34
Discussion Paper No. 0114 Adelaide University SA 5005, AUSTRALIA Lobbying, Trade and Renewable Resource Harvesting Richard Damania and E. Barbier April 2001

Lobbying, Trade and Renewable Resource Harvesting

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Discussion PaperNo. 0114

Adelaide UniversitySA 5005, AUSTRALIA

Lobbying, Trade and Renewable ResourceHarvesting

Richard Damania and E. Barbier

April 2001

CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC STUDIES

The Centre was established in 1989 by the Economics Department of the AdelaideUniversity to strengthen teaching and research in the field of international economics andclosely related disciplines. Its specific objectives are:

• to promote individual and group research by scholars within and outside the AdelaideUniversity

• to strengthen undergraduate and post-graduate education in this field

• to provide shorter training programs in Australia and elsewhere

• to conduct seminars, workshops and conferences for academics and for the widercommunity

• to publish and promote research results

• to provide specialised consulting services

• to improve public understanding of international economic issues, especially amongpolicy makers and shapers

Both theoretical and empirical, policy-oriented studies are emphasised, with a particularfocus on developments within, or of relevance to, the Asia-Pacific region. The Centre’sExecutive Director is Professor Kym Anderson (Email [email protected]) andDeputy Director, Dr Randy Stringer (Email [email protected]).

Further details and a list of publications are available from:

Executive AssistantCIESSchool of EconomicsAdelaide UniversitySA 5005 AUSTRALIATelephone: (+61 8) 8303 5672Facsimile: (+61 8) 8223 1460Email: [email protected]

Most publications can be downloaded from our Home page athttp://www.adelaide.edu.au/cies/

ISSN 1445-3746 series, electronic publication

CIES DISCUSSION PAPER 0114

Lobbying, Trade and Renewable Resource Harvesting

Richard Damania and E. Barbier

Adelaide UniversitySchool of Economics and CIES

SA 5005, [email protected]

andUniversity of Wyoming

April 2001

Copyright 2001 Richard Damania and E.Barbier________________________________________________________________________

ABSTRACT

Lobbying, Trade and Renewable Resource Harvesting

Richard Damania and E. Barbier

The over-exploitation of renewable resources has intensified international concerns over the

management of these resources. This has prompted calls for the use of international policy

interventions such as trade sanctions and contingent transfers, to encourage sustainable

resource management practices in these countries. A growing body of literature suggests

that resource harvesting in these countries is largely determined by the rent seeking

activities of special interest groups This paper develops a model to assess the interaction

between lobbying, trade and the incentives to extract a renewable resource. It is

demonstrated that in a lobbying equilibrium trade sanctions may be counterproductive and

lead to greater harvesting of the renewable resource. The paper further considers whether

aid in the form of international transfers can be used to encourage more sustainable

harvesting practices. We find that when resource stocks are sufficiently low, transfers may

also fail to reduce over-exploitation of the resource. However, it is possible to design a

transfer scheme that overcomes this problem. Thus, an appropriately designed system of

transfers is likely to be more effective in promoting sustainable harvesting practices.

JEL Codes: Q23, Q28, D78, F19.

Keywords: Trade Sanctions, Environment, Renewable Resources, Political Economy.

Keywords:

JEL codes:

Contact author(s):

Richard DamaniaAdelaide UniversitySchool of Economics and CIESSA 5005, AUSTRALIATel: +61 8 8303 4933Fax: +618 8223 [email protected]

2

I IntroductionConcerns over the management of renewable resources have intensified in

recent years. Perhaps the most widely publicized example is the loss of tropical

rainforests, which have been the focus of international negotiations since the Rio

Earth Summit in 1992. Similar problems have emerged in other contexts too, such as

the over-exploitation of fish stocks and wildlife1.

