2nd Order of Sustainability

  • Upload
    daisy

  • View
    214

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    1/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    ANALYSIS

    Second-order sustainabilityconditions for the development of

    sustainable innovations in a dynamic environment

    Christian Sartorius *

    Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research, Breslauer Str. 48, D-76139 Karlsruhe, Germany

    Received 5 September 2003; received in revised form 6 July 2005; accepted 6 July 2005

    Abstract

    In particular radical innovations can be important means to achieving improved sustainability. Due to the existence of path

    dependency and lock-in, however, the transition from one technological trajectory to another, more sustainable one is often

    impeded by significant barriers. Fortunately, these barriers are by their nature subject to substantial changes in time; so, it makes

    sense to carefully distinguish between periods of stability (showing high barriers) in which the given trajectory can hardly be

    left and periods of instability (characterized by low barriers) where a new trajectory can be reached more easily. The latter

    distinction matters since sustainable innovations often rely on governmental regulation and the economic burden arising from

    this regulation will be much lower in periods of instability. Moreover, due to the complexity and dynamics of change in theirrespective environments, innovations are generally associated with fundamental uncertainty such that it becomes impossible to

    predict the degree of sustainability yielded by specific innovations in the longer run. Under these circumstances, it is essential to

    facilitate the change between trajectories and to allow for the possibility to select between a variety of alternative trajectories

    within a process of trial and error. Sustainability as viewed from this evolutionary perspective is therefore better understood as

    the general capability to adapt, that is, to readily change from less to more sustainable technological trajectories. Since the latter

    kind of sustainability determines the conditions under which the former kind (i.e. sustainability related to a specific technology)

    can be achieved, the two kinds are respectively called second-order and first-order sustainability.

    Finally, a series of determinants (and corresponding indicators) from the techno-economic, political, and socio-cultural

    sphere is identified which, after proper measurement and weighting, allow for making an assessment whether and when the

    incumbent industry is sufficiently destabilized and the political system rendered sufficiently favorable to the new, more

    sustainable technology such that a transition to the preferred trajectory is possible without too much effort.

    D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Sustainability; Innovation; Path dependence; Lock-in; Uncertainty; Indicators

    1. Introduction

    Innovations play a crucial role not only as the

    basis of the persistent economic growth prevailing

    0921-8009/$ - see front matterD 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2005.07.010

    * Tel.: +49 721 6809 118.

    E-mail address: [email protected].

    Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx

    www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

    ECOLEC-02304; No of Pages 19

    DTD 5

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    2/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    especially in developed countries since the beginning

    of the industrial revolution (see Schumpeter, 1934;

    Nelson and Winter, 1982, for evolutionary; Romer,

    1986, for neoclassical perspectives on innovation-driven growth); they are also an important, if not

    the only, means for maintaining the sustainability of

    this development, that is, for avoiding destruction of

    the natural environment and exhaustion of natural

    resources that may be needed by all our descendents

    in order to maintain at least the current level of

    wealth (see Rennings, 2000 for an overview). How-

    ever, innovations towards sustainability are often

    associated with substantial costs. From the point of

    view of environmental economics this is due to the

    fact that environmental innovations internalize exter-nal costs for which the innovator does not receive a

    compensating benefit. By contrast, Porter and Van

    der Linde (1995) claim that these costs can be sub-

    stantially reduced, if, rather than merely redressing

    the consequences of existing technologies (e.g. by

    end-of-pipe solutions), innovation is understood as

    an integrated process avoiding environmental extern-

    alities right from the beginning. The remaining costs

    can even be turned into a benefit, if, due to its more

    fundamental character, an innovation avoids both

    external and internal costs.

    Despite the basic attractiveness of this kind of

    innovation, employing them is far from rendering

    the path towards sustainability self-sustaining for

    two reasons. On the one hand, all environmentally

    more benign substitutes after a while tend to give rise

    to unforeseen environmentally hazardous side effects

    such that, in the longer run, new technological

    (including organizational) substitutes have to be gen-

    erated again and again. Moreover, the development

    and becoming effective of new substitutes takes time,

    allowing related technology branches to exhibit envir-

    onmental externalities in their turn. Due to the higheruncertainty associated with fundamental innovations,

    they will show this tendency even more markedly

    than incremental innovations succeeding within one

    paradigm. As a consequence, sustainability will gen-

    erally remain temporary and more or less incomplete.

    On the other hand, fundamental technological

    change requires the transition from one technology

    paradigm to another and, therefore, is not only less

    likely to occur and but also associated with higher

    uncertainty and risk than innovation along a given

    trajectory (Dosi, 1982, 1988). Accordingly, the fre-

    quency of environmentally sound and economically

    profitable fundamental innovations will remain low

    unless they are supported by policy instruments spe-cifically referring to the causes of paradigm formation

    and the related lock-ins. Klemmer et al. (1999) to

    some extent point in this direction when they

    acknowledge that a mix of regulative measures is

    needed to properly account for the complexity of

    circumstances in which innovation arise.

    In this paper, both time and uncertainty will be

    accounted for more thoroughly as crucial conditions

    of technological development in general and espe-

    cially with regard to sustainability. In particular, it is

    assumed that, along with the change in circumstances,periods of stability of a given technological trajectory

    (where establishing a new paradigm requires much

    effort) alternate with periods of instability (where such

    a shift is more easily achieved). It is further assumed

    that it is possible to identify and even strategically use

    the latter phases of instability in the search for the

    lowest possible cost of achieving a higher degree of

    sustainability. In order to justify this claim, Section 2

    starts with a discussion of the relevance of innovation

    in the context of sustainability from both the neoclas-

    sical and ecological economics perspective. In Sec-

    tion 3, an evolutionary framework is used to show

    how potential progress towards greater sustainability

    by means of innovations may be hampered by com-

    plexity, uncertainty, path dependency and lock-in.

    While identifying the strategic elements for overcom-

    ing these shortcomings, Section 4 specifies the con-

    ditions for the more ready identification and

    implementation of sustainable innovationsa prop-

    erty we call second-order sustainability because it

    refers to the dynamic interrelation between innova-

    tions rather than the innovations themselves. In order

    to make use of this dynamic concept of sustainability,Section 5 identifies a variety of its potential determi-

    nants and indicates how they may be applied. Finally,

    conclusions are drawn in Section 6.

    2. Innovation and sustainability

    A very wide-spread understanding of innovation is

    reflected in the definition used by the OECD (1997),

    which distinguishes (1) process innovations allowing

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx2

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    3/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    to produce a given quantity of output (i.e. goods or

    services) with less input, (2) product innovations

    characterized by the improvement of existing, or the

    development of new, goods or services and (3) orga-nizational innovations including new forms of man-

    agement. While the exact meaning of even this

    relatively simple definition of innovation depends on

    the methodological and normative background

    assumed by its respective applicator, it is even more

    difficult to relate to each other the concepts of innova-

    tion and sustainability. In this section, I will try to

    elucidate this relationship first from the neoclassical

    and then from the ecological economics perspective.

