Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    1/56

    ADAPTATION AND CONVERGENCE IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: THE

    CASE OF CHINESE LISTED COMPANIES

    Iain MacNeil

    INTRODUCTION

    Prior to 1978, private enterprise had been effectively eliminated in China as a result

    of central (state) planning of the economy. Recent years have, however, seen a

    transformation. The economic reform process, which began in 1978, has led to

    fundamental changes in enterprise organisation, a re-definition of the role of the state

    and recognition of a role for private capital and private enterprise. The main elements

    of that process have been the introduction of company and securities law, conversion

    of state-owned entities into companies and listing of these companies on the Stock

    Exchanges. From this process, there has emerged a group of public listed

    companies, which represent a substantial part of Chinas economy. A more recent

    development has been the introduction of Corporate Governance Guidelines for

    listed companies.

    The creation of the legal and institutional framework which supports listed companies

    in China raises a number of interesting issues. First, as company and securities law

    had to be created ab initio so as to allow for the participation of private capital in the

    economy, China provides a real example of the choices available in the design of a

    corporate governance framework. A number of basic issues had to be addressed.

    One was definition of the rights of shareholders and other stakeholders. Another was

    the structure of the legal rules and in particular the balance between mandatory and

    default rules. The rights of minority shareholders were also an important

    consideration if private capital was to participate in the newly formed stock

    exchanges. Second, the Chinese experience in establishing a regulatory regime forlisted companies provides some indication of the extent to which convergence

    towards international norms is a significant force in corporate governance. This is of

    particular interest in China, in view of the stated objective of the company and

    securities law of promoting a socialist market economy. In particular, the experience

    in China may provide some guidance as to elements of the corporate governance

    The Law School, University of Aberdeen. Research for this article was undertaken during a term of sabbatical leave spent in Hong Kong and China. I am grateful to the Leverhulme Trust for financial

    support; to the Hong Kong Baptist University for the provision of research facilities; to Alex Lau of HKBU for translating Chinese legal materials; and to the many LLM alumni of Aberdeen Universitywho provided valuable assistance, particularly Zhou Xinguo, my research assistant.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 1

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    2/56

    framework effectively mandated by global capital markets and the residual power left

    to individual countries to pursue their own objectives. Third, the Chinese experience

    provides an interesting example of the interaction of two alternative approaches to

    corporate governance. One approach is to focus on the internal governance

    mechanisms of the company, and in particular the role allocated by the company

    constitution to the companys organs of governance such as the board of directors

    and shareholders meeting. Another approach is to focus on external regulation of the

    company (either by courts or regulatory agencies) through rules relating to matters

    such as employment contracts and environmental standards. The Chinese

    experience provides an interesting perspective particularly in relation to external

    regulation, which, unlike most countries in the west, has been pursued through

    extensive state ownership of listed companies and intensive regulation of the

    financial markets.

    This paper aims to examine the emergence of listed companies in China from the

    perspective of these issues. It begins by reviewing the current debate on comparative

    corporate governance. This is followed by a short history of enterprise reform in

    China and identification of the main features of the corporate and securities laws,

    which were introduced as part of the reform process. The role envisaged for private

    capital and shareholders in the Chinese system is then analysed. This leads on to a

    discussion of the manner in which the state regulates the operation of financial

    markets and directly influences listed companies through its role as controlling

    shareholder. An important element of the states control over listed companies is the

    legal framework for the operation of the board of directors, which is analysed from

    the perspective of the structure, composition and role of the board of directors.

    Finally, the paper considers the role of minority shareholders in Chinese listed

    companies in the context of recent research demonstrating close links between

    minority shareholders rights and the development of capital markets.

    A. ADAPTATION AND CONVERGENCE IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

    National systems of corporate governance can be placed at some point on an axis

    between two extremes, the shareholder model and the stakeholder model. The

    shareholder model takes the maximisation of shareholder wealth as the primary

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 2

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    3/56

    objective of the company. 1 In this model corporate governance is characterised

    largely as a set of solutions to the principal (shareholder)/agent (manager) problem

    which arises from the separation of ownership and control in the modern company.

    The essence of the principal/agent problem is that (a) the interests of the managers

    may not always be aligned with that of the owners and (b) it is not possible ex ante

    for the owners to specify the manner in which their capital should be employed (or

    put another way, the principal/agent relationship in the corporate context is a classic

    example of an incomplete contract). Corporate governance, as a set of solutions to

    the principal/agent problem, has three main aspects. First, aligning the incentives of

    managers with owners (e.g. through various forms of share ownership). Second,

    protecting shareholders from expropriation by managers (e.g. through self-dealing).

    Third, making managers accountable through mechanisms such as the market for

    corporate control, which is assumed to make poorly performing companies

    susceptible to takeover and the incumbent management susceptible to removal by a

    successful bidder. The shareholder model is essentially a creation of market

    expectation because it seems doubtful that there is (at least in the United Kingdom)

    any legal duty imposed on directors to maximize shareholder value. 2

    The stakeholder model takes a broader view of a company in which it is viewed as

    being responsible to a wider constituency. While this wider constituency may in the

    past have been regarded as open-ended, the new stakeholder model adopts a

    more restrictive approach, categorising stakeholders as those who have contributed

    firm-specific assets 3 or (in less technical terms) those who enter into long-term co-

    operative relationships with the company. 4 Employees are always regarded as falling

    into the category of stakeholders, but customers and suppliers may or may not be

    regarded as stakeholders depending on their relationship with the company. The

    nature of a stakeholders interest in a company differs from that of a shareholder in

    that (a) there is no convenient unit for measuring stakeholder interest analogous to

    1 For a justification of such an approach see A. K. Sundaram and A.C. Inkpen, The CorporateObjective Revisited at ssrn.com.2 See S. Worthington, Shares and shareholders: property, power and entitlement (part 2) 22(2)Company Lawyer 307 (2001).3 See M. Blair, Ownership and control: rethinking corporate governance for the twenty-first century,Brookings Institute, Washington DC (1995).4 See J. Parkinson, Company Law and Stakeholder Governance p149 in G. Kelly, D. Kelly & A.Gamble (eds.) Stakeholder Capitalism (Macmillan 1997). Parkinsons proposals for reform of UKCorporate Governance include (a) the reformulation of directors duties to accommodate stakeholdersinterests and (b) the introduction of a two-tier board to facilitate a stakeholder approach. See also G.

    Kelly and J. Parkinson, The Conceptual Foundations of the Company: a Pluralist Approach in J.Parkinson, A. Gamble & G. Kelly (eds.), The Political Economy of the Company, (Hart Publishing,2000).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 3

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    4/56

    the role performed by the company share (b) there is no presumption of equality

    between different stakeholders. In common law legal systems, the tendency has

    been for the shareholder model to predominate, but within that there have been, at

    different stages in the history of the company, differing perceptions of the respective

    roles of the shareholders and the board of directors. 5

    A number of influences have been identified in the development of national systems

    of corporate governance, although it is not always clear whether these factors are the

    cause or outcome of systems of corporate governance. 6 Berle & Means identified

    ownership structure as a key issue in 1931. 7 The consequences, in their view, of the

    widely-dispersed structure of share ownership which had emerged in the United

    States was that directors powers had expanded to a point where they were virtually

    in control of public companies, with shareholders being largely powerless. Berle &

    Means classic analysis is now seen as having less relevance in a world in which

    widely-dispersed share-ownership is the exception rather than the norm and in which

    it is no longer apparent that widely-dispersed share-ownership will lead per se to

    inferior monitoring of management by shareholders. 8 The more recent focus on

    ownership structure has been on two issues. First, to compare the operation of

    market-based systems of corporate governance, in which share-ownership is

    relatively dispersed and financial markets play a major role in monitoring company

    performance, with blockholder systems, in which most public companies have a

    controlling shareholder and banks play a more significant role in corporate

    governance than financial markets. 9 The main conclusion is that there no ideal model

    of corporate governance. Both systems have advantages and disadvantages. The

    market-based system emphasises disclosure of financial information so as to allow

    shareholders to make informed decisions but tends to encourage a short-term focus

    on performance and exit rather than voice. The blockholding system allows the

    development of long-term relationships between shareholders and companies but

    5 See J. Hill, Visions and Revisions of the Shareholder 68 Am Jnl Comp Law 39 (2000).6 See generally, M. Bradley, C. Schipani, A. Sundaram and J. Walsh, The Purposes andAccountability of the Corporation in Contemporary Society: Corporate Governance at a CrossRoads62(3) (1999) Law and Contemporary Problems 9.7 A Berle and G Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property (Transaction Publishers NJ1991)8 See H. Demsetz and K. Lehn, The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences,93(6 ) Jnl Political Economy 1155 (1985).9 See N. Dimsdale and M. Prevezer, Capital Markets and Corporate Governance (Clarendon Press,1994) for an extensive discussion of the relative roles of banks and financial markets in the UK,

