the Court

concludes that STM, is to be treated as the leading case when assessing an

agreement to determine its object.241 Again, the CJEU finds that “since STM, it has

been settled case law and it is necessary first to consider the precise purpose of the

concerted practice, in the economic context in which it is to be pursued”.242 Where

“an analysis of the terms of the concerted practice does not reveal the effect on

competition to be sufficiently deleterious, its consequences should then be

237

Ibid, opinion, paras 44, 46. Also see para 104 where AG Trstenjak warns against the comparison of agreements. 238

Ibid, BIDS judgment, para 22. 239

Ibid, para 23 confirming the AG’s opinion. 240

These issues will be considered in the ensuing chapters. 241

Supra n2 T-Mobile, para 28; also GSK (supra n186), para 55. This reinforces the judgment in BIDS. 242

Ibid, T-Mobile, para 28 (emphasis added). See also para 27 (referring to IAZ/Anseau para 25 and BIDS paras 16 and 21): when assessing a concerted practice, the CJEU reaffirmed that “close regard must be paid in particular to the objectives which it is intended to attain and to its economic and legal context”.

Page 106: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 105

considered and, for it to be caught by the prohibition, it is necessary to find that

those factors are present which establish that competition has in fact

been…restricted…to an appreciable extent”.243 Therefore, there is “no need to take

into account the actual effects once it is apparent that its object is to…restrict

competition within the common market”.244

Notwithstanding the clear endorsement of the judgment in STM as a case that

informs the application of the object criterion, the CJEU again chooses to express

the distinction between object and effect in the same terms as in BIDS.245 The CJEU

thereby reinforced the statement’s significance. As highlighted above, the

statement is confusing. STM suggests that there are no absolute presumptions

about the anti-competitiveness of any agreements. Therefore, theoretically, object

is not limited to hardcore or obvious restrictions of competition. It is thus in one

sense contradictory for the CJEU to refer to “certain forms of collusion…by their

nature…being injurious to the proper functioning of competition”.

One explanation for the CJEU’s reasoning is that it is actually referring to the fact

that object is distinguished from effect, because it does not require the actual or

concrete effects of an agreement to be determined. The rationale for this is that it

is known that certain restrictions have a high potential for negative effects on

competition due to experience gleaned over the years. Therefore, such restrictions

automatically restrict competition regardless of their actual effects. They are

injurious by their very nature. Conversely, it could be argued that concrete effects

do not need to be demonstrated, because if an agreement has the aim or purpose

of restricting competition that in itself is sufficient to infringe Article 101(1) TFEU.

243

Ibid, T-Mobile para 28. However, the CJEU used BIDS para 15 as its citation as opposed to STM. 244

Ibid, para 29. The CJEU cites Consten & Grundig para 342; C-105/04 P Nederlandse Federatieve Verenigung [2006] ECR I-08725, para 125; BIDS para 16. 245

Ibid, T-Mobile para 29. The CJEU cites BIDS as the authority, which itself cites no authority for the proposition.

Page 107: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 106

This is a complex issue and therefore the merits of these arguments will be pursued

in subsequent chapters.246

In T-Mobile, the CJEU found that for a concerted practice to have the object of

restricting competition, it is sufficient that it has the “potential to have a negative

impact on competition”. That is, “the concerted practice must simply be capable in

an individual case, having regard to the specific legal and economic context, of

resulting in the…restriction of competition within the common market.”247 Not that

it must restrict competition. This propensity to affect competition is a condition

which must be satisfied under the object criterion.248 The statement in T-Mobile is

arguably a derivative of the principal first established in STM: that if the effect on

competition is not “sufficiently deleterious” then the actual consequences of the

agreement require determination and that an agreement does not need to be

successful.249 In T-Mobile, the Court held that if it is found that such

anticompetitive effects do result from the agreement, then the actual effects are

only relevant when determining the amount of any fine and assessing any claim for

damages.250 The implication of this finding is controversial. Some commentators

interpreted the judgment in T-Mobile as implying that standard of proof was

reduced further for restrictions by object.251 Such a conclusion is not, however,

necessarily implicit as can be seen in more recent CJEU judgments.252

More particularly, the case concerned a horizontal exchange of information and the

CJEU held that an exchange of information which is capable of removing

uncertainties between participants of a concerted practice regarding the “timing,

246

For the first time the CJEU seemingly elucidated on this very issue in Cartes Bancaires (supra n97), where it favoured the rationale of the necessary effect of certain types of agreement, para 51. However, the judgment requires careful consideration. 247

Supra n2, T-Mobile, para 31. 248

Hence the importance of a contextual analysis. Though the agreement does not need to be successful, as held in Miller (supra n88), General Motors (supra n125) and Sandoz (supra n76). Issues such as the neutrality of an agreement or that an agreement is incapable of effecting competition (because it is de minimis) and hence the significance of market power are considered in chapters 4 and 5. 249

Supra n2, STM, p249. 250

Supra n2, T-Mobile, para 31. 251

As noted at the BIICL conference on ‘Object/Effect’ held on 6 October 2010. 252

See Cartes Bancaires (supra n97).

Page 108: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 107

extent and details of the modifications to be adopted by the undertaking

concerned” will have an anti-competitive object.253 Nevertheless, in its assessment

the CJEU made reference to the nature of the products, the size and number of

undertakings involved and the volume of that market.254 The judgment therefore

confirms the emergence of the hybrid approach as, despite upholding a number of

key principles established in earlier case law supporting the MAAP, it references the

BIDS object/effect distinction. The implications of this are investigated in the

following chapters.

2.1.3. GlaxoSmithKline

The final case reported in this section is the CJEU’s judgment in GSK.255 In light of

the GC’s controversial judgment, this judgment was highly anticipated.

Disappointingly, the CJEU did not rise to the challenge of rigorously examining the

GC’s analysis of object.256 Instead, it would appear that the CJEU’s main objective

was to reject, with strong evidential support, the GC’s proposition that proving an

“agreement entails disadvantages for final consumers being a prerequisite for a

finding of object”.257 Furthermore, the judgment substantiates the place of the

hybrid approach alongside the orthodox approach and the MAAP.

The pre-eminence of STM as the leading case on determining restrictions by object

is referred to as “settled case-law”.258 The CJEU reverts, however, to language

more suited to the orthodox approach (as it did in BIDS and T-Mobile). The CJEU

refers to how the “anti-competitive nature” of an agreement should be assessed,

but then reiterates the STM Test.259 More intriguingly given that GlaxoSmithKline

253

Supra n2, T-Mobile, para 41. 254

Ibid, para 33. 255

Supra n186, GSK. 256

The CJEU had a wide remit in which to assess restrictions by object as it was examining whether the General Court committed an error of law in its assessment of the anti-competitive object of the agreement. Para 57 of the judgment demonstrates that the CJEU’s purpose is to ascertain if the GC’s assessment of object is “in accordance with the principles extracted from the relevant case-law”. This also highlights why the case law analysis within this chapter is so crucial in understanding the concept of object versus the Commission’s approach to object cases. 257

Supra n186, GSK, para 64. 258

Ibid, para 55. Note that the CJEU also refers to the “aim” of the agreement in para 59. 259

Ibid, para 58.

Page 109: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 108

admitted it had the intention of deterring parallel imports, it is significant that this

factor alone was deemed insufficient to determine the object of the agreement.

Instead the CJEU recounted the well-known principal that the parties’ subjective

intention is not a necessary factor in the objective assessment of an agreement’s

object, but can be taken into account.

When reflecting on the issue of parallel trade, the Court is unclear on the question

of whether there is a rebuttable (or irrebuttable) presumption that agreements

aiming to restrict parallel trade have the object of preventing competition. This is

because of a lack of consistency in the CJEU’s turn of phrase.260 Instead it finds,

correctly, that the GC committed an error of law as “requiring proof that the

agreement entails disadvantages for final consumers as a prerequisite for a finding

of anti-competitive object”.261 The CJEU takes this a step further, however, by

finding that the GC also committed an error in law as it did not find that the

agreement had the object of restricting competition.262 Other than a reliance on

the fact that the Court has “on a number of occasions” held that an agreement

aimed at limiting parallel trade is a restriction of competition by object, this

statement of the CJEU is fairly weak in light of its historical case law which has not

always supported such a contention.263 Nevertheless, it is notable that the CJEU

does not overturn the GC’s references to STM and hence the MAAP.

The judgment thus upholds the hybrid approach as it endorses the categorisation of

the object criterion as per the orthodox approach, but approves the methodology

postulated under the more analytical approach in view of its references to STM.

Unhelpfully, the CJEU chooses not to examine the concept of necessary effect, nor

the reason for the distinction between object and effect or the role of the object

criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU. Instead, the judgment leaves the impression

260

For instance, despite confirming the importance of STM, in paragraph 60 of the judgment, the Court states that agreements “aimed” at prohibiting or limiting parallel trade have “in principle” as their object the restriction of competition. The Court then muddies this statement by asserting “that principle, according to which an agreement aimed at limiting parallel trade is a restriction of competition by object”. 261

Ibid, para 64. 262

Ibid, para 64. 263

Ibid, para 61. See eg, Louis Erauw (supra n69).

Page 110: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 109

that the CJEU wanted swiftly to end speculation over the consumer detriment

aspect of the GC’s judgment, and thus glossed over more pertinent issues.

2.2. Conclusion: the Game Changer Cases

Even though the Game Changer Cases reflect a relatively brief period of the CJEU’s

jurisprudence,264 they ignited an important debate regarding the assessment and

function of the object criterion. They do not, however, signal a ringing

endorsement of the orthodox approach advocated within the Article 81(3)

Guidelines, nor do they blur the lines between restrictions by object and by effect.

Rather, they confirm an aspect of the CJEU’s jurisprudence that had been largely

overlooked: that of the more analytical approach. Following the case law review in

Part I, the judgment in STM is seen to continue to influence the CJEU to a greater

degree than, for instance, the GC’s judgment in ENS. However, the Game Changer

Cases did initiate a key development in the evolution of the MAAP. This was by

formalising a third approach to the object criterion, the hybrid approach.265

The hybrid approach emerged as all three judgments found that the methodology

applied to determine if an agreement is restrictive by object did not depart

dramatically from the original STM Test, but despite this acknowledgment, the

distinction between object and effect was presented in orthodox terms. Hence the

language of the orthodox approach, through the use of phrases such as ‘by its very

nature’, was revitalised. The concern with the hybrid approach stems from the fact

the CJEU did not explain, at this juncture, its rationale for such description of the

dichotomy. Furthermore, this blend of the orthodox and more analytical

approaches appears contradictory if the application of the legal and economic

context is taken seriously. The judgment in BIDS, in particular, exposes this

paradoxical approach when the CJEU recognises the limitations of an exhaustive

category of agreements.

264

The CJEU’s judgment in BIDS was rendered on 20 November 2008, T-Mobile on 4 June 2009 and GSK on 6 October 2009. 265

See also AG Kokott in T-Mobile and AG Trstenjak’s subsequent opinion in GSK. See chapter 4 for a more in-depth discussion of the scholarly commentary on this issue.

Page 111: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 110

Therefore it must be surmised that the hybrid approach is more fluid that the

orthodox approach. In particular, any categorisation of agreements automatically

seen to restrict competition by object must be deemed a rebuttable presumption

under Article 101(1) TFEU owing to the analysis of the ‘legal and economic context’

required under STM. Notably, the AGs in these cases were better orientated

towards providing more detailed elucidations of the more complex characteristics

of the object criterion.

The fact the CJEU overturned the GC’s judgment in GSK in the respect that it held

the agreement was indeed restrictive by object is not of great concern, as the more

important factor is how the CJEU recounted the application of the law. It upheld

the requirement that an agreement’s legal and economic context plays the central

role when determining its object and, upon its own application, decided that the GC

was wrong. Such a requirement had been overshadowed by the Article 81(3)

Guidelines, which do not reference the legal and economic context determinatively.

More recent case law continues to uphold the hybrid approach, which also

highlights the unsatisfactory nature of the Article 81(3) Guidelines, particularly as

the Commission tends to follow the hybrid approach in its decisional practice as

opposed to its own Article 81(3) Guidelines.266

3. Overall conclusion: Parts I and II

The purpose of this chapter was to scrutinise how the meaning and application of

restrictions by object had been applied to agreements by the European Courts.

Such an analysis of the case law would thereby allow the testing of the accuracy of

the orthodox approach as portrayed under the Article 81(3) Guidelines. To this

end, a comprehensive review of the case law emanating from both the CJEU and GC

was undertaken.

What materialised from this review is that the Courts have approached object in

two key ways, though a third hybrid approach has evolved as an amalgamation of

266

This case law is therefore investigated further in the next chapters. The evolution of the Commission’s approach to the object criterion was mapped out in chapter 1. The Commission has veered between applying the orthodox approach and the hybrid approach.

Page 112: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 111

the two.267 One method is based on categorising those agreements that “by their

very nature” restrict competition. This approach has had the greatest influence on

the orthodox approach, which is reflected in the Commission’s Article 81(3)

Guidelines. The other key method identified from the case law was the more

analytical approach, based on the seminal case of STM. One of the most striking

aspects of this review was that the more analytical approach has greater judicial

support. The language of the orthodox approach has been found to permeate the

case law, however, particularly more recently through the development of the

hybrid approach. This is confusing.

The key differentiation is that the objective of the assessment of an agreement’s

object is different under the three approaches. The orthodox approach prescribes

that a narrow category of agreements (which are usually ‘hardcore’, ‘serious’ or

‘obvious’) are presumed to automatically restrict competition by object.268 If it is

proved that the agreement contains such a restriction, then the agreement has the

object of restricting competition. This is deemed an irrebuttable presumption

under Article 101(1) TFEU.269

On the other hand, the more analytical approach is ‘free’ insofar as there are no

preconceptions about the anti-competiveness of an agreement. Instead, the focus

is on establishing whether the aim or purpose of the agreement is to restrict

competition. To ascertain that purpose an assessment of the specific ‘legal and

economic context’ in accordance with the STM Test is required. As such, the

process is flexible and the case law demonstrates that the level of economic

analysis depends on the facts of the case and its particular context. There are no

absolute presumptions as to the anti-competitiveness of an agreement from the

outset. Therefore, potentially any restriction of competition could be a restriction

267

Arguably AG Trstenjak advanced a similar argument in her opinion in GSK (supra n186), where she refers to the “standardised approach” and an alternative approach required to assess whether there is a “sufficiently deleterious effect on competition” for those agreements that do not come within the standardised approach: paras 91-92. 268

Though the Commission reserves itself the ability to extend the object category, Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 23. 269

(Whish, 2009), pp117-118.

Page 113: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 112

by object. As such, categorisation does not exist. Under this more analytical

method, in theory, agreements that could be seen to contain hardcore restrictions

of competition may be excused under the object heading or even come outside

Article 101(1) TFEU as a whole.270 Conversely, those agreements that do not

contain hardcore restrictions could be held to have an anti-competitive object. The

case law of the CJEU and GC upholds this interpretation: there are ample examples

where prima facie hardcore restrictions of competition have not been held to be

restrictive by object and,271 conversely, agreements which do not contain obvious

or hardcore restrictions have been found to restrict competition by object.272

Despite the delineation between these approaches, the case law also reveals that

the object criterion’s role under Article 101(1) TFEU is ambiguous. This lack of

clarity is also demonstrated by the fact that the most consistent message from the

Community Courts is that STM provides the legal foundation for the application of

the object element. Hence how the MAAP, as advocated in STM, relates to the

orthodox approach requires further investigation. The case law also demonstrates

that the object concept encompasses a number of subtleties and complexities.273

For instance, indirect restrictions can be anticompetitive by object. Conversely, an

assessment of an agreement’s object can consider its pro-competitive aspects or

whether it pursues a legitimate goal or has an objective justification. As such, the

use of the object criterion as a legal tool to determine whether an agreement

restricts competition has a far greater function than that allocated to it by

Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines. The categorisation of the object

criterion under the orthodox approach has meant its assessment under Article

101(1) TFEU has been confused, unclear and over-simplified.

What can be said with certainty is that the Commission’s approach to restrictions

by object in its Article 81(3) Guidelines is an extremely limited exposition of the

270

Of course, having established that an agreement does not have the object of restricting competition it may still be found to have that effect (unless the agreement is not appreciable). 271

See eg, various ATP cases such as Louis Erauw (supra n69), GSK (GC judgment, supra n73). 272

See eg, BIDS (supra n3). 273

Such as the issue of showing the positive benefits of an agreement (Asnef Equifax, supra n72) contrasted against the legitimate objective of an agreement (BIDS, supra n3).

Page 114: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 113

correct position in law.274 Within the Article 81(3) Guidelines, the Commission has

failed to highlight that the assessment of object should be undertaken within the

legal and economic context. Furthermore, it neglected a significant portion of the

case law, particularly that emanating from the CJEU.275 Instead, the Commission

has embarked on a redefinition of the case law without alluding to the volume of

jurisprudence supporting an alternative approach to restrictions by object. This

meant that the more complex nature of the object criterion was largely ignored.

Identifying restrictions of competition by object is not as straightforward as the

orthodox approach suggests and thus the Commission belies the technical difficulty

in establishing whether an agreement is anticompetitive by object for those less

obvious cases. Therefore, the orthodox approach is unable to explain the

anomalous case law where agreements that would be condemned under the

orthodox approach are found not to restrict competition by object and vice versa.

The MAAP is able to explain such anomalies by reference to the agreements’

context and the objective aim to restrict competition.

The detail in which this chapter recounts the law is justified as it has sought to

prove overwhelmingly that the orthodox approach is not fully reflective of the case

law. In order to provide a platform from which to examine the impact this

assessment of object has on Article 101 TFEU as a whole, the following chapters will

conduct a deeper investigation into the various characteristics of the object

criterion identified in this chapter. Given the prominence of the MAAP within the

jurisprudence of the Community Courts, chapters 3 and 4 will focus more closely on

explaining what the object concept means under than approach. To this end, more

recent case law of the European Courts is drawn upon to further demonstrate how

the object criterion has evolved and ascertain whether the hybrid approach now

informs how the European Courts, and indeed the Commission, applies the object

criterion.

274

An intriguing question is the degree of influence imparted by the Commission on the European Courts following the publication of the Article 81(3) Guidelines, particularly as the hybrid approach is far more prominent post the entry into force of the Guidelines. 275

Note para 7 of the Article 81(3) Guidelines, which states that the guidelines outline the current state of the case law of the Court of Justice. Moreover, the Article 81(3) Guidelines would have been drafted prior to the case of BIDS: see Part I.

Page 115: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 114

Chapter 3: Identifying the concept of object

1. Introduction

The following two chapters are both designed to probe the features comprising the

legal structure of the object criterion, identified in chapter 2, in greater depth. This

exercise enables a comprehensive legal account of the true meaning, application

and role of the object criterion to be drawn. Having restated the case law,1 chapter

3 has two main tasks. First, it identifies the core principles of the object criterion

that are a common thread in each of the orthodox, more analytical and hybrid

approaches. These key themes are consistently upheld by the Community Courts

and are applicable irrespective of which approach is followed. Secondly, it

examines whether it is possible to elicit a clear definition of the object concept from

the case law.

2. Universal legal principles of the object criterion

It is possible to elicit from the case law a number legal principles or rules relating to

the object criterion. These principles, as general statements, are rarely disputed by

either the European Courts or in academic texts. They are universally applied no

matter how the Courts scrutinise the object of an agreement. The devil, however,

is in the detail, which gives rise to a great deal of contention as regards the precise

interpretation of these core principles.

2.1. ‘Object’ and ‘effect’ are distinct concepts

The European Courts have consistently reiterated the basic principle that an

agreement falls within the prohibition under Article 101(1) TFEU when it has as its

‘object or effect’ the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition.2

Therefore, whether an agreement restricts competition under Article 101(1) TFEU

1 See chapter 2.

2 See Joined Cases C-403 & 429/08, Football Association Premier League Ltd v QC Leisure and Karen

Murphy v Media Protection Services Ltd, [2011] ECR I- 9083 (FA), para 135 and Case C-56/65 Société Technique Minière V Maschinenbau Ulm [1966] ECR 235, (STM) para 249.

Page 116: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 115

can be as a result of either its object or its effect and hence both elements do not

need to be proven. Consequently, object and effect are not cumulative concepts,

which need to be applied together, but disjunctive ones.3

2.2. Object does not require the concrete effects of an agreement to be examined

Closely interwoven with the principle that object and effect are distinct and not

cumulative concepts, is the principle that the concrete effects of an agreement do

not need to be proven under the object criterion.4 The General Court described

this when stating that “it is not necessary to show actual anticompetitive effects

where the anticompetitive object of the conduct is proved”.5 As discussed

previously, this principle is consistently upheld by the Community Courts. Object is

therefore an incredibly powerful tool: determining the actual effects of an

agreement demands a higher and thus more intensive and costly level of economic

analysis.6

The ‘no actual effects’ rule has been the source of much of the confusion and

misinterpretation surrounding the object criterion. It has often been construed to

mean that any form of effects assessment is superfluous and has no place in

determining the object of an agreement. This misunderstanding has sometimes

been exacerbated by the Courts handling of this principle. The use of the words

‘actual’ or ‘concrete’ have often been omitted when setting out the principal in

judgments despite the reference to cases such as STM. For instance, in Pierre Fabre

the Court omits to use the words ‘actual’ or ‘concrete’ effects and cites GSK as its

3 Confirmed in Case C-219/95P Ferrière Nord v Commission [1997] ECR I-4411, “it is not necessary

that an agreement should have both an anti-competitive object and an anti-competitive effect”, para 6; (Bellamy & Child, 2008), para 2.096. See also (Whish, 2009), p118. 4 STM (supra n2) and Joined Cases 56 & 58/64, Etablissements Consten SA and Grundigverkaufs-

GmbH v Commission, [1966] ECR 342 (Consten & Grundig). 5 T-62/98 Volkswagen AG v Commission [2000] ECR II 2707, para 178.

6 See (Bennett & Collins, 2010).

Page 117: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 116

authority.7 GSK does not use the words either, but cites T-Mobile, which then does

use the word ‘actual’.8

The omission of one vital word has had a huge impact on the interpretation of this

principle. There is a subtle distinction, often missed, between the propositions that

actual effects need not be demonstrated under the object criterion versus no

effects need be demonstrated at all. The case law does not prescribe that effects

must never be demonstrated under the object criterion. Therefore, demonstrating

potential (or even in some cases actual) effects is allowed, not least desirable, when

determining the object of an agreement.9 Certainly, much, if not all, of the case law

of the Community Courts has involved some form of analysis of effects under the

object heading.10 How those effects are in fact utilised is dependent on the context

of the agreement. This is seen, in particular, in various selective distribution cases

where the Courts have recognised restrictions are necessary in order to promote

competition. The no-effects rule raises important issues that require deeper

reflection.11 These are examined in chapter 4.

2.3. Object must be considered first

Having established that object and effect are disjunctive, a pertinent issue is

whether object and effect are true alternatives: can the effect of an agreement be

determined without having first considered its object?12 On the basis of the leading

case on object, STM, this issue would seem to be settled. The Court held that, first,

7 Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre Dermo-Cosmétique SAS v Président de l’Autorité de la concurrence,

[2001] ECR I-9419 (Pierre Fabre), para 34. 8 Case C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands BV and Others v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse

Mededingingsautoriteit, [2009] ECR I-4529, para 29. 9 See AG Trstenjak in C-501/06 P GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission (GSK) [2009] ECR

I-9291, paras 89 to 95 for a robust discussion of this issue. 10

In Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission [2006] ECR II-2969 the GC noted that even in Consten & Grundig a limited analysis had been undertaken (Joined Cases 56 & 58/64, Etablissements Consten SA and Grundigverkaufs-GmbH v Commission, [1966] ECR 342). See also Joined Cases C-96/82 etc, IAZ v Commission/ ANSEAU [1983] ECR 3369 and Case C-41/69 ACF Chemiefarma v Commission [1970] ECR 661. 11

For instance, what is the rationale behind the no actual effects rule, and how are the effects of an agreement incorporated within an object assessment. 12

See (Faull & Nikpay, 1999), para 2.60. Black states object is often evidence of effect, but not vice versa, (Black, 2005), p115.

Page 118: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 117

the precise purpose (the object) of the agreement needs to be considered.13 Then,

where such analysis of the clauses of the agreement does not “reveal the effect on

competition to be sufficiently deleterious, the consequences of the agreement

should then be considered”.14 This suggests that the object criterion should be

determined before ‘effect’ can be considered.

This interpretation has been upheld by numerous commentators and Court

judgments.15 The pragmatic rationale for this is that affirming an agreement’s

object avoids the examination of practical effects, “which is considerably more

difficult”.16 An inference that can be drawn from this principle is that testing for

object is different from testing for effect. The object concept encapsulates those

agreements which aim to restrict competition, but fail.17 Additionally, it is not

necessary for the agreement expressly to state the intention to restrict

competition. Instead, it is sufficient if the content of the agreement conclusively

indicates such a purpose.18 Effect then captures those agreements that do not

necessarily aim to restrict competition, but nonetheless have (or could have) that

effect.19 According to Black, object captures agreements not caught by effect and

vice versa.20

The issue then is whether object must be applied first and what the implications are

should this not be done. Put another way: is a finding of effect alone without first

having recourse to the object of an agreement sufficient for the purposes of

discharging obligations under Article 101(1) TFEU. The answer is somewhat fudged

in Court statements.

13

Supra n2, STM, para 249. 14

Ibid para 249. Upheld in Pierre Fabre (supra n7). 15

See (Goyder & Albors-Llorens, 2009), p118. Only if the purpose of the agreement does not appear to restrict competition is it necessary to consider the effects; Pierre Fabre, para 34 (supra n7); GSK (supra n9), paras 55-56; (Deringer, 1968), p35, para 163. 16

(Deringer, 1968), footnote 94, p35, para 163. This highlights the administrable savings of applying the object criterion. 17

(Black, 2005), p115. 18

(Deringer, 1968), p20, para 131. 19

(Black, 2005), p115. 20

(Black, 2005), p115.

Page 119: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 118

In FA, even though the CJEU agreed that object and effect are alternative criteria, it

said this meant:

“that it is appropriate, first and foremost, to determine whether

just one of them is satisfied, here the criterion concerning the

object of the agreement. It is only secondarily, when the analysis

of the content of the agreement does not reveal a sufficient

degree of impairment of competition, that the consequences of

the agreement should be considered...”.21

The Court’s statement does not fully support the principle that the object criterion

needs to be decided first before the effect of an agreement can be considered. This

is despite the Court citing cases, which in turn cite STM as authority.22 Thus, the

effect of an agreement can be assessed without having recourse to object first.

Conversely, in GSK the CJEU described why it is important that object is considered

before effect: because if that assessment is held to be an error of law then the

effect analysis will be dismissed.23

From a procedural perspective, there have been a number of notable instances

where the Commission has not determined the outcome of its object assessment

before considering the effect of an agreement.24 It has also been seen how both

the European Courts and the Commission have considered both object and effect

together in Article 101(1) TFEU assessments.25 Given that the onus is on the

Commission to prove that an agreement restricts competition under Article 101(1)

TFEU, whether it chooses to tackle the object or effect of an agreement first may

appear to be irrelevant. In more practical terms, however, the importance of

21

Supra n2, FA, para 135. 22

For instance, supra n9, GSK, para 55. 23

Ibid GSK, para 56. See also supra n7, Pierre Fabre, para 32. 24

See in particular the decision in Europay (Eurocard – Mastercard) [2009] OJ L318/17. Alternatively in GlaxoSmithKline 2001/791/EC, the Commission found the object was to restrict competition, but still assessed the effects of the agreement. 25

The CJEU has often referred to both concepts together in its judgments, for example, Case C-5/69 Franz Völk v SPRL Ets J Vervaecke [1969] ECR 295; Case C-28/77 Tepea BV v Commission [1978] ECR 1391; Case C-31/80 L’Oréal NV and L’Oréal SV v De Nieuwe AMCK PVBA [1980] ECR 3775; Case C-61/80 Cöoperatieve Stremsel-en Kleurselfabriek v Commission [1981] ECR 811; Case C-107/82 AEG-Telefunken v Commission [1983] ECR 3151. See in particular opinion of AG Tesauro in Case C-250/92 Gøttrup-Klim v Dansk Landbrugs Grovvareselskat AmbA [1994] ECR I-5641 (Gøttrup-Klim) who condemned this practice. See also (Slot & Johnston, 2006), p59.

Page 120: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 119

considering object first is that: (i) an object assessment does not require actual

effects to be proved, which reduces the burden on administrative resources, (ii)

even if an agreement is not implemented or successful does not negate a finding by

object,26 (iii) a finding of object is usually perceived as a more serious offence given

the higher level of fines attributed to restrictions by object,27 (iv) the availability of

an Article 101(3) TFEU exemption is statistically more unlikely for agreements found

restrictive by object,28 (v) parties have less inclination purposefully to restrict

competition by colluding if they know it is prohibited regardless of effect (the

preventative nature of the law), and (vi) the application of the object criterion can

result in an agreement falling outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether without the

need to determine its actual effects.29

For the Commission to ignore these practical consequences and insist on a full

effects analysis demonstrates how the advantages of applying the object criterion

are considerably weakened.30 In light of STM, it is sensible that the “precise

purpose” of the agreement is considered first.31 This means that the alternatives of

object and effect involve a two-stage examination in so far as if the object of an

agreement is not to restrict competition, then it must be determined whether it

then has that effect.32

2.3.1. When is the object criterion satisfied?

Having determined that the object of an agreement should be examined first under

Article 101(1) TFEU, this sub-section considers at what point that obligation is

discharged before the concrete effects of the agreement are considered. In other

26

C-277/87 Sandoz Prodotti Farmaceutici SpA v Commission [1990] ECR I-45; C-246/86 Belasco v Commission [1989] ECR 2117. But upholding the judgment in STM, the CJEU in T-Mobile held that an agreement must be “capable” of restricting competition, para 31 (supra n2 and n8). 27

Even though the Commission is at liberty to fine undertakings equally as harshly should they restrict competition by effect. 28

See the Article 81(3) Guidelines. 29

See eg, Völk (supra n25). 30

Certainly it seriously undermines arguments regarding the savings on administrative resources. 31

STM, para 250 (supra n2); T-Mobile, para 28 (supra n8), where the CJEU found it “necessary” to first consider the precise purpose of the agreement and then consider the effect should it not be possible to reveal the effect on competition to be sufficiently deleterious. 32

See eg, the opinion in GSK, para 89 (supra n9). Though determining an agreement’s object may bring the agreement outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether.

Page 121: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 120

words, when is the object of an agreement satisfied? It is an important issue, as

once the object of an agreement is proved, it is presumed anticompetitive: no

further evidence of an agreement’s restrictive effects needs to be produced.33 The

European Courts have not particularly focused on this issue: the jurisprudence

reveals itself to be inconsistent and discordant. In STM, the Court held that if the

analysis of the clauses of the agreement does not “reveal the effect on competition

to be sufficiently deleterious, the consequences of the agreement should then be

considered”.34 Conversely in Consten & Grundig the CJEU found the concrete

effects of an agreement do not need to be taken into account once it “appears” the

object of the agreement is to restrict competition.35 Alternatively, in Pierre Fabre,

the Court held that “where the anticompetitive object of the agreement is

established it is not necessary to examine its effects on competition”.36

The jurisprudence therefore suggests an element of discretion when proving

whether an agreement’s object to restrict competition is satisfied. Arguably, the

standard of proof is flexible and depends on the nature of the case.37 This is

underlined by the use of expressions such as when an agreement “appears” to have

the aim of restricting competition.38 This discretion ties in with the argument that

in EU competition law a judge decides less as to what the standard of proof is, but

instead to the persuasiveness of the evidence without being bound by pre-

determined evidentiary or probability “thresholds”.39 Hence, the object criterion is

satisfied when the evidence is persuasive enough.40 The ‘effect’ criterion does not

suffer from the same level of uncertainty in this regards as proving actual effects on

a market is less subjective and far more measurable. It is therefore helpful to

33

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p656. Also, opinion in GSK, para 89 (supra n9); Volkswagen, para 178 (supra n5). 34

Supra n2, STM, para 249 [emphasis added]. See also GSK, para 55 (supra n9): “where, however, the analysis of the content of the agreement does not reveal a sufficient degree of harm to competition [emphasis added], the consequences of the agreement should then be considered...”. 35

Supra n10 Consten & Grundig, p342. 36

Supra n7, Pierre Fabre, para 34. Emphasis added. The word “established” is also echoed in the EU Commission’s 81(3) Guidelines, para 20. 37

(Gippini-Fournier, 2010), p207. 38

Supra n10, Consten & Grundig and see eg supra n8, T-Mobile, para 31. 39

(Gippini-Fournier, 2010), p188. 40

Ibid, p207.

Page 122: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 121

understand the types of indicators that aide the determination that an agreement

restricts competition by object.41 One of those indicators is the subjective intention

to restrict competition.42

2.4. Subjective intention is not determinative when assessing object

Subjective intention relates to whether the parties to an agreement themselves

intend to restrict competition by entering into such agreements. The European

Courts have consistently found that subjective intention is not determinative when

assessing the object of an agreement. However, subjective intent can be taken into

account as part of that determination: evidence of subjective intent on the part of

the parties to restrict competition is a relevant factor, but not a necessary

condition.43 Conversely, a lack of subjective intention whereby the parties argue

they did not intend to restrict competition is not a defence.44 This is analogous with

ignorance of the law being no defence. Instead, whether an agreement has the

object of restricting competition depends on the content of the agreement and its

extenuating circumstances (such as its implementation, and the parties’ conduct).45

That the object of the agreement is dependent on objective manifestations

supporting that aim is logical. This is because the notion of subjective intention has

complexities. IAZ/Anseau is a good example of this.46 In that case, the parties

denied they knew they were restricting competition, let alone had the intention of

doing so. The factual scenario concerned the restriction of parallel trade by use of a

conformity label for washing machines and dishwashers. The parties argued that

41

See generally, eg (Bailey, 2012), (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’. 42

Other factors, such as the conduct of the parties, content, circumstances and context of the agreement were discussed in chapter 2. 43

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 22. Though no supporting citation provided. See IAZ/Anseau (supra n10); C-551/03 P General Motors v Commission [2006] ECR I-3173. 44

C-19/77 Miller International Schallplatten GmbH v Commission (1978) ECR 131 (Miller). The CJEU held that subjective intention was irrelevant in determining the level of fine as the applicant should have known an export ban had the object of restricting competition. According to the Court, an infringement of Article 101 TFEU is considered to have been committed intentionally if the person concerned is aware that the act in question had as its “object the restriction of competition”. It is irrelevant to establish whether the person concerned also knew he was infringing Article 101 TFEU. 45

See supra n25 Tepea BV; supra n10 IAZ/Anseau; C-29&30/83 Compagnie Royal Austrienne des Mines and Rheinzink (CRAM) v Commission [1984] ECR 1679 and supra n43 General Motors. 46

Supra n10 IAZ/Anseau.

Page 123: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 122

the purpose of the agreement was to protect public health, not to restrict

competition. The CJEU rejected this argument. It held that, if the parties who

drafted the agreement were aware that the agreement, by looking at its terms, the

legal and economic context in which it was concluded and to the conduct of the

parties, had as its purpose the restriction of parallel imports; they acted

deliberately by signing it. This was regardless of whether or not they were aware

that in so doing they were infringing Article 101(1) TFEU.47 In this case the Court

found the legal and economic context did not support the argument raised by the

parties that the purpose of their agreement was to protect public health.

2.4.1. Odudu and intent

The role of subjective intention has been extensively analysed by Odudu. According

to his early formula, subjective intention alone is proof of a restrictive object.48 This

view was later modified: Odudu subsequently asserted that allocative inefficiency

established by legal presumption has the object of restricting competition if it is

based on either the concept of necessary effect, or if an outcome is intended

(which he terms “intent based presumptions”).49 It is this latter contention that is

of interest here. Odudu claims that “if an outcome is intended it is more likely to

occur than if that same outcome is not intended”.50 Therefore, intent is relevant,

because undertakings are more likely to restrict competition when they intend to

restrict competition.51 The use of the word ‘intention’ therefore has great

significance in this context, particularly in view of its correlation with English

criminal law. Thus, the consideration of whether the intention needs to be

subjective or objectively determined is pertinent.52

47

Ibid, paras 23–25. 48

(Odudu, 2001), ‘Object as subjective intention’. See also the AG’s opinion in Case C-209/07 Competition Authority v Beef Industry Development Society Ltd and Barry Brothers (Carrigmore) Meats Ltd [2008] ECR I-8637 (BIDS), which supports Odudu’s interpretation, paras 44-46. 49

(Odudu, 2006), pp114, 127. 50

Ibid. 51

Ibid, p121. 52

For analogies with UK criminal law and the requirement of the ‘mens rea’ being satisfied by oblique intent see R v Moloney [1985] 1 All ER 1025; (Smith & Hogan, 2011) state that: (1) A consequence is intended when it is the accused's purpose. (2) A court or jury may also infer that a

Page 124: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 123

According to Norrie when it is claimed a person intends to do something what is

actually meant is that it is seen to be a virtually certain result of their action.53 This

means that an outcome can be predicted if it is intended.54 For Odudu, this is

sufficient to decide that ‘intent-based presumptions’ have the object of restricting

competition.55 Odudu goes further, claiming that such intent based presumptions

are irrebutable under Article 101(1) TFEU.56 This is not a comfortable conclusion.

Technically, Odudu’s research may reveal that (based on outcomes) such intent-

based presumptions exist.57 However, the European Courts have not alluded to this

phenomenon of intent based presumptions as a conclusive indicator that, by law,

an agreement restricts competition by object.58 Instead, subjective intent is one of

a number of factors that may be taken into account depending on the legal and

economic context of the agreement. It is understandable why Odudu submits that

intent carries a predictive nature and thus justifies a legal presumption that

“collusion with the intention to contrive a scarcity of output will lead to contrived

scarcity of output”.59 From an economic perspective this formula may make sense,

but irrebutable intent based presumptions ultimately detract from a legal analysis

of an agreement in its own context in accordance with the test established in STM.

A more compelling argument that could be deduced from Norrie’s hypothesis is

that intent based presumptions form a useful policy basis for establishing a

rebuttable presumption that Article 101(1) TFEU is infringed by object.

More fundamentally, it is easy for parties to argue that an outcome was not

intended. Odudu recognises this problem and therefore agrees that intent should

consequence is intended, though it is not desired, when (a) the consequence is a virtually certain result of the act, and (b) the accused knows that it is a virtually certain consequence. 53

(Odudu, 2006), p121 citing Norrie, ‘Oblique Intention and Legal Politics’ [1989] CrimLR 793-807, 800-802. Additionally, failure of that intention means that such a person will continue with a scheme until it succeeds. 54

(Odudu, 2006), p122. See also AG Trstenjak in BIDS (supra n48), para 45. 55

Ibid, p127. 56

Ibid, p127. 57

Ibid, pp121, 127. Though he qualifies his conclusion by stating that the content of such intent based legal presumptions must therefore be paid great attention. 58

Rather judgments focus on the extenuating circumstances, content of the agreement, conduct of the parties etc. 59

(Odudu, 2006), p121.

Page 125: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 124

be objectively determined from “external manifestations”.60 Odudu reasons that to

enhance deterrence, Article 101(1) TFEU must prohibit unsuccessful attempts,

hence the presumption of intent is conclusive, and in particular, ex post conduct

cannot be rebutted.61 This reasoning is more persuasive, though could be

explained alternatively: that the prohibition of unsuccessful attempts to restrict

competition is merely an elucidation of why the concrete effects of an agreement

need not be demonstrated under the object heading. As, based on its content and

context, an agreement aimed to restrict competition. This explanation better

reflects the jurisprudence.62

2.4.2. Conclusion

It is clear from the case law that subjective intention can play a key role in

establishing whether an agreement restricts competition by object. However, in

GSK the GC held that the agreement to restrict parallel trade, which was the

admitted intention of the parties, did not have the object to restrict competition.

Even though the Court of Justice overturned this by holding the agreement did have

such an object, it highlights that basing a finding of object on subjective intent

alone is insufficient. Jones agrees, stating that “intention is determined objectively,

so that the parties’ subjective intent cannot be relied upon to exculpate otherwise

unlawful behaviour”.63

2.5. Success and non-implementation of an agreement are extraneous

As seen above, the jurisprudence demonstrates that for a finding of object under

Article 101(1) TFEU it is not necessary to show an agreement is successful, nor that

it was implemented, applied or enforced.64 This enhances the role of the object

60

Ibid, p123. Though scant detail is provided on how this is done. 61

Ibid, pp123-124. That competition law must have an element of deterrence is prudent, hence the nature of fines, unenforceability of an agreement under Article 101(2) TFEU and that an agreement need not be successful. Deterrence assists ‘actors’ in guiding their own conduct: (Odudu, 2006), p1, describing a “self-enforcing legal obligation”. 62

Cf, Odudu is supported in his contentions by the AG Trstenjak in BIDS (supra n48), paras 44-47. However, the AG modified her views slightly in her opinion in GSK (supra n9), para 93. 63

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p664 64

See supra n44 Miller, paras 7-9; supra n26 Sandoz.

Page 126: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 125

criterion as a deterrent factor against undertakings seeking to restrict

competition.65

2.6. An agreement that restricts competition by object can still benefit from an

Article 101(3) TFEU exemption.

Technically, all agreements that infringe Article 101(1) TFEU can be exempted under

Article 101(3) TFEU if all the conditions of Article 101(3) TFEU are met.66 Hence,

restrictions by object have the possibility of exemption under Article 101(3) TFEU.

The relationship between the object criterion and Article 101(3) TFEU is considered

in chapter 5.67

2.7. Burden of proof

Under Article 101(1) TFEU, the burden of proof is on the plaintiff, therefore usually

the Commission. The burden is shifted to the defendant under Article 101(3)

TFEU.68 The question whether, when determining if the object of an agreement is

to restrict competition, the burden can be shifted on to the defendant under Article

101(1) TFEU, is discussed in chapter 4.

2.8. Conclusion

Even though common principles can be drawn out from the case law that are

applicable under the three key approaches to the object criterion, this section

highlights that they entail a degree of complexity. Therefore, a deeper

consideration of the issues is required in order to draw out the legal characteristics

of the object criterion as well as reveal areas that still require clarity from the

Courts. The multifaceted legal nature of the object criterion has long been

65

It also supports the understanding of the object criterion under the MAAP: that the object criterion is not dependent on necessary effect, but on the objective aim of the agreement to restrict competition. Alternatively, the orthodox approach could similarly argue experience dictates certain pernicious agreements tend to harm competition and therefore are automatically prohibited regardless of success. 66

T-17/93 Matra Hachette v Commission [1994] ECR II-595, para 85 and T-168/01 GSK (supra n10), para 58. See also (Italianer, 2013), Fordham Competition Law Institute. 67

See (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p669 onwards. Cf, in its BERs the Commission assumes object would not benefit from Article 101(3) TFEU. 68

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p656.

Page 127: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 126

concealed by policy and indeed economic and legal desires for ‘bright lines’. The

case law exposes a far more nuanced substantive provision. Teasing these issues

out and investigating their properties is an important step in revealing the legal

essence of the object criterion.

3. The definition of ‘object’: what does it mean?

Given the centrality of the legal term ‘object’, it would be reasonable to assume

that the Courts would have taken some trouble to define it.69 Having reviewed the

case law, this assumption is unfounded. On the contrary, defining the term has not

been high on the Courts’ agenda. Instead, the case law reveals that, depending on

how the Courts approach the object criterion, the way it has been defined differs.

Goyder notes that “it is hard to discern clear outlines of the concept of ‘object

restriction’...no meaningful over-arching definition has emerged”.70 By using the

three key approaches, how the Community Courts have tackled the meaning of the

object criterion is illustrated in this section. How legal presumptions and the

concept of necessary effect impact on such definitions is also investigated, and a

view as to which meaning should be given priority and why is proposed.

3.1. The more analytical approach

Under the more analytical approach the Community Courts place a greater onus on

the term ‘object’ itself. As highlighted in chapter 2, however, there is no single,

absolute definition of the object concept in the case law of the Community Courts.

Instead, the case law reveals at least seven different variants. These terms are

based on derivatives of the term ‘object’. References to the object of an

agreement have thus included the “precise purpose”,71 “purpose”,72 “aim”,73

69

This can be contrasted with the Court’s clear definition of an “effect on trade between Member States”: (Jones & Sufrin, 2014), p181. 70

(Goyder, 2011), section I. 71

Supra n2, STM. 72

Supra n10 IAZ/Anseau. 73

Supra n45 CRAM & Rheinzink.

Page 128: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 127

“intention”,74 “objective”,75 “objective function”,76 and the “design” of an

agreement.77

Under the MAAP, the definition of ‘object’ is intricately linked with the phraseology

of Article 101(1) TFEU as a whole.78 As such, the term itself is nonsensical without

reference to the context in which it operates. Hence, ‘aim’ or ‘purpose’ relates

intrinsically to the question of whether an agreement ‘aims’ to restrict competition.

The literal wording of Article 101(1) TFEU therefore plays a key role in the definition

of object restraints.79 This may seem an obvious point, but in the light of the

dominance of the orthodox approach even this simple statement of fact has

become muddied. The inter-relationship with what constitutes a ‘restriction of

competition’ therefore heavily influences the outcome of the application of this

definition.80 For instance, what constitutes a restriction of competition is

determined by, inter alia, competition law goals, economics, as well as those

restrictions of competition identified in Article 101(1)(a)-(c) TFEU).81 In one sense,

any so-called categorisation would encompass those restraints that are defined as a

‘restriction of competition’, not what is contained in an ‘object box’.

Establishing the aim of an agreement is an objective concept based on the content

of the agreement in its specific legal and economic context, though - as described

previously - the subjective intention of the parties may be relevant as may

extenuating circumstances and conduct. Therefore, defining object as the objective

aim or purpose of an agreement to restrict competition provides a good degree of

flexibility as opposed to the formalistic nature of the orthodox approach.

Conversely, such flexibility brings its own degree of complexity. This becomes

apparent when the purpose of an agreement is said to be a positive or pro-

74

Supra n10 ACF Chemiefarma, Case C-258/78 Nungesser v Commission [1982] ECR 2015. 75

Supra n25 L’Oréal, also arguably supra n25 Cöoperatieve Stremsel-en. 76

Supra n25 Gøttrup-Klim, as per AG Tesauro, para 16. 77

Supra n2 FA, para 140. 78

As evidenced in STM (supra n2). 79

See (Goyder, 2011) who also raises a similar point. 80

This relationship will be discussed further in Chapter 5. 81

See chapter 5.

