145
מאמרים על הזעזועים המניעים מחזורי עסקים חיבור לשם קבלת תואר דוקטור לפילוסופיה מאת נדב בן זאב הוגש לסנט האוניברסיטה העברית, בירושלים12/2011

םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

מאמרים על הזעזועים המניעים מחזורי עסקים

חיבור לשם קבלת תואר דוקטור לפילוסופיה

מאת

נדב בן זאב

בירושלים, הוגש לסנט האוניברסיטה העברית

12/2011

Page 2: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

מאמרים על הזעזועים המניעים מחזורי עסקים

חיבור לשם קבלת תואר דוקטור לפילוסופיה

מאת

נדב בן זאב

בירושלים, הוגש לסנט האוניברסיטה העברית

12/2011

Page 3: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

:של ועבודה זו נעשתה בהדרכת

פרופסור יוסף זעירא

Page 4: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

קצירת

? אילו זעזועים מניעים מחזורי עסקים: אחת משאלות המחקר החשובות ביותר במדע המקרו כלכלה הינה

קיימים עדיין כיום חילוקי דעות רבים וחוסר , מענה לשאלה זולמרות המחקר הרב שנעשה על מנת למצוא

עבודת הדוקטוראט שלי משתייכת לספרות . הסכמה לגבי סוגי הזעזועים אשר מניעים מחזורי עסקים

בעוד . הרחבה של מחזורי עסקים בעצם יכולתה לתרום להבנתנו בסוגי הזעזועים המניעים מחזורי עסקים

ים עדות אמפירית על זעזועי אינפורמציה לגבי טכנולוגיה בסקטור שני המאמרים הראשונים מספק

המאמר השלישי מפתח מסגרת , וזעזועי היצע אשראי כזעזועים המניעים מחזורי עסקים) IST(ההשקעה

.תיאורטית של משק קטן ופתוח אשר מאפשרת לחקור את השפעתם של זעזועי אינפורמציה ורעש

לאחרונה הוצעהאשר אינפורמציה זעזועי לזיהוי אמפירית מתודולוגיה מרחיב הראשון המאמר

.הכלכלה של האמיתי המודל סוג לגבי ההנחה על מגבלה הטלת ללא ל"הנ הזעזועים את לזהות שמטרתה

זעזועי שתזהה מתודולוגיה מציע אלא מסוים מבני מודל של מבנית אמידה אומד לא אני, כלומר

המתקיימות זיהוי הנחות באמצעות השפעתם ואת שקעההה בסקטור הטכנולוגיה על אינפורמציה

כי להראות בכדי, בפרט. אינפורמציה זעזועי הכוללים כללי למשק שיווי של כלכליים מקרו במודלים

- ניו מבני ממודל נתונים ייצרתי בהן קרלו הטמונ סימולציות ביצעתי, טוב זיהו מבצעת המתודולוגיה

הממצאים. המלאכותיים הנתונים על האמידה אלגוריתם את יויישמת פעמים של רב מספר יאניסקיינ

מעודדת עדות אכן זו טוב לזיהוי הוכחה לא זו כי ולמרות, טוב זיהוי מבצעת המתודולוגיה אכן כי מראים

כדי ב"ארה כלכלת על בנתונים שימוש עשיתי, מכך ביתרה. טוב זיהוי לבצע מסוגלת שהמתודולוגיה לכך

התיאורטיים אלו עם עקביים האמפיריים הממצאים. ל"הנ הזעזועים של יריתהאמפ ההשפעה את לבחון

את מגדילה בעתיד IST על חיובית אינפורמציה, כלומר. מוצג במאמרש התיאורטי מהמודל שנובעים

זעזועי האינפורמציה , בנוסף. לדפלציה מביאה בעת ובו מיידית וצריכה השקעה, תעסוקה, התוצר

המיתונים עשרתמתוך תשעהל ותרמו בפועל ל"תיות קצרת הטווח במשתנים הנמהתנוד 70% -מסבירים כ

מחזורי לייצר מסוגלים רק לא האינפורמציהזעזועי כי מראות התוצאות, לסיכום. ב"האחרונים בארה

60 - ב האמריקאי המשק של העסקים במחזורי בשישה ומרכזי חשוב תפקיד שיחקו שהם גם אלא עסקים

רומה המרכזית של מאמר זה מתבטאת בעדות האמפירית החזקה כי זעזועי הת. האחרונות השנה

.מהווים את הגורם המשמעותי מאחורי מחזורי עסקים ISTאינפורמציה על

מציע שאני הזיהוי שיטת. עסקים במחזורי ובתפקידם אשראי היצע בזעזועי עוסק השני המאמר

זה שזעזוע המגבלה תחת החיצוני המימון ייתפרמ את ביותר הטובה בצורה מסביר אשר הזעזוע את מזהה

ברמת תלויים בלתי הינם אשר הזעזועים קבוצת מתוך, כלומר. במשק הטכנולוגיה ברמת תלוי בלתי הינו

. החיצוני המימון פרמיית את טוב הכי שמסביר בזעזוע בוחר אני, בעתיד והן בהווה הן במשק הטכנולוגיה

הממצאים. החיצוני המימון פרמיית את טוב הכי מסביר אשר קושהבי זעזוע את מוצא בעצם אני, למעשה

Page 5: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

זה וזעזוע החיצוני המימון בפרמיית השונות רוב את שמסביר ביקוש זעזוע שישנו מראים אכן האמפיריים

במיתון מרכזי תפקיד ושיחק עסקים מחזורי לייצר מסוגל הוא, בפרט. אשראי היצע זעזוע כמו מתנהג

דומה באופן מתנהגים אשר אשראי היצע זעזועי הכולל תיאורטי מודל מפתח םג אני. ב"בארה האחרון

היצע זעזועי את לזהות מסוגלת שלי הזיהוי שיטת כי מראה אני, לבסוף. מזהה שאני האמפיריים לזעזועים

התרומה העיקרית ש מאמר .התיאורטי המודלי "בהתבסס על נתונים מלאכותיים המיוצרים ע האשראי

למרות שאינם הגורם הדומיננטי המסביר של , עדות האמפירית כ זעזועי היצע אשראיזה מתבטאת ב

, בתקופות שבהן ישנם זעזועי היצע אשראי גדולים, בפרט. מסוגלים לייצר מחזורי עסקים, מחזורי עסקים

ביחד עם התוצאות של המאמר הראשון. סביר כי ייווצר מיתון רציני ביותר, כמו במיתון העולמי האחרון

של מאמר זה מספקות תמונת מצב התוצאות , אשר זוהו במאמר הראשון ISTעל זעזועי האינפורמציה על

.מעניינת המצביעה על שני זעזועים אשר מסוגלים לייצר מחזורי עסקים

עם אינפורמציה מבנה של הרחבה ופתוח הכולל קטן משק של יאניסקיינ- ניו מודל מפתחהשלישי המאמר

זעזועי מולידה זו הרחבה. במשק הפרטים מקבלים אותם העתידי הכולל לפריון בנוגע רעש בעלי סיגנלים

את ממדל שאני לציין יש. העסקים במחזור תפקידם בחינת את ומאפשרת המודל לתוך ורעש אינפורמציה

של הולדה המאפשר דומה אינפורמציה מבנה עם סגור משק של יאניסקיינ- ניו כמודל העולם שאר כלכלת

הינה ורעש אינפורמציה בזעזועי העוסקת לספרות שלי התרומה. העולמית הכלכלה ברמת ל"הנ עיםהזעזו

הכלכלה ברמת והן המקומי המשק ברמת הן, ורעש אינפורמציה זעזועי של ההשפעה את בוחן שאני בכך

עיקרב כה עד שהתמקדה בספרות נעשה לא זה מסוג ניתוח, ידיעתי למיטב. ופתוח קטן משק על, העולמית

התמקדו פתוחים משקים בחנו שכן מאמרים של םצמוצהמ המספר, בנוסף. סגור משק של במודלים

שזעזועי כך על מצביעות המאמר של המרכזיות התוצאות. רעש זעזועי של בחינה ללא אינפורמציה בזעזועי

אינפורמציה זעזועי, לדפלציה וגורמים הכלכלית הפעילות את מרחיבים מקומיים חיוביים אינפורמציה

רעש וזעזועי בדפלציה המלווה מיידית אינפלציה ומייצרים הכלכלית הפעילות את מרחיבים כן גם עולמיים

ומייצרים הכלכלית הפעילות את המרחיבים טהורים ביקוש כזעזועי מתנהגים ועולמיים מקומיים

פוטנציאלי תפקיד רעשו אינפורמציה זעזועיל יש התיאורטית ברמה לפחות כי הינה המסקנה. אינפלציה

.פתוח קטן משק של העסקים במחזור חשוב

Page 6: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

Essays on The Sources of Business Cycles

Thesis submitted for the degree of

“Doctor of Philosophy” (Economics)

By

Nadav Ben Zeev

Submitted to the Senate of the Hebrew University

12/2011

Page 7: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

Essays on The Sources of Business Cycles

Thesis submitted for the degree of

“Doctor of Philosophy” (Economics)

By

Nadav Ben Zeev

Submitted to the Senate of the Hebrew University

12/2011

Page 8: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

This work was carried out under the supervision of:

Prof. Joseph Zeira

Page 9: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

1

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank my committee members - Joseph Zeira, Zvi Hercowitz, Bob

Barsky, and Michael Beenstock. I am especially grateful to my chair, Joseph Zeira,

without whom I would not have had the opportunity to pursue my research interests

and become part of the PhD program at Hebrew U. I enjoyed our discussions and

learned a lot from them. He was also the main reason behind my three months visit at

the University of Michigan which had a very positive effect on my dissertation.

A special thanks is also due to Bob Barsky with whom I was fortunate enough

to spend a semester at the University of Michigan during which time I benefited a lot

from numerous discussions with him. Bob's work on news shocks influenced me a

great deal and was the main reason for which I started to do independent work in the

field of news shocks. I also benefited from discussions with Zvi Hercowitz, who

introduced the concept of investment specific technology in the framework of an

otherwise standard macro model over 20 years ago. This concept has turned out to be

one of the main themes of my dissertation. Furthermore, I am very grateful to

Michael Beenstock who taught me a lot of what I know about time series

econometrics and was always patient and willing to read and discuss my work.

Lastly, I am greatly indebted to my parents for their love and support. They

have played a crucial part in my being able to pursue my academic goals. I am also

very grateful to my brother for always being there for me. I would also like to express

my deep gratitude to my girlfriend and best friend, Lori, for her love, support, and

patience during my PhD studies.

Page 10: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

2

Abstract

The quest for understanding the driving forces behind business cycles has been a

prominent feature of modern macroeconomic research. The role of several candidate

shocks as business cycle drivers has been studied, leaving much debate and lack of

consensus on the types of shocks that drive business cycles. This dissertation belongs

to the vast business cycle literature in that it tries to contribute to our understanding of

the types of shocks that drive the business cycle. While the first two papers in the

dissertation provide empirical evidence on news shocks about future investment

specific technology and credit supply shocks as business cycle drivers, the third paper

is a theoretical contribution that models the role of news and noise shocks in an open

economy setting.

The first paper focuses on the empirical role of news shocks about future

investment specific technology (IST), i.e. technology that is specific to the investment

goods sector, and provides robust evidence that IST news shocks constitute a

significant force behind the business cycle. Extending a recent empirical approach to

identifying news shocks, I find robust evidence that IST news shocks induce positive

comovement, i.e., raise output, consumption, investment, and hours of work, explain

70% of their business cycle variation, and have played an important part in nine of the

last ten U.S recessions. I also show that the empirical method I employ is indeed

capable of identifying IST news shocks from data generated by a standard DSGE

model. Overall, the main contribution of the paper is the robust evidence that IST

news shocks are the major force behind the business cycle. Hence, the paper offers a

potential resolution for the debate about which shocks actually drive business cycles.

The second paper studies the role of credit supply shocks in the business cycle,

an issue that has received considerable attention in light of the recent financial crisis

Page 11: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

3

and great recession in the U.S. Extending Uhlig's (2003) method, I identify the

demand shock that explains the most of the movements in the external finance

premium (EFP). This demand shock induces business cycle comovement and has

played an important part in the recent recession. Impulse response functions provide

an interpretation of this shock as a credit supply shock. Monte Carlo simulation

results based on a DSGE model with a financial accelerator, in which credit supply

shocks generate impulse responses consistent with the observed empirical responses,

indicate that the identification method does a good job of identifying these shocks

from model generated data. The results indicate that even though credit supply shocks

are not a dominant source behind the business, they have the potential of generating

business cycles. Moreover, as is evident from the recent recession, large adverse

credit supply shocks are likely to cause a serious recession.

The third paper studies the potential role of domestic and foreign news and

animal spirits shocks in a small open economy using a calibrated small open economy

new Keynesian model. The main contribution of the paper lies in proposing a setting

in which the effect of both foreign and domestic news and animal spirits shocks can

be studied. The news shock is a permanent but not immediate innovation to the level

of technology as it is an anticipation of a future technology shock. I only allow

domestic and foreign households to observe a noisy signal of domestic and foreign

news, respectively, and interpret a pure noise innovation as an animal spirits shock, as

it is associated with erroneous consumer optimism or pessimism. I find that foreign

news are expansionary and induce inflation on impact followed by deflation at longer

time horizons, while domestic news are expansionary and deflationary. Domestic

animal spirits are expansionary and inflationary playing the role of aggregate demand

Page 12: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

4

shocks whereas foreign animal spirits are expansionary and lead to deflation on

impact and inflation afterwards.

Page 13: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

5

Table of Contents

Acknowledgements ........................................................................................................ 1

Abstract .......................................................................................................................... 2

List of Figures ............................................................................................................... 8

List of Tables ............................................................................................................. 10

Chapter I. Introduction ................................................................................................ 11

Chapter II. News Shocks about Future Investment Specific Technology and Business

Cycles .......................................................................................................................... 14

1. Introduction ................................................................................................... …14

2. Empirical Strategy ............................................................................................. 17

2.1 Identification Strategy ................................................................................ 18

2.2 Simulation Evidence ................................................................................. 20

3. Empirical Evidence ............................................................................................ 27

3.1 Data ............................................................................................................ 27

3.2 Benchmark Results .................................................................................. 29

3.3 Sensitivity Analysis ................................................................................... 35

3.4 Relation with Previous Work ..................................................................... 37

4. Conclusion ......................................................................................................... 40

III. The External Finance Premium and Business Cycles............................................ 58

1. Introduction ......................................................................................................... 58

2. Empirical Strategy .............................................................................................. 61

3. Empirical Evidence ............................................................................................ 64

Page 14: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

6

3.1 Data ............................................................................................................ 64

3.2 Benchmark Results .................................................................................. 65

3.3 Sensitivity Analysis ................................................................................... 69

4. A DSGE Model with a Financial Accelerator .................................................... 72

4.1 Model ......................................................................................................... 72

4.2 Estimation ................................................................................................ 75

4.3 Results ........................................................................................................ 77

4.4 Simulation Evidence .................................................................................. 78

5. Conclusion ........................................................................................................ 80

IV. The Role of Domestic and Foreign News and Animal Spirits Shocks in a Small

Open Economy............................................................................................................. 97

1. Introduction ........................................................................................................ 97

2. Small Open Economy Model ........................................................................... 101

2.1 Households .............................................................................................. 101

2.1.1 The real exchange rate and the terms of trade ..................... 103

2.1.2 The Foreign Economy and International risk sharing .......... 104

2.1.2 Uncovered interest parity ...................................................... 105

2.2 Firms ....................................................................................................... 106

2.2.1 Technology and News Shocks .............................................. 106

2.2.2 Perceptions and Animal Spirits ............................................. 108

2.2.3 Price-Setting .......................................................................... 110

3. Equillibrium ..................................................................................................... 112

3.1 The Demand Side: Aggregate demand and output determination .......... 112

Page 15: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

7

3.2 The Trade Balance ................................................................................... 113

3.3 The Supply Side: Marginal Cost and Inflation Dynamics ....................... 114

3.4 Closing the Model: Domestic monetary policy rule and Foreign Economy

Equilibrium .............................................................................................. 115

4. Numerical Results .......................................................................................... 116

4.1 Calibration .............................................................................................. 116

4.2 Impulse Responses to the Structural Shocks ........................................ 117

4.3 Variance Decomposition ........................................................................ 120

4.4 Robustness ............................................................................................. 121

5. Conclusion ....................................................................................................... 124

V. Conclusion .......................................................................................................... 137

Page 16: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

8

List of Figures

Figure 2.1 : Model and Monte Carlo Estimated Impulse Responses to IST News

Shock............................................................................................................................ 50

Figure 2.2 : Model and Monte Carlo Estimated Impulse Responses to Unanticipated

IST Shock..................................................................................................................... 51

Figure 2.3 : Empirical Impulse Responses to IST News Shock ................................. 52

Figure 2.4 : Share of Forecast Error Variance Attributable to identified shocks ........ 53

Figure 2.5 : Identified News Shock Time Series and U.S Recessions ........................ 54

Figure 2.6 : Empirical Impulse Responses to Unanticipated IST Shock .................... 55

Figure 2.7 : Impulse responses to IST News shock: Alternative investment price

measure ........................................................................................................................ 56

Figure 2.8 Impulse responses to IST News shock: Larger VAR ................................. 57

Figure 3.1 : Empirical Impulse Responses to EFP Shocks .......................................... 89

Figure 3.2 : Share of Forecast Error Variance Attributable to identified shocks ........ 90

Figure 3.3 : Identified News Shock Time Series and U.S Recessions ........................ 91

Figure 3.4 : Impulse responses to EFP shocks: Smaller Sample ................................. 92

Figure 3.5 : Impulse responses to EFP shocks: Alternative measure of EFP .............. 93

Figure 3.6 : Impulse responses to EFP shocks: Including Credit Quantity ................. 94

Figure 3.7 : Impulse responses to Credit Supply shock for DSGE model ................... 95

Figure 3.8 : Model and Monte Carlo Estimated Impulse Responses to Credit Supply

shocks ........................................................................................................................... 96

Figure 4.1 : Impulse Responses to Technology Shocks ............................................ 127

Figure 4.2 : Impulse Responses to News Shocks ...................................................... 128

Page 17: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

9

Figure 4.3 : Impulse Responses to Animal Spirits Shocks ........................................ 129

Figure 4.4 : Forecast Error Variance Decomposition ................................................ 130

Figure 4.5 : Impulse Responses to Domestic Technology Shocks under Alternative

Policy Rules ............................................................................................................... 131

Figure 4.6 : Impulse Responses to Foreign Technology Shocks under Alternative

Policy Rules ............................................................................................................... 132

Figure 4.7 : Impulse Responses to Domestic News Shocks under Alternative Policy

Rules .......................................................................................................................... 133

Figure 4.8 : Impulse Responses to Foreign News Shocks under Alternative Policy

Rules .......................................................................................................................... 134

Figure 4.9 : Impulse Responses to Domestic Animal Spirits under Alternative Policy

Rules .......................................................................................................................... 135

Figure 4.10 : Impulse Responses to Foreign Animal Spirits under Alternative Policy

Rules .......................................................................................................................... 136

Page 18: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

10

List of Tables

Table 2.1: The Variables and Equations of the model ................................................. 45

Table 2.2 : Description of the Parameters of the Model and Bechmark Values .......... 47

Table 2.3 : Correlation Estimates................................................................................. 48

Table 2.4 : Historical Contribution of IST News Shocks to Output per Capita Loss in

U.S Recessions ............................................................................................................. 49

Table 3.1: Correlation Estimates.................................................................................. 84

Table 3.2 : Historical Contribution of EFP Shocks to Output per Capita Loss in U.S

Recessions .................................................................................................................... 85

Table 3.3: The Variables and Equations of the Model ................................................ 86

Table 3.4 : Description of the Parameters of the Model and Bechmark Values .......... 88

Page 19: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

11

Chapter I

Introduction

The field of macroeconomics has long been devoted to studying the sources of

business cycles. Though significant research has been conducted on identifying the

specific types of shocks that generate business cycles, we are still left with much

debate and lack of consensus on which shocks actually drive the business cycle. This

dissertation contributes to the business cycle literature by providing evidence

regarding the types of shocks that drive the business cycle.

Chapter II extends a recent empirical approach to the identification of news

shocks and applies this extended method to identify news shocks about future

investment specific technology (Henceforth IST) using U.S postwar data. These

shocks do not affect IST contemporaneously but rather portend future changes in it

and thus are defined as news shocks. The method is VAR based and essentially

identifies the IST news shock as the shock that is orthogonal to current IST and that

maximally explains future variation in IST over a finite horizon. Chapter II finds

robust evidence that IST news shocks induce positive comovement, i.e., raise output,

consumption, investment, and hours of work, explain 70% of their business cycle

variation, and have played an important part in nine of the last ten U.S recessions.

These novel findings suggest that business cycles are broadly generated by IST news

shocks hence offering a potential resolution for the debate about the types of shocks

drive business cycles.

While chapter II deals with technology related shocks, chapter III is concerned

with the identification of credit supply shocks, an issue that has received considerable

attention in light of the recent financial crisis and great recession in the U.S.

Extending Uhlig's (2003) VAR based method, I identify the demand shock that

explains the most of the movements in the external finance premium (EFP).

Page 20: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

12

Specifically, the identified shock is attained by finding the shock that maximally

explains future variation in the external finance premium under the restriction that it

has no effect on both neutral and investment specific technology at all horizons. It is

found that this demand shock induces business cycle comovement and has played an

important part in the recent recession. Impulse response functions provide an

interpretation of this shock as a credit supply shock. Even though credit supply shocks

are not the dominant force behind business cycles in general, the results indicate that

they are indeed capable of generating business cycles especially when large negative

shocks realize, as was clearly demonstrated by the recent recession.

Chapters II and III follow recent work which used monte carlo simulations

based on DSGE models to check the suitability of a given identification method (e.g.

Francis et al., Chari et al. (2008), and Barsky and Sims (2010a)). Accordingly, it is

verified in both papers that the identification strategy is capable of recovering the IST

news shock and credit supply shock as well as their dynamic effects from data

simulated from DSGE models. For each paper, a different DSGE model is used so

that a proper modeling framework is chosen. In chapter II, On the basis of simulations

from a state-of-the-art DSGE model that incorporates IST news shocks, it is shown

that the identification method is likely to perform well at identifying IST news shocks

in practice. In chapter III, Monte Carlo simulation results based on a DSGE model

with a financial accelerator, in which credit supply shocks generate impulse responses

consistent with the observed empirical responses, indicate that the identification

method does a good job of identifying these shocks from model generated data.

Chapter IV formulates a theoretical small open economy New Keynesian

model that incorporates domestic and foreign news shocks and animal spirits (noise)

shocks and allows an examination of the implications of these shocks for a small open

economy. The news shock is a permanent but not immediate innovation to the level of

technology as it is an anticipation of a future technology shock. I only allow domestic

and foreign households to observe a noisy signal of domestic and foreign news,

Page 21: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

13

respectively, and interpret a pure noise innovation as an animal spirits shock, as it is

associated with erroneous consumer optimism or pessimism.

The main contribution of the paper lies in proposing a setting in which the

effect of both foreign and domestic news and animal spirits shocks can be studied.

The reason such an extended setting is interesting is twofold. First, it is appealing to

examine whether the effects of domestic news and animal spirits shocks are different

for a small open economy model relative to a closed economy model. The findings

indicate that the effects are similar to the closed economy model as domestic news are

expansionary and deflationary while domestic animal spirits are expansionary and

inflationary playing the role of aggregate demand shocks. Second, it is interesting to

study how the effects of foreign news and animal spirits shocks differ from their

domestic counterparts. The findings indicate a difference with respect to the response

of inflation which is attributable to exchange rate behavior. In particular, it is found

that foreign news are expansionary and induce inflation on impact (due to currency

depreciation) followed by deflation at longer time horizons which is imported by the

deflation in the foreign economy, while foreign animal spirits are expansionary and

lead to deflation on impact (due to currency appreciation) and inflation afterwards as

the demand side effects of the shocks become more dominant than the exchange rate

effect.

The introduction of noise into the news signals arguably renders a more

realistic setting than one in which news shocks are perfectly observed and known in

advance. Chapter IV demonstrates that news shocks can be important even if they are

imperfectly observed as noisy signals. Nevertheless, as the news signals become

noisier their importance diminishes. Given that the VAR based identification method

used in chapter II is also suitable for the case in which news signals contain noise, it

can be deduced that IST news shocks are not dominated by noise even though it is

fairly reasonable to assume that they are not perfectly known in advance.

Chapter V presents concluding remarks and binds the various themes of the

dissertation together. It also discusses possible avenues for future related research.

Page 22: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

14

Chapter II

News Shocks about Future Investment Specific

Technology and Business Cycles

1. Introduction

This paper contributes to the vast literature that has strived to comprehend which

forces drive business cycles by providing robust evidence that IST news shocks are a

significant force behind business cycles. I identify IST news shocks by extending the

VAR based method for the identification of news shocks that was recently proposed

by Barsky and Sims (2010a),1 which in turn builds upon the maximum forecast error

variance (MFEV) identification approach developed by Uhlig (2003). Whereas the

former identified TFP news shocks as the shocks that maximally explain future

variation in TFP over a finite horizon orthogonalized with respect to unanticipated

TFP shocks, thus adding one identifying restriction to the MFEV optimization

problem, I add two identifying restrictions for the identification of IST news shocks.

In particular, the IST news shock is identified as the linear combination of reduced

form innovations orthogonal to both unanticipated TFP and IST shocks which

maximizes the sum of contributions to IST forecast error variance over a finite

horizon.2 As discussed in section 2.2, the main reason for including TFP and the

corresponding additional orthogonality restriction is that the monte carlo simulation

results, using DSGE model generated data, showed that it significantly improves the

identification of IST news shocks. The main virtue of this identification approach to

1 They focus on TFP news shocks and find the latter to be associated with an increase in consumption

and decrease in output, investment and hours worked on impact thus suggesting an unimportant role of

these shocks in the business cycle. 2 It's important to note here that TFP is a measure of exogenous neutral technology, as opposed to labor

productivity, and it is therefore appropriate to impose on IST news shocks to be orthogonal to it

contemporaneously.

Page 23: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

15

IST news shocks is that it does not impose a specific model structure on the data as in

the empirical DSGE literature but rather exploits two common assumptions in IST

news driven DSGE models that (i) only a limited number of shocks ever affect IST

and (ii) IST news shocks do not affect IST contemporaneously but rather portend

future changes in it. After it is shown that this identification procedure performs well

on DSGE model generated data in terms of identifying IST news shocks and their

business cycle effects, I apply it on postwar U.S data.3 I find robust evidence that IST

news shocks induce positive business cycle comovement, i.e., raise output,

consumption, investment, and hours of work, explain 70% of their forecast error

variance at business cycle frequencies, and have played an important part in nine of

the last ten U.S recessions. Overall, it can be deduced that IST news shocks are not

only capable of generating business cycles but also that they have played an important

role as drivers of U.S business cycles over the last sixty years.