    Germany and Japan. See M. Maher and T. Anderson, Corporate Governance: Effects on FirmPerformance and Economic Growth in Renneboog L., McCahery J., Moerland P. and Raaijmakers T.(eds.) Convergence and Diversity of Corporate Governance Regimes and Capital Markets (OUP 2000).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 4

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    5/56

    tends to suffer from lower standards of disclosure and the appropriation of private

    benefits by controlling shareholders at the expense of minorities. Second, to explain

    why the market-based system emerged in some countries and the blockholder

    system in others. Several theories have been put forward. Easterbrook and Fischel 10

    have argued that efficiency considerations are the main factor in the evolution of

    corporate governance structures: as the market prices the governance scheme,

    companies are forced to adopt the most efficient structure or else suffer a competitive

    disadvantage in the same was as if, for example, their raw materials were more

    expensive than those of competitors. 11 Roe has explained the evolution of the

    American system of corporate finance, characterised by relatively widely dispersed

    share ownership and reliance on the monitoring function of financial markets, as the

    result of politically-driven regulation of the financial sector, which was intended to

    prevent excessive economic power being concentrated in too few hands. Underlying

    the process of regulation was fear of the power of large corporations and trusts, an

    ideological bias in favour of small business and the influence of interest groups (such

    as small banks) who favoured fragmentation of financial power. 12 The evolution of

    shareholder voting rights in the United States and Europe has also been promoted as

    a significant influence in the development of national systems of corporate

    governance. 13 According to this view, the one-vote-per-share rule, adopted in

    corporation charters from the mid-nineteenth century onwards so as to displace the

    old common law default rule of one vote per member, combined with the emergence

    of anti-trust law later in the same century, contributed to the emergence of tightly-

    controlled and industrially-concentrated companies in the United States. In Europe,

    the survival of graduated voting scales into the twentieth century, combined with a

    lack of anti-trust law, resulted in a broader distribution of shareholder power and

    more reliance on cartels than mergers. A very different explanation is offered by La

    Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny (hereafter LLSV) who link the

    emergence of financial markets to the development of investor protection regimes in

    10 F. Easterbrook and D. Fischel, The Economic Structure of Corporate Law (Cambridge MA, HarvardUniversity Press 1991). 11 In its most extreme form, the Chicago school explanation of corporate governance formulated byEasterbrook and Fischel is an irrelevance theorem in which there is no need for the law to intervene incorporate governance structures as market forces will require them to evolve to their most efficientform. A milder version of this view is provided by Andrews, Corporate Governance Eludes the LegalMind 37 U Miami L. Rev. 213, 214-21 (1983).12 See M J Roe, A Political Theory of American Corporate Finance 91 Colum L. Rev. 10 (1991).13

    See C A Dunlavy, Corporate Governance in Late 19th

    Century Europe and the United States, TheCase of Shareholder Voting Rights in Hopt, Konda, Roe, Wymeersch, Prigge (eds) ComparativeCorporate Governance (OUP, 1998).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 5

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    6/56

    different countries and in particular to the protection given to minority shareholders. 14

    The essence of their thesis is that strong minority protection is necessary to

    encourage an equity culture and that unless this occurs, shareholders can only

    protect themselves through the accumulation of the power associated with

    blockholding. Path-dependence has also been viewed as a significant factor in

    determining national systems of corporate governance. One version of its role is that

    the corporate structures at any point in time will depend on those that existed at the

    outset, and that corporate rules affecting ownership will also depend on those initial

    structures. 15 Another is that differing national cultures and values can de directly

    associated with characteristics of a system of corporate governance and are likely to

    defeat attempts to import elements of governance systems from countries with

    fundamentally different culture and values. 16

    The extent to which there is, or should be, convergence in national systems of

    corporate governance towards one model is a matter of some dispute. Some

    commentators have argued for the superiority of the shareholder value system of

    corporate governance in the United States, pointing to its increasing acceptance

    worldwide and predicting its eventual worldwide hegemony. 17 Others have adopted a

    much more cautious view of convergence, recognising that there are unique

    institutional and cultural factors operating at the national level which preclude the

    importation of foreign governance systems. Put another way, for convergence to

    occur, features of corporate governance within one system must be detachable and

    so capable of transfer from one system to another: the more they are embedded in a

    unique institutional or cultural setting in one country the less detachable they will

    be. 18 To the extent that convergence is predicted, the main driving force identified is

    efficiency in governance structure, at least as viewed by investors in the global

    capital market in which the shareholder value model dominates. A broader view,

    however, would regard convergence in corporate governance as a sub-set of a more

    14 See LLSV, Legal Determinants of External Finance 52(3) Jnl of Finance 1131 (1997); Law andFinance 106(6) Jnl of Political Economy 1113 (1998); Investor Protection and CorporateGovernance at ssrn.com (update reference).15 See L.A. Bebchuk and MJ Roe, A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Ownership andGovernance Columbia Law School Center for Law and Economic Studies Working Paper no 131 atssrn.com.16 See A N Licht, The Mother of All Path Dependencies, Towards a Cross-Cultural Theory of Corporate Governance Systems at ssrn.com.17 See H. Hansmann and R. Kraakman, The End of History for Corporate Law at ssrn.com.18 See W. Bratton & J. McCahery, Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm:

    The Case against Global Cross Reference 38 Colum. J. Transnatl L. 213 , who present a useful matrixfor comparative corporate governance analysis at p17. See also E B Rock, Americas ShiftingFascination with Comparative Corporate Governance 74 Wash U.L.Q. 367.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 6

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    7/56

    extensive process of convergence in the structure and operation of capitalist systems.

    From this perspective, the main driving force is the speed of technological change,

    which, by making production more capital-intensive, encourages the globalisation of

    product and financial markets. 19

    If some degree of convergence can occur, what form will it take? Gilson provides a

    useful categorisation of the different forms of convergence that occur in the field of

    corporate regulation. Formal convergence involves change in the legal infrastructure

    and therefore requires political support and resort to the legislative process. This type

    of convergence is often associated with international harmonisation in the form of

    treaties, conventions or legislation made by supranational bodies. 20 The most

    significant step in this direction to date has been the limited harmonisation of

    company and securities law in the European Union although the proposals made by

    IOSCO for International Disclosure Standards may well represent a more significant

    future development for listed companies. 21 Functional convergence occurs without

    any formal legal change in circumstances in which the existing regulatory

    mechanisms are sufficiently flexible to respond to new circumstances without the

    need for formal change. The process by which the Combined Code of Corporate

    Governance has been developed and implemented in the United Kingdom could be

    cited as an example of such a process: the development occurred outside the formal

    legal and regulatory framework and the Code itself is appended to but does not form

    part of the UKLA Listing Rules. Contractual convergence occurs when the existing

    regulatory framework lacks the flexibility to adapt to new circumstances without

    formal changes and an ad hoc solution is adopted through the medium of contract. 22

    Contractual techniques can move relatively easily from country to country without any

    19 See S. Strange, The Future of Global Capitalism; or, will divergence persist forever? in C. Crouch& W. Streeck, Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, Mapping Convergence and Diversity (Sage

    Publications 1997). Associated with the process of convergence, in Stranges view, are (a) a decline instate sovereignty (b) asymmetry of regulatory power among states (with the USA predominant) (c)denationalization of firms, who adopt a multinational perspective (d) increased government reliance onfinancial markets as a result of the latters role in funding current spending through government bondissues.20 Proposals for formal convergence can also emerge from private sources: see e.g. Black &Kraakmans proposal for a self-enforcing model of corporate law, developed from models adopted inthe privatization process in eastern Europe (B. Black and R. Kraakman, A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law 109 Harv. L. Rev. 1911). See also J. Coffee Jnr. The Rise of Dispersed Ownership:The Role of Law and the Separation of Ownership and Control at ssrn.com.21 The proposal aims to establish minimum international standards for listing particulars andprospectuses, thereby making possible multiple listing based on a single document. See D W Arner,Globalization and Financial Markets: An International Passport for Securities Offerings? ???22

