32
A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy 2004

A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

A State LegislatorsGuide to Telecom

Policy

2004

Page 2: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

The Institute for Policy

Innovation (IPI)

is a non-profit, non-partisan public

policy “think tank” based in Lewisville,

Texas. Founded in 1987, IPI conducts

research, develops and promotes

innovative and non-partisan solutions

to today’s public policy problems. IPI

focuses on approaches to governing

that harness the strengths of individual

liberty, limited government and free

markets.

Page 3: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

1

The telecommunications industry has undergonea revolution. Even the most recent federal law

affecting the industry, the Telecommunications Actof 1996, failed to anticipate the widespread adop-tion of wireless telephone and new technologies likeInstant Messaging and Voice over Internet Protocol(VoIP), let alone their substitution for traditionalphone service. Never has there been a clearer example of the inability of law to keep pace withtechnology.

Now it is time for governments to substitute mar-ket-based competition for government-managedcompetition. Regulation stifles the investment necessary to stimulate economic growth and job cre-ation. Market-based competition is the hallmark ofa consumer-focused marketplace where providerscompete for customers on the basis of innovation,quality, price and customer service.

Without doubt, the communications technologiesthat best deliver the products and services embracedby consumers are those operating in unregulated orlightly regulated environments. Deregulation wouldspur even more innovation, competition, and con-sumer satisfaction.

This Legislators’ Guide explains in plain languagethe issues public policymakers face in consideringthe future of the U.S. telecommunications industry. It supplies legislators otherwise at the mercy of regu-latory jargon with the tools to make intelligent,principled decisions. The Guide reflects a nonparti-san but distinctly free-market approach that willlead to investment, job creation, and new productsand services for consumers.

Barry M. AaronsSolveig Singleton

Page 4: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

2

TABLE OFCONTENTS

GUIDING PRINCIPLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .3

A CLOSER LOOK AT THE ISSUES . . . . . . . . . .7Local Telephone Competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . .7

Interconnection . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .7Unbundling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .8Performance Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .11Getting to Negotiated Agreements . . . . . . . .12

Universal Service . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .12Access Charges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .14

Bringing Access Charges to Cost . . . . . . . . .14Charges on ISPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .15

Internet Telephony (VOIP) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .15Wireless . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .17

Public Safety and Wireless . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .17Broadband . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .18

Encouraging the Spread of Broadband . . . . .18Broadband Over Power Lines . . . . . . . . . . . .19Municipal Broadband Networks . . . . . . . . . .19

Cable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .20Cable vs. Satellite . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .20A La Carte Cable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .21

GLOSSARY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .23

Page 5: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

GUIDINGPRINCIPLES

ELIMINATE ARTIFICIALDISTINCTIONS

Public policy should be based on reality, and thereality of the digital world is that bits are bits,whether they store a live voice, an email, or aninstant message. Companies that once carried one-way video now compete with companies that oncecarried only two-way voice traffic, a phenomenoncalled convergence.

Convergence makes old legal distinctions irrelevant.In the digital world, the distinction between localand long-distance phone service has no meaning.Regulations based on these invalid distinctions arebound to fail.

SUBSTITUTION ISCOMPETITION

If consumers substitute one technology for another,this is competition. Wireless, cable telephony, VoIPand even email compete with traditional wirelinephone service, just as public transportation com-petes with automobiles. Consumers choose betweenthese media and substitute one for another. This is“intermodal” competition.

3

Page 6: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

NEUTRALITY SHOULD BETHE GOAL

Tax and regulatory policy should be technologicallyneutral. Why should one method for accessing theInternet be highly taxed and regulated, while oth-ers are not? But neutrality should not be achievedby applying pervasive regulation to new technolo-gies. Rather, incumbent technologies should bederegulated.

