41
David Marsh and Chris Lewis Chapter 15: Evaluating Policy Success In this Chapter we examine the ‘success’ of the Gillard Government, relying mainly on the expositions of various policy issues in this section of the book. To evaluate policy success or failure, we rely primarily on Marsh and McConnell’s heuristic (Marsh and McConnell, 2010; McConnell, 2010), which is one of the first attempts systematically to analyse policy success/failure. This heuristic is useful because it looks beyond most analyses of policy success which focus exclusively on the programmatic dimension of success, recognising two other dimensions of success; process success and political success. Here, we begin by outlining the heuristic and developments of it, before considering the Gillard Government’s performance in a broad range of economic and social policy. In addition, and in contrast to the Marsh and McConnell heuristic, we also examine policy areas in which there was little or no change, even where there were significant demands for such change. The Conceptual Frame: Assessing Success i) The Marsh and McConnell Heuristic The question of policy success has received limited academic attention. In fact, more attention has been paid to the question of policy failure (Adonis, Butler and Travers, 1994; Bovens and t’Hart, 1996; Boin, McConnell and t’Hart, 2008), or related concepts such as scandals (Tiffen, 1999; Garrard and

  · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

  • Upload
    lecong

  • View
    215

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

David Marsh and Chris Lewis

Chapter 15: Evaluating Policy Success

In this Chapter we examine the ‘success’ of the Gillard Government, relying mainly on the

expositions of various policy issues in this section of the book. To evaluate policy success or

failure, we rely primarily on Marsh and McConnell’s heuristic (Marsh and McConnell, 2010;

McConnell, 2010), which is one of the first attempts systematically to analyse policy

success/failure. This heuristic is useful because it looks beyond most analyses of policy

success which focus exclusively on the programmatic dimension of success, recognising two

other dimensions of success; process success and political success. Here, we begin by

outlining the heuristic and developments of it, before considering the Gillard Government’s

performance in a broad range of economic and social policy. In addition, and in contrast to

the Marsh and McConnell heuristic, we also examine policy areas in which there was little or

no change, even where there were significant demands for such change.

The Conceptual Frame: Assessing Success

i) The Marsh and McConnell Heuristic

The question of policy success has received limited academic attention. In fact, more

attention has been paid to the question of policy failure (Adonis, Butler and Travers, 1994;

Bovens and t’Hart, 1996; Boin, McConnell and t’Hart, 2008), or related concepts such as

scandals (Tiffen, 1999; Garrard and Newell, 2006), crises (Boin et al., 2008) and disasters

(Handmer and Dovers, 2007). Obviously, focusing on failure is important, given that, if we

understand why a policy has failed, we may be able to learn from the mistake and improve

policy making in that field, and others, in the future. However, such a focus may neglect the

fact that some, at least, policies are a success.

In our view, we need to focus on both policy success and policy failure, in effect to see the

two as at different ends of a continuum; an issue we return to below. In addition, we would

emphasise two other, related, points. First, policies are rarely either a total success or a total

failure; many, if not most, exist in what McConnell (201o) terms the ‘gray area in-between’.

In particular, using the framework we adopt below, a policy may be a success on one

dimension, process, programmatic or political, and less successful, or unsuccessful on

Page 2:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

another dimension. Second, and relatedly, even on a single dimension, a policy may be

successful in some ways, but not in other.

When research has turned its attention to assessing the success of policies, the focus has been

narrow, with the concentration almost exclusively upon the extent to which the

aims/objectives of the policy have been met; what here we term, following earlier literature,

the programmatic dimension of success. Much of this work has been done by economists

and, perhaps consequently, it ignores the fact that policies are incontrovertibly ‘political’. In

our view, shared by the emerging literature on success, we need to go beyond a focus on the

programmatic dimension, to acknowledge the importance of other dimensions when we are

trying to assess success.

To date, the key work on ‘policy success’ is that by Bovens, t’Hart and their various

collaborators (Bovens, t’Hart and Peters, 2001), Marsh and McConnell (2010) and

McConnell (2010) and Rutter, Marshall and Sims (2012). We have reviewed this literature

elsewhere (Marsh and Lewis, 2014). Here, we focus on the Marsh and McConnell heuristic,

while acknowledging that it builds on a critical appreciation of the work of Bovens, t’Hart

and Peters (2001).

a) The Dimensions of Policy Success

Marsh and McConnell add a process dimension to the programmatic and political dimensions

identified by Bovens, t’Hart and Peters (see Table 1). In addition, they discuss a series of

complexity factors, which are important to acknowledge in undertaking any assessment of

policy success/failure, here we consider two: the fact that one person/group’s success may

another person/group’s failure; and the temporal dimension, whereby politicians operate with

a limited timescale for assessing success (see Marsh and Lewis, 2014).

The process dimension of policy formation is important, but rarely considered in any

assessment of policy success. By ‘process’ we are referring to the initial stages of

policymaking, where issues and options are framed, options considered, interests consulted

and decisions made. Often policymaking is more rushed and less considered, but,

Page 3:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

nevertheless, processes are important, in both practical and symbolic terms. In particular, a

policy process which is thorough and ‘constitutional’ confers greater legitimacy on policy

outcomes, even if/when those outcomes are contested. So, establishing or conferring

legitimacy is an important indicator of process success.

Table 1: Three Dimensions of Policy Success: The Marsh and McConnell Framework

PROCESS DIMENSION PROGRAMME

DIMENSION

POLITICAL DIMENSION

Preserving Policy Goals

and Instruments

Conferring Legitimacy

Building a Sustainable

Coalition

Meeting Objectives

Effective

Implementation

Efficient Use of

Resources

Enhancing Electoral

Prospects/Reputation of

Government and

Leaders

Controlling the Policy

Agenda and Easing the

Business of Governing

Sustaining the Broad

Values and Direction of

Government

Source: Adapted from McConnell (2010), Table 2.2, p. 46.

It is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process

involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition of interests. The key

point her is that, for the policymakers, putting together a strong alliance to support a

particular policy is a putative measure of process success. Of course, a process success is

likely also to be measured in terms of the Government’s capacity to get a Bill through the

legislative process without alterations to its key objectives or detailed policy instruments.