    2.1. Environmental innovation in the neoclassicalcontext

    While, in the above-quoted OECD definition, pro-

    cess innovation is explicitly efficiency-oriented, the

    meaning of improvement or novelty in the definition

    of product innovations is not further specified. If, as is

    often done in economic contexts (see e.g. Rennings,

    2000), the notion of innovation is further qualified by

    its distinction from the term invention, the explicit

    reference to the marketability of an innovation implies

    that also product innovation is considered in terms of

    efficiency, providing more benefit (as revealed by the

    customers willingness to pay) at the same cost or the

    same benefit at the lower cost. So, in the (neoclassi-

    cal) economic context, the complete monetary com-

    mensurability of costs (for inputs) and prices (for

    outputs) renders it fairly easy to identify innovations

    in a given set of new processes or products.1 By

    contrast, maintaining this commensurability is essen-

    tially impossible, if the above concept of innovation is

    to be extended beyond the realm of human prefer-

    encesfor instance into ecological sustainability

    (compare Munda, 1997).In particular since the beginning of the industrial

    revolution growing human production and consump-

    tion led to ever more frequent, more persistent and

    more severe adverse impacts on the natural environ-

    ment, representing an overall increase in economic

    sustainability (i.e. persistent growth) at the expense

    of ecological sustainability.2 Neoclassical environ-

    mental economics tried to resolve this trade-off by

    determining (shadow) prices for those uses of nature

    giving rise to negative external effects and imposingthem by means of Pigou taxes and allowance trading

    (Pigou, 1920; Coase, 1960). Although functional in

    the neoclassical setting, both approaches often proved

    to be ineffective in practice for two reasons. First, due

    to asymmetries in the stakeholders endowment with

    knowledge and other resources and the public good

    character of most parts of the environment, it is

    impossible to determine the true willingness to pay

    (i.e. the price) for the services of nature with sufficient

    accuracy. And, second, even if this price could be

    determined sufficiently exactly, it may be doubtedwhether the two targets of satisfying the needs and

    wants of humans and meeting the requirements for the

    natural environment to sustain could be brought to

    coherence. Reasons for this are, among other things,

    the difference in time horizon between myopic

    humans and long-term processes in nature and, most

    of all, the basic ignorance of most individuals con-

    cerning the wide variety of causeeffect relationships

    in nature (I will deal with this point more extensively

    in Section 3). From the neoclassical perspective, this

    implies that the economy within or, respectively, with-

    out its natural environment would not converge to the

    same equilibrium and, therefore, possible disturbances

    1 In this context, organizational innovations are not mentioned

    explicitly because, with regard to their inputoutput relation, they

    can be treated like either process or product innovations.

    2 Since the Brundtland report (WCED, 1987) sustainability is

    usually discussed as a state or, better, a development in which three

    kinds of interests are met simultaneously: (1) the interest of the

    present generation to generally improve their actual living condi-

    tions (i.e. economic sustainability), (2) the search for an equalization

    of the living conditions between rich and poor (i.e. social sustain-

    ability), and (3) the interest in an intact natural environment that is

    capable of supporting the needs of future generations (i.e. ecological

    sustainability). Since social sustainability including the (re)distribu-

    tion of natural resources and the benefits drawn from their use aresubject to intense political discussion and continued negotiations

    especially between developed and developing countries, the norma-

    tive character of this issue is readily accepted as an argument to

    exclude it from the scientific discourse. Although balancing the

    interests of succeeding generations is a normative issue as well,

    the lacking possibility of the future generations to participate in the

    corresponding political discussion is in this case taken as a justifica-

    tion and as a potential for science to make fruitful contributions.

    Consequently, the discussion of sustainability particularly among

    economists essentially focuses on the question how to allow for the

    strongest possible growth now without compromising the potential

    for growth to persist in the future.

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 3

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    4/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    of the economyecology relationship cannot be cor-

    rected by merely relying on the market mechanism

    (Rennings, 2000).

    2.2. Strong sustainability and innovation

    As a consequence of the failure of market competi-

    tion alone to induce the innovations necessary to bring

    about ecological sustainability, a different approach

    has to be used. In search for such an approach, it is

    worthwhile to look more closely at the distinction

    between weak and strong sustainability and at the

    sustainability indicators developed in relation to the

    latter concept.

    From the anthropocentric point of view, sustainabledevelopment implies the preservation of a pool of

    natural resources and man-made capital that provides

    each generation with the opportunity to have its activ-

    ities based on equivalent sets of man-made and natural

    capital. This conceptualization of sustainable devel-

    opment as bnon-declining wealthQ (Pearce et al., 1989)

    finds two basically different expressions. On the one

    hand, economists in the tradition of Hartwick (1978)

    and Solow (1974, 1986) argue that a society using an

    exhaustible stock of resources could enjoy a constant

    stream of consumption over time if it invested all the

    rents from tapping on those resources, that is, if it held

    the overall capital stock constant. Evidently, this weak

    approach to sustainability is based on the implicit

    assumption that both natural and man-made capitals

    are complete (i.e. reversible) substitutes. While this

    assumption may be met in some cases, it does not

    hold in general because, first, for many types of

    natural assets (e.g. an endangered species, a habitat

    or the ozone layer) technical substitutes do not exist

    and once brought about many changes turn out to be

    irreversible (Munda, 1997). Moreover, the argument

    developed above clearly indicates that the mechan-isms for specifically identifying and implementing

    suitable technologies or inducing necessary innova-

    tions do not exist in the neoclassical framework

    underlying weak sustainability.

    On the other hand, concepts of strong sustainabil-

    ity, which are characteristic for ecological economics,

    specify the natural capital in terms of its physical

    function rather than the costs of actual damage caused

    to it. The logic of this approach is based on the

    assumption that, in order to continue to rely on certain

    essential functions of the environment (e.g. assimila-

    tion of waste or supply with resources), the ecosystem

    or at least certain parts of it have to be kept intact.

    Accordingly, substitutability has to be proven in eachspecific case rather than simply being assumed.

    Although this approach does not exclude monetiza-

    tion in principle (e.g. in terms of the opportunity costs

    of the avoided or restricted use of the environment),

    the (how ever aggregated) monetary figure does not

    suffice to eventually specify the state of sustainability.

    Instead, it is necessary to follow the following three-

    step procedure and to (1) identify those elements of

    the natural capital that are essential for the mainte-

    nance of the ecosystems stability or, better, its ability

    to recover from distressing impacts (i.e., resilience),(2) select those elements that are related to, and

    possibly endangered by, economic activities, and (3)

    derive a set of indicators each of which reflects the

    actual condition of a specific aspect of the environ-

    ment and puts it into relation to the sustainable state as

    determined by any suitable management rule (see

    Opschoor and Reijnders, 1991). Typical examples of

    the latter approach are Pressure-State-Response (PSR)

    indicators like the one employed by the OECD. Here,

    the causes of environmental problems (bpressureQ),

    the actual state of the environment (bstateQ), and

    efforts to solve the problem (bresponseQ) are moni-

    tored and quantified in separate modules (OECD,

    1993).

    The role of innovation in the latter framework

    consists in modifying existing, or implementing

    new, technologies in such a way that identified pres-

    sures are relaxed and problematic environmental

    states are improved. So far, however, this concept is

    still quite limited such that it needs further qualifica-

    tion and extension.

    2.3. Critical loads and non-linearity

    An important qualification of PSR-like schemes

    refers to their implication that it is generally possible

    to quantify the effect of an innovation in terms of

    reduction of those processes or their side-effects that

    caused the corresponding pressure in the first place. In

    reality, however, many counter-measures later turn out

    to be themselves not without side-effects such that the

    relaxation of pressure in their target field may go

    along with the increase of pressures in other fields.

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx4

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    5/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Rennings and Wiggering (1997) explain how this lack

    of innovative efficiency arises. The logic underlying

    the PSR approach implies a correlation according to

    which stronger (weaker) efforts to counteract an envir-onmental problem by means of the best-available

    technology generally lead to the alleviation (enhance-

    ment) of the pressure and, thus, to the improvement

    (deterioration) of the condition of the environment.

    Unfortunately, in the natural environment, such a

    blinearQ relation between causes and effects is not

    the rule. In contrast, effects like the following are

    frequently observed. Although in an agriculturally

    dominated region the intense use of mineral fertilizers

    was common practice for quite a while, contamination

    of the ground-water with nitrate could be observedonly recentlywith a strongly increasing rate. In this

    case, the existence (and transgression) of carrying

    capacities or buffer capacities gives rise to non-linear

    processes which typically show sudden changes or

    even jumps. Returning to a sustainable state then

    not only requires the reduction of emissions below

    the respective critical load or critical level. Since the

    latter may itself be adversely affected by the harm, it

    additionally requires the repair of the damages that

    had so far been caused by the excess emissions.

    With regard to the role of innovation as a consti-

    tuent of response in the PSR scheme, the non-linearity

    basically implies a substantial element of uncertainty.

    However, uncertainty is not limited to the adverse

    effects that innovation is supposed to reverse. The

    innovation itself is a source of uncertainty in so far

    as it can be the source of lacking sustainability unfore-

    seen at the moment of its implementation. More about

    the causes of uncertainty and approaches to deal with

    it will be said in the following.