Page 129: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 128

competitive one. This conundrum was evident in Asnef.82 Here, despite being a

horizontal credit information exchange agreement, the Court focused on

determining the ‘essential object’ of the agreement. The Court found that its aim

was to make relevant information on borrowers available to credit providers and

therefore the agreement did not have the object of restricting competition.83

The case law reviewed in chapter 2 revealed, that in some cases, an overriding

positive aim can trump or discharge a prima facie finding of restriction by object

under Article 101(1) TFEU. This, arguably, is the view taken by the Courts in

selective distribution cases.84 Conversely, in General Motors and cases such as

BIDS, an agreement may be regarded as having a restrictive object even if does not

have the restriction of competition as its sole aim, but also pursues other legitimate

objectives which, in some cases, are also pro-competitive.85 This discrepancy could

be attributed to the specific legal and economic context of an agreement. Hence,

better sense of the law would be gained by defining ‘object’ as the ‘precise

purpose’ of an agreement.86 Taking account of the content, circumstances and

context of the agreement, the object concept inquires whether the primary

purpose of the agreement is to restrict competition. The definition of ‘object’ is

thereby interwoven with its application. Whether an agreement is or is not

successful, or not even implemented, is unimportant if the true purpose is to

restrict competition. What matters most is understanding the rationale behind the

agreement.87

3.2. The orthodox approach

Defining ‘object’ under the orthodox approach is challenging. In ENS, the GC

deemed that when assessing an agreement containing “obvious restrictions of

82

Case C-238/05, Asnef-Equifax, Servicios de Información sobre Solvencia y Crédito, SL v Asociación de Usuarios de Servicios Bancarios (Ausbanc), [2006] ECR I-11125 (‘Asnef’). 83

See also (Jones, 2010),’Left Behind by Modernisation’, p652 and (Lasok QC, 2008), p8. 84

This issue is not straightforward. See the analysis of the judgment in Pierre Fabre (supra n7) in chapter 4 below. 85

Supra n43, General Motors, para 64. This was also argued in BIDS (supra n48). See also Pierre Fabre (supra n7), Case C-107/82 AEG-Telefunken v Commission [1983] ECR 3151. 86

As defined in STM (supra n2). 87

These issues, such as balancing the aims of an agreement, are considered more fully in chapter 4.

Page 130: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 129

competition” such as price-fixing, market sharing or control of outlets, such

assessment does not require that account be taken of the legal and economic

context.88 Subsequently, it can be reasoned that the orthodox approach suggests

that object means ‘obvious restrictions of competition’ or in the Commission’s

terms ‘hardcore restrictions’.89 The inference is that price fixing, market sharing

and other similar ‘hardcore’ restrictions can be understood as being automatic or

prima facie restrictions by object as they form part of a category of object

agreements.

Waelbroeck and Slater define the object concept as follows:

“According to established case law, restrictions of competition by

object are those which due to their very nature are highly likely to

restrict competition, in other words ‘manifest’ or ‘patent’

restrictions which display a sufficient degree of harm.”90

In support of this contention they cite one case, namely, the GC’s judgment in

GSK.91 As demonstrated in chapter 2, this case does not support such a definition

of the object concept. This only serves to highlight the entrenchment of the

orthodox approach. Hence, the concept of object encompasses ‘obvious’, serious

and easily identifiable restrictions of competition. This is further corroborated by

commentators such as Bennett and Collins for whom the object concept simply

reflects their belief in the categorisation of the particular restraints.92 It is therefore

“sufficient to demonstrate that the agreement fits into the object category and

hence breaches Article 101(1)”.93 Likewise, Goyder asserts that the object concept

is based on a category of restrictions, the precise scope of which is a crucial issue in

88

Cases T-374/94 etc European Night Services v Commission [1998] ECR II-3141 (ENS), para 136, referencing Case T-148/89 Tréfilunion v Commission (Welded Steel Mesh) [1995] ECR II-1063, para 109. 89

Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 23. In para 21 the Commission defines the object concept as agreements “that by their very nature have the potential of restricting competition”. 90

(Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), p140, C. 91

Ibid, footnote 33. 92

(Bennett & Collins, 2010), p313. Note, no citation is provided in support of their explanation of the legal framework. 93

Ibid, p314. The authors do however agree that the presumption of anticompetitive harm is, in theory rebuttable “if compelling evidence is adduced that the agreement does not have an anticompetitive object or effect given the overall context of the agreement”.

Page 131: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 130

any given case.94 To determine whether an agreement then restricts competition

by object, the party alleging the infringement “need only show the presence of an

agreement including such a restriction, and so does not need to establish the

relevant market, or the degree of market power held by the undertaking

concerned”.95

The categorisation of object restrictions under the orthodox approach is thus its

defining characteristic. Understandably, the question regarding which restrictions

are contained within the category features heavily in debate. This is due, in

particular, to its subsequent expansion over the years, which thereby questions

how influential and/or important the concept of necessary effect is on the

category.96

3.3. The hybrid approach

The hybrid approach draws heavily from the orthodox approach in terms of its

interpretation of the legal nature of the object criterion. In BIDS, notwithstanding

the AG’s opinion, the Court described the distinction between object and effect in

its own terms, which was a replication of its statement in T-Mobile.97 To reiterate,

this was said to arise:

“...from the fact that certain forms of collusion between undertakings

can be regarded, by their very nature, as being injurious to the proper

functioning of normal competition”.98

Like the orthodox approach, this statement implies that there is a category of

agreements that automatically restrict competition by object, ostensibly based on

the notion of their necessary effect. As noted in chapter 2, this contention was not

wholly supported by the AG, who argued that the aim of an agreement usually, but

not exclusively, relates to situations where the anticompetitive effects of a certain

94

(Goyder, 2011), VI. 95

(Goyder, 2011), VI. 96

See generally (Bennett & Collins, 2010). 97

Supra n8 T-Mobile, para 29. The Court cites BIDS (supra n48) as the authority, which itself cites no authority for the proposition. 98

Supra n48 BIDS, para 17.

Page 132: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 131

type of agreement are known.99 Though the CJEU acknowledged in its judgments

that agreements covered by Article 101(1)(a) to (e) TFEU do not form an exhaustive

list of prohibited collusion.100

This distinction drawn by the CJEU between object and effect has been replicated in

nearly every judgment concerning the object concept post BIDS.101 Up until 11

September 2014, the rationale behind this distinction was purely speculative, as the

CJEU did not cite any case law in support of such distinction nor expound upon it.

Ostensibly, the CJEU has now provided clarification on this point in Cartes

Bancaires.102 The facts of the case relate to various pricing measures introduced by

Groupement des Cartes Bancaires (CB) to balance the issuing and acquiring

activities within the CB payment system in France. CB was set up by the French

banks to manage a system for bank card payments and withdrawal. The measures

largely consisted of a series of fees paid by CB members that varied depending on

the type of membership. Both the Commission and GC found the agreement

restricted competition by object. The CJEU, however, disagreed.

The CJEU held that the case law shows “certain types of coordination between

undertakings reveal a sufficient degree of harm to competition that it may be found

there is no need to examine their effects”.103 That case law “arises from the fact

that certain types of coordination can be regarded, by their very nature, as being

harmful to the proper functioning of normal competition.”104 Therefore:

99

Ibid BIDS, para 46 of the opinion. In para 104 of AG Trstenjak’s opinion, the AG finds that the content of an agreement must always be examined against the background of its legal and economic context. She says that comparing agreements is not always the correct approach and may fail to address the question of when a restriction by object exists. 100

Ibid BIDS, para 23 of the judgment confirming the AG’s opinion. 101

See eg supra n8 T-Mobile, supra n9 GSK, supra n7 Pierre Fabre, Case C-32/11, Allianz Hungária Biztosító Zrt v Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, 14 March 2013, nyr (Allianz Hungária), supra n2 FA, Case C-226/11, Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence, 13 December 2012, nyr (Expedia), Case C-67/13 P, Groupement des Cartes Bancaires (CB) v Commission, 11 September 2014, nyr (Cartes Bancaires). 102

Supra n101. Judgment of 11 September 2014. A detailed consideration of this judgment is outside the scope of this thesis, however its potential significance merits that it is referenced as it will re-ignite the debate on the object criterion as evidenced in the various conferences being held, eg “Restrictions of Competition ‘by object’ after Cartes Bancaires and the Commission’s Initiatives”, Academy of European Law, 11 December 2014. 103

Ibid, Cartes Bancaires, para 49. 104

Ibid, Cartes Bancaires, para 50.

Page 133: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 132

“it is established that certain collusive behaviour, such as that leading to

horizontal price fixing by cartels, may be considered so likely to have

negative effects...that it may be considered redundant... to prove that

they have actual effects on the market. [Citing Guy Clair, para 22]

Experience shows such behaviour leads to falls in production and price

increases resulting in poor allocation of resources to the detriment...of

consumers”.

Moreover the object concept “can be applied only to certain types of coordination

between undertakings which reveal a sufficient degree of harm to competition that

it may be found that there is no need to examine their effects.”105

The CJEU therefore finds that the concept of necessary effect provides the rationale

behind the distinction between object and effect first elucidated in BIDS. It also

berates the GC for finding that the object concept should not be given a strict

interpretation, but does not then go on to define precise parameters for the

categorisation of the object concept, acknowledging that Article 101(1) TFEU does

not provide an exhaustive list of prohibited collusion.106 In fact, despite finally

articulating the concept of necessary effect within its jurisprudence, the CJEU does

not specifically cite any case law supporting its finding that experience leads to an

apparent presumption of effects other than its reference to Guy Clair.107

Furthermore, the CJEU has openly shifted emphasis on to a condition first

established in STM, that to be restrictive by object an agreement must have a

‘sufficient degree of harm’.

At first blush, the CJEU suggests that this requirement is satisfied by certain types of

collusion whose injurious effects on competition and indeed consumers are already

known. As such, only those types of collusion are able to satisfy a finding that they

are restrictive by object as they entail a sufficient degree of harm. Moreover, the

CJEU reasoned that it is not enough merely to find that an agreement has the

‘potential’ or is ‘capable’ of restricting competition, rather it must entail a sufficient

105

Ibid, Cartes Bancaires, para 58. 106

Ibid, Cartes Bancaires, para 58. 107

See chapter 2 for a discussion on Guy Clair which refers to an agreement’s ‘intention’ (Chapter 2 ft97).

Page 134: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 133

degree of harm.108 The CJEU distinguishes these notions and thus on its own

understanding raises the standard of proof on the Commission.

Therefore, under the hybrid approach, the CJEU has seemingly refined the

definition of ‘object’ as meaning certain types of collusion that by their nature are

injurious to competition as they entail a sufficient degree of harm. This is owing to

experience and explains why the effects of an agreement do not need to be

demonstrated. To summarise, object means presumption of effects.109 An

important question is how this impacts on the application of the object criterion.

As was clear in chapter 2, a reliance on necessary effect alone is not considered

sufficient to explain this distinction between object and effect, nor to provide the

justification for why the concrete effects do not require determination under the

object heading.

Placing so much emphasis on necessary effect creates problems. Moreover, under

the hybrid approach, any presumption of harm must be capable of rebuttal owing

to the assessment of the agreement’s legal and economic context as prescribed in

the STM Test. These issues are considered below.

3.4. Legal Presumptions

Before turning to the legal application of the object criterion, it is pertinent to

comment more fully on the relationship between legal presumptions and the object

criterion.110 The debate over legal presumptions and their association with the

object qualification is particularly unclear and ill-defined. One reason for this is the

amount of differing and undefined terminology associated with this area. For

instance, legal presumptions under the object criterion are often inter-linked with

the concept of ‘necessary effect’, ‘categorisation’ of object restraints, and

agreements that ‘by their very nature’ restrict competition.

108

Supra n101, Cartes Bancaires, para 55. Cf T-Mobile (supra n8). 109

See (La Madrid de Pablo, 2014). 110

See (Gerard, 2012).

Page 135: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 134

This section will concern itself with the fundamental question of whether the

concept of object embodies a presumption of anticompetitive effects as a result of

necessary effect or for alternative reasons. Then, if such presumption exists, such

restrictions embody a category of rebuttable or irrebuttable presumptions of

effect.111 The position adopted in this thesis is perhaps a controversial one: it is

contended that even the most ‘serious’ restrictions of competition carry no

absolute presumption of harm and hence do not automatically restrict competition

by object.112 As such, any presumption of effect is rebuttable within the context of

Article 101(1) TFEU, and not just under Article 101(3) TFEU. To this end, the

following issues are examined: first, the definition of a ‘legal presumption’; then

whether ‘hardcore’ restrictions are synonymous with restrictions by object; next

the concept of necessary effect and its influence on the debate; and finally, the

framework in which any legal presumptions are rebuttable under Article 101(1)

TFEU.

3.4.1. Definition of a ‘legal presumption’

Legal presumptions have a number of functions and are created to support

decision-makers.113 Presumptions can be evidential, substantive or procedural.114

An evidential presumption is one where a party will typically need to prove certain

facts in order for another fact to be inferred. The result of such a presumption is to

shift the burden of proof to the other party to prove the contrary is true, though

the legal burden of proof is not necessarily shifted and remains with the party that

it is originally held by.115 Substantive presumptions are often grounded in

administrative or judicial experience in applying the law and are often “an

expression of mainstream economic theory”.116 They may also be rebuttable or

111

See (Gerard, 2012) www.Kluwercompetitionlawblog.com/2012/02/17 who poses similar questions to those addressed in this thesis. 112

This stance is becoming more commonplace amongst commentators, such as: Jones, Bailey, Ibáňez-Colomo. 113

(Bailey, 2010), p363(C). See also section D. 114

Ibid. Also supported by (Svetlicinii, 2008), p122(C). 115

(Bailey, 2010), p363, C,I,1. 116

Ibid p363, C, II.1.

Page 136: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 135

conclusive.117 A procedural presumption is one where for procedural reasons,

usually convenience, a presumption can be made, for example, under Article 10(6)

of the EU Merger Regulation a merger is presumed compatible with the internal

market if the Commission has not taken a decision on the merger within the

prescribed time limits.118 From a procedural perspective, legal presumptions can

also indicate the shift of the burden of proof from the party who has proved the

fulfilment of the presumption to the party who could rebut such presumption.119

Whether competition law in the EU has developed legal presumptions under Article

101(1) TFEU in general is contested. Bailey asserts that “legal reasoning creates

presumptions in order to assist a decision-maker. A fact or conclusion may

(provisionally) be presumed because experience shows it is self-evident, or for

reasons of public policy or procedural convenience”.120 Such presumptions can

then be conclusive or rebuttable. An oft-made analogy is the connection between

hardcore restrictions and the object concept, which is examined below.

3.4.2. Hardcore restrictions

Whether ‘hardcore’ restraints (as determined by the Commission in its Article 81(3)

Guidelines) are synonymous with restrictions by object is an issue that appeared to

be largely resolved, though following the definition of the object criterion provided

in Cartes Bancaires the question may have reopened.121 The Commission has long

placed significance on the term in its soft law instruments and therefore it has

strong associations with the object criterion. Furthermore, the Commission claims

hardcore restrictions of competition are presumed to restrict competition by object

given their high potential for negative effects and serious nature based on

experience.122

117

Ibid. 118

Ibid, 367 III.1. 119

(Svetlicinii, 2008), p122(C). 120

(Bailey, 2010), p363(C). 121

See (Goyder, 2011). 122

Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 21 and 23. See (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p656 and (Goyder, 2011).

Page 137: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 136

Chapter 2 evidenced that the case law on the whole does not support the notion

that object and hardcore restrictions are one and the same. STM suggests that any

restriction of competition can infringe Article 101(1) TFEU by object. Moreover,

there are cases where apparent ‘hardcore’ restrictions have been held not to

infringe Article 101(1) TFEU by object and conversely restrictions that are not

usually seen to be ‘hardcore’ have been found restrictive by object.123 Goyder

lends support to this view.124 She neatly summarises the position: “object

restrictions of competition are conceptually different from ‘hardcore’ restrictions,

even if the types of restriction they refer to overlap to a large extent...the

Commission’s 2010 Guidelines on Vertical Restraints conflate the two concepts”.125

Despite such criticism of the Commission, Goyder labels the object concept as a

category of agreements that have the necessary consequence of restricting

competition.126 Even though the necessary consequence of an agreement forms

the basis of her understanding of what constitutes an object restriction, she

acknowledges - but moreover emphasises - that it is not sufficient simply to identify

a restriction as a type that has been found to be ‘by object’ before.127 This is

because she recognises that the analysis of an agreement’s object must go further

and such considerations may “negate the presumption of infringement arising

because the type of clause in question appears to be an object restriction”.128 More

importantly, Goyder does not base the categorisation of object on the

Commission’s understanding of the object concept, but rather on how object has

been determined by the CJEU.129 Goyder is therefore an advocate of the hybrid

approach.

123

See eg C-27/87 Erauw-Jacquery v La Hesbignonne [1983] ECR 1919 (Louis Erauw), BIDS (supra n48), Pierre Fabre (supra n7) etc. 124

(Goyder, 2011), p1. Though she does uphold the categorisation of the object concept. 125

(Goyder, 2011), p5. 126

(Goyder, 2011), pp1-3. 127

(Goyder, 2011), p3. 128

(Goyder, 2011), p3. 129

(Goyder, 2011), p5. Overall, Goyder underlines that it is the CJEU that interprets and makes the law and not the Commission.

Page 138: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 137

It befell the Court in its Pierre Fabre judgment to settle the matter of whether

hardcore restrictions and the object concept are synonymous. The question

referred to the CJEU for a preliminary ruling was whether “a general and absolute

ban on selling contract goods to end-users via the internet...in fact constitutes a

“hardcore” restriction of competition by object”.130 The CJEU swiftly recast the

question pointing out that neither Article 101 TFEU nor Regulation No 2790/1999

refers to the concept of ‘hardcore’.131 The Court reframed the question as whether

the contractual clause at issue amounts to a restriction of competition by object.132

Consequently hardcore restrictions and the object criterion are distinct concepts,

though they do of course at times overlap.

3.4.3. Necessary effect/necessary consequence/prior belief

Closely linked with the concept of hardcore restraints is the tricky issue of

necessary effect. Chapter 2 briefly recounted what the concept means, but did not

resolve whether it forms an absolute presumption of harm.133 A presumption of

anti-competitiveness is said to arise in respect of certain agreements, which have

the inevitable consequence of restricting competition.134 The concept of necessary

effect is thus consistently used to justify two propositions: first, that it is the reason

why the actual effects of an agreement do not need to be demonstrated under the

object criterion, and secondly, that as a result there is a category of agreements

130

Supra n7, Pierre Fabre, para 31. 131

Ibid, para 32. Also note the excellent AG opinion, paras 24-25. 132

Ibid, para 33. Though the CJEU then erroneously looks at the “classification of the restriction...as a restriction of competition by object” [emphasis added]. Note some commentators have argued, incorrectly, that in Pierre Fabre, the CJEU indicated that ‘restrictions by object’ and ‘hardcore restriction’ mean the same thing: (Svetlicinii & Sad, 2011), III (3). In Cityhook Limited v OFT [2007] CAT 18, the CAT found that ‘object’ and ‘hardcore’ were not synonymous. 133

See (Odudu, 2001) ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): the Object Requirement Revisited’, p384; (Black, 2005), p118, AG Trstenjak’s opinions in BIDS (supra n48) and GSK (supra n9); (Goyder, 2011), 1-2; and AG Mazák, Pierre Fabre, para 27 of the opinion (supra n7). Justifications for the concept of necessary effect are found in (Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), p144-145. Though much of the analysis is erroneously based on the Article 81(3) Guidelines. 134

(Odudu, 2009).

Page 139: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 138

that are presumed to restrict competition by object. Often these two concepts are

not distinguished. It is submitted that these propositions are not uncontentious.135

The examination of the case law undertaken in Chapter 2, demonstrated that there

is greater judicial support for the approach adopted in STM than that advanced in

ENS.136 The approach in STM does not support the idea of legal presumptions, or

alternatively, does not support irrebuttable legal presumptions of anti-competitive

effect under Article 101(1) TFEU. It is also clear from Consten & Grundig that the

concept of necessary effect was not considered to justify the rule that no actual

effects need be demonstrated under an object assessment. The simple reason for

this is that at the time of the judgment there was no body of case law or experience

to draw on. Moreover, the wording of Article 101(1) TFEU does not specifically link

‘object’ with particular restrictions. Instead, Article 101(1)(a)-(e) TFEU lists a

number of examples of the types of agreements that restrict competition.

Therefore it is unclear how some commentators argue the wording of Article 101(1)

TFEU endorses the categorisation of those restrictions within an object category.137

In fact, until the judgment in Cartes Bancaires the CJEU never offered a sufficient

explanation for the no actual effects rule.138 Even the Commission offers no judicial

support for the proposition. In Cartes Bancaires the CJEU expanded upon the now

well-known delineation between object and effect: that the case law shows

“certain types of coordination reveal a sufficient degree of harm to competition

that it may be found there is no need to examine their effects”.139 It went far

further than in cases such as BIDS as it expressly used the concept of necessary

effect as the rationale behind the object concept and the no actual effects rule.140

Moreover the CJEU reiterates that the coordination must result in a ‘sufficient

degree of harm’, which it pointedly differentiated from the ‘potential’ to restrict

135

See, in particular, AG Kokott in T-Mobile, para 43 (supra n8). 136

See (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation?’, pp663-668 for her interpretation of whether the presumption of anticompetitive effects can be rebutted. 137

See eg, (Goyder, 2011), sections I and III. 138

Supra n101, Cartes Bancaires, para 48-51; Article 81(3) Guidelines, para 21. 139

Ibid, Cartes Bancaires, paras 49-51. 140

Ibid, paras 50-51.

Page 140: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 139

competition.141 However, the CJEU’s choice of citation in support of these

statements includes STM, BIDS and Guy Clair, which chapter 2 evidences do not

unequivocally support the concept of necessary effect as the only rationale for the

no actual effects rule.142

The CJEU also muddies the water by using ambiguous phraseology, for example,

that certain agreements “may be considered” harmful.143 Coupled with its

requirement that an “analysis” of the coordination must reveal a sufficient degree

of harm to competition determined on the basis of its content, objectives and

economic and legal context, this suggests that any prior belief is capable of

rebuttal.144 Therefore, relying purely on ‘necessary effect’ cannot be the only

explanation for the no actual effects rule. To date, the CJEU has not provided a

convincing explanation.

An alternative explanation for the rule is proffered in STM: if the agreement itself

intends or has the ‘purpose’ of restricting competition, then that is enough to

satisfy the object requirement. This is based on the notion that EU competition law

is also preventative or ex ante in nature. Hence, it is irrelevant whether or not an

agreement is successful.145 How this purpose is proven is objectively determined

and relies heavily on what constitutes a ‘restriction of competition’ and thus the

STM Test. This means that even if an agreement contains an apparent ‘restriction

of competition’ as listed in Article 101(1)(a) to (c) TFEU, it may not have that object

when assessed in accordance with the principles of STM.146 The determinative

question is whether the agreement is designed to restrict competition.147 The case

law is unequivocal in demonstrating that even supposed hardcore restrictions of

141

Ibid, paras 55-56 citing T-Mobile (supra n8). Though notably the judgment in T-Mobile also refers to the need for ‘sufficient harm’, para 28. 142

Ibid, paras 49-51. 143

Ibid, see in particular, para 51. 144

Ibid, para 52. 145

(Deringer, 1968), para 131. As previously noted, AG Kokott and AG Trstenjak have compared this notion to risk offences or inchoate offences: see T-Mobile; BIDS. 146

STM, supra n2, paras 162-172. 147

(Deringer, 1968), para 163. See FA, para 140 (supra n2).

Page 141: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 140

competition have been found to come outside Article 101(1) TFEU or been found to

be restrictive by effect and vice versa.148

This alternative vision of the law as described under the MAAP is favoured over the

concept of necessary effect as the only sustainable explanation of the object

concept’s no actual effects rule. The case law proves that prior experience of

negative effects is not enough to taint an agreement with an anticompetitive

object. The Courts have, naturally, gained experience in applying Article 101(1)

TFEU over the decades, so it is axiomatic that certain types of agreement tend to

infringe competition by object more often than other types, in particular those

agreements which are seen to be the most serious forms of collusion.149 As such, it

makes sense that necessary effect plays a role in the assessment of object restraints

and gives rise to legal presumptions of harm. However, such presumptions are not

absolute or determinative.150

This view was shared by AG Mazák in Pierre Fabre who pointed out that “the

anticompetitive object of an agreement may not...be established solely using an

abstract formula”.151 Moreover:

“...while certain forms of agreement would appear from past

experience to be prima facie infringements by object, this does

not relieve the Commission or a national competition authority of

the obligation of carrying out an individual assessment of any

agreement...while the inclusion of [hardcore] restrictions in an

agreement would give rise to concerns regarding the conformity

of that agreement with Article 81(1) EC and indeed, after

examination of, inter alia, the particular agreement and the

economic and legal context of which it forms a part, may in fact

result in a finding of a restriction by object, there is no legal

148

See eg Cartes Bancaires (supra n101), C-27/87 Erauw-Jacquery v La Hesbignonne [1983] ECR 1919 (Louis Erauw). 149

This experience is often indirectly referred to eg, FA, para 139 (supra n2). 150

See AG Trstenjak in BIDS, para 44 (supra n48). Also ibid, FA, para 140. 151

Supra n7, Pierre Fabre, para 26 and generally paras 25–30 of the opinion. This is because “while a finding of infringement by object with respect to an agreement will not require a demonstration of its anticompetitive effect in order to establish its anticompetitive nature, the Court has held that regard must be had, inter alia, to the content of the provisions of the agreement, the objectives it seeks to attain and the economic and legal context of which it forms part”, (para 25).

Page 142: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 141

presumption that the agreement infringes Article 81(1) EC...a

individual examination is therefore required in order to assess

whether an agreement has an anticompetitive object even where

it contains a restriction which falls within the scope of [the

Vertical Block Exemption Regulation].”152

In BIDS, AG Trstenjak, was also clear that the necessary consequence of an

agreement was not the only factor to be taken into consideration in an object

assessment.153 She sided more closely with Odudu’s interpretation, finding that

“when acting rationally undertakings will expect the agreement to have the effects

which can reasonably be assumed according to the circumstances, with the result

that they intended those effects at least to some extent.”154 Overall, the question

of necessary effect requires a degree of sensibleness. The case law does not uphold

the notion that the object concept is based entirely on the concept of necessary

effect. It would, of course, be ludicrous to deny that necessary effect has any place

in an object assessment. However, it is not the sole nor overriding consideration in

any assessment of an agreement by object under Article 101(1) TFEU. That role is

left to the ‘legal and economic context’.155

3.4.3.1. Categorisation

Associated with the concept of necessary effect is the ensuing belief that a category

of agreements exist, which are ‘by their very nature’ restrictive by object.156 How

this category of agreements is constituted is controversial,157 and in particular the

question of whether it is narrow or widely construed. Any widening of the object

category is deemed concerning as raises the prospect of abuse should the

152

Supra n7, Pierre Fabre, paras 27–30 of the opinion. 153

Supra n48, BIDS, para 46. 154

Ibid, BIDS, paras 45 and 46 of the opinion. See, eg (Odudu, 2009). 155

AG Kokott also acknowledges this, T-Mobile, para 48 (supra n8). Note presumptions of harm can be seen to form part of the legal and economic context. 156

See (Mahtani, 2012). 157

See also (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p663 who believes the principles underlying object classification are not always clearly set out or explained in the case law as they could be.

Page 143: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 142

authorities be able to expand the category of nefarious agreements and thereby

disengage in an effects assessment.158

The interpretation of the law on the object concept as consisting of a category of

agreements is a false friend. It conveys an impression that is not consistently

upheld by the CJEU. In BIDS, the CJEU did not agree that the object concept relates

to an exhaustive list of prohibited forms of collusion.159 Furthermore, the AG in

BIDS did not support the argument that it can be inferred from ENS that the notion

of restriction of competition by object is limited to ‘obvious’ cases.160 This is

compounded by the case law which shows that agreements can indirectly restrict

competition by object.161

Categorisation is a useful policy tool as it gives undertakings guidance as to the

types of agreement that are generally restrictive by object, but to rely on it as a

legal mechanism is imprudent. The judgment in Cartes Bancaires shows that

“relying on pigeon holes or formal categories to identify object restrictions can

often be misleading.”162 The interpretation of the law offered under the MAAP

ensures that there is no emphasis on categorisation, particularly in view of how the

object of an agreement is determined.163 The constant reference by the Courts to

agreements that ‘by their very nature’ harm competition also gives an artificial

impression. Ideally, the term should be struck from the vocabulary of the object

concept. The case law shows that that it does not conclusively mean

“independently of any competitive analysis”.164 If it merely refers to the ‘no effects’

rule, then the CJEU should clarify this. What is clear is that the question of

categorisation will continue to be debated. The judgment in Cartes Bancaires

158

See generally (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, (Goyder, 2011), (Bennett & Collins, 2010), (Gerard, 2013). Note, cases such as T-Mobile (supra n8) and Pierre Fabre (supra n7) seemingly added new restrictions to the object category. 159

Supra n48, BIDS, para 23 confirming the AG’s opinion. This was upheld in Cartes Bancaires, para 58 (supra n101). 160

Ibid, BIDS, para 47 of the opinion. See chapter 2. 161

See supra n43, General Motors. 162

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2014) ‘Groupement des Cartes Bancaires and the resilience of the case law on restrictions by object’. 163

See chapter 4. 164

Supra n9, GSK, para 120.

Page 144: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 143

exacerbates this. Indeed, some practitioners have hailed the judgment as

confirming a narrow interpretation of restrictions by object.165

3.4.4. Rebuttable legal presumptions versus no legal presumptions under Article

101(1) TFEU

Having acknowledged the relationship between the concept of necessary effect and

the object criterion, this section examines whether legal presumptions of harm are

rebuttable under Article 101(1) TFEU.166 It is clear that any such presumptions are

not absolute. This position owes itself partly to the conflict between the concept of

necessary effect and the definition of the object criterion under STM, but in

particular to the consideration of the legal and economic context. The object

criterion is thus context driven and fact specific. Jones agrees that there are

“undoubtedly possibilities of rebutting a presumption of illegality under...Article

101(1) TFEU”.167 Those situations are “rare and hard to identify” and therefore

could lead to a perception of per se illegality.168 For Jones, the starting point in an

assessment of whether an agreement restricts competition by object is that:

“...the restraints identified in past precedents have, in principle, as

their object the restriction of competition, and it is only in

exceptional circumstances that an analysis of the purpose of the

agreement in its economic and legal context may indicate that the

presumption of anticompetitive effects is inappropriate”.169

Though this position improves on the orthodox approach, it diminishes the role of

an agreement’s context. Jones is correct to say that it is difficult to determine when

165

(Bell & Heilpern, 2014). Conversely, the Commission has interpreted the judgment as finding it requires ‘novel’ restrictions to have their object assessed more carefully and fully within their legal and economic context than those restrictions that benefit from experience: (Italianer, 10 December 2014), ‘The object of effects’, CRA conference, Brussels, 10 December 2014. 166

(Odudu, 2001), ‘The Object Requirement Revisited’, p384. See also (Black, 2005), p118. 167

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p663. 168

Ibid. 169

Ibid, p668.

Page 145: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 144

the presumption can be rebutted given the confused status of the case law.170 For

her the answer to this question remains obscure.171

The question of which agreements could give rise to a legal presumption of a

restriction by object is a pertinent one. An easy answer is that the concept of

necessary effect plays a key role in identifying those restraints most likely to

infringe Article 101(1) TFEU by object. Odudu has a more sophisticated answer,

contending that “legal presumptions developed from experience or based on party

intent that certain collusive conduct will result in allocative inefficiency”.172 Jones

also has a two-pronged approach to what she terms the “categorisation” of object

restraints, which have the “presumption of illegality” attached to them.173 She

argues that the category of object restraints constitutes specific restraints that

experience shows are likely to be anticompetitive, and “other arrangements whose

anticompetitive nature is apparent from the objective it pursues and/or the context

in which it operates”.174 Therefore she believes that “the category does not...

comprise a finite list of conduct based on past precedent” as highlighted by the AG

in BIDS.175

The fact that legal presumptions can be rebutted under Article 101(1) TFEU (and

not just under Article 101(3) TFEU) begs the question of who has that task: whether

the burden of proof under Article 101(1) TFEU is reversed to fall onto the

defendant.

3.4.4.1. Reversing the burden of proof within Article 101(1) TFEU

As discussed above, the definition of the object criterion under the MAAP does not

support presumptions of illegality. Conversely, the hybrid approach does. Hence,

170

Ibid, p668. 171

Ibid, p676. 172

(Odudu, 2006), p127. 173

(Jones, 2010), ’Left Behind by Modernisation?’, p656. 174

Ibid, p657. 175

Ibid, p657, ft 43. Jones does not, however, fully endorse the more analytical approach: her definition of ‘object’ is not the same as the definition set out in STM. She would seem to define object as conduct, which is “by its very nature injurious to competition or anticompetitive in nature”, p656.

Page 146: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 145

the following question of rebuttal is more pertinent to an understanding of the law

postulated under the latter approach.

It is clear that the onus of proof as regards a finding that an agreement restricts

competition under Article 101(1) TFEU rests on the plaintiff, usually the

Commission.176 Whether the burden of proof can then be shifted onto the

defendant to disprove a presumption of illegality by object under Article 101(1)

TFEU is tricky. Under the MAAP, the onus arguably remains at all times on the

Commission to prove to the requisite level that the object of the agreement is to

restrict competition. An incorrect or incomplete assessment would open the

Commission up to challenge. The burden and standard of proof under the MAAP is

clearly more demanding than under the orthodox approach. The extent to which it

is more demanding depends on the facts of the case.177 That is not to say, however,

that the defendant cannot influence the outcome.

Bailey submits that the legal burden remains on the competition authority to prove

the infringement it is asserting. However, the evidential burden of proving the facts

in issue may shift between the parties.178 A number of commentators support the

proposition that the defendant plays a role in rebutting a presumption under Article

101(1) TFEU. Andreangeli interprets AG Trstenjak in BIDS as accepting that “a party

seeking to disprove the allegations of an infringement to prove the existence of

‘elements of legal and economic context which could cast doubt on the existence of

a restriction of competition’”.179 Odudu also supports this by stating that the effect

of the presumption is to shift the burden of proof within Article 101(1) TFEU.180 He

considers that it is for those engaged in the practice to demonstrate the absence of

detrimental consequences.181

176

(Bailey, 2010), B.I. 177

See chapter 4. 178

(Bailey, 2010), B.I. 179

(Andreangeli, 2011), p225. See also (Odudu, 2009), p14: “The ability to ‘cast doubt’ on the applicability of the presumption that competition is restricted makes it clear that the presumption of necessary consequences is rebuttable rather than conclusive”. 180

(Odudu, 2009), p15. 181

Ibid.

Page 147: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 146

This interpretation is supported by the CJEU in FA.182 The Court did not believe the

defendant (in this case the FA) to have provided sufficient evidence of

circumstances within the legal and economic context to justify a finding that the

agreement did not restrict competition by object.183 Mahtani surmises that the

Court did not clarify precisely when a prima facie breach by object will not result in

a restriction by object, “although it seems to have been the FA’s burden to

discharge”.184 Thus, the shift in the evidential burden of proof is a valid argument:

in FA it was for the parties to provide convincing evidence “falling within the

economic and legal context”, to disprove that the agreement was not liable to

impair competition and therefore not have an anticompetitive object.185

Nevertheless, the issue of rebuttal is far from straightforward. Odudu suggests that

it is possible to disprove detrimental consequences, which - if one believes that

object means ‘necessary effect’ or ‘presumption of effect’ - then dilutes the sense

of that concept.186 Additionally, the concept of necessary effect is supported by the

common rule that the success of an agreement is irrelevant to a finding by object.

Hence, the real issue is the need to understand what the function of any such

rebuttal is. For instance, is its role to rebut: (i) the legal presumption of harm, that

is, restrictive effects and/or, (ii) that particular agreements are automatically

considered restrictive by object, or (iii) that the aim of the agreement to restrict

competition? The answer to this remains unclear. It arguably depends on how the

object criterion is assessed. The orthodox approach does not permit presumptions

of negative effects to be rebutted, whereas the hybrid approach suggests that

presumptions of harm are capable of rebuttal, either because the aim of an

agreement is not to restrict competition despite containing a prima facie object

restraint, or because the detrimental consequences can be disproved. Although

technically the MAAP demands that the plaintiff must prove an agreement has the

purpose of restricting competition, it recognises necessary effect as a relevant

182

FA (supra n2), as cited in (Mahtani, 2012), p14. 183

(Mahtani, 2012), p14; FA, para 143 (supra n2). 184

Ibid (Mahtani, 2012). 185

FA, para 143 (supra n2). 186

(Odudu, 2009).

Page 148: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 147

factor in such assessment. Hence, parties would be wise to adduce evidence to

rebut any presumptions of harm and prove that the agreement was not designed to

restrict competition.

This issue is aided by Bailey who argues that there should be no conclusive

substantive or evidential presumptions in EU competition law.187 Moreover, he

considers that what may suffice as convincing evidence to rebut a presumption and

the ease with which this is done will vary depending on the presumption in

question.188 Ultimately this underlines, again, how dependent the assessment of

the object criterion is on the facts of the case. Indeed, the case law suggests that it

is for the plaintiff to convince the Court it sufficiently assessed whether an

agreement has the object or effect to restrict competition.189

The contention is, therefore, that ultimately the legal burden under Article 101(1)

TFEU remains with the Commission, though the defendant can produce evidence

demonstrating why the burden should be rebutted.190 Evidently, the consideration

of an agreement’s specific legal and economic context is key to such a finding.191

Hence the application and assessment of the object criterion under Article 101(1)

TFEU is considered closely in chapter 4, which focuses on the role of the legal and

economic context.

3.4.5. Conclusion: presumptions of harm

This section examined whether there are legal presumptions that particular

restraints restrict competition by object due to their known negative effects. The

outcome is that there are no absolute legal presumptions: under the MAAP any

agreement is capable of restricting competition by object whereas under the hybrid

approach any such presumptions are capable of rebuttal.192 The role of necessary

187

(Bailey, 2010), IV, E. 188

Ibid, III.C. 189

See both GSK judgments, GC judgement in particular (supra n9 and n10). 190

(Svetlicinii & Sad, 2011), III (3), p351. 191

See chapter 4. 192

Odudu agrees the presumption of necessary consequence is rebuttable as was successfully demonstrated in the GC’s judgment in GSK and in O2: (Odudu, 2009).

Page 149: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 148

effect is significant in this regard. It is axiomatic that, after 60 years of case law,

experience will now play a part in the determination of infringements of

competition under Article 101(1) TFEU. However, the concept of necessary effect is

not sufficient justification for a category of restrictions to exist, by law, which can

be said to automatically restrict competition by object. Even if such a category of

agreements were to exist, then it would need to be flexible.193 As such, the value of

categorisation is limited given its fluidity. How the CJEU grapples with this issue

unfortunately becomes no clearer with time.194 Moreover, the presence of the

legal and economic context in every assessment of object reinforces this view. The

question as to whether the burden of proof within Article 101(1) TFEU shifts on to

the defendant can nonetheless be answered by reference to Bailey’s interpretation.

The evidential burden may shift, but ultimately the legal burden under Article

101(1) TFEU to prove that an agreement has the object of restricting competition

remains with the plaintiff.

3.5. The definition of ‘object’: conclusion

This section was tasked with assessing how the Courts have defined (if at all) the

object criterion. This exercise revealed that the definition is dependent on the

context in which it is delivered, namely, whether under the MAAP, the orthodox

approach or the hybrid approach.

Under the MAAP, the object of an agreement is understood as whether its ‘precise

purpose’ is to restrict competition and thus is an open-ended enquiry as any type of

agreement has the propensity to restrict competition under this guise.195

Conversely, the orthodox and hybrid approaches do not turn on a literal definition

of the term, rather a notion that the object criterion relates to serious and

ostensibly obvious restrictions of competition, which ‘by their very nature’ infringe

Article 101(1) TFEU. Hence, the notion of ‘object’ rests on a category of

193

Further, any category would only be based on judgements of the European Courts and not on pronouncements by the Commission. 194

See eg Cartes Bancaires (supra n101). 195

The relationship between the object concept and what constitutes a restriction of competition is considered in chapter 5.

Page 150: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 149

agreements that automatically restrict competition, primarily due to their

necessary effect.

These definitions appear to conflict and can immediately be seen as capable of

producing different results. For instance, under the MAAP it is perfectly

conceivable (though that is not to suggest it is likely) that restrictions that are not

obvious or prima facie hardcore may be found to infringe Article 101(1) TFEU by

object. Conversely, the orthodox approach applies to obvious restrictions based on

their known negative effects. The concept of necessary effect is a key driver in the

interpretation of the object criterion under both the orthodox and hybrid

approaches. However, chapter 2 found that, on the whole, the MAAP benefits from

greater judicial support. Its attributes as regards the definition of the object

criterion are clear; it is flexible and has the ability to adapt to changing economic

circumstances in view of its close association with what constitutes a ‘restriction of

competition’. Hence, the definition of the object criterion should follow the

MAAP’s interpretation. The merits of the MAAP versus the hybrid and orthodox

approaches cannot be appropriately assessed, however, until the application of the

object criterion is investigated.196

Having explained the way in which the three approaches define ‘object’, this

chapter closes the discussion on its meaning. The next chapter, therefore, hones in

on how the object of an agreement is determined under the MAAP. To this end, it

focuses on the application of the legal and economic context, which is the

cornerstone that underpins our understanding of the notion of restrictions of

competition by object.

196

See chapter 4.

Page 151: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 150

Chapter 4: Applying the object concept to agreements in accordance

with the MAAP

1. Introduction

Building upon the legal analysis of the meaning of the object concept in accordance

with the jurisprudence of the European Courts, this chapter examines the

application of the object concept under Article 101(1) TFEU. Chapter 3 identified

that, under the MAAP, the object concept means the ‘precise purpose’ of an

agreement. How that purpose is then determined in accordance with the more

analytical approach is the focus of this chapter.

This chapter proceeds as follows: first, it considers the application of the legal and

economic context. This comprises an investigation of its definition and how it

determines an agreement’s purpose with reference to influences such as legitimate

goals/ objectives and ancillary restraints. How the legal and economic context may

be used as tool to rebut presumptions of harm is also reflected upon. Secondly, it

asks how restrictive effects impact on the application of the legal and economic

context, including use of the counterfactual. Thirdly, it examines how other

commentators have rationalised the case law on the object criterion and highlights

the subtle differences between the MAAP and hybrid approaches in respect of

presumption rebuttal. Finally, it will make a judgment from a purely legal

perspective as to what is the best interpretation of ‘restrictions of competition by

object’. It will conclude that, based on a granular investigation of the case law, the

best interpretation of the object criterion is in accordance with the MAAP.

2. Legal and economic context

The direction of recent case law has driven attention towards the pivotal role of the

legal and economic context in determining the object of an agreement.1 The

1 Such as the Game Changer Cases and more recently Case C-32/11, Allianz Hungária Biztosító Zrt v

Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, 14 March 2013, nyr (Allianz Hungária); Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre Dermo-Cosmétique SAS v Président de l’Autorité de la concurrence, [2001] ECR I-9419 (Pierre Fabre);

Page 152: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 151

European Courts have consistently reiterated the significance of context to an

object assessment in nearly every judgment since BIDS. This is largely due to the

consistent citation of STM. Determining an agreement’s object within its legal and

economic context is therefore not a choice, it is a legal requirement.2 Despite the

recognition of its importance, the precise boundaries of the legal and economic

context and hence its role in the assessment of agreements under Article 101(1)

TFEU necessitates examination.

A useful starting point is to examine the AG’s Opinion in BIDS. AG Trstenjak dealt

specifically with the issue of the legal and economic context and her opinion

highlights how it impacts on the outcome of a determination by object, and notes

the various issues that can be taken into account under its umbrella.3 As seen in

chapter 2, the Advocate General insisted that the legal and economic context “must

be taken seriously”, though it should not be “seen as a gateway for any factor which

suggests that an agreement is compatible with the common market”.4 Instead,

only the elements of the legal and economic context which may cast doubts on the

existence of a restriction of competition can be taken into account.5 The AG

thereby suggested that the legal and economic context is a means by which to

question and rebut legal presumptions of anti-competitiveness under Article 101(1)

TFEU. She recognised that presumptions play a role in the determination of the

object of an agreement, but also that such presumptions are rebuttable within the

context of Article 101(1) TFEU. In this guise, she has supported the hybrid

approach.

AG Trstenjak recounted three categories where the “assumption of a restriction of

competition” could be rebutted as a result of an investigation into the legal and

Case C-67/13 P, Groupement des Cartes Bancaires (CB) v Commission, 11 September 2014, nyr (Cartes Bancaires). 2 Andreangeli notes that even though the CJEU in BIDS found that the arrangements constituted an

inherently ‘obvious’ infringement which justified a presumption of anti-competitive effects, the CJEU still expressly chose to analyse the arrangement against its legal and economic context: (Andreangeli, 2011), p225. 3 Case C-209/07 Competition Authority v Beef Industry Development Society Ltd and Barry Brothers

(Carrigmore) Meats Ltd [2008] ECR I-8637 (BIDS), paras 50-59. 4 Ibid, para 50.

5 Ibid, para 50.

Page 153: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 152

economic context.6 These are: (i) when a limitation on the freedom of undertakings

to determine their policy on the market independently has no effects in relation to

competition;7 (ii) where an agreement is ambivalent in terms of its effects on

competition (that is, it has a pro-competitive aim) and there is a necessary

restriction of the requirement of independence; and (iii) ancillary agreements which

are necessary in order to pursue a primary objective. In this last respect, where the

primary objective is neutral or promotes competition then the ancillary restrictions

are necessary to achieve that aim and so do not infringe Article 101(1) TFEU.8

Arguably, the legal and economic context does not simply provide a rebuttal

mechanism for legal presumptions, but provides the scope to assess whether an

agreement has the primary purpose of restricting competition. This can be

achieved by applying the counterfactual, the ancillary restraints doctrine and

assessing whether a restriction in an agreement has a legitimate objective or is

objectively justified.9 The case law is not entirely clear in this respect, particularly

as regards the law on an agreement having multiple purposes and legitimate

aims.10 Nevertheless, it does permit tentative conclusions to be drawn, particularly

with a view to how the law could be applied in the future.

2.1. Definition

As with the phrase ‘of its nature’, what constitutes the ‘legal and economic context’

is rarely defined. Mahtani complains that there is insufficient clarity to show how

the application of the legal and economic context should be applied to cases and

that it has been invoked inconsistently.11 Certainly, the definition is wide and has

the propensity to encompass any aspect of analysis of an agreement needed to

6 Ibid, paras 51-54.

7 See eg (Mahtani, 2012), p37. He interprets this as an application of a form of the counterfactual.

8 Ibid, p37. Mahtani likens the final two categories as being similar to when a prima facie object

restriction is balanced against a legitimate commercial purpose and the conduct is necessary to achieve that purpose. 9 See Joined Cases C-403 & 429/08, Football Association Premier League Ltd v QC Leisure and Karen

Murphy v Media Protection Services Ltd, [2011] ECR I- 9083 (FA), para 140. Cf (Mahtani, 2012), p19. 10

See eg supra n3, BIDS; Joined Cases C-96/82 etc, IAZ v Commission/ ANSEAU [1983] ECR 3369; cf supra n1, Pierre Fabre. 11

(Mahtani, 2012), p26.

Page 154: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 153

determine its object.12 STM provides the best indication of the factors, particularly

economic ones, that should be taken into account when considering the object of

an agreement.13 These factors have already been documented.14 What is pertinent

is that such factors are applicable to determining both object and effect.15 This

level of assessment indicates that defining the market would not be a step too far in

order to apply the STM Test. In fact, it may be necessary to understand not only

one market, but the relationship between two or more markets.16 L’Oréal also

supports such conclusion.17 The case law review in chapter 2 demonstrates how

extensively the European Courts have looked at the market concerned, the position

of the parties on that market, the nature of the product or services and the

surrounding circumstances of the agreement when carrying out an examination of

the object criterion. Hence, the economic context relates to the specific context of

the agreement itself: what were the circumstances of its implementation and why,

what is the background to the agreement as well as what were the market factors

and the position of the parties within that market. Ultimately, the Court is asking,

what is the agreement’s genesis?