As we emphasised, Programmatic success is often seen as synonymous with policy success

and the contemporary focus among most Western democracies on evidence-based policy

making, or, as Tony Blair’s put it, ‘what matters is what works’, is further confirmation that

the assessment of success is outcomes-based and judged by ‘the evidence’ (Parsons, 2002;

Sanderson, 2002). Here, a policy is successful to the extent that it achieves its objectives.

Page 4:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

Hence, there is a significant focus on effective policy implementation, together with a

recognition that this is a more complex problem, given the growth of multi-level governance

and public sector fragmentation (Exworthy and Powell, 2004).

Another aspect of programmatic success focuses more directly on the operation of policy,

whether the policy instruments are appropriate, the skills of those delivering the policy

adequate and the resources available sufficient to ensure that the policy is implemented as

intended. This focus on the effective use of resources has been reflected in the growth of

public audit bodies, value for money studies, national competition councils and productivity

commissions. In this context, policy success is often claimed on the grounds that the policy

led to ‘waste’ reduction, cost cutting or more efficient use of available resources.

Political success is crucial from the perspective of the government and the governing party.

Crucially here, a policy is seen as successful if it assists the government’s reputation and

electoral prospects, evidenced perhaps in public opinion polls. Of course, a policy can also

help the government retain control of the political agenda or help it retain its image of

governing competence and the idea that it is ‘on track’, while, in contrast, a policy disaster

may undermine that image and presage electoral defeat.

When considering these different dimensions of policy success, it is important to recognise,

as Bovens, t’Hart and Peters (2001) acknowledge, that a policy may be a success on one

dimension, but not on another. For example, the Home Insulation Programme (HIP),

introduced by the Rudd Government, was, in many senses at least, a process success, but, in

most senses, a programmatic disaster (REFS). In addition, a policy may be successful along

one dimension at one time, but this may change over time. Again, the HIP provides an

example here, as it was initially a political success, but subsequently a political disaster.

b) Complexity Problems

Even if we recognise the various dimensions of policy success, the issues/problems involved

with assessing/measuring success don’t end there. So, Marsh and McConnell (2010) identify

a number of what they term complexity factors, particularly: the importance of ontological

and epistemological issues; the question of success for whom; and the fact that success varies

across time, space and cultures. Here, we consider only two of these issues: the question of

success for whom; and the temporal dimension involved in accessing success (for a

Page 5:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

discussion of the other factors in relation to the ‘success’ of recent Australian policy making

see Marsh and Lewis, 2014).

Marsh and McConnell emphasise that any policy is unlikely to affect all citizens equally.

Indeed, the nature of politics means that outcomes will always be, to some extent, contested.

So, we should not expect government, politicians, civil servants, interest groups, citizens and

others to all agree on whether, or not, any aspect of a particular policy is successful. At the

same time, some policies may benefit some interests/sections of society, while

disadvantaging others, given that politics and policy is sometimes, perhaps often, a zero-sum

game. Inevitably, this raises crucial issues about power relations and a key question becomes

the extent to which one interest or set of interests is consistently benefited (Marsh and

McConnell, 2010, 575).

The temporal dimension of policy making is particular important, given that the timeframes

with which politicians operate, clearly related to electoral cycles, are much shorter than those

necessary to assess whether a policy has been successful (see Marsh and McConnell, 2010,

577). Sometimes, this difficulty can be exacerbated by political factors, so a government can

introduce a policy which is then repealed by a succeeding government, before there has been

a chance to assess whether it has been successful in programmatic terms. Here, the key issue

is that the time-scale of the Gillard Government is insufficient to definitively, perhaps even

adequately, judge whether a policy was a programmatic success. At best, we can suggest that

it appears likely a particular policy will be a programmatic success/failure. All this means

that the process and political dimensions feature more strongly in situations, such as this,

where an assessment of policy success is being conducted with a short time-frame.

ii) Beyond Marsh and McConnell

McConnell (2010a) deepens and broadens the discussion by emphasising that the distinction

between policy success and policy failure is not an absolute one. He identifies (McConnell,

2010b) five points on a ‘spectrum of success’: process success; resilient success; conflicted

success; precarious success; and process failure.

Table 2: Policy as Program: The Spectrum from Success to Failure

Page 6:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

Program Success Resilient Success Conflicted Success Precarious Success Program Failure

Implementation in

line with

objectives.

Implementation

objectives broadly

achieved, with

minor changes.

Mixed results, some

successes, but also

unexpected problems.

Minor progress

towards

implementation as

intended, but beset

by chronic failures

Implementation

fails to be executed

in line with

objectives.

Achievement of

desired outcomes.

Outcomes broadly

achieved, despite

some shortfalls.

Some successes, but

partial achievement of

outcomes

counterbalanced by

unwanted results.

Limited outcomes

achieved, but

overwhelmed by

controversial, high

profile failures.

Failure to achieve

desired outcomes.

Creating benefit for

a target group.

A few shortfalls,

but intended

target group

broadly benefits.

Partial benefits, but

not as widespread or

deep as intended.

Small benefits,

accompanied and

overshadowed by

damage to

beneficiary group.

Damaging a

particular target

group.

Meets policy

domain criteria.

Some minor

shortfalls in

relation to desired

outcome.

Partial achievement of

goals, accompanied

by some failures.

A few minor

successes, but

plagued by

unwanted media

attention.

Clear inability to

meet the criteria.

Opposition to

program

aims/values/

implementation

virtually non-

existent

Some opposition

to program

aims/values/

implementation,

but outweighed

by support.

Opposition and

support for program

aims/values/

implementation

equally balanced.

Opposition to

program

aims/values/

implementation

outweighs support.

Opposition to

program

aims/values/

implementation

virtually non-

existent.

McConnell’s continuum is laid out in Table 2. He examines the continuum in relation to each

of the three dimensions of policy success; process, programmatic and political success. The

Figure largely speaks for itself, but the key point is, again, that we need to be much more

sophisticated about how we conceptualise, and therefore assess, success than is the case in the

Page 7:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

mainstream, rationalist, literature, which treats the measurement of success as a

straightforward, largely technical, exercise.