A recent and growing body of literature suggests that lobbying by special

interest groups is one of the major causes of environmental damage in countries

endowed with a relative abundance of renewable resources. For instance, in a survey

of environmental policies in ten developing countries Desai (1998) asserts that:

"….political elites use their power to.. exploit their countries' vast natural

resources in partnership with selected businesses, with no regard to

environmental degradation." (p 15)

This conclusion is reinforced in numerous other case studies. According to Broad

(1998), timber harvesting licenses in the Philippines were granted to firms with close

links to government officials. Moreover, the funds generated from timber concessions

were used to finance electoral campaigns. Similar problems are identified in

Indonesia, where logging concessions have been awarded to a small group of

conglomerates associated with the ruling political party (Hafner (1998)). Other

examples include logging in the tropical hardwood forests of Thailand, India and

Malaysia with concessions being granted to firms who engage in intensive political

lobbying.2 What these and other surveys reveal is that declining stocks of natural

1 Common examples of wild animals threatened with extinction through over-harvesting includeelephants (who are harvested for ivory), rhinoceros (who are sought for their horns) and tigers (whosebones and organs are demanded for their presumed therapeutic properties) (TRAFFIC Network Report(1997, 1998)).2 Rainforest News Spring, 1999. See also Bromley (1999) for a discussion of the role of politicalinstitutions and rent seking.

3

forests have done little to slow the pace of harvesting. Moreover, lobbying and

political influence are critical in determining who obtains a timber license and how

much timber is extracted.

Despite the prevalence of these problems, the existing literature has failed to

examine the impact of special interest lobbying on resource harvesting decisions.

This issue is of economic significance for at least two reasons. Firstly, political

factors appear to be responsible for a major reallocation of global renewable

resources. Thus, an understanding of the effects of lobbying on resource harvesting is

of considerable economic relevance. Secondly, many of these renewable resources

confer significant cross-border external benefits3. This has prompted calls for the use

of various policies, such as trade sanctions and transfers, to coerce these nations to

reduce the level of resource exploitation. It is clearly important to determine whether

such interventions strengthen or weaken the distorting influence of lobby groups on

domestic resource management decisions. This paper represents a first step in

analyzing these issues. It is shown that there are circumstances when trade

interventions may be counterproductive and lead to greater harvesting of the resource.

Similarly, when resource stocks are low conditional transfers may also be ineffective

and simply induce more intense lobbying by resource extractors. The results thus

highlight the manner in which lobbying can negate international efforts to influence

harvesting policy.

The paper extend Grossman and Helpman's (1994) common agency model of

lobbying to the case of a renewable resource4. Accordingly, it is assumed that a self-

interested government cares not only about aggregate welfare, but also the political

3 For instance, forests may provide transboundary amenities in their role as stores of carbon, geneticmaterial and the existence values associated with species who reside in these habitats.4 This model has been previously applied to study static environmental externalities by Fredriksson(1997, 1999).

4

contributions that it receives from lobby groups. Political donations influence the

government’s decisions because of their many uses such as consolidating power,

funding election campaigns and deterring rivals. It is assumed that the incumbent

government determines the quantity of a renewable resource that is to be harvested by

issuing a license which defines the maximum allowable harvest. An industry group

lobbies the government for greater access to the resource by offering political

contributions. The government chooses the harvest to maximize its own welfare.

Since the analysis focuses upon the effects of lobbying by resource extractors,

the role of an opposing environmental lobby group is suppressed. As noted by Desai

(op cit) this seems reasonable for developing countries where environmental

movements are often centered in poor rural communities, which have little influence

on policy decisions. 5

We begin by analyzing the impact of trade sanctions on resource stocks. It is

demonstrated that if the government placed a high value on political contributions,

then trade sanctions may lead to lower stocks of the renewable resource in

equilibrium. Intuitively, this reflects the fact that in a lobbying equilibrium, the

contributions of the lobby group mirror the profits that are obtained from a given

harvest. When sanctions are imposed, the profits from harvesting decline and

political contributions fall. A government that values political donations sufficiently

will adopt policies to mitigate the decline in profits and contributions. It does this by