The extent to which such analysis is undertaken varies from case to case.18 It is

consistently reiterated by the Courts, and indeed by commentators, that the

context refers to the specific context of the particular case.19 As such, each case is

considered on its merits and unique circumstances.20 From the perspective of the

MAAP, the goal of assessing an agreement in its legal and economic context is not

to prove that the agreement has the actual effect of restricting competition,21 but

12

This view is supported by the CJEU in Cartes Bancaires, para 78 (supra n1). See also paras 77-90. 13

Confirmed in Allianz Hungária and Cartes Bancaires (supra n1). 14

See the STM Test (chapter 2). 15

Case C-56/65 Société Technique Minière V Maschinenbau Ulm [1966] ECR 235, (STM), 250. Reinforced by cases such as Allianz Hungária. 16

See supra n1, Cartes Bancaires, paras 73-82, which considered two-sided markets. 17

Case C-31/80 L’Oréal NV and L’Oréal SV v De Nieuwe AMCK PVBA [1980] ECR 3775, para 19. 18

See eg STM (supra n15). 19

See (Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), para 4.19 onwards; (Jones, 2010), Left Behind By Modernisation? Indeed the GC rebuked the Commission in Case T-168/01 GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission [2006] ECR II-2969 for simply looking at past precedents without proper reference to the agreement’s context, para 138. 20

See (Lasok QC, 2008). 21

Thereby distinguishing itself from ‘effect’.

Page 155: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 154

simply to ascertain whether the true purpose (that is, the object) of the agreement

is to restrict competition.22 Under the hybrid approach, there is an additional

challenge. The use of the legal and economic context is also required to determine

if a presumption of anti-competitiveness can be rebutted. As will be seen, despite

the Courts alluding to the application of the hybrid approach when describing the

distinction between object and effect, in many cases they are in fact looking to

determine the aim of the agreement when applying the legal and economic

context.23 Considering the context of an agreement to determine an agreement’s

purpose may encompass, inter alia, assessing its potential effects. Therefore, the

economic context of an agreement is wide-ranging and by its nature unspecific.

Yet, it cannot be comfortably described as completely ‘abstract’.24

The ‘legal context’ on the other hand presumably consists of the relevant law, such

as the case law of the European Courts, and any relevant Directives, Regulations or

other applicable national laws or regulatory frameworks, including the legal or

regulatory context within which the parties to the agreement operate. These

factors suggest that past precedent is a factor to be taken into consideration. This

requirement needs to be balanced against the economic context of the agreement.

Notably, the CJEU has not always referred specifically to an agreement’s ‘legal’

context, instead specifying the consideration of its ‘economic’ context.25 The

implications of this inconsistency are unclear though probably immaterial, as

arguably taking account of an agreement’s legal context can be inferred from the

requirement that the general circumstances of the agreement should be considered

22

See eg (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘Groupement des cartes bancaires and the resilience of the case law on restrictions by object’. 23

See eg BIDS (supra n3). 24

Cf, opinion in Case C-250/92 Gøttrup-Klim v Dansk Landbrugs Grovvareselskat AmbA [1994] ECR I-5641 (Gøttrup-Klim). This understanding of ‘context’ subjects the MAAP to criticism from proponents of categorisation who value bright lines and legal certainty. 25

The judgment in Joined Cases 56 & 58/64, Etablissements Consten SA and Grundigverkaufs-GmbH v Commission, [1966] ECR 342 (Consten & Grundig) introduced the notion of the ‘legal and economic’ context, though judgments such as Case C-5/69 Franz Völk v SPRL Ets J Vervaecke [1969] ECR 295 (Völk) do not refer specifically to the ‘legal’ context.

Page 156: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 155

in any assessment of an agreement’s object.26 Nevertheless, the CJEU usually now

refers to the ‘legal and economic context’ of an agreement.27

To demonstrate how wide ranging the application of the legal and economic

context is, the section below focuses on three areas. It will examine how context is

used as a medium: (i) to undertake a form of balancing exercise by balancing the

positive attributes of an agreement against its negative attributes; (ii) to consider

the applicability of an objective justification or legitimate aim; and (iii) to consider

whether particular restrictions are ancillary to an overall pro-competitive object.

2.2. Applying the legal and economic context to determine the precise purpose of

an agreement: balancing the positive aims of an agreement against negative ones

Any proposal to balance the positive and negative attributes of an agreement is

contentious as it leads, inevitably, to comparisons with the US rule of reason. As

has been clearly established by the Courts (regardless of whether that

interpretation is correct), the rule of reason does not have a role in EU competition

law, more specifically within the context of the effect analysis.28 Therefore, as with

references to ‘per se’, the rule of reason does not provide an appropriate analogy

under EU law for the balancing process that sometimes occurs under Article 101(1)

TFEU.29 Instead, this process can be viewed somewhat differently: the question is

whether a pro-competitive aim of an agreement has the power to trump particular

restrictions of competition contained within it.30 Chapter 2 revealed that there

have been a number of cases where, when assessed under the object criterion, the

positive attributes of an agreement have either outweighed the negative attributes

26

See eg Case C-23/67, Brasserie De Haecht v Wilkin (no.1), [1967] ECR 407; and Anseau/IAZ (supra n10). In C-501/06 P GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission (GSK) [2009] ECR I-9291 (GSK), paras 61-64 the CJEU referred to the fact that agreements aimed at limiting parallel trade are, in principal, prohibited by object. See chapter 2. 27

See eg Pierre Fabre; Cartes Bancaires, para 53 (supra n1). 28

See Andreangeli’s analysis of the balancing undertaken by the European Courts under Article 101 TFEU: (Andreangeli, 2011), p227 onwards. 29

The position in the US will be briefly compared with that in the EU in chapter 6. 30

See eg Case T-328/03, O2 (Germany) GmbH & Co OHG v Commission, [2006] ECR II-1231, Case C-519/04P, Meca-Medina v Commission, [2006] ECR I-6991, Case C-309/99, Wouters v Algemene Raad van de Nederlandsche Orde van Advocaten, [2002] ECR I-1577.

Page 157: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 156

so that the agreement did not restrict competition by object or were not

considered sufficient to excuse the application of object.31

Knowing quite when the positive attributes of an agreement will trump an

application of the object criterion is difficult. This is because the case law

establishing the MAAP proposes that the legal and economic context should

determine whether such attributes will be successful in a particular case.

Therefore, it is not possible to predict with certainty whether the factors that were

successful in rebutting a restriction by object in one case will be equally as

successful in another case. The outcome will depend on the facts of the case.32 It is

of course helpful nevertheless to understand when the European Courts look at the

positive attributes of an agreement and in what circumstances those attributes

either fail or succeed to rebut a presumption of restriction of competition by

object, bringing an agreement outside Article 101(1) TFEU entirely or warrant that

its ‘effect’ requires determination.33

Under the MAAP it is conceivable that an agreement that has a pro-competitive aim

could be found not to restrict competition by object despite containing apparent

‘by object’ restrictions. The question for consideration is: how is the primary

purpose of the agreement determined if an agreement has an apparently pro-

competitive aim, but otherwise contains restrictions of competition? In responding

to this question, the case law has produced some interesting answers.

In Asnef Equifax a horizontal credit information exchange agreement was held not

to have the object of restricting competition as its “essential object” was to make

31

See eg Case C-41/69 ACF Chemiefarma v Commission [1970] ECR 661. In Anseau/IAZ (supra n10) the purpose of the agreement (to counter a shortage of raw materials and to protect the public health respectively) was not enough to invalidate the anticompetitive object of the agreement. In C-27/87 Erauw-Jacquery v La Hesbignonne [1983] ECR 1919 (Louis Erauw) absolute territorial protection was not held to infringe Article 101(1) TFEU and, in fact, came outside it as the Court recognised it was important that persons should be allowed to protect their financial investment in developing their products. Whereas in Völk (supra n25, paras 5-7), ATP was held to come outside Article 101(1) TFEU as the effect on the market was insignificant, which was established by a reference to the actual circumstances of the agreement. 32

See supra n9 FA, paras 140, 143. 33

Scholars such as Jones, Andreangeli, Goyder, Mahtani and Odudu have also found no consistent rational explanation or methodology and have thus proffered their own conclusions.

Page 158: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 157

available to credit providers relevant information about existing or potential

borrowers.34 Therefore, its positive attributes outweighed the fact that it was a

horizontal information exchange agreement. The CJEU has viewed selective

distribution agreements in a similar vein. In AEG, the Court found that the object of

the agreement was to improve competition and therefore particular restrictions of

competition were justified.35 In Pierre Fabre the AG articulated very well the

inherent balancing that takes place as regards selective distribution systems.36 He

emphasised that “an individual examination is...required in order to assess whether

an agreement has an anticompetitive object even where it contains a restriction

which falls within the scope of [the VBER]”.37 When allowing absolute territorial

protection (ATP) in Louis Erauw, the Court explained that plant breeders need to

protect their financial investment when developing products.38 In that case, the

Court considered that such a clause would fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU.39

Conversely, in Asnef the CJEU found that the register did not have a restrictive

effect. It appears that once an agreement is not found restrictive by object the

circumstances of the case dictate whether it then falls outside Article 101(1) TFEU

or must be assessed by effect.40

These cases show that there is clear precedent for a positive, pro-competitive

purpose of an agreement to be taken into account and actively balanced against

the restrictions contained in the agreement under the object criterion.

Furthermore, a positive aim may trump a finding that any related restraints have

the object of restricting competition. In these instances, those restrictions do not

outweigh the benefits of the positive aim of the agreement and therefore should be

34

Case C-238/05, Asnef-Equifax, Servicios de Información sobre Solvencia y Crédito, SL v Asociación de Usuarios de Servicios Bancarios (Ausbanc), [2006] ECR I-11125 (‘Asnef’). This point is also noted by (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, pp649, 652. 35

C-107/82 AEG-Telefunken v Commission [1983] ECR 3151. 36

Pierre Fabre, footnote 39 of the opinion and paras 35, 42 and 52 of the opinion (supra n1). 37

Ibid, para 30. 38

Louis Erauw, paras 10-11 (supra n31). Though the reasoning for this decision could also be attributed to the fact such restrictions are ancillary to the main purpose of the agreement. 39

Ibid, paras 10-11. This can be contrasted with a different approach that the Court adopted in Völk (supra n25, paras 5-7). Here, the Court held that any restriction of competition will not be a restriction by object if the effect on the market is insignificant. In fact, in such cases the agreement would fall outside Article 101 TFEU entirely. 40

This is considered further below.

Page 159: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 158

assessed by reason of their ‘effect’ or fall outside Article 101 TFEU entirely.

Whether this is a true case of ‘balancing’ is, however, a matter of labelling. Any

such balancing is not concerned merely with weighing the effects of an agreement

(though these may be taken into consideration). It could instead be described as a

method by which the Court establishes the primary purpose of the agreement, and

finding that on the facts, restrictions required to achieve that (pro-competitive) end

are justified.41

The best examples of this kind of balancing are seen when the Courts assess

selective distribution agreements. In Pierre Fabre the Court held a restriction of an

absolute ban on internet sales was a step too far: it was not justifiable.42 The Court

took this a step further by pronouncing that selective distribution agreements were

“restrictions by object” in the absence of “objective justification”.43 Understanding

the law in accordance with the MAAP does not support such a proposition.

Selective distribution agreements are not automatically designated or categorised

as restrictions by object. Instead, it is perhaps more appropriate to say that they

“necessarily restrict competition”, that is, they restrict competition.44 The AG made

the point in a more adroit fashion, “the mere fact that the selective distribution

agreements in question...may restrict parallel trade may not in itself be sufficient to

establish that the agreement has the object of restricting competition pursuant to

Article 101(1)”.45

The main point of interest in Pierre Fabre was the reference by the Court to

“objective justification”.46 This pointed to an open acknowledgment that an

agreement can escape a finding of object if it can be objectively justified, which

41

The notion that the analysis of the object of an agreement must reveal a sufficient degree of impairment of competition is also pertinent in this regard: the scope of factors that may be considered under the STM Test is broad. See, FA, para 135 (supra n9). 42

Supra n1 Pierre Fabre. See (Mahtani, 2012), p37. 43

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 39. 44

Ibid, Pierre Fabre para 39. No further cases can be found linking object with selective distribution agreements. 45

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, opinion, para 42. The Court ostensibly followed the AG’s opinion, though couched certain elements of the opinion in its own terms, which due to the nuances in language involved inevitably leads to an entirely different interpretation. This is not a lone example of such careless law-making. 46

The position taken by the CJEU is correct and has precedent, see chapter 2.

Page 160: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 159

implies that any legal presumption of anti-competitiveness is capable of being

rebutted within Article 101(1) TFEU. Moreover, justification of a restriction of

competition by object requires a form of balancing between the positive versus the

negative attributes of an agreement.47 Furthermore, such analysis is based on the

facts of the particular case in issue in its unique legal and economic context.48 If the

purpose of an agreement is to improve competition then - particularly in the

context of selective distribution agreements - so long as certain criteria are met (in

this instance, the Metro criteria) an agreement will not be held to restrict

competition under Article 101(1) TFEU. The significance here is that those types of

agreement do not then require analysis under the effect criterion to determine

their actual effects. Therefore the Courts have shown willingness to devise criteria

to allow what are, ultimately, pro-competitive agreements to come outside Article

101(1) TFEU entirely. The fact that the Courts are prepared to do this would

suggest that they are also prepared to allow other types of restraints in other

circumstances. Ultimately, it highlights how limiting the orthodox approach is. It

does not cater for these anomalies in the case law.49

To therefore reflect the so-called ‘balancing’ of the positive aims of an agreement

under the legal and economic context, the best definition of ‘object’ under MAAP is

confirmed as the ‘precise purpose’ of the agreement.

Another case where the Court balances the pro-competitive aspects of an

agreement despite acknowledging known negative effects on competition (that is,

the necessary consequence of the agreement) was that of Wouters.50 The CJEU

held that a national regulation adopted by a body such as the Bar of the

Netherlands did not infringe Article 101(1) TFEU, since that body could reasonably

have considered that the regulation, despite the restrictive effects inherent in it,

47

Supra n1, Pierre Fabre, para 40. 48

Ibid, paras 39 to 47, in particular para 47. 49

Ibáñez Colomo believes AG Wahl in Cartes Bancaires understands the significance of context when determining if “an agreement is a plausible source of efficiency gains”, that is, only agreements that have no credible redeeming features will restrict competition by object: (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘Chapeau bas, Prof Wahl’. 50

Supra n30, Wouters. See also (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p666.

Page 161: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 160

was necessary for the proper practice of the legal profession within the Member

State concerned.51 Moreover, the Court maintained that “not every agreement

between undertakings or every decision of an association of undertakings which

restricts the freedom of action of the parties or of one of them necessarily falls

within the prohibition laid down in Article 101(1) of the Treaty”.52 This case

demonstrates perfectly, that an agreement that has known negative effects on

competition can still fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU entirely if the restraints are

necessary to support the ultimate aim of the agreement, in this case, to regulate

the legal profession. The Court clearly showed how it weighed up the positive

attributes of the agreement against the negative ones with an eye firmly on a

Member State’s ability to regulate its legal profession.53

2.3. Legitimate goals/aims/objectives and objective justifications

Alongside the idea that a pro-competitive purpose can lawfully allow certain

restrictions of competition to be contained within an agreement without infringing

Article 101(1) TFEU, is the concept of an agreement having a ‘legitimate

goal/aim/objective’.54 The Courts use of these phrases has not always been

consistent. Therefore, the overlap with what constitutes a ‘positive aim’ or

‘purpose’ of an agreement can be considerable, and in many cases probably means

the same thing. If there were a distinction between having a legitimate aim versus

a positive purpose, it could be as follows: the European Courts have said in a

number of cases that simply having a ‘legitimate goal’ is not enough to bring an

agreement outside the realms of Article 101(1) TFEU or to escape a finding of

restriction by object.55 This was aptly demonstrated in BIDS, where the ‘legitimate

goal’ of the agreement, as argued by BIDS, was to address the overcapacity in the

51

Ibid, Wouters, para 110. 52

Ibid, Wouters, para 97. 53

Ibid, Wouters, paras 73-110. 54

These phrases are used interchangeably. 55

See supra n3, BIDS.

Page 162: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 161

Irish processing industry.56 Hence, the issue was considered at length by AG

Trstenjak.57

Her strategy was first to determine if the purpose of the agreement was to restrict

competition, and if that was found to be the case then to consider whether a pro-

competitive object or unobjectionable primary objective could cast doubt on the

finding of the existence of a restriction of competition.58 The twist in this strategy

was that despite agreeing that ‘obvious’ restrictions are not required in order to

find a restriction by object, she considered that the legal and economic context was

to be “taken into account only in so far as it can cast doubt on the existence of a

restriction of competition”.59

To determine the object of an agreement, the AG found that regard “must be had

to the content of the agreement in the light of its legal and economic context”.60

What is more, the AG’s methodology involved assessing the effect on market

conditions of the agreement’s restrictions on the parties’ independence.61 The AG

applied the counterfactual to determine this and took account of the effects which

were the “necessary consequence” of the agreement and the effects which the

parties intended to achieve through those restrictions.62 Such an analysis cannot be

described as anything other than detailed. Having considered, inter alia, the

counterfactual, the agreement’s effect on market conditions and on the withdrawal

of players from the market, the effects of overcapacity in that market, levies,

lessons from “economic science”, and restrictions on use and disposal, the AG

56

See chapter 2 for the facts. 57

See BIDS, paras 23-34 of the opinion (supra n3), which sets out the arguments of the parties. This clearly illustrates how BIDS considered none of its restrictions fell within the object category and they had the legitimate objective of eliminating overcapacity (paras 25 and 26). 58

Ibid, BIDS, para 60: “first it must be considered whether the agreements have restrictions of competition as their necessary consequence or are aimed at limiting the freedom of the parties to determine their policy on the market independently and thereby at affecting market conditions. Subsequently it must be examined as part of an overall assessment whether the restrictive elements are necessary in order to achieve a precompetitive object or a primary objective which does not come under...Article [101]1 TFEU”. Emphasis added. 59

Ibid, para 59. 60

Ibid, para 43 citing STM. Emphasis added. 61

Ibid, para 62-93. 62

Ibid, para 63-65.

Page 163: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 162

reached an “interim conclusion”.63 She found that the agreement’s purpose of

reducing production capacity, through processors leaving the market, the staging of

levies and the restrictions on use and disposal had, as a ‘necessary consequence’,

the restriction of competition.64 This initial conclusion was then subject to the

consideration of whether the agreements had a pro-competitive or a primary

objective which could call such conclusion into doubt.

Surprisingly, the AG gave rather brief consideration to the rebutting factors. She

looked at the “aims” pursued by the BIDS agreements. BIDS argued that the

restrictions (collection of levies, restrictions on use and disposal) were justified as

the agreement had a legitimate objective of limiting overcapacity and achieving

economies of scale.65 The AG reiterated that obvious restrictions are not the only

types of restriction capable of restricting competition by object and, even if a sector

is experiencing a structural crisis this does not prevent the application of Article

101(1) TFEU.66 The AG reasoned that the BIDS situation was different from those

where an agreement pursues “either a pro-competitive object or an object which is

neutral from a competition point of view”.67 This is because the “aim of increasing

the profitability of the processing industry as a whole by reducing the overcapacity

by 25% inevitably results in a restriction of competition”.68 Therefore, the BIDS

agreements had the object of restricting competition.

AG Trstenjak concluded, sagely, that the content of an agreement must always be

examined against the backdrop of its legal and economic context. Hence, to

compare agreements is not always appropriate. Such an exercise can fail to address

the question of when a restriction of competition by object exists.69 Ultimately, the

AG credits the balancing of positive versus negative attributes of an agreement

63

Ibid, paras 62-93. 64

Ibid, paras 62–94, para 70. 65

Ibid, para 96. 66

Ibid, paras 98-99, citing Joined Cases T-217/03 and T-245/03 FNCBV v Commission [2006] ECR II-4987, para 90 and IAZ/Anseau (supra n10). 67

Ibid, BIDS, para 100. Emphasis added. 68

Ibid, BIDS. Emphasis added. 69

Ibid, BIDS, para 104. This mirrors a similar point made by the GC in GSK (supra n19).

Page 164: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 163

under the object criterion. This highlights how it is inherently possible for any type

of restriction to restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU.

Conversely, the consideration of an ‘objective justification’ as a means to justify a

restriction of competition, as opposed to arguing that an agreement had a

legitimate aim, was considered by the Court in Pierre Fabre.70 The CJEU, however,

makes little distinction between what constitutes a legitimate objective and an

objective justification. The CJEU found that in the absence of an objective

justification a selective distribution agreement was to be considered a restriction by

object.71 According to the CJEU, the Court has always recognised that there are

“legitimate requirements” that may justify “a reduction of price competition in

favour of competition relating to factors other than price.”72 Such legitimate

requirements include the maintenance of a specialist trade capable of providing

specific services as regards high-quality and high-technology products.73 When

selective distribution systems “aim” at the “attainment of a legitimate goal capable

of improving competition in relation to factors other than price” such agreements

can be in conformity with Article 101(1) TFEU.74 In Pierre Fabre, a preliminary

reference case, the question referred was whether a prohibition on all forms of

internet selling was capable of being “justified by a legitimate aim” or alternatively

whether the restrictions of competition “pursue legitimate aims in a proportionate

manner”.75 The Court, however, chose to limit its frame of reference by

considering the restrictions in the context of selective distribution agreements

examined in accordance with the Metro criteria.76 This questions whether the

70

Supra n1, Pierre Fabre. 71

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 39. Note the Court provides no citation supporting this contention. It was however correct to say that, as per AEG-Tellefunken that selective distribution systems ‘necessarily affect competition’. Cf para 42 of the opinion which clarifies selective distribution systems ‘necessarily restrict competition’. 72

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 40 73

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 40. 74

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 40. 75

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, paras 42, 43. 76

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 43 referencing para 41.

Page 165: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 164

issues raised in Pierre Fabre should be considered outside the realms of selective

distribution.77

It is unwise to disregard the Pierre Fabre judgment, however, as the CJEU closely

considered the application of the object criterion. It clarified that an aim to

maintain a brand’s prestigious image does not constitute a ‘legitimate aim’ for

restricting competition.78 In this case, the agreement required the sale of products

to be made in the presence of a qualified pharmacist, the result of which was that

internet sales of those products were banned. An interesting factor is that the

agreement did not specifically ban internet sales. It was inferred from the

consequences of the requirement that a qualified pharmacist be present at the

point of sale, hence it was an indirect restriction. This underlines, again, the

importance of assessing an agreement’s content and circumstances as well as its

potential effects.

Ultimately, the Court found that in the context of selective distribution systems, a

clause requiring the sale of products to be made in the presence of a qualified

pharmacist thus resulting in a ban on the use of the internet for those sales,

amounts to a restriction by object. This finding relied on an:

“individual and specific examination of the content and objective of that contractual clause and the legal and economic context of which it forms a part, and it is apparent that, having regard to the properties of the products at issue, that clause is not objectively justified.”79

77

Ibid, Pierre Fabre. See also para 47. 78

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 45. 79

Ibid, Pierre Fabre, para 47. Cf (Svetlicinii & Sad, 2011) who argue that the CJEU has never previously referred to objective justifications as allowing agreements that have an anticompetitive object to escape Article 101(1) TFEU. Instead they argue the CJEU is applying a preliminary Article 101(3) assessment to determine if an agreement should be viewed restrictive by object under Article 101(1) TFEU. Therefore by allowing an objective justification the burden of proof is shifted to the parties from the Commission’s prima facie assessment under Article 101(1) TFEU to objectively justify their agreement, which the Commission must look at again within a “truncated Article 101(3) TFEU assessment taking into account the legal and economic context”.

Page 166: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 165

It is unclear from the judgment precisely what conditions need be taken into

account for an objective justification to rebut a finding of object.80 To find an

answer it is helpful to turn to the opinion upon which the CJEU’s judgment was

based. AG Mazák’s opinion provided a clearer and more legally robust discussion of

the issues. He was also less concerned to confine his opinion to the realms of

selective distribution agreements. Instead, his opinion is relevant to the concept of

object as a whole. In particular, he examined the issue of objective justification in

depth.81

AG Mazák considered that regulatory obligations would be an objective justification

for the ban on internet sales (although this was not the case in the case at hand).82

He acknowledged that there may be certain exceptional circumstances where

restrictions on internet sales may be objectively justified owing to the nature of the

goods or the customers to whom they are sold, and therefore a national or

Community regulation would not be the only source of a potential justification.83

Restrictions that are justified are then likely to fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU so

long as they “do not go beyond what is necessary in accordance with the principle

of proportionality”.84 For AG Mazák, a ‘legitimate objective’ that a party wishes to

rely on must “be of a public law nature”.85 As such, it must be “aimed at protecting

a public good and extend beyond the protection of the image of the products

concerned”.86

This analysis by AG Mazák is compelling. First, he confirms that a form of balancing

can be undertaken within an assessment of the object criterion. Secondly, he limits

such justification to one that is of a public law nature, though it does not have to be

contained within a regulation. He thereby addresses AG Trsjenjak’s concern that

80

The Court simply states that the restriction in question restricts competition by object and is not justifiable. This situation could be compared with Louis Erauw where the Court was able to see the positive purpose of the ATP provision (supra n31). 81

Pierre Fabre, opinion, paras 31 to 43 (supra n1). Though that is not to say there are no flaws in the opinion, eg the reliance on BIDS to justify the distinction between object and effect. 82

Ibid, para 34. 83

Ibid, para 35. 84

Ibid. 85

Ibid. AG Mazák cites Wouters, para 97 (supra n30). 86

Ibid, para 35.

Page 167: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 166

not just any factor should invalidate a finding by object. Finally, he draws parallels

with the concept of ancillary restraints: whether restraints are necessary and

proportionate, but ancillary to the primary purpose of the agreement. He

reiterates the need to examine the legal context (in this instance the case-law of

the Court on selective distribution) and concludes that, as a result of such

examination, the plaintiff (Pierre Fabre) did not have a sufficient objective

justification for banning internet sales in order to protect the image of its product.87

Consequently, whether a restriction is objectively justified depends on the case, its

context and its purpose or objective. The correlation between objective

justifications and the concept of ancillary restraints is particularly thought-

provoking. The AG stated that to determine whether restrictions are inherent to an

agreement, such restrictions must not go beyond what is objectively necessary in

order to carry out the purpose of the agreement.88

The AG also addressed the question of necessary effect. He agreed that, “in

principle”, agreements aimed at prohibiting parallel trade have as their object the

restriction of competition.89 He qualified this, however, by finding that “the mere

fact that the selective distribution agreements in question...may restrict parallel

trade may not in itself be sufficient to establish that the agreement has the object

of restricting competition”.90 He thus recognised that agreements that restrict

parallel trade have exceptionally been held to be compatible with Article 101(1)

TFEU, means that those exceptions “suffice to establish that agreements which

restrict...parallel trade do not automatically have the object of restricting

competition...thus a mere appraisal of the terms of an agreement without

assessing...the legal and economic context in which it was drafted and currently

operates will not...suffice”.91 Assessing whether a selective distribution agreement

has a restrictive object must “be carried out in the light of the nature of selective

distribution agreements and the case-law thereon which forms part of the

87

Ibid, paras 36-37. 88

Ibid, para 57. See infra section 2.4 on ancillary restraints. 89

Ibid, para 42. 90

Ibid, para 42. 91

Ibid, footnote 33 of the opinion.

Page 168: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 167

economic and legal context in which the agreements were concluded and

operate.”92

Similar issues regarding legitimate objectives and objective justifications were

raised in ACF Chemiefarma and IAZ/Anseau.93 The cases saw the parties argue that

the restraints were necessary due to a shortage of raw materials (a crisis cartel) and

to protect public health respectively. Both arguments were dismissed by the Court,

which took them into consideration, but found that the context of the agreements

did not justify their restrictive object.

The question is, therefore, when will an objective justification argument succeed?

The answer is that it depends on the case and, in particular, whether a legitimate

goal outweighs the restraints required to achieve it. Clearly in ACF Chemiefarma

and IAZ/Anseau, as in BIDS, the Court was not convinced that this was the case. It

can be argued that parties to an agreement must adduce convincing evidence that

proves that any restraints are ancillary and proportionate to the primary purpose of

the agreement, namely, a legitimate objective (commercial and public) or a pro-

competitive purpose.94 Regardless of whether this method is a form of rebuttal

mechanism under Article 101(1) TFEU or part of the methodology to determine the

purpose of an agreement, the legal and economic context (based on the content of

the agreement) takes centre stage when assessing an objective justification.95

Goyder supports AG Mazák, contending that only agreements which have public

policy aims have benefited from objective justification arguments.96 The CJEU, on

the other hand, is willing to consider commercial justifications of restraints in the

92

Ibid, para 43. See also para 54 which discusses whether restrictions are “proportionate” and demonstrates that even apparent ‘hardcore’ restrictions preventing a ban on passive sales (as per the Commission’s various Guidelines) still can be seen to be proportionate, though admittedly in very exceptional circumstances. 93

Supra n31, ACF Chemiefarma and n10 Anseau/IAZ. 94

See Louis Erauw and Asnef Equifax (supra n31, 34). 95

Goyder asserts that the Commission and the European Courts recognise that an agreement may not be restrictive by object if it is objectively justified, though this is narrowly defined: (Goyder, 2011), II. B. 96

(Goyder, 2011), II. B, as shown in Wouters and Meca Medina. This is an important point as usually issues such as public policy etc are traditionally reserved for Article 101(3) TFEU. AG Mazák in Pierre Fabre limited objective justifications to those of a public law nature aimed at protecting a public good.

Page 169: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 168

pursuit of a legitimate aim.97 It would seem to be unwise to dismiss commercial

rationale as a basis of objective justification. It is clear, however, that the raising of

such a defence is rarely successful.98

2.4. Object and the ancillary restraints doctrine

As has been conspicuous in the cases recounted above, the concept of ancillary

restraints is closely correlated with balancing, legitimate goals and objective

justifications. As with legitimate goals and objective justifications, the terms are

used interchangeably, for instance, where particular restraints are deemed ancillary

to the purpose of pursuing a pro-competitive goal or a legitimate objective. The

question of whether a restriction can be ancillary to the main operation of an

agreement is historically a consideration when assessing the ‘effect’ of an

agreement.99 An illustration of this is seen in Andreangeli’s work. She examines

the concept of ‘ancillarity’ in relation to Article 101(1) as a whole.100 She contains

the concept within the framework of restrictions on parties’ freedom to trade. In

this sense, she considers that the European Courts have taken a view that in such

circumstances restraints “that were ‘necessary’ and ‘proportionate’ to pursue a

‘legitimate commercial purpose’, as well as...a public interest goal, could be

regarded as falling outside the remit of Article 101(1) TFEU altogether”.101 She

regards this more “economics-principled” and realistic approach to Article 101(1)

TFEU as “a step closer to ‘balancing’ the pro- and anti-competitive effects” of

agreements in the same way as under Article 101(3) TFEU.102

The same principles are applicable, however, within the realms of the object

criterion. This is notwithstanding that it does not have at its heart the balancing of

the pro and anti-competitive effects of an agreement, but rather a balancing of the

97

Pierre Fabre, supra n1, para 47. This is reinforced by the judgment in Cartes Bancaires where the CJEU stated that consideration should be given to whether a legitimate objective (in this case combating free-riding) precludes an agreement from being found restrictive by object: para 70. 98

It would be interesting to assess if arguments in favour of RPM could be made under this banner (as in the US). 99

See eg, (Nazzini, 2006); Article 81(3) Guidelines. 100

(Andreangeli, 2011), p227 onwards. 101

Ibid, (Andreangeli, 2011), p227. 102

Ibid. This is shown in Meca Medina (supra n30).

Page 170: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 169

positive and negative attributes of the purpose of the agreement. What is striking

about Meca Medina (and Wouters) is that, unlike in BIDS, the Court held that a

limitation in the freedom of action of an undertaking should not be automatically

regarded as prohibited by Article 101(1) TFEU, without an analysis of the legal and

economic context.103 Since the agreement in Meca Medina pursued legitimate

goals (in this case the protection of health of athletes and the integrity of

competitive sports) and the restraints were limited to what was necessary to

achieve that objective, the restraints were not found to be incompatible with

Article 101(1) TFEU.104 Therefore, even though the restraints restricted the

economic freedom of the parties, the rules were not caught by Article 101(1) TFEU.

In the case of BIDS, it could be argued that the restraints imposed were not ‘limited’

and that, in that instance, the CJEU did not believe the purpose of the agreement

constituted a legitimate goal.105

Although not commonly linked, the ancillary restraints doctrine has a clear place

under the object criterion. This is because it helps explain why the ‘object’ of an

agreement is often described by the Courts as the ‘primary purpose’ or ‘precise

purpose’, and hence why the object concept permits particular agreements

typically seen as containing hardcore restrictions to fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU

altogether.106 A hypothetical example can be envisioned as follows: an agreement

between competitors is designed to improve a distribution channel, which the

parties currently do not share but could, and such collaboration would potentially

benefit consumers due to increased efficiencies. In order for the parties to have

the incentive to invest in improving the distribution channel, they require various

short-term territorial protections from each other and market sharing

arrangements. Debatably, the primary purpose of the agreement (to improve the

distribution channel) could be viewed as being pro-competitive or as having a

legitimate objective. The restraints could be seen as ancillary to that purpose as

they are objectively necessary and proportionate to that primary aim.

103

Lasok argues object and effect have the same assessment process, (Lasok QC, 2008). 104

(Andreangeli, 2011), p227-228. 105

See the CJEU’s explanation of the BIDS judgment in Cartes Bancaires, paras 83-87 (supra n1). 106

See eg Case T-360/09, E.ON Ruhrgas AG v Commission, 29 June 2012, nyr, para 141.

Page 171: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 170

Alternatively, they could be understood to be objectively justified.107 Moreover, to

determine whether the agreement is ‘sufficiently deleterious’, an analysis of the

agreement under the STM Test would take those factors into account in order to

establish whether the ‘precise purpose’ of the agreement is to restrict competition.

Aspects of such a hypothesis can be seen in E.ON Ruhrgas AG.108 The Commission

fined E.ON and GDF Suez EUR 553 million on account of agreements relating to

their joint construction of the MEGAL pipeline to deliver Russian natural gas to

Germany and France.109 On appeal, the GC specifically linked the idea that the

parties did not have the object of restricting competition as the agreements were

ancillary to the overall purpose of the primary agreement.110 Although the GC

ultimately rejected this argument, it gave the argument credence as it found the

agreements were not directly related and objectively necessary to the

implementation of a main operation, which must be proportionate.111 Notably, the

GC emphasised that the requirement of objective justification does not mean that

the pro- and anticompetitive effects of an agreement must be weighed.112 This

observation gets to the crux of the matter. The seemingly interchangeable notions

of balancing, legitimate objectives, objective justifications and the doctrine of

ancillary restraints are not looking specifically to assess the pros and cons of the

effect of an agreement. Rather, they are tools used to identify the primary purpose

of the agreement within its legal and economic context.113

What is particularly interesting in E.ON is that the GC recognised that the

assessment of the ancillary nature of the agreement in relation to the main

operation “entails complex economic assessments”.114 This emphasises how,

despite an apparently restrictive object (to share markets, which is seen by the

107

Therefore objective justification and ancillarity could be viewed as one and the same. 108

Supra n106, E.ON. 109

Case COMP/39.401 — E.ON/GDF. The judgment is discussed further below and in chapter 5. 110

E.ON, para 138. 111

E.ON, paras 62-64. 112

E.ON, para 65. 113

Ibáñez Colomo refers to this as analysing the “rationale” behind the agreement to determine its “nature” as opposed to its “effects”: (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘Chapeau bas Prof Wahl’. 114

Supra n106, E.ON, para 69. Though the GC held that judicial review of that assessment is limited: the essence being that the Court cannot substitute its own economic analysis.

Page 172: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 171

Commission as a hardcore restriction), the Court accepted that the doctrine of

ancillary restraints can and should be considered under, what must be assumed to

be, the object criterion where appropriate. Indeed, the Commission itself

considered the evidence in this regard.115 From this it can be concluded that the

object criterion has the propensity to find apparently hardcore restraints as being

ancillary to a pro-competitive purpose, a legitimate objective (which may also be

pro-competitive) or a purpose that has a neutral effect. The outcome of such a

finding would generally bring an agreement outside the realms of Article 101(1)

TFEU. How this then impacts on the relationship between object and effect is

considered in the following chapter.

This conclusion would be rejected by some commentators. Nazzini, for instance,

does not believe there is a separate ancillary restraints doctrine under Article

101(1) TFEU beyond the balancing of welfare enhancing and welfare reducing

effects.116 The case law shows that this view is too narrow. An interesting

summation is provided by Jebelli. He claims that the role of the ancillary restraints

doctrine is to protect an undertaking’s legitimate business interests to ensure a

more efficient and competitive market and thus enable efficient business

transactions.117 Protecting legitimate business interests that are not necessarily

directly pro-competitive, but are objectively necessary is compatible with

“workable competition”.118

115

Ibid, para 138. The parties also argued in the alternative that the purpose of the agreements was ‘neutral’ having regard to the economic context existing at the time. This argument also failed, though it is notable that it was considered here as an alternative to ancillarity: that if the agreement is not ancillary to the main operation then its purpose could be deemed as neutral, that is, the agreement has a neutral effect on competition. A neutral purpose would also bring the agreement outside Article 101(1) TFEU. The neutrality of an agreement is considered further below. 116

(Nazzini, 2006), pp534, 535. Ibáñez Colomo argues that the Court is looking to determine, within the context of the agreement, if that agreement “is a plausible source of efficiency gains”: (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘More on AG Wahl and restrictions by object’. 117

(Jebelli, 2010), section 2. He argues that the Court does not look at the pro-competitive effects of an agreement, but rather any pro-competitive effects that may be considered are merely as an indirect result of protecting the parties’ legitimate interests. Such legitimate interests can only be protected by restrictions that are proportionate to the interest and do not go further than is necessary. 118

Ibid.

Page 173: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 172

As highlighted by AG Trstenjak in BIDS, the ancillary restraints doctrine is not a

gateway through which every restriction of competition might escape Article 101(1)

TFEU. Deringer reminds us that the fact that an agreement pursues other

objectives is unimportant to a finding of restriction by object.119 The object

criterion could therefore be described as ascertaining whether an agreement is

designed to restrict competition. The ancillary restraints doctrine is another tool

that can be utilised by parties who wish to convince the authorities their agreement

is not restrictive by object: whether this is by means of presumption rebuttal or by

highlighting the agreement’s primary purpose.120 Viewing the application of the

doctrine as a form of balancing is not necessarily an inappropriate analogy. Under

the object heading, any so-called ‘balancing’ involves identifying the aim of the

agreement. Thereby certain restraints within an agreement may be ‘necessary’ in

order to secure, for example, a positive purpose. Conversely, balancing under the

‘effect’ criterion relates more specifically to the positive and negative effects of the

agreement outweighing each other.121 For instance, agreements with a restrictive

effect which are necessary to enable parties to achieve a legitimate purpose fall

outside Article 101(1) TFEU, provided they are no more restrictive than is

necessary.122 By utilising this doctrine within the context of the object criterion, it is

therefore also possible for agreements to come outside Article 101(1) TFEU, by-

passing an analysis of their actual effects.

The type of balancing exercise described above has been most commonly used in

cases concerning export bans. Such bans have sometimes been viewed as ancillary

restraints as they were proportionate, necessary and directly related to the

implementation of the main agreement.123 The question is one of determining, not

whether:

119

(Deringer, 1968), paras 130-131. 120

This is likely to be dictated by how the Commission approaches the case. 121

See cf (Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), pp555-556, 560. 122

Ibid, pp558-560. Agreements leading to substantial transaction cost reductions, and that do not go beyond that deemed necessary to achieve these reductions, can be presumed to fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU. 123

See eg, supra n31 Louis Erauw; Case C-258/78 Nungesser v Commission; Case C-262/81 Coditel SA v Cine Vog. In these cases the export bans were contained in licensing agreements which the CJEU

Page 174: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 173

“the restriction is indispensable to the commercial success of the main operation, but [instead] of determining whether, in the specific context of the main operation, the restriction is necessary to implement that operation. If, without the restriction, the main operation is difficult or even impossible to implement, the restriction may be regarded as objectively necessary for its implementation”.124

Moreover, such restraints may be seen as furthering a legitimate purpose or being

objectively necessary in order to penetrate a new market.125 In these

circumstances, the restraints do not infringe Article 101(1) TFEU by object, but also

fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether. Even though the types of cases that

have succeeded in the application of the ancillary restraints doctrine and objective

necessity test have involved export bans, there is nothing to prevent the Courts

from using the same principles for other types of restraint, such as RPM.126

2.5. Conclusion: legal and economic context

This section examined the application of the legal and economic context as a means

to determine the precise purpose of an agreement. Its scope was seen to be wide

ranging. Under the umbrella of the legal and economic context, the following

factors have been taken into account: the positive attributes of an agreement,

objective justifications or legitimate aims/goals/objectives and the ancillary

restraints doctrine. The legal and economic context thus provides the core to any

assessment by object based on the content of the agreement. The facts of the case

then determine to what extent such assessment is required.127 This assessment can

lead to three possible outcomes: (i) an agreement is restrictive by object; (ii) it

comes outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether; or (iii) it requires an examination by

‘effect’. Consequently, the implications of the legal and economic context on an

outcome are profound, whether by acting as a rebuttal mechanism under the

found to be objectively justified on the basis that they were proportionate in relation to the need to protect the right holder’s economic interests. 124

Case T-112/99 M6 v Commission, [2001] ECR II-2459, para 109, 58. 125

See eg, (Kolstad, 2009), p47. 126

Ibid, p51. 127

The remit of the legal and economic context means there is potentially greater scope to conduct a comprehensive economic analysis of an agreement under Article 101(1) TFEU as opposed to the more prescriptive elements that may be considered under Article 101(3) TFEU – see chapter 5 for further analysis.

Page 175: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 174

hybrid approach or assessing an objective justification, objective aim, legitimate

goal, pro-competitive purpose or ancillary restraint.

It is notable from this examination of the legal and economic context that the

effects of an agreement have evidently been considered by the Courts in cases

seeking to determine an agreement’s object. This has been seen, in particular, in

those cases where legitimate objectives, pro-competitive purposes as well as

objective justifications are appraised.

3. The role of ‘effects’ under the legal and economic context

This section examines the extent to which the effects of an agreement are taken

into account when considering whether an agreement is restrictive by object.

Accordingly, the judgment in Allianz Hungária is used as a vehicle to demonstrate

this.128 The judgment signalled the endorsement of the hybrid approach to the

object criterion by the CJEU, despite underlining the significance of the MAAP’s

methodology and uncovering the primary purpose of the agreement. More

importantly, the judgment emphasises the status of the STM Test.129

What is more, defining the relevant market, usually closely intertwined in

determining an agreement’s effect, is unmistakeably now a feature of an object

assessment.130 For instance, the GC’s judgment in Fresh Del Monte reveals the

degree to which the GC investigated the market, the market power of the parties,

the regulatory framework and economic arguments raised by the parties in order to

determine whether the agreement in contention (a concerted practice) had the

object of fixing prices.131 The judgment in Cartes Bancaires likewise reaffirms the

importance of market definition when determining if an agreement is “by nature

128

Supra n1 Allianz Hungária. The judgment rendered by the CJEU took a different path to that of the AG. In support of the outcome of chapters 2 and 3, the judgment demonstrates a clearer and more in-depth appreciation of the concept of object. The opinion, on the other hand, relied heavily Commission’s Article 81(3) Guidelines. Notably, the CJEU ignored much of the AG’s opinion (for example, the CJEU does not endorse that “the classification of an agreement...as restrictive of competition by object acts as a kind of ‘presumption’” (para 64). 129

Upheld in Cartes Bancaires (supra n1). See chapter 2. 130

Supra n1 Allianz Hungária, para 42. 131

Case T-587/08 Fresh Del Monte, 14 March 2013, nyr, paras 293-585. Particularly paras 375-440, which relate to the legal and economic context.

Page 176: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 175

harmful to the proper functioning of normal competition”, and therefore “all

relevant aspects” such as the nature of the services, the real conditions of the

functioning and structure of the markets should be considered.132 However, merely

determining the relevant market is alone not sufficient to understand whether the

object of an agreement is to restrict competition as the context of an agreement is

the key factor in any analysis.

3.1. Allianz Hungária

The judgment in Allianz Hungária deserves particular scrutiny, as it largely

supported the wave of case law emanating from the CJEU since BIDS and addressed

a number of key themes raised in this thesis. It was also a preliminary ruling and

thus gave the CJEU greater scope for legal interpretation. Moreover, it was a

controversial judgment. The Court has been accused of blurring the distinction

between restrictions by object and by effect.133 If the object concept is understood

in accordance with the orthodox approach, then the judgment also appears to add

a new type of restriction to the object category. The question referred to the CJEU

was whether agreements that car insurance companies entered into with their

dealers acting as car repair shops, were restrictive by object as the rate of payment

the dealers received for repairs was linked to the amount of insurance they sold.134

On their face such vertical agreements would not appear to be obvious restrictions

anticompetitive by object.135 Nonetheless, the CJEU held that such agreements

could amount to restrictions by object.136 The purpose of the agreement was not

obvious. Once it was assessed within its legal and economic context taking into

account its potential effects, however, the fact that its primary purpose was to

increase the market power of the insurance companies became apparent.137

Increasing market power is not a hardcore restriction, but the CJEU deemed that

132

Supra n1, Cartes Bancaires, para 77. See paras 73-82. 133

See (Graham, 2013), ‘How to decide when an agreement has the object of restricting competition’. See eg Allianz Hungária, para 36. 134

Supra n1, Allianz Hungária, para 31. 135

A point correctly raised by the AG. See opinion, para 77. 136

Allianz Hungária, para 51. 137

Allianz Hungária, para 44.

Page 177: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 176

such a purpose had the propensity to restrict competition by object. Reaching this

conclusion, it closely followed the wording of the STM Test and recounted part of

the STM Test rarely cited by the European Courts, namely, that the nature of the

goods affected and the real conditions of the functioning and structure of the

market should be considered as part of the context.138

The reliance on STM is somewhat undermined by the notion of categorisation when

the CJEU insisted on delineating object from effect in the same terms referenced in

BIDS: that “certain forms of collusion between undertakings can be regarded, by

their very nature, as being injurious to the proper functioning of normal

competition”.139 To determine this does, however, require a careful examination of

the facts. The CJEU made specific reference to how the link between the two

services, namely the car repair service and car insurance brokerage, was possible

because the dealers acted in a dual capacity.140 The CJEU recognised that the

establishment of such a link “does not automatically mean that the agreement...has

as its object the restriction of competition.”141 On closer analysis such a link can,

nevertheless, constitute an important factor in determining whether such

agreement is “by its nature injurious to the proper functioning of normal

competition...in particular, where the independence of those activities is necessary

for that functioning.”142

Furthermore, the CJEU emphasises how the potential effects of an agreement are

crucial to an assessment of an agreement’s object by asserting that it is “necessary”

to take into account whether the agreement is “likely to affect not only one, but

two markets...and its object must be determined with respect to the two markets

138

Allianz Hungária, para 33-38, in particular para 36 (see also Case C-226/11, Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence, 13 December 2012, nyr (Expedia), para 21). Unfortunately the CJEU incorrectly cites Expedia, where it reiterates the same point, but more generally in respect of how a restriction should be assessed: para 21 referencing Asnef which makes the same point, but in respect of the ‘effect’ criterion; Asnef, para 49 (supra 34). See STM, para 250 (supra 15). 139

Supra n1, Allianz Hungária, para 35. 140

Allianz Hungária, para 40. 141

Allianz Hungária, para 41. 142

Ibid. This reinforces the CJEU’s continued allegiance to ordoliberal principles. Consumer welfare considerations, namely, allocative efficiency concerns, would be unlikely to be concerned with such activities. See generally (Gerber, 1998).