DON’T REGULATE WHATCAN’T BE REGULATED

Policymakers are sometimes tempted to enact unen-forceable rules as political gestures. For example,laws aimed at the Internet can be evaded by relocat-ing a server offshore. One U.S. Senator threatenedto “pull the plug on the Internet” if his proposedlegislation couldn’t be enforced. Such empty threatsresult in a cynical attitude to all law.

DON’T REGULATE WHATDOESN’T REQUIREREGULATION

Free innovation drives increased productivity, fastergrowth, and higher personal incomes. If somethingdoesn’t need to be regulated, it shouldn’t be regulat-ed. Regulations designed in an age of monopoly are actually harmful in today’s rapidly changing,competitive market. Regulations designed for oldtechnologies should not be applied to new andemerging technologies.

4

Page 7: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

LEGISLATION IS BETTERTHAN REGULATION

The will of taxpayers is best reflected in the actionsof their elected legislators, not in the decrees of afew appointed regulators. Legislation also creates amore predictable environment for business planningthan discretionary regulatory oversight. Wheneverpossible, elected legislators should determine andimplement telecommunications policy.

THE CONSUMER SHOULD BE KING

The legal ground rules for the telecom industryshould respect consumer choice. If consumers wanta bundle of services from a single provider, theyshould be allowed to have it.

Existing “consumer protection” rules often protectcompanies from their competitors, rather than pro-tecting consumers. Consumer protection regulationsshould be directed at real harms like fraud, not somevague potential for harm.

5

Page 8: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

6

Page 9: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

A CLOSERLOOK ATTHE ISSUES

LOCAL TELEPHONECOMPETITION

The Telecommunications Act of 1996 (The Act)provides a framework for efforts to bring competi-tion to all local service markets. But rather thanlooking to cable, wireless, and others to build newnetworks to bypass aging copper facilities (facilities-based competition) regulators encouraged competi-tors to piggyback on the old networks though resale,interconnection, and unbundling. Who, then, willbuild new networks?

InterconnectionThe Act requires all telephone companies to physi-cally connect their networks to those of other carriers(wireless, long distance, or local), enabling sub-scribers of one service to call subscribers of anotherservice.

What Price Interconnection? When a local carrierconnects with a long distance carrier, the local com-pany charges the long distance carrier fees known as“access charges.” When two local carriers intercon-nect, the fees are called “reciprocal compensation.”This distinction is outdated. Under both systems,the calling party’s network pays.

Access charges and reciprocal compensation prices

7

Page 10: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

are regulated. The challenge for regulators is tomove towards negotiated prices or to prices thatbetter reflect costs, such as “bill and keep.” (Under“bill and keep” carriers bill only end users for thecosts of connecting a call, not other carriers.)

Collocation: Collocation is the placement of a com-petitor’s equipment in the incumbent telco’s centralswitching office to enable interconnection.Collocation raises concerns about the abuse of onecompany’s equipment by another’s employees. Thisis a consequence of rules that force the sharing ofproperty. The best solution is to set ground rulesthat encourage the technical details of interconnec-tion to be negotiated.

Unbundling Under the 1996 Telecommunications Act, incum-bent local exchange (phone) companies (ILECs)must offer the use of parts of their networks (unbun-dled network elements, or UNE’s) to competinglocal exchange carriers (CLECs) without which theCLECs would suffer “impairment.” The perennialquestion is, which elements, and at what price?

The FCC’s attempts to implement the unbundlingrequirements of the 1996 Act were hotly disputedalmost since the Act was passed. Several aspects ofthe FCC’s most recent rules, the Triennial Review(Report and Order on Remand and Further Noticeof Proposed Rulemaking in CC Docket Nos. 96-98,98-147 and 01-338), were set aside by the D.C.Circuit Court of Appeals in March 2004 in USTAv. FCC, and the FCC is working on new rules. Thiswas the third time that this same set of rules hasbeen overturned by the courts.