    3. Sustainable innovations and the evolutionaryperspective

    Section 2 has elaborated on the possible impact of

    innovation on ecological sustainability and on the

    dependence of this impact on the underlying concepts

    of sustainability and the economic paradigms related

    to them. It could be shown that the preconditions for

    innovations effectively responding to emerging eco-

    logical challenges are rather demanding. This is not

    only due to the basic structural complexity of inter-

    action between a wide variety of elements in the

    economy as well as in the natural environment; it is

    even more due to the specific temporal interrelated-

    ness of these elements. In order to deal with thesedifficulties, a closer look will be taken at concepts like

    uncertainty, irreversibility, path dependency and coe-

    volution which are closely related to innovation in the

    sustainability context and in general and extensively

    discussed in the evolutionary branch of economics.

    3.1. Fundamental uncertainty and the trial-and-error

    approach of evolution

    It is the wide variety and high complexity of

    interactions between human actors and between thelatter and their natural environment that renders

    human (economic) activities as well as their environ-

    mental effects highly unpredictable particularly in the

    long run (see also Section 2.3). However, the uncer-

    tainty accruing in this context is not just a matter of

    probability distributions within a known or assumed

    set of possibilities and therefore cannot be accounted

    for by the concept of risk. Instead uncertainty is better

    characterized as ignorance in the face of novel, fun-

    damentally unpredictable, events. So the question

    arises how to deal with this fundamental uncertainty.

    If complete knowledge about the set of available

    alternatives is lacking, actors cannot maximize the

    expected utility of alternative choices and, thus,

    rational decisions cannot be made. One approach to

    the solution of this problem was made by Simon

    (1957) who proposed that human decision-making

    in situations of incomplete knowledge may better be

    described as being based on bounded rationality.

    However, the boundedly rational decision-makers

    striving for an acceptable (i.e. dsatisficingT) rather

    than a maximum level of utility still requires some

    knowledge as to which goals are attainable in princi- ple. Additionally, even bounded rationality assumes

    fixed sets of individual preferences that basically

    include all possible alternativesan assumption that

    simply turns out to be underdetermined in the face of

    real novelty.

    Therefore, it may be advisable to look at the solu-

    tion of (long-run) problems related to fundamental

    uncertainty and endogenously changing preferences

    from a completely different perspective: Darwins

    approach to evolution in nature. Like society, nature

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 5

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    6/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    is characterized by the complex interaction between

    its constituents, the living organisms and their physi-

    cal environment, and thus by the existence of funda-

    mental uncertainty and non-linearity which togethercan give rise to the formation of new species or the

    sudden extinction of major parts of the existing bio-

    sphere as well as for the persistence of existing spe-

    cies over prolonged periods of time. In order to

    bmanageQ such unpredictable processes, nature relies

    on the principles of heritance, random variation and

    natural selectionwith diversity created by random

    mutation and recombination within the existing

    genetic pool and selection resulting from continuous

    competition between species with inherited properties

    for a limited set of resources.A further step toward an increased problem solving

    capability in nature and, ultimately, in man is based on

    the capability of an organism to undergo specific or

    individual adaptation to varying circumstances and to

    transmit the acquired knowledge to other organisms

    that is to learn and communicate. While evolution on

    this level is based on social norms, individual values,

    and ideas rather than material genes, the basic princi-

    ples nevertheless remain essentially unchanged (Sar-

    torius, 2003, especially chap. 4). Initially, the

    perception of a problem leads to the assessment of a

    variety of alternative approaches to its solution. Those

    approaches giving rise to the solution of the problem

    are selected; those that fail are rejected. The solutions

    with the better performance are further modified and

    tested in subsequent rounds of selection.3 The wider

    the variety of alternative approaches the higher is the

    probability that at least one of them may perform

    better than in the status quo. With respect to human

    behavior, special use of evolutionary principles has

    been made by many proponents of evolutionary eco-

    nomics: in his search for new business opportunities,

    for instance, Schumpeters (1934) entrepreneurassumes significant risk but, at the same time, gives

    rise to novelty; Hayek (1978) interprets market com-

    petition as a process of selection (and detection) of

    innovations by means of the willingness-to-pay on the

    demand side; and Nelson and Winter (1982) show

    how profit may serve as the selecting force thatleads to the persistence of some innovations and to

    the vanishing of most others. A particular case of

    evolution leading to the solution of unprecedented

    problems is the selection of cooperation rules on the

    group level, a task that could never be fulfilled by

    individuals on the basis of their mere rationality

    (Hayek, 1988; Sartorius, 2002). In this context, envir-

    onmental and social sustainability can respectively be

    interpreted as cooperation (i.e. fair behavior with the

    potential of winwin situations) between succeeding

    generations and different parts of the same generation.The relevance of fundamental uncertainty and the

    corresponding problem-solving capability for sustain-

    ability is quite evident. Human activities frequently

    generate adverse environmental side-effects which,

    due to the complexity of their interaction with the

    environment, are often unforeseen (see Section 2.3).

    In the search for (long-term) sustainability, it therefore

    makes little sense to exclusively rely on the causes of,

    and solutions to, specific environmental problems

    since they may be subject to considerable variation

    over time. This does not at all imply that the determi-

    nation of critical substances and the application of

    critical thresholds do not make sense. Especially in

    the short run they are even indispensable. However, in

    the long run, that is, in the time perspective in which

    the sustainability concept is usefully applied, the pro-

    cess leading to sustainability also has to account for

    the conditions under which the identification of pro-

    blems as well as the search for the corresponding

    solutions and their translation into the appropriate

    measures takes place. Rather than referring to specific

    innovations whose characterization as being sustain-

    able can only be temporary, sustainability should beviewed as a property of the system and determined

    with reference to the systems general capability to

    bring about a variety of potentially useful innovations

    and, should the occasion arise, to allow for the ready

    implementation of the most promising alternative. In

    short, sustainability also, and from the evolutionary

    perspective predominantly, includes the flexibility and

    versatility of the entire system to allow for a quick and

    effective response to whichever environmental pro-

    blem arises (see Erdmann, 2000).

    3 Note that selection of the best alternative would only be possible

    in a static environment with very low complexity. In reality, the

    higher degree of complexity leads to the emergence of local rather

    than global optima and, due to the dynamics of the system, the

    successive choice of better alternatives influences the actual speci-

    fication of the respectively best alternative. Therefore, selection in

    the evolutionary approach adopted here refers to the better, but not

    to the best (see also Rammel, 2003).

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx6

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    7/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    3.2. Coevolution and the extension of innovation

    beyond the technological sphere

    The concept of coevolution basically refers to thefact that the development of an organism does not

    simply follow the conditions set by its environment,

    but that, in the process of adaptation, the organism

    itself is a source of change for this environment. In

    biology, coevolution usually describes the mutual

    adaptation of ecologically related species such as

    butterflies and plants (e.g. Ehrlich and Raven, 1964)

    which, under certain circumstances, can give rise to an

    arms race known as the Red Queen effect. In ecolo-

    gical economics, coevolution refers to the socio-eco-

    nomic development as a process of adaptation to achanging environment while being itself a source of

    this change ( Norgaard, 1994; Gowdy, 1994). While

    evolution in the socio-economic sphere was shown to

    have the potential of giving rise to better adaptation to

    the natural environment (Cavalli-Sforza and Feldman,

    1981; Boyd and Richerson, 1985), coevolution in this

    context typically accounts for the mutual interference

    between socio-economic and natural developments

    which, depending on their specific characteristics,

    can facilitate or hinder innovation processes leading

    to lesser or greater sustainability. In the case of spray-

    ing pesticides in agriculture, for instance, the forma-

    tion of resistance is a clear indication for a decrease in

    sustainability.

    With regard to sustainability-related innovations,

    coevolution has several crucial implications. First,

    the mutual interaction between several social spheres

    increases complexity giving rise to a higher degree of

    uncertainty that needs to be managed by human actors

    trying to pursue a sustainable development (see Sec-

    tion 3.1).