Page 178: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 177

concerned”.143 The need for market definition under the object criterion is thus

reinforced, particularly for cases where a restriction of competition is not

obvious.144 The court also asserted, however, that agreements “designed to

partition the market” would “have to be treated as a restriction by object”.145 This

pays homage to the hybrid approach.

Notwithstanding the fact that it is not referenced explicitly, the most striking aspect

of the Allianz Hungária judgment is its clear loyalty to STM. This is evident when

the CJEU states that it is necessary to determine whether, by taking into account

the legal and economic context, the agreement is “sufficiently injurious to

competition on the car insurance market as to amount to a restriction of

competition by object.”146 In STM, the CJEU referred to the “effect on competition

[needing] to be sufficiently deleterious”.147 This was subsequently recounted by

the CJEU in Cartes Bancaires.148 The significance of this statement in Allianz

Hungária relates to how the potential effects of an agreement and the context of

which it forms part helps determine whether it is restrictive by object. To this end,

the CJEU cited, inter alia, domestic law requirements and whether the structure of

the market meant that competition on that market would be eliminated or

seriously weakened following the conclusion of those agreements.149

Two things can be inferred from the fact that for an agreement to be found

restrictive by object it must be ‘sufficiently deleterious’. One is that agreements by

object must have the capacity to harm competition.150 Secondly, as found by the

143

Ibid, para 42. In para 44: the CJEU held that in respect of the car insurance market, the aim of entering into such agreements from the perspective of the insurers is to maintain or increase their market shares. This highlights the continued relevance of market power to any Article 101(1) TFEU assessment. Moreover, it questions whether the CJEU is clearing the path for considerations that would not merit scrutiny under Article 102 TFEU, to come in by the back door. 144

See L’Oréal (supra n17). Also González recounts two methods to establish object: (González, 2012), p17. 145

Supra n1, Allianz Hungária, para 45. Also see (González, 2012), p17. 146

Allianz Hungária, para 46. 147

Supra n15, STM, para 249. 148

Supra n1, Cartes Bancaires, para 52. 149

Supra n1, Allianz Hungária, para 48. See paras 47-49. 150

Or arguably an acknowledgment that restrictions by object must be appreciable: see Chapter 5. See also (Parret, 2010), ft 42: the Commission’s stance is that “it is assumed that there shall be a negative impact on competition”.

Page 179: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 178

CJEU in Cartes Bancaires, the agreement must have the necessary effect of

restricting competition based on experience.151 The key factor in determining

whether an agreement is sufficiently deleterious is an assessment of the

circumstances of the agreement, that is, its context. For example, in Allianz

Hungária, the CJEU referred to the expectations of insurance policyholders to

determine if the “proper functioning of the car insurance market is likely to be

significantly disrupted by the agreements”.152 The potential effects of the

agreement will therefore play an integral role in such a finding. Alternatively, in

Cartes Bancaires the CJEU found that if the potential effects of an agreement do

not reveal that it is by its nature harmful to competition, then such agreement

cannot be restrictive by object.153

In Allianz Hungária the CJEU stated that an agreement “would” restrict competition

by object if it is “likely that, having regard to the economic context, competition on

that market would be eliminated or seriously weakened following the conclusion of

those agreements”.154 Whether infringements by object can be found absent such

considerations is moot. The CJEU reiterated the STM Test when it stated that an

analysis of the agreements must “in particular” consider the structure of the

market, the existence of alternative distribution channels and their importance and

the market power of the companies concerned.155 There is therefore an implication

that such considerations are not limited to those mentioned. The key point as

regards any consideration of the potential effects of an agreement appears to be

this: potential effects are relevant in determining the agreement’s ‘objective’, but

are not utilised to carry out an analysis of the ‘effect’ of an agreement.156

The judgment in Allianz Hungária is significant for a number of reasons: it questions

the categorisation of the object criterion in view of the restrictions considered by

the CJEU in that case which are not normally associated with the object criterion; it

151

Supra n1, Cartes Bancaires, para 51. 152

Supra n1, Allianz Hungária, para 47. 153

Supra n1, Cartes Bancaires, para 82. 154

Supra n1, Allianz Hungária, para 48 (emphasis added). 155

Ibid. 156

Supra n1, Cartes Bancaires, paras 82, 86.

Page 180: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 179

reaffirms the importance of establishing the object of an agreement based on the

content of the agreement; it confirms that the aim of an agreement must be

considered on its merits, its own unique circumstances and with consideration of its

specific legal and economic context; it highlights the need for market definition, in

particular in respect of less ‘obvious’ cases; and it serves to highlight how the

orthodox approach belies the complexity of the object criterion and thus the

inappropriateness of a generic process of restriction identification.157

Essentially, the judgment in Allianz Hungária demonstrates that the effects-based

approach is not the preserve of the effect criterion. It is utilised also under the

object criterion when viewed through the lens of the MAAP and indeed the hybrid

approach. Thus, criticisms aimed at the Commission for failing to engage with the

effects-based approach miss the point as when an agreement is assessed in

accordance with the MAAP such criticisms fall away.158 To circumvent having to

apply a more economic approach to agreements that may be restrictive by effect,

the Commission has instead chosen to abuse the object category. To this end, it

has expanded the object category, thereby enabling the Commission to engage in a

limited assessment under the object criterion.159 The Commission has finally been

taken to task for this by the CJEU.160 Despite the reliance on the STM Test, the CJEU

in Cartes Bancaires chose to use the concept of necessary effect as the primary

rationale against widening the category. This is not entirely reflective of the law.

When the law is understood under the MAAP, widening the object category is not a

concern as the standard of proof is raised. Rather, the focus is on the methodology

used to determine the precise purpose of the agreement. The judgment in Allianz

Hungária does not examine the concept of necessary effect. Instead, it

157

Supra n1, Allianz Hungária, para 51 “...agreements...can be considered as a restriction of competition ‘by object’..., where, following a concrete and individual examination of the wording and aim of those agreements and of the economic and legal context of which they form part, it is apparent that they are, by their very nature, injurious to the proper functioning of normal competition on the one of the two markets concerned”. 158

See (Gerardin & Girgenson, 2011), pp2, 15. 159

Though see comments on the decision in Lundbeck in Chapter 1. 160

Supra n1, Cartes Bancaires, para 58.

Page 181: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 180

concentrates on establishing the aim of the agreement and, as such, better reflects

the law.161

3.2. Determining potential effects: the capacity to restrict competition

Examining the potential effects of an agreement to help determine an agreement’s

object is seen further in cases where the purpose of the agreement could be seen

to be neutral. In such cases, there is no objective to affect competition at all. This is

seen in both E.ON and Protimonopolný, which examine the tricky issue of whether

an agreement must have the capacity to affect competition in order to be found

restrictive by object. This also encompasses a consideration of the counterfactual

within such assessment.

An example, which encapsulates how capacity and the object criterion may relate

to one another, is found in the E.ON Decision.162 As discussed previously, the

decision pertains to the joint venture entered into by E.ON and GDF to build the

MEGAL pipeline in order to bring gas into both Germany and France. The parties

entered into side letters, which prohibited them from entering each other’s home

markets. The Commission found that the agreements restricted competition by

object and fined the parties accordingly. In their defence, the parties argued that

the agreements had no impact on competition as prior to 2000 the gas markets

were not liberalised and market entry would not have been possible. The

Commission rejected these arguments and declared that a counterfactual analysis

would have been impossible to build and was irrelevant. For the Commission, the

mere fact that the parties concluded the agreement, regardless of whether they

would have entered each other’s markets in the absence of the agreements, meant

161

In Allianz Hungária the CJEU underscores that the success of an agreement is not a pre-requisite to a finding of object. Using the wording of T-Mobile, the CJEU stresses that for an agreement to be found to be restrictive by object it is “sufficient that it has the potential to have a negative impact on competition...that it be capable in an individual case of resulting in the...restriction of competition...”, para 38. The CJEU points out “actual” effects are only relevant when determining the fine and assessing any claim for damages (supra n1). 162

Supra n109, E.ON/GDF.

Page 182: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 181

that Article 101(1) TFEU was infringed. Participation in the agreement alone was

seen as sufficient to infringe Article 101(1) TFEU.163

The GC did not wholly support the Commission’s opinion in this regard and partially

rejected its submissions concerning the question of capacity.164 The parties argued

that as they were not potential competitors until after 2000, the agreement was

not subject to Article 101(1) TFEU. Significantly, the GC agreed that Article 101(1)

TFEU only applies to sectors open to competition.165 However, to examine the

conditions of competition requires an assessment of both existing and potential

competition between undertakings on the market. Such assessment ascertains

whether there are real possibilities for the undertakings to compete or for a new

competitor to enter the market and compete.166 Therefore, the counterfactual is

relevant in this regard. The GC found that the burden is on the Commission to

determine whether an undertaking is a potential competitor by assessing what the

situation would be had the agreement not applied: in those circumstances would

there have been a real, concrete possibility for the parties to enter the market and

compete.167 Moreover, the GC held that a potential competitor can be labelled as

such if it has the ability to enter the market: whether it is precluded from doing by a

monopoly derived from national legislation is irrelevant to such an assessment if

there is a theoretical possibility.168 The GC found that the Commission had not

shown sufficient evidence that there was in fact potential competition on the

German market between 1980 and 1998.169 Hence, the agreements were not

subject to Article 101(1) TFEU during that period. The GC held that “the system of

competition established by Articles 81 EC and 82 EC [was] concerned with the

economic consequences of agreements, or of any comparable form of concertation

or coordination, rather than with the their legal form.”170

163

Ibid, para 241-246. 164

Supra n106, E.ON. 165

Ibid, para 84. 166

Ibid, para 85. 167

Ibid, paras 86 and 105. 168

Ibid, paras 87 and 105, 106. 169

Ibid, para 115. 170

Ibid, para 251.

Page 183: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 182

The judgment in E.ON is a reminder that the parties to an agreement must have the

capacity or the ability to restrict competition, which seemingly requires the parties

to be potential competitors. It is therefore understandable that undertakings

would endeavour to argue such a position in order to take their agreements

containing ‘hardcore’ restrictions, as in the case of E.ON, outside the remit of

Article 101(1) TFEU.171 To determine such capacity requires consideration of the

counterfactual as demonstrated in E.ON.

Under the MAAP, the counterfactual forms part of the STM Test.172 As such, its use

may be relevant in determining an agreement’s precise purpose. Certainly, to

assess what the situation would have been absent the agreement helps explain why

certain restraints are seen as necessary, justifiable or ancillary to a pro-competitive

purpose.173 The judgment in E.ON showed how using the counterfactual is also

relevant when determining the capacity of the agreement to restrict competition.

This potentially means that agreements that aim to restrict competition may not be

found to restrict competition by object and thereby fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU

altogether if the parties lack the capacity to affect competition. In the case of E.ON,

this was because the undertakings were not potential competitors during particular

periods. This finding brings to the fore the issue of whether an agreement can be

found to be restrictive of competition by object even when it is impossible for it to

have an effect on competition. The answer is not straightforward and is ostensibly

linked to the fact that an agreement does not have to be successful to be found

restrictive by object.

171

See supra n131, Fresh Del Monte. 172

Cf (Gerardin & Girgenson, 2011), p7. Gerardin believes the effects-based approach and counterfactual method are not involved in determining the object of an agreement. Conversely, Andeangeli finds the counterfactual only applies to “less obvious breaches” of Article 101(1) TFEU, (Andreangeli, 2011), p242. 173

As was the case for instance in O2, which was an ‘effect’ case (supra n30). Drawing on the judgment in O2, Andreangeli comments that owing to the application of the counterfactual, practices that would have previously been found to be restrictive of competition “may now be considered to be ‘neutral’ for competition and, furthermore, that some of the analysis that has hitherto taken place against the framework of the legal exception now occurs as part of the ‘in-context’ approach that the prohibition clause now details”, (Andreangeli, 2011), pp232-233.

Page 184: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 183

The complexity of this issue is highlighted in Protimonopolný. In a short judgment,

the Court answered the question of whether an agreement that has no effect on

competition can still be found restrictive by object in the affirmative.174 In this case,

the CJEU held that the fact that an undertaking was allegedly operating illegally

(Akcenta) on the relevant market at the time the agreement was concluded, had no

impact on whether the agreement restricted competition by object under Article

101 (1) TFEU. The facts involved several banks who colluded to terminate, in a

coordinated manner, current and future contracts that the banks had with Akcenta.

As Akcenta did not have the requisite licence to carry out its business, the banks

argued it was operating illegally and could not therefore be regarded as a

competitor. Hence, the agreement did not have the object of restricting

competition. The CJEU disagreed and found the object of the agreement between

the banks to be the restriction of competition as the agreement was intended to

eliminate a competitor.175 It noted that Akcenta was adversely affected by the

agreement.

The judgment bears some scrutiny. On one hand, it could be seen to strengthen

the orthodox approach as the CJEU refuted the need to prove the capacity of the

agreement to do harm (that is, cause a potential effect). If the parties exclude a

player who has no right to be in the market at all, then it is arguable that the

agreement is not capable of having any effect on competition. This undermines the

necessity of assessing the agreement in its legal and economic context as there is

no need to prove the capacity of an agreement to do harm, or indeed investigate

whether the economic context explains that capacity. On the other hand, the case

strengthens the philosophy underpinning the more analytical approach: whether

Akcenta was acting illegally does not mean that the agreement was not capable of

having an effect on the market as the parties aimed to restrict competition by

eliminating Akcenta (their competitor regardless of whether Akcenta was acting

illegally or not). On the facts, Akcenta was operating in the market, albeit illegally,

but was nonetheless having a measurable impact on the market to the extent that

174

C-68/12 Protimonopolný úrad Slovenskej republiky v Slovenská sporitel’ňa, 7 February 2013, nyr. 175

Ibid, see the answer to first and second questions.

Page 185: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 184

the banks wished to eliminate it. If the correct counterfactual was that Akcenta

would be able to continue operating illegally on the market absent the agreement,

then the agreement restricted competition.176

It is submitted that the CJEU was correct to reject the argument that the agreement

did not restrict competition because Akcenta was acting illegally. The banks

colluded with the purpose of excluding a player in the market and were unable to

rebut this. This rationale was enough to satisfy the CJEU of that object based on its

assessment of the specific legal and economic context. This principal operates in a

similar way to the success of an agreement being irrelevant to a finding by object,

which is why actual effects do not need to be demonstrated. Entering an

agreement with the purpose of restricting competition as determined under the

STM test is restrictive by object.177 The legal and economic context is thus

fundamental to this determination. In Protimonopolný, the CJEU stated that the

agreement “specifically had as its object the restriction of competition” and the

question of illegality was not enough to refute this.178 A similar point was made in

E.ON where the GC held that GDF’s monopoly was meaningless as this did not

preclude the fact that the aim of the agreement (the prohibition of supply of gas)

was to circumvent possible legal and factual changes during the lifespan of the gas

pipeline.179 Hence, the concept of necessary effect alone is not sufficient when

determining the capacity of an agreement to restrict competition or whether an

agreement has an effect.

In summation, Protimonopolný demonstrates that arguments relating to an

undertaking operating illegally were irrelevant to the consideration of the legal and

economic context when determining the object of the agreement. Arguably, the

appropriate place for considering whether an anti-competitive agreement can be

176

The question of capacity to restrict competition is a complex issue and is discussed further in chapter 5 in conjunction with the de minimis doctrine. 177

See Case C8/08 T-Mobile [2009] ECR I-4529: for an agreement to be found to be restrictive by object it is “sufficient that it has the potential to have a negative impact on competition...that it be capable in an individual case of resulting in the...restriction of competition...”. 178

Supra n174, Protimonopolný, para 19. 179

Supra n106, E.ON para 135.

Page 186: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 185

justified by the fact Akcenta acted without a licence, is Article 101(3) TFEU.180 The

CJEU was correct to find that the undertakings should have reported Akcenta to the

authorities as opposed to taking it upon themselves to eliminate a competitor.

Should the banks have jointly reported Akcenta to the authorities, then there would

not have been a restriction of competition in those circumstances. Instead, the

banks agreed between them to terminate their contracts with Akcenta, which

meant that it was unable to carry out its business and therefore was eliminated

from the market. The moral compass surrounding whether undertakings should be

allowed to protect their industry is thus immaterial to Article 101(1) TFEU.

3.3. Conclusion: The role of effects under the legal and economic context

This section considered the extent to which the effects of an agreement are taken

into account when determining whether an agreement is restrictive by object. The

judgment in Allianz Hungária was examined, and it was demonstrated how the

legal and economic context was used as a means to determine whether the

agreement was designed to restrict competition. This encompassed the need for a

definition of the relevant markets, the market structure, and the position of the

parties on those markets in order to uncover the true aim of the agreement.

Whether every case requires such an in-depth assessment of its context depends

on the facts, but it is the plaintiff’s burden to discharge. Taking into account an

agreement’s effects also helps determine whether an agreement is sufficiently

deleterious, as the concept of necessary effect is not solely relevant in this

regard.181

The effects of an agreement are also relevant in determining whether an

agreement has the capacity to restrict competition or has no effect on the market

whatsoever and thereby circumvents a finding by object. The counterfactual is

invaluable in this regard, though whether it needs to be applied in every contextual

180

This is analogous with cases such as BIDS where the parties attempted to argue that the agreement was necessary to preserve the beef industry. Additionally an undertaking’s charitable status does not prevent it from being subject to the competition rules. 181

Note, the definition of the ‘legal context’ includes previous case law, therefore precedent is relevant in such determination. Also, taking effects into account is different from having to prove effects (actual or potential) under the ‘effect’ heading.

Page 187: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 186

analysis under the MAAP is open to interpretation. What is clear is that these

issues are complex. The answer to the question of whether the capacity of an

agreement to restrict competition should be a bar to a finding of object is far from

straightforward. In E.ON, the Court agreed that, during particular periods of time,

the parties were unable to compete due to the structure of the market (it was not

liberalised). However this did not mean that the undertakings were able to

continuously flout the competition rules. Likewise, undertakings which are

potential competitors and have the capacity to restrict competition can be found to

restrict competition by object, even if the agreement is not implemented or is

unsuccessful or a party is operating illegally. How these factors are then

distinguished from the notion of appreciability and the related issue of market

power requires careful thought.182

4. Commentator rationale: explaining the anomalies without abandoning

categorisation

In the wake of recent court decisions, there has been a spate of scholarly papers

concerning the object criterion. These papers articulate disparate attempts to

rationalise the case law. The increased debate and analysis surrounding the object

criterion is a welcome development. It shows no sign of abating.183 How scholars

interpret the law on the application and function of the legal and economic context,

in particular, deserves scrutiny. Many commentators now acknowledge the

anomalous case law, but have tended to retain a focus on the categorisation

approach to the object criterion.184 For instance, Jones argues that it is hard to

rationalise when, as she terms it, the object category is expanded or narrowed.185

She argues that the anomalous cases have arisen in two main areas, namely where

horizontal price or output restraints are essential to the attainment of the pro-

competitive goals of a joint venture, and where absolute territorial protection (ATP)

182

The contentious issue of whether restrictions of object need be appreciable is considered in the following chapter. 183

Apparent from the spike in commentary published on the internet following the judgment in Cartes Bancaires and subsequent conferences planned on the academic and practitioner circuits. 184

This thesis argues that the object concept should move away from categorisation. 185

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p664.

Page 188: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 187

is necessary to the distribution or licensing arrangement.186 She has examined

Wouters finding that when an agreement is designed to achieve a legitimate

objective, even if it involves a severe horizontal restraint, then such restraint may

not breach Article 101(1) TFEU at all.187 Jones suggests that the circumstances in

which restraints are objectively necessary are very limited, and are connected to

the nature of the product in issue. This indicates to Jones that ATP for the

distributor is “inherent or necessary to the success of the distribution

arrangement”.188 This view is supported by the CJEU’s judgment in GSK where the

CJEU reinforced the narrow nature of the exception. Jones points out that the GC

had “taken a different view”, holding that “the Commission had been wrong to

characterise Glaxo’s distribution agreements designed to restrict parallel trade... as

restrictive by object simply by relying on the clauses of the agreement without

reference to the legal and economic context”.189

This is an important point, and it is submitted that the GC’s judgment was correct in

this regard. The GC was highlighting the fact that based on the particular facts of

the case the presumption of anticompetitive effects did not apply. Furthermore,

the CJEU did not reject this element of the GC’s judgment.190 In fact, the AG in GSK

endorsed the GC’s understanding of the legal and economic context.191 What the

CJEU rejected was the GC’s subsequent requirement that such an agreement must

restrict competition to the detriment of the final consumer.192 For Jones, the

answer to how and why the object category is expanded or narrowed is not clear,

but she considers that cases such as BIDS, GSK and T-Mobile:

“suggest categorisation is not simply a presumption that can be set aside by establishing that consumer harm or anticompetitive effects are not likely (or have not occurred) on the facts of the case. Cases

186

Ibid. Jones cites Commission and Court cases. This is also recognised by (Mahtani, 2012), p11. Mahtani also points out that there are cases which contain an apparent object restriction but do not ultimately breach Article 101(1) TFEU by object (p 10). 187

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p666. 188

Ibid, p667. 189

Ibid. 190

Supra n19, GSK, para 58. 191

Supra n26, opinion, para 137 . 192

Ibid, para 119, paras 63-64.

Page 189: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 188

such as Erauq-Jacquery and Wouters indicate, however, that hardcore restraints inherent in, or reasonably necessary to achieve, legitimate, pro-competitive objectives of an agreement may fall outside Article 101(1) altogether.”193

This view endorses the position that the potential or actual effects of an agreement

ultimately do not bear on whether an agreement is anti-competitive by object. This

ties in with the rule that an agreement does not need to succeed or produce effects

to infringe Article 101(1) TFEU.194 Consequently, her opinion credits the

proposition that the role of effects in any analysis of the legal and economic context

is best suited to understanding whether an agreement has a primary purpose of

restricting competition and its restraints are necessary and ancillary to such, most

commonly, pro-competitive purpose. That is, they can be balanced.

Alternatively, Mahtani makes a bold attempt to explain the anomalies and to clarify

the case law. He too recognises that there are cases where the outcome predicted

by an application of the orthodox approach has not resulted in the identification of

an object restriction.195 He divides the cases into two groups identifying those

cases where an apparent object restriction exists, but the agreement did not breach

Article 101(1) TFEU by object and, secondly, those cases where a breach of the

object criterion was established by an analysis that was beyond merely identifying

the object restriction. Like Jones, he limits the circumstances in which the object

assessment has not resulted in the outcome predicted by the orthodox approach

due to the analysis conducted.196 Using FA as an example, Mahtani notes that the

CJEU stated that ATP may not breach Article 101(1) TFEU by object if “other

circumstances falling within its economic and legal context justify the finding that

such an agreement is not liable to impair competition”.197 For Mahtani, the case of

Pierre Fabre highlights that the context (or circumstances) of the agreement can

193

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p668. 194

An agreement can infringe competition by object irrespective of the effects it produces. This issue links in with Jones’ assertion that restrictions by object come outside Article 101(1) TFEU entirely if there is no credible theory of harm (Ibid, p664): this is significant when the de minimis doctrine is considered in chapter 5. 195

(Mahtani, 2012), p10. 196

Ibid, p11, see also ft 438. 197

Ibid, p14.

Page 190: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 189

justify a prima facie breach by object and that such analysis is not defined by

abstract principles.198 Nevertheless, Mahtani plays down the role of the legal and

economic context by stating that merely a “number of cases” make reference to the

context.199 This is wrong. The vast majority of case law, in particular more recent

case law, reaffirms the prominence of the legal and economic context in any

assessment by object.

Overall, Mahtani disagrees with Jones’ position that the exceptions to the orthodox

approach should be viewed as a narrowing of the object category of agreements in

certain circumstances.200 Instead, he considers that the object category as

delineated by the object box is never narrowed, rather:

“in certain circumstances the category approach is disapplied. To seek to codify those circumstances within the object box (as refinements or narrowing) could be overly prescriptive. Nor do we necessarily need to consider such situations as exceptional as such, but part of the framework of Article 101(1) TFEU.”201

Mahtani believes that the case law reveals that an object analysis involves two

stages: (i) a review of the clauses of an agreement to determine whether a prima

facie object restriction exists; and (ii) a deeper consideration of the purpose and the

context. Though the context is limited to the commercial purpose of the

coordination and the means used to achieve that purpose:202

“this analysis involves the identification of such a legitimate commercial purpose to the restriction and an assessment of whether the restriction goes not further than necessary to achieve that purpose. If the commercial purpose is legitimate and the prima facie object restriction is a necessary and proportionate means of achieving that purpose, no breach of the object aspect of Article 101(1) is occasioned.”203

198

Ibid, p16. That the legal and economic context is not abstract is correct. Cf opinion in Gøttrup Klim (supra n24). 199

(Mahtani, 2012), p18. 200

Ibid, p18. 201

Ibid, p19. 202

Ibid. 203

Ibid. Also citing (King, 2011).

Page 191: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 190

Further, Mahtani also recognises that in addition to those occasions where

judgments appear to create “exceptions” to the object box, there are also instances

where a breach of the object aspect is found without direct reference to a category

of object restrictions.204 He acknowledges that in these instances there is a desire

for the object criterion to operate more flexibly then the object-as-category

understanding.205 Moreover, he recognises that these cases have explicitly rejected

the premise that the object criterion operates narrowly, limited to a short list of

‘hardcore restraints’. He considers BIDS and T-Mobile demonstrate that the CJEU

“identified coordination which breached the object aspect of Article 101(1), not by

reference to precedent or to the existence of specific restraints, but by examining

whether the coordination as a whole had the consequence of directly restricting

rivalry between competitors.”206 Mahtani also accepts that in cases such as BIDS,

the analysis was specific to the factual circumstances of the case.207 Mahtani’s

rationale is simply to say these types of cases operate outside the object

category.208

Mahtani acknowledges that the common factor in all these cases is the presence of

the legal and economic context. For him, the legal and economic context has been

invoked inconsistently and used to “do too much and to do so in an unstructured

way”.209 This is not an unfair criticism. Instead of adjusting the parameters of the

object category or using the legal and economic context to mitigate its harshness,

Mahtani’s solution is for us to “recognise the object aspect of Article 101(1) TFEU as

encompassing a structured, multi-layered assessment, which includes, but allows

more than, the mere identification of a restraint belonging to an established

category of such restraints”.210 He bases this recommendation on the opinion of

AG Trstenjak in GSK.211 He recognises that the AG’s methodology requires that the

204

Ibid, p20. 205

Ibid. 206

Ibid. However it is submitted that this type of analysis by the CJEU is not necessarily unusual or simply limited to the circumstances outlined by Mahtani. This is amply demonstrated in chapter 2. 207

Ibid, p25. 208

Ibid. 209

Ibid, p26. 210

Ibid, p27. 211

Ibid.

Page 192: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 191

legal and economic context must always be considered under the object

criterion.212 For Mahtani, however, the primary role of the legal and economic

context is simply to cast doubt on a prima facie breach by object.

Mahtani recognises the presence of the three approaches put forward in this thesis.

He concludes that object can be established in one of three ways, namely: (i) the

categorisation of object drawn from precedent; (ii) by considering the aim or

purpose of the parties to the restriction; and (iii) by an abridged analysis of the

expected effects of the restriction (the presumption of restrictive effects).213

Mahtani thus acknowledges that there is a ‘rebuttal mechanism’ within the object

criterion and cites the AG Trstenjak in BIDS as the authority for the ways in which

the object of an agreement can be rebutted.214 Specifically, he argues there are

three ways this can happen: first, where a limitation on commercial freedom has no

anticompetitive effects as the parties are not competitors or there is insufficient

competition that can be restricted by the agreement (Mahtani refers to this as a

form of the counterfactual); secondly, where an agreement is ambivalent in terms

of its effects on competition, and so has - for example - a pro-competitive purpose

and the restrictions required are ancillary, and thirdly, where ancillary restraints are

necessary to pursue a primary objective, which is neutral as regards competition or

promotes competition and the ancillary restraints are necessary to achieve that

objective. Mahtani likens the second and third scenarios to situations where the

prima facie object is to restrict competition and is being balanced against a

legitimate commercial purpose and the conduct is necessary to achieve that

purpose.215 This results in what Mahtani terms the “Two-stage Object Analysis”:216

Breach by object established by: Prima facie breach capable of rebuttal by:

the existence of a specific restraint identified by reference to a category of restraints—limited factual assessment required

evidence that no competition exists absent the restriction; or a legitimate commercial purpose and restrictions proportionate to that purpose

212

Ibid, p28. 213

Ibid, p27. 214

Ibid, p37. Also described as “casting doubt on a prima facie restriction by object”. 215

Ibid. 216

Ibid, p38 where this table is originally produced.

Page 193: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 192

an abridged analysis of negative effects on competition— broad factual assessment required

evidence that no competition exists absent the restriction; or a legitimate commercial purpose and restrictions proportionate to that purpose

a specific collective purpose to bring about negative effects on competition—broad factual assessment required

no rebuttal possible

Mahtani’s arguments certainly support many of the issues and findings raised in

this thesis, in particular, his examination justifies the detail in which the various

aspects and facets of the object criterion are discussed in this chapter. Despite

having much sympathy for a number of the points made by Mahtani, however, the

continued focus on Whish’s ‘object box’ in a comprehension of the object criterion

is unsatisfactory. The object box interpretation of the law lacks credibility in the

eyes of the European Courts.217 Instead, understanding the law in accordance with

the MAAP is, in one sense, a simpler means of explaining how the Courts have

tackled the object criterion, in particular as it is framed around STM.218

Goyder also supports the continued categorisation of the object criterion. Her view

is that there is an object restriction where a restriction of competition is the

“necessary consequence” of the content of the agreement, regardless of the actual

intentions of the parties.219 She recognises that a subjective intention to restrict

competition is relevant, but a restriction may have an anticompetitive object even if

the parties also have legitimate objectives.220 She agrees that is “not sufficient, in

order to establish an object restriction, to identify a restriction as a type that has

been found to be ‘by object’ before...a ‘prima facie’ object restriction. The case law

requires that the analysis go further than an examination of the actual terms of the

agreement in question”.221 This entails a consideration of the economic and legal

context, which may result in the negation of the “presumption of infringement

arising because the type of clause in question appears to be an object restriction”.

217

In particular it is not referred to by the European Courts as forming part of the object criterion, nor is it specifically referred to by the Commission as the basis of its interpretation. 218

This is because, as well as raising the standard of proof, applying the MAAP means the same legal framework is applicable to any given scenario. Therefore, there are no anomalies or exceptions to the rule. 219

(Goyder, 2011), II. 220

Ibid. 221

Ibid.

Page 194: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 193

Then any possible “objective justification” must be examined, and if an agreement

is de minimis it will fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU as it does not have an

appreciable effect on competition.222 Goyder agrees that, in exceptional

circumstances, a restriction of the type that is normally classified as being by object

can, once considered within its legal and economic context, be found not to be

anticompetitive by object. An objective justification or the application of the de

minimis principal may also negate what is prima facie an object restriction.223

Goyder separates the legal and economic context from objective justifications and

the de minimis doctrine.224 It is submitted that the legal and economic context in

fact encompasses all the various elements that may cast doubt on a presumption of

object. Moreover, it is not simply a rebuttal mechanism. Ultimately, Goyder

highlights that there are no magic formulae when considering the application of the

object criterion. She concurs that the EU framework is significantly more flexible

than, for example, the US framework at dealing with unusual cases.

Andreangeli provides an alternative interpretation of the CJEU’s approach to the

object criterion, which supports both the more analytical approach and hybrid

approach.225 She recognises that the CJEU has applied some of the elements

“characterising the more flexible and ‘economics-principled’ approach hitherto

relevant for ‘by-effect’ cases to the assessment of prima facie restrictions by

object”.226 Moreover, as was found in chapter 2, she recognises that although the

CJEU continues to rely on the dichotomy between object and effect restrictions, it

has scrutinised the goals and content of agreements by taking into account their

actual context. This has been carried out in a similar pattern of analysis to that of

“less serious” infringements.227 As a result, she proposes that the Court now

adopts an approach to Article 101(1) TFEU better characterised as a “continuum”

222

Ibid. 223

(Goyder, 2011), IV. 224

Object’s relationship with the de minimis doctrine will be considered in chapter 5. 225

(Andreangeli, 2011). 226

Ibid, p216. 227

Ibid. Though as previously noted, the Court’s current understanding of the dichotomy is problematic, particularly in view of how it in fact applies the object criterion post BIDS.

Page 195: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 194

between more and less serious infringements than by a relatively stark alternative

between ‘by-object’ and ‘by-effect’ restrictions of competition.228 This, she argues,

is demonstrated by the Court’s framework for appraisal, which reserves

intervention only for those agreements inherently incompatible with Article 101

TFEU or result in actual impairment of competition.229

Andreangeli illustrates this using the AG’s opinion in the BIDS case.230 She considers

that even though AG Trstenjak recognised that the agreement was pursuing a pro-

competitive primary objective, the fact the agreement imposed, inter alia,

production cuts, the exiting of competitors from the industry and the imposition of

levies, resulted in the agreement restricting competition by object as the restraints

stifled potential competition by erecting barriers to entry.231 She acknowledges

that the CJEU cemented this approach by referring to the market share of the

parties to the agreement, which aimed as a result of the agreement to increase its

concentration.232 As such, the parties were unable to engage in competitive rivalry.

Industrial policy considerations were relegated to consideration under Article

101(3) TFEU.233 Moreover, crucially, she confirms that the Court rejected any

attempt to read an exhaustive list of ‘serious infringements’ into Article 101(1) and

thus concluded that the BIDS arrangement breached Article 101(1) TFEU by object.

In this vein, Andreangeli supports many of the conclusions identified in this thesis.

The fact that the Court is assessing the potential (and in some cases) actual effects

of an agreement within its appraisal of the object of an agreement is significant.

Indeed, Mahtani’s interpretation of the case law places little emphasis on this

phenomenon. The one-dimensional portrayal of the object criterion under the

orthodox approach is again exposed. Andreangeli also recognises the important

question of how the concept of a ‘restriction of competition’ should be construed

228

Ibid. 229

Ibid. 230

The continued reliance on AG Trstenjak by all commentators highlights the significance of the opinion. 231

(Andreangeli, 2011), p220. 232

Ibid, p221. 233

Ibid, p222.

Page 196: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 195

under any assessment by object. For the MAAP, this question is pivotal to an

appraisal of the object of an agreement.234 However, Andreangeli’s overall

interpretation of BIDS does have some distinctions. For instance, she places much

emphasis on the fact that the Court distinguished between object and effect by

considering the “seriousness of each infringement on the basis of the experience of

its impact on competition”.235 For her, the Court drew a line between very

damaging practices for the competitive process and those that were less

deleterious.236 Consequently, the former will, due to their nature, be presumed to

have anticompetitive effects without the need to enquire into their impact on the

market. The latter will require a closer examination to determine whether they

have in fact resulted in an appreciable restriction of competition.237

Despite this, Andreangeli recognises that BIDS suggests the possibility, through the

application of the “in-context” and more “economics-principled” pattern of

analysis, that the presumption of anticompetitive effects by reason of an

agreement’s object can be rebutted under Article 101(1) TFEU.238 Moreover,

whether an agreement falls within the ‘by object’ or ‘by effect’ category is not

based on an “exhaustive list”, and therefore each agreement has to be determined

by way of an examination of its content and purpose against its legal and economic

context.239 Despite her understanding of the BIDS case, she compares it to the GC’s

judgment in ENS.240 In the light of ENS, she considers that the judgment in BIDS is

not consistent with the pre-existing stark dichotomy between object and effect as

suggested in ENS.241 For her, the Court had not simply considered the “hardcore

nature of the restraints that the BIDS deal entailed”, but rather chose to conduct a

close scrutiny of the agreement’s individual clauses against their legal and

economic context. Through this latter method, the Court found that the agreement

234

This issue will be considered in chapter 5. 235

(Andreangeli, 2011), p224. However she cites STM as an example of this. A reading of the case does not support this analysis. 236

Ibid. 237

Ibid. 238

Ibid. 239

Ibid, p233. 240

Ibid, p234. 241

Ibid.

Page 197: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 196

restricted competition by object.242 On this basis, Andreangeli finds that the

pattern of analysis carried out by the Court suggests that it wished to extend some

aspects of the more ‘economics-guided’ approach already adopted in by-effect

cases to more serious object cases. Furthermore, it also took into consideration

issues previously reserved for the application of Article 101(3) TFEU.243

The case law analysis undertaken in chapter 2 does not wholly support such an

interpretation. The CJEU had already been applying a methodology to the object

criterion since STM that had the scope to be applied in a more ‘economics-guided’

way. Certainly, the STM Test has the capacity to tolerate an ‘effects-based'

analysis. Consequently, the effects-style analysis carried out by the Court in BIDS

was not particularly ‘new’, and the Court did not go a step beyond its existing case

law.244 Rather, the flaw in Andreangeli’s argument is her reliance on ENS. It is ENS

that is the anomaly in the case law, and it is ENS that misinterpreted the case law of

its superior court. This is evident from the GC’s rejection of its own methodology in

cases such as GSK.245 The judgment in BIDS simply re-emphasised the analysis

advocated by the more analytical approach. The main issue with BIDS is the Court’s

choice of wording when explaining the distinction between restrictions by object

and those by effect: it is this aspect of the judgment that ensures the orthodox

approach continues to enjoy some legitimacy.246 Therefore, the advent of a ‘hybrid

approach’ to the object criterion has dawned.

Andreangeli does go on to modify her initial stance, but remains of the opinion that

BIDS is the turning point in the jurisprudence.247 She believes that it is preferable to

consider the CJEU’s “current approach” as “one akin to the idea of a continuum, as

a result of which the type of assessment should be framed in light of the practice’s

nature and inherent seriousness as well as the inherent features of the market”.248

242

Ibid. 243

Ibid. Note that Andreangeli then looks at the impact of BIDS on the future interpretation of Article 101(1) and subsequently does not find that the ENS methodology is appropriate. 244

Ibid, 235. 245

Also supra n1, Cartes Bancaires. 246

See (Andreangeli, 2011), p235. 247

Ibid, pp235-238. 248

Ibid, p236.

Page 198: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 197

Prima facie infringements of Article 101(1) TFEU must, however, be assessed in the

legal and economic context and that this is not limited to specific categories of

agreements, but also encapsulates any practice suspected of being anti-

competitive.249 She thus recognises, like Paul Lasok QC, that it “could” be argued

that the analysis in the initial stages would be the same for all types of

anticompetitive agreements as such analysis would concentrate on its “content and

purpose”.250 As a result, if the agreement was seen to be so pernicious that it was

almost inevitable to harm consumer welfare it will infringe Article 101(1) TFEU

without the need to determine its actual impact on competition in the relevant

market.251 Conversely, if such initial enquiry does not reveal such harm then its

lawfulness must be tested under the ‘effect’ criterion and will only be prohibited it

can be shown competition has been distorted as a result of it.252 Essentially, her

rationale follows the judgment in STM.

From this, Andreangeli argues that the CJEU has moved away from a strictly literal

and categorical approach to Article 101(1) TFEU and towards a legal standard for

analysing the content and purpose of any agreement. Such analysis “focuses more

on the inherent seriousness rather than on their formal characteristics”.253 As a

result, Andreangeli believes that in accordance with BIDS, the question to be

considered is whether an agreement’s content and purpose is compatible with the

objectives of Article 101 TFEU (namely, economic efficiency for the purpose of

promoting consumer welfare) as opposed to whether the agreement belongs to a

formalistic category as cases such as ENS suggest.254 Therefore the type of inquiry

required for a particular agreement depends on its nature and seriousness.

Andreangeli’s arguments are extremely persuasive, but she places too much

emphasis on BIDS. BIDS did not progress the law as such, rather it cemented

principals the CJEU had already established.

249

Ibid. 250

Ibid. 251

Ibid. 252

Ibid. 253

Ibid. 254

Ibid.

Page 199: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 198

4.1. Analysis of the commentary

On the whole, the commentary recounted above seeks to explain the anomalous

case law fairly cautiously. The position advanced in this thesis is less cautious. The

review of the case law in chapter 2 brought into sharp focus the divergent ways in

which the European Courts have tackled the object criterion. It is not denied that

the jurisprudence is confusing and at times unclear. Nevertheless, there are

unambiguous paths which the CJEU has taken and varying paths which the GC has

taken over the years. The advent of modernisation and increasing reliance on

economic coherence has meant that the test originally devised in STM has taken on

a renewed significance and role.255 The prospect of a more analytical approach has

always been present within the jurisprudence, but this was put in the shadow by

the Commission’s more formalistic approach to the object criterion as highlighted

in its Article 81(3) Guidelines and in many of its decisions. The Commission’s

approach is evolving, however, although its goal is different from that of the Courts.

The Commission must police the competition rules and therefore devise policies

(for itself, undertakings and national competition authorities) to follow in this

regard. As such, undertakings and NCAs must take note of the Commission’s

predilection. The tension, therefore, between the approach of the Commission and

the European Courts is evident.

The ordering of the case law and the development of a framework under which

object should be applied undertaken by commentators such as Mahtani is

admirable. Such a ‘multi-layered structured methodology’ is complicated, however,

and does not reduce the possibility that, in the future, other types of situation may

arise that do not fall neatly within the various categories advocated. It thus seems

almost futile to attempt to identify precise scenarios where exceptions to the

general rule advocated by the orthodox approach may be granted. The truth is that

there is likely to be no single ‘correct’ answer. As so many commentators have now

established, the case law is not consistent. The Courts have not used consistent

255

Andreangeli recognises that the Courts in their more recent decisions suggest a strong commitment to upholding an ‘in context’ and economics-based interpretation of Article 101(1) TFEU and thus to a ‘modernised’ reading of Article 101 TFEU: (Andreangeli, 2011), p243.

Page 200: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 199

terminology in relation to the object criterion, have not provided a clear cut

definition of object or of the various terms utilised in connection with it, nor have

always followed a set methodology when applying ‘object’ to cases.256 Even leading

commentators such as Jones and Whish are unable adequately to ‘rationalise’ the

case law. Therefore, an entirely alternative approach is needed.

Bright lines in law are clearly important, but rigid lines are not always appropriate.

Even the US Courts have had to adapt their per se approach to accommodate

situations that they had not legislated for with the ‘quick look rule of reason’. The

approach advocated herein is that, while it is of course useful to understand and

recognise the situations in which any presumptions of anti-competitiveness by

object can be rebutted, it is not then appropriate to limit such circumstances.

Instead, a more fluid approach to the object criterion is required.257 Therefore, the

so-called anomalies in the case law should be viewed from the perspective that the

role of the object criterion is simply to determine whether the precise purpose of

the agreement is to restrict competition.

That assessment must be undertaken within the legal and economic context of the

particular facts pertaining to the agreement in question. Given the influence of the

concept of necessary effect, this is a factor that should be taken into account within

the legal context (though it is not the defining factor or the starting position). Even

though it may be extremely difficult to rebut a presumption of harm,258 the fact

remains it is possible to do so. Chapter 2 demonstrated the circumstances where

such rebuttal has been achieved. In future, different types of scenario may justify a

rebuttal, or be seen to have a pro-competitive purpose or legitimate objective, and

thus tolerate certain restraints ancillary to that primary purpose. The defining

factor is the analysis of the facts of each case: the concept of object is flexible and

256

See also (Mahtani, 2012), p39 citing (Howard, 2009); also (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’; (Goyder, 2003), I. 257

See also Mahtani’s conclusion, (Mahtani, 2012), p38-39 where he recognises that “object is not applied in a linear or abstract fashion – flexibility is afforded by an examination of the purpose of the coordination, its likely market consequences, and the legal and economic context”. 258

See (Odudu, 2006), (supported by Mahtani) regarding the inability to rebut presumptions of subjective intention to restrict competition.

Page 201: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 200

case-specific. Overall, the dichotomy between by object and by effect restrictions

as portrayed by the Commission and in cases such as ENS requires refinement. Any

restraint is, in principal, capable of restricting Article 101(1) TFEU by object; hence

the ability of any so-called ‘category’ to expand.259 Therefore, the reliance on the

concept of ‘necessary effect’ to delineate the dichotomy is erroneous: rather, it

rests on the nature of the agreement itself. If its purpose is not to restrict

competition, then either it falls outside Article 101(1) TFEU or its actual effects must

be determined.

5. Conclusion

This chapter was tasked with investigating the application of the object criterion

under the MAAP. The sheer scale of this undertaking demonstrates that the object

criterion is nuanced and complex. There is also increasing consensus among

commentators regarding the multifaceted nature of the object criterion.

Nevertheless, attempts to rationalise the case law have proved difficult for many

commentators who continue to subscribe to the notion that the object criterion

involves a form of categorisation as advanced under the hybrid approach.

Supporting the hybrid approach ensures, however, that the significance of the legal

and economic context is at least recognised. Consequently, there is agreement that

the concept of object cannot be dismissed as a simplistic, formalistic or abstract

formula.

The MAAP provides an alternative, though persuasive, explanation of the apparent

anomalies in the case law (that is, the deviations from the orthodox approach).

However, the European Courts and indeed the Commission currently follow the

hybrid approach.260 Hence, reliance on the categorisation of the object criterion

has not abated. The legal and economic context was seen to play the central role in

every assessment of an agreement’s object whether under the MAAP or hybrid

approaches. Its purpose under the hybrid approach, however, is not just to

259

As shown in supra n1, Pierre Fabre. 260

Though, notably, the Article 81(3) Guidelines follow the orthodox approach more closely than the hybrid approach, which creates a conflict between the Commission’s practical application of the law in decisions such as Lundbeck and its interpretation of the concept within its various Guidelines.

Page 202: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 201

determine the agreement’s aim, but also to provide a mechanism under which the

effects of an agreement can be rebutted. The AG in BIDS proposed that particular

elements of an agreement’s legal and economic context may draw into question

the preliminary labelling of an agreement as restrictive by ‘object’. This can occur

when: (i) the restriction does not produce relevant effects on competition; (ii) the

agreement has ambivalent effects on competition and is intended to promote

competition; or (iii) the restriction is ancillary to the broader agreement. AG

Trstenjak has been proved correct as regards the consideration of such elements,

but it is submitted that such factors are not merely used to rebut presumptions of

harm. Rather, they serve to determine if the purpose of the agreement is to restrict

competition. This is an open-ended enquiry, but does not imply that every

agreement can be found restrictive by object. The emphasis on legal context will

ensure past precedent is relevant, but not a defining factor in this regard.

Most recently, the CJEU has suggested that the object concept is not open-ended,

but rather is reserved for those types of coordination that by their nature harm

competition due to their known necessary effect.261 The merits of these

arguments are considered more closely in the next chapter. Focusing on the

necessary effect of an agreement is limiting the usefulness of the object criterion as

a tool under Article 101(1) TFEU. Additionally, it implies that new types of

restrictive practice cannot be found to be anticompetitive by object.262 Moreover,

such an understanding proposed by the CJEU does not accurately reflect the law as

discussed in this chapter. It is therefore submitted that, in accordance with the

case law of the European Courts, the MAAP is the best interpretation of the object

criterion. The following chapter will examine the impact of this finding on Article

101 TFEU as a whole.

261

See supra n1, Cartes Bancaires. Though the CJEU did not then define the contents of such category. 262

On the basis of the judgment in Cartes Bancaires, the Commission should lose the appeal in Lundbeck as it found an agreement restrictive by object, which had not previously been found to do so. Given the Commission cannot expand the object category (unlike the European Courts), the reasoning of the Court is eagerly anticipated.