The Gillard Government’s Record

Here, we could have looked at individual policies, or policy fields, and assess, for either or

each, whether it was a process, programmatic or political success. However, instead, we

organise our treatment in terms of the Marsh and McConnell frame, assessing the policy

output of the Gillard Government in relation to each dimension of success. Subsequently, we

will examine a number of areas in which there were no policy innovations, on the grounds

that this also tells us something about the policy ‘success’, or otherwise, of the Gillard

Government.

i) Process Success

In broad terms, as Chapter Three, the Gillard Government was successful in getting policy

through, even in the context of minority government. So, as Singleton (Chapter 3)

emphasises, 561 pieces of legislation received Royal Assent, compared to 549 during the last

term of the Howard government and 409 for the Rudd Government. Notably, no government

bills were defeated on the floor of the House of Representatives although five were

withdrawn by the government through lack of sufficient support. This success was achieved

despite 50 per cent of the bills introduced into the House of Representatives being contested

by the Opposition (Singleton, 2013).

The best examples of process success were in the social welfare, health and education fields;

areas of Labor’s historical policy strengths. Here, we would point to four substantial policy

initiatives which were achieved, although often through compromise, and rarely with total

community and political support.

The National Disability Insurance Scheme (beginning July 2013) which had

bipartisan political support.

A new hospital funding scheme concluded with all State Premiers and Territory Chief

Ministers to provide the States with $16.4 billion from July 2014 to 2020, including

strict national standards, such as a four-hour emergency treatment “target” and the

Page 8:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

delivery of 95% of elective surgery procedures within a recommended time (Packham

and Kelly, 2011).

A National Education Reform Agreement which offered $14.5 billion extra to primary

and high school education over six years; although only NSW, South Australia and

the ACT signed up by the end of the Gillard Government. For the first time, there was

a funding entitlement and formula for all students, regardless of whether they attend

government or non-government schools (Ferrari, 2013). With a base level of funding

for each student starting in 2014 at $9,271 for a primary student and $12,193 for a

secondary student, amounts would be topped up by “loadings” targeting categories of

disadvantage, based on disability and low socio-economic status (Hurst, 2013).

A $4.1 billion dental package, supported by the Australian Dental Association, the

Australian Medical Association, the Public Health Association of Australia and the

Australian Healthcare and Hospitals Association; although most of the money would

not be available until 2014. This included $2.7 billion over six years to give free or

subsidised dental care to 3.4 million children (aged 2 to 17) for families that qualify

under Family Tax Benefit A, up to $1,000 over two years. Another $1.3 billion would

go to State-run public dental clinics to fund 1.4 million dental services for low-income

adults, while $225 million will be spent on improving facilities and boosting the

dental workforce. These programs allow the closure of the Howard-era Chronic

Disease Dental Scheme, which cost taxpayers nearly $1 billion annually, and Labor's

own Teen Dental scheme, which cost $65 million in 2011-12, but had consistently

failed to hit its targets, because it funds only check-ups and not the treatments found

to be needed cleaning and fillings (Cresswell, 2012). This was despite the Chairman

of the Association for the Promotion of Oral Health (Professor Hans Zoellner) arguing

that few children needed enough dental treatment to get near the $500-a-year cap,

whereas the few children with more serious problems would be disadvantaged by the

new cap and were previously covered by the much higher $4250 limit available

through the CDDS (Cresswell, 2012).

However, elsewhere, the pattern is more mixed. So, the controversial carbon tax, which, as

we shall see later, was a major ‘programmatic’ and ‘political’ failure, could be seen as a

conflicted process success, because, while the policy was introduced without major

amendment, and accompanied by a taxation reform that increased the tax free threshold to

Page 9:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

$18,200, its implementation was strongly contested and this clearly affected its chances of

programmatic success (Check carbon tax chapter).

In the same vein, while the Murray Darling Basin Plan (MDBP) could be viewed as a

sensible attempt to balance economic and environmental sustainability, the supposed

consultation process which underpinned its development was deeply flawed. As Linnegar

(2012) argues: ‘the (Murray Darling Basin) Authority (MDBA) simply turned up in rural

towns, told the local residents, business people and farmers that somewhere between 30-40

per cent of the water sustaining the town (some 3,000-4,000 gigalitres) would be removed

and then left’. As such, the MDBP was generally perceived by affected rural and regional

communities to have failed to respond to their interests and as a cave-in to urban city voters.

While later concessions were made to rural/farming interests and the MDBA has significantly

changed its approach, this is still, at best, a conflicted process success (Evans Ref).

While the Rudd Government’s flawed handling of the Resource Super Profits Tax was one of

the main reasons for the replacement of Rudd by Gillard as Prime Minister, the compromise

Gillard subsequently agreed with the mining sector was a major process, and indeed

programmatic and political, failure, given Labor’s initial aims (see Bell and Hindmoor, 2013;

Lewis, Marsh and Chesters, 2013). The 2012-13 Budget set aside the putative proceeds of the

new tax to fund: family payments; a bonus for school-aged children; small business tax

breaks; and a compulsory superannuation increase. However, the scale of the tax was heavily

curtailed, as a result of concessions to the big miners. So, the Minerals Resource Rent Tax

(MRRT) established a 30% tax on just a few minerals (iron ore and coal), whereas the

initially proposed Resource Super Profit Tax had proposed a 40% levy on all extractive

industry. Consequently, the tax yield was derisory. It is difficult to see this as other than a

process failure, as the Government failed to argue its case strongly enough to the public in the

face of pressure from the miners (see Lewis, Marsh and Chesters, 2013).

iii) Programmatic Success

As we argued, it is still too early to judge the programmatic success of most of the Gillard

Government’s policies given the short-time frame. This is particularly true in the case of the

Government’s four main process successes: the National Disability Insurance Scheme; the

Page 10:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

latest hospital funding scheme to operate from July 2014 to 2020; the dental reforms; and the

National Education Reform Agreement.

However, the Gillard Government had a number of major programmatic failures. Here, we

highlight three examples: the budget surplus and related economic policy; the carbon tax;

and the mining tax. At the same time, it important to emphasise that judging a policy a

programmatic success, almost by definition, involves a longer time frame than judging a

policy a failure.