    Second, coevolution involving the social or cul-

    tural sphere has the potential of giving rise to a highdegree of diversity with regard to flexibility and

    adaptability to temporally or spatially varying condi-

    tions (Munda, 1997). This potential is however con-

    trasted by the possibility of the Red Queen effect

    which is likely to give rise to maladaptation and the

    reduction of diversity. These two opposing effects are

    the basis for the trade-off between diversity and flex-

    ibility on the one hand and economic efficiency on the

    other (Rammel, 2003), which will be further discussed

    in Section 4.

    Third, the coevolution (especially the Red Queen

    effect) is an intriguing example of path dependence

    where the developmental path can not easily be shifted

    from one trajectory to another (see Section 3.3).Forth, and most evidently, coevolution implies that

    successful innovation in general, and successful sus-

    tainable innovation in particular, has to acknowledge

    the involvement of, and mutual interaction between,

    more than the mere technical and economic spheres.

    The current human way of life being coherent with the

    existing institutions (including codified rules and

    social value and belief systems) and giving rise to

    technology-caused transgressions of the sustainability

    boundary in many and profound ways and, contra-

    riwise, the support of this lifestyle by just thesetechno-economic conditions are an evident instance

    of coevolution. Accordingly, efficiency changes under

    the proviso of sustainability may be achieved more

    readily through an integrated approach employing

    institutional or social in addition to technical innova-

    tions. With regard to the aim for increased sustain-

    ability, it is therefore necessary to broaden the view

    from the merely technical towards the social and

    political aspects of innovations. In accord with these

    thoughts, Klemmer et al. (1999, see also Rennings,

    2000) broadly define the term denvironmental

    innovationT as all measures of relevant actors that

    lead to the development and application of new

    ideas, behavior, products and processes and, thereby,

    contribute to a reduction of environmental burdens or

    to ecologically specified sustainability targets. This

    may include process and product innovations, organi-

    zational changes in the management of firms, and, on

    the social and political level, changes in environmen-

    tally counter-productive regulation and legislature,

    consumer behavior, or lifestyle in general. This

    emphasis on social innovations is all the more impor-

    tant because unsustainable development itself is oftenthe result of btechnology outpacing changes in social

    organizationQ (Norgaard, 1994, p. 16). Moreover, after

    an intense and extended discussion in environmental

    economics about the brightQ instruments towards an

    environmentally sound, sustainable development, it

    more and more turns out that there is not a single

    suitable instrument. Instead, it seems to depend on the

    respective circumstances (e.g. type of competition or

    existence of information asymmetries), whether Pigou

    taxes, markets for pollution rights, the setting of stan-

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 7

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    8/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    dards, or even temporary subsidization of promising

    innovations is the more effective instrument

    (Rennings, 2000). Jaenicke (1999) even goes one

    step further by claiming that the relevance of instru-ments for environmental policy has generally been

    overemphasized. Instead, the discussion should

    focus on other elements of a successful environmental

    policy such as long-term goals, mixes of instruments,

    policy styles, and constellations of actors.

    Altogether, the above emphasis on social and

    political aspects makes clear that the success of

    sustainable innovations depends on more than their

    mere technical (or even economic) superiority. This

    is all the more evident when, following the sugges-

    tion of Section 3.1, sustainability is considered as the property of an entire system rather than a specific

    innovation.

    3.3. Irreversibility and path dependence

    Beside fundamental uncertainty and the need for

    diversity following from the preceding sections, the

    complexity of multiple-interaction systems has

    another at least equally important consequence for

    the sustainability discussion. If the sequence of events

    within a complex system was described by means of

    several independent parameters, careful analysis

    would reveal non-ergodicity. That is, of all basically

    possible states only some are likely to occur in any

    single moment. Whether or not a given state is likely

    to arise accordingly depends on the past or, more

    exactly, on the succession of states preceding the

    actual statea phenomenon called path dependence.

    In biology, this issue is discussed among evolutionary

    biologists and ecologists in the context of the phylo-

    genetic development of organisms and successions in

    ecosystems. Gould and Eldredge (1977), for instance,

    emphasize that the complex architecture of all moreadvanced organisms strongly limits the potential for

    successful further mutations and, thus, better adapta-

    tion. The reason for this is that most changes that may

    be advantageous from an isolated perspective may not

    be so in a complex context in which advantageousness

    requires the meeting of many strict preconditions. As

    a consequence, a variety of mutations would have to

    come up simultaneously which is very unlikely to

    occur. So, once a certain amount of genetic informa-

    tion has accumulated within an organism and hap-

    pened to be arranged in a sufficiently complex system

    of mutual interaction, the entire system is stabilized

    against further change (Waddington, 1969). Interest-

    ingly, the parameter decisive for the stability of thesystem is the average number of interaction from one

    element to others and not so much the number of

    genes (Kaufman, 1995).

    With regard to sustainability, path dependence

    plays a particularly important role in three respects.

    First, as shown above, the wide variety of life forms in

    nature represents a large source of solutions for pro-

    blems not only in the natural environment but also in

    the human spherefor the assimilation of wastes, the

    production of food, and the design of pharmaceuticals,

    to mention just a few examples. Every species evi-dently represents a piece of knowledge that could

    potentially be useful for present or future generations.

    Against the backdrop of path dependence, however, it

    is also clear that the loss of any species leads to a loss

    of such knowledge that is irreversible. For every

    species is the outcome of a succession of phylogenetic

    stages in which the formation of every single stage is

    based on the existence of its respective predecessor

    a fact that renders it impossible to reconstruct a spe-

    cies once it has been lost.

    Second, even when knowledge is not directly

    acquired from models in nature, but derived through

    trial and error in the scientific process, this does not

    imply that all knowledge is equally accessible.

    Instead, technical knowledge generation is character-

    ized by technological paradigms (Dosi, 1982, 1988).

    Within such paradigms, knowledge acquisition occurs

    gradually along the respective trajectoriesby the

    systematic variation of single parameters and the

    selection of those variants showing the desired effect

    most markedly. Incremental innovations proceeding

    along such a path are to some extent predictable but

    the marginal cost-to-effect ratio is subject to increasesuch that maintaining the profitability (in economic

    terms) of innovations becomes increasingly more dif-

    ficult. With regard to sustainability, end-of-pipe solu-

    tions fit into this category because they add

    environmental soundness to an existing technology.

    According to economic wisdom, they do this at

    increasing marginal costs.

    An alternative route is the search for radical

    innovations leading to a transition between trajec-

    tories in different paradigms. While this approach

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx8

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    9/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    has the potential of achieving much better profitabil-

    ity in economic contexts, it is characterized by a high

    degree of uncertainty representing a substantial

    threshold for typically risk-averse people. In the sus-tainability context, Porter and van der Linde (1995)

    emphasize that integrated environmental innovations

    (where harm is avoided from the beginning rather

    than redressed after its generation) can be so efficient

    that the environmentally beneficial effect induced by

    suitable regulatory measures is achieved at no addi-

    tional cost.

    The third aspect of path dependence to be

    addressed here refers to the induced resistance-to-

    change and, thereby, to some extent relates to the

    second. It plays an important role in the discussionabout technology development and is of central

    importance for the objective of this paper: the search

    of determinants for a sustainable technology develop-

    ment. Innovations and the introduction of new tech-

    nologies often are the key instruments to the

    (temporary) avoidance or redressing of adverse envir-

    onmental effects. However, even if negative external

    effects were completely internalized and the new

    technology turned out to be technologically and envir-

    onmentally superior to the existing one, successful

    commercialization and diffusion into the market can-

    not be taken for granted. A frequently quoted example

    for this kind of failure of a superior technology to

    prevail refers to the design of typewriter and computer

    keyboards (David, 1985). Although the totality of

    users could benefit from the use of a better design

    that allows for a significantly higher writing speed, the

    traditional QWERTY keyboard is maintained because

    just for the first users of any new alternative, a devia-

    tion from the dominant design would cause costs that

    are much higher than the expected benefits (Arthur,

    1988). While network externalities are the relevant

    factor in the latter case, a variety of other effectswill be identified in Section 5 that lead to the lock-

    in of a conventional technology and, accordingly, to

    the lock-out of its superior challenger.