Page 203: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 202

Chapter 5: The implications of adopting the more analytical approach

on Article 101 TFEU

1. Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to investigate the implications for Article 101 TFEU as

a whole of finding that the best legal interpretation of the object criterion is in

accordance with the MAAP. It therefore seeks to determine whether the MAAP fits

well within the framework of Article 101 TFEU and thereby justifies the conclusion

that it is the better rationalisation of the law. To this end, the chapter focuses on

four key aspects of Article 101 TFEU that are directly affected by the examination of

the object concept undertaken in chapters 2, 3 and 4. These aspects are pertinent

also to the ‘effect’ criterion. First, the relationship between the object criterion and

the application of the de minimis doctrine is tackled. Chapter 3 found that a neutral

effect or the capacity of the parties to affect competition may have a bearing on the

outcome when determining an agreement’s object. This section thus addresses the

MAAP’s response to the impact of market power on any analysis of an agreement’s

object and questions whether an agreement restrictive by object must be

appreciable. Next, this chapter addresses the objectives of Article 101 TFEU and

the relationship between such objectives and the object criterion. The correlation

between the concept of a ‘restriction of competition’ and the object criterion is

pertinent in this regard. Next the distinction between restrictions of competition

by ‘object’ and by ‘effect’ is assessed, and the criticism that the two concepts

become blurred under the MAAP is addressed. Finally, it investigates what the

MAAP means for the availability of an Article 101(3) TFEU exemption as well as its

relationship with Article 101(3) TFEU.

Page 204: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 203

2. De Minimis: How appreciable is object?

2.1. Introduction

This section examines the relationship between the object concept and appreciable

effects. This relationship is also pertinent to an understanding of the object/effect

dichotomy. AG Kokott has argued that when examining whether a restriction by

object is appreciable, this does not mean it should be measured against the same

thresholds (such as market share thresholds) applied when examining the

appreciable effect of restrictions of competition by effect: “otherwise the

fundamental difference between restrictions of competition ‘by effect’ and ‘by

object’ would become blurred”.1

The nature of the relationship between the object concept and appreciable effects

has been thrown into uncertainty by the recent suggestion that the de minimis

doctrine is not applicable to the object criterion at all. The uncertainty flows from

the CJEU’s controversial judgment in Expedia, which has since been preserved by

the Commission in its revised De Minimis Notice and accompanying guidance.2 In

Expedia, the CJEU held that an “agreement that may affect trade between Member

States and that has an anticompetitive object constitutes, by its nature and

independently of any concrete effect that it may have, an appreciable restriction on

competition”.3 The Commission recounted this verbatim in its Notice and

interpreted it to mean that the object criterion cannot benefit from the de minimis

doctrine.4 Hence, the revised Notice does not cover agreements that have as their

object the restriction of competition.5

1 Case C-226/11, Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence, 13 December 2012, nyr (Expedia), AG

Kokott, para 54. 2 Ibid, Expedia; 2014/C 291/01, Communication from the Commission — Notice on agreements of

minor importance which do not appreciably restrict competition under Article 101(1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (Revised De Minimis Notice); C(2014) 4136 final, Guidance on restrictions of competition "by object" for the purpose of defining which agreements may benefit from the De Minimis Notice - 25.6.2014. 3 Ibid, Expedia, para 37.

4 Revised De Minimis Notice, point 2. Note the Commission has always maintained this position, but

now cites legal authority for its contention. 5 Ibid.

Page 205: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 204

Such an approach challenges the widespread belief that any restriction of

competition must have an appreciable impact on the market.6 The de minimis

doctrine provides the rationale behind the belief held, by many commentators, that

a quantitative component to any object analysis is only necessary when

determining if an agreement has an appreciable impact on competition. This is in

view of the rule that there is no need to prove anti-competitive effects for

agreements restrictive by object.7 Moreover, the significance of the de minimis

doctrine is that if a restriction of competition by object is not appreciable it could

fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU.8 Hence, the ruling by the CJEU in Expedia merits

careful reflection.

In the following paragraphs, therefore, the relationship between the object

criterion and the de minimis doctrine is probed in more depth in light of the

judgment in Expedia.9 This is a complex area, the analysis of which centres on two

key issues. The first is whether restrictions by object should be deemed

automatically appreciable.10 The second concerns the appropriateness of the link

made by the CJEU in Expedia between restrictions by object and the effect on trade

requirement under Article 101(1) TFEU. This section demonstrates that it is

questionable whether the Commission is entitled to conclude that “by definition”

anti-competitive agreements by object have “an appreciable impact on

competition” and cannot be considered as minor.11 Arguably, the Commission has

failed adequately to address the complexity of the issues involved, and has ignored

established case law.12 It is therefore imperative that the rationale and application

of the de minimis doctrine are understood. To this end, the Expedia judgment is

used as a basis to explore these issues and to determine how the MAAP rationalises

the law.

6 (Whish & Bailey, 2012), pp120, 140-144. The de minimis doctrine was established in Case C-5/69

Völk v Vervaecke [1969] ECR 295, 5/7, 302. 7 (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p120.

8 Ibid.

9 The De Minimis Notice thus only links restrictions by ‘effect’ with the de minimis doctrine.

10 For instance, what is the role of market power in any ‘by object’ assessment.

11 See Commission press release IP/14/728 dated 25 June 2014.

12 Supra n6, Völk, p302; see (King, 2013).

Page 206: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 205

2.2. Expedia: background to the case

A French transport regulator had levied a fine on SNCF and Expedia for an

agreement they had entered to create an online travel agency for the sale of train

tickets. The regulator found that the “object and effect” of the agreement was to

restrict competition.13 Further, it found that as the parties were competitors in the

market for on-line travel agency services, their market share was more than 10% as

stipulated in the former De minimis Notice, and therefore the de minimis rule was

not applicable. The parties appealed the fine and argued that the market shares

had been overestimated, though they did not dispute the finding that the

agreement had an anticompetitive object. It was in this light that the Cour de

Cassation made a reference for a preliminary ruling. It requested clarity on

whether NCAs were precluded from applying Article 101(1) TFEU to an agreement

that does not reach the thresholds specified by the Commission in its De Minimis

Notice.14

Both the 2014 and 2001 De Minimis Notices set out the Commission’s guidance on

the concept of appreciable effect under Article 101(1) TFEU.15 It is well

documented that following the judgment in Völk, an agreement - whether by its

object or effect - that has only an ‘insignificant effect’ on the market will fall outside

the remit of Article 101(1) TFEU and therefore not restrict competition.16 The

Commission did not fully endorse the judgment in Völk in its 2001 De Minimis

Notice, as it refused to exempt restrictions by object from this rule.17 According to

Jones and Sufrin, however, that does not mean that those types of agreement will

13

Supra n1, Expedia, para 8. 14

Ibid, paras 12 and 13. Note that the De Minimis Notice referenced in Expedia was to its previous incarnation of 2001. It has been revised following the Expedia judgment. Together referred to the as ‘De Minimis Notices’. 15

Notice on Agreements of Minor Importance OJ [2001] C 368/13. It prescribes that if the aggregate market share held by undertakings at a horizontal level is less than 10% and for undertakings at a vertical level the aggregate market share is less than 15%, those agreements will not fall within the scope of Article 101(1) TFEU. This notice has now been superseded by the Revised De Minimis Notice. 16

Supra n6 Völk; Joined Cases T-68/89 etc Società Italiana Vetro SpA v Commission [1992] ECR II-01403; and Notice on Agreements of Minor Importance, paras 16 and 17. See also (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p120; (Jones & Sufrin, 2011), pp171, 172-177. 17

Supra n15, para 11; and (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p142. Jones and Sufrin take a more nuanced stance to the Commission’s position (Jones & Sufrin, 2011), p176.

Page 207: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 206

never fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU: an agreement may still be considered of

“minor importance” if the market shares are significantly lower than those

contained in the Notice.18 Consequently, the more serious the restraint, the more

insignificant the position of the parties to the agreement must be.19 This stance

was espoused by AG Kokott in Expedia, who delivered an opinion that deserves

further scrutiny.20

2.3. Opinion of Advocate General Kokott

The opinions of AG Kokott are often compelling and influential, if sometimes

contentious. She has clear ideas on how the law concerning the object criterion

should be interpreted for the future. Her views are not, it is submitted, always

faithful with the case law.21 The Expedia case is an excellent example of an instance

in which AG Kokott shifted boundaries and moulded the law into a form that she

wished it to take.22 She advocated the hybrid approach to the object criterion,

though she has a clear vision of the role that she wishes the object concept to

perform based on the concept of necessary effect and the promotion of legal

certainty.23 For AG Kokott, the reply to the question referred would determine the

scope that NCAs would have in the future when applying Article 101 TFEU.24 She

also saw the case as providing an opportunity for “further clarification of the

requirements for a finding of restrictions of competition by object at both Union

and national level”.25

18

(Jones & Sufrin, 2011), p176. 19

(Jones & Sufrin, 2011), p172, 176-177 citing (Faull & Nikpay, 2007), 3.159-3.161. 20

Supra n1, Expedia, paras 48-50, 54-56. 21

As evidenced in her opinion in Case C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands and others [2009] ECR I-4529. See (Whish & Bailey, 2012) for commentary on her opinions: pp118-119. AG Kokott approves of the idea that the object concept is there to create legal certainty and therefore moves towards positions that support that interpretation (see (Bailey, 2012), p560, ft 9). However, she also understands that agreements are assessed on the basis of their own contexts and this tension with her support of a more orthodox understanding of the object concept is not always reconciled in her opinions. 22

See similar issues raised by Pablo Ibáñez Colomo in relation to AG Kokott’s interpretation of copyright in the Greek decoders case: (Ibáñez Colomo, 2011). 23

Supra n21, T-Mobile, opinion, para 43. 24

Supra n1, Expedia, para 5. 25

Ibid.

Page 208: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 207

One theme in AG Kokott’s opinion was that de minimis market share thresholds are

irrelevant for assessing agreements between undertakings with an anti-competitive

object.26 Specifically, she asked whether an appreciable effect on competition may

be presumed where an anti-competitive object is being pursued, but the de minimis

thresholds under the De Minimis Notice are not reached.27 Acknowledging that the

De Minimis Notice is not legally binding on NCAs, she recognised that the

prohibition under Article 101 encompasses “only appreciable restrictions of

competition”.28 She cited case law such as Völk and STM to support this, and

proceeded to state that restrictions of competition must be appreciable for both

restrictions by object and by effect.29 Her citation of STM at this juncture was

curious. She later used the case to illustrate where the CJEU had not required

restrictions by object to be appreciable.30

According to the AG, the requirements concerning proof of an appreciable effect

differ dependent on whether the agreement concerns restrictions by object or

effect.31 This, she concluded, manifests itself as a result of the dichotomy between

restrictions by object and by effect: that restrictions by object do not require actual

anti-competitive effects to be proved.32 All that must be shown in an object case is

that the agreement is “actually capable” of restricting competition.33

Accordingly, “these different requirements regarding proof arise from the fact that

restrictions ‘by object’ are regarded, by their very nature, as being injurious to the

proper functioning of normal competition” as they have harmful consequences for

26

Ibid, paras 44-57. 27

Ibid, para 45. 28

Ibid, para 30, 39, 47. Though see para 38 where she adds NCA’s should not ignore Notices due to their duty of sincere cooperation. 29

Ibid, para 47. 30

Ibid, para 55. Though this is not necessarily because the CJEU merely presumed appreciability for restrictions by object. This is discussed below. 31

Ibid, para 48. 32

Ibid, paras 49-50. 33

Ibid. This is in-keeping with the Article 81(3) Guidelines, though not with the judgment in STM which requires agreements to be sufficiently deleterious.

Page 209: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 208

society.34 Moreover, they can “hardly be regarded as de minimis infringements”.35

More philosophically, AG Kokott contended that it must be presumed that

undertakings “always intend” an appreciable effect on competition, irrespective of

their market power when they enter into agreements that have an anti-competitive

object.36 Although providing no citation, she would seem to have drawn from

Odudu’s contention, though itself now somewhat modified, that subjective

intention is proof of a restrictive object.37 AG Kokott argued that the non-

application of the de minimis market share thresholds to anticompetitive

agreements by object makes sense in law and in terms of competition policy.38 This

is because undertakings with market shares below the thresholds would otherwise

be encouraged to engage in anticompetitive behaviour.39 It follows that market

share thresholds as set out in the de minimis notice are irrelevant when

determining whether restrictions of competition by object are appreciable.40

AG Kokott explained that the judgment in Völk supports the proposition that Article

101(1) TFEU is not applicable to agreements that have an anticompetitive object if

the agreement has an “insignificant effect” on the market, taking into account the

weak position of the parties on the relevant market.41 This is significant as it

amounts to confirmation that restrictions by object can fall outside Article 101(1)

TFEU if they have an insignificant effect. Moreover, AG Kokott stressed that this

does not then mean that “the appreciable effect of restrictions of competition ‘by

34

Ibid, para 50 citing BIDS and T-Mobile. How the CJEU recounts the distinction between object and effect is troublesome as the statement originally made in BIDS provides no legal citation, but yet has subsequently been cited in judgments such as T-Mobile, Pierre Fabre, Expedia. 35

Ibid, paras 50-51. This statement clearly supports the Commission’s position which specifically omits the safety net of the de minimis thresholds for hardcore restrictions. Such understanding of the law begs the question, why should restrictions by object need to be appreciable at all if this is how the Court interprets the object criterion? Notably in Cartes Bancaires, despite the CJEU upholding the object/effect distinction set out in BIDS, it found how the object of an agreement is determined turns on whether the analysis reveals the agreement is sufficiently deleterious (as per the STM Test). 36

Ibid, para 50. 37

(Odudu, 2001), ‘The Object Requirement Revisited’. See also Case C-209/07 BIDS [2008] ECR I-8637, paras 44-46 of the opinion, which also support Odudu’s interpretation. See also (Odudu, 2006), p114 and chapter 3 of this thesis. 38

Supra n1, Expedia, opinion, para 52. 39

Ibid. 40

Ibid, para 53. 41

Ibid, para 54.

Page 210: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 209

object’ must be measured by reference to market share thresholds and still less by

reference to the same thresholds as those used when examining the appreciable

effect of restrictions of competition ‘by effect’”.42

In the light of her reasoning, AG Kokott reached the conclusion that the

requirements concerning proof that restrictions of competition by object are

appreciable, should not be more stringent than the requirements concerning proof

of an appreciable effect on trade between Member States.43 She did not explain

why she made that link, though she did comment by way of a footnote that an

“appreciable effect on trade” can be found from a market share that is normally

around 5%.44 She concluded that if it is established that an agreement that is

“anticompetitive by object is capable of appreciably affecting trade between

Member States, it may be readily inferred that the agreement is also capable of

appreciably restricting...competition”.45 This suggests that for by-object restrictions

appreciable effects need only be potential and not concrete.46 A similar link was

made in Völk, whereby the Commission submitted that the same reasons why the

agreement in question did not have the object of restricting competition were

applicable to why the agreement did not affect trade between Member States.47

In answer to the preliminary reference, AG Kokott proposed that a Member State

may impose penalties on undertakings on the grounds that the agreement they

have entered is anti-competitive and does not reach the thresholds set out in the

De Minimis Notice, provided that the NCA has taken account of the Notice and

proves in another way that the object or effect of the agreement is an appreciable

restriction of competition.48 Furthermore, the Notice should be interpreted to

42

Ibid. Emphasis added. 43

Ibid, para 56. 44

Ibid, para 58, ft 57. 45

Ibid, para 57 46

This aspect is not expanded upon in the opinion. 47

Supra n5, Völk, p301 (g). Though notably this is not the same as saying the requirements of proof are identical when determining appreciability for the effect on trade criterion and when establishing whether there is a restriction of competition. 48

Supra n1, Expedia, para 58(1).

Page 211: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 210

mean that the market share thresholds are irrelevant when determining whether

agreements with an anti-competitive object are appreciable.49

Though much of the opinion is valuable and sensible, it is problematic.50 For

instance, AG Kokott did not sufficiently address the relationship between the object

concept and the requirement that it be appreciable,51 or its relationship with the

jurisdictional function of the effect on trade criterion and the associated test

establishing an effect on trade. Ostensibly, AG Kokott agreed that the object

concept must be appreciable (though to a lesser degree than under the effect

concept), and that exclusive reliance on market shares is not the only means to

measure or prove appreciability. Her reasoning, however, does not give any real

indication why she supports the position that object should be appreciable at all.

This is especially pertinent given that the majority of her opinion aims to show why

the de minimis thresholds in the De Minimis Notice are irrelevant to restrictions by

object.52 Nonetheless, her opinion is more nuanced and considered than the

subsequent judgment of the Court.

2.4. Judgment of the Court

At first sight, it would appear that the CJEU agreed with much of AG Kokott’s

opinion. The CJEU responded to the question referred by the Cour de Cassation by

stating:

“Article 101(1) TFEU and Article 3(2) of [Regulation 1/2003] must be interpreted as not precluding a national competition authority from applying Article 101(1) TFEU to an agreement between undertakings that may affect trade between Member States, but that does not reach the thresholds specified by the European Commission in its [de minimis notice], provided that the agreement constitutes an appreciable restriction of competition”.53

49

Ibid, para 58(2). 50

See infra section 2.5. 51

Supra n1, Expedia, paras 53-57 (particularly 55). 52

Note that STM requires restrictions by object to be “sufficiently deleterious”. AG Kokott does not allude to this. 53

Supra n1, Expedia, Operative part.

Page 212: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 211

Seemingly, the Court is merely reiterating that a Notice issued by the Commission is

only binding on the Commission. In this regard, the Commission binds itself over

the exercise of its own powers as it is constrained in applying EU competition law

within the parameters of its own guidance.54

In its judgment, the CJEU correctly reasons that an agreement will come outside

Article 101(1) TFEU if it has only an “insignificant effect” on the market. It notes

that both agreements by object and agreements by effect must “perceptibly”

restrict competition, and must also be capable of affecting trade between Member

States in accordance with Article 101(1) TFEU.55 It also recounts how a restriction of

competition should be assessed by reiterating the conditions set out in the STM

judgment (although it did not directly cite that case).56 As well as recounting the

judgment in Völk, the Court recognised that the position of the parties on the

market is not the only basis upon which an agreement may have an appreciable

effect.57 The CJEU also agreed with the AG that the Commission’s De minimis Notice

is not binding on Member States: NCAs may take into account the thresholds in the

Notice, but are not required to do so.58 It found that such thresholds are one of

several factors that enable an authority to determine whether a restriction is

appreciable when examining the actual circumstances of the agreement.59 In view

of the anticompetitive object of the agreement, the CJEU subsequently made the

point that the concrete effects of an agreement do not need to taken into account

once it appears that it has as its object the restriction of competition.60 The Court

then described the now familiar distinction between infringements by object and

infringements by effect, arising from the fact that “certain forms of collusion

54

This ensures the adherence to principles of equal treatment and the protection of legitimate expectations. 55

Supra n1, Expedia, paras 16-17. 56

Ibid, para 21. 57

Ibid, para 22, citing Bagnasco and Others, para 35. 58

Ibid, para 31. 59

Ibid. 60

Ibid, para 35.

Page 213: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 212

between undertakings can be regarded, by their very nature, as being injurious to

the proper functioning of normal competition”.61

Despite the logical build up to the ratio decidendi of the judgment, the CJEU then

used the distinction between object and effect as the basis for the statement that

an “agreement that may affect trade between Member States and that has an

anticompetitive object constitutes, by its nature and independently of any concrete

effect that it may have, an appreciable restriction on competition”.62 This implied

that if an agreement affects trade between Member States (which must be

appreciable) and is also determined to be a restriction by object it will automatically

be an appreciable restriction of competition. That is, ‘object’ means ‘appreciable

restriction of competition’. If that is the CJEU’s intention, then the judgment is

ground-breaking.

On its face, this ruling reflects the link made by AG Kokott between the satisfaction

of the effect on trade criterion with an anticompetitive object, which ‘may’ imply

that an agreement is capable of appreciably restricting competition.63 The CJEU has

made the link more definite however. The significance of the statement therefore

necessitates reflection as the CJEU is potentially overruling its previous case law.64

The questions raised by this statement are numerous: is the object concept now

intrinsically linked with the satisfaction of the effect on trade criterion, and if so,

why? Is that then an appropriate test to determine whether an agreement has an

appreciable effect on competition, and what would this mean for the relationship

between object and appreciability?

The judgment has been interpreted by a number of practitioners as stipulating that,

“an agreement that has an effect on interstate trade and an anticompetitive object

constitutes an appreciable restriction on competition per se”.65 Also, that the CJEU

61

Ibid, para 36. 62

Ibid, para 37. 63

Ibid, opinion, paras 56-57. 64

See supra n6, Völk: that any agreement must have an appreciable impact on competition to infringe Article 101(1) TFEU regardless of its object or effect. 65

(Stibbe, 2013).

Page 214: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 213

has “simplified the case law by ruling that agreements with the object to restrict

competition that have an effect on trade between Member States will always

constitute a violation of Article 101 TFEU”.66 Hence, the suggestion is that the CJEU

does not require the object criterion to be appreciable, which gives rise to the

possibility of a return to a more formalistic understanding. In this vein, there is no

quantitative component to the object criterion; if one follows the orthodox

approach it is clear that certain restrictions automatically harm competition and do

not require separate assessment to determine if they have an appreciable effect.

Akman considers the judgment to declare that “any object agreement which has an

appreciable effect on trade between Member States has an appreciable effect on

competition”, and therefore that object agreements that have an effect on trade

can no longer make use of the de minimis doctrine.67 This means that for

restrictions by object there is a presumption that they will have an appreciable

effect on competition.68 For Akman, the judgment in Expedia has thus over-turned

the judgment in Völk.69

Re-enforcing that position, the Commission has adopted the stance that the CJEU

has “now established that the concept of a non-appreciable impact on competition

(de minimis) does not apply when the agreement in question contains a so-called

‘by object restriction’”.70 Hence, it appears to affirm that there is no need to prove

appreciability for the object criterion as it is automatically appreciable per se.

Whether such an interpretation is correct is not categorical given both the CJEU’s

statement that agreements must “perceptibly” restrict competition, and its actual

answer to the question referred.71 The propensity for confusion and lack of clarity

regarding the object criterion, despite subsequent judgments such as Allianz

66

Ibid. This was said to be in contrast to the Völk judgment where any restriction whether by object or effect will fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU if it only has an insignificant effect on the market, taking into account the weak position of the parties on the relevant market. 67

(Akman, 2013). 68

Ibid. 69

Ibid. 70

Commission, Public Consultations, Revision of the De Minimis Notice, Objective of the consultation, July 2013. 71

Supra n1, Expedia, paras 20, 38.

Page 215: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 214

Hungária and Cartes Bancaires which advocate a more analytical approach, has thus

been heightened.

If the Commission is right, the implications of the judgment are profound as it

seemingly reinforces the orthodox approach. Such an understanding of the

judgment could have consequences that the CJEU did not intend.72 The most

obvious consequence has been the Commission’s tendentious interpretation of the

judgment and its influence on the revised De Minimis Notice.73 AG Kokott gave

clear reasoning as to why the De Minimis Notice thresholds are not applicable to

restrictions by object, but she did not then reject the idea that the object criterion

requires some form of appreciable impact.

2.5. Analysis of the judgment

Contrary to the views expounded above, the CJEU did not in fact announce a new

position in law, particularly in the light of its concluding statement and the context

of its judgment.74 The Court does not, moreover, readily proffer contentious

judgments. Rather, in Expedia it was merely stating the obvious: that agreements

that affect trade and have an anticompetitive object will normally appreciably

restrict competition. To have actually determined the object of an agreement

would have required the Court to assess an agreement within its legal and economic

context. Therefore, whether the agreement was appreciable would have already

been assessed at that juncture.

Alternatively, the CJEU was asserting that satisfaction of the effect on trade criterion

will also satisfy the requirement that the object of an agreement is appreciable.

This latter interpretation is more problematic as the CJEU did not disclose how the

concepts should be linked. Furthermore, it could be misinterpreted as suggesting

that when assessing the object of an agreement any analytical component is now

redundant if the effect on trade criteria has been satisfied. Chapters 2 and 3

72

This is amplified in the CJEU’s judgments in Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária and Case C-67/13 P Cartes Bancaires. 73

See De Minimis Notice, para 2, and accompanying press releases. 74

Supra n1, Expedia, para 38.

Page 216: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 215

demonstrate that if this were the case the CJEU would have been turning its back on

decades of case law. Moreover, at no point does the Court state that the object

criterion cannot benefit from the de minimis doctrine as coined in Völk. On the

contrary, the CJEU reaffirms the fact that restrictions by object must be

perceptible.75

What is unfortunate about the judgment is that it has allowed inferences to be

drawn that have ultimately been preserved by the Commission in its revised De

Minimis Notice. The scope for misinterpretation of the law and its misapplication is

therefore significant. The revised De Minimis Notice and accompanying guidance

document brings the Commission back to a more orthodox approach despite

subsequent judgments in Allianz Hungária and Cartes Bancaires, which support a

more contextual analysis.76 Rather than recasting the law, Expedia raises pertinent

questions regarding the role of de minimis in any assessment of the object of an

agreement.77 It is this relationship and its appropriateness that is considered next.

2.5.1. Appreciable effects

The requirement that restrictions of competition under Article 101(1) TFEU need be

appreciable is not a requirement of the Treaty. Therefore, demonstrating the

existence of market power is not a pre-requisite for a finding of a restriction of

competition.78 Rather, the European Courts have determined that an agreement

must restrict competition to an appreciable extent and that Article 101(1) TFEU is

not concerned with agreements that have an insignificant effect on the market.79

Moreover, the case law shows that even agreements containing hardcore restraints

can fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU should they have an insignificant effect.80 What

75

Ibid, para 38. 76

Though the Commission has conceded that in “exceptional” cases a restriction by object may be compatible with Article 101(1) TFEU if it is objectively necessary or protects a legitimate goal; in such instances the agreement comes outside Article 101(1) TFEU: section 1 of the De Minimis Guidance. 77

Expedia also crucially recounts how restrictions of competition are determined: para 21. This is then specifically related to the object criterion in Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária, para 36. 78

(Jones & Sufrin, 2011), p215. 79

Case 22/71 Béguelin Import Co v GL Import-Export S.A [1971] ECR 949. Supra n6, Völk, p302. 80

Supra n6, Völk. See in particular the Commission’s comments in section IV (e), (f) and (g) as well as the ‘grounds of judgment’ pp301-302 in Völk, which support the more analytical approach and a

Page 217: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 216

the case law does not tell us is what constitutes an ‘insignificant effect’, or whether

the measure changes depending on the nature of the restraint. Neither does it

explain in the context of the object criterion whether that effect need be an actual

or potential effect on competition. Moreover, the case law does not explain

whether the effect of agreements-by-object should be appreciable and, if so,

whether that is at all appropriate.

The judgment in Expedia succeeds in further fudging the essence of the object

criterion. This is due to the interplay between the MAAP and the orthodox

approach, which are both advocated in the judgment.81 It is unclear whether the

CJEU was reiterating AG Kokott’s conclusion in its own terms and thus approving

the link she established between proof of effect on trade and proof of appreciable

effect. The practical implications of this are ambiguous.82 Moreover, a concern is

whether then proving the object of an agreement requires any meaningful

quantitative component, particularly as concrete effects do not need to be proven

(or indeed, if the Commission is believed, potential effects).83

It is submitted that Expedia does not counsel the abandonment of any quantitative

component. The CJEU still expressly stipulated that to assess whether a restriction

under Article 101(1) TFEU exists, recourse to the content of the agreement, its

objectives and the legal and economic context is necessary and must perceptibly

restrict competition.84 Whether proving an effect on trade provides a short cut to

the assessment of whether an agreement restricts competition by object is

dubious. It is not correct that the only quantitative component when determining if

strict reading of the STM and Consten & Grundig judgments. See also AG Kokott’s comments in para 43 of Expedia (supra n1). 81

Supra n1, Expedia, paras 17-22 versus para 36-37. 82

See (Bailey, 2012), p590 who notes that “a complicating factor has been that the idea of an appreciable effect on competition is sometimes intermingled with the separate concept of appreciable effect on trade”. 83

See section 1, De Minimis Guidance. 84

Supra n1, Expedia, paras 17, 21.

Page 218: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 217

an agreement is restrictive by object arises when assessing its appreciability.85 This

is due to the increasingly recognised role of the ‘legal and economic context’.86

The Court was right to affirm that the Commission’s thresholds in its De minimis

Notice may be disregarded by the NCAs “provided that the agreement constitutes

an appreciable restriction of competition”.87 This is because whether an agreement

is appreciable or not depends on the facts of the case, and thus on its own legal and

economic context. It axiomatic that certain agreements that come under the de

minimis thresholds could still, in principal, have an appreciable effect. The

thresholds are the Commission’s enforcement policy choice: these are essential

tools for the Commission to carry out its work, but are not necessarily upheld by

law. They give undertakings a degree of certainty that the Commission will not

investigate agreements below the threshold.

The relationship between the object criterion and the de minimis doctrine is

abstruse. The necessity to prove actual appreciable effects in an effect analysis was

first raised in STM.88 Even though the Community Courts have consistently upheld

the de minimis doctrine since Völk,89 it is still not altogether unambiguous. This will

undoubtedly be exacerbated by Expedia.90 Whether appreciability makes sense for

restrictions by object requires reflection. This is because restraints by object do not

require the plaintiff to prove the agreement actually has a restrictive effect on

competition. Furthermore, the success or implementation of an agreement is

irrelevant to a finding by object. Others believe that a detailed analysis of

appreciability would undermine the distinction between object and effect.91 It is

also argued that those undertakings with extremely low market shares would

almost be “invited to refrain from effective competition with each other and to join

85

Cf (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p120; (Rose, 24 February 2010). 86

See chapters 2, 3 and 4. 87

Supra n1, Expedia, para 38. 88

Case C-56/65 STM, 249. Note it is not a requirement of the TFEU itself. 89

Supra n79, Béguelin; Case T-77/92 Parker Pen Ltd v Commission [1994] ECR-II-549; C-260/07 Pedro IV Servicios SL v Total Espana SA [2009] ECR I-2437; Case T-49/02 Brasserie Nationale v Commission [2005] ECR II-3033. 90

See (Bailey, 2012), p590. 91

(Bailey, 2012), p591.

Page 219: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 218

together in restraint of trade”.92 There is certainly case law that could be seen to

endorse the position that appreciability is not a requirement for satisfying the

object criterion.93 Appreciability is almost viewed as a step removed from the

process of determining the object or effect of an agreement, as if it is a separate

requirement.

It is proposed that, contrary to being a separate component, the requirement of

appreciability should be seen, when determining restrictions of competition by

object, as part of the overall assessment as to whether an agreement has the object

of restricting competition. This is drawn from a consideration of the legal and

economic context. It is clear from the judgment in Völk that restrictions by object

can benefit from a form of appreciability as the Court held that, with reference to

the actual circumstances of the agreement, an agreement may fall outside Article

101(1) TFEU if the effect on the market is insignificant.94 The Court did not specify

at what level the effect is considered ‘insignificant’, nor did it specify that to

determine such effect required knowledge of the parties’ actual market shares.

Rather, it referred to “the weak position which the persons concerned have on the

markets of the product in question”.95 The STM test upholds this notion as it

requires that when assessing the precise purpose of the agreement (that is, the

object), if an analysis of the clauses of the agreement does not reveal the “effect on

competition to be sufficiently deleterious” then the consequences (the actual

effects) of the agreement should be considered to determine whether competition

has in fact been restricted to an appreciable extent.96

Determining whether the effect on competition is sufficiently deleterious would

arguably involve an understanding that an agreement had some form of

appreciable effect. It does not necessarily warrant, however, a determination of

92

Supra n1, Expedia, opinion, para 52. 93

Case C-56/65, STM, 249. See also ibid, Expedia, opinion, para 55. 94

Supra n6 Völk, para 5/7, p302. Emphasis added. 95

Ibid, para 5/7. 96

Case C-56/65, STM, 249. Emphasis added. See this replicated in C-67/13P Cartes Bancaires, para 52. Though it is questionable what the distinction is between ‘sufficiently deleterious’ and ‘appreciable’. See the Commission’s submission in Völk, p 300 IV (e) (supra n6).

Page 220: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 219

actual appreciable effect. Rather, that it is capable or has the potential of having a

negative impact on competition.97 In STM, the Court stipulated that to decide

whether a restriction is prohibited by its object or effect, it is appropriate to take

into account, inter alia, the nature and quantity of the products covered by the

agreement and the position and importance of the supplier and distributor on the

market for the products concerned.98 This requirement was repeated in Allianz

Hungária, Expedia and Cartes Bancaires, though in some cases the citations made in

support were inaccurate and moreover the pertinent authority for this, STM, was

omitted.99 That aside, the case law review in chapter 2 highlights that each case

should be assessed on its own merits and facts.100 As such, it would depend on the

agreement at what point it would be ‘sufficiently deleterious’.101 This point was

picked up on by the CJEU in Cartes Bancaires where it referred to the need for the

agreement to reveal a sufficient degree of harm.102 Determining whether an

agreement reveals a sufficient degree of harm to competition necessitates an

analysis of the agreement’s legal and economic context, which involves taking

account of the nature of the goods and the real conditions of the functioning and

structure of the market/s in question.103 Hence, the parties’ market power may be

an important factor in such analysis when determining if an agreement’s purpose is

to restrict competition.104

The judgment in Völk stated that an agreement falls outside Article 101(1) TFEU

when it has:

“only an insignificant effect on the markets, taking into account the weak position which the persons concerned have on the market of the product in question. Thus an [exclusive dealing] agreement, even with absolute territorial protection, may, having regard to the

97

See eg, C-32/11 Allianz Hungária, para 38. Cf De Minimis Guidelines, section 1. 98

Case C-56/65, STM, p250. 99

(Graham, 2013), ‘Methods for determining whether an agreement restricts competition: comment on Allianz Hungária’, p548. Also, C-32/11 Allianz Hungária, para 36; supra n1, Expedia, para 21. 100

C-32/11, Allianz Hungária, para 38. 101

See (Faull & Nikpay, 2007), para 3.158 and case law cited. 102

C-67/13P, Cartes Bancaires, paras 52-53, 78. However, the notion that this is dependent on experience alone is not supported herein. 103

C-67/13P, Cartes Bancaires, para 53; See also supra n1, Völk. 104

Ibid, Völk, para 54.

Page 221: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 220

weak position of the persons concerned on the market in the products in question...escape the prohibition laid down in Article [101]”.105

This passage is taken to mean that the weak position of the parties to the

agreement on the product market in question should be taken into account when

assessing the actual circumstances of the case for agreements whether by object or

effect. Therefore, the legal and economic context is key. This assessment goes

hand in hand with an assessment of the effect on trade criterion, which too must be

satisfied.106 The Court’s judgment in Völk follows its rephrasing of the question

referred as: “whether, in deciding whether [exclusive distribution agreements] fall

within the prohibition set out in Article [85](1) of the Treaty, regard must be had to

the proportion of the market which the grantor controls or endeavours to obtain in

the territory ceded”.107

Consequently, it would appear that where the parties have a market share between

1% and 5% the effect on competition is insignificant.108 From an economic

perspective, it is hard to see where the economic harm might be if two

undertakings with no market power colluded. This view is upheld by Akman who

considers it to be unacceptable to suggest that an agreement where the parties

have a market share of 2% will have an appreciable effect on competition.109 That

said, parties that aim to restrict competition should not benefit from a rule that

allows their agreements to fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU per se as a result of their

low market shares.110 However, this depends on what the parties are seeking to

achieve and is context driven.111 For instance, it is less plausible that horizontal

agreements would be seen to be de minimis as opposed to vertical ones.112 The

thresholds set out by the Commission in its revised De Minimis Notice may well not

105

Ibid, Völk, para 5/7, p302. Emphasis added. 106

Ibid. 107

Ibid, para 2/4, p301/302. 108

(Faull & Nikpay, 2007), para 3.160. 109

(Akman, 2013). 110

This is separate from the Commission setting out thresholds as safe harbours against prosecution in a De Minimis Notice. Therefore the Commission will not pursue parties to agreements that are below a particular market share. That is a justifiable policy decision, but not the law. 111

See C-19/77, Miller International [1978] ECR 131. 112

See Expedia, opinion, ft 56 (supra n1).

Page 222: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 221

apply to restrictions by object, but that is not to say that there is no place for

consideration of market shares and an agreement’s potential impact on

competition.

The judgment in Expedia does not overturn Völk. Rather, it illustrates how the CJEU

does not always enunciate the subtleties of Article 101(1) TFEU and can thus

confuse rather than clarify. The phraseology used by the CJEU is unhelpful:

arguably there is an innate finding of appreciable effects when the object of an

agreement is determined within its legal and economic context. This resolution of

the law is, however, contentious. For example, there is a question over whether

determining appreciability is a separate element from determining the object of an

agreement. In Ziegler SA v Commission, the GC found that agreements that restrict

competition by object infringe Article 101(1) TFEU only if they have an appreciable

effect on competition and on trade between Member States.113 This suggests

appreciability is assessed after a finding of object, and that it seemingly must

measure an actual effect on competition. Whether the determination when

appreciability is assessed makes any material difference to the eventual outcome

for a restriction by object is moot. To perceive appreciability as part of the legal

and economic context as well as the appraisal of the circumstances of the

agreement would surely be more sensible. This is partly because it would then

discourage the idea that there is no quantitative component to the object criterion.

The fact of the matter is, the impact of agreements that are restrictive by object

must be appreciable, but at what point they become appreciable is debatable.114

113

T-199/08 Ziegler SA v Commission 11 July 2013, nyr, paras 41-45; T-49/01 Brasserie Nationale v Commission [2005] ECR II-3033, para 140. The De Minimis Notice would also suggest de minimis is determined after a finding of object. 114

See (Bailey, 2009), p359. Bailey suggests that the OFT has found in several decisions that agreements which have the object of restricting competition are, by their very nature, capable of having an appreciable effect on competition and therefore trade. That is, a finding of object could satisfy the requirement of an appreciable effect on trade within the UK. However, Bailey caveats his interpretation by saying, “...save in exceptional circumstances, agreements that have as their object the restriction of competition necessarily have at least the potential to affect trade within the United Kingdom”. (Emphasis added). Bailey thereby turns AG Kokott’s reasoning around by finding that, within UK law, an [appreciable] effect on trade [in the UK] may be inferred from the existence of an appreciable restriction of competition: p361.

Page 223: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 222

That even a tiny market share could potentially result in a finding of an

infringement by object is therefore not in question, although it is doubtful. The

more pertinent issue is whether anything else other than market shares could

satisfy the requirement that agreements are perceptibly restrictive of competition.

Whish and Bailey suggest that market power can be influential where the parties

hold a tiny proportion of the market for a particular product, but have an important

position on the market generally.115 They also suggest that the case law shows

agreements have been found not to be appreciable, not because of the parties’

market power, but because the restriction is insignificant in a qualitative sense.116

In summation, STM highlights that each case is decided on its merits, hence the

consideration of the position of the parties on the market within the analysis of the

legal and economic context. The judgment in Völk concurs with this as the outcome

of whether an agreement comes outside Article 101(1) TFEU depends on the

“actual circumstances” of the agreement.117 Bailey argues – correctly – that what

constitutes appreciability under the object criterion is different from that under

effect: that actual appreciable effects do not need to be proved under the object

criterion, rather that “the potential effects on competition of the conduct are

inherently likely to be significant”.118 Otherwise, it would undermine the

object/effect dichotomy.119 Bailey asserts that the de minimis doctrine is based on

the idea that “the risk of competitive harm is too small for the law to be concerned

with”.120 Therefore the de minimis doctrine only applies to cases of real economic

insignificance.121 Consequently, it is not inconceivable that parties to an agreement

with a tiny market share (below 5%) may, within the agreement’s context, be found

to restrict competition by object.122 Ultimately, the outcome depends on the

115

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p143 citing Case 30/78 Distillers Co Ltd v Commission [1980] ECR 2229. 116

Ibid, p144. 117

Supra n1, Völk, para 5/7, p302. 118

(Bailey, 2012), pp590, 591. 119

See eg Bailey, ibid, p590. 120

Ibid, Bailey, p590, 4.3. 121

Ibid, Bailey, p591. 122

Supra n111, Miller. See also (Bailey, 2012), ft 214.

Page 224: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 223

purpose of the agreement.123 For instance, Völk concerned a vertical agreement

(exclusive dealing). Whether the same conclusion would have been reached if the

case had concerned a horizontal price fixing cartel is doubtful.124

AG Kokott was aware of these issues concerning the frailty of the relationship

between appreciability and the object concept; hence, her suggestions that the

level of proof differs when establishing the object of an agreement. In addition, she

marked out as significant the fact that appreciability can also be proved without

recourse to market shares, a point also picked up by the CJEU in its judgment.125

For the Commission, the de minimis doctrine plays a different role. Drawing on the

Commission’s De minimis Notices, appreciability refers to whether the effects on

competition are sufficient to warrant the EU’s intervention under Article 101(1)

TFEU.126

Whether the de minimis doctrine is appropriate for the object concept is,

nonetheless, debatable. It is submitted that the doctrine is suitable as it cannot be

truly said that an agreement aims to restrict competition if the potential effect on

competition is insignificant.127 This should be determined when examining the legal

and economic context of an agreement: is an agreement so unimportant, that

despite the anticompetitive purpose of the agreement it should still fall outside the

realms of Article 101(1) TFEU altogether as its potential effect on competition in

that market is inconsequential. STM refers to the “precise purpose” of an

agreement, which denotes the over-arching purpose of the agreement and,

secondly, that the effect on competition be “sufficiently deleterious”.128 This

123

Though Bailey describes this by stating the de minimis doctrine only applies “to cases of real economic insignificance”, (Bailey, 2012), p591. Also Joined Cases T-67, 68,71 & 78/00, JFE Engineering v Commission, [2004] ECR II-2501, para 384. 124

Bailey refers to a number of judgments in support of such a stance whereby the Court rejected the argument that a cartel did not appreciably restrict competition. (Bailey, 2012), p591. 125

Supra n1, Expedia, para 22. 126

For a discussion regarding the Commission’s consultation on revising the De Minimis Notice in view of Expedia, see (Graham, 2013), ‘Rethinking the de minimis rules’. 127

See eg (Bailey, 2012), p590: the doctrine is based on the concept of de minimis non curat lex, that is, the risk of competitive harm is too small for the law to be concerned with. Cf (Blanco, 2012), p23 and pp30-33. 128

Case C-56/65, STM also refers to the consideration of the position and importance of the parties on the market.

Page 225: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 224

alludes to the balancing act that can take place under the object criterion when

determining what the true purpose of the agreement is. The complicating factor

resulting from Expedia is whether, in respect of the object criterion, the CJEU

intended to link satisfaction of the effect on trade criterion with satisfaction of an

appreciable effect on competition.

2.5.2. Effect on trade

The most important aspect of the effect on trade criterion is that, unlike the

substantive test which determines whether an agreement restricts competition, it is

a jurisdictional test.129 It determines whether an examination of an agreement or

conduct is warranted under Articles 101 and 102 TFEU.130 Article 101 TFEU requires

that it is applicable only to agreements that “may affect trade between Member

States”. The requirement ‘may affect trade’ relates to the fact that is possible to

foresee with a sufficient degree of probability that the agreement “may have an

influence, direct or indirect, actual or potential, on the pattern of trade between

Member States”.131 Therefore it is necessary that an agreement is capable of

having an effect, but it is not necessary to prove it will do so.132 Whether the

pattern of trade is influenced it is merely necessary to show that trade has been

influenced by means of a reduction or, indeed, an increase in trade.133 Given the

wide remit of the notion ‘may affect’, it highlights that the jurisdictional reach is

extensive.134 Moreover, an agreement containing a so-called ‘hardcore restriction’

may circumvent the remit of Article 101(1) TFEU if it does not satisfy the effect on

trade requirement.

129

(Jones & Sufrin, 2014), p181. 130

(Whish, 2009), p144; (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p146; C-22/78, Hugin Kassaregister AG and Hugin Cash Registers Ltd v Commission [1979] 3 CMLR 345. See also generally, (King & Scott, 2012). 131

Guidelines on the effect on trade concept contained in Articles [101 and 102 TFEU], (Guidelines on Inter-state Trade), para 23. 132

Ibid, para 26. 133

Ibid para 34. 134

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p146.

Page 226: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 225

The effect on trade must be appreciable.135 To assess appreciability, the

Commission looks to the market position of the parties to the agreement. The

larger the market share, the more likely that trade will be affected.136 According to

the Commission, not only is an undertaking’s market share relevant, but also the

value of its turnover.137 Moreover, the assessment should be undertaken within

the legal and economic context.138 Arguably, this aspect of the test is similar to that

required when assessing the object of an agreement in accordance with STM. What

is more, the Commission states that appreciability, in the context of effect on trade,

is satisfied when the parties aggregate market share is above 5% and their turnover

is below 40 million EUR.139 This test differs from that set out in the De Minimis

Notices. It is this distinction that is drawn upon by AG Kokott in Expedia.140

It is submitted that the outcome of the effect on trade test should not

autonomously satisfy whether an agreement restricts competition by object, nor

that the functions of the jurisdictional and substantive tests be merged. The

jurisdictional test and substantive test pursue different goals.141 The ruling by the

CJEU in Expedia has had the unfortunate consequence of bringing into question the

relationship between the jurisdictional and substantive elements of Article 101(1)

TFEU. Consequently, there will be speculation over whether a satisfaction of the

effect on trade test will automatically satisfy the requirement that restrictions by

object are appreciable.142 As stated above, some commentators have interpreted

135

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p147. 136

Supra n131, Guidelines on Inter-state Trade, para 45. 137

Ibid, paras 46-47. 138

Ibid, para 49. 139

Ibid, para 52. 140

Supra n1, Expedia. 141

(Bailey, 2012), p590, 4.3. 142

It is hard to see that AG Kokott intended this outcome.

Page 227: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 226

this as removing any analytical component from the object concept.143 It is

proposed that the CJEU did not necessarily intend such conclusion.144

It is not denied that there are superficial factors that connect the effect on trade

criterion and the substantive test under Article 101(1) TFEU: factors used to

determine whether there is an effect on trade will often have similarities to those

used to determine whether there is a restriction of competition. For instance, a

consideration of the nature of the products and the position and importance of the

parties on the market will be relevant in both cases.145 It would therefore not be

inappropriate to surmise that these were the reasons why AG Kokott deemed it

suitable to link those lesser thresholds under the Effect on Trade Notice with the

satisfaction of the requirement that restrictions by object can be inferred as being

appreciable.146

Aside from the fact the effect on trade requirement is a jurisdictional test, however,

there are crucial differences. An effect on trade is determined on the basis of

whether an agreement may have “an influence, direct or indirect, actual or

potential, on the pattern of trade between Member States”.147 Therefore the test

relates to a determination of the ‘pattern of trade’, not whether there is a

‘restriction of competition’. Fundamentally, the goals of the requirements are

different. Linking the satisfaction of the jurisdictional test with the substantive test

can only result in confusion.148 The results of the jurisdictional test should not form

the basis for an automatic irrebuttable presumption that an agreement found to

have a restrictive object is appreciable.149 To blur the lines between the

143

See commentary by Greenberg Traurig (Urlus & Mulder, 29 January 2013), which states “any contract with an effect on interstate trade within the EU including an anti-competitive object, constitutes an appreciable restriction on competition per se. Ergo, clauses with such an anti-competitive object are banned, and it is not necessary to investigate whether the restriction in such clauses is capable of affecting competition”. 144

As borne out in the judgments of Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária and Case C-67/13P Cartes Bancaires. 145

(Jones & Sufrin, 2011), p179. 146

Supra n1, Expedia, paras 55-57 of the opinion: though the point was made in relation to the higher thresholds set out in the De Minimis Notice. 147

Case C-56/65 STM, p249. 148

(Jones & Sufrin, 2011), p177 onwards. 149

Arguably AG Kokott did not intend her inference to be interpreted as irrebutable.