Gillard committed to delivering a budget surplus by 2013-14 in her first press conference as

Prime Minister on 23 June 2010. This commitment is dealt with at more length by Garnett

and Lewis, who argue that it was a policy largely driven by the Opposition. However, as

Garnett and Lewis emphasise, in the Gillard years, average Government spending, as a

proportion of GDP, was 24.6%, while average Government receipts were 23.5% of GDP.

Garnett and Lewis argue that this deficit resulted from a combination of a failure to rein in

public expenditure and seriously over-optimistic estimates of receipts from the carbon and

mining taxes. In addition, they point out that Australia had its highest-ever debt levels and

this was recalculated by Rudd’s new Treasurer, Chris Bowen, as standing at $30billion, up

from $18b three months earlier. In this context, the Government withdrew its commitment to

balance the budget at the end of 2012; which reflected a political, as well as a programmatic,

failure.

At the same time, the Australian Bureau of Statistics indicated that Australia’s employment

rate was 13.1%, if one included: those who worked just one hour a week; discouraged

jobseekers; the underemployed; and those who wanted to start work within a month, but

couldn’t begin immediately (ABS, 2013). In addition, the average hours worked per

Australian worker declined from 35 in the 1980s, to 34 in the 1900s, 33 since 2000; reaching

32.9 in 2011 (ABS, 2012). Total manufacturing employment fell to 938,300 in the March

2013 Quarter, thus meaning that manufacturing job losses under Rudd-Gillard were 143,300

(Mirabella, 2013). Manufacturing’s share of Australia GDP also declined further, to 7.1% in

2011-12, after being 11.2% in 2003-04 (Colebatch, 2013). In addition, despite a low

Consumer Price Index being aided by periods of low food prices, there was double-digit

growth in electricity prices after 2007, including 14% in 2012-13 (Wood, 2013). Overall, this

is hardly a picture of success in terms of economic policy.

Page 11:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

The carbon tax, legislated as part of the Clean Energy Bill 2011 and intended to last for three

to five years before a full emissions trading scheme (ETS) was implemented (Packham and

Massola, 2012), can also be seen as a major programmatic failure. It is true that the Climate

Commission revealed that Australia’s emissions from electricity generation dropped by 4.7%

between 2010 and 2011. However, this was because of the greater use of renewable energy

and a decline in Australia’s manufacturing sector (Marszalek, 2013), rather than the carbon

tax (Dennis and McIntosh’s chapter). More broadly, global CO2 emissions reached a record

31.6 gigatonnes in 2012 (Zhu, 2013), while the average concentration of atmospheric carbon

dioxide reached 400 parts per million in some monitoring stations (Artic and Hawaii), with a

recent prediction that the level would rise to 450ppm would be faster than previous rates of

increase (Landau, 2013). Of course, supporters of the carbon tax may argue that it is better

than doing nothing, but it is hard to argue that it has delivered in either economic or

environmental terms. In addition, the Government failed effectively to counter the Opposition

argument that it would lead to higher electricity prices and a loss of Australian jobs offshore;

a political failure.

As Garnett and Lewis stress, the carbon tax was designed to be budget-neutral, raising $4

billion in the first year, which would pay for compensation, tax cuts and clean energy

programs. However, the Treasury’s forward estimates for the period when Australia moved to

an ETS were based on an assumption that the carbon price would rise to $38/tonne by 2019.

In early 2013, the European Union’s carbon price, to which the Australian one will be fixed,

was $6/tonne. The problem is, of course, that the Gillard Government’s policies which will

require heavy expenditure, like the Gonski reforms or the National Disability Scheme, are

dependent, in large part, on a high carbon price generating significant income.

The mining tax is also widely viewed as a programmatic failure. As Garnett and Lewis

emphasise, the Gillard Government had originally budgeted for the tax to raise $3.7 billion on

average during its first three years (2012/3-2015/6), but raised just $126 million during its

first six months. In large part this results from the concessions which the Government made

to the large miners during the evolution of the legislation (see Garnett and Lewis, 2013; Bell

and Hindmoor, 2013; and Lewis, Marsh and Chesters, 2013). Here, we can see how process

failure linked to programmatic failure.

Page 12:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

iii) Political Success

Political success is not easy and, as the introduction to this volume indicates, there were

several contextual realities that may have hindered the Gillard Government’s prospects of

political success, particularly its minority government status and the tough economic

environment.

However, as we have seen, both process and programmatic terms failures hindered the

Government’s prospects of political success. Here, we are thinking particularly of the

inaccurate budget predictions, along with the mining and carbon taxes. In the case of the

latter, the political reputation of the Gillard Government was also severely damaged from the

start of its term when it reneged on a promise not to introduce a carbon tax, without

community debate, a development which Ireland (2013) argues reinforced a negative public

perception of Gillard that had originated in response to the way in which she overthrew Rudd.

In contrast, Johnson (2011a and b) argues that Gillard had the chance to utilise the past Labor

tradition of enhancing educational opportunity and to build upon Rudd’s initial promotion of

the National Broadband Network and the National Disability Insurance Scheme, not to

mention the Rudd Governments’ efforts to avoid economic recession. In that context, he

suggests, the Gillard Government’s many policy failures entrenched an unfavourable view of

its economic competence. So, early in Gillard’s term, Labor only trailed the Coalition slightly

(43% to 40%; Newspoll, 13-15 August, 2010) in terms of economic governing competence,

by early 2013 it tariled 28% to 50% (Newspoll, 23-26 February, 2013), at a time when

Australia had one of the lowest OECD unemployment rates at around 5% (OECDa).

The Government’s political standing was also weakened by its decision to appoint the former

Liberal MP Peter Slipper as Speaker of the House, given he later resigned for inappropriate

conduct (Ireland and Wright 2012), and its support from the disgraced former Federal Labor

MP Craig Thomson, who was arrested on 1 February 2013 and charged with 150 counts of

fraud, because of his previous conduct as head of the Health Services Union, which had

already led to civil action against him.