    4. Second-order sustainability

    While traditional approaches to achieving (strong)

    sustainability typically start with the identification of

    the technical or social causes of a current lack of

    sustainability and then point to possible alternatives,

    the implications of fundamental uncertainty, coevolu-

    tion and path dependency go far beyond such an

    assessment of specific innovations. In order to accord-ingly develop a more comprehensive conception of

    sustainability, it is necessary to return once again to

    the shortcomings of the traditional approach of attain-

    ing sustainability.

    4.1. Knowledge gain through trial-and-error

    First, in most societies, and all the more in all

    advanced economies, the common wealth is yielded

    by the complex interaction of numerous individuals in

    the context of a variety of technologies and social andpolitical institutions. Due to the uncertainty prevalent

    in such complex systems (see Section 3.1), it is

    impossible to predict all the specific effects of any

    human intervention. This argument explains the some-

    times low success in fitting a new technology or

    institution into a given setting in general. And it

    particularly explains the frequent failure of technical

    or institutional innovations in terms of sustainability.

    As a consequence, the search for increased sustain-

    ability, while in principle being the result of human

    action, will usually not be the well-specified outcome

    of a man-made plan. Hayek (1973) referred to this

    phenomenon as the bfailure of constructivist

    rationalismQ and identified mans constitutive lack of

    knowledge as its main cause. Instead of looking for

    the one and only perfect substitute, Hayek suggests, it

    therefore appears much more promising to engage

    into a trial-and-error process based on a variety of

    potential substitutes.

    4.2. Diversity as precondition for trial-and-error

    The second argument in disfavor of the specificreplacement of a non-sustainable technology (or insti-

    tution) also refers to the uncertainty aspect, but it

    focuses on the effect of dynamic change rather than

    the mere lack of knowledge. Since, in a complex

    system, the change in one component always gives

    rise to a change of the restrictive conditions for all

    others (compare the discussion of coevolution in

    Section 3.2), it is little surprising that sustainability

    as achieved by the employment of whichever technol-

    ogy or institution (e.g. property rights or social pre-

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 9

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    10/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    ferences) can only be a temporary state of a system.

    Even those interventions that successfully redress

    instances of lacking sustainability at first will them-

    selves change the entire system in such a way thatnew losses of sustainability are likely incurred in the

    futureeither due to their interaction with other com-

    ponents or directly by themselves. In order to main-

    tain sustainability over longer periods of time, it is

    therefore not sufficient to simply solve a given pro-

    blem; rather the problem-solving capacity must keep

    pace with the rise of new problems. So, the Darwinian

    process of trial-and-error has to cope with timea

    scarce resource especially in dynamic systems; and in

    order to do so, two preconditions need to be met

    which at first appear to be given quite naturally, butin fact do not come for free. Variation, the first pre-

    condition, implies the existence of a wide variety of

    potential alternatives on which selection can act. For

    socioeconomic systems in general, Matutinovic

    (2001) shows that diversity is a systematic and resi-

    lient property the lack of which could provoke

    instability and eventually lead to the collapse of the

    system. Since in present-day economies the selective

    effect of market competition is rather strong, self-

    sustained maintenance of a high degree of diversity

    cannot be taken for granted. Especially with regard to

    the uncertainty associated with long-term sustainabil-

    ity problems, it may therefore even be necessary to

    actively keep competition in a more early stage

    against the self-enforcing advantages of productiv-

    ity-increasing specialization (see Kemp, 1997).

    Accordingly, it is evident that this diversity is costly

    since, (1) for the supply of promising technologies

    society needs to promote learning, that is, to invest

    into human capital. More specifically, incentives for

    an engagement into R&D have to be provided for the

    respective firms. (2) Prior to eventually reaching mar-

    ket diffusion and successful commercialization, parti-cularly the more radical inventions may additionally

    need governmental support (e.g. through subsidization

    or the creation of niche markets). (3) Finally, the

    partial suspension of market forces needed to maintain

    a certain degree of diversity and keep competition in

    an early stage not only leads to the less efficient

    adaptation of technologies to the existing uses; (4) it

    also prevents part of the cost-saving potentials of

    economies of scale and scope or learning effects

    from being realized. The trade-off we face here is

    one between (short-term) economic and (long-term)

    sustainability-related efficiency.

    4.3. Lock-in resolution as precondition fortrial-and-error

    In contrast to the preceding arguments, the third

    argument against the possibility of an easy substitu-

    tion of more sustainable technologiesand respec-

    tively the second precondition for the successful

    employment of trial-and-error processesrelates to

    the systemic integration of established technologies

    and institutions rather than their potential substitutes.

    For even in the presence of a variety of alternative

    solutions, selection and further development of themost suitable technology by means of the market

    forces will remain ineffective so long as the estab-

    lished technology is subject to strong stabilization and

    withstands its displacement by even strongly superior

    alternatives.4 In Section 3.3, this resistance to change

    of the established technology known as lock-in was

    shown to be caused by a wide variety of effects of

    which a more complete account will be given in

    Section 5. Sustainability is particularly affected by

    such a lock-in because the more radicaland thereby

    often more effectiveinnovations (Rennings, 2000;

    Ashford, 2002) face more opposition than the less

    effective incremental ones because they belong to a

    new paradigm. To the extent that lock-in effects are to

    be undermined, economic actors again have to bear

    the cost of refraining from the realization of the

    corresponding economies of scale, learning and net-

    work effects, etc. (see Section 4.2). Although, this

    time, the trade-off between short-term and long-term

    efficiency is basically a purely economic one, it has

    important consequences for sustainability.

    4 The careful reader will have recognized that, on the one hand,the proposed approach relies on the selective capacity of (market)

    competition to identify and gradually improve more sustainable

    technologies while, on the other hand, competition has to be par-

    tially suspended in order to create the diversity on which selection

    can act. This apparent contradiction is resolved by temporal, spatial

    or functional disjunction of the two functions. While temporal

    disjunction can be achieved by the mere alternation of phases of

    variation and selection, spatial and functional disjunction, respec-

    tively, imply implementation and testing of new technologies on a

    locally or application-specific markets. The latter two approaches

    also constitute the basis for strategic niche management (Kemp et

    al., 1998).

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx10

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    11/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    4.4. Second-order sustainability as adaptive flexibility

    While the specific problem-solving capacity of cer-

    tain innovations gives rise to sustainability in specificcircumstances and for limited periods of time, it is the

    total number of such solutions or, more concisely, the

    context-dependent trial-and-error process giving rise to

    their implementation that brings about sustainability in

    more general termsin the long run and in dynamic

    contexts. The latter idea conforms well with the view of

    Kemp (1997), Van den Bergh and Gowdy (2000),

    Rammel and Van den Bergh (2003) and Rammel

    (2003) that sustainability is the result of a strategic

    process (rather than a certain state) trying to deal

    with uncertainty and unpredictable emerging propertiesby means ofbadaptive flexibilityQ. This emphasis of the

    process character does, of course, not render specific

    sustainable innovations dispensable in the search for

    sustainability in general, but due to their conditional

    effectiveness they represent sufficient (rather than

    necessary) conditions of sustainability whereas the

    conditions for the effective working of the basic trial-

    and-error process are necessary (but not sufficient)

    ones. Since, from the functional perspective, bgeneralQ

    sustainability determines the conditions under which

    bspecificQ sustainability can be achieved, the two kinds

    of sustainability describe the function of a system on

    two different levels with general sustainability repre-

    senting the more basic level. Since sustainability, and

    more so its lack, is immediately perceived as specific

    instance of resource or environmental problems

    whereas the working of its general problem-solving

    capacity (albeit more fundamental) is less immediately

    evident, I refer to the two aspects as first-order and

    second-order sustainability, respectively.

    In the preceding parts of this section, a variety of

    measures was mentioned that would increase diversity,

    improve selection and, thus, support second-order sus-tainability, but most of these measures would come

    with significant (opportunity) costs only. Conversely,

    the lack of second-order sustainability caused by the

    unwillingness to pay this price leads itself to the incap-

    ability to adapt to changing circumstances and, thus, to

    a loss of welfare that arises from the high cost of

    redressing or functionally replacing a damaged envir-

    onment. In this trade-off between the costs and benefits

    of second-order sustainability, the optimum degree of

    diversity is not easily determined ex ante. However,

    also this optimum can be approached in a trial-and-

    error mannerby the gradual change and subsequent

    assessment of the conditions for second-order sustain-

    ability particularly in those industries and economicsectors where the most severe violations of first-order

    sustainability are encountered.