    Gilson cites as an example the contract terms that are typically adopted in venture capital limitedpartnerships providing for distribution of the proceeds of investments that become liquid and theliquidation of the partnership after a fixed period.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 7

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    8/56

    need for change in the legal or regulatory framework. On the one hand, widespread

    usage of ad hoc contractual governance techniques may indicate a failure of formal

    legal and regulatory techniques to deliver appropriate forms of governance

    mechanism. On the other hand, such usage may indicate the superiority of

    contractual techniques as a governance mechanism by comparison with regulation

    (e.g. as a result of their inherent adaptability) and suggest a re-evaluation of the

    extent to which regulation is appropriate. Such an assessment of the appropriate role

    of regulation by comparison with private ordering through contract parallels the

    debate in company law over the appropriate balance between mandatory and default

    rules. 23

    Transposing this background to the context of corporate governance in Chinese

    listed companies, a number of issues emerge. First the institutional and cultural

    setting in China is quite different to the west and to the countries of the former Soviet

    bloc. China has not, as was the case in the former Soviet-bloc countries, undergone

    a rapid transition from a planned economy to a market economy. Market-based

    reforms and adoption of the corporate form for enterprises were adopted in China as

    a pragmatic solution to poor economic performance under state planning. 24 They

    were grafted onto an ideological position that remained essentially collectivist and

    socialist in its outlook. 25 Experimentation with the corporate form in China therefore

    provides some indication of the inherent adaptability of the corporate form to

    accommodate considerations wider than those dominating the shareholder value

    model of corporate governance that is prevalent in the west. Second, Chinese listed

    companies provide a practical example of the extent to which the global capital

    market can drive convergence in corporate governance in an ideological environment

    in which markets are regarded as means to end in a socialist society rather than an

    end in themselves. This helps answer the question of the extent to which corporate

    governance features are portable. It also provides some indication of how the overallsystem of enterprise organisation can be structured within a socialist society so as to

    accommodate global capitalism but allow the survival of other forms of organisation

    that are more inherently socialist in their structure.

    23 See J. Gordon, The Mandatory Structure of Corporate Law (1989) 89 Columbia Law Review 1549.24 The inherent pragmatism of Chinas reform process is typified by the analogy used by DengXiaoping in 1962 to refer to reform of the system of production. He used a popular Sichuan saying, Itdoes not matter if it is a yellow cat or a black cat as long as it catches mice. While this may havelacked resonance in the 1960s (Deng was purged during the Cultural Revolution), it later came totypify the post-1978 reform process. See Lan Cao, The Cat that Catches Mice: Chinas Challenge tothe Dominant Privatization Model (1995) 21 Brook. J. Intl L 97.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 8

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    9/56

    B. ENTERPRISE REFORM IN CHINA

    The process of economic liberalization in China, from which listed companies

    eventually emerged, can be traced back to 1978 when the Communist Party resolved,

    beginning in 1979, to focus the party's work on "socialist modernization". 26 This

    change in policy away from state control of the economy and the effective exclusion

    of private enterprise, recognized that China's economy had under performed for

    many years, a realisation made particularly clear by the close proximity of several

    examples of strong economic performance, such as Taiwan, Korea, Hong Kong and

    Singapore (the four little dragons). The most important aspect of the modernization

    was the gradual recognition of the role of private enterprise.

    Practical development occurred first in the form of authorisation being given for

    individual businesses to engage a maximum of five employees. 27 The 1982

    Constitution recognized the role of individual business by providing for the protection

    of its lawful interests. In association with reform of the rural economy, in which the

    majority of the Chinese population is employed, the relaxation of state control

    resulted in the emergence in the 1980s of a new and rapidly growing non-state

    sector in which Town and Village Enterprises (TVEs) 28 and joint ventures with foreign

    capital participation played a significant role. By 1988, the acceptance of the role of

    private business was sufficient to result in an amendment to the Constitution so as to

    refer expressly to the role of the private economy as a complement to the socialist

    economy. 29 Later in 1988 the State Council 30 provided a basis for the authorisation

    25 For a review of the ideological context within which enterprise reform in China has been pursued,see G. Crane, Globalization in China 4(2) New Political Economy (1995) 215.26 See A W Connor, "To get Rich is Precarious: Regulation of Private Enterprise in the People's

    Republic of China", Journal of Chinese Law , Spring 1991 1.27 For a discussion of these regulations and more generally on the history of the emergence of privatebusiness in China see W. Kraus, Private Business in China (University of Hawaii Press 1991).28 TVEs are collective enterprises under the ownership and nominal control of governments at the localtownship, provincial and village level. They emerged as the post-1978 reforms permitted localgovernments to promote and engage in business. For an assessment of their significance to the Chineseeconomy, see H G Broadman, The Businesses of the Chinese State at ssrn.com. On TVE ownershipstructure, see H. Williams, Property Rights and Legal Reform in Township and Village Enterprises inChina 2 Asia-Pacific Law and Policy Jnl 227 (2001).29 The relevant article (11) was subsequently amended in 1999 to provide greater emphasis to theprivate sector. The words The individual economy of urban and rural working people, operatingwithin the limits prescribed by law, is a complement to the Socialist public economy was replaced bythe words the non-public sector, including individual and private businesses, is an important

    component to the socialist market economy. See the Constitution of the PRC athttp://www.qis.net/chinalaw and J. Chen, Chinese Law, Towards an Understanding of Chinese Law Its Nature and Development (Kluwer 1999) Chap 3 (Constitutional Law).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 9

    http://www.qis.net/chinalawhttp://www.qis.net/chinalaw
  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    10/56

    and control of private businesses that employed more than eight people by issuing

    the Preliminary Regulations for Private Business. In 1992, the Fourteenth National

    Congress of the Communist Party of China adopted the policy of establishing a

    socialist market system and gave priority to reforming State Owned Enterprises

    (SOEs). 31 The main focus was on separating SOEs from the government

    bureaucracy within which they had operated in the past and consequently to allow

    them to operate independently from the government. 32

    This policy was pursued in four different ways. 33 First, the introduction of business

    autonomy: the State Enterprise Law of 1988 recognised SOEs as legal persons

    separate from the state and defined the operational spheres of autonomy of SOEs

    while a "contract responsibility system" was introduced to enhance the accountability

    of SOE management. 34 This was followed by the introduction of fourteen

    autonomous rights for SOEs in 1992, intended to enhance the autonomy of SOE

    managements. Second, the transformation of SOEs into shareholding companies, a

    process generally referred to as corporatization. This policy was implemented by a

    series of administrative measures which recognised and created mandatory standard

    forms for two types of company: Limited Liability Companies, which are broadly

    comparable to private companies in the UK and Joint Stock Companies which are

    broadly comparable to public companies in the UK. 35 Corporatization had the effect

    30 The State Council is the executive body of the National Peoples Congress (NPC), which is thesupreme organ of state power (article 57 of the PRC Constitution). It includes the Premier, Vice-Premier and Ministers. As the NPC meets only once a year for several weeks, much of the detail of lawmaking is delegated to the State Council.31 State-owned enterprises are those with at least 51% state ownership and annual sales of at least RMB5m (US$0.6m approx). In principle, this definition can include listed companies but the term is mostcommonly applied to state enterprises that have not been listed.32 For a discussion of the problems which had in the past plagued SOEs and held back progress in theChinese economy see Mai Yinhua & F. Perkins, China's State Owned Enterprises, (EEAU Briefing

    Paper No 7, Dept. of Foreign Affairs and Trade Australia 1997). For an assessment of the currentposition of SOEs in the Chinese economy see H.G. Boardman, The Business (es) of the ChineseState at ssrn.com.33 See China's Management of Enterprise Assets: The State as Shareholder (World Bank CountryReport, 1997 Washington DC).34 The contract responsibility system, which had already been introduced prior to widespreadcorporatization with objective of improving accountability, improved SOE performance. See Groves,Hong, McMillan & Naughton, "Autonomy and Incentives in Chinese State Enterprises" 109(1)Quarterly Journal of Economics (1994). See also Lan Cao (above n24) for a discussion of the systemin rural reform.35 The relevant measures were mainly (1) The Measures for Experimental Joint Stock Enterprises (May15, 1992) issued jointly by the State Commission for the Restructuring of the Economic System, TheState Economic Planning Commission, the Ministry of Finance, the Peoples Bank of China (The