Towards the end of its term, this lack of political success led the Gillard Government to

modify its policy stance, often seeming desperate to court popularity. One of its biggest

s428864, 23/08/13,
Check figure)
s428864, 23/08/13,
date
Page 13:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

policy reversals occurred in regard to asylum seekers (see Walsh). Initially, the Government,

like the previous Rudd Government, opposed the Howard Government’s offshore processing

approach, using the Nauru option, on the grounds that it was not a signatory to the UN

Refugee Convention. As such, they preferred East Timor as a location for new detention and

processing facilities, although this proposal was rejected by the East Timorese (Kelly, 2010).

Subsequently, on 31 August 2011 the High Court rejected an alternative plan to exchange

800 asylum seekers for 4,000 processed refugees from Malaysia (Gordon, 2011), given it was

also not a signatory to the UN Refugee Convention, which by that time Nauru had signed.

The Government then, after convening and accepting the recommendations of the Expert

Panel on Asylum Seekers panel chaired by Angus Houston, moved towards the resumption of

processing at Nauru and Manus Island, endorsing the plan during August 2012. During

October 2012, the Gillard Government confirmed support for offshore processing and

announced the re-opening of sites at Nauru and Manus Island, in response to growing

numbers of boat arrivals, along with reported deaths at sea. In line with the recommendation

of the panel, the Government also increased Australia’s humanitarian program to 20,000

places in 2012-13 from 13,750 for 2011-12 (Gillard and Bowen, 2012).

During June 2013, the Government even introduced tougher legislation to require subclass

457 visa sponsors to demonstrate that there are no qualified and experienced Australian

workers readily available to fill a position to be taken by a proposed 457 visa holder, unless

an exemption applies. They did so, despite previously ignoring criticism from trade unionists

and Labor MPs during May 2012, when re-stating approval for mining magnate Gina

Rinehart to bring in 1700 skilled foreign workers to get her $9.5 billion Roy Hill iron ore

mine underway in the Pilbara (Farr, 2012).

The Gillard Government’s lack of political success also led it to look for political scapegoats.

Notably, during 2012, Swan accused mining magnates Clive Palmer, Andrew Forrest and

Gina Rinehart of trying to assert too much influence over Australian politics, given their

strident opposition to the carbon tax and the mining tax (Swan, 2012). Similarly, Gillard,

responding to another debate over the economics of education, suggesting that people who

lived on Sydney's North Shore were not ‘real people’ (Nadin and Salusinszky, 2012). The

Government also sought to counter perceived media bias, although it failed to win

parliamentary support for its media law reform bill. Similarly, Gillard’s description of Abbott

Page 14:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

as ‘sexist and misogynist’ gave, at best, a temporary boost to Gillard’s approval ratings

(Essential Report, Essential Research 15 October 2012).

The Absence of Policy

Marsh and McConnell’s framework focuses on policies which have been introduced to

examine whether they have been successful. However, another issue is clearly important:

what issues did the Gillard Government avoid, even where there appeared to be a need for

policy changes?

In a sense, the most important are here again is economic policy. The Gillard Government

gave little attention to how best to generate wealth or, even, as we saw earlier, to achieving a

balanced budget. In this context, Johnson (2011a) claims that the Gillard Government was

closer to the economic rationalism of Hawke and Keating, than to Rudd, given the latter had

provided a critique of neo-liberalism. Certainly, the Gillard Government appeared happy to

accept a growing reliance upon mining and services, while Australia’s manufacturing and

agricultural sectors faced further relative decline, as export-exposed industries experienced

much greater competition, given the rise in the Australian dollar.

Australia continued to benefit from mining and fuels (including coal), after the global export

value of those sectors increased by 16% between 2000 and 2005 and 14% between 2005 and

2011, the latter occurring despite a decline of 39% in 2009 (WTO, 2012). However, with

global manufacturing exports (non-food products) worth around 65% of total global

merchandise exports, and still dwarfing global commercial service exports by a ratio of

nearly 4.5 to 1, Australia was being asked to compete with the world’s developed nations for

global trade exports. At the same time, the value of Australia’s food product imports

increased by 371% between 2000 and 2011, while exports went up just 204% (WTO, 2012).

Of course, these growing economic problems, which, as Garnett and Lewis emphasise,

resulted at least in part from Gillard Government policies, impacted on Gillard Government’s

social policies, given the need to pay for them.

However, the Gillard Government failed to acknowledge, or even discuss, possible fiscal

limitations in the future. All this meant that, while Labor was committed to maintaining the

Coalition’s level of government expenditure as a percentage of GDP, the total level of social

Page 15:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

welfare expenditure reached a near record level of 18% of GDP in 2012 (OECDb). This was

funded by deficit spending, at a time when, as we saw, budgetary forecasts proved wrong

time and time again.

Of course, there was some attempt to balance the ledger. In this context, the Government’s

social policy innovation (discussed by Singleton in Chapter Three) was often only enabled by

controversial cuts and reforms in other policy areas. So, Labor increased means-testing of the

private health insurance rebate after July 2012 (Deloitte 2011; ANOP 2011) and increase the

Medicare levy to partially fund the National Disability Insurance Scheme. It also adopted a

temporary flood levy to raise $1.8 billion from July 2011 after the devastating flood caused

widespread damage to Queensland. However, at the same time, $2.5 billion was to be cut out

of the university sector in the four years from 2013, while $520 million was raised by

capping tax deductions for self-education expenses.

Some cuts particularly effected the more disadvantaged. So, around 84,000 sole parents were

moved off parenting payments, when their youngest child turns eight, which meant 60,000

single parents moved on to Newstart from January 2013, with estimates that many would lose

$60-100 a week - this policy even led to a damning letter from the UN (AAP 2013). In

addition, the Newstart allowance (unemployment benefit) was frozen, meaning that the base

rate had not increased in real terms since 1994, with even the Business Council of Australia

President Tony Shepherd calling for an increase at a National Press Club address (Crook,

2013). However, the Gillard Government’s 2013 budget did allow welfare recipients to keep

an extra $19 a week from part-time work before payments are affected.

Such policies hardly helped the 13% of Australians living below the poverty line, deemed by

ACOSS to now be $358 per week for a single person and $573 per single parent, given

Newstart weekly rates were $256.30 for a single person and $266.50 for a single parent, far

less than the disability pension of $375 a week and the minimum wage of $590 (Crook,

2013).