    5. Determinants of second-order sustainability

    In Section 3.3, it was suggested that certain struc-

    tural properties of a given technology can severely

    restrict the probability with which new innovations

    may become effective. The way in which these states

    of rigidity are sometimes discussed (David, 1985) ormodeled (Arthur, 1988) in the literature could imply

    that such states of stability are omnipresent and, once

    they turn up, tend to persist for prolonged periods of

    time. Not surprisingly, many economists (e.g. Lie-

    bowitz and Margolis, 1994) are convinced that latter

    position crossly overstates the relevance of network

    externalities, as this would allow them to become the

    cause of almost ubiquitous market failure. In the latter

    debate, an intermediate position is taken by Witt

    (1997) who, while principally acknowledging the

    relevance of network effects, limits their general

    importance for the function of the market to certain

    restricted periods of time. So periods of stability tend

    to alternate with periods of instability where new

    networks can be formed. Such a period in which the

    direction of technological progress is flexible is

    referred to as a bwindow of opportunityQ (Witt,

    1997). Disregarding these windows could severely

    hamper, if not completely inhibit, the introduction of

    any useful innovation. And even when, in the pursuit

    of sustainability, a new (sustainable) technology was

    successfully pushed by governmental regulation with

    no regard at the specific circumstances, the differencebetween stable and unstable phases would be worth a

    lot of money. It will therefore be the main objective of

    this section to identify those factors that allow poli-

    tical and other decision makers to make a well-

    founded judgement as to whether the preference for

    a potentially sustainable innovation is based on eco-

    nomic, social and political feasibility.

    The first set of factors will be economic ones. It

    will become evident in the following that the variety

    of relevant effects is wider and their respective time

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 11

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    12/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    pattern more diverse than may have been implied by

    the repeated reference to network externalities in pre-

    vious parts of this paper. Additionally, it is a special

    characteristic of many sustainable technologies that,beyond the competitive disadvantage frequently aris-

    ing from their failure to internalize reduced external

    costs, the government typically plays a crucial role in

    overcoming existing barriers to competitiveness in the

    relevant markets. In doing so the government inevi-

    tably faces opposition from those whose interests are

    negatively affected: the incumbent industry and other

    groups paying the price for the measures taken. Typi-

    cally, a government or policy makers in general are

    not inclined to neglect such an opposition unless the

    promoting forces from other parts of the society aresufficiently strong. More so, major techno-economic

    changes require a general openness or even a readi-

    ness to change (i.e. a phase of instability) on the part

    of the political system. For these reasons, the techno-

    economic factors will have to be supplemented by

    both, political and social factors. The selection of

    these criteria occurred on the basis of a priori theore-

    tical plausibility considerations and ex post after the

    screening of relevant case studies (Sartorius and Zun-

    del, 2005). Due to the large number of relevant fac-

    tors, it is not possible to present them here at length;

    for a more detailed discussion, the reader is therefore

    referred to Sartorius and Zundel (2005, ch.2).

    5.1. Determinants of (in)stability in the

    techno-economic system

    5.1.1. Economies of scale

    Economies of scale account for the greater effi-

    ciency of larger manufacturing devices. They are typi-

    cally measured on the firm level in terms of average

    unit cost as a function of output rate. As these average

    costs decrease with increasing scale, they give rise tostrong competitive disadvantage for new technologies

    which, at the beginning of their life cycle, cannot

    immediately engage into large-scale production.

    5.1.2. Economies of scope

    Economies of scope account for synergies between

    different production lines from the common use of

    certain resources, intermediate products, or production

    facilities. While economies of scope lead to important

    cost decreases for the established industry, the mutual

    dependencies between existing processes renders it

    more difficult for a radically new technology to

    become competitive.

    5.1.3. Learning by doing

    Unlike the cases of economies of scale and econo-

    mies of scope, the cost decreasing effect of growing

    experience in designing, constructing (dlearning by

    doingT), and using production facilities (dlearning by

    usingT) is usually expressed as the percentage of cost/

    price reduction per doubling of the cumulative pro-

    duction output in the respective branch. While learn-

    ing effects give rise to a large potential for further cost

    reductions for any new technology, they confront it

    with a high cost disadvantage in the beginning.

    5.1.4. Network externalities

    Network externalities refer to the fact that the

    utility derived from the use of a given technology is

    positively correlated with the number of its users.

    Alternatively, a technology can be subject to network

    externalities if it relies on another technology that

    forms a network in its turn. The weaker the depen-

    dence on the established network or the better the

    compatibility, the smaller is the entry barrier for the

    new technology.

    5.1.5. Sunk cost

    Investment into a new technology can cause sig-

    nificant sunk costs if it renders useless an old technol-

    ogy prior to its complete depreciation. While sunk

    costs represent opportunity costs of any new technol-

    ogy, they do not come to bear in competitive markets.

    Instead, they are relevant whenever market access is

    restricted by other causes. The rate of capitalization in

    the relevant industry and data about the investment

    cycle can be used to assess sunk costs; but this

    analysis needs to be supplemented by the competitivestructure of the industry in question (see below).

    5.1.6. Market structure

    Although natural or regulated oligopolies or mono-

    polies do not exclude competition in principle, such

    market structures will provide the corresponding firms

    with strong incentives to maintain the existing market

    barriers, engage in strong activities to preserve these

    monopoly rents and neglect innovative activities.

    While the innovation-related forces of market competi-

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx12

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    13/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    tion may be characterized as biased in favor of the

    established technology by (above-mentioned) increas-

    ing returns to adoption, any non-competitive market

    structure will stabilize the technological status quoeven more because it does not give rise to innovation

    in the first place.

    5.1.7. Potential versus risk

    In order to replenish their earned innovation rent

    and, thus, maintain their current profit margins within

    a competitive market environment, entrepreneurs

    occasionally have to complement their technological

    portfolios with more radical innovations. Since the

    latter are associated with higher risk, an (expected)

    strong potential (including its regulatory conditions)will be decisive for the success or failure of this

    technology being adopted.

    5.1.8. Demand

    To be considered an economic substitute for an

    existing technology, a new technology at first has to

    fulfill certain functions of the former. In order to

    attract the attention and raise the specific demand of

    consumers and investors that would prefer the more

    familiar, established technology over its otherwise

    quite dissimilar counterpart, a new technology has to

    fulfill certain extra-functions to overcome this inertia.

    5.1.9. Niche markets

    If the entry barrier for a new technology is high, it

    may need a long period of subsidization until general

    competitiveness is achieved. At the same time, partial

    competitiveness may be achieved much sooner under

    certain, geographically or culturally specified, favor-

    able conditionsoften called a niche market. Since

    the existence and extent of niche markets can be

    decisive for reaching competitiveness of a new tech-

    nology in general, the strategic use or the artificial(regulatory) creation of such niche markets can be an

    important approach to the successful implementation

    of a new technology as suggested by the strategic-

    niche-management approach of Kemp et al. (1998).

    5.2. Determinants of in-/stability in the political system

    The basic characteristics of the political system

    generally play an important role in allowing a new,

    more sustainable technology to prevail. As a precon-

    dition for this to happen, the political system either

    must be in favor of the new technology from the

    beginning or it needs to be destabilized itself in the

    first place. While in the former case, structural char-acteristics of the political system play the most impor-

    tant role, both structural and procedural aspects are

    important in the latter. The following enumeration will

    begin with the structural factors.

    5.2.1. Institutional embeddedness

    Many technologies, particularly those related to

    environmental protection, are subject to substantial

    political regulation determining which external effects

    a technology is allowed to exert and which (and how)

    others must be avoided. In this context, the closemutual relationship between the established technol-

    ogy and its regulatory environment tends to adversely

    influence the competitive position of any (radically)

    new competitor. An example for the self-stabilizing

    effect that needs to be overcome by a new technology

    is the reference many regulations make to the state of

    the art (related to the established technology) for

    solving an environmental problem.