The role of several candidate shocks as business cycle drivers has been

studied, leaving much debate and lack of consensus on the types of shocks that drive

business cycles. Such candidate shocks include total factor productivity (TFP) shocks

(e.g. Gali (1999) and Basu, Fernald, and Kimball (2006; Henceforth BFK)),

investment specific technology (IST) shocks (e.g. Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell

(2000; Henceforth GHK), Fisher (2006), Justiniano et al. (2010a, 2010b), and Khan

and Tsoukalas (2011)), and news shocks about future TFP, i.e. shocks that portend

future changes in TFP (e.g. Beaudry and Portier (2006), Beaudry and Lucke (2009),

and Barsky and Sims (2010a)).

The few papers that have tried to assess the role of IST news shocks in the

business cycle did so using estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE)

models (i.e. Davis (2007), Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008), and Khan and Tsoukalas

(2010)). The main advantage of the DSGE approach is that it provides a structural

interpretation of the mechanisms transmitting the shocks. The disadvantage, however,

3 I follow GHK (1997, 2000), Fisher (2006), Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008), Beaudry and Lucke

(2009), and Liu et al. (2011) and use a real investment price measure to gauge IST (see section 3.1 for

data descriptions).

Page 24: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

16

is that model based inferences often depend upon the assumed structure which could

be different from the true one. Therefore, imposing a certain structure on the data

could lead to incorrect inferences. Davis (2007) introduces news shocks in the

Christiano et al. (2005) model and finds that IST news shocks account for about 52%

of the variation in output growth.4 By contrast, Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008)

estimate a flexible price-wage DSGE model with TFP and IST news shocks and find a

strong role for TFP news compared to a negligible role for IST news. Lastly, Khan

and Tsoukalas (2010) estimate a DSGE model with both real and nominal frictions,

including TFP and IST news shocks, and find a relatively weak role for news shocks

as drivers of the business cycle. That the above DSGE literature arrived at different

conclusions about the relative importance of each type of news shock suggests that

some features of the model structure may themselves have an effect on the

quantitative assessments. Overall, the empirical DSGE literature has not found robust

evidence in support of a strong role for IST news shocks as business cycle drivers.

The empirical findings of this paper stand in contrast to the findings of the

DSGE literature on IST news shocks. While the results from this literature depend on

the type of structure of the model, my results are derived from a model-free

identification approach that does not impose any structure on the data but is still

capable of identifying IST news shocks and their business cycle effects from a variety

of model structures. Nevertheless, it's important to understand what type of model

structure is needed in order for IST news shocks to be at the very least capable of

generating business cycles. In the next section, which provides monte carlo simulation

evidence that confirms that the proposed identification approach works fairly well on

DSGE model generated data, I present a state-of-the-art DSGE model that is capable

of providing the structure that is needed for IST news shocks to be drivers of business

cycles. The model is a standard New-Keynesian DSGE model (e.g. Smets and

Wouters (2007)) augmented with the recently popularized Jaimovich and Rebelo

4 Nevertheless, it is unclear whether or not IST news shocks produce business cycle comovement in his

paper as the impulse responses are not shown.

Page 25: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

17

(2009) preference structure and a specification of the cost of utilization in terms of

increased depreciation of capital, as originally proposed by Greenwood, Hercowitz

and Huffman (1988; Henceforth GHH) in a neoclassical setting. The model

essentially contains the three elements that are needed for IST news shocks to be

capable of generating business cycles, as shown by Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009):

preferences with a small wealth effect on labor supply, investment adjustment costs,

and variable capital utilization.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section the

details of the empirical strategy are laid out and simulation evidence that the

identification procedure performs well on data generated from a state-of-the-art

DSGE model is provided. Section 3 begins with a description of the data, after which

it presents the main empirical evidence and provides a sensitivity analysis of the

results as well as a discussion on their relation to earlier work. The final section

concludes.

2. Empirical Strategy

It is assumed that IST is well-characterized as following a stochastic process driven

by two shocks. The first is the traditional unanticipated IST shock of the IST

literature, first introduced in the pioneering work of GHH (1988), which impacts the

level of IST in the same period in which agents observe it. The second is the news

shock, which is differentiated from the first shock in that agents observe the news

shock in advance and it portends future changes in IST. The following is an example

process that incorporates both unanticipated and IST news shocks:

1 1

is is is is

t t t tgε ε η− −= + + (1)

1

is is is

t t tg g eκ −= + (2)

Here log IST, denoted by is

tε , follows a unit root process where the drift term itself

1

is

tg − follows an AR(1) process. Parameterκ describes the persistence of the drift

term. is

tη is the conventional unanticipated IST shock. Given the timing

assumption, is

te has no immediate impact on the level of IST but portends future

Page 26: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

18

changes in it. Hence, it can be defined as an IST news shock. In a VAR including

empirical measures of TFP, IST and several macroeconomic aggregates, the IST news

shock is identified as the shock that best explains future movements in IST over a

horizon of fifteen years and that is orthogonal to both TFP and IST unanticipated

shocks. The restriction with respect to IST is important for identification as it imposes

on the identified shock to have no contemporaneous effect on IST, which complies

with the definition of a news shock. I include TFP in the VAR and impose the

corresponding additional orthogonality restriction because monte carlo simulation

evidence indicated that doing so significantly improves identification. In practice, this

identification strategy involves finding the linear combination of VAR innovations

contemporaneously uncorrelated with TFP and IST innovations which maximally

contributes to IST's future forecast error variance.

The remainder of this section is organized as follows. Section 2.1 introduces

terminology and lays out the identification strategy more formally. This paper follows

recent work which used monte carlo simulations based on DSGE models to check the

suitability of a given identification method (e.g. Francis et al., Chari et al. (2008), and

Barsky and Sims (2010a)). Thus, it is verified in Section 2.2 that the identification

strategy is capable of recovering the IST news shock and its dynamic effects from

data simulated from DSGE models. On the basis of simulations from a state-of-the-art

DSGE model, it is shown that the identification method is likely to perform well at

identifying IST news shocks in practice.

2.1 Identification Strategy

The identification method pursued in the paper will now be presented in detail.

Let ty be a k x1 vector of observables of length T. Estimating a stationary vector error

correction model (VECM) or an unrestricted VAR in levels can generate the reduced

form moving average representation in the levels of the observables:

ty B(L)ut = (3)

Where L is the lag operator and0

B(L) B Lτττ

=

=∑ . It is assumed there exists a linear

mapping between innovations and structural shocks:

Page 27: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

19

t tu Aε= (4)

This implies the following structural moving average representation:

t ty C(L)ε= (5)

Where C(L) B(L)A= and 1At tuε −= . The impact matrix A must satisfy 'AA = Σ ,

whereΣ is the variance-covariance matrix of innovations. However, there's an infinite

number of impact matrices that solve the system 'AA = Σ . In particular, for some

arbitrary orthogonalization, A (e.g. a Choleski decomposition), the entire space of

permissible impact matrices can be written as AD , where D is a k x k orthonormal

matrix ( 'DD I= ).

The h step ahead forecast error is:

t+h t t+h t+h-

0

y -E y = B ADh

τ ττ

ε=∑ (6)

The contribution to the forecast error variance of variable i attributable to structural

shock j at horizon h is then:

'

' '

i,j , ,

0

(h) B A A Bh

i iτ ττ

γγ=

Ω =∑ (7)

γ constitutes the jth column of D. Aγ is then a k x 1 vector corresponding with the jth

column of a possible orthogonalization and ,Bi τ represents the ith row of the matrix of

moving average coefficients at horizonτ . Let TFP and IST occupy the first and

second positions in the system, respectively, and let the unanticipated TFP and IST

shocks be indexed by 1 and 2, respectively. Finally, the news shock is indexed by 3

and is identified as the shock that is orthogonal to unanticipated TFP and IST shocks

and that maximally explains movements in IST not accounted for by its own

innovations and TFP innovations. In particular, the IST news shocks is identified by

finding theγ which maximizes the sum of contribution to the forecast error variance

of IST at horizons from 0 to H subject to the restriction that this shock have no

contemporaneous effect on TFP and IST. This implies solving the following

optimization problem:

Page 28: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

20

'* ' '

2,3 2, 2,

0 0 0

'

arg max ( ) B A A B

A(1, ) 0 1

A(2, ) 0 2

. (1,1) 0

(2,1) 0

1

H H h

h h

h

j j

j j

s t

τ ττ

γ γγ

γγγ γ

= = =

= Ω =

= ∀ >

= ∀ >

=

=

=

∑ ∑∑

H is some finite truncation horizon. The first four constraints impose on the identified

shock to have no contemporaneous effect on TFP and IST. The fifth restriction that

imposes onγ to have unit length ensures thatγ is a column vector belonging to an

orthonormal matrix. Following Uhlig (2003), this maximization problem can be

rewritten as a quadratic form in which the non-zero portion ofγ is the eigenvector

associated with the maximum eigenvalue of the lower (k-2) x (k-2) sub-matrix of the

following matrix S:

( ) ( ) ( )'

2, 2,

0

S 1 B A B AH

H τ ττ

τ=

= + −∑

Hence, this procedure constitutes an application of principle components.

Specifically, it identifies the IST news shock as the first principal component of the

lower (k-2) x (k-2) sub-matrix of matrix S orthogonalized with respect to IST and

TFP innovations.

2.2 Simulation Evidence

Simulation evidence which confirms that the above proposed empirical strategy is

indeed capable of doing a good job of identifying IST news shocks will now be

presented. I consider the by now classic Smets and Wouters (2007) model augmented

with three elements, along the lines of Khan and Tsoukalas (2010, 2011): the recently

popularized Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009) preferences that allow for an arbitrarily

weak wealth effect on labor supply,5 specification of the cost of utilization in terms of

increased depreciation of capital, as originally proposed by GHH (1988) in a

5 These preferences nest two polar specifications that have featured prominently in the business cycle

literature: the one used in King et al. (1988) and the one introduced by GHH (1988).

Page 29: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

21

neoclassical setting,6 and finally the model also includes TFP and IST news shocks.

TFP news shocks are also included in the model in order to be consistent with the

news shocks literature. Prior to presenting the simulation evidence I will first present

the model used to simulate the data.

The preference structure suggested by Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009), which

conveniently nests two special cases which we describe below, is assumed.

Specifically, the utility function of household [0,1]j∈ is

1 1

0

0

( ( ) ) 1

1

lbt t t t t

t c

C L j XE

σ σε χβ

σ

+ −∞

=

− − −

∑ (8)

Where 1t t tX C Xω ω−= and agents internalize the dynamics of tX in their maximization

problem. E0 denotes the expectation conditional on the information available at time

zero, 0 < β < 1, lσ > 1, χ > 0, Cσ > 0, 0 <ω < 1, and b

tε is the preference shock.

When 1ω = the preferences are the same as in King et al.(1988) with the implication

that intertemporal substitution effect influences labor effort. When 0ω = the

preferences are the same as in Greenwood et al.(1988), with the implication that

intertemporal consumption-saving choice does not affect labor effort.

The budget constraint and the capital accumulation equation are given as

1 1( ) ( ) k

t t t t t t t tt t t

t t t t t t

B B W j L j R Z K DivC I T

R P P P P P

− −+ + − ≤ + + + (9)

[ ]1 1(1 ( )) 1 ( / )i

t t t t t t tK Z K S I I Iδ ε− −= − + − (10)

respectively, where tI is investment, is

tε is investment specific technology, tB are

nominal government bonds, tR is the gross nominal interest rate, tP is the price level,

tT is lump-sum taxes, Wt(j) is the nominal wage, k

tR is the rental rate on capital, tZ is

the utilization rate of capital, ( )tZδ is an increasing and convex function of the

utilization rate as in GHH (1988), and tDiv the dividends distributed to the

households from labor unions. The left hand side of (9) represents real expenditures at

6 Traditionally, the cost of utilization is specified in terms of forgone consumption following

Christiano et al. (2005), who studied the effects of monetary policy shocks. I follow Khan and

Tsoukalas (2011) who use the capital depreciation specification and show that it has a superior fit with

the data relative to the Christiano et.al (2005) specification. This specification is also used in Jaimovich

and Rebelo (2009).

Page 30: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

22

time t net of taxes on consumption, investment, and bonds. The right hand side of (9)

indicates real receipts from wage income, earnings from supplying capital services net

of cost, and dividends. In (3), 1( / )t tS I I − is a convex investment adjustment cost

function. In the steady state it is assumed that S=S'=0, and S''>0. The aggregate

resource constraint is

t t t tC I G Y+ + = (11)

The first-order condition for optimal utilization of capital is given by the

following equation

'( )k

tt t

t

RQ Z

Pδ= (12)

where tQ is the shadow value of installed capital in consumption units, given by the

ratio of the marginal value of installed capital and the marginal value of

consumption.

The equilibrium conditions of the model log-linearized about the balanced

growth path, along with the definition of the variables, are presented in table 2.1.

Equation (T.1) is the aggregate resource constraint; Eq. (T.2) is the Euler equation for

consumption where the coefficients 1c and 2c depend on the underlying model

parameters and the steady state level of hours worked;7 Eq. (T.3) is the Euler equation

for investment; Eq.(T.4) depicts the dynamics of Tobin’s q; Eq.(T.5) is the aggregate

production function; Capital services used in production are a function of capital

installed in the previous period and capital utilization, as described by eq. (T.6); Eq.

(T.7) expresses the optimal capital utilization rate as a function of the value of capital

and rental rate on capital; Eq. (T.8) is the capital accumulation equation; The price

mark up is defined by Eq. (T.9); Inflation dynamics are described by the New-

Keynesian Phillips curve in Eq. (T.10); Cost minimization by firms implies that the

capital-labor ratio is inversely related to the rental rate of capital and positively related

to the wage rate, as described by eq. (T.11); The wage markup is given by Eq. (T.12);

7 The reader is referred to Khan and Tsoukalas (2010, 2011) for the exact expressions for these

parameters.

Page 31: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

23

The wage inflation dynamics are described by Eq. (T.13); Lastly, Eq. (T.14) describes

the monetary policy rule.

The news processes, given by eq. (T.16) and (T.21), are simply a smooth

version of the news process studied in Beaudry and Portier (2004) and Jaimovich and

Rebelo (2009) where the news shock portends a future permanent change in

technology j periods into the future. This smooth specification is consistent with the

smooth gradual news processes employed in Leeper et.al (2009) and Leeper and

Walker (2011). Identification also performs well when the more standard

specification of Beaudry and Portier (2004) and Jaimovich and Reblelo (2009) is

used. Nevertheless, I choose the smooth version specification because it seems to be

more consistent with the data, as indicated by the empirical results in section 3.

Labels, definitions and benchmark values of the parameters are in Table 2.2.

The benchmark values of the discount factor, intertemporal elasticity, capital share

and capital utilization elasticity are set in accordance with Jaimovich and Rebelo

(2009). The wealth elasticity parameter is set at 0.1.8 The values for the news

persistence parameters follow Barsky and Sims (2010b) while those of the monetary

policy rule are consistent with the empirical estimates of Coibion and Gorodnichenko

(2007), Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2007), Erceg, Guerrieri, and Gust

(2006), and Ireland (2004). The standard deviation of the news shocks is set in

accordance with Khan and Tsoukalas (2010) while all remaining parameters' values

by and large follow the estimates of Smets and Wouters (2007).9

I simulate 2000 sets of data with 240 observations each, drawing all eight

exogenous shocks from normal distributions. The sample size of 240 observations

matches in size the empirical postwar sample employed in section 3 which spans the

8 The value chosen here is bigger than the estimate of Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008) (0.007) though

significantly smaller than the estimate of Khan and Tsoukalas (2011) (0.53) and Khan and Tsoukalas

(2010) (0.85). While bigger values have no noticeable effect on the simulation results, I prefer to use a

smaller value as it generates a robust increase in hours on impact in response to IST news shocks. 9 I follow Fisher (2006), Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008), Fernandez-Villaverde (2009), and Jaimovich

and Rebelo (2009) and assume that TFP and IST follow a unit root process (see eq. T.15 and eq. T.21

in table 1). This implies that TFP and IST news shocks have a permanent effect on TFP and IST,

respectively. The identification results are robust to assuming stationary processes for TFP and IST as

in Smets and Wouters (2007) and Khan and Tsoukalas (2010, 2011).

Page 32: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

24

period 1951:Q1-2010:Q4. So as to make the simulated data as close as possible to

actual data, the simulated series are transformed by adding back in trend growth

where applicable.10

For each simulation, I estimate a four-lag VAR with a constant

that includes the levels of TFP, IST, output, investment, consumption, hours, nominal

interest rate, and inflation, which coincides with the benchmark empirical VAR in

Section 3. The truncation horizon is set at H=60. In other words, the IST news shock

is identified as that shock orthogonal to current TFP and IST which maximally

explains IST over a horizon of fifteen years. A truncation horizon of fifteen years,

which is also used for the empirical VAR in section 3, is both long enough to account

for potentially strong long run effects of IST news shocks on IST and short enough to

provide reliable results. Following the identification procedure outlined above the

estimated impulse responses and identified time series of IST news shocks for each

simulation are collected.

Figure 2.1 depicts both theoretical and estimated impulse responses of IST,

output, consumption, investment, hours, and inflation averaged over the simulations

to a favorable IST news shock. The theoretical responses are represented by the solid

lines and the average estimated responses over the simulations are depicted by the

dashed lines, with the dotted lines depicting the 10th

and 90th

percentiles of the

distribution of estimated impulse responses. It is apparent that the business cycle

effects of IST news shocks are well identified. In particular, the estimated empirical

impulse responses are unbiased on impact and for a number of quarters thereafter

while being downward biased at long horizons. Nevertheless, the unbiasedness of the

estimated responses at short horizons coupled with the observation that the confidence

intervals do not include zero are especially important since my focus is not on the

long horizon implications of IST news shocks, but rather on their ability to generate

business cycles. Figure 2.2 depicts the results for identification of unanticipated IST

shocks. Overall, the identification performs well at short horizons while being

10

Following Fernandez-Villaverde (2009), quarterly trend growth rates of 0.28% and 0.34% are added

to TFP and IST, respectively, and in accordance with the balanced growth path 0.63% is added to

output, investment and consumption.

Page 33: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

25

downward biased at long horizons. The identification of the effects of TFP shocks

(not shown) also performs well, in particular at short run horizons.

The average correlation between the identified IST news shock and the true

IST news shock across simulations is 0.81, with the median correlation 0.82 and the

10th and 90th percentile correlations 0.71 and 0.88, respectively. The mean

correlation between identified unanticipated TFP and IST shocks and their

corresponding true shocks is higher reaching 0.90 and 0.91, respectively.

A similar simulation exercise in which TFP was not included in the VAR was

conducted as well. The results from this simulation indicate that on top of a

significantly lower mean correlation (48%), the confidence interval of the empirical

distribution of the estimated impulse responses is considerably wider. For example,

the confidence interval for the output, consumption, and investment responses is more

than three and a half times as large on impact and more than twice as large for the six

quarters thereafter when TFP is excluded compared to the benchmark case, after

which the difference is also considerable. This implies that estimation is much more

precise, as measured by the confidence bands, when TFP and the corresponding

orthogonality restriction are included in the estimation procedure.11

Therefore, it is

found that excluding TFP from the VAR is inferior to the benchmark case.

My series of simulation results also indicate that the issue of VAR non-

invertibility is not a major concern for my identification strategy. VAR invertiblity

pertains to the case in which DSGE models produce moving average representations

in the observables which can be inverted into a VAR representation in which the VAR

innovations correspond to economic shocks (see Fernandez-Villaverde, Rubio-

Ramirez, Sargent, and Watson (2007) for the conditions needed for VAR

invertibility). Invertibility problems potentially arise when there are unobserved state

variables which do not enter the estimated VAR (Watson (1986)). Hence, having

news shocks in the model generates invertibility problems as the latter constitute both

shocks and unobserved state variables. I also experimented with news specifications

11

Similar results obtain when the standard deviations of the estimated responses are compared.

Page 34: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

26

in which news shocks affect IST with a lag of several periods as opposed to one

period as in the benchmark case, thus exacerbating VAR invertibility problems due to

the introduction of additional unobserved state variables, and found that identification

still performs well despite a slight decline in the mean correlation between identified

shocks and true shocks. Nevertheless, the empirical results of the next section provide

evidence in favor of a news process in which there is a gradual increase in future IST

starting with a lag of one period.

It is also important to note that the identification method is robust to assuming

signal extraction problems facing agents. Blanchard, L'Hullier, and Lorenzoni (2009)

consider a framework in which agents receive news about productivity that is

contaminated with noise and conclude that it is not possible to employ long run

restrictions to separately identify the noise shock. Nevertheless, similarly to the

Barsky and Sims (2010a) identification method, the identification strategy pursued in

this paper is still capable of identifying news shocks in the presence of noise since the

introduction of noise into the news signals merely weakens the effect of news shocks

on agents' actions while not altering any of the identifying assumptions as the IST and

news processes themselves remain unaffected.

The suitability of the identification strategy appears robust to alternative

calibrations of the model. Since the identification algorithm mechanically picks out

from all the shocks that are orthogonal to current IST and TFP the shock that

maximally explains future variation in IST, the method naturally performs better in

calibrations in which there is more variation in IST directly attributable to the IST

news shock. It is therefore encouraging that the empirical results, which will be

presented in the next section, indicated that IST news shocks drive a considerable

share of IST variation accounting for 83% of the latter at the fifteen year horizon.

Furthermore, taking into account that the estimated effects of IST news shocks on IST

at long horizons most likely understate the true effects, as demonstrated in figure

Page 35: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

27

2.1,12

suggests that we can be fairly confident that the identification method has

performed well in practice. Overall, the monte carlo simulations suggest that the

identifying strategy is capable of doing a good job of identifying both IST news

shocks and their business cycle effects on macroeconomic aggregates.

3 Empirical Evidence

In this section the main results of the paper are presented. The findings indicate that

favorable IST news shocks generate a rise in output, investment, consumption, and

hours worked, explain 70% of their business cycle variation, and have played an

important role as drivers of U.S business cycles over the last sixty years. Before

proceeding, a brief discussion of the data is given. Then, section 3.2 presents the main

empirical results in detail followed by a sensitivity analysis section which will provide

evidence that the above results are robust. Finally, section 3.4 compares this paper to

previous work in the literature.

3.1 Data

Proper identification of IST news shocks requires an appropriate gauge of IST. I

follow GHK (1997, 2000), Fisher (2006), Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008), Beaudry

and Lucke (2009), and Liu (2011) and use a real investment price measure to gauge

IST. This price is measured as a consumption deflator divided by an investment

deflator. The consumption deflator corresponds to nondurable and service

consumption, derived directly from the National Income and Product Accounts

(NIPA). The investment deflator corresponds to equipment and software investment

and durable consumption, also derived directly from the NIPA. Some authors, such as

GHK (1997, 2000) and Fisher (2006), preferred to use Gordon’s (1990) price series

for producer durable equipment (henceforth the GCV deflator), as later updated by

Cummins and Violante (2002), so as to better account for quality changes. More

recently, Liu et al. (2011) used an updated GCV series constructed by Patrick Higgins

at the Atlanta Fed that spans the period 1959:Q1:2010:Q4. I prefer to use the NIPA

12

It is apparent that there is a relatively big downward bias at long horizons for the effect of the IST

news shock on IST, as manifested in the failure of the confidence bands to contain the true response.

Page 36: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

28

deflators since they allow for a larger sample size. Furthermore, as Justiniano et al.

(2010b) note, the NIPA deflators include quality adjustments that generate price

declines in accordance with other studies based on micro data (e.g. Landefeld and

Grimm, 2000). Nonetheless, it is shown in section 3.3 that the results are robust to the

use of the recently updated GCV deflator used by Liu et al. (2011).13

For the TFP series, I employ the real-time, quarterly series on total factor

productivity (TFP) for the U.S. business sector, adjusted for variations in factor

utilization - labor effort and capital’s workweek, constructed by Fernald (2009) and

available for downloading from his website. The utilization adjustment follows BFK

(2006).

The output measure used is the log of real GDP at a quarterly frequency. The

consumption series is the log of real non-durables and services. The hours series is log

of total hours worked in the non-farm business sector. These series are converted to

per capita terms by dividing by the civilian non-institutionalized population aged

sixteen and over. The output, investment, and consumption data are taken from the

BEA; hours and population data are taken from the BLS. The population series in raw

form is at a monthly frequency. It is converted to a quarterly frequency using the last

monthly observation of each quarter. The measure of inflation is the percentage

change in the CPI for all urban consumers. Use of alternative price indexes generates

similar results. The three month Treasury Bill is used as the measure of the interest

rate. Similar results obtain when the federal funds rate is used instead. I prefer to use

the former because it is a better gauge of the theoretical interest rate in standard

DSGE models where the time period is quarterly. The inflation and interest rates

series are at a monthly frequency. As with the population data, these series are

converted to a quarterly frequency by taking the last monthly observation from each

quarter. My benchmark data series span the period 1951:Q1-2010:Q4.14

13

I thank Patrick Higgins at the Atlanta Fed for providing me with this series. The reader is referred to

the appendix in Liu et al. (2011) for a description of the methods used to construct the series. 14

Similar results obtain when the entire postwar sample is used. Nevertheless, I prefer to start the

sample in 1951 due to the Treasury-Fed Accord announced on March 3, 1951which restored

independence to the Fed and therefore constituted a potentially important structural shift.

Page 37: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

29

3.2 Benchmark Results

Eight variables are included in the benchmark system: TFP, IST, nominal interest

rates, inflation, output, investment and durables, non-durables and services

consumption, and total hours worked. As a benchmark, the system is estimated as a

VAR in levels. This system is identical to the one that was used in section 2.2 for the

monte carlo simulations. The levels specification is preferred over a VECM because it

produces consistent estimates of the impulse responses while being robust to

cointegration of unknown form. In particular, it avoids making potentially invalid

assumptions concerning common trends which can yield misleading results (e.g.

Fisher (2010)). Furthermore, as was noted in section 2.2, the benchmark identification

method is also valid in the presence of unit roots. The Akaike, Hannan-Quinn

information and Schwartz criteria favor two lags, while the likelihood ratio test

statistic chooses eight lags. Given the large number of variables in the VAR, a middle

ground of four lags is chosen. Robustness to the levels specification and to alternative

lag lengths will be considered in section 3.3.

In terms of the identification strategy outlined in the previous section, the

truncation horizon is set at H=60. In words, then, the IST news shock is identified as

that shock orthogonal to current TFP and IST which maximally explains movements

in IST over a fifteen year horizon. As with lag length, robustness along this dimension

is discussed below.

Table 2.3 presents estimates of both unconditional and conditional correlations

between the growth rate of output and the growth rates of consumption, investment,

and hours. The conditional correlations estimates are based on the benchmark VAR

model and computed in accordance with Gali's (1999) formula where the conditioning

is made with respect to IST news shocks. These estimates can be used to infer the

extent of the capability of IST news shocks to generate business cycles. As the first

column of table 2.3 shows, the unconditional correlations, which are computed

directly from the data, are high, as expected, reflecting the well known feature of the

business cycle that output, consumption, investment, and hours move in tandem. As

Page 38: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

30

the second column of the table demonstrates, the conditional correlations of output

with consumption, investment, and hours are very high at 91%, 97%, and 94%,

respectively, all being statistically significant at the one percent level.15

That the

conditional correlations are at such high levels is an indication that IST news shocks

have the potential of generating business cycles.