Page 228: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 227

jurisdictional and substantive assessments under Article 101(1) TFEU undermines

the body of case law, which rightly separates the two requirements.

Whilst the outcome and methodology applied when determining if the

jurisdictional test has been satisfied may be a helpful basis upon which to

determine if the object of an agreement is appreciable within its legal and

economic context, it cannot be depended upon.150 Rather, the substantive test

would need to reaffirm whether the object of an agreement was to restrict

competition appreciably. This is also because the test to satisfy the requirement

that an agreement affects trade is a broad one, and it is of no consequence whether

the pattern of trade is potentially reduced, restricted or even increased.151

2.6. Conclusion: not a landmark judgment

The judgment in Expedia is unhelpful in terms of the impact it may have on the

interpretation of the object criterion. The judgment forms the basis of the

Commission’s stance for its exclusion of restrictions by object to its de minimis

thresholds in its revised De Minimis Notice. AG Kokott, whose opinion seems to

have influenced the CJEU, is wrong to state so categorically that if an agreement

with an anti-competitive object is capable of appreciably affecting trade between

Member States it can be inferred that the agreement is also capable of appreciably

restricting competition.152 At the very least, such inference must be rebuttable. It

is perhaps true that the effect on trade criteria demands lower thresholds to prove

an appreciable effect on trade and that it could be closely seen to mirror a form of

substantive analysis. That said such rationale undermines the determination of

restrictions by object. The judgment in Expedia gives a false impression that there

is a short cut to the more analytical approach advocated in STM and confirmed in

subsequent cases such as Allianz Hungária. There are indeed arguments in favour

of having a far lower de minimis threshold for restrictions by object, but that is not

150

Jones and Sufrin in the past argued that the Commission is more willing to accept that an agreement containing hardcore restraints may escape Article 101(1) TFEU on the ground that the agreement does not appreciably affect trade, (Jones & Sufrin, 2011), p177. 151

See eg Case C-56/65 STM; supra n6, Völk; (Jones & Sufrin, 2014), p183. 152

Supra n1, Expedia, opinion, para 57.

Page 229: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 228

to say that the consideration of appreciability is redundant. The treatment of the

de minimis doctrine by the CJEU in Expedia has been damaging and it is submitted

that, although AG Kokott makes salient points regarding infringements by object,

she ultimately would prefer to follow her normative vision of what constitutes the

object criterion rather than a faithful reading of the case law.

AG Kokott’s reasoning is flawed by her linking of the jurisdictional and substantive

elements of Article 101(1) TFEU. If she had simply concluded that the requirements

concerning proof of an appreciable restriction by object should be no more onerous

than the requirements for proof of an appreciable effect on trade, such reasoning

would have made more sense.153 In her attempt to simplify the law and to highlight

the distinction between restrictions by object and by effect she has, however,

evoked uncertainty. She by-passed the subtleties of the law regarding the object

criterion sketched out above. Certainly, the Commission believes that the CJEU

intended to reflect her opinion when stating that agreements that may affect trade

between Member States and that have as their object the restriction of

competition constitutes an appreciable restriction of competition.154

The conclusion drawn in this thesis is that the CJEU did not necessarily intend to be

contentious by changing the law. Notably, the CJEU continues to uphold the

requirement that restrictions by object must be “perceptible”.155 The Expedia

judgment has therefore not overturned Völk.156 Whether the effect on trade

analysis can satisfy the requirement for an appreciable restriction of competition by

object is unclear. The CJEU is not explicit enough in this regard.157 Instead, the

153

Ibid, para 56 of the opinion. 154

Ibid, para 37 of the judgment; revised De Minimis Notice, para 2. 155

Ibid, para 38 of the judgment. 156

Jones and Sufrin agree: (Jones & Sufrin, 2014), p228. 157

For instance it does not highlight the fact that under the object criterion appreciable effects need only be potential ones. It simply alludes to that fact: supra n1, Expedia, para 35.

Page 230: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 229

CJEU has succeeded in perpetuating confusion.158 This is exacerbated by its

subsequent and comprehensive judgment in Allianz Hungária.159

3. The impact of the MAAP on the objectives of Article 101 TFEU

3.1. Introduction

The judgment in Expedia raises a number of themes concerning the relationship

between the object criterion and particular elements of Article 101 TFEU as a

whole, such as the de minimis doctrine and the effect on trade criterion. These

features raise the broader question of the objectives of EU competition law. This

section examines how the object criterion, when interpreted in accordance with the

MAAP, complements the changing objectives of Article 101 TFEU. In particular, it

examines the close relationship between the object concept and the notion of a

‘restriction of competition’. This in turn enables the distinction between ‘object’

and ‘effect’ to be scrutinised. This section will demonstrate that the object

criterion is able to fit comfortably within the framework of Article 101 TFEU when

understood in accordance with the MAAP.

3.2. The objectives of Article 101 TFEU: what is a restriction of competition

According to Bork, it is not possible to “frame a coherent body of substantive rules”

until the goals of competition law are understood.160 He considers that competition

law policy cannot be understood unless we know what the normative purpose of

the law is.161 Bork’s point is pertinent, though would require an unchanging set of

aims.162 The history of the development of EU competition law reveals that the

goals of EU competition law vary over time and, in conjunction, there will continue

to be a body of substantive rules.163 More specifically, in relation to the object

158

Particularly as it does not adequately explain the leap between paragraphs 36 and 37 of its judgment in Expedia, if indeed there is an explanation. AG Kokott is more explicit in this regard (paras 54-57), but it is not certain the CJEU completely agreed with her analysis. 159

See Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária; cf supra n1, Expedia, paras 34-36. 160

(Bork, 1993), p50. 161

Ibid. 162

(Monti, 2007), p3. 163

Ibid.

Page 231: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 230

criterion, aside from the Commission’s stance in its Article 81(3) Guidelines, there is

no clear consensus from the European Courts as to the precise role of the object

concept. Despite this, the law relating to the object criterion has continued to

develop and evolve and, in the background, the objectives of EU competition law

have also changed, which in turn shape the direction of the law.164

This section is not concerned with undertaking an in depth investigation into the

goals of EU competition law. Rather, it seeks to gain a more basic understanding of

how the objectives behind Article 101 TFEU help shape the application and role of

the object criterion, as interpreted under the MAAP, when applying Article 101

TFEU to agreements. Such an exercise helps put the object concept into context

when assessing its pivotal role within Article 101 TFEU: the concept of object relates

directly to our understanding and assessment of what is a ‘restriction of

competition’. The power of the object concept to determine this therefore

depends largely on the characterisation of a ‘restriction of competition’. What

comprises a restriction of competition in turn depends on how the goals of EU

competition law are perceived. The goals and objectives of Article 101 TFEU have,

unsurprisingly, been the source of intense debate in recent years, particularly as a

result of modernisation.165

On a more practical level, the Commission is responsible for devising EU-wide

competition policy and polices its enforcement.166 Thus, the Commission has a

huge influence on the orientation of the EU’s competition policy and dictates its

enforcement priorities. Nonetheless, the European Courts have the ultimate power

in interpreting the law. As the Courts’ views on the objectives of EU Competition

law are not always consonant with those of the Commission, this creates tension.167

It has been argued that the European Courts have become less tolerant of the

Commission’s policy-driven approaches. Monti points out that policy can guide the

164

Ibid,p3. 165

See (Townley, 2011). Also, (Chirita, 2014). 166

This is achieved through its drafting of guidelines, notices and decisions etc. See Case C-344/98 Masterfoods v HB Icecream [2000] ECR I-11369; (Parret, 2010), p372. Also see (Monti, 2009), p16. 167

(Townley, 2011), p441. (Parret, 2010), p345.

Page 232: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 231

evolution of law, but only within reason.168 Furthermore, legal language cannot be

stretched so far as to deprive it of meaning in order to reach a desired end.169 This

proposition is particularly pertinent for the MAAP, which closely follows the

wording of the Treaty, and contradicts the orthodox approach, which imposes its

own extraneous meaning on the object criterion.

To understand what the main objectives of EU competition law are, it is necessary

to look at numerous sources, such as the treaties, legislation, jurisprudence as well

as policy documents.170 Motta asserts that the main objectives are “most probably

economic efficiency and European market integration”.171 Conversely, Monti

contends that the core values of EU competition law are market integration,

economic freedom and economic efficiency.172 These core values shift in

importance and interpretation over time depending on current influences such as

politics, economics and institutions.173 This assessment must be correct: the law

does not operate in a vacuum. A system of competition law naturally includes both

the law (that is, a body of legal rules and standards) and policy, which together

regulate and enforce EU competition law and ensure the maintenance of

competitive markets.174

What is understood to constitute the goals of EU competition policy also differs

depending on whether lawyers or economists are consulted.175 Consumer welfare

is now at the heart of competition law policy for the Commission,176 though the

CJEU still holds a torch for ordoliberal principles, public policy aspirations, and

market integration goals as demonstrated in cases such as GSK, Pierre Fabre and FA

168

(Monti, 2007), p43-44. 169

Ibid. 170

(Parret, 2010), p359; (Monti, 2009), p15. 171

(Motta, 2004), p15. See also (Parret, 2010), p341; (Nazzini, 2006), p504. 172

(Monti, 2007), pp51-52. 173

(Monti, 2007), pp1-6, 52 and (Parret, 2010). 174

(Parret, 2010), pp341, 352. 175

(Parret, 2010),345. (Townley, 2011), p441 who is particularly scathing of economist influence at DG Comp. 176

(Parret, 2010), pp357, 359. (Townley, 2011), p441. See Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 13 and 43.

Page 233: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 232

(Premier League).177 EU competition law and policy has moved towards a

neoclassical model and away from the maxim that every agreement that restricts

economic freedom is a restriction of competition.178 The current focus on the

economic concept of consumer welfare and economic efficiency (the effects-based

approach), has again recast the objectives of EU competition law.179 Hence, the

debate as to the objectives of Article 101 TFEU and the meaning of ‘competition’

remain.180

This serves to illustrate the shifting sands of EU competition law objectives.

Nevertheless, such objectives continue to be relevant in judgments, in particular, in

the context of determining an agreement’s object.181 The judgment in E.ON

Ruhrgas AG demonstrates how these objectives permeate the outcome of the case

law. In that case, the GC took account of its understanding of the Community’s

objectives when determining whether the object of an agreement was to share

markets.182 The Court referred to the CJEU’s desire to unite national markets in a

single market, which was an “essential object of the Treaty”.183 The object of the

agreement under scrutiny could not be said to be neutral as it was concluded at a

time when the liberalisation of the energy markets could be reasonably

envisaged.184 The judgment in E.ON Ruhrgas AG is a useful point of reference as it

not only depicts non-economic goals being considered by the GC within Article

101(1) TFEU, but evinces that the single market objective was taken to be part of

177

Joined Cases C-501/06 P, GSK, para 61-63; Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre; Joined Cases C-403 & 429/08 FA. (Parret, 2010), p347. The CJEU still talks about firms needing to independently determine their own commercial policy. See as an alternative example, supra n37, BIDS. Also (Conway, 2014), p517; (Gerard, 2013), section D, pp36-38. 178

(Monti, 2007), p52; (Parret, 2010), p349; Case C-309/99 Wouters. 179

See in particular Regulation 1, 2003 and the White Paper supporting it. For commentary on the potential conflict between consumer welfare and efficiency see (Parret, 2010), pp349-350, 361; (Townley, 2011), pp441-443. Townley refers to the DG COMP’s “blind fetishism with consumer welfare” owing to the rise in importance given to economic thinking and economists within the Commission, p441. 180

See (Monti, 2007), p51-52 and (Motta, 2004), pp1-17. Though see Articles 2 and 3 of the EC Treaty. Also, (Parret, 2010), p362; (Monti, 2009), p 14. 181

See also Case T-587/08, Fresh Del Monte Produce Inc v Commission, para 548; Case C-68/12 Protimonopolný, First and Second Questions. 182

Case T-360/09 E.ON Ruhrgas AG v Commission, 29 June 2012, nyr (E.ON). 183

Ibid, E.ON, para 146. 184

Ibid, para 148.

Page 234: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 233

the consideration of the ‘economic context’ of the agreement.185 Similarly, in BIDS

a deciding factor in the judgment was the freedom of the undertakings

independently to determine their own commercial policy.186

It is contended that the MAAP is far better placed than more formalistic

alternatives to react flexibly to such changing objectives of EU competition law, not

least changing policy objectives.187 As the object criterion is based on

understanding whether an agreement’s purpose is to restrict competition, this

enables considerations relating to competition law goals to be balanced within the

legal and economic context. For instance, the orthodox approach automatically

prohibits ATP, and conversely experience dictates the type of restriction

automatically condemned by object.188 Hence, in those cases where the CJEU has

found certain restraints justifiable or has newly found others to infringe Article

101(1) TFEU by object, they would be seen as anomalous.189 This is illustrated by

the Lundbeck decision where the Commission struggled to adapt the orthodox

approach to its changing policy objectives. Under the MAAP, however, specific

economic circumstances may justify such restraints and the agreement is not then

found to restrict competition by object.190 Conversely, the hybrid approach is

founded on categorisation based on experience (if the judgement in Cartes

Bancaires is believed) so is less able to accommodate the changing goals of

competition law than the MAAP, but unlike the orthodox approach, any

presumption of harm would be rebuttable within Article 101(1) TFEU.

185

Ibid, paras 138-148. 186

Supra n37, BIDS, paras 34, 36. 187

See (Andreangeli, 2011), p236: the “decisive question would be whether its ‘content and purpose’ are compatible with the objectives of Article 101 TFEU, that is, economic efficiency for the purpose of promoting consumer welfare and not whether they belong to a relatively formalistic category...”. 188

See chapter 1. 189

See eg, Case C-27/87 Louis Erauw. 190

Though that is not to say such arguments would necessarily succeed. See for instance the arguments made by the GC in Case T-168/01 GSK regarding the pharmaceutical industry and consumer welfare.

Page 235: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 234

3.2.1. Conclusion: the relationship between the object concept and restrictions of

competition

The MAAP is able to adapt to the changing objectives of EU competition law due to

the relationship between the object criterion and what constitutes a ‘restriction of

competition’. Like the objectives of EU competition law, what constitutes a

restriction of competition will evolve depending on the economics and political

influences present at a given time.191 Therefore, its meaning is heavily influenced

by the goals of EU competition law. The Treaty itself provides a list of examples of

‘restrictions’ in Article 101(1)(a)-(e) TFEU.192 Nazzini concludes that it means “anti-

competitive effects”.193 He finds that Article 101 TFEU “prohibits collusive

behaviour that reduces, or is likely to reduce, consumer welfare through restricting

output and raising prices or through partitioning the common market”.194 For

Monti, the evolving role of a ‘restriction of competition’ is evident as he believes it

has transformed from meaning a “substantial interference with economic freedom”

to a “restriction of economic freedom [that] now serves only to establish a

presumption that the agreement reduces efficiency to the detriment of consumers,

a presumption which can be aided when the firms have market power”.195 The

influence of economics on such an understanding of what constitutes a restriction

of competition is however questionable.196 Monti argues that following the

drafting of Article 101 TFEU a restriction of competition must have a non-economic

meaning as, if there is efficiency (as found under Article 101(3) TFEU), then there is

no restriction of competition.197

191

(King, 2011), p295. 192

As noted by (Deringer, 1968), ft 122; Chapter 2. 193

(Nazzini, 2006), ft 2. 194

(Nazzini, 2006), p506. Nazzini believes that the STM Test involves a balancing of welfare reducing and welfare-enhancing effects under Article 101(1) TFEU. 195

(Monti, 2007), p52. 196

(Monti, 2009), p13. 197

Ibid. See also (Townley, 2011), p443.

Page 236: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 235

So what does this mean for the object concept? Under the MAAP, if object is

understood as ‘purpose’ then it is well placed to adapt flexibly to whatever is

deemed to entail a restriction of competition.198 Such purpose is assessed within its

own particular context. The jurisprudence demonstrates that if a type of

agreement has been previously identified by the European Courts as being

restrictive by object this does not then denote that it will in future automatically be

found to contravene Article 101(1) TFEU. Moreover, both object and effect serve

the same purpose, to establish whether competition is restricted.199 This is

underpinned by STM which underlines how the elements share a basic

methodology.200 The orthodox approach, on the other hand, imparts less

significance to the notion of a ‘restriction of competition’.201 Instead, it is

constrained by the concept of necessary effect.202

It has been seen that the European Courts have expanded the object category, a

fact that undermines the rationale supporting the orthodox approach (the

contention that the category of agreements-by-object should be narrowly

construed). Furthermore, the CJEU often uses vague language when finding that

particular restrictions may restrict competition by object depending on the

circumstances of the case, particularly its legal and economic context.203 This also

challenges the straightforwardness of the orthodox approach on the basis that it

“eradicates the need to prove, at cost, the adverse consequences of provisions

which are in practice likely to lead to inefficiency and are unlikely to have any

198

Case C-56/65 STM. See also (Gerard, 2013), p14, though he argues that under the effects-based approach, which is premised on the need for tailored competitive analysis depending on the economic context of the case (such as the market) and the related market power of the parties, this reduces the value of the case-law as precedents as their value is constrained to their own set of facts. 199

(King, 2011), p274; for similar reasoning see (González, 2012), p10. 200

(King, 2011), p279. 201

See Case T-14/89 Montedipe SpA v Commission, para 265 and Case T-148/89 Tréfilunion v Commission, para 109. 202

See (Whish, 2009), p122: which agreements come within or outside the object box are dependent on the Courts (and indeed the Commission through its Guidelines). Whish recognised the object box requires “refinement” from time to time as its size and content is capable of change. This undermines its administrable benefits, particularly if the contents of the object box are unclear. 203

See eg, Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre.

Page 237: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 236

redeeming justification”.204 SA Binon is a good illustration of a case in which the

CJEU did not automatically link particular (hardcore) restrictions with the object

criterion, instead finding that certain provisions in an agreement simply amounted

to restrictions of competition.205 The Court held that provisions fixing prices

“constitute, of themselves, a restriction on competition”, particularly as these types

of agreement are listed in Article 101(1) TFEU.206 This cannot be interpreted to

mean the object criterion is synonymous with particular restraints.207

It is contended that the MAAP therefore makes better sense of the functioning of

Article 101(1) TFEU as a whole. If ‘object’ was used as a more limited analytical tool

when determining whether an agreement restricts competition by focusing on its

‘aim’ or ‘purpose’, then the ‘restriction of competition’ element of Article 101(1)

TFEU would more clearly centre around the examples in Article 101(1)(a) to (c)

TFEU as types of agreements that can harm competition. Included in such

definition of what constitutes a ‘restriction of competition’ are other restrictions

which the Courts have held to be ‘obvious’, ‘serious’ or indeed just ‘restrictions of

competition’, as well as novel types of restrictions. The object criterion would then

be used to clarify whether the agreement indeed has the aim or primary purpose to

restrict competition by, for example, fixing prices or sharing markets. The

agreement’s success in this regard is irrelevant as is its non-implementation.

Moreover, it is increasingly accepted that the object concept is not limited to an

object box: not every hardcore restriction will be a restriction of competition by

object and vice-versa.208 This establishes - in the case of hardcore restrictions in

particular - a rebuttable presumption of anti-competitiveness. The value of

categorisation is therefore questionable. For this reason, as with the orthodox

approach, the merits of the hybrid approach as a methodology are not promoted in

this thesis. What is needed is an alternative vision of the law. This is found in the

204

(Jones & Sufrin, 2014), p232. 205

Case C-243/83 SA Binon, [1985] ECR 2015. 206

Ibid, para 44. 207

See chapter 2. 208

See eg (Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind By Modernisation’, (González, 2012), (Whish & Bailey, 2012).

Page 238: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 237

MAAP. An interesting example where the MAAP could be more effectively

deployed is that of RPM. RPM is a form of vertical price fixing, which many

economists and lawyers believe should not be a restriction of Article 101(1) TFEU

per se.209 The orthodox approach risks over enforcement when it finds RPM is

always restrictive by object. It is not inconceivable that the MAAP (with its focus on

an agreement’s specific legal and economic context) could find that, despite

containing a form of RPM, an agreement does not have the precise purpose of

restricting competition. The agreement would then need to be considered under

‘effect’ to determine if it did in fact restrict competition to an appreciable extent.

In such a scenario, there is a possibility that either the agreement would be found

not to restrict competition by effect, or would be able to benefit from an exemption

under Article 101(3) TFEU.

4. The distinction between restrictions by object and by effect

With its focus on the legal and economic context an obvious criticism of the MAAP

is that the distinction between restrictions by object and by effect is ambiguous,

which thereby diminishes the role of ‘effect’.210 This criticism is seemingly

exacerbated by cases such as Allianz Hungária.211 It can be rejected, however, as

the research does not support such a criticism. Rather, understanding the object

concept in accordance with the MAAP enhances and explains the relationship

between the two substantive elements. They complement each other, and have

divergent roles in the determination of whether a given agreement restricts

competition.212

The roles of object and effect are thus distinct. The object concept looks to identify

whether the purpose, indeed the rationale behind the agreement, objectively

determined, is to restrict competition. The effect concept looks to confirm that an

agreement does in fact restrict competition (whether actually or potentially) if the

209

See (Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), p504. 210

See (Graham, 2013), ‘Comment on Allianz Hungária’; (Vedder, 2013). 211

Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária, where the CJEU referred to the need for an agreement to reveal a “sufficient degree of harm” when determining its object (paras 34-36). 212

See eg (González, 2012); (Kolstad, 2009).

Page 239: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 238

object of an agreement cannot be determined. Furthermore, under the MAAP, the

object criterion does not require the actual effects of the agreement to be

determined, which is not due only to the necessary consequence of the agreement,

but because the agreement aims to harm competition.213

Over time, many commentators have considered that it was only when determining

the effect of an agreement that the “whole economic context” need be taken into

account (that is, defining the relevant market and the parties’ positions on it, as

well as examine the counterfactual).214 From this perspective, it was unnecessary

when examining an agreement’s object to carry out such a detailed examination.

The Article 81(3) Guidelines, for example, are “unequivocal on the point”.215 This

has been proven to be inaccurate. That the initial assessment process for both

object and effect is similar under the MAAP is not to be seen as a flaw, but rather as

a positive factor. The MAAP raises the standard of proof on the part of the claimant

or regulator. This is crucial given the tendency for the Commission to frame all

Article 101(1) TFEU cases in object terms thereby exploiting the object concept to

avoid an in-depth effects analysis. That approach incontrovertibly does mean a

reduced role for ‘effect’.216 Moreover, the levels of fines imposed on undertakings

infringing Article 101(1) by object justify a more robust assessment under that

criterion.217 The decisive factor, however, is the re-emergence and

acknowledgment of STM as a leading case on the object concept.

From an economic perspective, it has been argued that the dividing line between

restrictions by object and restrictions by effect is whether restraints found in an

agreement can be “plausibly explained on efficiency grounds”.218 When

213

The analogy made by AG Kokott with risk offences is pertinent in this regard. 214

(Howard, 2009), p2. 215

Ibid. 216

The CJEU addressed this in Case C-67/13P Cartes Bancaires. 217

See (Killick & Berghe, 2010) for comments regarding the human rights aspect of the significant fines imposed by the Commission. For a discussion on the quasi-criminal nature of fines and the impact of the European Convention of Human Rights see (Wils, 2010) and (Forrester, 2010). See infra the concluding chapter of this thesis. 218

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), pp561-562. Cf (Nazzini, 2006), pp497-498. Nazzini sees the distinction as follows: the object criterion is either a presumption of anti-competitive effect or (in line with Odudu)

Page 240: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 239

determining an agreement’s object, the CJEU concentrates on whether an

agreement lacks redeeming virtues as opposed to its potential to restrict

competition.219 For Ibáñez Colomo, a given restraint will only restrict competition

by object where “it is not a plausible source of efficiency gains”.220 Utilising the

MAAP methodology, he argues that:

“The true question does not seem to be whether the restraint...can be presumed to have anti-competitive effects, or whether it bears a particular form; but whether, in the light of the nature of the agreement, and the context in which it is concluded, it is a convincing means to enhance efficiency and not simply a means to extract wealth from customers or suppliers...the crucial factor is not that the agreement can be presumed to deteriorate the conditions of competition on the relevant market(s), but the fact that it cannot be expected to improve them”.221

Therefore it is only where the particular restraint has “no redeeming virtues” (such

as naked price fixing) that ‘anti-competitive intent’ can be presumed.222 Hence,

where the agreement cannot be reasonably explained on efficiency grounds or

where, for example as in BIDS, there is no clear link between the efficiency claims

and the restraint, it can be assumed that the primary motivation of the parties is to

restrict competition.223 Ibáñez Colomo believes that the CJEU does not see the

notion of restriction by object as a presumption of the likely effects of the

agreement. Instead, the CJEU views the object concept as enabling the Court to

understand the agreement’s genesis, whereas the effect criterion establishes the

likely (negative) effects of an agreement on the market.224

This reasoning is persuasive and compliments the methodology of MAAP. The

economic arguments presented by Ibáñez Colomo are untested for the purposes of

this thesis, but the explanation is an interesting one and would seem to fit neatly

an objectively determined anti-competitive intention, whereas effect focuses on whether there are anti-competitive effects. 219

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), pp561-562. 220

Ibid, p549. Put differently, is it realistic to expect pro-competitive effects from the agreement in light of the context in which it is implemented. 221

Ibid, p549. 222

Ibid, p549. 223

Ibid, p549. 224

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘More on AG Wahl and restrictions of competition by object’.

Page 241: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 240

with the understanding of the law postulated herein. Ultimately, he finds that an

increase in market power is not determinative when assessing whether an

agreement restricts competition.225 He recognises that there is an innate flexibility

with which Article 101(1) TFEU has been interpreted.226 The crucial distinction in

the argument advanced in this thesis is that what is proffered is a legal explanation

as opposed to an economic one. First and foremost, judges apply the law, not a

series of economic models. In that vein, under the MAAP the object concept is

concerned with determining the agreement’s purpose in its legal and economic

context and the effect concept is concerned with its actual effect on competition.

In contrast, the orthodox approach makes little sense from an economic

perspective as it is unable to react to nuances or changing economic circumstances,

which is why an improved dichotomy is needed.227

It is therefore proposed that viewing the dichotomy in a different light is of more

benefit given the limitations of categorisation, its proven anomalies and the

prominence of the legal and economic context in any assessment by object. Using

the object criterion as a more powerful and flexible legal tool means that ‘effect’ is

reserved for those agreements that cannot truly be said to be restrictive by object

and therefore require a full market analysis in order to reveal their concrete

effects.228 The CJEU attempted to address the dichotomy in its judgment in Cartes

Bancaires.229 It appears that the CJEU wanted to reinforce the point that the object

concept is not a gateway to allow any type of coordination to be found restrictive

by object. Otherwise, “the Commission would be exempted from the obligation to

prove the actual effects on the market of agreements which are in no way

established to be, by their very nature, harmful to the proper functioning of normal

225

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), pp555-557. 226

Ibid, p562. 227

See the new De Minimis Guidance, section 1 where the Commission has attempted to respond to this. It describes the distinction between object and effect stating that it is unnecessary to demonstrate any actual or likely effects as restrictions by object are those that by their very nature have the potential to restrict competition. However it then concedes that in “exceptional cases” a restriction by object may be compatible with Article 101 TFEU because it is objectively necessary or protects a legitimate goal and thus falls outside Article 101 TFEU. 228

See Case C-67/13P Cartes Bancaires, para 58. 229

Ibid.

Page 242: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 241

competition”.230 To this end, the CJEU relied heavily on the concept of necessary

effect, but supported this with the requirement that such agreements must

demonstrate a “sufficient degree of harm to competition” determined in

accordance with the STM Test.231 Hence, the CJEU continues to keep the hybrid

approach alive.232

There is no doubt that the object concept should be interpreted restrictively.

Under the hybrid approach (as interpreted under Cartes Bancaires), this stems from

the concept of necessary effect. From the perspective of the MAAP, it is because

the agreement lacks the precise purpose to restrict competition. Moreover,

applying the STM Test ensures that an agreement’s context supports that

assessment, which - as the CJEU emphasises - must demonstrate a sufficient degree

of harm. It is submitted that if the CJEU insists on relying on STM, then it should do

so absolutely. STM does not support categorisation. The hypothesis that there

should be a narrow category of agreements restrictive by object is unworkable in

practice owing to the case law of the European Courts. This is exacerbated by the

CJEU’s continued use of nebulous wording.233 Instead, it is more prudent to work

with the case law than against it. Therefore the distinction between restrictions by

object and by effect needs to be recast as suggested under the MAAP.

Andreangeli uses the US antitrust rules to help demonstrate her explanation of the

dichotomy.234 As discussed in chapter 4, she postulates that the CJEU has moved

away from a stark distinction between infringements by object and by effect and

instead has embraced a concept of ‘restriction of competition’ that forms a

continuum or spectrum ranging from more serious to less obvious infringements.235

230

Ibid, para 58. 231

Ibid, para 49. 232

See eg supra n37 BIDS, para 17. The CJEU’s attempt to confine the application of object in Cartes Bancaires makes more sense if the orthodox is applied, so as to prevent the abuse of the object criterion by resource-stricken competition authorities. 233

The CJEU is fond of using words such as ‘may’ as opposed to definitive statements of intent, which therefore leaves room for interpretation. See eg supra n228 Cartes Bancaires, paras 49, 51. 234

(Andreangeli, 2011), pp242-243: the US Supreme Court has moved away from a sharp distinction between ‘per se’ and ‘rule of reason’ following its judgment in California Dental Association. 235

Ibid, pp236, 242-243.

Page 243: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 242

‘Serious’ restrictions refer presumably to hardcore restraints.236 The type of inquiry

would therefore depend on the nature and seriousness of the agreement in hand:

“the more serious the prima facie breach is, the more likely it will be for it to have

anti-competitive effects and, consequently, to justify ‘early antitrust intervention’

by way of the application of a presumption of anti-competitive impact”.237 The

position adopted herein is that the CJEU has always had an in-context approach to

the object criterion and has rarely been as formalistic as the Commission.

This leads to the following conclusion: the dichotomy between restrictions by

object and by effect does not encapsulate a stark distinction as proffered in ENS.

The case law is unequivocal on this point. Moreover, understanding the object

concept as applying to ‘serious’ restrictions, depends on how ‘serious’ is defined.

Andreangeli does not define ‘serious’, though she suggests that it encapsulates

more than classic ‘object box’ restrictions and uses the premise of ‘experience’ as a

guide. If the Courts were to adopt the MAAP as opposed to the currently favoured

hybrid approach, then there is better scope to utilise the object concept in a more

economically orientated way. Thus, serious restrictions would be those agreements

that aim to restrict competition ‘sufficiently deleteriously’, which are objectively

determined based on their content and context. Experience would continue to be

an important feature of such assessment, but would not be the only denominator.

The effect criterion would then ensure that those agreements that do not have

such an aim, but which in fact result in anti-competitive harm are also caught.

Moreover, the role of the object criterion is enhanced as it has the ability to cast

certain agreements outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether.238

236

See eg Case T-374/94 ENS [1998] ECR II-3141. 237

(Andreangeli, 2011), p238. 238

For instance, if the restriction is ancillary to a pro-competitive purpose, is objectively justified or the agreement pursues a legitimate objective.

Page 244: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 243

5. Article 101(3) TFEU: the legal exception

5.1. Introduction

The enhanced role envisaged for the object criterion under the MAAP in contrast to

its orthodox function raises questions regarding the impact on the scope of Article

101(3) TFEU.239 This section discusses the relationship between the object concept

and Article 101(3) TFEU, and the implications for Article 101(3) TFEU that would be

generated by the consistent application of MAAP. It may be that the application of

Article 101(3) TFEU would be reduced on account of two factors. On one hand, a

more thorough assessment of an agreement’s object would be undertaken within

Article 101(1) TFEU,240 while on the other hand, the object assessment may remove

agreements outside the remit of Article 101 TFEU altogether. However, this does

not mean the death of Article 101(3) TFEU, merely that the emphasis shifts back to

Article 101(1) TFEU as is proper following modernisation and in view of the

extensive case law adopting a more economic and analytical approach when

establishing whether an agreement restricts competition. Furthermore, the

application of Article 101(1) TFEU is more flexible than the more rigid provisions

requiring satisfaction under Article 101(3) TFEU: this is also exemplified by the

continued debate over whether aspects aside from economic arguments can be

considered under Article 101(3) TFEU.241

239

More significantly, Alexander Italianer also raised this question in relation to his understanding of the “sliding scale” approach in terms of the analysis undertaken under Article 101(1) being proportional to the seriousness of the restraint. He queried what impact such “continuum” approach would have on Article 101(3) as “Article 101(1) would probably find its mirror image when making the balancing in Article 101(3)”: (Italianer, 2013). 240

This could mean that arguments traditionally reserved for Article 101(3) TFEU are employed under Article 101(1) TFEU and therefore an agreement that may satisfy elements of Article 101(3) TFEU could potentially ensure a finding that an agreement does not restrict competition by object and therefore should be assessed by ‘effect’. The resultant impact on the availability of Article 101(3) TFEU should the agreement then be found to be restrictive by effect would be interesting in terms of whether more agreements traditionally seen to be restrictive by object could be exempted by Article 101(3) TFEU if they became ‘effect’ cases. A prime example of this is the decision in Visa International - MIF. This proposition would need to be tested further however. 241

See generally (Townley, 2009) and (Monti, 2002) on public policy considerations and Article 101(3) TFEU.

Page 245: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 244

5.2. The relationship between restrictions by object and Article 101(3) TFEU

Article 101(3) TFEU is the legal exception and allows for agreements found to be

restrictive of competition under Article 101(1) TFEU to be exempted on the grounds

such agreements satisfy four strict conditions. Historically, the role of applying

Article 101(3) TFEU was the exclusive preserve of the Commission, though the

burden of proof is placed on the defendant. This monopoly ended with the advent

of Regulation 1/2003. However, the legacy of Regulation 17 of 1962 still remains

given the continued existence of block exemption regulations (BERs) that fall within

the remit of Article 101(3) TFEU. Provided undertakings ensure their agreements

meet the conditions set out in the relevant BER such agreements are exempted

under Article 101(3) TFEU. Whether BERs should still be framed in terms of Article

101(3) TFEU post-modernisation is debatable in view of the increased economic

assessment of agreements under Article 101(1) TFEU. This is an important issue. If

the effects-based approach is truly adopted under Article 101(1) TFEU it is then

hard to reconcile the favourable economic arguments made in various BERs under

the umbrella of Article 101(3) TFEU, which would be better placed under Article

101(1) TFEU at the point of determining whether an agreement restricts

competition.242

It is well-documented that despite the availability of Article 101(3) TFEU for all

restrictions of competition by object, the truth of the matter is that agreements

containing such restrictions are rarely permitted.243 This is because such a strong

presumption has been created that agreements containing restrictions by object,

particularly hardcore restrictions, will not satisfy Article 101(3) TFEU.244 This is due

in part to the lack of availability of the BER’s for agreements containing ‘hardcore

242

This issue is outside the scope of this thesis, but is an area that would benefit from further research. 243

(Whish & Bailey, 2012), p153 citing T-17/93 Matra Hachette v Commission, para 85. Also see Case C-243/83 SA Binon, para 46; Joined Cases C-501 etc/06 P GSK, para 58; Joined Cases C-403 & 429/08 FA, para 145; Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre, para 49 where the availability of Article 101(3) TFEU for restrictions by object is made clear. Alexander Italianer also endorsed the position that “no restraint is ever necessarily and irretrievably unlawful, and that includes restrictions by object”: (Italianer, 2013). See below for further discussion. 244

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p669.

Page 246: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 245

restrictions’.245 More significantly, the advent of Regulation 1/2003 has

exacerbated this presumption: the exemption process was abolished, hence there

is scant jurisprudence providing clarification on when agreements containing

hardcore restraints will satisfy Article 101(3) TFEU. Moreover, the Commission has

not issued any non-infringement decisions since 2004, which it has the power to do

under Regulation 1/2003.246

The scope of Article 101(3) TFEU has also been narrowed by the Commission in its

Article 81(3) Guidelines. Jones contends that the Article 81(3) Guidelines

“significantly raised the bar for those seeking to rely on Article 101(3)”.247

According to the Commission, Article 101(3) TFEU is intended “to provide a legal

framework for the economic assessment of restrictive practices and not to allow

the application of the competition rules to be set aside because of political

considerations”.248 This exposes a tension with the jurisprudence interpreted by

scholars such as Monti and Townley.249

Therefore given the Commission’s clear message that agreements containing

hardcore restrictions are unlikely to satisfy the requirements of Article 101(3) TFEU

coupled with the lack of jurisprudence providing guidance on the application of the

provision, “firms have been unwilling to take the risk of inserting hardcore

restraints into agreements, especially as the consequences of getting the

assessment wrong might be a significant fine from the Commission or a NCA”.250

That the Commission finds few salvaging features for agreements containing

hardcore restrictions cannot be underestimated in terms of the impact this may

have on how undertakings conduct their business. In particular, to have to apply

245

See Jones, ibid, p669 and ft 109; (Bailey, 2012), p595 reiterates how the various BER’s state that severe restrictions are unlikely to fulfil the conditions of Article 101(3) TFEU, because hardcore restrictions rarely enhance efficiencies or benefit consumers and frequently are dispensable; also Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, para 47. 246

Article 10 of Regulation 1/2003. 247

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p669. See Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 51,52-59, 73, 83-104. 248

Ibid Jones, p669 citing Commission White Paper on Modernisation of the Rules Implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty [1999] OJ C132/1, para 57. 249

(Monti, 2002); (Townley, 2009). 250

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p670.

Page 247: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 246

Article 101(3) TFEU means that an agreement would have already been found to be

restrictive of competition. Hence, if the criteria under Article 101(3) are not

satisfied then undertakings cannot exclude the possibility that they may be heavily

fined.

To be able to conduct a wider ranging economic analysis of an agreement under

Article 101(1) TFEU in accordance with the MAAP could, therefore, be an attractive

alternative for businesses. Furthermore, as a result of applying the MAAP, aside

from a finding that the agreement is restrictive by object, the agreement will either

fall outside Article 101(1) TFEU entirely or be found not to restrict competition by

object and therefore be required to be assessed by its ‘effect’. Should the

agreement be deemed to be restrictive by effect, then the availability of an Article

101(3) exemption may not seem as unrealistic. The point is that, particularly owing

to the direction of recent case law confirming the application of a more in-depth

methodology when assessing the object criterion, the Commission must work

harder to discharge its burden of proof under Article 101(1) TFEU. It must look far

more closely at factors that it previously may have given scant attention to, such as

economic rationale and potential effects, or which it reserved for assessment under

Article 101(3) TFEU.251

Firms may therefore be inclined to take more commercial risk if they consider that

their agreements - which they genuinely believe do not aim to restrict competition,

but which under the orthodox approach may be seen automatically to restrict

competition by object - at least have a possibility of being considered only

restrictive by effect, if at all, when assessed in accordance with the MAAP. Given

the lack of case law concerning Article 101(3) TFEU, this could be an attractive

option.252 Despite the CJEU now being at pains to point out that restrictions by

object can benefit from Article 101(3) TFEU, until concrete judgments are handed

251

See eg Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária. 252

(Svetlicinii & Sad, 2011) make a similar point though argue the judgment in Pierre Fabre introduced a type of Article 101(3) assessment when determining whether the object of an agreement is to restrict competition under Article 101(1) TFEU. They argue this may help parties “seeking to exempt their otherwise ‘hardcore’ agreement at an early stage, before the full-scale uncertainty of the Article 101(3) TFEU assessment”.

Page 248: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 247

down there is little real certainty as to the availability of an Article 101(3) TFEU

exemption.253 Notably, the Commission, perhaps in recognition of the CJEU’s

stance, is modifying its tone on the availability of Article 101(3) TFEU.254

5.2.1. Application: division of labour between Articles 101(1) and (3) TFEU

For commentators such as Nicolaides, Article 101(3) TFEU permits only restrictions

that are necessary for the agreement to generate the claimed efficiency gains:

known as the indispensablilty requirement.255 Conversely, Article 101(1) TFEU:

“seeks to determine the overall, actual, potential and inter-temporal effect of an agreement on competition. By contrast...Article [101](3) asks whether an agreement with an overall anti-competitive effect should be allowed to go ahead, because it generates sufficient gains for consumers. In other words, Article [101](3) evaluates the desirability of the agreement from the point of view of consumers.”256

The tension between the acceptability of arguments under Articles 101(1) TFEU and

contrarily under Article 101(3) TFEU is not new. This was highlighted by Korah who

criticised the Commission for finding that restrictions were indispensable under

Article 101(3) TFEU, while considering them simultaneously to be restrictive of

competition under Article 101(1) TFEU.257 Therefore an agreement found to restrict

competition under Article 101(1) TFEU could be found to be lawful if the

“efficiencies relevant under Article 81(3) outweigh the negative effects the

restriction of competition has on competition and allocative efficiency”.258 Kolstad

calls it a “balancing test” as the allocative efficiency loss through reduced

competition must be quantified: by applying Article 101(3) TFEU it is therefore

253

See supra n37 BIDS. The case was remitted to the Irish High Court, but BIDS subsequently withdrew the claim for exemption under Article 101(3) TFEU. 254

See (Italianer, 2013). Though previous examples of the Commission’s tolerance of Article 101(3) TFEU arguments are the joint fixing of the price or the area of sale of a product manufactured through a joint venture, which is often seen to be indispensible to the functioning of the joint venture. Even the Commission in its decision in Visa International - MIF found that the agreement on MIF’s between acquitting banks and issuing banks was indispensable to the functioning of the Visa network. See (Nicolaides, 2005), p129. 255

Ibid, Nicolaides citing Case C-258/78 Nungesser. 256

Ibid, Nicolaides, p134. 257

Ibid, Nicolaides, pp139, 144. 258

(Kolstad, 2009), pp54-55, 54.

Page 249: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 248

necessary to assess the concrete effects on competition of agreements that restrict

competition by object.

This is a pertinent point: the apparent benefit of applying ‘object’ under Article

101(1) TFEU is that actual effects do not need to be demonstrated thus easing the

administrative burden and cost. The burden of proof is on the plaintiff, which is

usually the Commission. Conversely under Article 101(3) TFEU the burden of proof

is on the defendant. However, the Commission (or plaintiff) would still need

appropriately to consider economic arguments raised (it has been criticised by the

European Courts for not doing this in the past) by the defendant under Article

101(3) TFEU. Therefore, it is arguable that all the administrative savings made in a

finding of ‘by object’ under Article 101(1) TFEU would be lost. This would not apply

if the defendant chose not to seek exemption under Article 101(3) TFEU. If the

MAAP was applied under Article 101(1) TFEU, then it is debatable whether

defendants would still seek to apply Article 101(3) TFEU given that a form of

‘balancing’ has already occurred under Article 101(1) TFEU as economic arguments

are taken seriously. Article 101(3) TFEU could then be reserved for those cases

concerning arguments that are not necessarily as appropriately considered under

Article 101(1) TFEU.259 Ibáñez Colomo argues that despite the Commission’s prima

facie approach of rejecting non-economic considerations under Article 101(3) TFEU,

the very fact that the analytical framework revolves around efficiency means that

“the supposed peculiarities” of such situations are captured.260 This is because

consideration of non-economic factors can be seen as a proportionate response to

a particular market failure and therefore not to be in conflict with allocative

efficiency.261

It is submitted that applying the object criterion in accordance with MAAP would

help allay a number of criticisms raised, simply because there is scope better to

259

Such as social, political and environmental considerations. Cf AG Mazák in Case C-439/09 Pierre Fabre. The Commission may not view this as a sensible solution given its stance on Article 101(3) TFEU set out in its Article 81(3) Guidelines. 260

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), p561. 261

Ibid. Examples include environmental protection could be seen as a “reaction to the negative externalities generated by some economic activities”.

Page 250: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 249

consider economic arguments under Article 101(1) TFEU. Criticism levelled at the

Commission by scholars such as Korah was not misplaced when Article 101(1) TFEU

was formalistically applied to agreements which restricted commercial freedom.

However, with the more economics-based interpretation of Article 101(1) TFEU,

economic arguments historically considered by the Commission under Article

101(3) TFEU should instead be relevant and appraised under Article 101(1) TFEU.262

Another point of debate is whether the criteria in Article 101(3) TFEU are applied

more strictly to agreements found to be restrictive by object. Kolstad argues not.263

He recognises that it will be more difficult to prove that the Article 101(3) TFEU

criteria are satisfied in respect of restraints by object.264 This is evident as

agreements restricting competition by object generally have a greater potential for

anti-competitive harm, so will tend to be detrimental to competition.265 For this

reason, he argues that it would explain why agreements that restrict competition

by object will normally have little chance of realising the type of production

efficiencies needed under Article 101(3) TFEU.266 Moreover, as such agreements

have greater potential for anti-competitive harm as a result the efficiencies must be

rather substantial in order for the Article 101(3) TFEU criteria to be fulfilled.267

Therefore, it will only be in rare cases that agreements restricting competition by

object will satisfy Article 101(3) TFEU.268

This interpretation can be contrasted with the position adopted by Andreangeli.269

In her paper, Andreangeli assesses the consequences of her “continuum” approach

on the legal assessment of Article 101(3) TFEU. The outcome of her research

highlights the need for a different appraisal depending on the seriousness of the

262

For example see Ford/Volkswagen [1993], OJ L20/14. Here the Commission accepted that individually the parties could not act and that the agreement was necessary for the parties to manufacture a new car, but then went on to consider those arguments under Article 101(3) TFEU and granted an exemption: see (Nicolaides, 2005), p139. 263

(Kolstad, 2009), pp54-55. See (Andreangeli, 2011). 264

Ibid, Kolstad. 265

Ibid, Kolstad. 266

Ibid, Kolstad. 267

Ibid, Kolstad. 268

Ibid, Kolstad. 269

(Andreangeli, 2011), pp238-241.