.

The Gillard Government’s almost hopeful attitude to economic and social matters was

critiqued by experts concerned about how future social welfare policies would be funded. In

relation to health, a Grattan Institute report (April, 2013) predicted that health expenditure

s428864, 29/08/13,
how do these paras link – the cuts may be regressive, but they were cuts?
Page 16:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

would be the biggest contributor to a blowout in State and Federal budget deficits by 2023,

due primarily to an ageing population (Daley, 2013). Similarly, John Deeble, the health

economist who advised both the Whitlam and Hawke Governments on universal healthcare

(Medibank and Medicare), argued that the States were shouldering too much of the burden of

health funding and that subsidising private health insurance could help to solve the problem, ,

as long as it became more ‘comprehensive and stayed comprehensive’. Deeble declared: ‘I

don’t see how you are going to solve the problem in an equitable way unless you make some

very nasty decisions” (Heath, 2013).

At the same time, the Chief Executive of one of Australia’s largest private health insurers

(NIB), Mark Fitzgibbon, also argued that the level of public health expenditure was

‘impossible’ and that the private health system would have to be expanded to include GP

visits, while supporting the introduction of means-testing, given the rollback of government

support for private health was inevitable (Heath, 2013). Similarly, during May 2013, the

AMA noted that financial pressures (wages and costs) on medical practices meant that the

bulk billing rate for GP services was likely to fall after the Gillard Government’s decision to

delay the indexation of the GP Medicare rebate (currently $36.30) by eight months, from

November 2013 to July 2014 (AMA 2013).

In contrast to Australia, Canada, which is also faced with an ageing population, and where the

bulk of healthcare spending is by Provincial Governments, slashed healthcare spending

during the 1990s, in face of a public debt crisis. The argument here was that increased

spending was a choice for governments, until they had no choice but to cut public spending

(Keane, 2013). The point here is that the need to balance wealth creation and social welfare

policies appeared largely lost on the Gillard Government, given its almost cavalier approach

to economic matters.

Perhaps this is why new policies are emerging, albeit begun much earlier than the Gillard

Government, which mask the real solutions through rhetorical aims based more on wishful

thinking. For example, while the Government built upon the National Assessment Program –

Literacy and Numeracy (NAPLAN), which, since 2008, has annually assessed students in

Years 3, 5, 7 and 9, by launching a revamped My School website during March 2011, another

report by the Grattan Institute stated that “neither creating more competition among schools

nor giving them more autonomy without support to improve learning are the vital solutions”

s428864, 29/08/13,
Don’t see the link between these two paras
Page 17:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

would “lift the performance of Australian students”. The Myth of Markets in School

Education report noted a number of reasons: at least 40-60% of schools ‘face no or very

limited competition’; ‘providing more information about schools, cutting private school fees

or increasing the capacity of high-performing government schools will do little to increase

school competition and lift student performance’; and giving school leaders autonomy to run

their schools ‘has little impact on performance when governments do not implement it as part

of a larger plan to improve teaching and learning’, a point strengthened by the fact that

greater school autonomy in Victoria did not lead to greater performance than in NSW, which

remained centralised until recently. As summarised by Jensen in a summary of his Grattan

Institute Report The myth of markets in school education, the world’s best systems: ‘have

varying levels of autonomy but they all articulate the best way to teach and learn, then make

sure they have the best teachers to carry it out’ (Jensen, 2013).

The failure to even consider, let alone face up to, difficult issues is clear in the debates about

climate change and population growth. As we saw, the Gillard Government answer to

generating wealth in these difficult times, focused on more of the same, So, Australia exports

pollution at the same time as cutting, admittedly in a limited way, its own greenhouse gas

emissions, with no consideration of this apparent contradiction. Such contradictions are

similarly present if we consider the population debate. While Gillard, rhetorically, re-

positioned Labor away from Rudd’s original “Big Australia” population goal (Leslie, 2010),

the Government maintained Australia's long-term support bi-partisan support for a large,

multi-ethnic, annual immigration program. So, during the 2011-12 year, there were 184,998

legal migrants, including 125,755 for the skill stream and 58,604 for the family stream (Dept.

of Immigration and Citizenship, 2012).

Conclusion

As earlier chapters also demonstrate, the Government’s economic and social policy record

was mixed at best, even allowing for a tough international economic environment, with

Australia continuing to embrace freer trade, the instability caused by a former leader (Rudd),

determined to regain the prime ministership, and the reality of a minority government, which

demanded a careful monitoring of numbers and support from controversial MPs. The

Government’s inability to win over public opinion even led to the return of Rudd as Prime

Minister, as caucus members feared a loss of their seats.

s428864, 29/08/13,
Don’t understand this para either
Page 18:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

The Government was successful in achieving a legislative process success, with the support

of the Greens and key independents. In particular, it achieved some significant changes in

health and education (notably the NDIS), although this was at the cost of tougher conditions

for a substantial minority of welfare recipients. Unfortunately, the policy areas in which it

achieved process success will require time before any assessment can be made of

programmatic success. However, in the areas in which there were significant process

failures, notably in economic policy and on the carbon and mining taxes, programmatic and

political failure quickly followed.

In the end, the Gillard Government did not do enough to convince a sufficient number of

Australians of their policy success, despite Australia’s strong economic performance, when

compared to other developed nations. Even allowing for the particularly difficult context in

which the Government operated, it fail to implement an effective economic policy mix that

could help win public support, at time when a growing minority faced tougher times, due to

employment uncertainty, higher housing prices and, even, rapidly increasing utility bills.