Figure 2.3 shows the estimated impulse responses of IST, output, investment,

consumption, hours, and inflation to a favorable IST news shock from the benchmark

VAR, with the dashed lines representing 1st and 99

th percentile confidence bands.

These bands are constructed from a residual based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000

times. I use the Hall confidence interval (see Hall (1992)) which attains the nominal

confidence content at least asymptotically under general conditions and was also

shown to have relatively good small sample properties by Kilian (1999). Following a

favorable IST news shock, IST does not change on impact, by construction, after

which it grows gradually and persistently increasing by 1.34 percent after ten years

and eventually peaking after 27 years at 2.07 percent higher than its pre-shock value.

Output, investment, consumption, and hours all jump up on impact, with the

responses being both statistically and economically significant at 0.29, 0.27, and 0.26

percent for output, consumption, and hours, respectively, and 1.07 percent for

investment, after which they all keep growing where output, investment, and hours

reach their peak after six quarters while consumption peaks after thirteen years. The

significant positive conditional comovement among aggregate variables on impact is

compatible with IST news shocks being an important source of fluctuations.

Moreover, the identified IST news shock series significantly raises the three month T-

Bill rate with a lag of one period while it significantly reduces inflation on impact and

has an insignificant effect on TFP. The responses of inflation, interest rate, and real

macroeconomic aggregates are broadly consistent with the DSGE model presented in

the previous section. As the primary focus of this paper is the business cycle

15

The confidence bands (not shown) for the conditional correlation estimates were constructed from a

residual based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

Page 39: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

31

relevance of IST news shocks, the impulse responses of TFP and interest rates are

omitted.

Figure 2.4 depicts the share of the forecast error variance of several of the

variables in the VAR attributable to the IST news shock and unanticipated IST and

TFP shocks over a range of five years. IST news shocks account for 47 percent of the

forecast error variance share of IST at the five years horizon and 72 percent at the ten

year horizon (not shown). The IST news shock and the unanticipated IST innovation

combine to account for 91 percent or more of the forecast error variance of IST at

frequencies up to ten years. At the five year horizon, 91 percent of IST fluctuations

are explained by the two shocks. That such a small portion of IST remains

unexplained at both short and long horizons validates the assumption underlying

identification that most of the movements in IST can be attributed to only two shocks,

and suggests that the identification method has done a good job at identifying the IST

news shock.

IST news shocks account for a large share of the forecast error variance of

macroeconomic aggregates at business cycle frequencies. In particular, they explain

60 percent of output fluctuations at the one year horizon and 72 percent at the two

year horizon. IST news shocks account for 74 percent of consumption and hours

forecast error variance at the two year horizon, and 65 percent of investment forecast

error variance. Overall, the results indicate that IST news shocks are a substantial

source of the business cycle.

Figure 2.5 plots the time series of identified IST news shocks from the

benchmark VAR. The shaded areas represent recession dates as defined by the NBER.

So as to make the figure more readable, the one year moving average of the identified

shock series is shown as opposed to the actual series. Negative IST news shocks are

associated with nine of the last ten U.S recessions, the exception being the 1981-1982

recession.16

Furthermore, a series of positive IST news shocks is prevalent in the mid

16

Given that the average quarterly growth rate of IST in the sample period is 0.55%, it should be

emphasized that negative IST news shocks do not imply an expected decline in IST in the future but

rather that IST is expected to grow less than its steady state growth rate (i.e. 0.55%).

Page 40: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

32

to late 1990's confirming the view that the ten year long 1990's expansion was in part

induced by positive news about IST. The story that emerges from figure 2.5 is

consistent with the results from the historical decomposition discussed below which

indicate that IST news shocks were an important driver of U.S business cycles in the

last sixty years.

Table 2.4 shows the historical contribution of IST news shocks to the ten

NBER determined U.S recessions since 1951. In particular, for each recession the

contribution of IST news to the percentage change in output per capital from peak to

trough (in deviation from trend growth) is calculated. A 1.7% output per capita steady

state annual growth is assumed, which is consistent with the average growth rate of

output per capita over the sample. The results indicate that IST news were a driving

force behind nine of the last ten U.S recessions, where the only recession in which

IST news had no role was the 1981-1982 recession. The recent recession, in which

output loss was 7.8 percent, seems to have been driven in part by IST news shocks

which contributed 3.8 percent of that accumulated decline. IST news shocks also

contributed 1.6 percent and 5.1 percent of the accumulated 2.7 percent and 7.9 percent

output per capita loss during the 1990-1991 and 1973-1975 recessions, respectively.

Moreover, that 1.1 percent of the 1.5 percent output loss in the 2001 recession is

attributed to IST news shocks is consistent with the view that a downward revision of

expectations about future IST took place after the IST news driven boom of the mid to

late 1990's. One may be concerned that the above results for the recent recession and

some of the prior recessions (e.g. 1973-1975, 1980, 1990-1991) may be driven in part

by credit market shocks and oil price shocks, respectively. Robustness along this

dimension is discussed below in the next section where it is shown that these results,

as well as the other results in the paper, are not driven by oil shocks or financial

shocks. Overall, the historical decomposition results point to a central role of IST

news shocks as a driving force of the business cycle.

Figure 2.6 shows the impulse responses of aggregate variables to the

unanticipated IST shock. IST's response to its own innovation is large and significant

Page 41: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

33

on impact and also quite persistent. Output rises for the first three quarters following

the shock, after which it starts to decline. Investment rises significantly for the first

five quarters and then starts to fall though this negative response is insignificant.

Hours follow a similar pattern as investment whereas consumption falls significantly

on impact and thereafter as well. The negative response of consumption is consistent

with a modified version of the DSGE model of the previous section in which the cost

of utilization is specified in terms of forgone consumption as in Christiano et al.

(2005) (see Khan and Tsoukalas (2011)). Taken as a whole, the results indicate that

unanticipated IST shocks are not an important source of the business cycle, a finding

that may appear surprising in light of a growing recent literature arguing that this type

of shock represents an important driver of aggregate activity (e.g. Fisher (2006),

Justiniano et al. (2010a), and Khan and Tsoukalas (2010)). Nevertheless, Schmitt-

Groh'e and Uribe (2008) include the real price of investment as an observable in their

structural estimation procedure and find that unanticipated IST shocks have a

negligible role as drivers of the business cycle. They argue that, at least in the context

of structural DSGE models estimated using Bayesian methods, this discrepancy is

explained to a large extent by whether the set of observables used for estimation

includes or not the price of investment. Furthermore, Beaudry and Lucke (2009), who

combine short and long run restrictions in an SVECM framework, also find that

unanticipated IST shocks have a negligible role as business cycle drivers.

Given the stark contrast between the responses to unanticipated shocks

compared to IST news shocks, a brief discussion should be made on the normalization

of the shocks. In accordance with the SVAR literature, figures 3 and 6 present the

impulse responses to a one standard deviation unanticipated shock and one standard

deviation IST news shock, respectively. Hence, one may be concerned that once the

shocks are normalized such that their long term effect on IST is equalized, the

aforementioned contrast between the effects of the two shocks will be greatly

diminished. The IST news shock raises IST in the long run by nearly three times as

much than the unanticipated IST shock. However, even if one were to triple the

Page 42: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

34

effects of the unanticipated IST shock, IST news shocks would still have a bigger

effect on the other variables. For example, IST news shocks have a peak on output of

one percent whereas that of the unanticipated shock is two tenths of a percent.

Moreover, the latter effects go in opposite directions as the effect of IST news shocks

is positive whereas that of the unanticipated shock is negative. Hence, changing the

normalization will not change the main result of the paper regarding the business

cycle effects implications of IST news shocks as well as the stark contrast in the

responses to IST news shocks versus IST news shocks.

An additional concern regarding the results from figure 6 is that the Monte

Carlo simulations indicated that there is a bigger downward bias for the response of

output and consumption to unanticipated shocks compared to IST news shocks.

Hence, it may be the case that the true effect of unanticipated IST shocks on

consumption and output is underestimated more so than that of IST news shocks. It is,

however, apparent that the size by which the downward bias in the unanticipated

shock is larger than that in the news shocks is significantly smaller than the size by

which the estimated responses in figure 6 is smaller than those in figure 3. For

example, while the downward bias at the two year horizon for output in response to

the unanticipated shock is twice as much relative to that in response to the news

shock, the estimated response of output at the corresponding horizon to the news

shock is more than ten time as much than the estimated response to the unanticipated

shock. Hence, one can be fairly confident in the result that IST news shock have a

much bigger effect on the variables than unanticipated shocks.

Lastly, the impulse responses of aggregate variables to the unanticipated TFP

shock (not shown) indicate that positive TFP shocks generate an increase in output,

investment, and consumption and a decline in hours. These results are consistent with

the findings of Gali (1999) and BFK (2006) which indicate that TFP shocks are not

important drivers of business cycle fluctuations.

Page 43: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

35

3.3 Sensitivity Analysis

The main result that IST news shocks are an important force behind business cycles is

robust to alternative lag structures, different truncation horizons for the maximization

problem underlying identification, alternative real investment price measure, larger

systems containing additional variables as well as estimation of a VECM which

accounts for a potential long run relationship between non stationary variables in the

model.

At all tested lag lengths, output, investment, consumption and hours rise on

impact in response to a favorable IST news shock with the effect being similar both

qualitatively and quantitatively. With more lags in the reduced form system there is

more evidence of reversion in the series at long horizons, but the basic qualitative

nature of the responses is unchanged. The qualitative and quantitative nature of the

responses is also unaltered with different truncation horizons, both shorter ones such

as H=40 and longer ones such as H=80. The results are also similar across sub-

samples (e.g. estimating the VAR only post 1984). In the interest of space, these

figures are omitted from the paper.

The main results are also robust to using a different measure of the real

investment price. I estimated the benchmark system with the real price of investment

measured by the GCV deflator instead of the NIPA deflators, as used by Liu et al.

(2011). Figure 2.7 presents the impulse responses from this system. Both the

quantitative and qualitative nature of the results remains unchanged as IST news

shocks continue to induce business cycle comovement. Moreover, news shocks are

deflationary as in the benchmark case.

Robustness to the levels specification was also considered. While estimation

of a VAR in levels will in general produce consistent estimates of the impulse

responses and variance decomposition, estimation of a vector error correction model

(VECM) will result in an efficiency gain in finite samples if the non-stationary

variables in the VAR share a common stochastic trend. Nevertheless, as discussed in

Section 3.2, the levels specification is preferred because it produces consistent

Page 44: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

36

estimates of the impulse responses while being robust to cointegration of unknown

form. In particular, it avoids making potentially invalid assumptions concerning

common trends which can yield misleading results (e.g. Fisher (2010)). Impulse

responses from an estimated VECM (not shown) in which I allowed for two

cointegrating vectors between TFP, IST, consumption, output, and investment, while

imposing that interest rates, inflation, and hours are stationary, indicate that the effects

of IST news shocks are both quantitatively and qualitatively similar to the benchmark

results. Similar results also obtain when a different number of cointegrating vectors is

allowed for. The only difference lies in the estimated long-run responses, with more

evidence of reversion evident in the levels specification.

Furthermore, the IST news shock was also identified in a larger system. In

addition to the eight variables in the benchmark system, measures of stock prices and

consumer confidence were also included. The measure of stock prices used is the log

of the real S&P 500 Index, taken from Robert Shiller's website. This series is

converted to a quarterly frequency by taking the last monthly observation from each

quarter. The results are insensitive to dividing the stock price data by the population.

The consumer confidence data are from the Michigan Survey of Consumers, and

summarize responses to a forward-looking question concerning aggregate

expectations over a five year horizon. This series is available from 1960:Q1 hence

dictating 36 fewer observations compared to the benchmark sample. There are several

reasons for including these additional variables. Stock prices and consumer

confidence are naturally forward-looking, and previous research has shown them to be

prognostic of future movements in economic activity in general and TFP in particular

(e.g. Beaudry and Portier (2006) and Barsky and Sims (2010b)). Thus, it is reasonable

to presume that these variables also contain information about future IST. Moreover,

as stressed by Watson (1986), the inclusion of forward-looking variables mitigates the

impact of potential non-invertibilities even if these variables do not fully reveal the

missing state(s). Furthermore, it is of interest in and of itself to examine the responses

of these forward-looking variables to IST news shocks. Figure 2.8 depicts the

Page 45: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

37

responses of the six benchmark variables as well as stock prices and consumer

confidence to a favorable IST news shock. It is apparent that the main results are left

unchanged; favorable IST news shocks generate positive comovemnent and are

deflationary. Moreover, IST news shocks are associated with a significant positive

increase in both stock prices and consumer confidence, a finding which is consistent

with the view that these variables contain important information about the future

value of IST.

Finally, as noted in the previous section, it was also confirmed that the results

in the paper are not driven by either financial shocks originating in credit markets or

shocks to the real price of oil. In relation to the issue of a possible connection between

the identified IST news shocks and credit market shocks, it was found that the results

are robust to adding to the VAR a risk premium variable, measured by the spread

between the expected return on medium-grade bonds and high-grade bonds (Moody's

seasoned Baa corporate bond yield and Aaa corporate bond yield, respectively), and

imposing on the identified IST news shock to be orthogonal to the risk premium

innovation. This robustness is an indication that the results regarding IST news shocks

reported in section 3.2 are not driven by pure financial shocks that originate in the

financial system. Moreover, so as to verify that the results are not driven by oil

shocks, an extended identification procedure was also applied to larger systems

including the real price of oil where the identified IST news shock was imposed upon

to be orthogonal to oil innovations. The results obtained were similar to the

benchmark results, both qualitatively and quantitatively.

3.4 Relation with Previous Work

The robust evidence found in this paper that IST news shocks are important drivers of

business cycles contrasts with the mixed evidence provided by the relatively small

number of papers that estimated DSGE models which contain IST news shocks.

Given that there is no clear agreement on what the true structure of the economy is,

and that inferences regarding the role of IST news shocks based on different structural

models differ, it seems worthwhile to use an identification method that does not

Page 46: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

38

impose any structural model on the data but rather imposes identifying assumptions

that are common to different IST news driven DSGE models. This is precisely what is

done in this paper, thus offering new insights regarding the business cycle

implications of IST news shocks.

The results in this paper indicate that unanticipated IST shocks are not an

important source of the business cycle as opposed to IST news shocks. Fisher (2006)

identified unanticipated IST shocks in an SVAR framework with long run restrictions

and found that IST shocks are important drivers of the business cycle. Since his

identification procedure allows IST shocks to raise IST on impact while imposing that

they are the only shocks to affect IST in the long run, it really identifies a combination

of unanticipated IST shocks and IST news shocks, thus offering a potential

reconciliation with the results presented here. So as to further shed light on the

difference between my results and Fisher's, I applied both my identification method as

well as Fisher's using the same variables he used in his paper and found that the

correlations between my identified IST news shocks and unanticipated shocks and

Fisher's identified unanticipated IST shocks are 0.8 and 0.25, respectively. This

evidence indicates that Fisher's method identifies a combination of unanticipated IST

shocks and IST news shocks, though his identified shock is more strongly associated

with IST news shocks than unanticipated IST shocks.17

Even though there has not been an attempt in the literature to identify IST

news shocks along the lines of the identification approach presented in this paper,

Beaudry and Lucke (2009) employ a method that, at least to some extent, resembles

the one used in this paper. They use a combination of short and long run restrictions

in an SVECM framework for the identification of news shocks. In particular, in

systems featuring TFP, IST and other variables their identified news shock is

identified by postulating zero effects on both types of technology on impact, but

17

It's interesting to note that this result is sensitive to whether hours enter the VAR in levels, as in

Fisher's baseline specification, or in first differences in accordance with Fisher's alternative

specification. In particular, when hours enter the VAR in first differences the correlations between my

identified IST news shocks and unanticipated shocks and Fisher's identified IST shocks are 0.66 and

0.58, respectively.

Page 47: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

39

allowing for unrestricted long-run effects. Thus, under their identification scheme

news can be news about both TFP and IST. In contrast, the identification approach in

this paper is aimed at identifying specific news shocks, namely IST news shocks. In

fact, as was shown in section 2.2, my identification method performs well on data

generated from a DSGE model that contains both TFP and IST news shocks, in which

case the Beaudry and Lucke (2009) identification method would not be appropriate as

it does not impose any restriction on the type of news shocks being identified. In

particular, Schmitt-Grohé (2010) shows that their SVECM identification method fails

to identify both IST news shocks and TFP news shocks once the true model contains

both news shocks. Nevertheless, Beaudry and Lucke (2009) do report results in favor

of news shocks being an important driver of business cycle while interpreting their

identified news shock as TFP news because these shocks explain about 60% of TFP

forecast error variance in the long run.

From a methodological standpoint, even though the identification method used

in this paper builds on the one employed by Barsky and Sims (2010a), there is a

difference worth noting. In their work, the identified TFP news shock is orthogonal

only to the unanticipated TFP shock. I extend their identification method by imposing

upon the IST news shock to be orthogonal to both IST and TFP shocks thus enabling

me to identify both unanticipated IST and TFP shocks in addition to IST news shocks.

As was reported in section 2.2, adding TFP to the system and imposing the

corresponding orthogonality restriction improves the identification of IST news

shocks. Furthermore, that the identified IST news shock has an insignificant and

negligible effect on TFP confirms that the identified IST news shocks are not related

to TFP news shocks.

Lastly, while this paper has mainly focused on presenting empirical evidence

on the strong role of IST news shocks in the business cycle, it is also important to

comprehend the mechanism by which IST news drive the business cycle. As

Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009) show, endogenous capital utilization is an important

element that must be contained in standard DSGE models so that they are able to

Page 48: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

40

generate IST news shocks that are business cycle drivers. The empirical results of this

paper provide evidence in favor of the importance of the capital utilization channel for

transmitting the effect of IST news shocks on macroeconomic variables. Given a

capital share of 0.36, which is what is assumed in Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009) and

also in the theoretical model of section 2, the empirical result of this paper that output

rises on impact by 0.29 percent while hours do by 0.26 percent implies a rise in the

capital utilization rate of 0.34 percent, which is larger than all of the variables apart

from investment.18

In the theoretical model of section 2, capital utilization rises by

one percent, indicating the importance of the capital utilization channel in a

theoretical context as well, as was discussed in detail by Jaimovich and Rebelo

(2009). Overall, it can be deduced that an important mechanism at play here is the

capital utilization channel, which could provide valuable information for builders of

future DSGE models in constructing models that are capable of matching the results

of this paper.

4 Conclusion

This paper has closely examined the hypothesis that IST news shocks are important

drivers of business cycles. While the few papers that have examined the role of IST

news shocks employed fully specified estimated DSGE models to do so, this paper

used a different identification approach that does not impose a structural model on the

data but rather exploits identifying assumptions that are common to a variety of IST

news driven DSGE models. Specifically, I extended the empirical VAR based

approach to identifying news shocks that was recently proposed by Barsky and Sims

(2010a), which is directly based on the implications of theoretical models of

expectations driven business cycles, and showed that this approach performs well on

model generated data in terms of identifying IST news shocks and their business cycle

effects on macroeconomic aggregates.

18

This computation merely relies on the production function equation. Since hours rise by 0.26 percent

and their weight is 0.64 the remaining contribution to the change in output is 0.29-0.64*0.26=0.12.

Given that capital is a predetermined variable and hence does not change on impact, the change in the

capital utilization rate is 0.12/0.36=0.34.

Page 49: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

41

Applying this empirical procedure on postwar U.S data, I found robust

evidence that IST news shocks induce positive comovement, i.e., raise output,

consumption, investment, and hours of work, and explain 70% of their forecast error

variance at business cycle frequencies. Furthermore, the historical decomposition

results indicate that IST news played an important part in nine of the last ten U.S

recessions. Overall, it can be deduced that IST news shocks are not only capable of

generating business cycles but also that they have played an important role as drivers

of U.S business cycles over the last 50 years.

The empirical results of this paper with respect to IST news shocks are

broadly consistent with the state-of-the-art DSGE model presented in section 2.2,

which extends the by now classic Smets and Wouters (2007) model via the addition of

two elements, along the lines of Khan and Tsoukalas (2011): the recently popularized

Jaimovich and Rebelo preferences that allow for an arbitrarily weak wealth effect on

labor supply and specification of the cost of utilization in terms of increased

depreciation of capital, as originally proposed by GHH (1988) in a neoclassical

setting. Nevertheless, this model does not match the empirical results found by Barsky

and Sims (2010a) that TFP news shocks are associated with a contemporaneous

decline in output, investment, and hours and an increase in consumption thus

indicating an unimportant role for these shocks in the business cycle. Hence, it seems

interesting and important for future research to focus on formulating a DSGE model

that fits both Barsky and Sims' (2010a) results and this paper's results.

Page 50: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

42

References

Barsky, Robert, and Eric Sims. 2010a. Forthcoming. “News Shocks and Business

Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics.

Barsky, Robert, and Eric Sims. 2010b. Forthcoming. “Information, Animal Spirits,

and the Meaning of Innovations in Consumer Confidence.” American Economic

Review.

Basu, Susanto, John Fernald, and Miles Kimball. 2006 . “Are Technology

Improvements Contractionary?.” American Economic Review, 96(5): 1418-1448.

Beaudry, Paul, and Bernd Lucke. 2010. “Letting different views about business cycles

compete.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 24, ed. Daron Acemoglu,

Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 413 – 455. University of Chicago Press.

Beaudry, Paul, and Frank Portier. 2004 . “An Exploration into Pigou's Theory of

Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(6): 1183-1216.

Beaudry, Paul, and Frank Portier. 2006. “Stock prices, news and economic

fluctuations.” American Economic Review, 96(4): 1293-1307.

Blanchard, Olivier J., Jean-Paul L'Huillier, and Guido Lorenzoni. 2009. “News,

Noise, and Fluctuations: An Empirical Exploration.” NBER Working Paper 15015.

Chari, Varadarajan V., Patrick Kehoe, and Ellen McGrattan. 2008. “Are Structural

VARs with Long Run Restrictions Useful in Developing Business Cycle Theory?”

Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(8): 1337-1352.

Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans. 2005. “Nominal

rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy.” Journal of Political

Economy, 113(1): 1-45.

Coibion, Olivier, and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2007. “Strategic Interaction Among

Price-Setters in an Estimated DSGE Model.” Unpublished.

Cummins, Jason G., Giovanni L. Violante. 2002. “Investment-specific technical

change in the US (1947–2000): Measurement and macroeconomic consequences.”

Review of Economic Dynamics, 5(2): 243–284.

Davis, Joshua M. 2007. “News and the Term Structure in General Equilibrium.”

Unpublished.

Erceg, Christopher J., Luca Guerriei, and Christopher Gust. 2006. “SIGMA: A New

Open Economy Model for Policy Analysis.” International Journal of Central

Banking, 2(1): 1-50.

Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus, Juan Rubio-Ramirez, Thomas Sargent, and Mark

Watson. 2007. “ABCs (and Ds) for Understanding VARs.” American Economic

Review, 97(3): 1021-1026.

Page 51: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

43

Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus, and Juan Rubio-Ramirez. 2007. “How Structural are

Structural Parameters?” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 22, ed. Daron

Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 83 – 137. University of Chicago

Press.

Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus. 2009. “The Econometrics of DSGE Models.” NBER

Working Paper 14677.

Fernald, John., 2009. “A Quarterly Utilization-Adjusted Series on Total Factor

Productivity.” Unpublished.

Fisher, Jonas. 2006. “The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific shocks.”

Journal of Political Economy, 114(3): 413-451.

Fisher, Jonas. 2010. “Comment on: "Letting Different Views about Business Cycles

Compete".” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 24, ed. Daron Acemoglu,

Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 457 – 474. University of Chicago Press.

Francis, Neville, Michael Owyang, and Jennifer Roush. 2007. “A Flexible Finite

Horizon Identification of Technology Shocks.” Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank

of St. Louis.

Gali, Jordi. 1999. “Technology, employment and the business cycle: Do technology

shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?” American Economic Review, 89(1): 249-271.

Gordon, Robert J.1990. “The Measurement of Durable Goods Prices.” University of

Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Gregory W. Huffman. 1988. “Investment,

capacity utilization and the real business cycle.” American Economic Review, 78(3):

402-417.

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell. 1997. “Long-run implications of

investment-specific technical change.” American Economic Review, 87(3): 342-362.

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell. 2000. “The Role of Investment-

Specific Technological Change in the Business Cycle.” European Economic Review

44 (1): 91-115.

Hall, Peter. 1992. The Bootstrap and Edgeworth Expansion. Springer Series in

Statistics, Springer-Verlag.

Ireland, Peter N. 2004. “Technology Shocks and the New Keynesian Model.” Review

of Economics and Statistics, 86(4): 923-936.

Justiniano, Alejandro, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti. 2010a.

“Investment shocks and business cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 57(1):

132-145.

Page 52: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

44

Justiniano, Alejandro, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti. 2010b.

Forthcoming. “Investment Shocks and the Relative Price of Investment.” Review of

Economic Dynamics.

Khan, Hashmat, and John Tsoukalas. 2010. “The Quantitative Importance of News

Shocks in Estimated DSGE Models.” No. 09-07, Carleton Economic Papers, Carleton

University, Department of Economics.

Khan, Hashmat, and John Tsoukalas. 2011. “Investment Shocks and the Comovement

Problem.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 35(1): 115-130.

Kilian, Lutz. 1999. “Finite-Sample Properties of Percentile and Percentile-t Bootstrap

Confidence Intervals for Impulse Responses.” The Review of Economics and

Statistics, MIT Press, 81(4), 652-660.

King, Robert, Charles Plosser, and Sergio Rebelo. 1988. “Production, Growth and

Business Cycles: I. the Basic Neoclassical Model.” Journal of Monetary Economics,

21(2-3): 195-232.

Landefeld, Steven J., and Bruce T. Grimm. 2000. “A note on the impact of hedonics

and computers on real GDP.” Survey of Current Business, December.

Leeper, Eric M., Todd B. Walker, and Shu-Chun Susan Yang. 2009. “Fiscal foresight

and information flows.” NBER working paper No. 14630.

Leeper, Eric M., and Todd B. Walker. 2011. “Information flows and news driven

business cycles.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 14(1): 55-71.

Liu, Zheng, Daniel F. Waggoner, and Tao Zha. 2011. Forthcoming. “Sources of

Macroeconomic Fluctuations: A Regime-Switching DSGE Approach.” Quantitative

Economics.

Jaimovich Nir, and Sergio Rebelo. 2009. “Can news about the future drive the

business cycle?” The American Economic Review, 99(4): 1097-1118.

Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie, and Martin Uribe. 2008. “What's news in business cycle.”

Unpublished.

Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie. 2010. “Comment on "Letting Different Views about

Business Cycles Compete".” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 24, ed.

Daron Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 475-489. University of

Chicago Press.

Smets, Frank. and Raf Wouters. 2007. “Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A

Bayesian DSGE approach.” American Economic Review, 97(3): 586-606.

Uhlig, Harald., 2003.“What Drives GNP?” Unpublished.

Watson, Mark. 1986. “Vector autoregressions and cointegration.” In: Engle, R. and

McFad-den, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Econometrics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 2843-

2915.