    Central Bank) and the Production Office of the State Council (2) The Opinions for the Standardizationof the Experimental Joint Stock Companies (May 15, 1992) issued by the State Commission for theRestructuring of the Economic System (3) The Opinions for the Standardization of the Limited

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 10

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    11/56

    of formalising the separation of state from SOEs, as the state became a shareholder

    rather than the direct owner of productive assets. This resulted in state control having

    to be directed through the mechanisms provided by corporate law rather than being a

    simple emanation of state authority. It also provided a long-term strategy for

    integrating the state-owned sector of the economy into the global capital market, a

    necessary adjustment if China were to fully embrace the concept of a market-

    economy. The more immediate reasons for the process of corporatization were,

    however, the inability of state firms to remain self-financing and solvent and the

    desire of the state to tap into a pool of private capital in the non-state sector outside

    its control. 36 The availability of a substantial pool of private capital, held primarily in

    bank deposits 37 , made it possible for the state to envisage a re-organisation of SOEs

    that involved a substantial injection of new capital and not simply a re-allocation of

    ownership rights through privatization. The third element of the policy was

    clarification of the role of the state as owner. The Supervision Regulations 38

    introduced in 1994 provide the legal basis for the system under which the state owns

    and supervises companies. State ownership is organised through a network of

    organisations at the national, provincial, municipal and district level. Ultimate

    responsibility rests with the State Council, which, as representative of the people, is

    the ultimate owner of the state shareholdings. The fourth element of the policy was

    clarification of the role of the state as regulator. This was necessary because in the

    past the role of the state as regulator and owner had been merged. 39 The opening-up

    of ownership in SOEs to the public, through shareholding, in principle required that

    the role of the state as regulator and owner be separated, although, as noted later,

    there remains some confusion between these roles.

    Mass privatization, in the form pursued in Russia and other "eastern-bloc" countries 40 ,

    has not been a feature of the re-organization of state owned enterprises in China

    Liability Companies (May 15, 1992) issued by the State Commission for the Restructuring of theEconomic System.36 See Lan Cao (above n24).37 By 1996, bank deposits represented 56% of GDP; see R Gordon and Wei Li, Government as aDiscriminating Monopolist in the Financial Market: The Case of China Darden Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Virginia Working Paper No 01-20 at ssrn.com.38 Regulations Governing the Supervision and Management of State-Owned Enterprises' Property(1994).39 The World Bank commented in 1997 (above n33 at p38) on the confusion of the role of governmentas shareholder and regulator "Overall, in the absence of more substantive "separation", these[ownership] structures face inherent internal contradictions between governmental and shareholder-ownership incentives. In such circumstances, the scope of reform they can accomplish is very narrow."40

    See J. Nellis, The World Bank, Privatization and Enterprise Reform in Transition Economies: ARetrospective Analysis (at ssrn.com), for an account of privatization in Poland, Czechoslovakia andRussia. The rationale for such mass privatization is explained by Wardle and Towle as follows: ".. it

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 11

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    12/56

    even when those enterprises have been transformed into listed companies.

    Corporatized SOEs have been listed on the Stock Exchanges and have raised new

    capital but the state has generally retained a controlling shareholding. In effect, China

    has rejected the conventional wisdom 41 underlying privatization in Russia and

    elsewhere, that fundamental changes in ownership rights are necessary to transform

    the performance of inefficient state enterprises. 42 The dominant model of privatization

    was the big-bang approach in which there was a rapid change from state planning to

    a market economy dominated by newly privatized companies. What emerged in

    China differed in several important respects. 43 First, enterprise reform left in place a

    wholly state-owned but organisationally reformed sector, which still plays an

    important, albeit reduced, role in the economy. Second, there emerged from the

    ranks of SOEs a group of companies which were listed on the stock exchanges and

    issued shares to the public, but in which the state was controlling shareholder. Third,

    the reform process gave rise to a vibrant non-state sector, comprising listed

    companies with no state interest, TVEs and joint ventures, which have enjoyed rapid

    growth. 44

    C. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK IN CHINA

    Two features of a particularly Chinese character were evident in the development of

    shareholding companies. The first was that the formal legal framework, represented

    by the company law, was put in place at a relatively late stage. By the time the

    serves the political purpose of entrenching the break with the past by giving each citizen theopportunity to have a personal stake in their country's income-producing assets, thereby reducingsupport for any future attempts to nationalize. It also provides an expectant public with a tangible signof the political changes and compensation for past hardship and deprivation of individual rights" (D.Wardle and N. Towle, "Global Privatization" in International Privatization p7 (eds. D. Campbell and B.

    Hollywood, Kluwer, London 1996).41 The conventional wisdom was evident in the approach of the World Bank and was supported by abackground of successful privatization in developed economies such as the UK Canada and NewZealand as well as a growing academic literature linking privatization with improved financialperformance. See J. Nellis (above, note?) and S Djakov and P Murrell, The Determinants of Enterprise Restructuring in Transition Economies World Bank. September 2000. (see p76 of NellisArticle).42 For a discussion of the potential effects of privatization on the economy, see A. Schipke, Why doGovernments Divest? The Macroeconomics Of Privatization (Springer-Verlag, Berlin-Heidelberg,2001) and J.J. Laffont and J. Tirole, "Privatization and Incentives", 7 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 84-105.43 For a general discussion see Lan Cao (above n24).44 While SOEs share of the output of Chinese industrial enterprises fell from 47% to 28% between

    1993 and 1999, the share of individually owned enterprises rose from 8% to 18%, collectives(including TVEs) from 34% to 35% and others (including companies with either a minority or nostate shareholding) from 11% to 26%. See H G Boardman (above n32).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 12

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    13/56

    Company Law 45 became effective on 1 July 1994, many companies had already

    been established and the process of corporatization of SOEs was well established.

    The formation of companies had in fact even preceded the "Standard Opinions" 46 ,

    with several companies being formed in the 1980s 47 . This pattern of development

    can be associated with the Chinese tendency to subordinate law to government (and

    hence party) authority and to exercise detailed administrative control over economic

    activities rather than permitting activity within a range defined by law. The need to

    take account of the socialist structure into which the corporate form was being

    introduced also delayed the passage of the Company Law. The second feature is the

    experimental and localized manner in which the early forms of regulation of

    shareholding companies was developed. Particularly significant in this respect were

    the regulations 48 adopted in Shanghai, which had strong pre-communist trading links

    with the west, and Shenzhen, a recently established city designated as a "special

    economic zone (SEZ)" 49 , occupying an important strategic position on the Pearl River

    delta between Hong Kong and Guangzhou. This process reflected both the

    considerable decentralization 50 of government in China to the provincial level

    (permitting provincial and city authorities to introduce such regulations) and also a

    willingness to experiment with the corporate form at a local level before adopting a

    national measure.

    The Chinese Company Law has a number of distinctive features.

    45 For an assessment of the company law see K.T. W. Ong and C.R. Baxter, "A comparative study of the fundamental elements of Chinese and English Company Law" 48 ICLQ 88 (1999); N.C. Howson,

    "China's Company Law: One Step Forward, Two Steps Back? A Modest Complaint" 11:1 Columbia Journal of Asian Law 127 (1997); Png Cheong Ann, "Some concerns about Chinese company law",17(7) Company Lawyer 199 (1996); Lawrence Liu, Chinese Characteristics Compared: A Legal andPolicy Perspective of Corporate Finance and Governance in Taiwan and China at ssrn.com.46 These were the administrative regulations that preceded the Company Law. See footnote 35 above.47 See Fang Liufang, Chinas Corporatization Experiment (1995) 5 Duke J. Comp. & Intl L. 149.Companies created under ad hoc administrative measures in the 1980s and the 1992 "StandardOpinions" are the subject of a "grandfathering" provision in article 229 of the company law, whichprovides that such companies shall continue to be recognized but are required to meet the requirementsof the company law within a timescale set by the State Council.48 The Shanghai and Shenzhen Trial Measures (sometimes referred to as the Interim Measures).49 Shenzhen was one of five SEZs, the others being Xiamen in Fujian Province, Zhuhau, Shantou inGuangdong Province and (later) Hainan Island. The purpose of the SEZs was to facilitate interaction

    with the global economy on a limited basis.50 See S. Breslin, Decentralization, Globalization and Chinas Partial Re-engagement with the GlobalEconomy 5(2) New Political Economy (2000) 205 for a discussion of this process.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 13

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    14/56

    (a) There is extensive state regulation of company formation. Approval

    must be obtained from the relevant government departments in addition to

    satisfying the requirements of the company law. 51

    (b) Two types of company can be formed with private capital. They bear

    some resemblance to private and public companies in the UK but there

    are some differences. A limited liability company (LLC) must have

    between two and fifty shareholders and cannot offer its shares to the

    public. Shareholders have pre-emption rights over any sale of shares by

    another shareholder, resulting in a closed shareholding structure. Joint

    Stock Companies (JSCs, sometimes referred to as companies limited by

    shares) are designed to allow capital to be raised through public share

    issues. JSCs can be formed either by the public subscription method or

    the promotion method. The former requires no less than 35% of the

    capital to be subscribed by the promoters (the remaining 65% being

    offered to the public) whereas the latter involves the promoters taking up

    100% of the shares. Formation by the promotion method does not in itself

    require listing, but as a public offering normally follows formation by the

    promotion method, it is normal for such JSCs to be listed.