8

Page 11: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Impairment: The FCC’s early interpretations ofimpairment gave CLECs access to almost every-thing, giving them little reason to build their ownfacilities. The Supreme Court rejected this approach,saying that the FCC must consider whether CLECscould find the element they needed outside theILEC’s network (AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board,525 U.S. 366, 387-92 (1999)). The D.C. CircuitCourt later reminded the FCC again not to discour-age facilities-based competition by paying closerattention to real costs and particular markets.

In the Triennial Review, the FCC ruled that aCLEC would be impaired when lack of access to anelement created a barrier to entry. These barriersmight include economies of scale, sunk costs, first-mover advantages, and barriers controlled by anILEC. The D.C. Circuit generally upheld this defi-nition. But the court did direct the FCC to includespecial access services in its impairment analysis(and thus vacated the FCC’s determination thatwireless carriers were impaired without access todedicated transport).

Which Network Elements? In the TriennialReview, the FCC determined that ILECs’ broadband(fiber to the home) networks, hybrid loops withpacket switching, and line-sharing need not beunbundled. (Line-sharing lets competitors use partof the local loop to carry data traffic, while theILEC used another part to carry voice traffic.) Thecourt upheld this, stating that without evidence thatCLECs are impaired without those elements, forcedsharing “would skew investment incentives in unde-sirable ways . . . [and] intermodal competition from

9

Page 12: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

cable ensures the persistence of substantial competi-tion in broadband.”

The FCC had delegated the decision about switch-ing for mass-market customers (residential and smallbusiness) to state public utility commissions, givingthem nine months to decide. The D.C. Circuitfound such delegations unlawful, and requires theFCC to revisit this ruling. The court also vacatedthe FCC’s nationwide impairment determinationswith respect to high-capacity voice-grade lines (alsoknown as DS1 & D3) and dark fiber.

The Unbundled Network Elements-Platform(UNE-P): UNE-P results from competitors puttingtogether all UNEs into a single bundle. The DCCircuit struck down the rules that allow a CLECaccess to every part of an incumbent’s network inone package, known as “unbundled network ele-ment platform” or UNE-P.

TELRIC Pricing: The FCC set the prices forunbundled elements using a formula called “total ele-mental long-run incremental cost” (TELRIC), theprice based on the cost of a hypothetical, perfectlyefficient future network. TELRIC is very low com-pared to actual costs—the perfect future network isassumed to be cheap, real networks aren’t—soCLECs are better off piggybacking on the old net-works than building their own. The FCC’s datashow that CLECs owned fewer access lines in 2002than in 1999. TELRIC ultimately should bereplaced by negotiated prices, and in the interim bysome method that reflects current costs.

10

Page 13: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Performance MeasuresRegulators use performance measures, such as count-ing the seconds it takes for an ILEC’s computer torespond to a request for interconnection or thenumber of days the company takes to respond to acustomer’s request for service or repair, to assess cus-tomer service and progress towards competition.Performance measures may have their place, buthave been misused. Sometimes, for example, anILEC must purposely slow down its network toaccommodate the inferior technology of its com-petitors. And some measures are impossible to comply with; for example, until recently Qwest wasrequired to repair all phones within two days or payan automatic annual fine of $1 million.

Performance measures have proliferated to thepoint where literally millions of measurements mustbe tracked and reported. Performance measureshave become a revenue-generator for regulators,and a means of harassment rather than guarantorsof competition.

The costs of compliance and the fines generated bysuch a staggering number of measurements must bepassed on to customers at both the wholesale andretail level.

The counterproductive expansion of performancemeasures is a prime example of the tendency of reg-ulation to lose touch with reality and become anend in itself. Growing intermodal competition willbest improve customer service.

11

Page 14: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Getting to Negotiated AgreementsThe best way to end politicking over access to localphone networks is to encourage CLECs and ILECsto agree on access terms. The 1996 Act envisionedsuch agreements, but few negotiations took place.Most CLECs knew they could get a better deal fromregulators. Since the D.C. Circuit struck downmajor parts of the FCC’s Triennial Review, ILECsand CLECs have begun to negotiate agreements,such as that between SBC and Sage Telecom. Tokeep this trend alive, the new ground rules shouldnot reward either party for resorting to regulation.