Page 53: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

45

Table 2.1

The Variables and Equations of the Model

(a) The variables of the model; (b) the equations of the model

a)

L a b e l D e f in i t io n

O u tp u t

In v e s tm e n t

C o n s u m p tio n

H o u r s

In s ta l le d c a p i ta l

C a p i ta l s e r v ic e s

In f la t io n r a te

T o b in 's q

R e a l c a p i ta l r e n ta l r a te

N o m in a l r a te

U ti l i z a t io n r a te

P r ic e m a r k - u p

W a g e m a r k -u p

t

t

t

t

t

s

t

t

t

k

t

t

t

p

t

w

t

y

i

c

l

k

k

q

r

r

z

u

u

π

b)

t y t y ty = (1-i -g )c + i i + g

y tε (T.1)

1

t t t+1 1 t t 1 2 t t+1 t 2 t t+1 tc = E c + c (r - E + ) + c E (l - l ) + c (1 ) E (x - x ) b

t t lπ ε σ −+ + (T.2)

1

t t-1 t t+1 t1 2

1 1i = i + E i + (q + )

1c

c

is

t

σσ β ε

β ϕ−

γ + γ γ

(T.3)

*t t t t+1 t t+1 t t+1

* *

r (1 )q = (r -E + ) + E r + E q

r (1 ) r (1 )

kb k

t k k

δπ ε

δ δ−

−+ − + −

(T.4)

t ty = ( k + (1- )l + )s a

p t tφ α α ε (T.5)

t-1 tk = k + zs

t (T.6)

z (r )k

t t tqψ= − (T.7)

'

*t t-1 t

(1- ) (1- ) (1- )k = k + 1- i + 1- is

t t

Zz

δ δ δ δε

ν ν ν ν −

(T.8)

t t(k -l ) + p s a

t t tu wα ε= − (T.9)

1 1

t t-1 t t+11 1 1

(1- )(1 ) = + E -

1 1 (1 )(1 ( 1) )

c c

c c c

p p p p p

t

p p p p p p

u

σ σ

σ σ σ

ι β ι β ξ ξπ π π

β ι β ι β ι φ ε ξ

− −

− − −

γ γ −

+ γ + γ + γ + − (T.10)

Page 54: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

46

t t tr (k -l ) + wk s

t = − (T.11)

( )( )( )

(1 ) (1 ) (1 )( 1)/ 1 ( 1)/ ( 1)/

t * * *

(1 ) (1 ) (1 )( 1)/ 1 ( 1)/ ( 1)/

* * *

(1 ) (1 )( 1)/ 1 ( 1)/

* *

u = w (1 ) (1 )

(1 ) (1 )

(1 ) )

l l l

l l l

l l

w

t l l t

l t

t

L L L l

L L L x

L L c

σ σ σω ω ω ω ω ω

σ σ σω ω ω ω ω ω

σ σω ω ω ω

χω χω σ χω σ

χω χω χω σ

χω χω

+ + +− − − −

+ + +− − − −

+ +− − −

− − γ − γ + γ

+ − γ − γ + γ

− − γ γ

(T.12)

1

t t-1 t t+1 t t+1 t t-11 1 1 1

1

1

1 1 1 = + 1 (E +E )

1 1 1 1

(1- )(1 ) ((1 ) )(( 1) 1)

c

c c c c

c

c

w

w ww wt t

w w w

w w w

u

σ

σ σ σ σ

σ

σ

β ιπ π π

β β β β

β ξ ξε

β ξ φ ε

− − − −

+ γ− − + + γ + γ + γ + γ

γ −− +

+ γ − +

(T.13)

1 (1 )( ) r

t r t r t y t tr p r p yππ ε−= + − Θ +Θ ∆ + (T.14)

1 1

a a a a

t t t tgε ε η− −= + + (T.15)

1

a a a

t t tg g eκ −= + (T.16)

1

b b b

t b t tε ρ ε η−= + (T.17)

1

g g g

t g t tε ρ ε η−= + (T.18)

1 1

w w w w

t w t t w tε ρ ε η κ η− −= + − (T.19)

1 1

is is is is

t t t tgε ε η− −= + + (T.20)

1

is is is

t t tg g eκ −= +

(T.21)

Notes: This table presents the equations of the DSGE model of section 2.2. tx is an index

variable that makes preferences non-time-separable in consumption and hours worked (see

Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009)). The eight disturbances are: TFP unanticipated shocka

tε ; TFP

news shocka

te ; monetary policy shockr

tε ; preference shock b

tε ; government spending

shockg

tε ; wage mark-up shockw

tε ;IST unanticipated shockis

tε ; IST news shockis

te . In

particular, news processes 1

a

tg − and 1

is

tg − are stochastic drift terms that follow AR(1) processes

(T.16) and (T.21), respectively. Following Barsky and Sims (2010a, 2010b), the

corresponding i.i.d shocksa

te andis

te in (T.16) and (T.21) are defined as TFP and IST news

shocks as they portend future changes in TFP and IST, respectively.

Page 55: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

47

Table 2.2

Description of the Parameters of the Model and Benchmark

Values

L a b e l D e f in it io n B e n c h m a r k V a lu e

In v e r s e in te r te m p o r a l e la s t ic i ty 1

W e a lth e la s t ic i ty 0 .1

C a lv o w a g e s 0 .7

In v e r s e la b o r e la s t ic i ty 1 .8 3

C a lv o p r ic e s 0 .6 6

W a g e in d e x a t io n 0 .5 8

P r ic e in d e x a t io n 0 .2 4

C a p i t

c

w

l

p

w

p

σ

ωξσ

ξιι

ψ a l u t i l iz a tio n e la s t ic i ty 0 .1 5

F ix e d c o s t s h a r e 1 .2 5

S te a d y s ta te la b o r m a r k e t m a rk -u p 1 .2 5

G o o d s m a r k e t c u r v a tu r e 1 0

L a b o r m a r k e t c u r v a tu r e 1 0

M o n e ta r y P o l ic y ru le in f la t io n 4 .5

M o n e ta r y P o l ic y ru le

p

w

p

w

rp

π

φ

φεε

Θ

*

in f la t io n 0 .7 5

M o n e ta r y P o l ic y ru le o u tp u t g r o w th 1

In v e s tm e n t a d ju s tm e n t c o s t 5 .8 8

D e te r m in is t ic o u tp u t g r o w th 0 .0 0 6 3

D e te r m in is t ic c a p i ta l g r o w th 0 .0 0 9 2

D is c o u n t f a c to r 0 .9 8 5

L S te a d y s ta te h o u r s 0 .5 3

C a p

y

ϕγν

β

α

Θ

i ta l s h a r e 0 .3 6

R is k p r e m iu m p e r s is te n c e 0 .2 2

G o v e r n m e n t s p e n d in g p e r s is te n c e 0 .9

W a g e m a r k -u p p e r s is te n c e 0 .9

W a g e m a r k -u p M A 0 .9

N e w s s h o c k p e r s is te n c e 0 .8

T F P s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 .0 0 4 5

T F P

b

g

w

w

a

a

e

ρρρ

κκ

σσ n e w s s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 .0 0 0 9

R is k p re m iu m s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 .0 0 2 3

G o v e r n m e n t s p e n d in g s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 .0 0 0 1 6

M o n e ta ry p o l ic y s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 .0 0 2 3

IS T s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 .0 0

b

g

r

is

σσ

σσ 4 5

IS T n e w s s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 .0 0 1 9i s

Notes: This table presents a description of the parameters of the DSGE model of section 2.2

as well as their benchmark values.

Page 56: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

48

Table 2.3

Correlation Estimates

Unconditional Conditional

Output 1 1

Consumption 0.54 0.91

Investment 0.84 0.97

Hours 0.73 0.94

Notes: Table 3 reports estimates of both unconditional and conditional correlations between

the growth rate of output and the growth rates of consumption, investment, and hours. The

unconditional correlations are computed directly from the data whereas the conditional

correlations estimates are based upon the benchmark VAR model where it is assumed that

IST news shocks are the only shocks hitting the economy.

Page 57: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

49

Table 2.4

Historical Contribution of IST News Shocks to Output per

Capita Loss in U.S Recessions

Recession Percentage Change in

Output per Capita (deviation

from trend growth)

Contribution of IST News Shocks

1953:2-1954:2 -5.5 -1.9

1957:3-1958:2 -5.4 -1.9

1960:2-1961:1 -2.8 -1.2

1969:4-1970:4 -4.1 -1.2

1973:4-1975:1 -7.9 -5.1

1980:1-1980:3 -3.9 -1.4

1981:3-1982:4 -6.3 1.6

1990:3-1991:1 -2.7 -1.6

2001:1-2001:4 -1.5 -1.1

2007:4-2009:2 -7.8 -3.8

Notes: Table 4 reports estimates of the contribution of IST news shocks to each of the

recessions in my sample period. The first column presents the percentage change from peak to

trough of output per capita, relative to trend growth, in every recession. The second column

reports the contribution of IST news shocks, based on the benchmark VAR model, to the

corresponding output loss. A 1.7% output per capita annual trend growth is assumed, which is

consistent with the average growth rate of output per capita over the sample.

Page 58: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

50

Figure 2.1

Model and Monte Carlo Estimated Impulse Responses to IST

News Shock

The solid lines show the theoretical impulse response to an IST news shock from the model of

section 2.2. The dashed lines depict the average estimated impulse responses over 2000

Monte Carlo simulations, with the dotted lines representing the 10th and 90

th percentiles of the

distribution of estimated impulse responses.

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1IST

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

Model

Estimated

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.08

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0

0.02

0.04Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

int

De

via

tio

n

Page 59: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

51

Figure 2.2

Model and Monte Carlo Estimated Impulse Responses to

Unanticipated IST Shock

The solid lines show the theoretical impulse response to an unanticipated IST shock from the

model of section 2.2. The dashed lines depict the average estimated impulse responses over

2000 Monte Carlo simulations, with the dotted lines representing the 10th and 90

th percentiles

of the distribution of estimated impulse responses.

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8IST

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

Model

Estimated

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.5

0

0.5

1Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.5

0

0.5

1Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0

0.02Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

int

De

via

tio

n

Page 60: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

52

Figure 2.3

Empirical Impulse Responses to IST News Shock

The solid lines are the estimated impulse responses to the IST news shock from the

benchmark VAR. Dashed lines represent 1st and 99

th percentile Hall (1992) confidence bands

generated from a residual based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.5

1

1.5IST

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.5

1

1.5

2Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.5

1

1.5

2Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

1

2

3

4

5

6Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 61: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

53

Figure 2.4

Share of Forecast Error Variance Attributable to Identified

Shocks (IST News, Unanticipated IST and TFP)

The above bar diagrams show the share of forecast error variance of each variable attributable

to the identified IST news, unanticipated IST and unanticipated TFP shocks from the

benchmark VAR. As the identification pursued in the paper is a partial one, the sum of

relative contributions of all three shocks do not necessarily add up to one as there are

potentially additional unidentified shocks also accounting for part of the forecast error

variance.

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

IST

IST News

Unanticipated IST

Unanticipated TFP

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Output

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Consumption

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

rInvestment

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Hours

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Inflation

Page 62: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

54

Figure 2.5

Identified News Shock Time Series and U.S Recessions

Smoothed IST News Shock Series

This figure plots the time series of identified IST news shocks from the benchmark VAR. U.S

recession are represented by the shaded areas. So as to render the figure more readable, the

plotted data is smoothed using a one year moving average. Specifically, it is calculated

as 3 2 1( ) / 4s

t t t t tε ε ε ε ε− − −= + + + . The series begins in 1952:4 and ends in 2010:4.

Page 63: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

55

Figure 2.6

Empirical Impulse Responses to Unanticipated IST Shock

The solid lines are the estimated impulse responses to the unanticipated IST shock from the

benchmark VAR. Dashed lines represent 1st and 99

th percentile Hall (1992) confidence bands

generated from a residual based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2IST

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-1

-0.5

0

0.5Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-2

-1

0

1

2Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-1

-0.5

0

0.5Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 64: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

56

Figure 2.7

Empirical Impulse Responses to IST News Shock: Alternative

Investment Price Measure

The solid lines are the estimated impulse responses to the IST news shock from the

benchmark VAR with the real price of investment measured by the GCV deflator instead of

the NIPA deflators, as used in Liu et al. (2011). Dashed lines represent 1st and 99

th percentile

Hall (1992) confidence bands generated from a residual based bootstrap procedure repeated

2000 times.

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5IST

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.5

1

1.5

2Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.5

1

1.5

2Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

1

2

3

4

5

6Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 200

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 65: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

57

Figure 2.8

Empirical Impulse Responses to IST News Shock: Larger VAR

The solid lines are the estimated impulse responses to the IST news shock from a larger VAR

that includes stock prices and consumer confidence in addition to the eight benchmark

variables. The consumer confidence series starts in 1960:Q1, hence dictating 36 fewer

observations for the larger system compared to the benchmark system. Dashed lines represent

1st and 99

th percentile Hall (1992) confidence bands generated from a residual based bootstrap

procedure repeated 2000 times.

0 5 10 15 200

0.5

1

1.5

2IST

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 200

0.5

1

1.5

2Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 200

0.5

1

1.5

2Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 200

1

2

3

4

5

6Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 200

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 202

4

6

8

10

12Stock Prices

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 200

2

4

6

8

10

12Consumer Confidence

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 66: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

58

Chapter III

The External Finance Premium and Business

Cycles

1. Introduction

The recent financial crisis and great recession in the U.S have generated a new wave

of interest in research on the role of the external finance premium (EFP) in the

business cycle. The empirical literature on EFP has well established that credit

spreads, which proxy for the external finance premium, are valuable in predicting

economic growth (Stock and Watson (1989), Gertler and Lown (1999), Mueller

(2007), Gilchrist, Yankov and Zakrajsek (2009)). The DSGE literature has illustrated

that EFP is a central variable in the business cycle both in terms of propagating other

shocks (Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999; Henceforth BGG), De Graeve (2008),

Christensen and Dib (2008), and Queijo von Heideken (2008)) and in terms of

mirroring exogenous changes in credit supply (Gilchrist, Ortiz and Zakrajsek (2009;

Henceforth GOZ), Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2009; Henceforth CMR), and

Hirakata et.al (2010)). Nevertheless, it still unclear, at least empirically, which shocks

drive EFP and in turn, even more importantly, what is their role in the business cycle?

This paper tries to provide an answer to this question by providing robust evidence

that credit supply shocks are important drivers of EFP and have the potential of

generating business cycles. Specifically, the empirical findings suggest that these

shocks explain 87%, 77%, and 70% of EFP variation at the one year, two year, and

three year horizons, respectively, and generate business cycle comovement while

reducing inflation and interest rates. Even though these shocks are not the dominant

source of business cycle fluctuations on average, explaining 13% and 11% of the

business cycle variation in output and investment, respectively, 5% of that in

consumption and 23% of hours' business cycle variation, the historical decomposition

Page 67: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

59

results show that they have played a crucial part in the recent great recession. Namely,

periods in which large credit supply shocks are realized are likely to transform into

serious recessions.

Initially, I identify the demand shock that explains the most of the movements

in EFP via an extension of Uhlig's (2003) maximum forecast error variance (MFEV)

method. In particular, the identified demand shock is a shock which has no effect on

both neutral (TFP) and investment specific technology (IST) at all horizons and which

maximizes the sum of contributions to EFP forecast error variance over a finite

horizon. The impulse response functions (IRF's) for this shock lead me to interpret it

as a credit supply shock of the kind studied by GOZ (2009), CMR (2009), and

Hirakata et.al (2010).1 This interpretation is confirmed by presenting a New

Keynesian DSGE model with a financial accelerator in which credit supply shocks

generate IRF's that are consistent with the observed empirical responses to the

identified demand shock. Furthermore, following the recommendation of the recent

work by Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2008), which questioned the ability of VARs

to effectively identify shocks from DSGE models, I provide Monte Carlo simulation

results, based on such a model, which indicate that the identification method does a

good job of identifying credit supply shocks and their dynamic effects from model

generated data.

The identification approach taken in this paper is similar to the one pursued in

Uhlig (2003) and more recently in Kurmann and Otrok (2010). The former tried to

identify the shocks that drive real GNP while the latter aimed to identify the shocks

that drive the term premium. Both papers employed Uhlig's (2003) MFEV method to

identify the shocks and then tried to give them economic interpretation based on

1 CMR (2009) provided a structural interpretation of the credit supply shock in their model as a shock

that signifies an increase in the variance of idiosyncratic shocks affecting the firm’s profitability, which

aggravates the costly-state verification problem faced by entrepreneurs. They argue that this shock,

referred to as a 'risk shock', largely originates in the credit market in that it reflects changes in the

perceptions about borrowers' creditworthiness. In the BGG model, a credit supply shock may also

mirror an increase in the monitoring costs (i.e., a decline in recovery rates in the case of default).

Hirakata et.al (2010) introduce an additional risk shock which represents an increase in the variance of

idiosyncratic shocks affecting the profitability of the financial intermediary (FI) and find that the

effects of the two shocks are qualitatively similar, though the FI shock has a stronger effect.

Page 68: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

60

economic theory. I offer an extension of this method in that it is imposed that the

identified shock have no effect on TFP and IST, thus restricting it be a pure demand

shock, as opposed to the above two papers which placed no restrictions on the

identified shocks other than having them maximally explain a target variable's FEV.

Imposing these restrictions allows an identification of shocks that are orthogonal to

both unanticipated TFP and IST shocks and TFP and IST news shocks, which

separates this paper from the vast literature that studied the role of these shocks in the

business cycle.2

Moreover, as noted above, the demand shock identified in this paper explains

a considerable share of EFP, though this share declines with the time horizon from

87% at the one year horizon to 70% at the three year horizon. These shares are lower

than the ones obtained in Boivin et.al (2010), for instance, who employed factor

augmented VAR's (FAVAR) for the identification of credit supply shocks using

monthly data and recursive restrictions, where they exceed 90%. These differences

can be explained by the identifying restrictions that are imposed in order to identify a

pure demand shock.

The identification approach pursued in this paper might not be very useful if

there are many demand shocks that drive EFP of which no shock is truly dominant.

Nevertheless, under the null hypothesis that credit supply shocks are important drivers

of EFP, in relation to the other demand shocks in the economy, this identification

method will do a good job of identifying credit supply shocks and their dynamic

effects, as shown in sub section 4.4. In the theoretical model presented in sub section

4.1 credit supply shocks drive a considerable part of EFP fluctuations, though the

share declines with the time horizon from 99% at the two year horizon to 83% and

70% at the five year and ten year horizons, respectively. This is mainly due to an

2 For example, Gali (1999) and Basu, Fernald and Kimball (2006) studied unanticipated TFP shocks,

Greenwood, Hercowitz and Krusell (2000; Henceforth GHK), Fisher (2006), Justiniano et al. (2010a,

2010b), and Khan and Tsoukalas (2009) studied unanticipated IST shocks, Beaudry and Portier (2006),

Beaudry and Lucke (2009), and Barsky and Sims (2010) studied TFP news shocks, and Davis (2007),

Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008), Khan and Tsoukalas (2010) and Ben Zeev (2010) studied IST news

shocks.

Page 69: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

61

increasing share attributed to unanticipated TFP shocks. Overall, the main conclusion

of the monte carlo simulation evidence from sub-section 4.4 is that as long as credit

supply shocks drive a considerable share of EFP in relation to the other demand

shocks in the model, the proposed identification method will do a good job of

identifying credit supply shocks and their effects on macroeconomic variables.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section the

details of the empirical strategy are laid out. Section 3 presents the main empirical

evidence and provides a sensitivity analysis of the results. In section 4 I present a

DSGE model augmented with the financial accelerator ˋa la BGG (1999) in which

credit supply shocks generate impulse responses consistent with the observed

empirical responses obtained in section 3. Simulation evidence that the identification

procedure performs well on data generated from this model in terms of identifying

credit supply shocks and their dynamic effects is also provided. The final section

concludes.

2. Empirical Strategy

The identification method pursued in the paper is now presented in detail. Let ty be a

k x1 vector of observables of length T. One can form the reduced form moving

average representation in the levels of the observables either by estimating a

stationary vector error correction model (VECM) or an unrestricted VAR in levels:

ty B(L)ut =

(1)

Where L is the lag operator and0

B(L) B Lτττ

=

=∑ . Assume there exists a linear mapping

between innovations and structural shocks:

tu A tε= (2)

This implies the following structural moving average representation:

y C(L)t tε= (3)

Where C(L) B(L)A= and 1At tuε −= . The impact matrix A must satisfy 'AA = Σ ,

whereΣ is the variance-covariance matrix of innovations. However, there's an infinite

number of impact matrices that solve the system 'AA = Σ . In particular, for some

Page 70: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

62

arbitrary orthogonalization, A (e.g. a Choleski decomposition), the entire space of

permissible impact matrices can be written as AD , where D is a k x k orthonormal

matrix ( 'DD I= ).

The h step ahead forecast error is:

t+h t t+h t+h-

0

y -E y = B ADh

τ ττ

ε=∑ (4)

The contribution to the forecast error variance of variable i attributable to structural

shock j at horizon h is then:

'

' '

i,j , ,

0

(h) = B A A Bh

i iτ ττ

γγ=

Ω ∑ (5)

γ constitutes the jth column of D. Aγ is then a k x 1 vector corresponding with the jth

column of a possible orthogonalization and ,Bi τ represents the ith row of the matrix of

moving average coefficients at horizonτ . Let TFP and IST occupy the first and

second positions in the system, respectively. Without loss of generalization, let EFP

occupy the third position in the system. System (1) can now be written equivalently as

follows:

1 111 12

2 221 22

B(L) B(L)

B(L) B(L)

t t

t t

y u

y u

=

(6)

The group of variables 1y consists of TFP and IST while group 2y consists of

the rest of the variables. The shocks are partitioned in a corresponding manner. The

identified demand shock is identified as the shock that has no effect on TFP and IST

at all horizons and that maximally explains movements in EFP. In particular, this

shock is identified by finding theγ which maximizes the sum of contribution to the

forecast error variance of EFP at horizons from 0 to H subject to the restriction that

this shock has no effect on TFP and IST at all horizons. The latter restriction is

imposed via the constraint that 12( ) 0B L = , i.e. TFP and IST are assumed to be block-

exogenous with respect to the rest of the variables (see Hamilton (1994)), coupled

with the constraints that (1, ) 0 1, (2, ) 0 2A j j A j j= ∀ > = ∀ > , namely that TFP

and IST are also contemporaneously exogenous with respect to the rest of the

Page 71: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

63

variables. For the identification of the demand shock, I first apply maximum

likelihood estimation of the VAR under the assumption of block exogeneity of TFP

and IST to arrive at consistent estimates of ( )B L , as detailed in Hamilton (1994), after

which the following optimization problem is solved:

'* ' '

3,3 3, 3,

0 0 0

'

arg max ( ) B A A B

A(1, ) 0 1

A(2, ) 0 2

. (1,1) 0

(2,1) 0

1

H H h

h h

h

j j

j j

s t

τ ττ

γ γγ

γγγ γ

= = =

= Ω =

= ∀ >

= ∀ >

=

=

=

∑ ∑∑

H is some finite truncation horizon. The first four constraints impose that the

identified shock has no contemporaneous effect on TFP and IST. Note that the block

exogeneity restriction is already imposed through the B matrices in the objective

function. The fifth restriction that imposes onγ to have unit length ensures thatγ is a

column vector belonging to an orthonormal matrix. Following Uhlig (2003), this

maximization problem can be rewritten as a quadratic form in which the non-zero

portion of γ is the eigenvector associated with the maximum eigenvalue of the lower

(k-2) x (k-2) sub-matrix of the following matrix S:

( ) ( ) ( )'

3, 3,

0

1 B A B AH

S H τ ττ

τ=

= + −∑

Hence, this procedure constitutes an application of principle components.

Specifically, it identifies the demand shock as the first principal component of the

lower (k-3) x (k-3) sub-matrix of matrix S under the restriction of block exogeneity of

TFP and IST.3

3 Similarly, the second, third, etc. principle components determine the second, third, etc. most

important shocks in terms of explaining EFP FEV. Since these shocks explain a negligible amount of

EFP variation, I focus only on the first shock identified via the first principle component which

explains a considerable amount of EFP FEV.

Page 72: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

64

3 Empirical Evidence

In this section the main results of the paper are presented. It is found that the

identified demand shocks (Henceforth: EFP shocks) are associated with a decline in

output, investment, consumption and hours worked, explain 13% and 11% of the

business cycle variation in output and investment, respectively, 5% of that in

consumption and 23% of hours' variation, and have played an important role as

drivers of the recent recession. Before proceeding I begin with a brief discussion of

the data.

3.1 Data

Two critical data series needed to proceed are the IST and TFP series. These variables

need to be measured in an accurate manner so as to properly identify a pure demand

shock. I follow GHK (1997, 2000), Fisher (2006), Schmitt-Grohé and Uríbe (2008)

and Beadry and Lucke (2009) and use a real investment price measure to measure

IST. This price is measured as a consumption deflator divided by an investment

deflator. The consumption deflator corresponds to nondurable and service

consumption, derived directly from the National Income and Product Accounts

(NIPA). The investment deflator corresponds to equipment and software investment

and durable consumption, also derived directly from the NIPA. For the TFP series, I

employ the real-time, quarterly series on total factor productivity (TFP) for the U.S.

business sector, adjusted for variations in factor utilization - labor effort and capital’s

workweek, constructed by Fernald (2009). The utilization adjustment follows Basu,

Fernald, and Kimball (BFK, 2006).4

The external finance premium variable (EFP) is measured by the spread

between the yield to maturity on Moody's Baa bonds and 10 year government bonds.

The robustness of the results to using the Baa-Aaa spread is discussed in sub-section

3.3. I also include a measure of firms' leverage ratio gauged by total market value of

assets of nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business divided by their total market value

4 I downloaded the series from John Fernald's website.

Page 73: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

65

of net worth. The leverage ratio variable is added to the system being that it's a central

variable in the theory of financial frictions in macro models. Moreover, it will help to

give a structural interpretation of the identified shock. The output measure used is the

log of real GDP at a quarterly frequency. The consumption series is the log of real

non-durables and services. The hours series is total hours worked in the non-farm

business sector. These series are converted to per capita terms by dividing by the

civilian non-institutionalized population aged sixteen and over. The output,

investment, and consumption data are taken from the BEA; hours and population data

are taken from the BLS. The population series in raw form is at a monthly frequency.

It is converted to a quarterly frequency using the last monthly observation of each

quarter. The measure of inflation is the percentage change in the CPI for all urban

consumers. Use of alternative price indexes produces similar results. The three month

Treasury Bill is used as the measure of the interest rate. The inflation, EFP and

interest rates series are at a monthly frequency. As with the population data, these

series are converted to a quarterly frequency by taking the last monthly observation

from each quarter. The 10 year government bonds yield series is available from

1953:Q2; all other series begin in 1948. Hence, the benchmark data series span the

period 1953:Q2-2010:Q2.