Page 19:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

References

AAP. 2013, ‘Gillard snubs UN on single parent welfare’, The Australian, 4 March 2013.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/news/breaking-news/govt-silent-on-poverty-report-acoss/

story-fn3dxiwe-1226589883703

ABS. 2012. 1393.0 - As a Matter of Fact, 2012, 23 May 2012.   

http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/[email protected]/latestmf/1393.0~5

ABS, 2013. 6105.0 - Australian Labour Market Statistics, 10 July 2013.   

http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/[email protected]/Latestproducts/6105.0Feature%20Article1July

%202013?opendocument&tabname=Summary&prodno=6105.0&issue=July

%202013&num=&view=

AMA (Australian Medical Association). 2013. ‘Bulk billing warning as rebates freeze’, 17

May 2013.

https://ama.com.au/ausmed/bulk-billing-warning-rebates-freeze

Anderson, John. 2013. ‘Desperate graziers will meet at a summit as prices push the beef

industry into crisis’, Townsville Bulletin, May 06.

http://www.couriermail.com.au/news/queensland/desperate-graziers-will-meet-at-a-summit-

as-prices-push-the-beef-industry-into-crisis/story-e6freoof-1226635598112

ANOP Research Services, 2011. Means Testing the Private Health Insurance Rebate The

Impact on Private Health Insurance Membership in Australia, Report on the 2011 ANOP

Survey for the AHIA, April 2011.

http://youshouldknow.com.au/wp-content/uploads/ANOP-full-report-for-AHIA2011.pdf

Colebatch, Tim. 2013. How we lost our place in the global car industry, Canberra Times, 28

May 2013.

http://www.canberratimes.com.au/federal-politics/political-opinion/how-we-lost-our-place-

in-the-global-car-industry-20130527-2n7a1.html

Cooper, Hayden. 2013. ‘Workers accuse IT giant of 457 abuse’, Australian Broadcasting

Corporation, 20 June 2013.

Page 20:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

http://www.abc.net.au/7.30/content/2013/s3786315.htm

Coorey, Phillip. 2013. ‘Gillard, Lowy defend multiculturalism’, Sydney Morning Herald

(online), 20 September 2012.

http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/gillard-lowy-defend-multiculturalism-

20120919-2671o.html

Cresswell, Adam. 2012. ‘Truth of federal government's $4bn dental boost like pulling teeth’,

The Australian, 30 August 2012.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/health/truth-of-federal-governments-4bn-

dental-boost-like-pulling-teeth/story-fn59nokw-1226461149159

Crook, Andrew. 2013, ‘PromiseWatch 2013: Newstart Allowance comparison’, Crikey, 2

May 2013.

http://www.crikey.com.au/2013/05/02/promisewatch-2013-newstart-allowance-comparison/

Daley, John. 2013, Budget pressures on Australian governments, Grattan Institute, April

2013.

http://grattan.edu.au/static/files/assets/ff6f7fe2/187_budget_pressures_report.pdf

Deloitte. Australian Health Insurance Association, Economic Impact Assessment of the

Proposed Reforms to Private Health Insurance, Final Report, 28 April 2011.

http://youshouldknow.com.au/wp-content/uploads/Deloitte-Final-Report_28-April-2011.pdf

Dept. of Immigration and Citizenship. 2012. 2011–12 Migration Program Report

Program year to 30 June 2012.

http://www.immi.gov.au/media/statistics/pdf/report-on-migration-program-2011-12.pdf

Durie, John. 2013. ‘Simplot, maker of Chiko rolls, Edgell and Birdseye, may close local

plants’, The Australian, 5 June 2013.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/business/companies/simplot-maker-of-chico-rolls-edgell-

and-birdseye-may-close-local-plants/story-fn91v9q3-1226657841656

Page 21:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

Evershed, Nick, 2013. ‘Was Julia Gillard the most productive prime minister in Australia's

history?’, The Guardian, 28 June 2013.

http://www.guardian.co.uk/news/datablog/2013/jun/28/australia-productive-prime-minister

Farr, M. 2012. "Gillard labels Abbott "Gina Rinehart's butler"". news.com.au. 28 May 2012.

http://www.news.com.au/national-news/gillard-labels-abbott-gina-rineharts-butler/story-

e6frfkvr-1226369949693

Ferrari, Julia with Michael Owen. 2013. ‘Gillard to punish Gonski school funding hold-outs’,

The Australian, 5 June 2013.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/education/gillard-to-punish-gonski-hold-

outs/story-fn59nlz9-1226657377599

Firsova, A; Strezov, V and Taplin, R, 2012, ‘After 20 years of creating Australian climate

policy: was the proposed carbon pollution reduction scheme a change in direction?’,

Australian Journal of Environmental Managment 19(1):21-34.

Gillard, J and Chris Bowen, ‘Refugee Program increased to 20 000 places’, Joint media

release, 23 August 2012.

http://www.minister.immi.gov.au/media/cb/2012/cb189459.htm

Gordon, Michael. 2011. ‘The Malaysia solution is shipwrecked". The Australian, 1 Sept.

2011.

http://www.theage.com.au/national/the-malaysia-solution-is-shipwrecked-20110831-

1jmfm.html

Heath, Joanna. 2013. ‘Medicare architect backs private health’, Australian Financial Review,

23 April 2013.

http://www.afr.com/p/national/

medicare_architect_backs_private_t69vQWT3GamZsOQavCHlYO

Hurst, Daniel. 2013. ‘Gonski school funding reforms now law’, Sydney Morning Herald, 26

June 2013.

Page 22:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/gonski-school-funding-reforms-now-

law-20130626-2own5.html

Ireland, J. 2013, ‘There may be achievements, but voters still aren't getting Labor's message’,

SMH (online), 24 March 2013.

http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/there-may-be-achievements-but-

voters-still-arent-getting-labors-message-20130323-2gmft.html

Ireland, Judith and Jessica Wright. 2012. ‘Coalition fails to oust Slipper’, Sydney Morning

Herald, 9 Oct. 2012.

http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/coalition-fails-to-oust-slipper-

20121009-27a2g.html

Jensen, Ben. 2013. ‘The myth of markets in school education’, Grattan Institute (online), 10

July 2013.

http://grattan.edu.au/publications/reports/post/the-myth-of-markets-in-school-education/

Johnson, Carol. 2011a, ‘Gillard, Rudd and Labor Tradition’, Australian Journal of Politics

and History 57(4):562-579.

Johnson, Carol. 2011b, ‘The Politics of Broadband: Labor and New Information Technology

from Hawke to Gillard’, Australian Journal of Political Science 46(1):3-18.