Page 251: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 250

infringement under Article 101(1) TFEU. She recognises that the adoption by the

Courts of a more flexible and economics-based approach to Article 101(1) TFEU

raises issues for the scope of Article 101(3) TFEU and its application.270 Up until the

judgment in Metropole,271 she contends that the legal analysis under Article 101(1)

TFEU focused more formalistically by ascertaining if an agreement was restrictive

by reason of its object or effect rather than in accordance with her “continuum”

concept.272 The function of Article 101(3) TFEU here was to “gauge the extent to

which the practice, despite its harmfulness, nonetheless enhances the competitive

process. Gains in terms of ‘allocative’ as well as of ‘productive’ efficiency would

have to be taken into account and weighed against its anticompetitive effects”.273

For Andreangeli this traditional understanding of Article 101(3) TFEU does not

provide a complete picture.274 This is because Article 101(3) TFEU has been used to

consider objectives that are not plainly economic efficiency arguments. Townley

and Monti have both argued how other factors, such as environmental, social and

political issues, have played a part in exempting agreements under Article 101(3)

TFEU.275 In view of this, Andreangeli proposes a solution that depends on the

nature of the agreement in accordance with her continuum. Accordingly, she

differentiates the application of Article 101(3) TFEU between serious and less

serious breaches as opposed to by object and by effect infringements.276 For less

serious restraints, the role of Article 101(3) TFEU is limited to an inquiry into the

extent to which the practice furthers productive efficiency and seeks to achieve

270

Ibid, p238. 271

Case T-112/99, Métropole, paras 74-79. 272

(Andreangeli, 2011), p238. She contends the continuum means that instead of the Courts revolving around a formalistic dichotomy between by-object and by-effect infringements, it is now evolving towards a continuum between “nefarious” breaches and “less obvious” restrictions of competition under Article 101(1) TFEU. As a result the type of inquiry as to its impact on the market, that is whether the effects are presumed or have to be actually demonstrated and therefore its (il)legality, would have to be determined: pp239-240. 273

Ibid, p238. 274

Ibid, p239. 275

As demonstrated, inter alia, in Case C-67/96 Albany International and CECED (Commission Decision 2000/475/EEC). See also (Odudu, 2006), p160 who recognises this phenomenon, though does not agree with it as he considers goals other than efficiency are external to competition law; p174. 276

(Andreangeli, 2011), p239

Page 252: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 251

specific public policy goals.277 Given the ability for Article 101(1) TFEU to engage in,

as Andreangeli sees it, a limited degree of balancing for less serious restraints,

Article 101(3) TFEU would be confined to assessing the benefits of such agreements

for instance technological advancement or the ultimate goals of the Treaty, even

those “less obviously” economic in nature.278

Conversely, Andreangeli contends that if a restraint is found to be a serious one

under Article 101(1) TFEU, the prohibition clause must then consider a wider range

of issues than less obvious restraints.279 Not only would productive efficiency and

public policy arguments be assessed, but also any allocative efficiency benefits.

Thus such inquiry would look at any types of ‘gains’ arising from the agreement and

must therefore be viewed as more probing.280 Andreangeli dismisses criticism that

her approach would contradict the logic of her continuum, as her approach would

ostensibly demand a more in-depth inquiry into serious restrictions of competition

and vice versa for less serious restraints.281 Her justification is that the Commission

has argued that a “pressing justification” would be needed in order to apply Article

101(3) TFEU to serious infringements, hence the need for a more extensive inquiry

in those circumstances.282 Then for less serious infringements, given they would

have already been subjected to an in-depth assessment under Article 101(1) TFEU,

the focus on only public policy and productive efficiency-related objectives would

be justified. The fact such restraints were already subject to a probing analysis of

their actual effects under Article 101(1) TFEU means they would “be less likely to be

inconsistent with the objectives” of the EU competition regime.283

Andreangeli’s arguments have merit and are logical if the continuum approach is

supported.284 It is submitted that what Andreangli’s position underlines ultimately

277

Ibid, p240 referencing Odudu and Townley. Odudu contends that Article 101(3) TFEU concerns only a productive efficiency enquiry, (Odudu, 2006), p157. 278

(Andreangeli, 2011), p240. 279

Ibid. 280

Ibid. 281

Ibid, pp240-241. Also p226. 282

Ibid, p241 citing Visa International, paras 74 et seq. 283

Ibid, p241. 284

See chapter 4, section 4.

Page 253: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 252

is a simple point: that when applying Article 101(3) TFEU it is done on a case by case

basis, which mirrors the position of Article 101(1) TFEU as expressed in accordance

with the MAAP. The influence of considerations other than economic ones is not in

doubt and this thesis does not support Odudu’s pure economic interpretation, as

the case law does not uphold such an understanding. However, it seems rational

that the application of Article 101(3) TFEU to restrictions by object as understood in

accordance with MAAP should be more demanding or wider in scope depending on

the nature of the restraints. The case itself therefore determines the type of

enquiry needed under Article 101(3) TFEU.

As to the precise delineation between Articles 101(1) TFEU and 101(3) TFEU, the

following points can be considered.285 Given MAAP supports a raft of economic

arguments, including pro-competitive benefits of an agreement, it is difficult to see

what Article 101(3) TFEU could bring to the table. This is because agreements that

do fall foul of Article 101(1) TFEU when assessed under the MAAP and are found to

be restrictive by object must be serious indeed. Therefore an in-depth assessment

as postulated by Andeangeli for more serious restraints could be justified as it

would be difficult to see what other economic arguments could salvage the

agreement. As such, the focus on factors other than economic ones is a more

appealing role for Article 101(3) TFEU. The points raised by Kolstad ring true. If an

agreement is restrictive by object in accordance with MAAP it will be more difficult

to prove the Article 101(3) TFEU criteria. This is not to say, however, that economic

factors would not be pertinent under Article 101(3) TFEU, rather that the economic

benefits gauged thereunder would rarely, if ever, outweigh the harm on

competition. Hence, the delineation between Articles 101(1) and 101(3) TFEU will

arguably turn on the specific case in issue.

285

See Monti’s interpretation: (Monti, 2007), pp26-28.

Page 254: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 253

5.2.2. The practical implications and practice of applying Article 101(3) TFEU

It is notable, however, that the Commission has not always refused to exempt all

apparent hardcore restrictions from Article 101(3) TFEU.286 It is therefore possible

to envisage scenarios when Article 101(3) TFEU would be relevant. For example,

the Commission has been willing to exempt crisis cartels.287 More recently, the

CJEU was fairly encouraging about the use of Article 101(3) to justify a reduction in

capacity in order to rationalise the beef industry in Ireland.288 The Commission

submitted written observations to the Irish High Court regarding how it would

approach the restructuring under Article 101(3) TFEU.289 It would seem that the

Commission does support the idea that certain types of coordinated industry

reorganisation in particular markets could be capable of satisfying Article 101(3)

TFEU, and has provided limited guidance on how the requirements under Article

101(3) TFEU could be satisfied.290

The Commission has also been more lenient when regarding multilateral

interchange fees (MIF) for card payment systems. There were a number of cases

where, despite a finding that Article 101(1) had been infringed, the Commission

exempted the agreements.291 What is so interesting about MIF is that it relates to

horizontal pricing practices, usually an immediate classification of restriction by

object under the orthodox approach. Hence, it is an anomaly in the Commission’s

286

See (Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, pp668-675, 671 and (Bailey, 2012), pp593-598. Though contrast with the Article 81(3) Guidelines, which make crisis cartels harder to justify, ibid (Jones, 2010), p671. 287

Synthetic Fibres [1984] OJ L207/17. Though exempting crisis cartels have not been consistently supported by the Commission. Former Commissioner Neelie Kroes made clear that the Commission would not turn a blind eye to crisis cartels despite the financial crisis: (Kroes, 8 October 2009). Ibid, (Jones, 2010), ft 119. 288

Supra n37, BIDS. Even though the case was not ruled on by the Irish Supreme Court, it was clear the Court was favourably disposed to arguments in support of the crisis cartel under Article 101(3) TFEU and stated that providing precise estimates or calculations of efficiencies was not required. See also (Bailey, 2012), pp597-598. 289

Observations of the Commission under Article 15, para 3, of Regulation 1/2003, Case 2003 No.7764P. 290

(Bailey, 2012), pp597-598. 291

See eg Visa International - MIF [2002]; Reims II [1999]; CECED [1999]; Société Air France/Alitalia Linee Aeree Italiane, OJ 2004, L362/17 (paras 107, 132, 138-141). In CECED the Commission found that despite the agreement restricting output, it nonetheless helped promote the production of energy efficient washing machines, which benefited consumers and the environment generally. See also (Bailey, 2012), p596.

Page 255: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 254

enforcement and description of the object criterion under its Article 81(3)

Guidelines. The Commission’s position has now modified following its decision in

Mastercard, though in that case it could not quite bring itself to condemn the

agreement as restrictive by object despite clearly veering towards that conclusion,

and instead found the agreement was restrictive by effect.292 The Commission then

chose not to exempt the MIF, and subsequently brought proceedings against Visa

Europe.293

Examples of where the Courts have shown a willingness to exempt agreements

found to be restrictive by object by the Commission have included agreements

containing ATP, restraints on parallel trade and RPM provisions.294 Notably, the

Courts did not in fact exempt the agreements, but made clear that they were

capable of meeting the exemption criteria.295 The Courts have also been willing to

criticise the Commission for its application of Article 101(3) TFEU, even when it had

sole jurisdiction under pre-modernisation. In GSK, the GC criticised the Commission

for rejecting evidence and arguments that appeared to be credible and relevant.296

Overall, the “case law indicates that the parties must put forward convincing

evidence and arguments showing that the conditions of Article 101(3) are met”.297

The Commission has answered some of the criticism that it should move in line with

progressive economic thinking and recognise, for instance, that in certain

circumstances even hardcore restraints as being indispensible within the

parameters of a vertical arrangement.298 It therefore conceded in its 2010

Guidelines on Vertical Restraints that it would “assess substantiated efficiencies of

hardcore restraints against the negative impact under Article 101(3)”, and that in

292

Europay (Eurocard – Mastercard) [2009] OJ C264/8. 293

Visa Case COMP/39.398, decision 8 December 2010. Notably the parties in the Mastercard COMP/34.579 and Groupement des Bancaires COMP/38.606 decisions both appealed to the GC arguing the Commission had raised the evidential bar too high under Article 101(3) TFEU. See (Bailey, 2012), p593. 294

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, ft132 citing, inter alia, Joined Cases 56&58/64 Consten & Grundig; Case 30/78 Distillers Co Ltd v Commission [1980] ECR 2229. 295

Ibid, (Jones, 2010), p674. 296

Case T-168/01 GSK, paras 233-307. This point was upheld by the CJEU on appeal. 297

(Bailey, 2012), p594. 298

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Modernisation’, p674.

Page 256: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 255

particular circumstances parties could plead an efficiency defence to justify ATP and

price restraints.299 The Commission has even recognised the need for RPM for a

limited amount of time in order to introduce a new product to the market.300

However, the appropriateness of these concessions by the Commission under

Article 101(3) TFEU is questionable. Such arguments could also be made within the

legal and economic context. Moreover, real efficiencies brought about as a result

of an agreement cannot be said truly to be aimed at restricting competition within

the meaning of Article 101(1) TFEU.

5.2.3. A new order?

In his speech at the Fordham Competition Law Conference in September 2013, the

Director General for Competition, Alexander Italianer, gave an enlightening insight

into the Commission’s approach to the Article 101(1)/101(3) division.301 As well as

confirming that any restriction by object is never irretrievably unlawful nor the “end

of the story”, he highlighted what he considered was the important distinction

between Article 101(1) TFEU and Article 101(3) TFEU.302 He reiterated the standard

line that the contextual analysis under Article 101(1) TFEU for both object and

effect “never goes as far as balancing the anti- and pro-competitive effects. It only

aims at gauging the negative consequences of the restraint for the process of

competition...in other words, the analysis under Article 101(1) deals exclusively

with identifying competitive harm.”303 This means that “the balancing between

competitive harm and redeeming virtues is made exclusively under 101(3).”304 This

summation may not tally entirely with the evidence of what the Courts, let alone

the Commission, have considered within the legal and economic context under

Article 101(1) TFEU assessments. Nonetheless it is a salutary lesson in how the

Commission has not entirely moved on in its thinking, despite the significant

299

Ibid, (Jones, 2010), p674. Vertical Guidelines 2010, paras 60-4, 223-9. See generally (Bailey, 2012), p595. 300

Vertical Guidelines 2010, para 225. 301

(Italianer, 2013). 302

Ibid, p7. 303

Ibid, p7. 304

Ibid, p7.

Page 257: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 256

advances made by certain sectors of the Commission in its understanding of

restrictions by object.305

Italianer stressed how parties seeking to apply Article 101(3) TFEU need to provide

“sufficient and verifiable evidence that a restraint is ultimately pro-competitive and

beneficial for consumers.”306 He was at pains to point out how the availability of

Article 101(3) TFEU is not dead in respect of restrictions by object. He used the

decision in the Star Alliance case to highlight how restrictions by object may satisfy

the legal exemption.307 The decision involved an “innovation in the way [the

Commission] looks at efficiencies under Article 101(3)” as it accepted “out-of-

market efficiencies” for the first time.308 This means the Commission looked at

efficiencies generated on a market other than the market which entailed

competitive concerns. The Decision in Star Alliance broadens the general test set

out in the Article 81(3) Guidelines, though does not replace it.309 As a result of the

new test the Commission was able to allay its concerns over the negative effects to

consumers stemming from the cooperation between the airlines.310 For Italianer

this new test demonstrated how Article 101(3) TFEU is still alive and available to

restrictions by object and that the Commission is willing to review its policy under

Article 101(3) TFEU “where this is justified and appropriate”.311 This is positive, but

also highlights how undertakings are firing into the dark with efficiency arguments

as it is unlikely that the Commission will often be willing to change its policy, and it

does not specify the circumstances in which it will do so.312

Given the increased economic enlightenment of the Commission post-

modernisation, any concessions by the Commission are to be welcomed.

305

As demonstrated in Italianer’s speech, ibid, pp4–6. See also comments made regarding the decision in Lundbeck in chapter 1. Cf De Minimis Notice. 306

(Italianer, 2013), p7. This point is often made by the Courts too, but is ultimately unhelpful unless the Courts go out of their way to demonstrate how this could be achieved. 307

Ibid, p8. Continental/United/Lufthansa/Air Canada, 23 May 2013, COMP/AT.39595. 308

Ibid, p11. 309

Ibid, p11-12. 310

Ibid, p12, though for 5 out of 6 routes. 311

Ibid, p12. 312

Note that Star Alliance was ultimately a commitment decision. Also the Courts can now rule on how the Commission applies Article 101(3) TFEU.

Page 258: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 257

Moreover, some of the considerations that the Commission sees as belonging to

the realm of Article 101(3) TFEU assessments could, if not should, just as easily be

considered under Article 101(1) TFEU within the ‘legal and economic context’. It is

this proposition that gives rise to a certain panic amongst some commentators

regarding the death of Article 101(3) TFEU. Such worry is misplaced or, perhaps,

incorrectly elucidated. Moreover, it is unwarranted as Article 101(3) TFEU is highly

specific. That a more measured role for Article 101(3) TFEU might come about

cannot be a bad thing in view of the Commission’s previous monopoly over its

application. The function of Article 101(1) TFEU has evolved into a more

economically orientated provision and therefore it should be unsurprising if the

application of Article 101(3) TFEU were also to adapt in view of this. This does not

indicate the death of Article 101(3) TFEU, merely its reincarnation.

The precise role of Article 101(3) TFEU will continue to be debated. Arguments

regards ‘balancing’ have skewed matters: it is predominantly a labelling exercise as

it is unquestionable that the European Courts and indeed the Commission have

engaged in a form of balancing of effects under Article 101(1) TFEU.313 Overall,

opinions regarding the role of Article 101(3) TFEU are divided. For instance,

González claims the enquiry under Article 101(3) TFEU focuses on whether “the

agreement objectively produces pro-competitive benefits that outweigh its

(previously established) anti-competitive impact, and in light of which a general

exemption from the general prohibition can be obtained at all.”314 Odudu suggests

that Article 101(3) is concerned with productive efficiency whilst Townley and

Monti have argued that other non-competition factors have and should come into

play. Italianer is correct in the sense that Article 101(1) TFEU is concerned with

identifying restrictions of competition or as he puts it “competitive harm”.

A more pertinent question may be whether Article 101(3) TFEU is hampered by

what happens under Article 101(1) TFEU. It is not. Article 101(3) TFEU specifically

asks for positive factors to be demonstrated that would counter the negative

313

See Chapter 4 and (Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), p559. 314

(González, 2012), p8.

Page 259: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 258

finding under Article 101(1) TFEU. Article 101(1) TFEU, on the other hand, deals

with the determination of whether competition is restricted, which in itself may

require positive attributes of an agreement to be considered. That does not then

mean that similar or even the same arguments cannot be raised again under the

exemption provision if an agreement is found to be restrictive by object or effect.

Jones raises the point that despite the various gestures by the Commission towards

progressive economic thinking, the fact remains that there is insufficient guidance

as to when parties could be sure of raising a convincing efficiency argument and a

restraint be considered indispensable.315 This is the major hindrance to the

application of Article 101(3) TFEU. More importantly, in relation to the contentious

area of RPM, she considers that the structure of Article 101(3) TFEU does not allow

the argument that RPM imposed by a manufacturer lacking market power for the

purposes of increasing dealer services and sales would not cause anticompetitive

effects.316 This is because anticompetitive effects are already presumed under

Article 101(1) TFEU, though doubtless also because an agreement has already been

found to be restrictive by object or effect. This is why such economic arguments

are better utilised under Article 101(1) TFEU and why presumptions should be seen

to be rebuttable.

Overall, it remains a “daunting task” to justify an infringement by object on

efficiency grounds under Article 101(3) TFEU.317 The success rate for exempting

restrictions by object is pretty rare.318 Given that the Commission had a monopoly

over the application of Article 101(3) TFEU for so long, its legacy will be hard to

shift. Further, the Commission was able to mould its application as it desired. The

Commission does not have the same level of control over Article 101(1) TFEU.

Rather than rely on a judgment for clarification, Bailey observes that it would be

315

(Jones, 2010), ‘Left Behind by Competition’, p675. This position is also supported by (Bailey, 2012), p598. 316

Ibid, Jones, p675, citing Leegin, ft 139. 317

(Padilla, 2010); (Bailey, 2012), p585 quotes para 46 of the Article 81(3) Guidelines where the Commission highlight that severe restrictions of competition are unlikely to fulfil the conditions of Article 101(3) TFEU. 318

See (Bailey, 2012), p593.

Page 260: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 259

more useful for the Commission to adopt a decision under Article 10 of Regulation

1/2003, which would show how the criteria under Article 101(3) TFEU are satisfied

for different types of situation.319 This is unlikely to happen soon. Therefore any

clarification may be a long time coming.

5.3. Conclusion: the death of Article 101(3) TFEU?

The lack of clarity between the division of labour between paragraphs (1) and (3)

still rings true.320 That the bifurcation of Article 101 TFEU is the “original sin” of EU

competition law remains a valid point.321 As such, few may mourn the arguable

demise of Article 101(3) TFEU if the trend for object-only cases under Article 101(1)

TFEU continues in light of the Commission’s enforcement priorities.322 For authors

such as Ibáñez Colomo, the fact that balancing of the pro- and anti-competitive

effects of an agreement is conducted “in some form” under Article 101(1) TFEU

does not then mean that Article 101(3) TFEU is devoid of purpose.323 Contrast this

with the judgment in Métropole whereby the GC was categorical that it was only

within the framework of Article 101(3) TFEU that the pro- and anticompetitive

aspects of a restriction could be weighed.324 Otherwise, if such balancing were to

occur under Article 101(1) TFEU, Article 101(3) would lose much of its

effectiveness.325

Ibáñez Colomo believes that Article 101(3) TFEU allows undertakings to quantify

efficiency gains explicitly and to show that the agreement is pro-competitive on the

whole.326 This is in contrast to Article 101(1) TFEU where efficiency gains are not

expressly quantified. By this understanding of the relative scope of the two

provisions, one can see the arguments in favour of using Article 101(3) TFEU.

Ibáñez Colomo submits that Article 101(3) TFEU would come into its own where it is

319

Ibid, p598 320

(Odudu, 2006), p176. 321

Whish, panel discussion, 1998. 322

(Hawk, 1995), pp987-998 who argued the bifurcation of Article 101 “grossly complicates with little or no redeeming virtues, both the formulation and enforcement of specific rules”. 323

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), p559. 324

Case T-112/99 Métropole, para 74ff. 325

Ibid. See (González, 2012), pp6-8. 326

(Ibáñez Colomo, 2012), p559.

Page 261: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 260

necessary to quantify efficiency gains because an agreement “creates or

strengthens market power beyond a certain degree” or where the context in which

an agreement is concluded “suggests the negative impact on prices and output may

weigh more than the allocative efficiency gains achieved”.327 Alternatively, Article

101(3) TFEU would be a useful forum in which to investigate whether restraints go

beyond what is deemed necessary to achieve the gains identified.328

It is submitted that the greatest, albeit misplaced, concern is that Article 101(3)

TFEU will have no function if the assessment under Article 101(1) TFEU has a

greater emphasis on economic analysis. Moreover, the European Courts have been

accused of applying a light standard of review in respect of Article 101(3) TFEU,

because they consider it “too complex and abstract”.329 Arguably, this then aided

the Commission’s control over Article 101(3) TFEU. Perhaps more concerning are

different factors, which have impacted on the so-called demise of Article 101(3)

TFEU. Modernisation has meant that the Commission shifted its priorities to

serious infringements of competition, which tend to be those restrictive by object

in the context of Article 101(1) TFEU. La Madrid and Petit illustrate how this meant

cases where Article 101(3) TFEU would be more applicable were left to the NCAs

and national courts to determine.330 As a result, chiefly due to the difficulty and

uncertainty in applying Article 101(3) TFEU and the perception (amongst NCAs and

national courts in particular) that an effects-based assessment is only relevant in

‘effect’ cases under Article 101(1) TFEU, has meant that very few Article 101(3)

TFEU assessments are undertaken.

There is a greater problem. Not all NCAs and national courts have caught up with

the developments in the case law regarding the object criterion and instead rely

heavily on the Article 81(3) Guidelines, and thus on the orthodox approach. This is

evident in submissions made to the Community Courts and in national decisions.331

327

Ibid. 328

Ibid. Though this could potentially conflict with the application of MAAP in terms of the arguments raised about ancillary restraints. See chapter 4. 329

(La Madrid de Pablo & Petit, 2011). 330

Ibid. 331

See eg supra n37, BIDS.

Page 262: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 261

This indicates that developments in the application or understanding of the law

take time to “trickle down”, which could ultimately lead to a divided approach not

only to the object criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU, but also to the application of

Article 101(3) TFEU.332 This undermines the entire ethos behind the modernisation

process.

If the MAAP were consistently adopted by the Commission and European Courts

then some of the concerns should fall away. It is clear that arguments traditionally

reserved for Article 101(3) TFEU are relevant under Article 101(1) TFEU. This means

the role of Article 101(3) TFEU would need to adapt and evolve. By doing so its role

will become less vital if undertakings are able to come up with strong reasoning for

their ostensibly restrictive agreements under Article 101(1) TFEU. The uncertainties

surrounding the application of Article 101(3) TFEU would thereby be somewhat

alleviated and non-economic arguments could then play a clearer role.333 The

application of Article 101(3) TFEU would therefore be seen to be case specific. It is

thus apparent there is no perfect answer to the bi-furcation of Articles 101(1) and

101(3) TFEU and the division of labour. However using the MAAP is one solution

that is able to address the concerns facing Article 101 TFEU.

Overall, this chapter demonstrates that the MAAP, despite its shortcomings, makes

better sense of our understanding of Article 101 TFEU as a whole within a

modernised EU. This is due to a number of factors, including in particular the

legitimacy it derives from the case law of the CJEU. Furthermore, it is more

adaptable to the general trend for an ‘effects-based’ approach to Article 101 TFEU

and is able to respond to the need for deeper economic assessment where

required, as it is not constrained by categorisation. As such, the MAAP is a flexible

legal tool that is able to react to economic developments and fits intelligently

within the framework of Article 101 TFEU as a whole.

332

Not aided by the distinct lack of decisional guidance on its application by both the Commission and European Courts. 333

See eg (Hawk, 1995), pp987-988.

Page 263: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 262

Conclusion: The function of the object criterion under Article 101(1)

TFEU

1. Introduction

This thesis established the legal essence of the object criterion under Article 101(1)

TFEU based on a careful assessment of the jurisprudence of the European Courts.

Consequently, it found that the Commission’s approach to restrictions by object set

out in its Article 81(3) Guidelines does not fully reflect the case law. Instead, the

analysis of the case law revealed three key tests that the Courts have applied to

assess the object of an agreement, namely:

1. The orthodox approach: a class or category of agreements that by ‘their very nature’ restrict competition.1 There is an irrebuttable legal presumption that those types of agreements automatically harm competition and thus infringe Article 101(1) TFEU given their serious nature.

2. The more analytical approach: focuses on whether the aim or purpose of the agreement is to restrict competition determined in its legal and economic context.2 Ostensibly any restriction of competition could therefore have the object of restricting competition under Article 101(1) TFEU.

3. The hybrid approach: a combination of the orthodox approach and the MAAP. The concept of object is still limited to those restrictions that by ‘their very nature’ restrict competition, but the agreement is assessed in its ‘legal and economic context’ in accordance with the STM Test.3 As such, the legal presumption of harm is apparently rebuttable under Article 101(1) TFEU.

It was shown how the case law falls in to one of these three approaches, though the

precise parameters of these approaches are not stark. Chapter 1 focused on the

orthodox approach, whereas chapter 2 found that historically the jurisprudence

predominantly supports the MAAP and that a hybrid approach has also evolved.

1 Joined Cases T-374, 385, 384 & 388/94 ENS [1998] ECR II-3141.

2 Case C-56/65 STM [1966] ECR 249.

3 Case C-209/07 BIDS [2008] ECR I-8637; Case C-8/08 T-Mobile [2009] ECR I-4529; Joined Cases C-

501, 513, 515, 519/06P GSK [2009] ECR I-9291. See chapter 2, section 2.1.

Page 264: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 263

Chapters 3 and 4 probed the features comprising the legal structure of the object

criterion in more depth in order to reveal its true meaning and application. By

reference to the case law, the best interpretation of the object criterion was found

to be that which accords with the MAAP. The implications of adopting the MAAP

for Article 101 TFEU as a whole were also considered. It was found that the MAAP

fits comfortably within the framework of Article 101 TFEU: it helps make sense of

the wording of Article 101 TFEU, is able to adapt to the changing objectives of EU

competition law and so is compatible with a move towards an effects-based

approach.

However the story of the object criterion does not end there. The practical

implications of this research bear some reflection. It has been shown that the

Commission applies the object criterion irrationally. Together, the Commission and

the European Courts have produced anomalous decisions and judgments that have

little resemblance to the outcome predicted under the orthodox approach set out

in the Article 81(3) Guidelines. The Commission’s decisional practice demonstrates

that it sometimes treats similar cases differently using diverse reasoning. Hence,

there is an inequality between the cases.4 The orthodox approach is thus not

strictly followed, nor indeed overwhelmingly supported, by the law. This creates a

tension between the case law, the Commission’s decisional practice and its

guidance.

This thesis addresses this tension by highlighting the availability of an alternative

approach to the object criterion supported by the case law: the MAAP. That

approach accurately reflects not only the meaning and application of the law

ascribed by the leading case, STM, but also explains how the context of a particular

case may generate a different outcome from that predicted under the orthodox

approach.

4 For example the Visa and Mastercard decisions: see Chapter 1. See also (Gerard, 2013), p30.

Page 265: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 264

Nonetheless, the practical consequence of the status quo is that the Court and

indeed the Commission are currently applying versions of the hybrid approach.5

The hybrid approach recognises the categorisation of object agreements, but

focuses on a contextual analysis which permits any presumption of harm to be

rebutted within Article 101(1) TFEU. It is therefore constrained by categorisation in

the same way as the orthodox approach, and has the propensity to be expanded by

the Courts or indeed by the Commission in its Guidelines and BERs.

The problem with this apparent resolution is that despite enjoying better judicial

support than the orthodox approach, the hybrid approach is not accurately

reflected within the Article 81(3) Guidelines.6 Hence, the legal application of the

category of object agreements is inconsistent. Moreover, the practical limitations

of having a category of agreements that are restrictive by object has been shown to

be problematic given the difficulties with object classification and the increasing

expansion of the so-called ‘object box’. The impact that this status quo has on

NCAs and NC’s, and indeed on undertakings, is a live issue.7 This is particularly the

case in view of the recent appeal of the Lundbeck decision and the subsequent

warning call issued by the CJEU in Cartes Bancaires coupled with the requirement of

consistency under Regulation 1/2003.8 This situation is unacceptable. A key

question is therefore how best to move forward from this point.

One way would be to explore more closely the optimum function of the object

criterion under Article 101(1) TFEU.9 What the function of the object criterion

5 Note that within the Commission itself are tensions between how the Legal Service and DG

Competition interpret the law: compare (Italianer, 2013) against the revised De Minimis Guidance. 6 For instance, assessing an agreement within its legal and economic context is not optional, but a

mandatory requirement, which means presumptions of harm are capable of rebuttal within Article 101(1) TFEU. 7 Particularly following the judgment in Case C-226/11, Expedia, 13 December 2012, nyr. The NCA’s

and NC’s have an apparently impossible task of giving regard to the Commission’s guidelines and decisional practice as well as the case law. 8 Recital 8 of Regulation 1/2003. The appeals in Lundbeck seek to remedy the errors in the

Commission's decision including the misinterpretation of the object criterion and the imposition of fines on the parties despite the novelty of the factual and legal issues raised in the case, which violates the principle of legal certainty. See eg 2013/C 325/71 (Case T-460/13 Ranbaxy v Commission); 2013/C 325/74 (Case T-470/13). Case C-491/07 Cartes Bancaires, 11 September, nyr. 9 There are in fact a number of important areas stemming from the status quo that would benefit

from further research. See infra ft 61.

Page 266: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 265

ought to be can be approached in a number of ways. For instance, it could be

assessed from the perspective of what makes good law or from the angle of

effective enforcement. It is an important normative question. It has been argued

that within the constraints of the law, the MAAP provides a workable solution that

is able to overcome anomalous case law, developments in economic thinking,

whilst still respecting presumptions of harm and raising the standard of proof.

Nevertheless, having articulated the law and proposed that the MAAP is the best

legal interpretation, a key factor is whether this outcome is then compatible with

the object concept’s optimum function. If not, in light of that function, which of the

three tests fits best?

For the purposes of this concluding chapter, the role that the object criterion ought

to play from an enforcement perspective has been selected.10 How the object

concept could be used as a tool for effective enforcement is a pressing issue given

the limited resources of competition authorities throughout the EU.11 This

concluding chapter therefore provides an outline of whether the optimum role of

the object criterion is indeed best served by the MAAP from an enforcement

perspective. While the advantages of the MAAP have been advocated throughout

this thesis, it does have some weaknesses. It is susceptible to the criticism that it

blurs the line between object and effect and increases the administrative burden in

terms of enforcement costs, resources and time. Conversely, its application

reduces Type I and II errors; it follows the wording of the Treaty and is supported by

the case law. In particular, it applies the STM Test and hence is not constrained by

the problems with categorisation. The following sections will address, first, the role

ascribed to the object criterion by the Commission and the Courts, and then

consider what function it ought to play in that light.

10

Due to the constraints of space, this concluding chapter provides only an outline of that function and would therefore benefit from further research. 11

See also Kirchner, Future Competition Law in (Ehlermann & Laudati, 1998) ,pp513–523. Also within the same text, Panel Discussion (1998) Future Competition Law. Also (Motta, 2004).

Page 267: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 266

2. The role of the object criterion: Commission and Courts

The role the object concept plays within Article 101(1) TFEU has been threaded

throughout this research.12 According to the Article 81(3) Guidelines, the

Commission bases its view of the object criterion on the concept of necessary

effect; restrictions of competition by object are deemed those that by their very

nature have the potential to restrict competition given their known negative effects

on competition.13 Hence, there is no requirement to demonstrate actual effects

given the legal presumption that a category of particular restraints always harm

competition.14 Merely identifying a particular restraint in an agreement is

ostensibly all that is required. This view is comparable with the speed limit analogy.

This thesis has been critical of this view in light of the case law.15

The CJEU on the other hand has been less transparent regarding its perception of

object’s role.16 Despite setting out its interpretation of the distinction between

object and effect in BIDS, it was not until its judgment in Cartes Bancaires that it

revealed that such belief is based largely on the hypothesis that experience shows

that certain types of collusion harm competition.17 Nevertheless, it has not

12

For instance, when considering the relationship between object and effect in chapter 5 and the definition of object of chapter 3. 13

Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 20-21. It has been noted that the use of the phrase ‘by its very nature’ is problematic as it has rarely been defined, for instance, does it mean the rationale of the agreement or presumption of effects. 14

Article 81(3) Guidelines, paras 20-21. This view is endorsed by AG Cruz Villalón in Case C-32/11 Allianz Hungária, para 65. 15

Ibáñez Colomo claims the notion that the object category captures agreements that can be presumed to have anticompetitive effects is problematic, because it contradicts the principle that an agreement may restrict competition by object irrespective of the effects it produces: there is a distinction between assessing the nature of an agreement (that is its rationale) versus assessing its effects: (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘Chapeau bas, Prof Wahl!’ and (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘More on AG Wahl’. 16

Though the AG’s have been more forthcoming: see AG’s Kokott and Trstenjak in T-Mobile and BIDS (supra n3). Both AG’s likened the object criterion to an inchoate/risk offence. NB: an inchoate offence is a criminal offence whereby an action or agreement prepares for an even bigger infringement. Thus a substantive offence may not have come to completion, but nevertheless an offence has been committed because the actions or agreements are in preparation for the substantive offence. 17

Case C-491/07 Cartes Bancaires, 11 September 2014, nyr, paras 50-52, 58. Bailey suggests experience is derived from economic theory, empirical research, comparative experience and policy judgment: (Bailey, 2012), p565. The Commission has, however, interpreted the judgment to mean that novel restrictions can still be found restrictive by object, but that a deeper assessment of an agreement’s legal and economic is needed: (Italianer, 10 December 2014).

Page 268: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 267

expanded upon the precise parameters of such a category, merely concluding that

the types of agreement covered by Article 101(1) TFEU do not constitute an

exhaustive list of prohibited collusion.18 This thesis has also raised concerns with

this interpretation of the law.19 As to determine whether such collusion “reveals a

sufficient degree of harm” requires an examination of the “objectives” of the

agreement based on its content and its legal and economic context.20

The reliance on categorisation may prove desirable from a normative perspective,

but in light of the jurisprudence it has proved problematic. The contents of the

category have proved fluid. The case law demonstrates that the types of hardcore

restraint identified by the Commission in its Article 81(3) Guidelines have not

always been found to be restrictive by object by either the Courts or the

Commission. Conversely, agreements not typically seen as hardcore have been

found to restrict competition by object. The jurisprudence thus limits the

effectiveness of categorisation, which in turn undermines the value of precedent

and reduces legal certainty.21 The rebuttal mechanism afforded by the application

of the legal and economic context strengthens this assessment.22 In light of the

case law, it is questionable whether categorisation is workable from an

enforcement perspective.

3. The ought question: effective enforcement

Numerous commentators have proffered views on what function the object

criterion ought to play within Article 101(1) TFEU.23 A popular view that supports

18

Ibid, Cartes Bancaires, para 58. It is unclear whether the CJEU refers to formal categories such as price-fixing or market sharing or agreements based on experience and economic analysis. 19

For instance, categorisation ignores factors such as an assessment under the object criterion can result in an agreement coming outside Article 101(1) TFEU altogether. An interesting discussion on this issue took place in the comments section of the ‘chillingcompetition’ blog (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘Chapeau-bas Prof Wahl’. 20

Supra n17, Cartes Bancaires, para 53. 21

The jurisprudence also shows that not all object cases are ‘obvious’ or ‘serious’ (depending on its definition). See (Gerard, 2013), pp29-32 for an informed discussion. 22

Though the legal and economic context is not just concerned with rebutting any presumptions of harm: see chapters 3 and 4. 23

Such as, (Gerard, 2013); (Bennett & Collins, 2010); (Bailey, 2012), p562-570; (Kolstad, 2009); (King, 2011), p270. Howard asks “Is the object test an anachronistic legalistic device to facilitate the evidential burden on claimants and prosecutors who have asymmetric information and limited

Page 269: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 268

the orthodox approach is that the object concept should be based on a narrow

category of agreements presumed to restrict competition by their very nature due

to their known serious harm to competition.24 What is more, disregarding the need

for a deep contextual analysis under the object criterion is convenient for bringing

prosecutions with limited administrative resources.25 It is clear, however, that the

Article 81(3) Guidelines do not reflect the reality of the case law, which shows that

object and effect are not quite so disparate. Furthermore, increasingly

sophisticated business relationships mean “plain vanilla cartels” are no longer the

norm.26 For example, price fixing and market sharing arrangements often form part

of vertical relationships between non-competitors. Therefore, using such labels to

conclude that a particular collusion is restrictive by object is overly simplistic as

there may well be wider commercial reasons for sharing information or allocating

areas of responsibility between business partners.27 Moreover the outcome of

“complex collaborative arrangements [between businesses]...has become

increasingly difficult to predict.”28 The crux is that businesses need to be able to

innovate, and if strait-jacketed into a constrained category then the concern is they

will be more reluctant to do so.29 Moreover, the objectives of competition law also

come into play: what the law is seeking to protect may influence how the function

of the object criterion is perceived. Whether effective enforcement is a greater

priority than commercial freedom is moot.30

Additionally, it may be that application of the object criterion should be compatible

with the burden and standard of proof required in quasi-criminal proceedings by

resources? Or does it still serve a useful purpose in securing infringements that are clearly motivated by anti-competitive intent, even if they are inchoate and may only amount to an attempted infringement?”: (Howard, 2009). 24

See (Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), pp131-156. Such application of the law may generate Type I errors, but is arguably justifiable given the serious harm such restrictions cause. 25

See (Howard, 2009). 26

(Howard, 2009). 27

Ibid. See also (Ibáñez Colomo, 2014), ‘Chapeau-bas Prof Wahl’, who considers such labels are arbitrary. 28

(Gerard, 2013), p30. 29

The nature of global markets and ability for companies to compete on a level playing field is important in this regard. 30

The advent of the effects-based approach recognised the importance of commercial transactions and the benefit of economic analysis to determine whether an agreement did indeed harm competition.

Page 270: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 269

the European Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental

Freedoms 1950:

“If the law presumes that certain types of behaviour amount to a per se infringement with limited room for objective justification there are nagging doubts about the respect for the presumption of innocence and the right to a full hearing under art 6 of the Convention”.31

In view of the serious level of fines that can be imposed on undertakings that

infringe the competition rules coupled with criminal sanctions imposed in some

Member States, competition law is seen by some to be of a criminal nature.32

Notable also is the fact that the shifting landscape of enforcement has led to an

increased emphasis on negotiated procedures such as leniency, settlement and

commitments (which perhaps do not respond so well to concrete by-object

categories). In light of this, the consequences of infringing Article 101(1) TFEU and

the enforcement and procedural mechanisms in place to support such findings are

of crucial significance. The role of the object criterion is a central part of this

process.

3.1. How the object criterion should be delineated: criticising the effects-based

approach

Having set out the features that influence the background to the normative

question, this section sketches out those factors that make for effective

enforcement. Cost-benefits are clearly important in this regard: if a particular

agreement of a type is very rarely beneficial, it may not be worth incurring the

enforcement costs needed to identify them.33 One rationale for an easily

identifiable object category that operates in relation to only the most serious

infringements, which experience shows display significant harm to consumers and

31

(Howard, 2009). Though in the UK, the Competition Appeal Tribunal held that the Human Rights Act 1998 does not require the criminal standard of proof ‘beyond all reasonable doubt’ to be applied, rather the civil standard ‘balance of probabilities’, though the imposition of a fine would increase the standard of proof: (Whish & Bailey, 2012), p400 citing Napp Pharmaceutical Holdings Ltd v Director General of Fair Trading, Case No 1000/1/1/01 [2002] Cat 1. 32

(Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), p137; cf (Forrester, 2010). 33

(Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), pp152-157; (Posner, 2001), (ix); (Bailey, 2012), pp562-570.

Page 271: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 270

can be presumed illegal, is that it reduces the costs of enforcement and increases

legal certainty.34 It is an administrable approach as actual effects are not required

to be proven and increases the deterrence factor.35 Waelbroeck and Slater argue

that strong presumptions of harm based on past experience justify the reversal of

the presumption of innocence.36

Conversely, such an approach can be heavily criticised as being liable to generate

errors of all types and is unable to deal with the greater sophistication of the

competitive analysis of agreements.37 Hence, the introduction of the effects-based

approach to EU competition law sought to redress this by increasing the

effectiveness of competition law and thus its predictability.38 This move was

captured under the guise of modernisation.39

An effects-based approach to the object concept under Article 101(1) TFEU does

have its opponents.40 This is because it “reduces the precedential value of

decisions which, combined with a scarcity thereof and the parallel development of

negotiated procedures, tends to reduce legal certainty and to compel businesses of

relying increasingly on abstract categories and guidance.”41 The effects-based

approach also increases enforcement costs for both the authorities and

companies.42

34

(Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), p151. Such category must be narrowly defined based on solid empirical and theoretical foundations so that it provides the requisite level of predictability to justify the imposition of criminal sanctions; pp152-156. 35

(Bailey, 2012), 568-570. Ibid, Waelbroeck and Slater argue that a presumption of culpability resulting from the categorisation of a restriction of competition by object is acceptable, so long as it is confined within very strict limits. 36

(Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), p156. 37

See (Hawk, 1995). This is coupled with the question whether cost benefits should trump the burden of proof. Given the tendency for a per se system to generate false positives, how this can then be reconciled with basic civil rights to property and contract requires reflection. 38

See (Gerard, 2013), p20 for an explanation of the meaning of ‘effect-based approach’ and pp33-35. The Nobel prize winning economist Jean Tirole argued, “The best regulation or competition policy should… be carefully adapted to every industry’s specific conditions.” http://www.globaleconomicsgroup.com/antitrustcompetition-policy/a-tribute-to-jean-tirole-winner-of-the-2014-nobel-prize-in-economic-science/#sthash.WBoZJaxb.vNJ2lD67.dpuf 39

Regulation 1/2003. 40

See (Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013); (Gerard, 2013). 41

(Gerard, 2013), pp13-14 42

(Gerard, 2013), p13.

Page 272: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 271

The benefit of having a strictly enforced, narrowly defined object category is not in

doubt, but it raises the prospect of whether it is at all workable in practice. Legal

certainty is not improved by anomalous case law or exceptions. It is widely

acknowledged that under specific market conditions even the most serious

restrictions may be harmless.43 Therefore, looking to the experience in the US may

provide a useful example of the operation of such a system in practice.

3.1.1. US per se offences: s.1 Sherman Act

As previously stated, under the Sherman Act 1890, the American antitrust law

system makes unequivocal use of presumptions in its set of ‘per se rules’. These

rules allow the US courts to rule on the illegality of certain practices, which prima

facie satisfy the conditions required by such rules without recourse to a detailed

examination of all the relevant facts.44 Moreover, where there is a per se

infringement then the parties cannot argue that it does not restrict competition.

This is because, US law has determined that a small, limited category of agreements

automatically restrict competition and the parties cannot argue the contrary.45 As

such, all that the plaintiff need prove is that the prohibited practice occurred.

This system is not mirrored under EU law.46 Hence analogies between the US per

se/rule of reason and the EU object/effect dichotomy are inappropriate and tend to

breed confusion.47 What is perhaps more appropriate is the increasing recognition

that the US has moved away from a bright line distinction between per se and rule

of reason infringements toward one which is tailored to the suspect conduct in

each case.48 The Supreme Court held in California Dental Association that both

43

(Waelbroeck & Slater, 2013), p146. 44

(Svetlicinii, 2008), pp117-134, 122(C). 45

(Bailey, 2010), p363, II, 2. 46

Restrictions by object may be exempted under Article 101(3) TFEU and the analysis of an agreement’s legal and economic context can rebut any presumptions of anti-competitiveness. Marquis argues that “the competition law systems in the EU and US may circle each other in their orbits, but they remain separate worlds”, (Marquis, 2007), p46. 47

See (Goyder, 2011), p7. 48

Citing California Dental Association, Andeangeli also acknowledges that the US Supreme Court has moved away from a stark distinction between ‘per se’ and ‘rule of reason’ infringements to that of a continuum whereby the inquiry for a particular practice is determined in light of its nature and seriousness, (Andreangeli, 2011), p243. Jones reaches a similar conclusion, (Jones, 2010), ‘Left

Page 273: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 272

elements consisted of the same type of appraisal focusing on the “competitive

significance of the restraint” and how each case was assessed depended on the

case itself:49

“The truth is that our categories of analysis of anticompetitive effect are less fixed than terms like ‘per se’, ‘quick look’ and ‘rule of reason’ tend to make them appear. We have recognized, for example, that ‘there is often no bright line separating per se from Rule of Reason analysis,’ since ‘considerable enquiry into market conditions’ may be required before the application of any so-called ‘per se’ condemnation is justified. (...) As the circumstances here demonstrate, there is generally no categorical line to be drawn between restraints that give rise to an intuitively obvious inference of anticompetitive effect and those that call for more detailed treatment. What is required, rather, is an enquiry meet for the case, looking to the circumstances, details and logic of a restraint.”50

As with the development of the case law in the EU, in the US an agreement’s

context plays an important role. The developments in the US thus highlight how a

system specifically devised to support per se infringements may still invoke

considerable analysis of an agreement, not least when restraints considered to be

condemned per se are in fact determined under the rule of reason.51 Therefore the

cost benefit arguments are questionable.52

It has been suggested that the traditional dichotomy of per se rules versus rule of

reason is outdated and “a continuum of intermediate solutions” which are rules

that limit the extent of case analysis, but are not as basic as per se rules is more

desirable.53 A model for the optimal degree of rule differentiation is when decision

errors (Type I and II) and the costs of regulation are minimised. Consequently

Behind by Modernisation’, p660 citing Polygram Holding, Inc v FTC 416 F3d 29, 33-34 (DC Cir 2005). In the 1960’s Commissioner Loevinger of the US Supreme Court noted that the distinction between the two concepts was not particularly clear cut, (Loevinger, 1964), pp23-35. Also, (Kolstad, 2009), p51. 49

(Andreangeli, 2011), pp237, 243. 50

California Dental Association v FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 779, 780, 781 (1999). See NCAA v Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 US 85 at 104. 51

See Leegin, 551 US 887 (2007) and FTC v Actavis, 570 US 756 (2013). 52

See (Christiansen & Kerber, 2006), pp215-244. 53

Ibid, section I.

Page 274: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 273

competition rules are likely to be different for different types of business

behaviour.54

The experience in the US shows, similarly to the EU, that the theory behind a

narrow category of agreements does not necessarily reflect the actuality. Whether

the hybrid approach is an efficient compromise of resources, despite its drawbacks

from a legal perspective, is an interesting question.55

4. Conclusion

That the object criterion should respect calls for legal certainty, predictability, ease

of administrative burden and resources is not in doubt. The system currently in

operation falls short on a number of these fronts given the tension between the

Article 81(3) Guidelines and the jurisprudence. The normative answer may

nominally point towards a narrow category of agreements in terms of enforcement,

but the experience in the US legitimately questions whether this is the correct

solution for the EU’s particular legal system given the development of the case law.

This thesis has clarified the law and opened it nuances up to scrutiny: the outcome

of the analysis is that the law on the object concept is far from straightforward.

Despite the Commission endeavouring to pursue the orthodox approach in its

Article 81(3) Guidelines, the reality is that this has proved impossible to enforce in

practice and has the propensity to be abused.56 In response to criticisms, the

Commission has acknowledged the significance of an agreement’s legal and

economic context and noted that particular restrictions may be objectively

necessary or have a legitimate goal, which may then fall outside Article 101(1)

54

Ibid. 55

Using a crude estimation, the orthodox and hybrid approaches share similar costs of enforcement: the claimant in both cases can rely on a presumption of harm. The defendant then incurs the expense of rebuttal. If the claimant accepts the rebuttal there are three outcomes, (i) it declares the agreement lawful, (ii) conducts an ‘effects’ analysis, or (iii) decides not to proceed. Therefore the hybrid approach could be seen to have an administrable benefit in line with the orthodox approach. This must be viewed against the Commission’s decisional practice: often it undertakes a comprehensive assessment of the market and an agreement’s effects in any event. Whether the MAAP involves far higher costs of enforcement needs to be modelled. 56

Gerard considers that by widening the object category the Commission has avoided the effects-based approach, (Gerard, 2013), pp 38-40.