3.2 Benchmark Results

Ten variables are included in the benchmark system: TFP, IST, EFP, leverage ratio,

interest rates, inflation, output, investment and durables, non-durables and services

consumption and total hours worked. As a benchmark, the system is estimated as a

VAR in levels. The levels specification is preferred to a VECM for three main

reasons. First, it produces consistent estimates of the impulse responses and is robust

to cointegration of unknown form.5 Second, the monte carlo simulation evidence from

section 4.4 confirmed that the levels specification continues to produce good

identification results in the presence of unit roots in TFP and IST. Third, invalid

5Standard unit root tests overwhelmingly fail to reject the hypotheses that TFP, IST, consumption,

investment and GDP are I(1); the tests are inconclusive for EFP, inflation, interest rates and hours.

Page 74: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

66

assumptions concerning common trends can yield misleading results (Fisher (2010)).

Nevertheless, the results are unchanged when a cointegrated VAR that accounts for

the long run relationship between the non stationary variables of the model is

estimated. The Hannan-Quinn information and Schwartz criteria favor two and one

lags, respectively, while the likelihood ratio test statistic chooses five lags. Given the

large number of variables in the VAR, a middle ground of two lags for each variable

is chosen. Robustness to the levels specification and to alternative lag lengths will be

considered in the next subsection.

In terms of the identification strategy outlined in the previous section, the

truncation horizon is set at H = 20. In words, then, the EFP shock is a shock that is

orthogonal to current TFP and IST and which maximally explains movements in EFP

over a five year horizon. A truncation horizon of five years is both long enough to

capture potential medium run forces and short enough to provide fairly reliable

results. As with lag length, Robustness along this dimension is discussed below.

Table 3.1 presents estimates of both unconditional and conditional correlations

between the growth rate of output and the growth rates of consumption, investment

and hours. The conditional correlations estimates are based on the benchmark VAR

model and computed in accordance with Gali's (1999) formula where the conditioning

is made with respect to the identified EFP shocks. These estimates can be used to

infer the extent of dominance of EFP shocks as business cycle drivers. As the first

column shows, the unconditional correlations, which are computed directly from the

data, are high, as expected, reflecting the well known feature of the business cycle

that output, consumption, investment and hours move in tandem. As the second

column demonstrates, the conditional correlations are very high exceeding 92% and

are statistically significant at the one percent level.6 That the conditional correlations

are at such high levels is an indication that EFP shocks have the potential of

generating business cycles.

6The confidence bands for the conditional correlation estimates were constructed from a residual based

bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

Page 75: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

67

Nevertheless, for the interpretation of the identified shock to be reliable,

comprehensive information with respect to the dynamic effects of the EFP shocks

needs to be examined. Figure 3.1 shows the estimated impulse responses of EFP,

leverage, output, investment, consumption, hours, interest rates and inflation to a

positive EFP shock from the benchmark VAR, with the dashed lines representing 5th

and 95th percentile confidence bands. These bands are constructed from a residual

based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times. I use the Hall confidence interval

(See Hall (1992)) which attains the nominal confidence content at least asymptotically

under general conditions and was also shown to have relatively good small sample

properties by Kilian (1999). Following the EFP shock, EFP jumps on impact and

stays higher for about two years prior to returning to its pre shock level. Leverage

increases for four years following the EFP after which it begins to decrease signifying

the beginning of a persistent deleveraging process.

Output, investment, consumption and hours all decline on impact, with the

responses being both statistically and economically significant, after which they all

keep declining where output, investment and hours reach their dip after one year

while consumption dips after four years. The conditional comovement among

aggregate variables on impact demonstrates that EFP shocks have the potential of

driving business cycles. Moreover, the EFP shock series is negatively and

significantly correlated with the three month T-Bill rate and inflation. The finding that

EFP shocks are deflationary while inducing an interest rate decline is consistent with

their characterization as demand shocks. Note that the fact that EFP shocks reduce

interest rates while decreasing economic activity helps to negate an interpretation of

the identified shock as a monetary policy shock. Moreover, it is straightforward to

negate an interpretation of EFP shocks as being related to oil shocks given that the

former are both contractionary and deflationary whereas oils shocks are

contractionary and inflationary.

The above IRF's can be also used to refute an interpretation of EFP shocks as

the net worth shocks recently studied by GOZ and CMR. The finding that the EFP

Page 76: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

68

shock first increases leverage for the first four years after which the deleveraging

process starts to take place is consistent with the GOZ findings with respect to adverse

credit supply shocks. In contrast, GOZ show that adverse net worth shocks are

associated with an immediate and persistent increase in leverage. These results are

also consistent with the DSGE model I present in section 4. Therefore, it is unlikely

that EFP shocks represent net worth shocks but rather embody credit supply shocks.

Figure 3.2 depicts the share of the forecast error variance of several of the

variables in the VAR attributable to the EFP shock and unanticipated IST and TFP

shocks over a range of five years. EFP shocks account for 87 percent of the forecast

error variance share of EFP at a horizon of one year and 65 percent at the five year

horizon. While IST shocks account for 9% of the variation in EFP on impact with this

share declining with the time horizon, TFP shocks explain less than 3% of EFP

variation at all time horizons. Therefore, even though TFP, IST and EFP shocks

explain at least 95 percent of EFP fluctuations from impact to the one year horizon,

15% and 21% of the variation are left unexplained at the two and three year horizons,

respectively. My identification method cannot explain which specific shocks are

responsible for these unexplained shares though it does indicate that that these shocks

are unrelated to both neutral and investment specific technology.

EFP shocks explain 13 percent of output fluctuations at the one year horizon

and 10 percent at the two year horizon while accounting for 11 and 5 percent of

investment and consumption forecast error variance at the one year horizon,

respectively. While the latter shares are quite small, EFP shocks seem to play a bigger

role as drivers of hours' fluctuations explaining 22% of the variation in hours at the

one year horizons. Nevertheless, these results indicate that EFP shocks are not a

substantial source of the business cycle though they have the potential of generating

business cycles.

Figure 3.3 plots the time series of identified EFP shocks from the benchmark

VAR. The shaded areas represent recession dates as defined by the NBER. So as to

make the figure more readable, the one year moving average of the identified shock

Page 77: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

69

series is shown as opposed to the actual series. Positive EFP shocks, representing

adverse credit supply shocks, are associated with the first three recessions, the 1982

recession, and the two recent recessions. Nevertheless, it is apparent that the biggest

role was played in the most recent recession. Furthermore, a series of negative EFP

shocks is prevalent in the mid 2000's to late 2007 just prior to the start of the recent

recession, confirming the view that a credit bubble may have been formed during

these years. Overall, the story that emerges from figure 3.3 is consistent with the

results from the historical decomposition discussed below; EFP shocks played a

relatively modest part as drivers of U.S business cycles in the last fifty five years,

apart from the recent recession in which they played a dominant part.

Table 3.2 shows the historical contribution of EFP shocks to the nine NBER

determined U.S recessions since 1954. In particular, for each recession the

contribution of EFP to the percentage change in output per capita from peak to trough

(in deviation from trend growth) is calculated.7 The results indicate that EFP shocks

contributed a modest portion of the 1957-1958 recession, 1960-1961 recession, 1969-

1970 recession, 1981-1982 recession, 2001 recession, while constituting a dominant

force behind the recent recession. This recession, in which output loss was 8.3

percent, seems to have been driven considerably by EFP shocks which contributed 4.7

percent of that accumulated decline.

3.3 Sensitivity Analysis

My main result that EFP shocks have the potential of generating business cycles is

robust to alternative lag structures, different truncation horizons for the maximization

problem underlying identification, estimation of a cointegrated VAR that accounts for

the long run relationship between the non stationary variables of the model, different

sample sizes, alternative measures of EFP, and a system that includes a measure of the

quantity of credit as opposed to the leverage ratio.

7 I assume a 2% output per capita steady state annual growth, which is consistent with the average

growth rate of output per capita over the sample.

Page 78: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

70

For space reasons, only three of the above robustness checks are reported here.

First, in light of the known argument that structural change occurred in the U.S

economy following Volcker's appointment as Fed chairman in 1979 and the great

moderation that started in 1984, the robustness of the results to using a sub-sample

starting in 1984 is confirmed. Figure 3.4 presents the IRF's to an EFP shock for this

sub-sample. It is apparent that the qualitative nature of the results is left unchanged

whereas all of the responses are significantly stronger quantitatively. This is

especially evident when looking at the variance decomposition results (not shown);

EFP shocks account for 40 percent and nearly 50 percent of output and hours business

cycle variation, respectively.

This interesting result could be explained by the period of significant financial

deregulation that commenced in the early 1980's up until the crisis of 2008. Note that

the latter crisis is not likely to be the driver of the strong sub sample results given that

the period of the crisis is included in both the large sample and the sub sample.

Nevertheless, it is outside the scope of this paper to directly test the hypothesis that

financial deregulation caused EFP shocks to be more important in the business cycle.

A structural model that explicitly models the aspect of financial regulation and its

impact on the model's behavior would be an interesting avenue of future research that

could address the financial regulation hypothesis in the context of my results.

Second, I examine the IRF's to an EFP shock replacing the benchmark EFP

measure with the Baa-Aaa spread. The latter measure is inferior to the benchmark

measure in that the Aaa yield does not represent the risk free rate as well as the ten

year government bond yield does. Nevertheless, it is worthwhile to test the robustness

of the results to this alteration. Figure 3.5 demonstrates that the overall qualitative

nature of the results is not changed when the Baa-Aaa variable is used as the measure

of EFP. The responses of the real variables are also quantitatively similar to the

benchmark ones. Nevertheless, the response of interest rates is significantly weaker.

The reason for this could be due to the Aaa yield not being an adequate measure of

the risk free rate as the ten year government yield.

Page 79: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

71

Third, one may be concerned that the shock being identified in this paper is

not a credit supply shock but rather a credit demand shock. So as to rule out this

conjecture, I applied my identification procedure in a VAR that replaced the leverage

ratio variable with a measure of debt gauged by total credit market instruments of

nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business, deflated by the GDP deflator. I added the

debt variable so as to be able to determine whether my identified shock constitutes a

credit supply shock or a credit demand shock, as a credit supply shocks should lower

the level of debt along with raising EFP. Figure 3.6 shows the results from the latter

exercise. It is apparent that the quantity of debt declines following the shock, a finding

which confirms that the identified shock cannot constitute a credit demand shcok but

rather a credit supply shock that raises the price of credit and lowers its quantity.

Moreover, it is also clear that the main result of the paper that EFP shocks have the

potential of generating business cycles is maintained as the latter continue to generate

business cycle comovement, reduce inflation, and raise interest rates.

Lastly, one might be worried that the identifying restriction that the identified

shock have no effect on TFP is too restrictive given the recent line of research that

argues that adverse credit supply shocks increase TFP via the destruction of the least

productive jobs (i.e. Petrosky-Nadeau (2011)). Thus, an identification procedure

where the latter identification restriction is relaxed was also employed. The results

from this identification procedure are nearly identical to the benchmark results.

Moreover, even though the response of TFP turn moderately positive after three

quarters, this effect is statistically insignificant. These results indicate that the

inference made based on the benchmark results is valid.

Overall, the results of this section indicate that the central result that EFP

shocks have the potential of driving business cycles is robust to various alterations of

the benchmark model, including changes in the specification of the empirical model

as well as changes in the maximization problem underlying identification.

Page 80: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

72

4 A DSGE model with a Financial Accelerator

This section presents a DSGE model augmented with the financial accelerator ˋa la

BGG (1999) in which credit supply shocks generate impulse responses consistent

with the observed empirical responses obtained in section 3. I also provide simulation

evidence that the identification procedure performs well on data generated from this

model in terms of identifying credit supply shocks and their dynamic effects.

4.1 Model

I consider the by now classic Smets and Wouters (2007) model augmented with three

elements: the financial accelerator mechanism via the BGG (1999) framework,

specification of the cost of utilization in terms of increased depreciation of capital, as

originally proposed by Greenwood et.al (1988) in a neoclassical setting8, and finally

the model also includes credit supply shocks and net worth shocks.9 I will now

present the model.

Each household [0,1]j∈ maximizes the utility function

1 1

0

0

1( ) exp(

1

1

c lct t t

t b lt

t c

C hC L

E

σ σσσ

β εσ

− +∞

=

− − +

∑ (7)

Where E0 denotes the expectation conditional on the information available at time

zero, 0 < β < 1, lσ > 1, χ > 0, Cσ > 0, b

tε is the preference shock, and h is the habit

formation parameter.

The budget constraint and the capital accumulation equation are given as

1 1( ) ( ) k

t t t t t t t tt t t

t t t t t t

B B W j L j R Z K DivC I T

R P P P P P

− −+ + − ≤ + + + (8)

[ ]1 1(1 ( )) 1 ( / )i

t t t t t t tK Z K S I I Iδ ε− −= − + − (9)

8 Traditionally, the cost of utilization is specified in terms of forgone consumption following

Christiano et al. (2005), who studied the effects of monetary policy shocks. I follow Khan and

Tsoukalas (2009) who use the capital depreciation specification and show that it has a superior fit with

the data relative to the Christiano et.al (2005) specification. This specification is also used in Jaimovich

and Rebelo (2009). Aside from this specification difference, the model here is identical in structure to

Gilchrist, Ortiz and Zakrajsek (2009). 9 TFP and IST news shocks are also included in the model so as to account for the potential importance

of these shocks.

Page 81: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

73

respectively, where tI is investment, is

tε is investment specific technology, tB are

nominal government bonds, tR is the gross nominal interest rate, tP is the price level,

tT is lump-sum taxes, Wt(j) is the nominal wage, k

tR is the rental rate on capital, tZ is

the utilization rate of capital, ( )tZδ is an increasing and convex function of the

utilization rate as in GHH (1988), and tDiv the dividends distributed to the

households from labor unions. The left hand side of (9) represents real expenditures at

time t net of taxes on consumption, investment, and bonds. The right hand side of (9)

indicates real receipts from wage income, earnings from supplying capital services net

of cost, and dividends. In (3), 1( / )t tS I I − is a convex investment adjustment cost

function. In the steady state it is assumed that S=S'=0, and S''>0. The aggregate

resource constraint is

t t t tC I G Y+ + = (10)

The first-order condition for optimal utilization of capital is given by the

following equation:

'( )k

tt t

t

RQ Z

Pδ= (11)

Where tQ is the price of physical capital in period t. The BGG framework focuses on

an entrepreneurial sector that borrows funds to purchase physical capital in period t at

price tQ , which it then operates in period t+1 and resells it at the end of period t+1 at

price 1tQ + . Therefore, the demand for capital by entrepreneurs is determined by

maximizing entrepreneurs' profit in period t+1 given that their cost of external

financing is 1

k

t tE R + . The BGG framework assumes a costly-state verification problem

between entrepreneurs and risk neutral financial intermediaries where the latter need

to pay monitoring costs in order to observe entrepreneurs' realized income in case of

default. BGG show the optimal debt contract in this framework implies the following

equation:

1 1

1

k

t t tt

t t

R Q KE s

R N

+ +

+

=

(12)

Page 82: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

74

Where s is an increasing function in the leverage ratio and tN is the net worth of the

entrepreneur. Lastly, BGG assume that entrepreneurs are long lived but discount the

future more heavily than households, thus implying that entrepreneurial net worth

depends on past net worth and on the return on capital relative to the expected return,

as described in log-linear form equation (T.16).

All of the equilibrium conditions of the model log-linearized about the

balanced growth path, along with the definition of the variables, are presented in table

3.3. Labels, definitions and benchmark values of the parameters are in Table 4. The

means by which these values were derived are described in the next subsection.

Equation (T.1) is the aggregate resource constraint; Eq. (T.2) is the Euler

equation for consumption; Eq. (T.3) is the Euler equation for investment derived from

solving the optimal quantity of investment supplied on the part of capital producers;

Eq.(T.4) describes the dynamics of Tobin’s q as derived from solving the optimal

quantity of capital demanded by entrepreneurs; Eq.(T.5) is the aggregate production

function; Capital services used in production by entrepreneurs are a function of capital

installed in the previous period and capital utilization, as described by eq. (T.6); Eq.

(T.7) expresses the optimal capital utilization rate as a function of the value of capital

and the marginal product of capital, as derived from log linearization of the first order

condition of entrepreneurial profit with respect to capital utilization rate; Eq. (T.8) is

the capital accumulation equation; The price mark up is defined by Eq. (T.9);

Inflation dynamics are described by the New-Keynesian Phillips curve in Eq. (T.10);

Combining the production function (T.5) with the log linearized first order condition

of entrepreneurs' profit with respect to labor implies that the capital-labor ratio is

inversely related to the marginal product of capital and positively related to the wage

rate, as described by eq. (T.11); The wage markup is given by Eq. (T.12); The wage

inflation dynamics are described by Eq. (T.13); Eq. (T.14) describes the monetary

policy rule;10 Eq. (T.15) represents the credit supply equation where the external

10 This rule was used by a number of recent papers (for example, Barsky and Sims (2008), Coibion and

Gorodnichenko (2007), Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2007), Erceg, Guerriei, and Gust

(2006), and Ireland (2004), and it postulates that the central bank sets nominal interest rates according

Page 83: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

75

finance premium, 1

k

t t tE r r+ − , is a function of entrepreneurs leverage ratio and the

credit supply shock;11

Lastly, Eq. (T.16) depicts the evolution of net worth of

entrepreneurs.

4.2 Estimation

Following Kurmann and Otrok (2010), the parameters are partitioned into two groups.

The first group includes parameters that are calibrated in accordance with the DSGE

literature while the second group of parameters is estimated by minimizing a weighted

distance between the model-implied IRFs to a credit supply shock and the empirical

counterparts from the VAR. This estimation method was used by Christiano et.al

(2005) in the context of monetary policy shocks and more recently by Kurmann and

Otrok (2010) in the context of TFP news shocks. In particular, denote by Ψ

a vector

of empirical IRFs to a credit supply shock attained from a VAR. Likewise, denote by

( )Ψ Φ the same vector of IRFs implied by the model, where Φ contains all the

structural parameters of the model. The estimator for the second group of

2Φ ⊆ Φ parameters is:

2

12 2 2arg min ( ( )) ' ( ( ))−

ΦΦ = Ψ −Ψ Φ Ω Ψ −Ψ Φ

Where Ω is a diagonal matrix with the sample variances of 2Φ along the diagonal

and the first 40 elements of each impulse response function are included. This

estimation approach is used to study whether a theoretical model that incorporates the

financial accelerator mechanism and credit supply shocks is capable of generating

IRFs that resemble the empirical counterparts which were interpreted as credit supply

shocks based on their dynamic effects on variables such as EFP, leverage, inflation,

interest rates and macroeconomic aggregates such as output, investment,

consumption, and hours.

to a partial adjustment mechanism where the interest rate in any period is equal to a convex

combination of the lagged interest rate and the central bank’s target rate, where the target rate is

adjusted in response to deviations of output growth and inflation from constant targets. For simplicity, I

assume the targets are equal to the steady state values of output growth and inflation. 11

This shock can be interpreted as an exogenous change in the variance of idiosyncratic shocks that

affect entrepreneurs' profitability. Hence, it is essentially a shock which originates in the credit market

as it reflects changes in the perception about borrowers' creditworthiness on the part of the financial

intermediaries.

Page 84: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

76

Table 3.4 presents the values for the calibrated parameters followed by the values of

the estimated parameters. The benchmark value of the discount factor is set in

accordance with Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009). The leverage ratio value corresponds

to the average leverage ratio in the U.S. nonfinancial corporate sector over our sample

period, as demonstrated in GOZ, the value of the survival rate of entrepreneurs

follows BGG, and the value for the standard deviation of the net worth shock follows

CMR. The values for the news persistence parameters follow Barsky and Sims (2009)

while the standard deviation of the news shocks is set in accordance with Khan and

Tsoukalas (2010). All remaining calibrated parameters' values by and large follow the

estimates of Smets and Wouters (2007).12

Overall, the point estimates of the estimated parameters do not deviate to a

large extent from the ones obtained in the DSGE literature. The estimate of the

inverse intertemporal elasticity is 0.98, compared to a mean estimate of 0.95 in GOZ.

Moreover, the wage and price rigidity parameter constrained estimates are 0.75 and

0.5 compared to 0.74 and 0.77, respectively, in GOZ.13

The monetary policy rule

smoothing and inflation parameters estimates are consistent with the empirical

estimates of Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2007), Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-

Ramirez (2007), Erceg, Guerriei, and Gust (2006), and Ireland (2004), while the

output growth parameter is very low. The elasticity of the external finance premium

with respect to the leverage ratio (0.027) is in between the GOZ estimate and the

Christensen and Dib (2008) estimate. Lastly, the capital utilization elasticity

parameter estimate is higher than the one estimated in Khan and Tsoukalas (2011) and

assumed in Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009) while the inverse of the labor supply

elasticity parameter is 2.3, consistent with the Smets and Wouters (2007) estimate of

2.4.

12

The empirical results in Ben Zeev (2010) indicate that the unanticipated IST shock is very persistent.

Therefore, I calibrate its persistence parameter to be equal to the 95th

percentile of the posterior

distribution of the AR(1) parameter for the IST process as estimated in Smets and Wouters (2007). 13

When necessary, I constrained the parameter values to avoid getting estimates which seemed to high

or low relative to the DSGE literatue. For instance, the wage and price rigidity parameters'

unconstrained estimates were too high at nearly one.

Page 85: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

77

4.3 Results

Figure 3.6 depicts the model IRFs to credit supply shocks along with the empirical

IRFs from the VAR and their bootstrapped 90% confidence intervals. Overall, the

model does fairly well in generating responses that are similar both qualitatively and

quantitatively to the empirical counterparts. Nevertheless, the model's major failure,

in quantitative terms, is in replicating the strong empirical response of interest rates

while its major failure in qualitative terms is replicating the hump shaped response of

hours. These two failures seem to manifest a shortcoming of the model and a need for

a richer model that is capable of generating a stronger decline in interest rates and a

hump shaped response of hours and consumption. Nonetheless, in accordance with

the empirical responses, the credit supply shock generates both a decline in interest

rates and hours.

There are two additional discrepancies related to the qualitative nature of the

response of leverage and consumption. The model delivers an immediate jump in

leverage in contrast to a hump shaped increase following the empirical EFP shock.

Nevertheless, the model successfully delivers a decrease in leverage following the

initial increase. Furthermore, consumption starts to exhibit a hump shaped response

only a year after the shock, whereas the empirical response is hump shaped from the

initial period. Nonetheless, this response is negative in accordance with its empirical

counterpart.

The model does a good job of generating the hump shaped response of output

and investment as well as the negative deflationary effect. The credit supply shock

behaves like a pure demand shock in that it reduces both economic activity and

inflation. Moreover, it causes a decline the risk free rate while increasing the external

finance premium. One can use the response of leverage to differentiate between credit

supply shocks and net worth shocks. Aforementioned, similarly to the empirical shock

identified in the previous section, the adverse credit supply shock initially increases

leverage after which it starts decreasing leverage. This contrasts with adverse net

worth shocks (not shown) which generate a persistent increase in leverage. These

Page 86: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

78

results were also reported by GOZ and are supportive of the interpretation of the

identified shock from the previous section as a credit supply shock.

4.4 Simulation Evidence

I simulate 2000 sets of data with 229 observations each, drawing all ten exogenous

shocks from normal distributions. So as to make the simulated data as close as

possible to actual data, the simulated series are transformed by adding back in trend

growth where applicable.14

For each simulation, I estimate a two-lag VAR with a

constant that includes the levels of TFP, IST, EFP, leverage, output, investment,

consumption, hours, nominal interest rate and inflation, which coincides with the

benchmark empirical VAR in Section 3. The truncation horizon is set at H = 20. In

other words, I identify the credit supply shock as that shock orthogonal to current TFP

and IST which maximally explains EFP over a horizon of five years. I follow the

identification procedure outlined in section 2 and collect the estimated impulse

responses and identified time series of credit supply shocks for each simulation.

Figure 3.7 depicts both theoretical and estimated impulse responses averaged

over the simulations to a credit supply shock. The theoretical responses are

represented by the solid lines and the average estimated responses over the

simulations are depicted by the dashed lines, with the dotted lines depicting the 5th

and 95th percentiles of the distribution of estimated impulse responses. It is apparent

that the estimated empirical impulse responses are roughly unbiased on impact and for

a number of quarters thereafter. While the estimated impulse responses are

moderately downward biased at longer horizons, the estimated dynamics are fairly

close to the true dynamics at all horizons.

The average and median correlation between the identified credit supply shock

and the true credit supply shock across simulations is 0.93, with the 5th and 95th

percentile correlations 0.89 and 0.96, respectively. The results improve even further

as the size of the simulated samples becomes arbitrarily large. While small biases still

14

Following Fernandez-Villaverde (2009), quarterly trend growth rates of 0.28% and 0.34% are added

to TFP and IST, respectively, and in accordance with the balanced growth path 0.63% is added to

output, investment and consumption.

Page 87: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

79

persist in large samples, the estimated impulse responses to credit supply shocks are

extremely close to the true responses at all horizons and the correlation between the

identified and true shocks exceeds 0.95.

The suitability of the identification strategy appears quite robust to alternative

calibrations of the model as well as to differences in the truncation horizon parameter

H and number of lags in the VAR. Nevertheless, in terms of the calibration of the

model, the method does perform better when there is more variation in EFP directly

attributable to the credit supply shock. The benchmark parameter values imply that

credit supply shocks drive a considerable part of EFP fluctuations, though the share

declines with the time horizon from 99% at the two year horizon to 88% and 78% at

the five year and ten year horizons, respectively. This is mainly due to an increasing

share attributed to unanticipated TFP shocks.

I also confirmed the superiority of the identification method with respect to the

original Uhlig (2003) procedure by relaxing the two identifying restrictions imposing

on the identified shock to have no effect on both and TFP and IST. The accuracy of

identification, as measured by the length of the IRF's confidence interval, is

considerably better for the benchmark identification method. For instance, the 90%

confidence interval at business cycle frequencies for the output IRF's under Uhlig's

original procedure is 73% and 94% wider than the benchmark case at the first and

second quarter horizons, respectively, after which it is more than twice as wide.

Overall, the main conclusion of this sub-section is that as long as credit supply

shocks drive a considerable share of EFP in relation to the other demand shocks in the

model, the proposed identification method will do a good job of identifying credit

supply shocks and their effects on macroeconomic variables. Furthermore, adding the

exogeneity restrictions of TFP and IST with respect to the identified shock results in a

significantly more accurate identification.

Page 88: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

80

5 Conclusion

This paper extends Uhlig's (2003) method for the identification of a shock that has no

effect on both neutral and investment specific technology and explains the most of

EFP variation over a horizon of ten years. This shock is found to generate business

cycle comovement while increasing EFP and reducing inflation and interest rates.

Even though it does not explain a significant amount of the business cycle variation of

output, the historical decomposition results indicate that it has played a non negligible

role in six of the last nine U.S recessions.

The empirical IRF's lead me to interpret the identified shock as a credit supply

shock. In particular, it is shown that credit supply shocks from a New Keynesian

DSGE model with a financial accelerator can generate theoretical IRF's which are

consistent with the observed empirical IRF's. Furthermore, monte carlo simulation

results indicate that the identification method used in this paper is capable of

identifying credit supply shocks and their effects on macroeconomic variables from

model generated data.