UNIVERSAL SERVICE

Federal and state universal service policies areintended to make telephone service available to allat uniformly low rates. The $7 billion federalUniversal Service Fund (USF) was established bythe Telecommunications Act of 1996. The statesdetermine eligibility to receive federal USF support.Most states have their own universal service pro-grams for low-income residents, and half have pro-grams for high-cost local phone companies.

The largest “explicit” federal USF programs are $4.5billion for carriers in high-cost areas, and $2.25 bil-lion to wire schools and libraries to the Internet.Programs targeted to low-income telephone sub-scribers account for $673 million. The “non-rural”fund, which goes only to large carriers (SBC, Qwest,Bell South and Verizon), is about $250 million.Federal universal service is funded by a line item on

12

Page 15: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

customers’ bills for interstate phone service. Many(not all) state programs are still funded by hidden(“implicit”) charges on intrastate long distance andbusiness revenue. Universal service programs grewup in an age of monopoly. In a competitive era, suchpolicies have lead to problems.

The problem most visible to consumers irate aboutthe line items on their bills is the rapid growth ofuniversal service costs. Everyone wants to take outof the pool, especially if they pay into it, and any-one who doesn’t stake a claim will lose out to moreaggressive competitors. Wireless companies facepressure from investors to qualify for the subsidies—and wireless providers pay much more into the fundthan they take out. But the costs of wireless build-out are so low it is doubtful they need any subsidy.

Ways to cap the funds’ rampant growth include:

Maintain Accountability: Make sure consumers cansee universal service charges on their bills.

Let markets spread “advanced” services likebroadband, so that more services do not becomeeligible for subsidies. Advanced services like VoIPshould not be forced to pay into the fund, either.Neutrality is best served by funding universal serviceout of general tax revenues.

Legislative Caps: The political process is moreeffective than regulators in limiting costs.Colorado’s fund grew from $35 million to over $60million within a few years, enraging consumers.This ended when Colorado legislators capped thefund at $60 million.

13

Page 16: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Make carriers compete for support: Auction theright to be the eligible carrier in a given region. Or,make the subsidies “portable,” so that when a carrierloses a customer, it loses part of the subsidy.

Give support to means-tested customers, not com-panies: While unpopular with small phone compa-nies, this approach is fairest for consumers nowpaying to subsidize service to other consumers noworse off than they are.

ACCESS CHARGES

Access charges are payments made by long distancetelephone carriers to local phone networks to carrylong distance calls to their destination. The struc-ture of access charges affects universal service, competition between phone companies, and thedevelopment of the Internet. Access charges causemany economic distortions.

Bringing Access Charges to CostBefore 1984, when the Bell System was still onecompany, long distance prices were held high tokeep local prices low. After the breakup, regulatorscreated access charges, keeping long distance priceshigh to preserve this subsidy. But competition forcedlong distance prices down, so this system was unten-able. The FCC began to bring interstate accesscharges down to cost. Many states, such as Texas,Minnesota, Maine, Ohio, Florida, and Californiaseek to do the same with intrastate access charges.This may mean letting local rates rise, while long

14

Page 17: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

distance rates fall; it is called rate rebalancing.

Fears that rate rebalancing would result in poor peo-ple giving up their phone service have provenunfounded. The demand for basic service remainsstrong. In Wyoming, basic residential rates wentfrom $14.64 in 1995 to $23.10 in 2002, with nomaterial effect on subscribership. Falling long dis-tance prices help low-income consumers, especiallyin isolated areas. And letting local prices rise some-what makes local residential service more attractiveto potential competitors; no one wants to competeagainst a company whose prices are below marketrates.

Although bringing access charges to cost is desirable,ultimately, freely negotiated charges should prevail.