    (c) The Chinese concept of the legal personality of a company differs from

    western models. This is most apparent in two areas. First, every company

    must have a legal representative, who is the natural person authorised

    to act on behalf of the company. The legal representative bears greater

    liability than an ordinary director of a Chinese company (both in respect of

    civil and criminal law) and also greater liability than a director in a UK

    company. 52 This qualifies the separate legal liability of the company by

    interposing a human agent who acts as the personification of the

    company. Second, the company law 53 provides that the state assets of a

    company belong to the State. This provision appears to have resultedfrom confusion over the ownership rights of the state in former SOEs.

    Following corporatization, the state exchanged direct property rights over

    enterprise assets for a shareholding in a company that has separate legal

    personality and owns the enterprise assets. By recognising continuing

    51 See article 77 (approval) and article 73 (conditions) in respect of JSCs. The relevant governmentdepartments are the State Administration of Industry and Commerce (SAIC) or the Ministry of Foreign

    Trade and Economic Co-operation (MOFTEC) for foreign-owned companies.52 See Ong and Baxter (above n45) p119.53 Article 4.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 14

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    15/56

    state ownership over assets in companies, the company law creates

    confusion over property rights. 54

    (d) There is more extensive reliance on mandatory rules in the structure of

    Chinese company law than is the case in common law jurisdictions,

    indicating a rejection of the contractarian model of company law. 55 This is

    evident both in the Company Law itself and in the mandatory nature of the

    articles of association. The company law, for example, requires

    administrative approval for the incorporation of a company and sets

    financial conditions for companies issuing shares. Such controls

    generally have no counterpart in the west. All Chinese listed companies

    are required to adopt standard articles of association and changes are

    subject to regulatory approval 56 , with the result that tailoring of the

    governance structure to individual circumstances is limited. The standard

    articles differ for domestic and overseas companies. 57 There is also

    extensive reliance on the criminal law to punish breaches of the company

    law, rather than reliance on private action.

    (e) Despite the rejection of a contractarian model of company law

    apparent in the heavy reliance on mandatory rules, the Articles of

    Association have a contractual status that appears to be even more

    extensive than the concept of the articles as "statutory contract" in the UK.

    The latter is a contract between the company and shareholders and

    between shareholders inter se. The standard articles (both domestic and

    overseas 58) envisage a contract with the following pattern of enforcement:

    company versus shareholder (and vice-versa); shareholder versus

    shareholder; shareholder versus director, supervisor, manager or other

    54 On this issue, and its implications for rights on winding-up, see Howson (above n45) p142 and PngCheong Ann, Some Concerns about Chinese Company Law (1996) 17(7) Co Law 199,200.55 On models of company law and the structure of its rules see I MacNeil, Company Law Rules: AnAssessment from the Perspective of Incomplete Contract Theory 1 Jnl Corporate Law Studies 107(2001). Greater use of mandatory rules in transition countries has been justified by reference to theneed to protect minority shareholders and creditors: see J. Avilov, General Principles of CompanyLaw for Transition Economies 24 J. Corp. L 196 (1999).56 Article 11 of the Company Law.57 The articles for companies listed on a domestic exchange are contained in the China SecuritiesRegulatory Commission (CSRC) measure Guidance on the Articles of Association of domestic listedcompanies (16 Dec 1997). The overseas provisions are contained in measure Mandatory Provisionsin Articles of Association of Companies Listed Overseas (promulgated 27 Aug 1994 by the Securities

    Committee of the State Council, reproduced in I A Tokley and T Ravn, Company and Securities law inChina, Sweet & Maxwell Asia 1998, p219).58 Article 10 of the domestic articles and article 7 of the overseas articles.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 15

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    16/56

    senior management personnel. 59 These rights are in addition to (a) article

    111 of the company law which provides for shareholders to apply for an

    injunction to prevent the implementation of resolutions of the

    shareholders' meeting which violate law or administrative regulations (b)

    article 118 which provides that directors shall be responsible for

    resolutions which violate law, administrative regulations or the articles of

    association and cause loss to the company.

    (f) The roles of shareholders and board differ from western models in that

    shareholders have more extensive control. This is discussed in more

    detail in part G.

    (g) Chinese companies are required to limit their business to that

    described in the scope of business at the time of registration (or as

    subsequently amended). Contracts outside the scope of business are

    illegal contracts and therefore not enforceable. There are no provisions

    that protect third parties who contract innocently with a company acting

    outside its scope of business. 60

    (h) The participation of workers in companies is ensured through the

    requirement for JSCs to have a supervisory board that includes employee

    representatives. 61 The board of directors is accountable to the supervisory

    board, whose members are entitled to attend meeting of the board of

    directors in a non-voting capacity. The Company Law also requires the

    Board of Directors to consult employees and trade unions on matters

    affecting their interests. 62

    The development of a system of securities law and regulation of securities markets

    was a natural accompaniment to the development of corporate law because the

    objective of transforming some of the (substantial) savings in the personal sector of

    the economy into investment in (corporatized and organizationally transformed)SOEs could only be met through the creation of securities markets. Another

    consideration was that securities markets made it easier for the state to raise loans,

    through the issue of bonds to domestic and international investors, to fund public

    59 The potential difficulties arising from this provision are discussed by Tokley and Ravn (above n57 atp100).60 Howson (above n45), p150, notes that the 1992 Standard Opinion provided for liability for thoseparties responsible for companies acting outside of their registered scope of business. The CompanyLaw has no such provision.61 Article 124 of the Company Law.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 16

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    17/56

    spending. Shanghai and Shenzhen were selected as locations for experimentation in

    the issue of shares and the first issue of shares occurred in Shanghai in 1984, with

    trading in shares beginning in 1986. The same pattern evident in the development of

    corporate law was repeated in respect of securities law and regulation. Thus, the

    stock exchanges in Shanghai and Shenzhen were established and operating prior to

    the adoption of national measures governing securities markets. 63 At this stage,

    regulation of the securities markets was in the hands of the Shenzhen municipality

    and the provincial government in Shanghai. National measures were introduced in

    May 1992 when The State Council promulgated the Share System Experimental

    Procedure of the PRC 64 , which set out the general objectives for stock-issuing

    enterprises and the principles by which the national securities markets were to be

    governed. 65 More detailed regulation followed in the form of the Provisional

    Regulations on the Administration of Issuing and Trading of Shares, promulgated by

    the State Council in April 1993. For share issues on the domestic stock exchanges,

    the Provisional Regulations were the main source of law until the Securities Law

    finally took effect on 1 July 1999. 66

    An examination of the securities law 67 reveals much less in the way of adaptation to

    Chinese circumstances than in the case of the company law. The extensive

    regulation of the process of listing and issuing securities is the most obvious

    difference between China and the west. While all countries regulate this process,

    62 Article 121 of the Company Law. This represents a dilution of the power previously held by workersin SOEs, such as the right to dismiss directors subject to government approval. See Ong and Baxter(above n45) p114.63 The Shanghai Stock Exchange (SSE) was established in 1984 and officially opened in December1990. The Shenzhen Stock Exchange (SZE) was established in 1987 and officially opened on 3 July1991. Lan Cao (above n24) notes that officials of the Shenzhen Special Economic Zone decidedunilaterally to open a Stock Exchange without Beijings approval. Beijings response was not to stopthe process but simply to delay the opening for a few months.64