Hence, the results of the paper can be used to infer that credit supply shocks

have the potential of generating business cycles. The results also confirm the view

that these shocks played an especially important role in the most recent recession.

Even though these shocks may not constitute a substantial source of business cycles

on average, particular periods in which large credit supply shocks hit the economy are

likely to transform into serious recessions.

Page 89: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

81

References

Barsky, Robert, and Eric Sims. 2008. Information, Animal Spirits, and the Meaning of

Innovations in Consumer Confidence. Unpublished.

Barsky, Robert, and Eric Sims. 2009. News Shocks, NBER-WP 15312.

Basu, Susanto, John Fernald, and Miles Kimball. 2006 . “Are Technology

Improvements Contractionary?.” American Economic Review, 96(5): 1418-1448.

Beaudry, Paul, and Bernd Lucke. 2010. “Letting different views about business cycles

compete.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 24, ed. Daron Acemoglu,

Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 413 – 455. University of Chicago Press.

Beaudry, Paul, and Frank Portier. 2006. “Stock prices, news and economic

fluctuations.” American Economic Review, 96(4): 1293-1307.

Ben Zeev, Nadav. 2011. “News Shocks about future Investment Specific Technology

and Business Cycles.” Unpublished.

Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist. 1999. “The financial

accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework.” In: Taylor, J.B., Woodford,

M. (Eds.), The Handbook of Macroeconomics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1341–1393.

Boivin, J., Gianonni, M. and Stevanovic, D. (2009). Dynamic effects of credit shocks

in a data-rich environment. Unpublished.

Chari, Varadarajan V., Patrick Kehoe, and Ellen McGrattan. 2008. “Are Structural

VARs with Long Run Restrictions Useful in Developing Business Cycle Theory?”

Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(8): 1337-1352.

Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans. 2005. “Nominal

rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy.” Journal of Political

Economy, 113(1): 1-45.

Christiano, Lawrence, Roberto Motto, and Massimo Rostagno. 2009. “Financial

Factors in Economic Fluctuations.” Unpublished.

Christensen, Ian, and Ali Dib. 2008. “The Financial Accelerator in an Estimated New

Keynesian Model.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11(1), 155-178.

Coibion, Olivier, and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2007. “Strategic Interaction Among

Price-Setters in an Estimated DSGE Model.” Unpublished.

Davis, Joshua M. 2007. “News and the Term Structure in General Equilibrium.”

Unpublished.

De Graeve, Ferre. 2008. “The External Finance Premium and the Macroeconomy:

U.S. Post-WWII Evidence.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32(11):

3415–3440.

Page 90: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

82

Erceg, Christopher J., Luca Guerriei, and Christopher Gust. 2006. “SIGMA: A New

Open Economy Model for Policy Analysis.” International Journal of Central

Banking, 2(1): 1-50.

Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus, and Juan Rubio-Ramirez. 2007. “How Structural are

Structural Parameters?” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 22, ed. Daron

Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 83 – 137. University of Chicago

Press.

Fernández-Villaverde, Jesus. 2010. “The econometrics of DSGE models.”

International Review of Economics, Springer, 1(1): 3-49.

Fernald, John., 2009. “A Quarterly Utilization-Adjusted Series on Total Factor

Productivity.” Unpublished.

Fisher, Jonas. 2006. “The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific shocks.”

Journal of Political Economy, 114(3): 413-451.

Fisher, Jonas. 2010. “Comment on: "Letting Different Views about Business Cycles

Compete".” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 24, ed. Daron Acemoglu,

Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 457 – 474. University of Chicago Press.

Francis, Neville, Michael Owyang, and Jennifer Roush. 2007. “A Flexible Finite

Horizon Identification of Technology Shocks.” Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank

of St. Louis.

Gali, Jordi. 1999. “Technology, employment and the business cycle: Do technology

shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?” American Economic Review, 89(1): 249-271.

Gertler, Mark, and Cara S. Lown. 1999. “The information in the high-yield bond

spread for the business cycle: evidence and some implications.” Oxford Review of

Economic Policy 15(3): 132–150.

Gilchrist, Simon, Albero Ortiz, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2009. “Credit Risk and the

Macroeconomy: Evidence from an Estimated DSGE Model.” Unpublished.

Gilchrist, Simon, Albero Ortiz, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2009. “Credit Market Shocks and

Economic Fluctuations: Evidence from Corporate Bond and Stock Markets.” Journal

of Monetary Economics 56(4): 471–493.

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Gregory W. Huffman. 1988. “Investment,

capacity utilization and the real business cycle.” American Economic Review, 78(3):

402-417.

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell. 1997. “Long-run implications of

investment-specific technical change.” American Economic Review, 87(3): 342-362.

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell. 2000. “The Role of Investment-

Specific Technological Change in the Business Cycle.” European Economic Review

44 (1): 91-115.

Page 91: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

83

Hall, Peter. 1992. The Bootstrap and Edgeworth Expansion. Springer Series in

Statistics, Springer-Verlag.

Hirakata, Naohisa, Nao Sudo, and Kozo Ueda. 2009. “Chained Credit Contracts and

Financial Accelerators.” IMES Discussion Paper Series 09-E-30, Institute for

Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan.

Ireland, Peter N. 2004. “Technology Shocks and the New Keynesian Model.” Review

of Economics and Statistics, 86(4): 923-936.

Jaimovich Nir, and Sergio Rebelo. 2009. “Can news about the future drive the

business cycle?” The American Economic Review, 99(4): 1097-1118.

Justiniano, Alejandro, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti. 2010a.

“Investment shocks and business cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 57(1):

132-145.

Justiniano, Alejandro, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti. 2010b.

Forthcoming. “Investment Shocks and the Relative Price of Investment.” Review of

Economic Dynamics.

Khan, Hashmat, and John Tsoukalas. 2010. “The Quantitative Importance of News

Shocks in Estimated DSGE Models.” No. 09-07, Carleton Economic Papers, Carleton

University, Department of Economics.

Khan, Hashmat, and John Tsoukalas. 2011. “Investment Shocks and the Comovement

Problem.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 35(1): 115-130.

Kilian, Lutz. 1999. “Finite-Sample Properties of Percentile and Percentile-t Bootstrap

Confidence Intervals for Impulse Responses.” The Review of Economics and

Statistics, MIT Press, 81(4), 652-660.

Kurmann, Andre, and Chris Otrok. 2010. “News Shocks and the Slope of the Term

Structure of Interest Rates.” Unpublished.

Petrosky-Nadeau, Nicolas. 2011. “TFP during a Credit Crunch.” Unpublished.

Queijo von Heideken, Virginia. 2008. “How Important are Financial Frictions in the

U.S. and the Euro Area?.” Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper No. 223.

Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie, and Martin Uribe. 2008. “What's news in business cycle.”

Unpublished.

Sims, Eric. 2009. “Expectations driven business cycles: an empirical evaluation.”

Unpublished.

Smets, Frank. and Raf Wouters. 2007. “Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A

Bayesian DSGE approach.” American Economic Review, 97(3): 586-606.

Uhlig, Harald. 2003.“What Drives GNP?” .Unpublished.

Page 92: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

84

Table 3.1

Correlation Estimates

Unconditional Conditional

Output 1 1

Consumption 0.56 0.97

Investment 0.87 0.92

Hours 0.74 0.94

Notes: Panel A in table 3 reports estimates of both unconditional and conditional correlations

between the growth rate of output and the growth rates of consumption, investment and hours.

Panel B reports estimates of both unconditional and conditional correlations between the

growth rate of leverage and the first difference of the external finance premium. The

unconditional correlations are computed directly from the data whereas the conditional

correlations estimates are based upon the benchmark VAR model assuming EFP shocks are

the only shocks present in the economy.

Page 93: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

85

Table 3.2

Historical contribution of EFP shocks to Output per Capita loss

in U.S Recessions

Recession Percentage Change in

Output per Capita (deviation

from trend growth)

Contribution of EFP Shocks

1957:3-1958:2 -5.7 -0.8

1960:2-1961:1 -3 -0.2

1969:4-1970:4 -4.4 -0.6

1973:4-1975:1 -8.2 0.1

1980:1-1980:3 -4 -0.1

1981:3-1982:4 -6.7 -1

1990:3-1991:1 -2.8 0.1

2001:1-2001:4 -1.7 -0.3

2007:4-2009:2 -8.3 -4.7

Notes: Table 4 reports estimates of the contribution of credit supply shocks to each of the

recessions in my sample period. The first column presents the percentage change from peak to

trough of output per capita, relative to trend growth, in every recession. The second column

reports the contribution of EFP shocks, based on the benchmark VAR model, to the

corresponding output loss. I assume a 2% output per capita annual trend growth, which is

consistent with the average growth rate of output per capita over the sample.

Page 94: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

86

Table 3.3

The Variables and Equations of the Model

(a) The variables of the model; (b) the equations of the model

a)

L a b e l D e f i n i t i o n

O u t p u t

I n v e s t m e n t

C o n s u m p t i o n

H o u r s

I n s t a l l e d c a p i t a l

C a p i t a l s e r v i c e s

N e t W o r t h

I n f l a t i o n r a t e

T o b i n 's q

R e a l c a p i t a l r e n t a l r a t e

N o m i n a l r a t e

U t i l i z a t i o n r a t e

P r i c e m a r k - u p

W

t

t

t

t

t

s

t

t

t

t

k

t

t

t

p

t

w

t

y

i

c

l

k

k

n

q

r

r

z

u

u

π

a g e m a r k - u p

b)

t y t y t 1y = (1-i -g - )c + i i + g g

y y y t y tn n nε ++ (T.1)

* *(1 )(1 )

1 * t t t+1 t-1 t t+1 t t t 11 1 (1 ) (1 )

c = E c - c - E (l - l ) - (r - E )

hW Lh h

c C

th h h hc c

σλ λ

σ σλ λ λ λ

π

− − + + + + +

(T.2)

1

t t-1 t t+1 t1 2

1 1i = i + E i + (q + )

1c

c

is

t

σσ β ε

β ϕ−

γ + γ γ

(T.3)

*t t+1 t t+1 t t+1

* *

r (1 )E r = + E mpk + E q

r (1 ) r (1 )

kk

t k kq

δδ δ

−−

+ − + − (T.4)

t ty = ( k + (1- )l + )s a

p t tφ α α ε (T.5)

t-1 tk = k + zs

t (T.6)

z ( )t t tmpk qψ= − (T.7)

'

*t t-1 t

(1- ) (1- ) (1- )k = k + 1- i + 1- i

t t

Zz

δ δ δ δε

ν ν ν ν −

(T.8)

t t(k -l ) + p s a

t t tu wα ε= − (T.9)

1 1

t t-1 t t+11 1 1

(1- )(1 ) = + E -

1 1 (1 )(1 ( 1) )

c c

c c c

p p p p p

t

p p p p p p

u

σ σ

σ σ σ

ι β ι β ξ ξπ π π

β ι β ι β ι φ ε ξ

− −

− − −

γ γ −

+ γ + γ + γ + − (T.10)

t t tmpk (k -l ) + ws

t = − (T.11)

Page 95: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

87

t 1

1u = w ( )

1

w

t l t t tl c hch

σ

λ

− + − −

(T.12)

1

t t-1 t t+1 t t+1 t t-11 1 1 1

1

1

1 1 1 = + 1 (E +E )

1 1 1 1

(1- )(1 ) ((1 ) )(( 1) 1)

c

c c c c

c

c

w

w ww wt t

w w w

w w w

u

σ

σ σ σ σ

σ

σ

β ιπ π π

β β β β

β ξ ξε

β ξ φ ε

− − − −

+ γ− − + + γ + γ + γ + γ

γ −− +

+ γ − +

(T.13)

1 (1 )( ) r

t r t r t y t tr p r p yππ ε−= + − Θ +Θ ∆ + (T.14)

t t+1 1 1E r ( )k risk

t t t t tr q k nχ ε+ +− = + − + (T.15)

1 1 11 ( )k nw

t t t t t t t

K Kn n r s r

N Nϑ π ε+ − −

= + − − + − +

(T.16)

1 1

a a a a

t a t t tgε ρ ε η− −= + + (T.17)

1

a a a

t t tg g eκ −= + (T.18)

1

b b b

t b t tε ρ ε η−= + (T.19)

1

g g g

t g t tε ρ ε η−= + (T.20)

1 1

w w w w

t w t t w tε ρ ε η κ η− −= + − (T.21)

1 1

is is is is

t i t t tgε ρ ε η− −= + + (T.22)

1

is is is

t t tg g eκ −= + (T.23)

1

cs cs cs

t risk t tε ρ ε η−= + (T.24)

Notes: This table presents the equations of the DSGE model of section 4.1. The ten

disturbances are: TFP unanticipated shocka

tε ; TFP news shocka

tg ; monetary policy

shockr

tε ;preference shockb

tε ; government spending shockg

tε ; Wage mark-up shockw

tε ;IST

unanticipated shock is

tε ; IST news shock is

tg ; Credit supply shockcs

tε ; Net worth shock nw

tε .

In particular, 1

a

tg − and 1

is

tg − are stochastic drift terms that follow AR(1) processes (T.16) and

(T.21), respectively. Following Sims (2009) and Barsky and Sims (2008, 2009), the

corresponding i.i.d shocks a

te and is

te .in (T.16) and (T.21) are defined as TFP and IST news

shocks as they portend future changes in TFP and IST, respectively.

Page 96: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

88

Table 3.4

Description of the Parameters of the Model and Benchmark

Values

L a b e l D e f i n i t i o n B e n c h m a r k V a l u e

E n t r e p r a n u r i a l s u r v i v a l r a t e 0 . 9 7 3

G o o d s m a r k e t c u r v a t u r e 1 0

L a b o r m a r k e t c u r v a t u r e 1 0

S t e a d y s t a t e l a b o r m a r k e t m a r k - u p 1 . 2 5

D e t e r m i n i s t i c o u t p u t g r

C a l i b r a t e d P a r a m e t e r s

p

w

w

ϑεεφγ

*

o w t h 0 . 0 0 6 3

D e t e r m i n i s t i c c a p i t a l g r o w t h 0 . 0 0 9 2

D i s c o u n t f a c t o r 0 . 9 8 5

L S t e a d y s t a t e h o u r s 0 . 5 3

/ S t e a d y S t a t e L e v e r a g e R a t i o 1 . 7

T F P p e r s i s t e n c e 0 . 9 5

P r e f e r e n c e s h o c k p e r s i s t e n c e 0 . 2 2

G o v e r n m e n t s p e n d i n g

a

b

g

K N

νβ

ρρρ p e r s i s t e n c e 0 . 9 5

W a g e m a r k - u p p e r s i s t e n c e 0 . 9 0

W a g e m a r k - u p M A 0 . 9 0

I S T p e r s i s t e n c e 0 . 9 0

N e w s s h o c k p e r s i s t e n c e 0 . 7 5

T F P s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 . 0 0 4 5

T F P n e w s s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 . 0 0 0 9

P r e f e r e n c e s h o c k s t . d e v .

w

w

i

a

a

e

b

ρκρκσσσ 0 . 0 0 2 3

G o v e r n m n t s p e n d i n g s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 . 0 0 0 1 6

M o n e t a r y p o l i c y s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 . 0 0 2 3

I S T C s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 . 0 0 4 5

I S T C n e w s s h o c k s t . d e v . 0 . 0 0 1 9

N e t W o r t h s h o c k s t . d e v 0 . 0 0 4

E s t i m a t e d P a r a m e t

g

r

i s

i s

e

n

σσσσσ

L a b e l D e f i n i t i o n B e n c h m a r k V a l u e

I n v e r s e i n t e r t e m p o r a l e l a s t i c i t y 0 . 9 8

I n v e r s e l a b o r e l a s t i c i t y 2 . 3 1

C a p i t a l s h a r e 0 . 2 1

C a l v o w a g e s 0 . 7 5

C a l v o p r i c e s 0 . 5

W a g e i n d e x a t i o n 0 . 4 9

P r i c e i n d e x a t i o n 0 . 2 7

F i x

e r s

c

l

w

p

w

p

p

σσαξξιιφ e d c o s t s h a r e 1 . 3 2

M o n e t a r y P o l i c y r u l e i n f l a t i o n 2 .0 0

M o n e t a r y P o l i c y r u l e s m o o t h i n g 0 . 6

M o n e t a r y P o l i c y r u l e o u t p u t g r o w t h 0 . 0 1

I n v e s t m e n t a d j u s t m e n t c o s t 4

H a b i t F o r m a t i o n 0 . 9 5

1 / C a p i t a l u t i l i z a t i o n

r

y

p

h b

π

ϕ

ψ

Θ

Θ

e l a s t i c i t y 0 . 3 8

E F P e l a s t i c i t y 0 . 0 2 7

R i s k s h o c k p e r s i s t e n e 0 . 8 0

R i s k s h o c k s t . d e v 0 . 0 0 2 7

r i s k

r i s k

χρσ

Notes: This table presents a description of the parameters of the DSGE model of section 2.2

as well as their benchmark values.

Page 97: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

89

Figure 3.1

Empirical Impulse Responses to EFP Shocks

Dashed lines represent 5th and 95th percentile Hall (1992) confidence bands generated from a

residual based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

0 10 20 30 40-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4EFP

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Leverage

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-2

-1

0

1

2Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-1

-0.5

0

0.5Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-60

-40

-20

0

20Interest Rate

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 98: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

90

Figure 3.2

Share of Forecast Error Variance Attributable to Identified

Shocks (EFP shock, Unanticipated IST and TFP shocks)

The above bar diagrams show the share of forecast error variance of each variable attributable

to the identified EFP shock, unanticipated IST and unanticipated TFP shocks. As the

identification pursued in the paper is a partial one, the sum of relative contributions of all

three shocks do not necessarily add up to one as there are potentially additional unidentified

shocks also accounting for part of the forecast error variance.

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

EFP

EFP Shock

Unanticipated IST

Unanticipated TFP

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Leverage

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Output

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Consumption

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Investment

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Hours

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Interest Rate

5 10 15 20 25 30 35 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cas

t E

rro

r

Inflation

Page 99: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

91

Figure 3.3

Identified EFP Shock Time Series and U.S Recessions

Smoothed EFP Shock Series

This figure plots the time series of identified EFP shocks from the benchmark VAR. U.S

recession are represented by the shaded areas. So as to render the figure more readable, the

plotted data is smoothed using a one year moving average. Specifically, it is calculated

as 3 2 1( ) / 4s

t t t t tε ε ε ε ε− − −= + + + . The series begins in 1955:2 and ends in 2010:2. I lose

four observations at the beginning of the sample due to the lag length and three additional

observations at the beginning and end of the sample due to the moving average.

Page 100: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

92

Figure 3.4

Impulse Responses to EFP shocks: Smaller Sample

The above are responses to an EFP shock from the benchmark VAR using a sub-sample

starting in 1984:Q1. Dashed lines represent 1th and 99th percentile Hall (1992) confidence

bands generated from a residual based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

0 10 20 30 40-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6EFP

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-2

-1

0

1

2Leverage

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-1

-0.5

0

0.5Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-4

-2

0

2

4

6Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Hours

HorizonP

erc

en

tag

e P

oin

ts

0 10 20 30 40-100

-80

-60

-40

-20

0

20Interest Rate

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 101: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

93

Figure 3.5

Impulse Responses to EFP shocks: Alternative Measure of EFP

The above are responses to an EFP shock from the benchmark VAR using Baa–Aaa spread as

the measure of EFP. Dashed lines represent 5th and 95th percentile Hall (1992) confidence

bands generated from a residual based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

0 10 20 30 40-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3EFP

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6Leverage

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-1

-0.5

0

0.5Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-40

-20

0

20

40Interest Rate

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 10 20 30 40-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 102: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

94

Figure 3.6

Impulse Responses to EFP shocks: Including Credit Quantity

The above are responses to an EFP shock from the benchmark VAR replacing the leverage

ratio variable with a measure of debt gauged by total credit market instruments of

nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business, deflated by the GDP deflator. Dashed lines

represent 5th and 95th percentile Hall (1992) confidence bands generated from a residual

based bootstrap procedure repeated 2000 times.

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4EFP

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5Debt

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-50

-40

-30

-20

-10

0

10Interest Rate

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

0 5 10 15 20-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

ints

Page 103: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

95

Figure 3.7

Impulse Responses to Credit Supply Shock for DSGE Model

The dashed lines show the theoretical impulse response to credit supply shocks from the

model of sub-section 4.1. The solid lines depict the empirical impulse response from the

VAR, with the shaded area representing the 90% bootstrapped VAR confidence interval.

Page 104: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

96

Figure 3.8

Model and Monte Carlo Estimated Impulse Responses to Credit

Supply Shocks

The solid lines show the theoretical impulse response to a credit supply shock from the model

of sub-section 2.2. The dashed lines depict the average estimated impulse responses over

2000 Monte Carlo simulations, with the dotted lines representing the 5th and 95th percentiles

of the distribution of estimated impulse responses.

0 10 20 30 40-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3EFP

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

int

De

via

tio

n

Model

Estimated

0 10 20 30 40-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Leverage

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 10 20 30 40-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1Output

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 10 20 30 40-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1Consumption

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 10 20 30 40-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Investment

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 10 20 30 40-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1Hours

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

De

via

tio

n

0 10 20 30 40-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1Interest Rate

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

int

De

via

tio

n

0 10 20 30 40-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1Inflation

Horizon

Pe

rce

nta

ge

Po

int

De

via

tio

n

Page 105: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

97

Chapter IV

The Role of Domestic and Foreign News and

Animal Spirits Shocks in a Small Open

Economy

1. Introduction

In this paper, I formulate a theoretical small open economy New Keynesian model

that incorporates domestic and foreign news shocks and animal spirits (noise) shocks

and allows an examination of the implications of these shocks for a small open

economy. To my knowledge, the effects of both news and animal spirits shocks have

not been studied in an open-economy setting. Hence, my contribution lies in

proposing such a setting in which the effect of both foreign and domestic news and

animal spirits shocks can be studied. The reason such an extended setting is

interesting is twofold. First, it is appealing to examine whether the effects of domestic

news and animal spirits shocks are different for a small open economy model relative

to a closed economy model. The findings indicate that the effects are similar to the

closed economy model as positive domestic news are expansionary and deflationary

while positive domestic animal spirits are expansionary and inflationary playing the

role of aggregate demand shocks.1 Second, it is interesting to study how the effects of

foreign news and animal spirits shocks differ from their domestic counterparts. The

findings indicate a difference with respect to the response of inflation which is

attributable to exchange rate behavior. In particular, it is found that positive foreign

news are expansionary and induce inflation on impact (due to currency depreciation)

followed by deflation at longer time horizons which is imported by the deflation in the

foreign economy, while positive foreign animal spirits are expansionary and lead to

1 Positive news and animal spirits shocks, as will be explained in detail in the next section, pertain to

the expectation that future productivity will be higher in the future, with news shock constituting

changes in expectations about future productivity that are correct, on average, whereas animal spirits

represent erroneous optimism about future productivity.

Page 106: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

98

deflation on impact (due to currency appreciation) and inflation afterwards as the

demand side effects of the shocks become more dominant than the exchange rate

effect.

Recently there has been a growing interest in examining the role of news

shocks as a driving force of business cycles. The literature includes, among others,

Beaudry and Portier (2004, 2006, 2007), Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2006) and

Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009). As is well known, in the standard neoclassical real

business cycle model, changes in expectations induced by the arrival of new

information to the economy (or news shocks) move consumption and labor in

opposite directions due to the wealth effect. For instance, if an increase in the

expected level of future productivity raises the present discounted value of income,

the consumer increases both consumption and leisure today, and hence reduces labor

supply. It follows that output and investment decline as well.

In order for news shocks to generate business cycles (i.e, comovement

between consumption, investment, labor, and output), the papers listed above modify

preferences and/or technology from the standard model. For instance, Beaudry and

Portier (2004, 2007) introduce a certain type of complementarity between production

technologies in a two-sector model; Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2006) introduce

habit persistence in consumers’ preference and a specific form of the adjustment costs

in investment; Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009) assumes preferences without income

effect on labor supply, the same adjustment cost as in Christiano, Motto and Rostagno

(2006), and variable capital utilization.

The role of news and noise shocks in a closed economy setting has been

studied by Barsky and Sims (2009), who incorporate both news shocks and noise

shocks in a new Keynesian economy model and show that news shocks are

deflationary and have a long lasting effect on economic activity whereas noise shocks

are inflationary and have a transitory effect on economic activity. In their model,

agents receive noisy signals about the future level of productivity. They interpret a

pure noise innovation as an animal spirits shock, as it is associated with erroneous

Page 107: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

99

consumer optimism or pessimism. This paper closely follows their modeling strategy

and extends it to a small open economy setting. It should be noted that the response of

the domestic variables to the domestic news and animal spirits shocks in the small

open economy of this paper is qualitatively similar to the ones found in Barsky and

Sims' (2009) closed economy model. That the shocks continue to be expansionary in a

mall poen economy setting is to be expected as both news and animal spirits shocks

cause real exchange rate depreciation in my model, hence generating an additional

channel through which output can increase following these shocks.

Two recent papers, Blanchard, Huillier and Lorenzoni (2009) and Lorezoni

(2008), have focused on noise shocks related to signals about current productivity

rather than future productivity and showed that noise shocks are a potentially

important driver of business cycles. My paper differs from theirs in that its modeling

strategy follows the one used by Barsky and Sims (2009) which follows the modeling

assumptions of the news shocks literature and offers a more natural setting for the

analysis of both news and noise shocks2.

The role of news shocks in an open economy setting has also been studied

recently. Beaudry, Dupaigne and Portier (2008), henceforth BDP, demonstrate that

the data supports the existence of news-driven international business cycles.

Furthermore, BDP propose a quantitative assessment of the international propagation

of news shock in a two-country extension of Beaudry and Portier (2004) closed

economy model in which they show that the model responses to a local technological

news shocks display an aggregate boom at home, and that this boom is also

transmitted to the foreign country. BDP also show that a more standard quantitative

international real business cycle (IRBC) model such as Backus, Kehoe, and Kydland

(1994) fails reproducing the latter conditional response to technological news shocks.

Moreover, Jaimovich and Rebelo (2008) propose a small open-economy model that

generates business cycles with respect to news about future domestic TFP and

2 As discussed above, the news literature has defined news shocks with respect to the level of future

productivity. Therefore, I choose to follow this modeling assumption as it allows me to model news

shocks, as defined in the news literature, in addition to noise shocks.

Page 108: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

100

investment-specific technical change. The key elements of their model are a weak

short run wealth effect on the labor supply and adjustment costs to labor and

investment. Nevertheless, their paper focuses on the effect of domestic news shocks

and not international news shocks.