Charges on ISPsSince 1983, the FCC has exempted services otherthan pure transmission (“enhanced serviceproviders”) from access charges. In 1997, the FCCruled that this exemption covered Internet ServiceProviders. This created problems, because ISP carri-ers then take in much more money than they payout to incumbent carriers. Again, the goal should beto allow carriers to move towards bill-and-keep orother negotiated arrangements.

INTERNET TELEPHONY(VOIP)

Voice-over-Internet Protocol (VoIP) uses softwareinstead of traditional circuit switching to carryvoice messages. Customers use VoIP to reduce

15

Page 18: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

phone and fax costs and to support applications likeunified messaging, in which voice, fax, and emailare combined.

There are no federal regulations for VoIP. FCCChairman Michael Powell believes the service doesnot need regulation. Although VoIP is inherentlyinterstate, some states have tried to regulate VoIP.California and Wisconsin have decided that theservice providers are subject to telephone regula-tion, while Minnesota exempted VoIP from telecomregulations. Nearly every telecom company calls forthe FCC to refrain from regulation.

VoIP is a classic disruptive and transformationaltechnology, which will bring productivity gains forbusiness and lower prices for consumers—that is,unless the heavy hand of regulation slows its deploy-ment and frustrates early adopters. As wireless service has shown, emerging technologies bringtheir benefits to the economy most quickly whenthey are not held back by pervasive regulation.

A few ground rules for VoIP may be necessary toprotect 911 services, to allow law enforcement tointercept calls in criminal investigations, and so on.But many of the rules that apply to traditionaltelephony (access charges, for example) should notbe applied to VoIP any more than to email orinstant messaging. Applying old-style regulation tosuch new technologies will create stagnation.

Some services use a mix of traditional and Internettelephony. Some long distance carriers, for example,route calls over a packet-switched network at some

16

Page 19: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

mid-point in the transmission. Where should oldregulation end? At some point one must draw a linein the sand, perhaps by requiring that at least oneend of the call be VoIP. If deregulation proceeds onthe traditional side of the line, the problem shouldnot persist for long.

WIRELESS

The most familiar wireless services are cellularphone and PCS service. But wireless has many otheruses. WiFi lets computer users access the Net in air-ports and coffee shops, and in an ever-widening hostof other locations.

Wireless competes with traditional local phone serv-ice. More and more homes and small businesses usewireless instead of wireline. And competition withinthe wireless community is fierce. Some argue thatwireless needs regulation. But this would onlyimpede the spread of service to consumers and pro-tect wireline service from competition.

Public Safety and WirelessFederal policymakers are moving more of the radiospectrum into private hands through auctions andother reforms. This will speed the offering of wire-less services to consumers. Traditionally, largeswathes of spectrum have been reserved for govern-mental purposes, and are often used very inefficiently.Public safety groups are concerned that spectrumwill no longer be reserved for them. But there is noreason that public safety organizations could not bid

17

Page 20: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

for spectrum and communications services in themarket the same way they buy fuel or typists.Keeping spectrum off the market will only exacer-bate shortages.

BROADBAND

Roughly speaking, broadband means enough band-width to carry multiple voice, video or data channelssimultaneously. Channels are separated by “guardbands” (empty spaces) to prevent interference. Moretechnically, broadband transmits voice, data, andvideo simultaneously at rates of at least 1.5 Mbps(although existing networks more commonly offerabout 500 Kbps). Sometimes, “broadband” refers toany high-speed, always-on Internet connection likeDSL and cable. Wireless broadband systems arebeing rolled out, promising to bring low-cost broad-band to remote areas.

The FCC has sought to classify broadband service as an “information service” instead of a “telecom-munications service” and thereby keep broadbandlightly regulated. But one court has rejected thisclassification.