Page 275: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 274

TFEU.57 In parallel to this, however, it has also attempted to re-simplify the object

concept by following the unsatisfactory judgment in Expedia. It may yet regret this

choice in light of judgments such as Cartes Bancaires.

An alternative solution is needed that is able to recognise both the parameters of

the law and the need for effective enforcement which is administrable. A

suggestion would be more clearly to delineate the functions of the Commission’s

policy approach versus its understanding of the jurisprudence. The words ‘policy’

and ‘law’ are at times used interchangeably, which is unhelpful as the European

Courts will often cede to the Commission’s policy-devising role as the executive,

though will not always do so in respect of the Commission’s interpretation of the

law.58 It is axiomatic that businesses require guidance on the types of prohibited

collusion and have knowledge of a coherent strategy for the application of EU

competition law across the Member States. It is also self-evident why the

Commission should set out its enforcement priorities and its interpretation of the

law in its Guidelines, guidance, Notices and BERs. That said, it is concerning that

the Commission’s policy approach sometimes masquerades as law. The strongest

example of this is the link made between its categorisation of ‘hardcore’ restraints

and the object concept. The Commission’s policy approach must be applied within

the legal framework as interpreted by the European Courts. Hence, the link

between hardcore restrictions, those which are black listed and the object concept

is not as clear cut as the Commission professes. This distinction between the law

and policy is rarely highlighted, and has played a major role in the confusion

surrounding the interpretation and function of the object criterion.59 Separating

the functions of law and policy would help ensure that businesses know the law,

but also understand how the Commission interprets it and when it will pursue

particular types of behaviour.60 It would allow businesses sensibly to make their

57

Gerber noted the Commission has made substantive changes under the radar during the modernisation process; (Gerber, 2008). This trend continues; see eg De Minimis Guidance, 1. 58

(Townley, 2011), pp442-443. Also, (Conway, 2014), pp517-518. 59

See (Townley, 2011), p443; for an interesting discussion on the Commission and ‘myth-making’ see (Akman & Kassim, 2010). See (King, 2011), p296. 60

This envisages, eg, the Article 81(3) Guidelines are recast to reflect the law more accurately and its actual application, which largely follows the hybrid approach. Therefore the requirement that an

Page 276: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 275

own judgment calls in respect of their commercial decisions through recourse to

the case law.

Further research into the function of the object criterion is needed, particularly as

effective enforcement is not the only parameter upon which good law is made.61

The orthodox approach, despite having normative support, does not accurately

reflect the law. This thesis supports the notion that the object criterion is a

powerful tool that has the propensity to be more effectively utilised in accordance

with an effects-based system. Its potential remains unfulfilled. The meaning and

application of the object concept have been revealed. The debate over its function

is set to continue.

agreement is assessed within its legal and economic context would draw attention to the fact that presumptions of harm are technically rebuttable under Article 101(1) TFEU. 61

See (Odudu, 2006), pp1-8. Further research into several areas arising as a result of the findings of this thesis would be of benefit. Such as the practical implications for the NCA’s and NC’s in view of the discord between the case law and the Commission’s guidelines (given their obligations under Regulation 1/2003); the relationship between the object concept and the level of fines, human rights implications and the standard of proof; the role of soft law and its impact on the object concept; the purpose of competition policy and its relationship with the law, and how economics may provide an alternative view of the law. Recommendations as to how the Commission should amend its Article 81(3) Guidelines are also required.

Page 277: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 276

Glossary/Abbreviations

AG – Advocate General

All ER - All England Law Reports

ATP – absolute territorial protection

BER – Block Exemption Regulation

CAT - Competition Appeal Tribunal (UK)

CJEU – Court of Justice of the European Union (formerly the European Court of

Justice)

CMA – Competition Markets Authority

CMLRev - Common Market Law Review

CMLR - Common Market Law Reports

Commission - European Commission

Community Courts – the General Court and Court of Justice

CompAR - Competition Appeal Reports

DG COMP - Directorate General for Competition

DoJ - Department of Justice (United States)

ECHR – European Convention for the Protection of Human Rights

ECLR - European Competition Law Review

ECN - European Competition Network

ECR - European Court Reports

ECSC – European Coal and Steel Community

Page 278: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 277

EEA – European Economic Area

EEC – European Economic Community

EL Rev - European Law Review

EU – European Union

European Courts – The General Court and Court of Justice

EWCA - England and Wales Court of Appeal

EWHC - England and Wales High Court

Fordham – Fordham Competition Law Institute

FTC – Federal Trade Commission (US)

GC – General Court (formerly the Court of First Instance)

Harv. LR - Harvard Law Review

ILCQ - International and Comparative Law Quarterly

IP - Intellectual Property

IPRs - Intellectual Property Rights

KB - Kings Bench

MAAP – the more analytical approach

MIF – Multilateral Interchange Fee

NCA – National Competition Authority

NC – National Court

OECD – Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

OFT - Office of Fair Trading

Page 279: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 278

OJ - Official Journal

OJLS - Oxford Journal of Legal Studies

Para - paragraph

QB - Queens Bench

RPM – resale price maintenance

SI - Statutory Instrument

TFEU - Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union

UKCLR - United Kingdom Competition Law Reports

US – United States

Page 280: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 279

Bibliography

1. Books, Chapters, Journal Articles & Conference Papers

Akman, P., 2013. Competition Law and Policy blog: The Court of Justice's Expedia

ruling undermines the economic approach by eliminating the 'de minimis' defence in

object agreements. [Online]

Available at: www.competitionpolicy.wordpress.com/2013/06/04/

Akman, P. & Kassim, H., 2010. Myths and Myth-Making in the European Union: The

Institutionalization and Interpretation of EU Competition Policy. Journal of Common

Market Studies, 48(1), pp. 111-132.

Alese, F., 2007. Unmasking the masquerade of vertical price fixing. European

Competition Law Review, 28(9), pp. 514-526.

Amato, G., 1997. Antitrust and the Bounds of Power. Oxford: Hart Publishing.

Amato, G. & Ehlermann, C.-D., 2007. EC Competition Law, A Critical Assessment.

s.l.:Hart Publishing.

Andreangeli, A., 2011. From Mobile Phones to Cattle: How the Court of Justice Is

Reframing the Approach to Article 101 (formerly 81 EC Treaty) of the EU Treaty.

World Competition, 34(2), pp. 215-243.

Andriychuk, O., 2010. Rediscovering the spirit of competition: on the normative

value of the competitive process. European Competition Journal, 6(3), pp. 575-610.

Austin, J., 1832. The Province of Jurisprudence Determined. s.l.:s.n.

Bailey, D., 2009. Appreciable effect on trade within the United Kingdom. European

Competition Law Review, 30(8), pp. 353-361.

Bailey, D., 2010. Presumptions in EU competition law. European Competition Law

Review, 31(9), pp. 362-369.

Page 281: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 280

Bailey, D., 2012. Restrictions of Competition by Object under Article 101 TFEU.

Common Market Law Review, Volume 49, pp. 559-600.

Bailey, D., 24 September 2013. The Role of Guidelines in EU Competition Law.

London, King's College London.

Beck, G., 2013. Publication Review: The Limits of Legal Reasoning and the European

Court of Justice. International & Comparative Law Quarterly, 62(2), pp. 515-519.

Bellamy, D. & Child, G., 2008. European Community Law of Competition. 6th ed.

Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Bellamy, D. & Child, G., 2013. European Community Law of Competition. 7 ed.

s.l.:Oxford University Press.

Bell, R. & Heilpern, T., 2014. Landmark European Court judgment confirms narrow

interpretation of restiction "by object". [Online]

Available at: www.lexology.com

Bennett, M. & Collins, P., 2010. The law and economics of information sharing: the

good, bad and the ugly. European Competition Journal, 6(2), pp. 311-337.

Bishop & Walker, 2010. The Economics of EC Competition Law. 3 ed. s.l.:Sweet &

Maxwell.

Black, O., 2005. Conceptual Foundations of Antitrust. s.l.:Cambridge University

Press.

Blanco, L. O., 2012. Market Power in EU Antitrust Law. s.l.:Hart Publishing.

Bork, R. H., 1993. The Antitrust Paradox; A Policy at War with Itself. New York: Basic

Books Inc.

Bourgeois, J. & Bocken, J., 2005. Guidelines on the Application of Article 81(3) of the

EC Treaty or How to Restrict a Restriction. Legal Issues of Economic Integration,

32(2), pp. 111-121.

Page 282: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 281

Bourgeois, J. & Waelbroeck, D., 2013. Ten Years of Effects-based Approach in EU

Competition Law: State of play and perspectives. Bruylant: GCLC Annual Conference

Series.

Bristows, 2014. bristowsclipboard: Object restrictions on the menu. [Online]

Available at: www.bristowsclipboard.com/#sthash.8H7yDnXQ.dpuf

Bruzzone, G. & Boccaccio, M., 2009. Impact-Based Assessment and Use of Legal

Presumptions in EC Competition Law: The Search for the Proper Mix. World

Competition, 32(4), pp. 465-484.

Carlin, F., 2013. EMEA Legal Insights Bulletin, Summer 2013: Pay-for-delay

settlements - EU Commission broadly aligns with US Supreme Court. [Online]

Available at: www.bakermckenzie.com/files/uploads/Documents/EMEA/

Chalmers, D., Davies, G. & Monti, G., 2010. European Union Law. 2 ed.

s.l.:Cambridge University Press.

Chalmers, D., Monti, G., Hadjiemmanuil, C. & Tomkins, A., 2006. European Union

Law: Text and Materials. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Charatjan, T., van Hasselt, E., Scher, I. & Urlus, H., 2014. Greenberg Traurig:

Antitrust compliance in the EU - Reason rules again!. [Online]

Available at: www.gtlaw.com/Nes-Events/Publications/Alerts/179240/

Chirita, A., 2014. A legal-historical review of EU competition rules. International &

Comparative Law Quarterly, 63(2).

Christiansen, A. & Kerber, W., 2006. Competition Policy with Optimally

Differentiated Rules Instead of 'Per Se Rules vs Rule of Reason'. Journal of

Competition Law & Economics, 2(2), pp. 215-244.

Comanor, W., 1985. Vertical Price-Fixing,Vertical Market Restrictions and the New

Antitrust Policy. Harvard Legal Review, Issue 98, p. 983.

Page 283: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 282

Conway, G., 2014. The Limits of Legal Reasoning and the European Court of Justice

(Cambridge Studies in European Law and Policy). Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press.

Cosma, H. & Whish, R., 2003. Soft Law in the Field of EU Competition Policy.

European Business Law Journal, 14(1), pp. 25-56.

Dabbah, M., 2004. EC and UK Competition Law: Commentary, Cases & Materials.

s.l.:Cambridge University Press.

Davies, H. & Holdcroft, D., 1991. Jurisprudence: Texts and Commentary.

s.l.:Butterworths.

Deringer, A., 1968. The Competition Law of the EEC: A commentary on the EEC rules

of competition including the implementing regulations and directive. s.l.:Commerce

Clearing House.

Dworkin, R., 1977. Taking Rights Seriously. s.l.:Duckworth.

Dworkin, R., 1986. Law's Empire. s.l.:Fontana.

Ehlermann, C. D. & Laudati, L. L., 1998. European Competition Law Annual 1997:

Objectives of Competition Policy. s.l.:Hart Publishing.

Faull, J. & Nikpay, A., 1999. The EC Law of Competition. Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Faull, J. & Nikpay, A., 2007. The EC Law of Competition. Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Forrester, I. & Norall, C., 1984. The Laicization of Community Law: Self-help and

Rule of Reason: How competition law is and could be applied. Common Market Law

Review, Volume 21, pp. 11-51.

Forrester, I. S., 2010. A Bush in Need of Pruning: the Luxuriant Growth of Light

Judicial Review. In: C. Ehlermann & M. Marquis, eds. European Competition Law

Page 284: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 283

Annual 2009: Evaluation of Evidence and its Judicial Review in Competition Cases.

Oxford: Hart Publishing.

Furse, M., 2003. Competition Law of the UK and EC. 4th ed. Oxford: Oxford

University Press.

Gerard, D., 2012. kluwercompetitionlawblog.com: Effects-based enforcement of

Article 101 TFEU: the "object paradox". [Online]

Available at: www.kluwercompetitionlawblog.com/2012/02/17/

Gerard, D. M. B., 2013. The effects-based approach under Article 101 TFEU and its

paradoxes: modernisation at war with itself. In: Bourgeois & Waelbroeck, eds. Ten

years of effects-based approach in EU Competition Law: State of play and

perspectives. s.l.:GCLC Annual Conference Series, pp. 17-41.

Gerardin, D. & Girgenson, I., 2011. The Counterfactual Method in EU Competition

Law: The Cornerstone of the Effects-based Approach, s.l.: www.papers.ssrn.com.

Gerber, D. J., 1998. Law and Competition in Twentieth Century Europe: Protecting

Prometheus. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Gerber, D. J., 2008. Two forms of modernisation in European Competition Law.

Fordham International Law Journal, Volume 31, p. 1235.

Gippini-Fournier, E., 2010. The Elusive Standard of Proof in EU Competition Cases.

World Competition, 33(2), pp. 187-207.

González, A. O., 2012. Object Analysis in Information Exchange Among Competitors.

Global Antitrust Review, Issue 5, pp. 1-57.

Goyder, D., 2003. EC Competition Law. 4th ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Goyder, J., 2011. Cet Obscur Objet: Object Restrictions in Vertical Agreements.

Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2(4), pp. 1-13.

Goyder, J. & Albors-Llorens, A., 2009. EC Competition Law. 5 ed. Oxford: Oxford

University Press.

Page 285: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 284

Graham, C., 2013. Competition Law Blog: Re-thinking the de minimis rules. [Online]

Available at: www.competitionlawblog.blogspot.co.uk/2013/07/re-thinking-de-

minimis-rules.html

Graham, C., 2013. Methods for determining whether an agreement restricts

competition: comment on Allianz Hungaria. European Law Review, 38(4), pp. 542-

551.

Hart, 1997. The Concept of Law. 2 ed. s.l.:Clarendon Law Series.

Hawk, B., 1995. System Failire: Vertical Restraints and EC Competition Law.

Common Market Law Review, Volume 32, pp. 973-989.

Howard, A., 2009. Object and Effect: What's in an Object?. Competition Law

Journal, Volume 8, pp. 38-40.

Ibáñez Colomo, P., 2011. AG Kokott reinvents (k)opyright. [Online]

Available at: www.chillingcompetition/2011/02/11

Ibáñez Colomo, P., 2012. Market Failures, transaction costs and Article 101(1) TFEU

case law. European Law Review, 37(5), pp. 541-562.

Ibáñez Colomo, P., 2014. Chillin'Competition: Groupement des Cartes Bancaires and

the resilience of the case law on restrictions by object. [Online]

Available at: www.chillingcompetition.com

Ibáñez Colomo, P., 2014. Chillin'Competition: More on AG Wahl and restrictions of

competition by object: 'pay-for-delay' setlements as a case study. [Online]

Available at: www.chillingcompetition.com/2014/05/22/more-on-ag-wahl-and-

restictions-by-object-pay-for-delay-settlements-as-a-case-study/

Ibáñez Colomo, P., 2014. Chillin'Competition: Restrictions of competition by object

under Article 101(1) TFEU: chapeau bas, Prof Wahl!. [Online]

Available at: www.chillingcompetition.com/2014/03/31/restrictions-of-

competition-by-object-under-article-1011-tfeu-chapeau-bas-prof-wahl/

Page 286: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 285

Italianer, A., 10 December 2014. The object of effects. Brussels, CRA conference.

Italianer, A., 2013. Competitor agreements under EU competition law. New York,

40th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, Fordham

Competition Law Institute.

Jebelli, K. H., 2010. EU ancillary restraints: a reasoned approach to Article 101(1),

s.l.: www.papers.ssrn.com.

Jephcott, M., 2011. Law of Cartels. s.l.:Jordan Publishing.

Jones, A., 2006. Analysis of agreements under US and EC antitrust law -

Convergence or divergence?. Antitrust Bulletin, Volume 51.

Jones, A., 2010. Left Behind by Modernisation? Restrictions by Object under Article

101(1). European Competition Journal, 6(3), pp. 649-676.

Jones, A., 2010. The Journey Towards an Effects-based Approach Under Article 101

TFEU - The Case of 'hardcore' Restraints. Antitrust Bulletin, 55(4).

Jones, A. & Sufrin, B., 2004. EC Competition Law: Text Cases and Materials. 2nd ed.

Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Jones, A. & Sufrin, B., 2011. EU Competition Law, Text Cases and Materials. 4th ed.

Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Jones, A. & Sufrin, B., 2014. EU Competition Law: Text, Cases and Materials. 5 ed.

Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Kelsen, H., 1934. The Pure Theory of Law. s.l.:s.n.

Kerse, C., 1998. Antitrust Procedure. 4th ed. s.l.:Sweet & Maxwell.

Killick, J. & Berghe, P., 2010. This is Not the Time to be Tinkering with Regulation

1/2003 - It is Time for Fundamental Reform - Europe Should Have Change We Can

Believe In. Competition Law Review, 6(2), p. 259.

Page 287: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 286

King, S., 2011. The Object Box: Law, Policy or Myth?. European Competition Journal,

7(2), pp. 269-296.

King, S., 2013. European Commission's consultation on the revision of the De

Minimis Notice.

s.l.:http://ec.europa.eu/competition/consultations/2013_de_minimis_notice/saskia

_king_en.pdf.

King, S. & Scott, A., 2012. Effect on interstate trade: An overview of EU and national

case law. [Online]

Available at: http://www.concurrences.com/anglais/bulletin/e-competitions-

bulletin?

Kolstad, O., 2009. Object contra effect in Swedish and European competition law,

Sweden: Konkurrensverket.

Korah, V., 1986. EEC Competition Policy - Legal Form or Economic Efficiency?.

Current Legal Problems, 39(1), pp. 85-109.

Korah, V., 1986. Pronuptia Franchising: The Marriage of Reason and EEC

Competition Rules. EIPR, 8(4), p. 99.

Korah, V., 2006. Cases and Materials on EC Competition Law. 3 ed. s.l.:Hart

Publishing.

Korah, V., 2007. An Introductory Guide to EC Competition Law and Practice. 9 ed.

s.l.:Hart Publishing.

Kozubovska, B., 2012. How important is the distinction in Article 101 TFEU between

agreements that restrict competition by object and those that restrict by effect?.

[Online]

Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/displayabstractsearch.cfm

Kroes, N., 8 October 2009. Tackling cartels – a never-ending task. Brazil, Anti-Cartel

Enforcement: Criminal and Administrative Policy – Panel session.

Page 288: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 287

Kuenzler, A., 2012. Presumptions as Appropriate Means to Regulate Resale Price

Maintenance: in Defence of Structuring the Rule of Reason. European Competition

Journal, 8(3), pp. 497-525.

La Madrid de Pablo, A., 2014. Chillin'Competition: 10 Comments on the ECJ's

judgment in Case C-67/13 P, Groupement des Cartes Bancaires. [Online]

Available at: www.chillingcompetition.com

La Madrid de Pablo, A. & Petit, N., 2011. The slow death of Article 101(3). [Online]

Available at: www.chillingcompetition.com

Lasok QC, P., 2008. Recent developments in the rule of reason in EC anti-trust law.

Competition Law Journal, Volume 7.

Lawrence, S., 2014. Bristows clipboard. [Online]

Available at: www.bristowsclipboard.com

Loevinger, 1964. Virginal Law Review, 50(1).

Loozen, E., 2010. The application of a more economic approach to restrictions by

object: no revolution after all (T-Mobile Netherlands (C-8/08)). European

Competition Law Review, 31(4), pp. 146-150.

Loozen, E., 2010. The workings of Article 101 TFEU in case of an agreement that

aims to limit parallel trade (GlaxoSmithKline Services (C-501/06 P, C-513/06 P, C-

515/o6 P and C-519/06 P). European Competition Law Review, 31(9), pp. 349-353.

Lovdahl Gormsen, L., 2013. Are Anti-competitive Effects Necessary for an Analysis

under Article 102 TFEU?. World Competition, 36(2), pp. 223-246.

Lugard & Hancher, 2004. Honey, I shrunk the Article! A critical assessment of the

Commission's notice on Article 81(3) of the EC Treaty. European Competition Law

Review, Volume 25.

Mahtani, M. R., 2012. Thinking outside the object box: an EU and UK perspective.

European Competition Journal, 8(1), pp. 1-39.

Page 289: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 288

Marquis, M., 2007. 02 (Germany) v Commission and the exotic mysteries of Article

81(1) EC. European Law Review, 32(1), pp. 29-47.

Minow, M., 2006. Archetypal Legal Scholarship - A Field Guide. AALS Workshop for

New Law Teachers.

Monti, G., 2000. European Competition Policy for 21st Century. In: B. Hawk, ed.

Fordham Corporate law Institute. s.l.:s.n.

Monti, G., 2002. Article 81 EC and Public Policy. Common Market Law Review,

Volume 39, p. 1057.

Monti, G., 2007. EC Competition Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Monti, G., 2009. EC Competition Law: The Dominance of Economic Analysis?. In: A.

Heineman, A. Kellerhals & R. Zach, eds. Development and Perspectives on

Competition Law. s.l.:Edward Elgar.

Motta, M., 2004. Competition Policy: Theory and Practice. s.l.:Cambridge University

Press.

Nagy, C. I., 2013. The Distinction between Anti-competitive Object and Effect after

Allianz: The End of Coherence in Competition Analysis?. World Competition, 36(4),

pp. 541-564.

Nazzini, R., 2006. Article 81 EC between time present and time past: a normative

critique of "restriction of competition" in EU law. Common Market Law Review,

Volume 43, pp. 497-536.

Nazzini, R., 2012. Administrative Enforcement, Judicial Review and Fundamental

Rights in EU Competition Law: A Comparative Contextual-Functionalist Perspective.

Common Market Law Review, Volume 49, pp. 971-1006.

Nicolaides, P., 2005. The Balancing Myth: The Economics of Article 81(1) & (3).

Legal Issues of Economic Integration, 32(2), pp. 123-145.

Page 290: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 289

Odudu, O., 2001. Interpreting Article 81(1): Object as Subjective Intention.

European Law Review, Volume 26, pp. 60-75.

Odudu, O., 2001. Interpreting Article 81(1): The Object Requirement Revisited.

European Law Review, Volume 26, pp. 379-390.

Odudu, O., 2006. The Boundaries of EC Competition Law: The Scope of Article 81.

s.l.:Oxford University Press.

Odudu, O., 2009. Restrictions of competition by object - what's the beef?.

Competition Law Journal, 9(1), pp. 11-17.

Odudu, O., 2011. Indirect Information Exchange: The Constituent Elements of Hub

and Spoke Collusion. European Competition Journal, 7(2), pp. 205-242.

Odudu, O., 2013. Competition Bulletin: e-books: Vertical participation in hub and

spoke agreements. [Online]

Available at: www.competitionbulletin.com/2013/07/18

Padilla, J., 2010. The elusive challenge of assessing information sharing among

competitors under the competition laws. s.l., OECD, Policy Round Tables.

Parret, L., 2010. Shouldn't we know what we are protecting? Yes we should! A plea

for a solid and comprehensive debate about the objectives of EU Competition Law

and Policy. European Competition Journal, 6(2), pp. 339-376.

Posner, 2001. Antitrust Law. 2 ed. s.l.:University of Chicago Press.

Pradelles & Ruiz-Calzado, 2014. Client Alert: "By Object" Restrictions of Competition

Revisited: European Court of Justice Endorses Narrow Interpretation, Brussels:

Latham & Watkins.

Robertson, B., 2007. What is a Restriction of Competition? The implications of the

CFI's judgment in O2 Germany and the Rule of Reason. European Competition Law

Review, Volume 28, p. 252.

Page 291: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 290

Rodger, B., 2014. The Object/Effect Distinction in Competition Law Article 101,

categorical distinctions and Predictable Enforcement. Istanbul, New Challenges in

Competition Law Enforcement Conference.

Rose, V., 24 February 2010. Per se infringements of the competition rules. s.l., King's

College London.

Russo, F., Schinkel, M. P., Gunster, A. & Carree, M., 2010. European Commission

Decisions on Competition: Economic Perspectives on Landmark Antitrust and

Merger Cases. s.l.:Cambridge University Press.

Shinder, J. I. & Kapoor, A., 2014. Antitrusttoday.com: Are Bright-Line Rules The Right

Prescription For Reverse-Payment Cases?. [Online]

Available at: www.antitrusttoday.com/2014/03/05/

Simonsson, I., 2010. Legitimacy in EU Cartel Control. s.l.:Hart Publishing.

Slot, P. J. & Johnston, A., 2006. An introduction to competition law. Oxford: Hart

Publishing.

Smith & Hogan, 2011. Criminal Law. 13 ed. s.l.:Oxford University Press.

Smith, S., 2004. Contract Theory. s.l.:Oxford University Press.

Stefan, O. A., 2008. European Competition Soft Law in European Courts: A Matter of

Hard Principles. European Law Journal, 14(6), pp. 753-772.

Sterling, S. &., 2014. The EU General Court gets a rap on its knuckles, Brussels:

Lexology.

Stibbe, 2013. European Court of Justice simplifies classic case law and rules that all

object infringements that have an effect on interstate trade violate Article 101

TFEU. [Online]

Available at: www.lexology.com

Svetlicinii, A., 2008. ECJ's Ruling in Beef Industry Case: Competition Law Must Be

Observed At All Times. European Law Review, Volume 12, pp. 402-406.

Page 292: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 291

Svetlicinii, A., 2008. Exploring the role of legal presumptions under the "convincing

evidence" standard in EC merger control. Global Antitrust Review, pp. 117-134.

Svetlicinii, A. & Sad, N., 2011. "Objective Justifications" of "Restrictions by Object"

in Pierre Fabre: A More Economic Approach to Article 101(1) TFEU?. European Law

Reporter, Issue 11, p. III.

Townley, C., 2009. Article 81 EC and Public Policy. Oxford: Hart Publishing.

Townley, C., 2011. Which goals count in Article 101 TFEU? Public Policy an its

discontents. European Competition Law Review, Issue 9, pp. 441-448.

Urlus, H. & Mulder, S., 29 January 2013. ECJ eliminates noticeability test in regard to

restriction of competition by object. [Online]

Available at: www.lexology.com/library/

Vajda QC, C. & Woolfe, P., 2010. The Chapter I Prohibition: Is It a Safe Bet?.

Competition Law Journal, 9(2), pp. 198-215.

Van Bael, I. & Bellis, F., 2005. Competition Law of the European Community. 4th ed.

s.l.:Kluwer Law International.

Van den Bergh, R. & Camesasca, P., 2006. European Competition Law and

Economics: A comparative Perspective. 2 ed. London: Sweet & Maxwell.

Vedder, H., 2013. European Law Blog: Allianz and the object-effect dichotomy in

Article 101(1) TFEU: a practical solution meets not so practical competition law.

[Online]

Available at: www.europeanlawblog.eu/?p=1664

Vogel, L., 2012. EU Competition Law Applicable to Distribution Agreements: Review

of 2011 and Outlook for 2012. Journal of European Competition Law & Practice,

Issue 19 April, pp. 1-16.

Waelbroeck, D. & Slater, D., 2013. The scope of object vs effect under Article 101

TFEU. In: Bourgeois & Waelbroeck, eds. Ten years of effects-based approach in EU

Page 293: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 292

Competition Law: State of play and perspectives. s.l.:GCLC Annual Conference

Series, pp. 131-157.

Wesseling, R., 1999. The Commission's White Paper on Modernisation of EC

Antitrust Law: Unspoken Consequences and Incomplete Treatment of Alternative

Options. European Competition Law Review, Volume 20, p. 420.

Wesseling, R., 2000. The Modernisation of EC Antitrust Law. s.l.:Hart Publishing.

Whish, R., 1993. Competition Law. 3rd ed. London: Butterworth.

Whish, R., 2003. Competition Law. 5th ed. London: Lexis Nexis Butterworths.

Whish, R., 2009. Competition Law. 6 ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Whish, R. & Bailey, B., 2012. Competition Law. 7th ed. Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Whish, R. & Sufrin, B., 1987. Article 85 and the Rule of Reason. Yearbook of

European Law, 7(1), pp. 1-38.

Wils, W., 2010. The Increased Level of EU Antitrust Fines and the impact of the

European Convention of Human Rights. World Competition, 33(1), p. 5.

Wyatt & Dashwood, 2006. European Union Law. 5 ed. s.l.:Sweet & Maxwell.

Zevgolis, N. E., 2013. Resale price maintenance (RPM) in European competition law:

legal certainty versus economic theory?. European Competition Law Review, 34(1),

pp. 25-32.

Page 294: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 293

2. Judgments and Opinions

2.1. EU (European Court of Justice / General Court)

Case C-204/00 P etc, Aalborg Portland v Commission, [2004] ECR I-123.

Case C-41/69, ACF Chemiefarma v Commission, [1970] ECR 661.

Case C-107/82, AEG-Telefunken v Commission, [1983] ECR 3151.

Case C-67/96, Albany International BV v Stichting Bedrijfspensioenfonds

Textielindustrie, [1999] ECR I-5751.

Case C-32/11, Allianz Hungária Biztosító Zrt v Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, 14 March

2013, nyr.

(Opinion delivered by AG Cruz Villalón on 25 October 2012)

Case C-238/05, Asnef-Equifax, Servicios de Información sobre Solvencia y Crédito, SL

v Asociación de Usuarios de Servicios Bancarios (Ausbanc) [2006] ECR I-11125.

(Opinion delivered by AG Geelhoed on 29 June 2006)

Case T-3/89, Atochem v Commission, [1991] ECR II-1177.

Joined Cases C-215/96 and C-216/69, Bagnasco Banca Popolare di Novara, [1999]

ECR I-135.

Case T-4/89, BASF v Commission, [1991] ECR II-1523.

Joined Cases T-175/95 and 176/95, BASF v Commission, [1999] ECR II-1581.

Case C-246/86, Belasco v Commission, [1989] ECR 2117.

Case C-22/71, Béguelin Import Co v GL Import-Export S.A, [1971] ECR 949.

Case T-53/03, BPB plc v Commission, [2008] ECR II-1333.

Case C-23/67, Brasserie De Haecht v Wilkin (no.1), [1967] ECR 407.

Page 295: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 294

Joined Cases T-49-51/02, Brasserie Nationale v Commission, [2005] ECR II-3033.

Case C-123/83, Bureau National Interprofessional Du Cognac v Guy Clair, [1985] ECR

391.

(Opinion delivered by AG Slynn on 2 October 1984)

Joined Cases T-25, 26, 30–32, 34–39, 42–46, 48, 50–65, 68–71, 87, 88, 103 &

104/95, Cimenteries CBR SA v Commission, [2000] ECR II-491.

Case T-213/00, CMA CGM v Commission, [2003] ECR II-913.

Joined Cases C-262/81, Coditel SA, Compagnie Generale Pour La Diffusion de La

Television and Others v Ciné-Vog Films Sa and Others, [1982] ECR 3381.

Case C-49/92 P, Commission v Anic Partecipazioni, [1999] ECR I-4125.

Joined Cases C-29 & 30/83, Compagnie Royale Asturienne des Mines SA (CRAM) and

Rheinzink v Commission, [1984] ECR 1679.

(Opinion delivered by AG Rosès on 1 February 1984)

Case C-209/07, Competition Authority v Beef Industry Development Society and

Barry Brothers (Carrigmore) Meals Ltd, [2008] ECR I-8637.

(Opinion delivered by AG Trstenjak on 4 September 2008)

Cases C-101 & 110/07 P, Coop de France Bétail et Viande v Commission, [2008] ECR

I-10193.

Case C-61/80, Coöperatieve Stremsel- en Kleurselfabriek v Commission, [1981] ECR

00851.

Case C-234/89, Delimitis v Henninger Bräu, [1991] ECRI-935.

Case C-30/78, Distillers Company v Commission, [1980] ECR 2229.

Case T-588/08 P, Dole Food v Commission, 14 March 2013, nyr. [on appeal]

Page 296: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 295

Case T-360/09, E.ON Ruhrgas AG v Commission, 29 June 2012, nyr.

Joined Cases C-56 & 58/64, Etablissements Consten SA and Grundigverkaufs-GmbH

v Commission, [1966] ECR 342.

(Opinion delivered by AG Roemer on 27 April 1966)

Joined Cases T-374, 375, 384 & 388/94, European Night Services v Commission,

[1998] ECR II-3141.

Case C-226/11, Expedia Inc v Autorité de la concurrence, 13 December 2012, nyr.

(Opinion delivered by AG Kokott on 6 September 2012)

Case C-219/95 P, Ferrière Nord v Commission, [1997] ECR I-4411.

(Opinion delivered by AG Léger on 20 February 1997)

Joined Cases T-217/03 and T-245/03 FNCBV v Commission [2006] ECR II-4987

Joined Cases C-403 & 429/08, Football Association Premier League Ltd v QC Leisure

and Karen Murphy v Media Protection Services Ltd, [2011] ECR I- 9083.

(Opinion delivered by AG Kokott on 3 February 2011)

Case C-5/69, Franz Völk v S.P.R.L Ets J. Vervaecke, [1969] ECR 295.

(Opinion delivered by AG Gand on 3 June 1969)

Case T-587/08, Fresh Del Monte Produce v Commission, 14 March 2013, nyr. [on

appeal]

Case T-368/00, General Motors Nederland and Opel Nederland v Commission,

[2003] ECR II-4491.

Case C-551/03 P, General Motors v Commission, [2006] ECR I-3173.

(Opinion delivered by AG Tizzano on 25 October 2005)

Page 297: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 296

Case T-168/01, GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission, [2006] ECR II-

2969.

Joined Cases C-501, 513, 515 & 519/06 P, GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v

Commission, [2009] ECR I-9291.

(Opinion delivered by AG Trstenjak on 30 June 2009)

Case C-250/92, Gøttrup-Klim v Dansk Landbrugs Grovvareselskab AmbA, [1994] ECR

I-5641.

(Opinion delivered by AG Tesauro on 16 June 1994)

Case T-38/02, Group Danone v Commission, [2005] ECR II-4407.

Case C-67/13 P, Groupement des Cartes Bancaires (CB) v Commission, 11

September 2014, nyr.

(Opinion delivered by AG Wahl on 27 March 2014)

Case T-491/07, Groupement des Cartes Bancaires GIE v Commission, 29 November

2012, nyr.

Case C-86/62, Hasselblad v Commission, [1984] ECR 883.

Case C-22/78, Hugin Kassaregister AG and Hugin Cash Registers Ltd v Commission,

[1979] 3 CMLR 345.

Case T-9/89, Hüls v Commission, [1992] ECR II-499.

Joined Cases C-96 to 102, 104, 105, 108 and 110/82 and others, IAZ International

Belgium SA v Commission, ANSEAU – NAVEWA, [1983] ECR 3369.

(Opinion delivered by AG Verloren van Themaat on 29 June 1983)

Case T-13/89, ICI plc v Commission, [1992] ECR II-1021.

Case C-306/96, Javico International v Yves Saint Laurent, [1998] ECR I-1983.

Page 298: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 297

Case T-67/01, JCB Service v Commission, [2004] ECR II-49.

Joined Cases T-67, 68, 71 & 78/00, JFE Engineering v. Commission, [2004] ECR II-

2501, para 185, upheld on appeal, Joined Cases C-403 & 405/04 P, Sumitomo Metal

Industries and Nippon Steel v Commission, [2007] ECR I-729.

Case C-7/95 P, John Deere v Commission, [1998] ECR I-3111.

Case T-127/04, KME Germany A.G. v Commission, [2009] ECR II-1167.

Case T-7/93, Langnese-Iglo GmbH v Commission, [1995] ECR II-1533.

Joined Cases T-305-307, 313–316, 318, 325, 328, 329 & 335/94, Limburgse

Maatschappij v Commission, [1999] ECR II-931.

Joined Cases C-238, 244, 245, 247, 250–252 & 254/99 P, Limburgse Vinyl

Maatschappij v Commission, [2002] ECR I-8375.

Case C-27/87, Louis Erauw-Jacquéry Sprl v La Hesbignonne Société Coopérative,

[1988] ECR 1999.

(Opinion delivered by AG Mischo on 9 December 1987)

Case T-112/99, M6 v Commission, [2001] ECR II-2459.

Case T-56/99, Marlines v Commission, [2003] ECR II-5225.

Case C-382/12P, MasterCard and Others v Commission, 11 September 2014, nyr.

Case T-111/08, Mastercard Inc v Commission, 24 May 2012, nyr.

Case C-344/98, Masterfoods v HB Icecream, [2000] ECR I-11369.

Case T-17/93, Matra Hachette v Commission, [1994] ECR II-595.

Case C-519/04P, Meca-Medina v Commission, [2006] ECR I-6991.

Case C-26/76, Metro SBGroßmärkte v Commission, [1977] ECR 1875.

Page 299: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 298

Case T-112/99, Métropole Télévision SA (M6) v Commission, [2001] ECR II-2459.

Case C-19/77, Miller International Schallplaten v Commission, [1978] ECR 131.

(Opinion delivered by AG Warner on 10 January 1978)

Case C-235/92 P, Montecatini v Commission, [1999] ECR I-4539.

Case T-14/89, Montedipe SpA v Commission, [1992] ECR II-1155.

Case C-393/92, Municipality of Almelo and Others v NV Energiebedrijf Ijsselmij,

[1994] I-01477.

Case C-105/04 P, Nederlandse Federatieve Verenigung, [2006] ECR I-08725.

Case C-258/78, Nungesser KB v Commission [1982] ECR 2015.

Joined Cases 96–102, 104, 105, 108 and 110/82, NV IAZ International Belgium and

others v Commission, [1983] ECR 3369.

Case C-31/80, NV L’Oréal and SA L’Oréal v PVBA De Nieuwe AMCK Puba, [1980] ECR

3775.

Case T-328/03, O2 (Germany) GmbH & Co OHG v Commission, [2006] ECR II-1231.

Case C-399/93, Oude Luttikhuis and Others v Verenigde Melkindustrie, [1995] ECR I-

4515.

Case T-146/09, Parker Pen Ltd v Commission, [1994] ECR II-549.

Case C-260/07, Pedro IV Servicios SL v Total Espana SA, [2009] ECR I-2437.

Case C-439/09, Pierre Fabre Dermo-Cosmétique SAS v Président de l’Autorité de la

concurrence, [2011] ECR I-9419.

(Opinion delivered by AG Mazák on 3 March 2011)

Case C-161/86, Pronuptia de Paris GmbH v Commission v Irmgard Schillgallis, [1986]

ECR 353.

Page 300: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 299

Case C-68/12, Protimonopolný úrad Slovenskej republiky v Slovenská sporitelňa, 7

February 2013, nyr.

Case T-1/89, Rhône Poulenc SA v Commission, [1991] ECR II-948.

Case C-243/83, SA Binon & Cie v SA Agence et Messageries de la Presse, [1985] ECR

2015.

Case C-277/87, Sandoz Prodotti Farmaceutici SpA v Commission, [1990] ECR I-45.

Joined Cases T-68/89, T-77/89 & T-78/89, Società Italiana Vetro SpA v Commission,

[1992] ECR II-01403.

Case C-56/65, Société Technique Minière v Maschinenbau Ulm Gmbh, [1966] ECR

249.

(Opinion delivered by AG Roemer on 23 March 1966)

Case T-29/92, SPO v Commission, [1995] ECR II-289.

Joined Cases 40 to 48, 50, 54 to 56, 111, 113 and 114-73, Coöperatieve Vereniging

"Suiker Unie" UA and others v Commission, [1975] ECR 01663.

Case C-403 & 405/04 P, Sumitomo v Commission, [2007] ECR I-00729.

Case C-28/77, Tepea BV v Commission, [1978] ECR 1391.

Case C-8/08, T-Mobile Netherlands BV v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse

Mededingingsautoriteit, [2009] ECR I-4529.

(Opinion delivered by AG Kokott on 19 February 2009)

Case C-279/87, Tipp-Ex GmbH v Commission, [1990] ECR I-261.

Case T-148/89, Tréfilunion v Commission, [1995] ECR II-1063.

Case T-62/98, Volkswagen v Commission, [2000] ECR II-2707.

Page 301: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 300

Case C-309/99, Wouters v Algemene Raad van de Nederlandsche Orde van

Advocaten, [2002] ECR I-1577.

Case C-439/11, Ziegler v Commission, 11 July 2013, nyr.

2.2. UK

Bookmakers’ Afternoon Greyhound Services Ltd v Amalgamated Racing Ltd, [2009]

EWCA Civ 750.

Cityhook Ltd v Office of Fair Trading, [2007] CAT 18.

JJB Sports plc v Office of Fair Trading, [2006] EWCA Civ. 1318.

Napp Pharmaceutical Holdings Ltd v Director General of Fair Trading, Case No

1000/1/1/01 [2002] Cat 1.

R v Moloney, [1985] 1 All ER 1025.

2.3. US

California Dental Association v FTC, 526 US 756 (1999).

Chicago Board of Trade v United States (1918) US 246.

Continental TV, Inc v GTE Sylvania 433 US 36 (1977).

FTC v Actavis, 570 US 756 (2013).

FTC v Indiana Federation of Dentists 476 US 447 (1986).

Leegin Creative Leather Products Inc v PSKS, Inc, DBA Kay’s Kloset...Kay’s Shoes, 551

US 887 (2007).

NCAA v Board of Regents of the Univ. Of Oklahoma, 468 US 85 (1984).

Polygram Holding, Inc v FTC 416 F3d 29, (DC Cir 2005).

Standard Oil Co (NJ) v United States (1911) 221 US 1.

Page 302: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 301

State Oil Co v Khan, 522 US 3 (1997).

Page 303: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 302

3. Commission Decisions

CECED, [1999] 2000/475/EC, OJ L187.

Continental/United/Lufthansa/Air Canada, 23 May 2013, COMP/AT.39595.

Europay (Eurocard – MasterCard), COMP/34.579 [2009] OJ C264/8.

E.ON/GDF, [2009] COMP/39.401.

FETTCSA, [2000] OJ L268/1.

Fine Art auction houses, [2006] COMP/E-2/37.784.

Ford/Volkswagen, [1993], OJ L20/14.

GlaxoSmithKline, 2001/791/ EC, [2001] OJ L302.

Groupement des Bancaires, [2008] COMP/38.606.

IAZ/Anseau, [1982] OJ L167/39.

Lundbeck, Case No. 39226, 19.06.2013, nyr.

Nederlandse Federatieve Vereniging voor de Groothandel op Elektrotechnisch

Gebied and Technische Unie, [2000] OJ L39/1.

Polistil/Arbois, [1984] IV/30.568.

Polypropylene, [1986] OJ L230/1.

REIMS II, [1999] OJ L275/17.

Seamless Steel Tubes, [2003] OJ L140/1.

Société Air France/Alitalia Linee Aeree Italiane, OJ 2004, L362/17.

Synthetic Fibres, [1984] OJ L207/17.

TACA, OJ [1999] OJ L95/1.

Page 304: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 303

VBBB and VBVB, [1982] OJ L54/36.

Visa International – Multilateral Interchange Fee, [2002] OJ L 318/17.

Visa MIF, [2010] Case COMP/39.398.

3.1. UK decisions

‘Exchange of information of future fees by certain independent fee-paying schools’,

Case CE/2890-03, Decision of the OFT, No.CA98/05/2006.

Page 305: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 304

4. On-line Resources

www.antitrusttoday.com

www.brickcourt.co.uk

www.bristows.com

www.backermckenzie.com

www.chillingcompetition.com

www.competitionlawblog.blogspot.co.uk

www.competitionpolicy.wordpress.com

www.competitionpolicyinternational.com

www.concurrences.com

www.curia.europa.eu

www.ec.europa.eu/dgs/competition/index_en.htm

www.europeanlawblog.eu

www.freshfields.com/en/global

www.globalcompetitionreview.com

www.globaleconomicsgroup.com/antitrustcompetition-policy/

www.lexology.com

www.lw.com

www.monckton.com

www.papers.ssrn.com

Page 306: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 305

www.slaughterandmay.com

www.twentyfirstcenturycompetition.com/author/kevincoates/

Page 307: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 306

5. Legislation/Notices/Press releases

1400/2002, Commission Regulation on Motor Vehicle Distribution [2002] OJ

L203/30.

1/2003, Council Regulation implementing Articles 81 and 82 [2003] OJ L 1/1.

772/2004, Commission Regulation on Technology Transfer [2004] OJ L 123/11.

773/2004, Commission Regulation on the conduct of proceedings by the

Commission pursuant to Articles 101 and 102 [2004] OJ L123/18.

662/2008, Commission Regulation on the conduct of settlement procedures in

cartel cases [2008] OJ L171/3.

330/2010, Commission Regulation on the application of Article 101(3) TFEU to

categories of vertical agreements and concerted practices [2010] OJ L102/1.

1217/2010, Commission Regulation on research and development agreements

[2010] OJ L 335/36.

1218/2010, Commission Regulation on the application of Article 101(3) of the

Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to certain categories of

specialisation agreements [2010] OJ, L 335/43.

Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2000] OJ C291/1.

Guidelines on the applicability of Article 101 of the TFEU to horizontal co-operation

agreements [2001] OJ C3/2.

Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer

agreements [2004] OJ C101/2.

Guidelines on the effect on trade concept contained in Articles 81 and 82 of the

Treaty [2004] OJ C101/81.

Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty [2004] OJ C101/97.

Page 308: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 307

Guidelines on the method of setting fines imposed pursuant to Article 23(2)(a) of

Regulation 1/2003 [2006] OJ C 210/2.

Guidelines on Vertical Restraints [2010] OJ, C130/10.

Guidelines on the applicability of Article 101 of the TFEU to horizontal co-operation

agreements [2011] OJ C11/01.

Commission staff working paper accompanying the report on the functioning of

Reg. 1/2003.

Commission Notice on the Definition of the Relevant Market for the purposes of

Community Competition Law [1997] OJ C 372/5.

Commission Notice on agreements of minor importance which do not appreciably

restrict competition under Article 81(1) [2001] OJ C 368/13.

Commission Notice on informal guidance relating to novel questions concerning

Article 81 and 82 of the EC Treaty that arise in individual cases [2004] OJ C101/78.

Commission Notice on restrictions directly related and necessary to concentrations

[2005] OJ C56/24.

Commission Notice on immunity from fines and reduction of fines in cartel cases

[2006] OJ C298/17.

Commission Notice on agreements of minor importance which do not appreciably

restrict competition under Article 101(1) of the TFEU [2014] OJ C 291/01.

Guidance on restrictions of competition "by object" for the purpose of defining

which agreements may benefit from the De Minimis Notice [2014] C 4136 final, 25

June 2014: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/de_minimis_notice_annex.pdf

White Paper on modernisation of the rules implementing Articles 81 and 82 of the

EC Treaty (formerly Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty), OJ C 132 of 12.5.1999.

Annual Report on Competition Policy, EU Commission (DG COMP), various years.

Page 309: Agreements that restrict competition by object under ...etheses.lse.ac.uk/3068/1/King_Agreements_that... · Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU:

Page 308

Commission press release, 24 May 2000 (modernisation).

Commission press release IP/13/563. (Lundbeck)

Commission press release IP/13/685. (Commission consults on review of safe

harbour for minor agreements [2013])

Commission press release IP/14/728. (Commission adopts revised safe harbour

rules for minor agreements [2014])