In sections 2 and 3, I develop a small open economy New Keynesian general

equilibrium model, a la Gali and Monacelli (2005), with six structural disturbances;

three domestic shocks and three foreign shocks3. The four fundamental shocks are

domestic and foreign technology shocks and news shocks. The technology shock is an

immediate and permanent innovation to the level of technology, while the news shock

is a permanent but not immediate innovation to the level of technology as it portends

a future change in technology orthogonal to the present. Following Barsky and Sims

(2009), I only allow domestic and foreign households to observe a noise-ridden signal

of domestic and foreign news, respectively, and interpret a pure noise innovation as

an animal spirits shock, as it is associated with erroneous consumer optimism or

pessimism. Hence, the two latter domestic and foreign animal spirits shocks together

with the four fundamental shocks comprise the structural shocks of the model. In

section 4, I discuss the implications of each of the six structural shocks of the model

for the domestic endogenous variables of the model. Moreover, I show in sub section

4.4 that the qualitative nature of the results is quite robust to deviations from the

benchmark values of the calibrated parameters.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section I lay

out the details of my model. Section 3 derives the equilibrium in log-linearized form.

Section 4 presents the main results of the paper and provides a sensitivity analysis of

the results. The final section concludes.

3 The foreign economy is modeled as a closed New Keynesian economy model which is exogenous to

the domestic economy.

Page 109: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

101

2. A Small Open Economy Model

2.1 Households

A representative agent in the model chooses sequences of consumption and leisure to

maximize

1 1

0

0 1 1

t t t

t

C NE

σ η

βσ η

− +∞

=

− − +

∑ (1)

where tN denotes hours of labor and tC is a composite consumption index defined by

1 1 1 1 1

tC (1 ) ( ) ( )

aa a a

h fa a a at tC Cλ λ

− − − ≡ − +

(2)

where h

tC is an index of consumption of domestic goods and f

tC is an index of

consumption of foreign goods given by the CES functions:

1 11 11 1

0 0

( ) ( )h h f f

t t t tC C j dj and C C j dj

χ χχ χχ χχ χ− −− −

= = ∫ ∫ (3)

where [0,1]j∈ denotes the good variety (See Gali and Monacelli (2005)).4

Parameter [0,1]λ∈ in (2) measures the degree of openness of the economy as it

represents the steady state share of foreign goods consumption out of total

consumption, parameter 0a ≥ in (2) measures the substitutability between domestic

and foreign goods, from the viewpoint of domestic consumers, and parameter 0χ > in

(3) denotes the elasticity of substitution between varieties of goods within domestic

and foreign goods.5

The demand function for each domestic and foreign good j can be derived by

minimizing the cost of purchasing a given amount of h

tC and f

tC , respectively:

( ) ( )

( ) ( )h f

h h f ft tt t t th f

t t

P j P jC j C and C j C

P P

χ χ− −

= =

(4)

4 Domestic firms produce a continuum of differentiated goods, represented by the unit interval. 5 The elasticity of substitution between varieties of goods is assumed to be the same within domestic

and imported goods.

Page 110: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

102

Where the aggregate price indexes are defined as

1 11 11 1

1 1

0 0

( ) ( )h h f f

t t t tP P j dj and P P j djχ χ

χ χ− −

− − ≡ ≡ ∫ ∫ (5)

The maximization of (1) is subject to a sequence of budget constraints of the form

, 1 1 h h f f

t t t t t t t t t t tP C P C E Q D D W N+ ++ + ≤ + (6)

for t = 0, 1, 2, . . ., where h

tP and f

tP are the price indexes of domestic consumption

goods and imported foreign consumption goods, respectively (expressed in domestic

currency, i.e. the currency of the importing country whose economy is being

modeled). 1tD + is the nominal pay-off in period t +1 of the portfolio held at the end of

period t, tW is the nominal wage, and , 1t tQ + is the stochastic discount factor for one-

period ahead nominal pay-offs relevant to the domestic household. I assume that

households have access to a complete set of contingent claims, traded internationally.

Prior to solving (1) subject to (6), the household optimally allocates any given

expenditure on a consumption basket between domestic and foreign goods. In

particular, the household chooses h

tC and f

tC so as to minimize h h f f

t t t tP C P C+ subject

to (2), yielding the following relative demand function:

1

ah h

t t

f f

t t

C P

C P

λλ

− − =

(7)

I now define an overall consumer price index (CPI), tP , as

1

1 1 1(1 )( ) ( )h a f a at t tP P Pλ λ− − − ≡ − + (8)

Accordingly, total consumption expenditures by domestic households are given by

h h f f

t t t t t tP C P C PC+ = . Thus, the period budget constraint can be rewritten as

, 1 1 t t t t t t t t tP C E Q D D W N+ ++ ≤ + (9)

Now, I turn to solving (1) subject to the constraint (6), yielding the following two first

order conditions:

tt t

t

WC N

P

σ η = (10)

Page 111: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

103

1, 1

1

t tt t

tt

C PQ

PC

σβ

σ+

++

− = −

(11)

where (10) is a standard intratemporal optimality condition and (11) is an

intertemporal Euler condition applied for a certain state of nature in period t+1

conditional on a given state of nature in period t. Taking conditional expectations on

both sides of (11) and rearranging terms a conventional stochastic Euler equation is

obtained:

1

1

1t tt t

tt

C PR E

PC

σβ

σ+

+

− = − (12)

Where , 11 / t t t tR E Q += is the gross return on a riskless one-period discount bond

paying off one unit of domestic currency in t + 1 (with , 1 t t tE Q + being its price). For

future reference it is useful to note that (10) and (12) can be respectively written in

loglinearized form around a zero steady state inflation rate as:

t t t tw p c nσ η− = + (13)

1 1

1 ( )t t t t t tc E c i E π

σ+ += − − (14)

where lower case letters denote the deviation in percentage terms of the respective

variables from their steady states.

2.1.1. The real exchange rate and the terms of trade.

Before proceeding with my analysis of the equilibrium I introduce several

assumptions and definitions that enable a derivation of a relation between the real

exchange rate and the terms of trade. First, I assume that the law of one price holds.

This implies that

f

t t tP P∗= Χ (15)

where tP∗ is the foreign currency price of foreign produced goods and tΧ is the

nominal exchange rate (price of foreign currency in terms of domestic currency). For

simplicity, I assume that all foreign goods sell for the price f

tP . This specification

Page 112: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

104

assumes complete exchange rate pass-through. It will be useful to define the terms of

trade, the price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods as

f

tt h

t

PS

P≡ (16)

Log-linearization of the CPI formula (8) around a symmetric steady state along with

employing the definition of the terms of trade yields:

(1 ) h f h

t t t t tp p p p sλ λ λ= − + = + (17)

where, once more, lowercase letters denote percentage deviation around the steady

state of the corresponding uppercase letter.

Next, a relationship between the terms of trade and the real exchange rate is derived.

First, the real exchange rate is defined as

t tt

t

PV

P

∗Χ= (18)

It then follows that

(1 )f

t t t t t t tv x p p p p sλ∗= + − = − = − (19)

where both (13) and (14) were utilized in the above derivation.

2.1.2. The Foreign Economy and International risk sharing.

To keep the analysis simple, it is assumed that the foreign country is large relative to

the home country. This is taken to mean that it is unnecessary to distinguish between

consumer price inflation and domestic inflation in the foreign country, and that

domestic output and consumption are equal (See Walsh, 2003).6 Goods produced in

the home country are sold to domestic residents and to foreigners. Let *h

tC be the

foreign country’s consumption of the domestically produced good. Similar to

domestic households, foreign households optimally allocate any given expenditure on

a consumption basket between domestic and foreign goods yielding the following

relative demand function of foreign households:

6 The home economy is assumed to be small relative to the foreign economy, which can be thought of

as the rest of the world economy. Namely, the home economy goods' share in the foreign economy's

consumption is negligible, thereby allowing me to assume that foreign consumption is equal to foreign

output.

Page 113: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

105

1 h

t t

fhtt

Y P

PC

γλ

λ

−∗

− =

(20)

where tY∗ represents foreign output and 0γ ≥ measures the substitutability between

domestic and foreign goods, from the viewpoint of foreign consumers. For simplicity,

it is assumed that foreign households derive utility only from consumption as the

amount of hours worked in the foreign economy is assumed to be constant, implying

that all fluctuations in foreign output are caused by technological changes.7

Under the assumption of complete securities markets, a first order condition

analogous to (11) must also hold for the representative household in the foreign

economy:

1, 1

1 1

t t tt t

t tt

PCQ

PC

σβ

σ

∗∗+

+∗∗+ +

− Χ =

− Χ (21)

Combining (11) and (21), together with the real exchange rate definition and the

equality between foreign consumption and foreign output, it follows that

1

t t tC Y V σϑ ∗= (22)

for all t, and whereϑ is a constant which will generally depend on initial conditions

regarding relative net asset positions (See Gali and Monacelli, 2005). Henceforth, and

without loss of generality, symmetric initial conditions are assumed (i.e. zero net

foreign asset holdings), in which case 1ϑ = . Log linearization of (22) around the

steady state, together with (16), generates the following equation linking domestic

consumption, foreign output and the terms of trade:8

1

t t tc y sλ

σ∗ − = +

(23)

2.1.3. Uncovered interest parity

Taking conditional expectations on both sides of (21) and rearranging terms a

standard intertemporal Euler condition for the foreign economy is obtained:

7 The specific modeling of foreign technology and the corresponding information structure will be

discussed in detail in section 2.2.1. 8 A similar relationship holds in many international RBC models. See, e.g. Backus and Smith (1993).

Page 114: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

106

1

1

1t tt

t

tt

Y PR E

PY

σβ

σ

∗ ∗

∗ +∗∗+

− = −

(24)

Where 1, 11 / t

t t tt

t

R E Q∗ ++

Χ=

Χ . The previous equation can be combined (12) to

obtain a version of the uncovered interest parity condition:

1, 1

, 1

tt t t

tt

t t tt

E QR

R E Q

++

∗+

Χ

Χ = (25)

Log-linearizing around the steady state, yields the familiar expression

1t t t ti i E x∗+= + ∆ (26)

It is important to point out that condition (26) is not an additional independent

equilibrium condition that will determine the dynamics of the exchange rate in the

solution of the model (See Gali and Monacelli (2005)). In particular, in the solution of

the model the dynamics of the exchange rate are already determined by the other

equations of the model involving the exchange rate. Specifically, condition (26) can

be obtained by combining Euler condition (14) and the risk sharing condition (23).

Therefore, the fact that (26) holds only provides the dynamics of exchange rate

expectations.

2.2 Firms

2.2.1. Technology and News Shocks

There is a continuum of identical monopolistically-competitive firms which have the

following production function:9

( ) ( )t t tY j AN j= (27)

where ( )tY j is a differentiated good, tA is total productivity and ln( )t tz A= follows the

unit root process

t 1 t-1z zt tg ε+−= + (28)

9 As is common in the literature dealing with open economy new Keynesian models, I abstract from the

inclusion of capital in the model. Nevertheless, it is interesting and challenging for future research to

examine the ability of news and noise shocks to generate business cycle comovement when

endogenous capital accumulation is included.

Page 115: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

107

Here tε is the contemporaneous technology shock and 1tg − is a stochastic drift term

which obeys the stationary AR(1) process 1t g t tg g eρ −= + , Where te is an i.i.d news

shock which is imperfectly observed by agents in period t, as will be further explained

below in sub-section 2.2.2 . I call te a news shock because it portends of future

changes in Technology. It is simply a smooth version of the news shocks studied by

Beaudry and Portier (2004) and Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009)10

.

Assuming a symmetric equilibrium for all j firms, log linearization of the aggregate

version of (27) around the steady state yields

t t ty z n= + (29)

An analogous equation to (29) for the foreign economy is

t t ty z n∗ ∗ ∗= + (30)

Where tz∗ represents foreign technology shocks, which follow the unit root process

1 t-1t

z zt tg ε∗ ∗ ∗ ∗+−= + (31)

Here, tε∗ is the contemporaneous i.i.d technology shock and 1tg

∗− is a stochastic drift

term which obeys the stationary AR(1) process * 1t g t tg p g e∗ ∗ ∗−= + , where te

∗ is an i.i.d

foreign news shock. Moreover, I follow the literature on IRBC (International Real

Business cycles) models and assume that technology shocks of the two economies are

contemporaneously correlated (See for example Backus et al. (1992), Baxter and Farr

(2005) and Wen (2006))11

. In our framework, assuming that technology shocks are

correlated naturally leads to the postulation that domestic and foreign news shocks are

also correlated as news shocks are simply anticipated future technology shocks. As I

discuss in sub-section 4.1, the correlation coefficients between domestic and foreign

technology and news shocks are set to 0.258.12

10

For simplicity, I assume here that the news shock occurs one period in advance. In general, it can

occur j periods in advance. Nevertheless, the assumption that the effect of the news shock on the drift

term is persistent implies that news arriving in the economy in the current period don't solely anticipate

a change in next period's technology, but also portend a gradual change in further future periods'

technology. 11 This assumption is based on empirical studies such as Backus et al. (1992), Reynolds (1993), and

Baxter and Crucini (1995) which estimated the correlation to be 0.258. 12

The assumption about the correlation between domestic and foreign technology and news shocks,

which aims to reflect technological spillover between the two economies, is not necessary for

generating expansionary foreign news and noise shocks in the model. In particular, for reasonable

Page 116: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

108

I should note here that due to the assumed nominal rigidities in the model,

there is an avenue here for output to expand upon the arrival of good news about the

future and therefore the model is not subject to the “bust” feature of neoclassical

models in which output declines after agents receive advance signals about future

technology.

2.2.2. Perceptions and Animal Spirits

While households observe the level of technology tz at each point in time, it is

assumed that they never explicitly observe shocks to technology tε and observe only

a noisy signal of the true news shock te . The signal they receive is equal to:

t t tv e u= + (32)

where tu constitutes and i.i.d noise shock in signal tv and is uncorrelated with both

the technology shock tε and news shock te . Following Barsky and Sims (2009), I will

interpret the noise innovation tu as an animal spirits shock. A positive tu means that

households erroneously believe that the future will be better. Given this belief, they

will desire to consume more immediately. Because firms do not share this belief,

there is no shock on the supply side of the model. In this way, this animal spirits

shock is a pure demand shock.

The set up described above is essentially a signal extraction problem in which

households imperfectly observe the stochastic drift term tg and need to estimate it. It

is posited that they update their perceptions according to a simple linear filter (See

Barsky and Sims (2009)):

1 1 1 1 2(1 ) ( )p p

t g t g t t tg g z z vρ ρ− −= −Ω + Ω − +Ω (33)

gρ is the autoregressive parameter of the drift term process, and the coefficients 1Ω

and 2Ω are functions of the variances of the shocks in the economy. In particular,

2 2

1 22 2 2 2

u e

u e u

andε

σ σσ σ σ σ

Ω = Ω =+ +

(34)

calibrations, both news and noise shocks are capable of generating economic fluctuations domestically

in the absence of the latter correlation, whereby foreign news behave essentially as pure demand

shocks as they no longer affect domestic productivity in the absence of technological spillover.

Nevertheless, I assume positive correlation in the benchmark model as to allow for technological

spillover.

Page 117: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

109

It is useful to consider a couple of extreme cases as well as intermediate cases

so as to better understand the assumed linear filter. If 2 0uσ = (i.e. there is no noise in

the signal pertaining to the true news shock) then 2 1Ω = , 1 0Ω = , and the perceived

drift term is equal to the truth at all times. If 2 0εσ = (i.e. there are no shocks to the

current level of technology), then 1 1Ω = . Namely, agents will be uncertain about the

current level of the true news shock due to the noise in the signal, but the realization

of next period's technology will reveal perfectly to them today’s actual news shock,

hence rendering no endogenous persistence of a false signal for more than one period.

With respect to intermediate cases, as the variance of the noise term in the signal

grows, 2Ω becomes smaller and 1Ω gets bigger – people will place little weight on a

very noisy signal but will place a lot of weight on the realization of actual technology

growth relative to their previous period’s perception in updating their current belief.

As 2

εσ gets bigger, 1Ω becomes smaller, implying that household perceptions about

the technology drift term will be more persistent. Intuitively, a very high variance of

technology shocks means that a realization of technology growth different from what

was expected is less likely to mean that the original perception of the drift term was

wrong, and more likely that there was simply an offsetting technology shock.

An analogous analysis to the one depicted above applies also to foreign

households. In particular, I assume that foreign households also observe level of

technology tz∗ at each point in time but that they never explicitly observe shocks to

technology t

ε ∗ and observe only a noisy signal of the drift term tg∗ . The signal they

receive is equal to:

t t tv e u∗ ∗ ∗= + (35)

where tu∗ constitutes i.i.d noise shock in signal tv

∗ and is uncorrelated with both the

technology shock tε∗and drift term tg

∗ as well as domestic news and noise shocks. I

will interpret the noise innovation tu∗ as a foreign animal spirits shock along the lines

of the analysis above for domestic households. A positive tu∗ means that foreign

households erroneously believe that the future will be better. Given this belief, they

will desire to consume more immediately inducing a foreign demand shock.

Page 118: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

110

Moreover, the assumption that domestic and foreign news shocks are correlated

implies that domestic and foreign signals are correlated. Therefore, foreign noise

which affects the foreign signal will also have an effect on the domestic signal and

thus domestic perceptions13

.

Lastly, foreign households face an analogous signal extraction problem to the

one faced by domestic households. It is assumed that their perceptions of the drift

term tg∗behave precisely as the perceptions of domestic households with respect to tg :

1 11 1 2

(1 ) ( )p p

t t t t tg gg g z z vρ ρ∗ ∗∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗

− −= −Ω + Ω − +Ω (36)

where all coefficients are defined analogously to the analysis of the domestic case.

2.2.3. Price–Setting

Following Calvo (1983) I assume that each individual firm j resets its price with

probability 1 θ− each period, independently of the time elapsed since its last price

adjustment. Thus, each period a measure 1 θ− of (randomly selected) firms reset

their prices, while a fraction θ keep their prices unchanged. Let ( )h

tP j denote the

price set by a firm adjusting its price in period t. Under the Calvo price-setting

structure, ( ) ( )hhtt kP j P j+ = with probability kθ for k = 0, 1, 2…. . Since all firms

resetting prices in any given period will choose the same price, I henceforth drop the j

subscript.

When setting a new price in period t firm j seeks to maximize the current

value of its dividend stream, conditional on that price being effective:

,

0

( )max ( )

h

th

h t t t k t t khPt kt

P jkE Q C j MCP

θ∞

+ +=

− ∑

(37)

subject to the sequence of demand constraints given by (4), where / h

t t t tMC W AP=

is the firm's real marginal cost. Using the demand curve for domestic good j in (4) to

eliminate ( )h

tC j , this objective function can be written as

13

This mechanism is not significantly important for the results of the model as foreign animal spirits are

still expansionary also in its absence.

Page 119: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

111

1

,0

( ) ( )max

h h

t th

h t t t k t k t kh hPt kt k t k

P j P jkE Q C MCP P

χ χ

θ

− −∞

+ + += + +

− ∑

(38)

While individual firms produce differentiated products, they all have the same

production technology and face demand curves with constant and equal demand

elasticities. In other words, they are essentially identical, except that they may have

set their current price at different dates in the past. However, all firms adjusting in

period t face the same problem, so all adjusting firms will set the same price.

Therefore, the j subscript is henceforth dropped. The first order condition for the

optimal choice of h

tP is:

,0

1(1 )

h h

t th

t t t k t k t kh h hk

t k t kt

P PkE Q C MCP PP

χ

θ θ θ

−∞

+ + += + +

− + ∑

(39)

Using the fact that ,

k t k tt t k

t t k

C PQ

C P

σ

β−

++

+

=

, I can rewrite the previous condition as

( )

( )

1

0

11

0

1

hk k h t k

t t k t k hhk

tt

hh

t k k h t kt t k t k h

kt

PE C MC

PP

P PE C MC

P

χσ

χσ

θ βχ

χθ β

∞ −+

+ +=

−∞ −

++ +

=

= − ∑

(40)

Equation (40) shows how adjusting firms set their price, conditional on the current

aggregate price level of domestically produced goods h

tP . This aggregate price index

is an average of the price charged by the fraction 1 θ− of firms setting their price in

period t and the average of the remaining fraction θ of all firms setting their price in

earlier periods. However, because the adjusting firms were selected randomly from

among all firms, the average price of the nonadjusters is just the average price of all

firms that prevailed in period 1t − . Thus, from (39), the average price in period t

satisfies

( ) ( ) ( )11 1

1(1 )hh htt tP P P

χχ χθ θ

−− −

−= − + (41)

Page 120: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

112

Equations (40) and (41) can be loglinearized around a zero inflation steady-state to

obtain an expression for aggregate domestic inflation (see Walsh (2003)) of the form

1h h

t t t tE mcπ β π ω+= + (42)

Where (1 )(1 ) /ω θ βθ θ= − − is an increasing function of the fraction of firms able to

adjust each period and tmc is real marginal cost, expressed as a percentage deviation

around its steady-state value. Equation (42) is often referred to as the new Keynesian

Phillips curve and it implies that current inflation depends on expected inflation and

current real marginal cost.14

3. Equillibrium

In the first subsection, I derive an equation describing the demand side of the

economy. In the second subsection, I derive an equation describing the supply side of

the economy.

3.1. The Demand Side: Aggregate demand and output

determination

Goods market clearing in the small open economy requires that total domestically

produced output equals its consumption by domestic households and foreign

households:15

h h

t t tY C C∗

= + (43)

Notice that consumption of domestic output by foreign consumers, h

tC∗

, is simply the

amount of exports of the domestic economy. In the steady state, assuming a

symmetric equilibrium where ss ssh f

t tP P= , it can be deduced from (7) and (2) that the

steady state shares of domestic produced goods and imported goods out of total

consumption are respectively 1 λ− and λ . Furthermore, since that in the steady state

the trade balance must equal zero thereby implying that total consumption equals total

output, log linearization of (43) around the steady state yields the following:

(1 ) h h

t t ty c cλ λ∗

= − + (44)

14 Equation (41) can be solved forward to show that current inflation depends upon present discounted

value of current and future real marginal costs (See Walsh (2003)). 15

I assume here that the goods are not durable and cannot be stored.

Page 121: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

113

Next, by log linearizing around the steady state equations (2) and (7), respectively, I

obtain

(1 ) h f

t t tc c cλ λ= − + (45)

f h

t t tc c as= − (46)

where ts denotes the percentage deviation around the steady state of the terms of

trade. Combining (45) and (46), I attain

h

t t tc c asλ= − (47)

Moreover, log linearization around the steady state of equation (20) gives

h

t t tc y sγ∗ ∗= + (48)

Now, using equations (23), (44), (47) and (48) I can obtain

t t ty c sλκσ

= + (49)

where (1 )( 1)aκ σγ λ σ≡ + − − . Notice that 1aσ γ= = = implies 1κ = .

Combining (49) with (23) gives

1

t t t

a

y y sσ

∗= + (50)

Where / (1 )aσ σ λ λκ= − + . Lastly, combining (17), (49) and (50) with Euler

equation (14) a final equation describing the demand side of the economy is obtained:

1 11

1 ( ) ( 1)( )h

t t t t t t t tt

a

y E y i E E y yπ λ κσ

∗ ∗+ ++

= − − + − − (51)

3.2. The Trade Balance

Let 1 t

t t th

t

Pnx Y C

PY

= −

denote net exports in terms of domestic output, expressed as

a fraction of steady state outputY . Moreover, a first order approximation of the above

relation yields t t t tnx y c sλ= − − which combined with (49) implies

( 1)t tnx sκ

λσ

= − (52)

Notice that in the special case 1a γ σ= = = we have 0tnx = for all t . For my

baseline parameter calibrated values, there's a positive relationship between the terms

of trade and net exports. Thus, any shock that improves the terms of trade will raise

Page 122: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

114

net exports. For example, domestic technology shocks which decrease domestic

inflation and therefore improve the terms of trade will cause an increase in net

exports.

3.3. The supply side: marginal cost and inflation dynamics

In the small open economy, the dynamics of domestic goods' inflation in terms of real

marginal cost are described by equation (42). The determination of the real marginal

cost as a function of domestic output in the small open economy differs somewhat

from that in the closed economy, due to the existence of a wedge between output and

consumption, and between domestic and consumer prices. Thus, we have

( ) ( )

(1 )

h

t t t t

h

t t t t t

t t t t

t t tt

mc w p z

w p p p z

c n s z

y y s z

σ η λ

σ η η∗

= − − =

− + − − =

+ + − =

+ + − +

(53)

where the last equality makes use of (13), (23) and (29). Thus, we see that marginal

cost is increasing in the terms of trade and world output. Both variables end up

influencing the real wage, through the wealth effect on labour supply resulting from

their impact on domestic consumption. In addition, changes in the terms of trade have

a direct effect on the product wage, for any given real wage. The influence of

technology (through its direct effect on labour productivity) and of domestic output

(through its effect on employment and, hence, the real wage—for given output) is

analogous to that observed in the closed economy.

Finally, using (50) to substitute for ts , I can rewrite the previous expression for

the real marginal cost in terms of domestic output and productivity, as well as world

output:

( ) ( ) (1 )t a t a t tmc y y zσ σ σ η η∗= − + + − + (54)

Notice that in the special cases 0λ = and/or 1aσ = = , which imply aσ σ= , the

domestic real marginal cost is completely insulated from movements in foreign

output.

Page 123: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

115

3.4. Closing the Model: Domestic monetary policy rule and

Foreign Economy Equilibrium

Following the literature on new Keynesian models, I specify a domestic nominal

interest rate rule implemented by the central bank. Following a number of recent

papers (for example, Barsky and Sims (2008), Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2007),

Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2007), and Ireland (2004)), it is postulated

that the central bank sets nominal interest rates according to a partial adjustment

mechanism where the interest rate in any period is equal to a convex combination of

the lagged interest rate and the central bank’s target rate, where the target rate is

adjusted in response to deviations of output growth and inflation from constant

targets:

1 (1 )( ( *) ( *))t t t y ti pi p y yπ π π−= + − Θ − + Θ ∆ − ∆ (55)

Note that policy rule (55) can coexist with the uncovered interest rate parity rule (26)

because of the endogeneity of the exchange rate. In particular, any shocks that affect

the domestic interest rate and generate domestic-foreign interest rate differentials also

affect the expectations regarding exchange rate future depreciation rate so that

condition (26) is satisfied. For instance, a shock that renders a positive differential

implies that agents expect the exchange rate to depreciate as the expected future

depreciation makes it worthwhile to hold foreign bonds that earn a lower interest rate

than domestic bonds.

As previously discussed in sub section 2.1.2, the foreign economy is treated as

a closed economy as it is essentially the rest of the world economy. I model the

foreign economy as the standard New Keynesian model (see Woodford (2003) or Gali

(2008) for complete derivation), implying the following two final equilibrium

equations:

1 1

1 ( t t t t t ty E y i E π

σ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗

+ += − − (56)

1t t t tE mcπ β π ω∗ ∗ ∗+= + (57)

Page 124: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

116

where (1 )(1 ) /ω θ βθ θ= − − is an increasing function of the fraction of firms able to

adjust prices each period, measured by 1 θ− , and ( ) (1 )t t tmc y zσ η η∗ ∗ ∗= + − + is real

marginal cost, expressed as a percentage deviation around its steady-state value. For

simplicity, I assume that the foreign preference parameters are equal to the domestic

ones. Equation (55) is simply the Euler equation for a closed economy. Equation (57)

is often referred to as the new Keynesian Phillips curve and it implies that current

inflation depends on expected inflation and current real marginal cost. I close the

foreign economy model with a nominal interest rate rule identical to the domestic one

in (55).