    5.2.2. Interest groups

    While it is a matter of political culture how influ-

    ential corporate bodies or individual actors can be in

    principle, it depends on the specific circumstances

    which effects they actually give rise to. Basically,

    the power of an interest group is known to be crucially

    dependent on the size of the group, the homogeneity

    of its interests, its organization, and the resources it

    controls (Olson, 1965). Other important factors are the

    economic relevance of the industry or its history and

    cultural integration. Particularly in mature industries

    with strong market power, lobbying may pay even for

    single firms as investing in a useful regulatory envir-

    onment is more profitable than investments in tech-nological innovations (Berg, 1995) with the

    corresponding stabilizing effect for the established

    technology.

    5.2.3. Asymmetry of knowledge

    For the solution of environmental problems, gov-

    ernments and political administrations need external

    advice. As long as the problem has not attracted too

    much public attention, the necessary information is

    most convenient obtained from the industry that

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 13

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    14/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Table 1

    Factors determining the stability or instability in each of the three subsystems and the indicators used for their operationalization

    Effect Indicators Operationalization

    Economies of scale cost (or price) development as a function of actual outputaverage capitalization of industry statistical data

    identification of investment cycles recurrent phase-shifted cycling of prices and investment

    Sunk costs

    political regulation cost of retro-fitting after regulation,

    delayed investment due to expectation of uncertain measures

    Economies of scope pattern of interactions between

    production lines

    number and relevance of interactions between the old (new)

    technology and the entire production network

    Learning by doing cost (or price) development as a function of cumulative output

    direct competition with (an)other

    network(s)

    market share(s) of the competitor(s),

    availability of gateway technologies

    Network externalities

    need for compatibility with comple-

    menting infrastructure or periphery:

    existence of public standards availability of an adapter which requirements are met?cost of the adapter, legal admission possible, payable royalties

    Market structure degree of competition as a function of

    market concentration

    market share of the biggest firm(s), Herfindahl index, legal

    regulations

    riskiness availability of capital marginal interest rate, capital share of venture capitalistsPotential / risk

    problem solving capacity

    realization of an innovation rent

    technical properties (benchmarks), associated costs

    readiness to pay for extra-functions market research

    existence of natural niche markets higher prices, non-applicability of the established technology

    Techno-economicsubsystem

    Extra-demand

    creation of artificial niche markets by

    means of regulation

    (eco-)taxes, tradable certificates, cost of retro-fitting the old

    technology

    Institutional

    embeddedness

    subsidies

    protection

    norms and standards

    financial support, tax breaks

    duties, other barriers to trade

    specificity of specification

    Interest groups resources under control (power)

    structure; degree of homogeneityinfluence; earlier success

    number and economic importance of represented firms/sector

    market shares, concentration index(qualitative)

    Asymmetry of

    knowledge

    influence of industry in hearings

    number of industry-independent

    research institutions/projects

    (qualitative)

    number, financial support, number and size of commissioned

    projects

    Parliamentary

    majorities

    stability of majorities size of majority, stability of constituting coalition (number and

    relation of parties)

    Election cycle distance to the next election ditto.

    political scandals deception by possible interest holdersSingular constraints

    catastrophes accidents, unexpected discoveries

    probabili ty of legislative initiatives number and relevance of potential init iators, number of cases

    legislative vs. administrative

    regulation

    number of laws referring to ordinances, actual number of

    ordinances

    reassessment and resubmission cycles deadlines, frequency, possible consequences

    corporate structure number, size, and frequency of political involvement of

    corporate organizations

    participation frequency and extent of incorporation of political outsiders

    (e.g. NGOs) into the decision process

    Politicalsubsystem

    Decision-making

    procedures

    supranational structures share of regulation that is not subject to national legislation

    relevant publications in scientific

    literature, contributions to conferences

    number of relevant articles (keyword search) in journals etc.;

    identification of seminal articles and quotation circles

    Scientific confirm-

    ation of threat to

    sustainability independence of research sources and quantity of research sponsoring

    Public concern about

    lack of sustainability

    Socio-cultural

    subsystem

    Public acceptance of

    possible solutions

    relevant articles in newspapers, reports

    in broadcast,

    formation of major protest campaigns

    number of articles/reports over time

    number and size of campaigns

    Source: own compilation.

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx14

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    15/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    caused the problem. According to the life cycle theory

    of bureaucracies, initially independent (regulatory)

    authorities will thus successively merge theirinterests

    with those of the established industry (Martimort,1999). This bregulatory capture of bureaucraciesQ

    often leads to quick and at most half-hearted solutions

    related to the dominant technology. By contrast, more

    radical changes can only be expected, if the necessary

    knowledge comes from more independent sources

    notably state-financed scientific research.

    5.2.4. Parliamentary majorities

    Especially more radical changes are often not

    unanimously supported since the associated improve-

    ments go at the expense of the established regime.Even if its basic attitude would tend to render a

    government supportive of the corresponding change,

    its actual realization will ultimately depend on the

    strength and stability of the majority on which it can

    rely. From this perspective, a large, stable majority

    basically opens the potential for more radical changes

    than does a minute or unstable one.

    5.2.5. Election cycle

    One of the most prominent stylized facts in poli-

    tical science states that more radical political changes

    usually occur at the beginning of an election period

    while incremental changes, if not political standstill,

    follow at the end (Troja, 1998). With regard to envir-

    onmental innovations this implies a potential for a

    political window of opportunity in the post-election

    period. Unfortunately, empirical tests so far failed to

    confirm this effect of the election cycle (Horbach,

    1992). A special popularity of environmental regula-

    tion, an eminent problem pressure or, like in Germany,

    the temporal alternation between state and federal

    elections could be reasons for this.

    5.2.6. Singular constraints

    The costs and, thus, the scope of each regulatory

    measure is subject to a budget constraint. While the

    power of the interest groups behind technologies gen-

    erally influences the allocation of governmental

    resources, it depends on the social appreciation of

    environmental protection or the reputation of the

    involved parties whether the incumbent industry can

    defend its subsidies or has to share it with its more

    sustainable competitors. In this respect, singular (i.e.

    exogenous) events like political scandals and envir-

    onmental or other disaster can bring about sudden

    changes.

    5.2.7. Decision-making procedures

    Since it is not possible here to extensively analyze

    the entire political decision-making process, just a few

    criteria will be presented that may allow for a basic

    characterization of the procedural aspects of a political

    system with regard to the stabilization or destabiliza-

    tion of a specific technology.

    (1) It is an important aspect of political culture

    whether the initiatives for regulatory acts typi-

    cally come from single actors (e.g. president,members of parliament) or major bodies (gov-

    ernment, parties, or the parliament). In general,

    the former tends to give rise to more radical

    (i.e. destabilizing) changes than those of the

    latter.

    (2) The relation between legislative bodies and

    executive administration determines whether

    a regulation is enacted by means of a law that

    has to pass a lengthy parliamentary approval

    procedure or whether this can be done by refer-

    ring to an ordinance that is quickly adopted by

    the administration alone.

    (3) Obligatory reassessment and resubmission

    cycles ensure that any existing regulation does

    not lead to the stabilization of the respectively

    benefiting technology.

    (4) Participation of larger parts of the society (e.g.

    NGOs, public research institutes) in the search

    for more sustainable solutions will not only

    facilitate the search for knowledge but also

    increase and widen the support for (often more

    radical) solutions.

    (5) Finally, it is important how a country is incor-porated into supranational structures (e.g. EU,

    WTO). While this limits a countrys possibility

    to implement innovations in an idiosyncratic

    manner, it broadens the scope and efficacy of

    many sustainable innovations.

    5.3. Factors of change in the socio-cultural system

    Public attention to a (perceived) problem and

    subsequent worry about its potential consequences

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 15

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    16/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    play a key role in provoking political reactions direc-

    ted to solving the problem or, at least, alleviating its

    consequences. This is all the more true in the context

    of environmental protection since due to their long-term relevance and public-good nature, environmental

    problems and their solutions are rarely issues that

    allow a politician to derive major benefits for himself.