Karvelas, Patricia, 2012. "Historic Constitution vote over indigenous recognition facing

hurdles". The Australian. 20 Jan. 2012.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/indigenous/historic-constitution-vote-over-

indigenous-recognition-facing-hurdles/story-fn9hm1pm-1226248879375

Keane, Bernard. 2013. ‘The rise and rise of health spending — but don’t blame the old

people’, 23 April 2013.

http://www.businessspectator.com.au/article/2013/4/23/health-and-pharmaceuticals/rise-and-

rise-health-spending

Page 23:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

Kelly, Joe. 2010. ‘East Timor's parliament rejects Gillard plan for regional asylum-seeker

centre’, The Australian (online), 25 July 2011.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/politics/east-timors-parliament-rejects-gillard-plan-for-

regional-asylum-seeker-centre/story-e6frgczf-1225890881986

Kelly, Paul, 2012a, (11 May 2012). "Military spending slumps to 1930s level". The

Australian, 11 May 2012.’

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/opinion/columnists/military-spending-slumps-to-1930s-

level/story-e6frg74x-1226352458112

Kelly, Paul. 2012b. ‘Labor's choice is Rudd or oblivion’, The Australian (online), 25 July

2012.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/opinion/columnists/labors-choice-is-rudd-or-oblivion/story-

e6frg74x-1226434217314

Ker, P. 2013. ‘BHP, Rio pay mining tax; Xstrata doesn't’, Sydney Morning Herald (online),

29 April 2013.

http://www.smh.com.au/business/mining-and-resources/bhp-rio-pay-mining-tax-xstrata-

doesnt-20130429-2io7o.html (accessed 4th July 2013)

Landau, Elizabeth, 2013. ‘CO2 levels hit new peak at key observatory’, CNN (online), May

14, 2013.

http://edition.cnn.com/2013/05/10/us/climate-change

Leslie, Tim. 2010. ‘Claims Gillard opposed paid parental leave’, Australian Broadcasting

Corporation (online), 27 July 2010.

http://www.abc.net.au/news/2010-07-27/claims-gillard-opposed-paid-parental-leave/921538

Linnegar, Matt, 2012. ‘Murray Darling Basin: work together on water’, 9 Jan. 2012.

http://www.abc.net.au/unleashed/3764018.html

Marszalek, Jessica. 2013. ‘Carbon tax and tight consumers help lower emissions, new report

says’, News Limited Network (online), April 29, 2013.

Page 24:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

http://www.news.com.au/national-news/carbon-tax-and-tight-consumers-help-lower-

emissions-new-report-says/story-fncynjr2-1226631177867

McAllister, I. and J. Clark. 2007. Trends in Australian Political Opinion: Results from the

Australian Election Study, 1987–2004. Canberra: Australian Social Science Data Archive.

Mirabella, Sophie. 2013. ‘Manufacturing Jobs Hit Record Low’, 20 June2013.

http://www.liberal.org.au/latest-news/2013/06/20/manufacturing-jobs-hit-record-low

Nadin, Mitchell; Salusinszky, Imre. 2012. "Julia Gillard takes on Tony Abbott in a reality

showdown". The Australian, 10 May.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/julia-gillard-takes-on-tony-abbott-in-a-

reality-showdown/story-fn59niix-1226351462739

OECDa, Economic Outlook Annex Tables

http://www.oecd.org/economy/outlook/economicoutlookannextables.htm

OECDb. Social Expenditure - Aggregated data, OECD StatExtracts.

http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=SOCX_AGG

Packham, Ben. 2012. 'Huge whack' to revenue means budget surplus is now unlikely: Wayne

Swan’, The Australian (online), Dec. 20, 2012.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/revenue-slide-in-2012-13-makes-labors-

surplus-task-harder/story-fn59niix-1226541057969

Packham, Ben and Joe Kelly, 2011. ‘Tony Abbott says Julia Gillard's revamped health

reform package is yet another backdown’, The Australian, 11 Feb. 2011.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/julia-gillard-details-revamped-health-

reform-package-with-the-states-before-coag/story-fn59niix-1226004336983

Packham, Ben; Massola, James. 2012. ‘Australia to have carbon price from July 1, 2012,

Julia Gillard announces’, The Australian, 24 Feb. 2012.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/news/gillard-to-reveal-climate-policy-today/story-e6frg6n6-

1226011223441

Page 25:   · Web viewIt is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition

Parliament of Australia. 2010. ‘ Multiculturalism: a review of Australian policy statements

and recent debates in Australia and overseas’, Elsa Koleth, Social Policy Section, Research

Paper no. 6 2010–11, 8 October 2010.

http://www.aph.gov.au/About_Parliament/Parliamentary_Departments/

Parliamentary_Library/pubs/rp/rp1011/11rp06#_Toc275248124

Plibersek, Tanya. 2013. ‘Transcript - Doorstop - Parliament House Canberra’, 16 May 2013.

http://www.health.gov.au/internet/ministers/publishing.nsf/Content/tr-yr13-tp-

tpsp120516.htm

Swan, W. (2012), ‘The 0.01 Per Cent: The Rising Influence of Vested Interests in Australia’,

The Monthly, March.

http://www.themonthly.com.au/issue/2012/march/1344425290/wayne-swan/001-cent-rising-

influence-vested-interests-australia

Tavan, Gwenda, 2012, ‘No Going Back? Australian Multiculturalism as a Path-Dependent

Process’, AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF POLITICAL SCIENCE 47(4):547-561.

Willox, Innes. 2013. ‘Business pays too much for carbon’, The Australian, 26 June 2013.

http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/opinion/business-pays-too-much-for-

carbon/story-e6frgd0x-1226669728678

Wood, Tony. 2013. ‘Why Australians are getting a raw deal on electricity prices’, The

Conversation, 22 April 2013.

http://theconversation.com/why-australians-are-getting-a-raw-deal-on-electricity-prices-

13296

World Trade Organization, International Trade Statistics 2012

http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/its2012_e/its2012_e.pdf

Zhu, Wenqian. 2013. ‘Global CO2 emissions at record high in 2012’, CNNMoney, 11 June

2013.

http://money.cnn.com/2013/06/11/news/economy/co2-emissions-record-high/index.html