4. Numerical Results

4.1. Calibration

In this section I present some quantitative results based on a calibrated version of my

model economy. Let me first state the main assumptions underlying my baseline

calibration, which is taken as a benchmark. Following Gali and Monacelli (2005), I

set σ=1, assume β=0.99 (with the interpretation of the unit of time as one quarter, this

implies a riskless annual return of about 4% in the steady state), set a=1 (substitution

elasticity between domestic and imported goods) and set parameter δ equal to 0.75, a

value consistent with an average period of one year between price adjustments.

Following Barsky and Sims (2009), I set the labor supply elasticity to equal 1,

assume a value of 0.85 for AR parameter of the stochastic drift term and set

0.75, 4.5, 2.5yp π= Θ = Θ = in the monetary policy rule. Moreover, the standard

deviations of technology shocks and news shocks are chosen so that each leads to an

ultimate increase in technology of one percent and the standard deviation of the noise

shock is chosen so that it is the same as the news shock (i.e. both shocks raise the

signal by an amount prognostic of an ultimate increase in the level of technology of

one percent).16

This implies a value of 0.5 for 2Ω and 0.022 for 1Ω .

16

Barsky and Sims (2009) also perform structural estimation of a closed economy new Keynesian

model augmented with a structural specification for consumer confidence and attain estimates of the

Page 125: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

117

I set the correlation coefficient between domestic and foreign technology and

news shocks to 0.258, in line with standard calibration in the IRBC literature (See

Backus et al. (1992), Reynolds (1993), Baxter and Crucini (1995), Baxter and Farr

(2005) and Wen (2006)). Lastly, I set a baseline value for λ (or degree of openness) of

0.4. The latter corresponds roughly to the import/GDP ratio in a prototype small open

economy (See Gali and Monacelli (2005)).

4.2. Impulse Responses to the Structural Shocks

Figure 4.1 shows the responses of output, consumption, hours of work, technology,

CPI inflation, domestic inflation, nominal exchange rate, real exchange rate and

exports to domestic and foreign technology shocks17

. The sizes of the shocks are

chosen so that each leads to an ultimate increase in technology of one percent. For all

variables the figures show the percentage response relative to the initial non-

stochastic steady state, aside from the inflation variables for which the response

shown is percentage point deviation from the zero inflation steady state. By

construction, both shocks lead to an immediate jump in technology that is expected to

remain forever at the new higher level, where the foreign shock has a smaller effect in

accordance with the calibrated correlation coefficient of 0.258 between the two

shocks. As is common in new Keynesian models, the domestic technology shock

leads to a decline in hours of work whereas the effect of the foreign shock is

essentially inexistent. The effect of both shocks on output is nearly identical to their

effect on technology as the response of hours is moderate relative to the response of

technology.

noise and news standard deviation parameters that are very similar to the calibrated standard deviations

used in this paper. 17

Although it is not shown here, I should note that the response of the foreign endogenous variables to

the foreign structural shocks is consistent with the findings in Barsky and Sims (2009); technology and

information shocks are deflationary and associated with persistent movements in measures of real

activity, while the animal spirits shocks are inflationary and associated with transitory increases in

domestic spending.

Page 126: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

118

Moreover, the domestic technology shock is deflationary in terms of both CPI

and domestic inflation while the foreign shock is deflationary in terms of CPI

inflation but inflationary in terms of domestic inflation. The reason for the latter result

lies in that the domestic technology shocks induces a supply side effect which is

stronger than the wealth driven demand side effect thus leading to domestic deflation,

whereas the foreign shocks induces a weaker supply side effect thus leading to

domestic inflation. CPI inflation is comprised of domestic inflation and imported

inflation which in turn depends on foreign inflation and the rate of change in the

foreign exchange rate. The foreign technology shock induces foreign deflation (not

shown in the figure) and currency appreciation that offset domestic inflation thereby

generating the resultant CPI deflation. While the domestic shock leads to currency

depreciation, the latter effect is weaker than the increase in domestic deflation which

dominates and generates overall CPI deflation as well. Lastly, it is apparent that the

foreign shock has a bigger effect on consumption than the foreign shock during the

first year following the shock and thereafter the domestic shock dominates. The

reason for this result can be explained by the risk sharing condition (23); foreign

technology shocks increase foreign consumption hence causing an increase in

domestic consumption as well. Nevertheless, the foreign shock also induces real

currency appreciation which eventually enables the effect of the domestic shock,

which causes real currency depreciation, to dominate at longer time horizons. The

latter behavior of the real exchange rate also explains the stronger effect of the

domestic shocks on exports.

Figure 4.2 shows the responses of output, consumption, hours of work,

technology, CPI inflation, domestic inflation, nominal exchange rate, real exchange

rate and exports to domestic and foreign news shocks. The sizes of the shocks are

chosen so that each leads to an ultimate increase in domestic and foreign technology

of one percent, respectively. In response to both shocks, output jumps on impact and

is expected to rise towards its new steady state value. Quite naturally, the effect of

domestic news is stronger given the imperfect correlation between domestic and

Page 127: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

119

foreign technology shocks. Both shocks raise employment on impact but the behavior

of employment thereafter is different following the two shocks. After the impact

effect, employment remains above its steady state for several periods before

converging to it following the foreign shock whereas it becomes negative relative to

its steady state following the domestic shock. This consequence is simply a

manifestation of the effect of the realized anticipated technology shocks portended by

the domestic news shock.

Moreover, the domestic news shock is deflationary in terms of both CPI and

domestic inflation while the foreign shock is inflationary on impact and thereafter

deflationary in terms of CPI inflation but inflationary in terms of domestic inflation.

Domestic news portend future supply shocks which reduce real marginal cost hence

causing deflation today as inflation is equal to the present value of future real

marginal costs. Notice that even though that domestic news generate currency

depreciation this is not strong enough to offset the decline in domestic inflation. In

contrast, foreign news reflect more of a wealth driven demand side effect than a

supply side effect hence causing domestic inflation. Nevertheless, foreign news also

induce foreign deflation (not shown in the figure) which cause CPI deflation but only

after causing CPI inflation on impact as the effect of currency depreciation dominates

initially. Lastly, both news shocks have an almost identical effect on consumption

despite the positive effect of foreign news on foreign consumption. This is due to real

currency depreciation/appreciation caused by domestic/foreign news which offset the

latter effect and also explain the bigger effect of domestic news on exports.

Figure 4.3 shows the responses of output, consumption, hours of work,

technology, CPI inflation, domestic inflation, nominal exchange rate, real exchange

rate and exports to domestic and foreign animal spirits shocks. The sizes of the shocks

are chosen so that they are the same as the corresponding news shocks (i.e. both

shocks raise the signal by an amount prognostic of an ultimate increase in the level of

domestic and foreign technology of one percent, respectively). By construction, the

shocks never have any effect on the actual level of technology. Both animal spirits

Page 128: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

120

shocks are differentiated from the news or technology shocks in that they are

associated with a transitory response of output. Furthermore, both shocks raise

employment and domestic inflation and resemble pure demand shocks. Nevertheless,

while domestic animal spirits raise CPI inflation as well foreign animal spirits induce

mild deflation on impact due to currency appreciation, after which CPI inflation turns

positive. The initial response of consumption is higher following foreign animal

spirits owing to the increase in foreign consumption but afterwards the effect of

domestic animal spirits is moderately higher due to the real currency

depreciation/appreciation domestic/foreign animal spirits induce which also explains

the bigger effect of domestic animal spirits on exports.

4.3. Variance Decomposition

Figure 4.4 illustrates the forecast error variance decomposition of output,

consumption, CPI inflation and the nominal exchange rate in terms of the six

structural shocks. It is apparent that unanticipated technology shocks play a bigger

role in economic fluctuations than anticipated shocks. At a horizon of 3 years, for

example, technology shocks account for 65% of output fluctuations compared to 26%

accounted for by domestic news. Foreign technology shocks matter mainly in the very

short run accounting for 32% and of output fluctuations on impact. With respect to

consumption, foreign technology shocks play an especially important role accounting

for 72% of consumption fluctuations on impact while foreign news shocks gain in

significance over longer time horizons explaining 20% of consumption fluctuations at

the 8 year time horizon. The observation that foreign shocks matter more for

consumption than output can be explained by the assumption of complete markets

yielding the risk sharing condition which strongly ties domestic consumption with

foreign consumption.

Fluctuations in CPI inflation are mostly explained by domestic technology and

news shocks accounting for 30% and 60% of inflation variation at the 3 year horizon,

respectively. The latter result is also obtained for the forecast error variance

decomposition of domestic inflation (not shown here). This outcome illustrates that

Page 129: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

121

supply shocks are an important factor in the determination of inflation as the latter

equals the present value of future real marginal costs. Lastly, exchange rate

fluctuations are mainly explained by domestic and foreign animal spirits which

account for 30% and 23% on impact and maintain these weights at longer horizons as

well. This is an interesting result as it implies that animal spirits affect the foreign

exchange rate more that pure news or unanticipated technology shocks. Furthermore,

domestic news attain the biggest weight on impact accounting for 23% of exchange

rate contemporaneous variation, whereas at longer time horizons the influence of

domestic news steadily declines.

4.4. Robustness

The qualitative nature of the results is quite robust to deviations from the benchmark

values of the calibrated parameters. Nevertheless, some of the results are sensitive to

the choice of monetary policy rule. In the benchmark model I assume a nominal

interest rate rule in the form of equation (55). However, it is worthwhile to examine

how the results differ when more standard monetary policy rules are considered. In

particular, in the present section I analyze the macroeconomic implications of two

alternative monetary policy regimes for the small open economy. Two of the simple

rules considered are stylized Taylor-type rules examined in Gali and Monacceli

(2005). The first has the domestic interest rate respond systematically to domestic

inflation, whereas the second assumes that CPI inflation is the variable the domestic

central bank reacts to18

. The main result is that rule (55) is needed in order to generate

news shocks that are deflationary, an outcome which was also discussed in Barsky

and Sims (2008).

Formally, the domestic inflation-based Taylor rule (DITR, for short) is

specified as follows:

h

t ti ψπ= (58)

The CPI inflation-based Taylor rule (CITR, for short) is assumed to take the form

18

It is assumed that the foreign monetary authority also responds only to inflation under the two

regimes.

Page 130: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

122

t ti ψπ= (59)

I follow the original Taylor estimate and set 1.5ψ = to reflect an aggressive monetary

policy rule which raises the interest rate by more than the increase in inflation so that

the real interest rate increases as well.

Figures 4.5 and 4.6 display the impulse responses of output, consumption,

hours of work, technology, CPI inflation, domestic inflation, nominal exchange rate,

real exchange rate and exports to domestic and foreign technology shocks of one

percent, respectively, under the benchmark monetary policy rule (55) and the CITR

and DITR as depicted in equations (58) and (59), respectively. It is apparent that

under CITR and DITR the negative effect of improved domestic technology on hours

is much weaker and in fact is even slightly positive under CITR. Therefore, the short

run increase in output is much higher under the latter regimes compared to the

benchmark case. Similarly, consumption and exports also exhibit bigger increases.

Likewise, foreign technology also generates a bigger increase in output and

consumption, especially under CITR where the effect on hours is significantly

positive.

An additional dissimilarity arises with respect to CPI inflation, domestic

inflation and the nominal and real exchange rates. Under CITR and DITR, domestic

technology shocks are inflationary rather than deflationary as in the benchmark model

while also generating much stronger nominal and real currency depreciation. On the

other hand, foreign technology shocks generate higher domestic inflation but are more

deflationary in terms of CPI inflation due to stronger currency appreciation.

Figures 4.7 and 4.8 display the impulse responses of output, consumption,

hours of work, technology, CPI inflation, domestic inflation, nominal exchange rate,

real exchange rate and exports to domestic and foreign news shocks, respectively,

under the benchmark monetary policy rule (55) and the CITR and DITR as depicted

in equations (58) and (59), respectively. The sizes of the shocks are chosen so that

each leads to an ultimate increase in domestic and foreign technology of one percent,

respectively. It is evident that domestic news is more expansionary in terms of output,

Page 131: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

123

consumption and hours under the two alternative regimes. Moreover, domestic news

generate both domestic inflation and CPI inflation under CITR and DITR as opposed

to deflation in under the benchmark regime. The latter results can be explained by the

lack of response to output growth by the monetary authority under CITR and DITR

which allows for more expansionary monetary policy in response to favorable news

hence causing inflation and a bigger increase in output. Moreover, domestic news also

cause stronger real currency depreciation which supports a bigger increase in exports.

With respect to foreign news, it is evident that the impulse responses are very similar

under DITR and the benchmark regime. Nevertheless, foreign news are more

expansionary under CITR causing a bigger increase in output, consumption, hours

while also being more inflationary. This can be explained by the fact that foreign

news generate domestic inflation compared to CPI deflation under the benchmark

regime and DITR. This means that a monetary authority that responds to CPI inflation

as opposed to domestic inflation would be more expansionary in response to foreign

news shocks thereby leading to a bigger increase in economic activity.

Figures 4.9 and 4.10 display the impulse responses of output, consumption,

hours of work, technology, CPI inflation, domestic inflation, nominal exchange rate,

real exchange rate and exports to domestic and foreign animal spirits shocks,

respectively, under the benchmark monetary policy rule (55) and the CITR and DITR

as depicted in equations (58) and (59), respectively. The sizes of the shocks are

chosen so that they are the same as the corresponding news shocks (i.e. both shocks

raise the signal by an amount prognostic of an ultimate increase in the level of

domestic and foreign technology of one percent, respectively). Not surprisingly,

domestic animal spirits are more expansionary and inflationary under the two

alternative regimes as monetary policy is more expansionary in response to positive

animal spirits shocks since it does not react to output growth. Moreover, CITR and

DITR allow for a bigger currency depreciation which in turn generates a bigger

increase in exports. The impulse responses to foreign animal spirits are quite similar,

Page 132: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

124

although it is apparent that foreign animal spirits cause stronger currency appreciation

under the two alternative regimes.

5. Conclusion

This paper studies the potential role of domestic and foreign news and animal spirits

shocks in the business cycle of a small open economy using a small open economy

new Keynesian model a la Gali and Monacelli (2005). I follow the approach of

Barsky and Sims (2009) and assume that domestic and foreign households observe a

noise-ridden signal of domestic and foreign news, respectively, and interpret a pure

noise innovation as an animal spirits shock, as it is associated with erroneous

consumer optimism or pessimism. Impulse response results indicate that foreign news

are expansionary and induce inflation on impact followed by deflation at longer time

horizons, while foreign news are expansionary and deflationary. Domestic animal

spirits are expansionary and inflationary playing the role of aggregate demand shocks

whereas foreign animal spirits are expansionary and lead to deflation on impact (due

to currency appreciation) and inflation afterwards.

In terms of the modeling framework, a potential avenue for future research

would be to introduce endogenous animal spirits whereby the optimism and

pessimism of agents partly depend on the variables of the model. For instance, it

seems reasonable to extend the model so that animal spirits depend on the business

cycle itself as expansionary (contractionary) periods could potentially lead to higher

optimism (pessimism). While this paper's results are theoretical, it seems important

and interesting to empirically investigate the role of foreign and domestic news and

animal spirits shocks in the business cycle of small and open economies. A challenge

that arises in such an empirical framework is being able to properly identify the

shocks and impulse responses. My ongoing research builds on the results of this paper

and further addresses the business cycle implications of news and noise shocks.

Page 133: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

125

References Adolfson, Malin, Stefan Laséen, Jesper Lindé, and Mattias Villani. 2007a. “Bayesian

Estimation of An Open Economy DSGE Model with Incomplete Pass-Through.”

Journal of International Economics, 72(2): 481-511.

Backus, David, Patrick Kehoe, and Finn Kydland. 1992. “International real business

cycles”. Journal of Political Economy, 100(4): 745– 775.

Barsky, Robert, and Eric Sims. 2009. “Information, Animal Spirits, and the Meaning

of Innovations in Consumer Confidence”. Unpublished.

Baxter, Marriane, 1995. “International trade and business cycles”, In: Grossman, G.,

Rogoff, K. (Eds.), Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3. Amsterdam, North-

Holland, pp. 1801–1864.

Baxter, Marianne, and Mario J. Crucini. 1993. “Explaining saving–investment

correlations.” American Economic Review, 83(3): 416– 436.

Baxter, Marianne, and Mario J. Crucini. 1995. “Business cycles and the asset

structure of foreign trade”. International Economic Review, 36(4): 821– 854.

Baxter, Marianne, and Darren Farr. 2005. “Variable capacity utilization and

international business cycles.” Journal of International Economics, 65(2): 335–347.

Beaudry, Paul, and Frank Portier. 2004 . “An Exploration into Pigou's Theory of

Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(6): 1183-1216.

Beaudry, Paul, and Frank Portier. 2006. “Stock prices, news and economic

fluctuations.” American Economic Review, 96(4): 1293-1307.

Beaudry, Paul and Frank Portier. 2007. “When can changes in expectations cause

business cycle fluctuations in neo-classical settings?” Journal of Economic Theory,

135(1): 458-477.

Beaudry, Paul, Martial Dupaigne, and Franck Portier. 2008. “The International

Propagation of Information Shocks”. Unpublished.

Bernard, Andrew, Jonathan Eaton, Bradford Jensen, and Samuel Kortum. 2003.

“Plants and Productivity in International Trade.” American Economic Review, 93(4):

1268-1290.

Blanchard, Olivier, Jean-Paul L’Huillier, and Guido Lorenzoni. 2009. “News, Noise,

and Fluctuations: An empirical exploration.” Unpublished.

Bloom, Nicholas, 2009. "The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks," Econometrica,

Econometric Society, 77(3): 623-685.

Page 134: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

126

Coibion, Olivier, and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2007. “Strategic Interaction Among

Price-Setters in an Estimated DSGE Model.” Unpublished.

De Walque, Grégory, Frank Smets, and Raf Wouters. 2005. “An Estimated Two-

Country DSGE Model for the Euro Area and the US Economy”. Unpublished.

Elliott, Graham, and Antonio Fatas. 1996. “International business cycles and the

dynamics of the current account.” European Economic Review, 40(2): 361-387.

Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus, and Juan Rubio-Ramirez. 2007. “How Structural are

Structural Parameters?” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 22, ed. Daron

Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff and Michael Woodford, 83–137. University of Chicago

Press.

Galí, Jordi, and Tommaso Monacelli. 2005. “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate

Volatility in a Small Open Economy.” Review of Economic Studies, 72(3): 707-734.

Harrigan, James. 1993. “OECD Imports and Trade Barriers in 1983”, Journal of

International Economics, 35(1-2), 91-111.

Ireland, Peter N. 2004. “Technology Shocks and the New Keynesian Model.”

Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(4): 923-936.

Jaimovich, Nir, and Sergio Rebelo. 2009. “Can News about the Future Drive the

Business Cycle?” American Economic Review, 99(4): 1097–1118.

Lorenzoni, Guido. 2008. Forthcoming. “A Theory of Demand Shocks.”American

Economic Review.

Lubik, Thomas, and Frank Schorfheide. 2005. “A Bayesian Look at New Open

Economy Macroeconomics.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, eds. Gertler, Mark and

Kenneth Rogoff, 313-366.

Reynolds, Patricia A., 1993. “International Comovements in Aggregate Productivity:

An Empirical Analysis.” Unpublished.

Wen, Yi. 2007. “By force of demand: Explaining international comovements.”

Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 31(1): 1–23.

Page 135: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

127

Figure 4.1

Impulse Responses to Technology Shocks

Dashed and Solid lines represent responses to foreign and domestic technology shocks,

respectively. The figure shows the percentage response relative to the initial non-stochastic

steady state for all variables aside from CPI and domestic inflation for which the response

shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero inflation.

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Output

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7Consumption

0 5 10 15 20-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Hours

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.2

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Exports

Page 136: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

128

Figure 4.2

Impulse Responses to News Shocks

Dashed and Solid lines represent responses to foreign and domestic news shocks,

respectively. The figure shows the percentage response relative to the initial non-stochastic

steady state for all variables aside from CPI and domestic inflation for which the response

shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero inflation.

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Output

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Consumption

0 5 10 15 20-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0

0.02

0.04Hours

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.08

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0

0.02CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.08

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0

0.02

0.04Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Exports

Page 137: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

129

Figure 4.3

Impulse Responses to Animal Spirits Shocks

Dashed and Solid lines represent responses to foreign and domestic noise shocks,

respectively. The figure shows the percentage response relative to the initial non-stochastic

steady state for all variables aside from inflation for which the response shown is the

percentage point deviation from the steady state zero inflation.

0 5 10 15 20-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05Output

0 5 10 15 200

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04Consumption

0 5 10 15 20-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05Hours

0 5 10 15 200

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-0.03

-0.02

-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05Exports

Page 138: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

130

Figure 4.4

Forecast Error Variance Decomposition

The figure shows the shares of the forecast error variances of output, consumption, CPI

inflation, and nominal exchange rate attributable to the six structural shocks of the model.

5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cast

Err

or

Output

Domestic News

Foreign News

Domestic Technology

Foreign Technology

Domestic Noise

Foreign Noise

5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cast

Err

or

Consumption

Domestic News

Foreign News

Domestic Technology

Foreign Technology

Domestic Noise

Foreign Noise

5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cast

Err

or

CPI Inflation

Domestic News

Foreign News

Domestic Technology

Foreign Technology

Domestic Noise

Foreign Noise

5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Time

Pro

po

rtio

n o

f F

ore

cast

Err

or

Nominal Exchange Rate

Domestic News

Foreign News

Domestic Technology

Foreign Technology

Domestic Noise

Foreign Noise

Page 139: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

131

Figure 4.5

Impulse Responses to Domestic Technology Shocks under

Alternative Policy Rules

Solid, dashed and dotted lines represent impulse responses to domestic technology shocks

under monetary policy rules (55), (58) and (59) respectively. The figure shows the percentage

response relative to the initial non-stochastic steady state for all variables aside from inflation

for which the response shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero

inflation.

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2Output

Benchmark

DITR

CITR

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Consumption

0 5 10 15 20-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2Hours

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 200

0.5

1

1.5Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2Exports

Page 140: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

132

Figure 4.6

Impulse Responses to Foreign Technology Shocks under

Alternative Policy Rules

Solid, dashed and dotted lines represent impulse responses to foreign technology shocks

under monetary policy rules (55), (58) and (59) respectively. The figure shows the percentage

response relative to the initial non-stochastic steady state for all variables aside from inflation

for which the response shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero

inflation.

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7Output

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Consumption

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4Hours

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-1

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-0.5

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7Exports

Benchmark

DITR

CITR

Page 141: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

133

Figure 4.7

Impulse Responses to Domestic News Shocks under Alternative

Policy Rules

Solid, dashed and dotted lines represent impulse responses to domestic news shocks under

monetary policy rules (55), (58) and (59) respectively. The figure shows the percentage

response relative to the initial non-stochastic steady state for all variables aside from inflation

for which the response shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero

inflation.

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Output

Benchmark

DITR

CITR

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Consumption

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1Hours

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Exports

Page 142: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

134

Figure 4.8

Impulse Responses to Foreign News Shocks under Alternative

Policy Rules

Solid, dashed and dotted lines represent impulse responses to foreign news shocks under

monetary policy rules (55), (58) and (59) respectively. The figure shows the percentage

response relative to the initial non-stochastic steady state for all variables aside from inflation

for which the response shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero

inflation.

0 5 10 15 200

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4Output

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Consumption

0 5 10 15 200

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08Hours

0 5 10 15 200

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 200

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-0.5

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4Exports

Benchmark

DITR

CITR

Page 143: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

135

Figure 4.9

Impulse Responses to Domestic Animal Spirits under

Alternative Policy Rules

Solid, dashed and dotted lines represent impulse responses to domestic noise shocks under

monetary policy rules (55), (58) and (59) respectively. The figure shows the percentage

response relative to the initial non-stochastic steady state for all variables aside from inflation

for which the response shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero

inflation.

0 5 10 15 200

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1Output

0 5 10 15 200

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06Consumption

0 5 10 15 200

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1Hours

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1Technology

0 5 10 15 200

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 200

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 200

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 200

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1Exports

Benchmark

DITR

CITR

Page 144: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

136

Figure 4.10

Impulse Responses to Foreign Animal Spirits under Alternative

Policy Rules

Solid, dashed and dotted lines represent impulse responses to foreign noise shocks under

monetary policy rules (55), (58) and (59) respectively. The figure shows the percentage

response relative to the initial non-stochastic steady state for all variables aside from inflation

for which the response shown is the percentage point deviation from the steady state zero

inflation.

0 5 10 15 20-0.02

0

0.02

0.04

0.06Output

0 5 10 15 200

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08Consumption

0 5 10 15 20-0.02

0

0.02

0.04

0.06Hours

0 5 10 15 20-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1Technology

0 5 10 15 20-0.03

-0.02

-0.01

0

0.01

0.02CPI Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-5

0

5

10

15x 10

-3Domestic Inflation

0 5 10 15 20-0.5

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0Nominal Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-0.05

-0.04

-0.03

-0.02

-0.01

0Real Exchange Rate

0 5 10 15 20-0.02

0

0.02

0.04

0.06Exports

Benchmark

DITR

CITR

Page 145: םיקסע ירוזחמ םיעינמה םיעוזעזה לע םירמאמarad.mscc.huji.ac.il/dissertations/W/JMS/001749582.pdf · 2013-04-17 · 1 Acknowledgements I would like to

137

Chapter V

Conclusion

The literature that has studied business cycles and their driving forces is a vast one.

This dissertation belongs to this literature in that it has taken a close look at potential

business cycle driving shocks. While chapter II and III provide empirical evidence

that IST news shocks and credit supply shocks have the potential of generating

business cycles, chapter IV offers a theoretical open economy framework in which the

effects of news shocks and noise shocks can be studied. All three chapters deal with

potential sources of the business cycles in which a great deal of interest has been

shown recently by the business cycle literature.

The results found in chapter II are the strongest in the sense that they put

forward a shock that generates business cycles in a dominant manner. From an

empirical standpoint, I think it would be worthwhile for future research to focus on

extending the study of these shocks to other economies, both large and small. On the

theoretical front, it would be interesting for future research to continue to explore

additional frameworks in which these shocks are business cycle drivers. The findings

in chapter III are important in that they are able to provide evidence of a demand

shock that is capable of generating business cycles and in fact has done so in terms of

contributing to six of the last nine U.S recessions, being the most dominant in the

recent recession. Combining the findings of chapters II and III, we have two shocks

that drive the business cycle and account well for post war business cycles.

Chapter IV is related to the news and noise shocks literature and thus is

naturally linked to chapter II which also belongs to the news shocks literature. It

seems interesting for future research to try to empirically gauge the role of noise

shocks in a framework of the kind that was used in chapter IV. In particular, it seems

especially challenging to do so without imposing any structure on the data but rather

using a model free approach such as the one employed in chapters II and III. This is

mainly difficult because there aren't enough identifying restrictions from the

theoretical model that an econometrician can rely upon in order to identify these

shocks.