    While awareness and concern by a considerable part

    of the population is neither sufficient nor necessary

    for political action to be initiated, their lack will

    usually lead to a failure or, at least, major delay in

    acting accordingly.

    Mass media play an important role not only as

    transmitters for the corresponding information but

    also for the assignment of meaning and valuationto the underlying problem. The relation between the

    media and their readers, listeners, or watchers is

    characterized by mutual interaction giving rise to

    positive and negative reinforcement The scientific

    verification of an environmental problem, which

    often stays at the beginning of such an dissue atten-

    tion cycleT (Downs, 1972), is identified through

    scanning the scientific literature for relevant key-

    words and trying to identify seminal publications

    through the tracing back of references. On the

    other hand, public concern about these problems

    can be measured to some extent by counting relevant

    articles in newspapers and reports in other mass

    media. Additionally, it may be necessary to account

    for the more qualitative aspects of concern and

    valuation, as the authors of relevant articles often

    differ in their basic attitude towards a given environ-

    mental problem. It is also important to realize that

    the attention of mass media to any given problem

    usually tends to decline more rapidly than the atten-

    tion of the public in general.

    Table 1 summarizes the comprehensive list of

    determinants of periods of instability elaboratedabove including the corresponding indicators and

    their potential operationalization.

    5.4. Windows of opportunity as periods of higher

    second-order sustainability

    In order to identify periods of greater or lesser

    second-order sustainability by means of these indi-

    cators, it needs to be pointed out first that sustain-

    ability correlates strongly with the instability

    (=flexibility) of the established technological regime

    and the political and social conditions supporting it.

    So, second-order sustainability will be strongest

    when the window of opportunity is most widelyopen and it will be weak when the window is closed.

    In order to identify a window of opportunity, an

    aggregation of its determinants is necessary. Since

    the direct comparison of all these indicators on the

    basis of a common denominator (e.g. monetary

    value) is not possible, however, any comparison

    can in the end only be of qualitative nature. There-

    fore, the following scheme of aggregation is used to

    arrive at least at a relative measure of second-order

    sustainability.

    In the techno-economic sphere, all factors essen-tially work in parallel. High sunk costs add to the

    stability of the incumbent technology as well as does

    extended learning. Niche markets for the new tech-

    nology on the other hand destabilize the incumbent

    technology. None of these factors relies on another

    one to become effective. So, even if one effect became

    zero, the other factors would remain unaffected. Their

    mode of aggregation is additive.

    By contrast, in the socio-cultural system, (scienti-

    fic) verification of an environmental problem is a

    necessary (but not sufficient) prerequisite for the for-

    mation of public concern. Conversely, public concern

    alone sometimes is little effective until the exact

    causes for an environmental problem are scientifically

    verified and unless an acceptable solution exists. So,

    all factors work in sequence with the combined effect

    yielded by multiplying the constituents.

    In the political system, both effects are found.

    While structural and procedural factors in general

    appear to complement each other in a multiplicative

    way, the specific structural (or procedural) factors tend

    to work in parallel.

    With regard to the relationship between the entiresystems, the political system not surprisingly is of

    central importance because in the end, it brings

    about the regulation necessary to achieve greater sus-

    tainability. However, the political system hardly

    works on its own; it needs impulses from the other

    systems: destabilizing impulses (for the existing

    regime) come from the society disapproving the lack

    of sustainability and from the new, more sustainable

    technological or institutional alternatives; opposite

    stabilizing impulses come from the incumbent indus-

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx16

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    17/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    try that caused the environmental problem and the

    loss of sustainability in the first place. Fig. 1

    summarizes how the composite indicator of sustain-

    able technology development is constructed from itsconstituents.

    6. Conclusion

    In particular radical innovations can be important

    means to the achievement of improved sustainability.

    Due to the existence of path dependencies, however,

    the transition from one technological trajectory to

    another, more sustainable one is often impeded by

    significant barriers. Fortunately, these barriers are bytheir nature subject to substantial changes; so, it

    makes sense to carefully distinguish between periods

    of stability (with high barriers) in which the given

    trajectory can hardly be left and periods of instabil-

    ity (characterized by low barriers) where a new

    trajectory can be reached more easily. With respect

    to sustainability, the latter distinction is particularly

    important for two reasons. First, more sustainable

    innovations often rely on governmental regulation.

    In periods of instability, the economic burden arising

    from this regulation will be much lower than in

    periods of stability; so, a given budget will yield a

    much better sustainability effect in the former case

    than in the latter. Second, due to the complexity and

    changes in their respective environments, innova-

    tions are generally associated with fundamental

    uncertainty such that it becomes impossible to pre-dict the degree of sustainability resulting from spe-

    cific innovations in the long run. Under these

    circumstances, it is essential to ensure flexibility

    including the possibility to select between a variety

    of different trajectories in a process of trial and error.

    Sustainability as viewed from this evolutionary

    perspective may therefore better be understood as

    the general capability to readily change between

    different technological trajectories. Since the latter

    kind of sustainability determines the conditions

    under which the former kind can be achieved,we call the two kinds first-order and second-order

    sustainability.

    In order to undergo successful diffusion, most

    sustainable innovations rely on regulatory measures

    especially in the beginning of their (economic) life-

    cycles. When looking for the factors determining

    periods of (in-)stability, the political system enacting

    this regulation therefore is of central interest. How-

    ever, while basically allowing for the convergence

    of both technological progress and sustainability, the

    political system itself can neither give rise to the

    search for sustainability nor bring about the appro-

    priate innovations in the first place. This is where

    the socio-cultural and, of course, the techno-eco-

    nomic sphere itself enter the focus of attention as

    emitters of positive impulses. Additionally, negative

    impulses like those coming from the incumbent

    industry need to be taken into account. After all, a

    series of factors (and corresponding indicators)

    could be identified which, after proper weighting

    and prioritization, allow to make an estimation

    whether, and possibly when, the incumbent industry

    is sufficiently destabilized and the political systemrendered sufficiently favorable to the new, more

    sustainable technology such that a transition to the

    preferred trajectory is possible without the lowest

    effort possible.

    Acknowledgement

    Funding of this research by the German Federal

    Ministry for Education and Research (grant

    Fig. 1. Reconstruction of a measure of second-order sustainability

    from its constituent factors in the techno-economic, political, and

    socio-cultural sphere.

    C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxxxxx 17

  • 8/14/2019 2nd Order of Sustainability

    18/19

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    07RIW5C) is gratefully acknowledged. I thank Guido

    Bunstorf, Jan Nill, Stefan Zundel and an anonymous

    referee for valuable comments on earlier versions of

    this paper.

    References

    Arthur, W.B., 1988. Self-reinforcing mechanisms in economics. In:

    Anderson, P.W., Arrow, K.J., Pines, D. (Eds.), The Economy as

    an Evolving Complex System. Addison-Wesley, Redwood City,

    pp. 9 31.

    Ashford, N.A., 2002. Government and environmental innovation in

    Europe and North America. American Behavioral Scientist 45

    (9), 1417 1434.

    Berg, C., 1995. Technologischer Fortschritt und okonomische Reg-

    ulierung. Lang Publ., Frankfurt/Main.Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J., 1985. Culture and the Evolutionary

    Process. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

    Cavalli-Sforza, L.L., Feldman, M.W., 1981. Cultural Transmission

    and Evolution: a Quantitative Approach. Princeton University

    Press, Princeton, NJ.

    Coase, R.H., 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and

    Economics 3, 1 44.

    David, P.A., 1985. Clio and the economics of QWERTY.

    American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 75 (2),

    332337.

    Dosi, G., 1982. Technological paradigms and technological trajec-

    tories. Research Policy 11, 147162.

    Dosi, G., 1988. Sources, procedures and microeconomic effects

    of innovation. Journal of Economic Literature 26 (Sept.),11201171.

    Downs, A., 1972. Up and down with ecology. The issue-attention

    cycle. The Public Interest 28, 3850 (Summer).

    Ehrlich, P., Raven, P., 1964. Butterflies and plants: a study in

    coevolution. Evolution 18, 586 608.

    Erdmann, G., 2000. Innovation, time, and sustainability. Paper

    Presente