Encouraging the Spread ofBroadbandWider broadband deployment, especially in ruralareas, will be an important driver of economicgrowth. The FCC has recognized that broadbandregulation would impede the investments needed tobuild out broadband networks. Imposing “open

18

Page 21: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

access” rules requiring cable broadband networks tocarry their competitors’ signals would reduce theincentives of those competitors to build their ownnetworks, and it would deprive cable investors ofthe promise of good returns on their investment.The same is true of access requirements on DSL.

Broadband Over Power LinesAmerica’s power companies own significant rights ofway along their power grids. If their power linescould be used for broadband, these companies wouldoffer powerful competition against DSL and cablemodem services. Power companies might bringbroadband to areas not served by cable or DSL.Transmitting signals over power lines is problematic,but advances in chip technology have made it possi-ble. But power companies and traditional broadbandface growing competition from wireless broadband.

Power companies are still regulated by state com-missions, some still using rate-of-return regulation.Power companies might be able to make broadbanda profit center, but if regulation deprives them of agood return, they will not make the investment.

Municipal Broadband NetworksFrustrated with the slow pace of broadband rollout,some local governments are building their ownbroadband networks. These municipalities areexposing their taxpayers to the risks of investing in ayoung technology with uncertain consumer demand.Taxpayers should not be asked to fund technologiesdoomed for extinction, like the French Minitel sys-tem, a White Elephant built in the 1980s and thenovertaken by the Internet. A 2002 study of munici-

19

Page 22: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

pal networks revealed customer enrollments farbelow projections, costs more than double projec-tions, and operating losses extending indefinitelyinto the future. Higher taxes and political scandalsare the hallmark of municipal networks. Local gov-ernment’s entry into the market will discourage moreefficient private entrants like wireless broadband.Local governments would be wiser to encouragebroadband deployment by making rights of wayavailable and keeping taxes and regulation low.

CABLE

Cable television took off in the mid-70’s as an alter-native to broadcast television. Municipalities weregenerally the first regulators. First the FCC and thenCongress in the 1984 Cable Act introduced federalregulation. At first, most cable franchises awardedmonopolies, but the 1992 Cable Act generallyrequires local governments to allow competition.Meanwhile, cable companies expanded their offer-ings to include telephone service and broadbandInternet service. They compete with phone compa-nies in markets for voice messages and broadband,ISPs, and satellite video services.

Cable versus SatelliteSatellite services are chipping away at cable’s mar-ket share in their core business area. Twenty-fivepercent of all subscription television service nowcomes through satellite reception. The huge satellitedishes of 20 years ago have yielded to 12-inch modelssmall enough to fit on the terrace of an apartment.

20

Page 23: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

In many states, cable companies have proposed thatsatellite customers pay broadcast service taxes tomake up for the franchise fees that cable customerspay. This would make little sense, since satellitecompanies do not usually use local rights of way. Itdoes make sense for local governments to keep fran-chise fees and taxes low.

Cable Channels a La CarteProposals have surfaced to require cable companiesto offer their channels unbundled, so a subscribercould buy only one or two channels instead of anentire tier. Many subscribers would be likely to sub-scribe only to the most popular channels, such asthe Discovery Channel and ESPN. But most cablerevenue comes from just a few popular channels; thecosts of developing and offering new and “niche”channels can only be recovered by bundling. The “a la carte” policy would decimate these new andniche channels. These channels, including educa-tional channels like the Science channel, are privately funded and not dependent on governmentsubsidies, as is PBS.

21

Page 24: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

22

Page 25: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Glossary ofTerms

Access Line: The circuit used to enter the communicationsnetwork.

Access Network: The part of the carrier network that reachesthe customer’s premises. The access network is also referred to asthe local drop, local loop, or last mile.

Asymmetric Digital Subscriber Line (ADSL): A data commu-nications technology that can “piggyback” a standard voice tele-phone connection.

Backbone: The primary transmission path between network seg-ments, or a major pathway within a network.

Bandwidth: (1) A measure of spectrum (frequency) use or capac-ity. For instance, a standard telephone conversation uses a band-width of about 3,000 cycles per second (3 KHz). A TV channeloccupies a bandwidth of 6 million cycles per second (6 MHz).Cable systems occupy 50 to 300 MHz. (2) Also, the measure ofcapacity of a transmission channel.