    Two notices gave effect to the procedure. First, the Notice of the Central Office of the State CouncilConcerning Problems in Share System Experiment Enterprises Issuing Stock to the Public, 1990,stating that "Other than the two stock exchanges at Shanghai and Shenzhen which have already beenpermitted to issue shares to society, all others which have been approved by local governments butwhich have not been through the approval procedures of the concerned ministries and agencies of thecentral government, must within the designated period report to the State Commission on Reform of the Economic System, the State Bureau for the Management of State Property, and the People's Bank of China to once again undertake approval procedures."Second, the Notice of the State Commission on Reforming the Economic System Concerning

    Renewed Approval for Share System Experiment Enterprises Issuing Shares to Society, reprintedCollection of Policies, Laws and Regulations for Share System Experiments (Shanghai Office forReform of the Economic System ed., 1992).65 See Fang Liufang, Chinas Corporatization Experiment 5 Duke J. Comp. & Intl L 149 (1995).66

    These regulations were not repealed following the introduction of the Securities Law and in practiceare still followed by securities lawyers.67 See generally Zhu Sanzhu, Securities Regulation in China (Simmonds & Hill Publishing Ltd., 2000).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 17

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    18/56

    China is distinctive in that it has favoured regulation over market forces in respect of

    a number of issues, discussed below in part E. The separation of regulation of the

    main financial sectors in China is a feature of many other regulatory systems, despite

    being recently abandoned in the United Kingdom. The China Securities Regulatory

    Commission (CSRC) is designated as the regulator for securities activities. 68 The

    Securities Law provides wide-ranging powers to the CSRC in respect of authorisation,

    rule making, investigation and enforcement of all aspects of the securities market. 69

    In the past, the Central Bank (the People's Bank of China) had been responsible for

    the entire system of financial regulation. From 1998, following the east Asian financial

    crisis, the government began to restructure the financial system and pursued a policy

    of separation of regulation of the four main financial sectors - banking, securities,

    insurance and trust 70 . This resulted in the emergence of the CSRC in its current form,

    the creation of a new regulator for the insurance sector (the China Insurance

    Regulatory Commission, CIRC) and the limitation of the regulatory role of the central

    bank to banking and trust business. However, while each financial sector is

    separately regulated, China has not required that ownership of enterprises operating

    in these sectors be separated, as was the case in the USA for many years prior to

    the repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act. 71

    In other respects, the Chinese securities law follows very closely the pattern of

    western models. This characteristic may be inherent in the nature of securities law.

    To the extent that it represents entry into the global capital market, there is less room

    for adaptation than in the case of company law. The tendency towards convergence

    with western models becomes even more apparent at the level of stock exchange

    listing rules where convergence with international norms is even more evident. 72 As

    noted elsewhere 73 , there appears to be a pyramid structure in corporate regulation in

    which there is some room for adaptation at the lowest level (company law) less in the

    68 Article 7 of the Securities Law. On the constitutional position of the CSRC and SCSC, see Zhu(above n67) chapter 3. The regulatory structure is complicated by the existence of local securitiescommissions and the involvement in securities markets of the State Commission for Restructuring theEconomic System, the State Planning Commission and the State Bureau for the Administration of StateAssets.69 See Chapter 10 of the Securities Law in Zhu Sanzhu, Securities Regulation in China (TransnationalPublishers, 2000).70 Article 6 of the Securities Law now gives effect to the policy of separate regulation of each financialsector.71 An example of cross-ownership of different financial activities is the Pinan Group based in Shenzhen,which operates in the trust, insurance and securities sectors.72 See A Lau, The new Shanghai Stock Exchange Listing Rules: an egg hatched or an egg within an

    egg? (1999) 20(7) Co Law 243.73 See I MacNeil and A Lau, International Corporate Regulation: Listing Rules and OverseasCompanies 50(4) ICLQ 787 (2001).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 18

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    19/56

    intermediate level (securities law and regulation) and almost none at the top level

    (listing rules).

    The most recent development in the legal framework of corporate governance in

    China is the promulgation by the CSRC of corporate governance guidelines for listed

    companies. 74 The guidelines contain 95 articles and, once implemented, will

    represent a substantial modernisation of corporate governance in Chinese Listed

    companies. The Guidelines have several notable characteristics. First, there is

    considerable evidence of convergence with western models of corporate governance

    as almost all the articles contained in the guidance have parallel provisions in the law

    or codes of corporate governance of the United Kingdom or United States. Second,

    there is a clear attempt to strengthen the independence of listed companies from

    controlling shareholders. This represents a limitation of the role of the state as

    controlling shareholder and shows willingness on the part of the state to subordinate

    its own interests as shareholder to the introduction of an effective system of

    corporate governance. This differs to the approach taken at the time of the

    introduction of the company and securities law, when there was greater emphasis on

    protecting the role of the state. Third, there is no clear demarcation between

    corporate and securities law and administrative regulations introduced by the CSRC.

    This is evident in the fact that several of the provisions of the Guidelines (e.g. the

    requirement in article 31 to use cumulative voting to elect directors in companies with

    a controlling shareholder)

    represent changes to the company law, a point made clear by the preamble to the

    Guidelines, which requires amendment of articles of association that do not comply

    with the Guidelines. This confusion of the legal basis of rules is a retrograde step,

    reminiscent of the period before the introduction of the company and securities laws,

    when administrative regulations were the only basis for the organisation of

    shareholding companies. It would be better if the company and securities law wereamended to contain those articles of the Guidelines in respect of which there is an

    overlap, leaving the Guidelines to cover points not included in the company or

    securities law.

    D. PRIVATE CAPITAL AND SHAREHOLDING

    74 The Notice Concerning the Announcement of Corporate Governance Guidelines for ListedCompanies, promulgated by the CSRC on 7 January 2002 and effective from that date.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 19

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    20/56

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    21/56

    business are exercised by local government officials and the significance of extended

    family connections in business networks. 79

    Second, it is evident in the regulatory regimes for both domestic and foreign capital

    that a primary concern was to protect the control of the state over the economy. 80

    The presence of the state as controlling shareholder in most listed companies in

    China made the adoption of a shareholder primacy model of corporate governance

    relatively attractive because it provided continuity with the previous system in which

    the state directly owned and controlled SOEs. Perversely, and in contrast to the

    historical developments from which it emerged in the United Kingdom, the

    shareholder primacy model was a mechanism by which the state could pursue the

    socialist market objective through its controlling interests in most listed companies.

    It leaves open the question, however, if there will be any substance left to the

    socialist market objective when (as seems likely) the state reduces or even

    completely ends its direct ownership of shares in listed companies. 81

    For small unincorporated businesses, the introduction of private capital mainly

    required the sanctioning of the employment of a limited number of workers, which

    had generally not been possible under the stricter interpretation of Communist

    principles that had previously prevailed. There were no issues here regarding

    transfer of state assets. Corporatization of SOEs, however, was more complicated as

    reform of the old enterprise system of necessity involved some change in the rights

    over SOEs previously vested in the state. Without such a change it would not be

    possible for the company form to be introduced as a method of business organisation.

    Prior to corporatization, SOEs could be regarded as part of the state 82 but once

    corporatized they have a separate legal personality and therefore the role of the state

    as shareholder/owner must be clarified and in particular it must be distinguished from

    the role of the state as regulator.83

    There were several reasons for this. First, there

    79 See Teemu Ruskola, Conceptualizing Corporations and Kinship: Comparative Law andDevelopment Theory in a Chinese Perspective 52(6) Stanford Law Review (2000) 1599.80 See the constitutional provisions discussed at note 29 above.81 This is discussed in more detail below.82 The State Enterprise Law of 1988 recognised SOEs as legal persons, but they were still at that stagewholly owned by the state and had not yet been corporatized.83 This was the conventional view articulated in Communist Party Policy and endorsed by internationaladvisers such as the World Bank. Others regarded the property rights issue as less significant. Simontook a pessimistic view of the effect of corporatization on property rights (W H Simon, The LegalStructure of the Chinese Socialist Market Enterprise 21 Iowa J. Corp L. 267). He argued that property

    rights in the SOE and TVE structures of the 1980's were relatively clear, with managers and workershaving strong control and income rights but relatively weak capital rights, the latter being preserved forthe benefit of the society at large. He saw the main problem as that of enforcing the rights against, for

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 21

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    22/56

    was a perceived need to ensure that the process of corporatization did not result in

    the misappropriation or transfer at an undervalue of state assets. 84 Second,

    clarification of property rights was necessary to make possible the sale of shares in

    SOEs to outside shareholders. In principle, that could only occur in an environment in

    which the role of the state was re-defined in a manner in which the rights of new

    shareholders were made clear. Third, the introduction of a market-based system

    involved a recognition that enterprises would be formed in which the state had no

    ownership interest and therefore it would no longer be possible for the state to

    continue to act in relation to these enterprises in the mixed role of owner and

    regulator. Fourth, although in principle all productive assets were owned by the state,

    corporatization required identification of which government department or

    ministry/agency was an investor in a particular SOE, so as to make clear to whom

    property rights were being assigned.