Broadband: “True” broadband transmits voice, data, and video atrates of at least 1.5 Mbps (although today’s networks commonlyoffer about 500 Kbps). Alternatively, “broadband” refers to anyhigh-speed, always-on Internet connection.

Central Office (CO): A telephone company building in whichend users’ lines terminate at switching equipment that connectsother end users to each other. Also known as End Office.

Circuit: A switched or dedicated communications path with aspecified bandwidth (transmission speed/capacity).

Circuit Switched Network: This type of network carries infor-mation on a dedicated, end-to-end connection established byswitches between two connected parties for the length of theircall. The public switched telephone network (PSTN) uses circuitswitching.

Customer Premises Equipment (CPE): Telephone terminaldevices, such as handsets and private branch exchanges (PBXs),located on the customer’s premises.

23

Page 26: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Dedicated Line: A communications circuit or channel providedfor the exclusive use of a particular subscriber.

Digital Subscriber Line (DSL): Broadband technology thatworks over regular copper telephone cabling.

Facilities-Based Carrier (FBC): A carrier that builds and uses itsown facilities to provide service, rather than using the facilitiesof others.

Incumbent Local Exchange Carrier (ILEC): The traditionallocal telephone companies such as the former Bell companies,or local exchange carriers designated as such by state PublicUtility Commissions.

Integrated Services Digital Network (ISDN): A digital tele-phone line that can be used for voice, fax, and data communica-tions like a regular telephone line, but can transport data fivetimes faster (or more) than a 28.8 Kbps V.34 modem and allowyou to talk on the phone to one person while sending data toanother.

Interexchange Carrier (IXC): A long distance phone carrier,like AT&T, MCI, or Sprint, as well as ILECs that have qualifiedto provide long distance service.

Local Access and Transport Area (LATA): These regions werecreated by the antitrust decree that broke up the Bell System,and were used for regulatory purposes. Most states contain severalLATAs.

Local Exchange Carrier (LEC): Telephone company lingo foryour local telephone company. See also RBOC.

Local Loop: This part of the telecommunications network con-nects end users to the central office network facilities. Twistedpairs of copper wire form the traditional medium of the localloop. Also known as the subscriber loop, local line and accessline.

Narrowband: This medium is capable of carrying voice, fax, pag-ing, and relatively slow-speed data (not full video applications),typically at 64 Kbps or less.

Network Element: As defined in the Telecommunications Actof 1996, a facility or equipment used to provide telecommunica-tions service.

Packet: A series of bits containing data and control information,including source and destination node addresses, formatted fortransmission from one node to another.

Packet Switching: A transmission protocol in which data isdivided into small blocks so that different packets could travelover different routes to avoid overloading a single facility. Pathsare temporary and dynamic.

Packet-Switched Network (PSN): A PSN network carriesinformation broken into digital “packets” that are transmitted

24

Page 27: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

independently and then reassembled in the correct order at thedestination.

Point of Presence (POP): The point where the inter-exchangecarrier’s responsibilities for the line begin and the local exchangecarrier’s responsibility ends.

Point-to-Point: A circuit connecting two nodes only, or a net-work requiring a separate physical connection between each pairof nodes.

Plain Old Telephone Service (POTS): This term often is usedto refer to analog voice telephone services provided over the pub-lic switched telephone network.

Primary Interexchange Carrier (PIC): The PIC is the mainlong-distance carrier used for “1+dialing” through which allinterstate long-distance toll calls are made.

Private Branch Exchange (PBX): A private switching deviceused by large organizations to bypass the telephone companies’central office switch, usually located on the customer’s premises.

Private Line Service: Dedicated telecommunications channelsprovided between two points or switched among multiple points.Privately leased for high-volume voice, data, audio or videotransmissions.