    While, in the main, the rights of shareholders are made clear by the company law,

    there remain some problems. First, the ownership rights of the state in respect of

    assets owned by SOEs that have been coporatized is not entirely clear. Article 4 of

    the Company Law provides that The State assets of a company belong to the State.

    Howson described this provision as nonsense and noted that there was no similar

    provision in the Standard opinion that preceded the Company Law. 85 It is difficult to

    disagree with this conclusion as it does not seem possible for assets that belong to a

    company, as a separate legal person, to be owned by another entity at the same time.

    The provision confuses the direct ownership rights previously held by the state over

    SOE assets with the ownership rights now held by the state in the form of

    shareholding. 86It does not, however, appear to have given rise to much practical

    example, managers who abused their position. Simon argued that the western experience in developingcompany law to facilitate the participation of many small investors in an enterprise was of littlerelevance to China where the expectation is that the state will remain the controlling shareholder inmost listed companies. It was therefore not surprising that the rights of minority shareholders remainedweak and uncertain even after the introduction of the company law, as the main objective of thecompany law was to reduce the state shareholding while still leaving the state in control. Lan Cao,CAT article, (above n24) discussing TVEs, also argued that the clarification of property rights was nota critical issue.84 As discussed below, some of this concern was misplaced as it resulted from a failure to recognize thefundamental change in ownership structure resulting from corporatization, which replaced direct stateownership of assets with shareholdings.85 See Howson fn p 142.86 It is an explicit example in Chinese law of an implicit tendency noted by Ireland in respect of English

    company law, whereby the conflating of shareholders ownership of capital paid into the company andof the companys assets has led to the emergence of the view that companies should be run exclusivelyfor the benefit of shareholders (see P. Ireland, above n75 at p49).

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 22

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    23/56

    difficulty, although that might change if the state were no longer the controlling

    shareholder in most listed companies.

    Second, the system of landholding in the PRC does not allow private ownership of

    land. Land users (including companies) can only acquire a land-use right for a

    specific time period and there are limits on the transfer of such rights. 87 The result is

    that major assets of a company, represented by land and buildings, are not directly

    owned by the company.

    Third, the presence of the state as controlling shareholder creates some difficulty in

    defining the rights of other shareholders. Two factors are relevant. The first is the

    constitutional and ideological support for the role of the state as controlling

    shareholder and the second is the regulation of marketability of shares.

    While neither has a direct bearing on the rights of shareholders as defined in the

    Company Law, they have important implications for corporate governance because

    they effectively entrench the position of the state as controlling shareholder and

    confine non-state shareholders to a minor role. This issue is discussed in more detail

    in part E below.

    The dominant role of the state is also evident in the development of the regulatory

    regime in respect of foreign capitals participation in Chinese business. It reflects the

    concern that China's economy, especially in strategically important industries, should

    not fall under the control of foreign investors. 88 Foreign capital has been invested

    mainly in joint-ventures, which can be organized either as limited liability companies

    or contractual joint ventures. 89 The main source of foreign capital has been Hong

    Kong 90 and it has been targeted mainly at cities on Chinas eastern seaboard. 91

    87

    See Png Cheong Ann, (above n45).88 One commentator viewed the position as follows: "..the PRC struck a compromise which continuesto animate China's policy and laws respecting foreign investment and corporate law: China wouldstrive to absorb enough foreign capital to bring about desired developmental benefits, while at the sametime maintaining state control over the terms of such investment through a system of approval controls,taxation policy, access to foreign exchange and production and distribution requirements": see N CHowson, "China's Company Law: One Step Forward, Two Steps Back? A Modest Complaint" (11) 1Columbia Journal of Asian Law 127,133.89 See generally, Guiguo Wang, Business Law of China chapter 8 "Organizations with a foreigninterest" (Butterworths Asia, 1999). The shares of foreign direct investment into China represented bydifferent forms of business enterprise between 1979-1997 was as follows: equity joint ventures 46%;contractual joint ventures 23%; wholly foreign-owned enterprises 30%; joint resource exploration 1%.(Source: OECD Financial Market Trends No 77, pp105-121 October 2000).90

    On the role of Hong Kong as a bridge between global markets and China see D. Crawford,Globalization and Guanxi: The Ethos of Hong Kong Finance 6(1) New Political Economy (2001) 45.91 See S. Breslin (above note 50) pp212/13 for details.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 23

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    24/56

    Since 1986, it has been possible for wholly foreign-owned enterprises to be

    established in China in the form of a LLC or JSC. The conditions to be met to gain

    approval for establishing such an enterprise are more stringent than is the case for

    joint ventures. 92

    Participation in listed companies accounts for a relatively small proportion of foreign

    investment in China, and one reason for this is that the options for participating in

    listed companies are quite limited. 93 China has adopted a policy of restricting foreign

    investors access to its capital market. 94 They cannot own A shares, which represent

    the majority of the marketable shares of listed companies. 95 There are, however,

    several ways in which foreign investors can participate in such companies. First,

    through the purchase of B shares, which are denominated in RMB, listed in China

    and traded in a foreign currency. 96 Until recently, such shares were only open to

    purchase by foreigners, but are now open to purchase by PRC residents. 97 In

    aggregate, B shares account for only 5% of the share capital of listed companies.

    Second, foreign investors can buy foreign shares of Chinese companies, which are

    listed and issued in an overseas market. Such shares are most commonly listed and

    issued in Hong Kong( H Shares), the NYSE (N Shares) and London (L Shares). In

    aggregate, they account for 5% of the capital of listed companies. 98 Approval is

    required from the CSRC for the issue of securities in an overseas market although

    the issue of admission to listing is a matter for the overseas market to determine. As

    discussed in more detail below, the Articles of Association of a company intending to

    issue securities on an overseas market must be amended to include the Mandatory

    Provisions for Articles of Association of Overseas Listed Companies. Third, since

    1995 it has been possible for foreign investors to invest directly into a (listed) Foreign

    Investment Company limited by Shares ("FICLB"). 99 This type of company is

    essentially the same as a JSC established under the Company Law with three main

    exceptions. First, it is also subject to the laws and regulations governing enterprises92 See Wang pp258-261.93 See Table 4 in the Appendix, which shows foreign equity capital and foreign bonds as a percentageof total foreign investment in China.94 On the rationale for this policy, see Gordon and Wei Li (above n37), who show that the Chineseownership restrictions are equivalent in their economic effects to taxes on income from equity.95 See Table 1 in the Appendix.96 B shares listed in Shanghai are denominated in US dollars, while B shares listed in Shenzhen aredenominated in HK dollars. The regulatory framework is contained in the "Listing of Foreign Firms inChina by a Company Limited by Shares Provisions". See Tokley and Ravn (above n57) p197.97 The restrictions on domestic investors owning B shares were partially lifted in February 2001 andcompletely removed in June 2001.98 See Table 1 in the Appendix.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 24

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    25/56

    with foreign investment and in particular the requirement that at least 25% of the

    shares must be held by the foreign investor. Second the establishment of a FICLB is

    subject to a minimum registered capital requirement of RMB 30m compared to RMB

    10m for a JSC established under the company law. Third, the establishment of this

    type of company has been limited to the promotion ("private placement") method as

    the CSRC has not authorised the listing and public issue by such companies. 100

    Finally foreign investors can participate in listed companies through the purchase of

    bonds, although as shown in Table 4 of the Appendix this has been a relatively minor

    part of total foreign investment in China.

    E. FINANCIAL MARKETS

    Financial markets, and in particular the legal and regulatory environment in which

    they operate, are closely related to the development of national systems of corporate

    governance. 101 At the most basic level, there is a clear relationship between the

    presence of strong investor protection and well-developed financial markets. 102

    Beyond that, there are more specific influences such as disclosure obligations for

    major shareholdings, takeover regulation and ownership restrictions (e.g. on banks

    ownership of equity).The manner in which market participants are regulated is also

    significant as it may influence the pattern of shareholding in a country. 103 So too is

    the relationship between ultimate investors and intermediaries (banks, fund

    managers, pension funds) in respect of issues such as voting rights over shares held

    by intermediaries. 104

    The transformation of the Chinese economy into a socialist market system 105 is

    evident in the rapid development of financial markets over the last ten years. As

    99 See Wang (above n89) pp304-312 for a discussion of the enabling regulations contained in the "JointStock Company with Foreign Investment Provisions".100 Some change in this policy on the part of the CSRC seems likely in the near future. See "Foreignfirms gain rights to China listing" South China Morning Post 9-11-2001. On 11 January 2002, theCSRC published on its website for public consultation rules governing information disclosure in aprospectus relating to a FICLB.101 See LLSV, Legal determinants of external finance 52 Jnl of Finance 1131-1150 (1997) and A.Shleifer and R. Vishny, A survey of corporate governance 52(2) Jnl of Finance 737-783 (1997).102 See LLSV, Investor Protection and Corporate Governance at ssrn.com (update reference).103 See M Roe (above n12) arguing that (politically driven) regulation in the USA has been the mainfactor shaping the modern system of corporate finance. (Political roots etc article)104 See R. Buxbaum, Institutional Owners and Corporate Managers: A Comparative Perspective 57

    Brook. L. Rev. 1 (1991) for a comparison between the USA and Germany on this issue.105 This term has been used extensively since its adoption in 1992 at the 14 th National Congress of theChinese Communist Party.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 25

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    26/56

    shown in Table 3, the ratio of stockmarket capitalization to GDP now stands at over

    50%, which places China ahead of most EU members other than the UK in terms of

    the significance of the stockmarket to the economy. 106 What is less clear is whether,

    and if so how, the socialist character of the system has been preserved in the midst

    of these developments. The key to that issue lies in the peculiar mix of regulation and

    market forces that has been adopted in the operation of financial markets in China.

    What has emerged is a system in which there is such extensive state control of the

    financial markets that the role of market forces has been marginalized.

    (I) Regulation of Markets and Marketability of Shares

    Prior to the introduction of national measures, regulation of the stock exchanges in

    Shanghai and Shenzhen was left to the respective provincial/municipal governments.

    The re-organisation of financial regulation in 1998 resulted in the CSRC assuming

    responsibility for the stock exchanges. The exchanges themselves have a significant

    regulatory role in setting rules for the operation of the market, but ultimately its is the

    State which is in control as the CSRC is appointed by the State Council. The

    Securities Law also contains important provisions in respect of the exchanges,

    providing that they should be non-profit organisations (article 95) with a mutual

    ownership structure (article 98). The effect of these provisions, taken together with

    the observation that exchange members (viz. Securities Companies, discussed

    below) are generally controlled by the state, is that the state is ultimately the owner of

    the exchanges, the regulatory authority and the controlling shareholder in most listed

    companies. 107

    The confusion between the different roles of the state is also evident in the complex

    manner in which marketability of shares is regulated. An examination of the

    provisions of the Chinese company law relating to share types and transfer rightssuggests, at first glance, a relatively simple picture. Article 130 provides that the

    conditions and price of shares issued as part of the same issue shall be the same

    and article 143 provides that shares may be transferred in accordance with law.

    106 For comparable data on the relative size of stockmarkets see Maher and Anderson, CorporateGovernance: Effects on Firm Performance and Economic Growth at ssrn.com. See also

    www.FIBV.com , the website of the Federation International des Bourses de Valeurs.107 The control of the state was reinforced when, in October 2001, Premier Zhu appointed two formervice-chairs of the CSRC to head the national exchanges.

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 26

    http://www.fibv.com/http://www.fibv.com/
  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    27/56

    However, the effect of regulations 108 made by the State Council, and state policy in

    respect of its shareholdings, is that shares are classified into two groups: marketable

    and non-marketable. 109 Categories 1 to 6 in Table 1 in the Appendix are designated

    as non-marketable shares. 110 Categories 7 to 9 in Table 1 are designated as

    marketable shares. The result is that the fraction of shares of Chinese listed

    companies that is available for trading in the market (the "free float") is just over one

    third of the total shares in issue.

    The different types of share and shareholder require some explanation, as the rules

    on transfer are formulated by reference to both. The concept of different share types

    relates essentially to the marketability of shares held by different shareholders rather

    than to different rights attaching to different types of share. Shares held by the state

    (category 1) are held either by the state (through agents at the national, provincial or

    local level) or by state legal persons. The latter are legal persons established with

    state capital and directed by the State. 111 Domestic promoter legal person shares

    (category 2) are shares held by the promoter involved in the formation of a JSC

    (either by way of promotion or by way of public offer for subscription). The "domestic"

    descriptor distinguishes this type of promoter from a foreign promoter. 112 It is possible

    for shareholders in category 2 to be state legal persons and therefore such

    shareholders can appear in either category.

    The limits on marketability within these two categories are also more complex than

    suggested by their designation as non-marketable . As discussed below 113 , state

    shares can be transferred in several ways, an outcome referred to rather obliquely by

    article 148 of the company law which simply refers to the possibility of state-owned

    investment institutions selling state shares and buying shares held by others in

    accordance with the law and administrative regulations. The non-marketable nature

    of state shares is a matter of state policy regarding its ownership rather than an108 The Provisional Regulations on the Administration of Issuing and Trading Shares (April 22, 1993)and The Provisional Regulations on the Administration of State Equity in Companies Listed by Shares(3 Nov, 1994).109 The terms marketable and non-marketable refer to whether or not the relevant shares can be tradedthrough the stock exchanges in Shanghai or Shenzhen. Some authors use the terms transferable/non-transferable or negotiable/non-negotiable to refer to the same distinction. However, as non-marketableshares can be transferred outside the recognised exchanges, it is submitted that the more accuratedistinction is between marketable and non-marketable shares.110 Title to shares is recorded in electronic form. Paper copies of the record distinguish transferablefrom non-transferable shares.111 See article 4 of the Opinion on the Implementation of the management of state-owned shareholdingsin experimental JSCs, March 11 1994, State Assets Administration Bureau.112 Article 75 of the company law provides that half of the promoters must reside in the PRC

    NewCGin PRC - 25/04/02 27

  • 8/8/2019 Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate

    28/56

    aspect of the rights attaching to shares. Even if state shares are sold by the state (by

    one of the methods indicated below) they remain in principle non-marketable as it is

    not possible for shares other than those issued to the public to become freely

    marketable. Promoters are required to hold their shares for three years after the

    establishment of a JSC and therefore the limit on the transfer of their shares is

    temporary rather than permanent. However, even after transfer, promoter shares will

    continue to be non-marketable. 114

    Overseas legal persons (category 3) can become holders of non-marketable shares

    through share issues made overseas by Chinese incorporated companies. This type

    of issue is less common than issues made to foreign investors of marketable shares.

    It is possible to make such non-marketable issues as some foreign investors are

    keen to hold equity in Chinese companies for the long-term, regardless of restrictions

    on marketability, which might be eased or abolished in due course. Social legal

    persons (category 4) are domestic legal persons other than those in which the state

    has a majority shareholding. This category includes LLCs and JVCs as well as co-

    operatives and TVEs.

    There are three share types that are designated marketable. They differ only in

    respect of the currency in which the shares are traded and who is entitled to hold

    them as the rights attaching to the shares are the same. A shares are denominated

    in RMB and can be held only by domestic investors. B shares are denominated in

    RMB, traded in foreign currency and until recently could only be held by foreigners.

    Recent changes to the regulations have permitted B shares to be held by domestic

    investors. 115 In overall terms, B shares represent a relatively small part of listed

    companies' capital. 116 H shares are shares issued by PRC incorporated JSCs to

    foreign investors through a listing on a foreign market. The most common option is to

    issue in Hong Kong (hence the H designation) although several issues have alsobeen made in other markets.

    The implications of this system of regulation of the market and marketability are

    considerable. The dual role of the state as regulator and controlling shareholder

    113 See section F for further discussion of the state shareholding.114 The restrictions on marketability are supported by the electronic systems in which legal title toshares is recorded: non-marketable shares are identified as such and this is shown on paper versions of the electronic record.115

    One result of the change in regulations was that the value of B shares rose sharply and is now closerto that of A shares - see Table 5 in the App