Public Switched Telephone Network (PSTN): The PSTN isthe worldwide circuit-switched telephone network. Once only ananalog system, these networks are digital, though most subscribersare connected via analog circuits.

Regional Bell Operating Company (RBOC): RBOCs comprisethe U.S. local carriers created in the 1982 Consent Decree tobreak up AT&T. Seven were formed to serve as parent companiesfor the 22 then-existing Bell Operating Companies. Today, theremaining RBOCs are BellSouth, Qwest, SBC and Verizon.

Resale: A type of market entry competitors can use to access theILECs’ network. CLEC resell telecommunications services pur-chased wholesale from another carrier.

Resale Carrier: A carrier that does not own transmission facili-ties, but obtains communications services from another carrier forresale to the public for profit. Also known as a Reseller.

Slamming: The switching of a customer’s long distance servicefrom one company to another without the customer’s permission.

Special Access Service: A transmission path directly connectingan InterExchange Carrier location in a LATA to an end userpremise or another InterExchange Carrier location.

Subscriber Line Charge (SLC): A monthly fee paid by telephonesubscribers to compensate the local telephone company for part ofthe cost of maintaining the telephone equipment linking privatehomes to the telephone network. The SLC was originated at thesame time as access charges to help support universal service.

25

Page 28: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Switched Circuit: A communications path that allows the origi-nator to specify a desired destination for each call.

Switched Circuit Network (SCN): Synonym for the PublicSwitched Telephone Network.

Switched Network: Any network in which switches are used todirect messages from the sender to the ultimate recipient.

Switched Services: All dial-up long distance services.

Switching Fee: A per-line fee (usually around $5) to reprogramthe telephone switching system to change a customer’s defaultcarrier. Subscribers must usually pay this fee when switching to areseller.

Switchless Reseller: A reseller of long-distance services thatdoes not use any of its own facilities (lines or switching equip-ment).

T-1: A type of high-speed digital data connection that operatesat 1.5 Mbps and requires a two-pair (four-wire) connectionbetween the telephone company Central Office and the customerpremises.

Tariff: A statement by a communications company that setsforth the services offered by that company, and the rates, termsand conditions for the use of those services.

Trunk: An analog or digital connection from a circuit switchthat carries user media content and may carry telephony signal-ing.

Twisted Pair: A pair of wires used in transmission circuits andtwisted about one another to minimize coupling with other cir-cuits.

Wideband: Wideband is a medium intermediate between narrow-band and broadband. Wideband transmits at speeds between 64 Kbps and 1.5 Mbps.

26

Page 29: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

27

Page 30: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

28

Page 31: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

About the Authors

Barry M. Aarons is a seniorresearch fellow with the Institute forPolicy Innovation (IPI) and owner ofThe Aarons Company, a public policyconsulting firm. He has numerousyears of both governmental and corpo-rate experience. His accomplishmentsinclude 20 years as the director ofgovernment relations and public policyfor US West Communications. In addi-tion he served as special assistant,legislative director and senior policyadvisor for former Arizona GovernorFife Symington.

Solveig Singleton is a lawyer andthe author of many articles ontelecommunications and regulation.She served for four years at the CatoInstitute, where she was director ofinformation studies, and for anotherthree years as a senior technologyanalyst at the Competitive EnterpriseInstitute. Ms. Singleton also served asvice chair of publications for theTelecommunications and ElectronicMedia Practice Group of the FederalistSociety for Law & Public PolicyStudies from 1996-1999. She holds aJ.D. cum laude from Cornell LawSchool and a B.A. in philosophy fromReed College.

Page 32: A State Legislators Guide to Telecom Policy · he telecommunications industry has undergone a revolution. Even the most recent federal law affecting the industry, the Telecommunications

Institute for Policy Innovation

1660 S. Stemmons Frwy. Suite 475

Lewisville, Texas 75067

Phone - (972) 874-5139

Fax - (972) 874-5144

www.ipi.org