5 Alternatively, the neglect of an environmental lobby group may be justified by assuming that thedamage from harvesting is so widely dispersed that it does not induce the affected individuals to form alobby group. In the parlance of Baron (1994) this represents a particularist policy, where the benefitsof harvesting are concentrated, but the environmental costs are so thinly spread that they do not providesufficient incentive for individuals to organize a lobby group, or make political donations. Moregenerally, this assumption would hold if the external costs of harvesting are non-pecuniary and thinlyspread over those who either lack funds or are credit constrained (e.g. the poor), while the benefits ofharvesting are pecuniary and concentrated. It is of further interest to note that in developed countriestoo environmental lobby groups seldom contribute funds directly to either governments or politicalparties. In a number of countries such as the Australia, New Zealand and the UK environmental groupshave received (modest) funds from the government

5

increasing the harvest rate. Thus, resource stocks decline in response to trade

sanctions. This result suggests that it may be difficult to predict the environmental

consequences of trade sanctions, since the eventual impact depends upon the

parameters of the problem and institutional arrangements. Caution may therefore

need to be exercised in using trade interventions as a resource management tool.

We then consider whether international transfers, which are contingent upon

environmental objectives, can be used to reduce over-exploitation of the resource.

Examples of such schemes include: debt-for-nature swaps, World Bank funding for

projects to counter deforestation (e.g. the Global Environmental Fund) and aid which

is conditional upon certain environmental criteria. The common feature of all these

initiatives is that the transfer is linked to certain environmental objectives. In this

paper we focus upon a simple scheme where the level of funds transferred to the

harvesting nation is conditional upon stocks of the resource.

It is shown that when resource stocks are low, transfers may fail to curb the

incentive to over-harvest the resource. Intuitively, in deciding whether to increase

resource stocks the government must trade off the benefits from the transfer against

the potential loss of political contributions. We identify the circumstances under

which the fall in political donations may outweigh the payoffs from the transfer. This

occurs when harvesting is highly profitable, so that political contributions are high

and resource stocks are low.

The paper further investigates whether it is possible to design a transfer

schedule which overcomes this problem. It is shown that if the transfer function rises

sufficiently rapidly at low resource stocks (i.e. is sufficiently concave), then transfers

will always induce the government to increase equilibrium stocks. Intuitively, a

concave transfer function strengthens the government's incentive to maintain stocks

6

when they are at low levels. However, this is precisely when the profits from

harvesting and the political contributions paid to the government are relatively high.

Hence, a sufficiently concave transfer function is required to curb the influence of the

lobbyist on policy decisions. Moreover, if there are significant cross-border

externalities associated with the resource, such transfers may be viewed as a means of

internalizing externalities and promoting more efficient resource usage.

Formally, the analysis is based on the following sequence of events. In the

political equilibrium, the firm chooses its political contribution and the government

sets the quota, which defines the maximum allowable harvest. Given knowledge of

these parameters the firm then decides its harvest. The model is solved by backward

induction.

There is a vast and burgeoning literature on the interaction between trade and

the environment. These studies can be divided into three broad categories. First,

there are models that examine the impact of trade on the political economy of

environmental policy formation in the presence of a static externality. This literature

while relatively modest in size, examines a variety of issues, such as the effects of

comparative advantage and trade protection on lobbying (e.g. Fredriksson (1999),

Liedy and Hoeckman (1994)). In contrast, a distinct body of work investigates the

consequences of trade on stocks of a renewable resource. The conventional view

holds that trade sanctions make harvesting less profitable and thus protect resource

stocks (Daly and Cobb (1989)). This conclusion been challenged in numerous recent

studies which suggest that the higher prices which result from trade may provide the

incentives necessary to profitably invest in the resource (Swanson (1990), Schulz

(1996), Barbier and Schulz (1997)). Finally, models of international trade have been

used to assess the consequences of trade with either an open access resource, or an

7

externality. The efficiency effects of trade are often found to be ambiguous, since in a

second best equilibrium trade may lower welfare (see, e.g. Chichlnisky (1994),

Brander and Taylor (1997), (1998)). The contribution of this paper differs from

previous work in several significant ways. Most obviously, we deal with the

influence of a lobby group on policy decisions in a renewable resource context.

There is also a growing literature on the role of aid which is conditional upon

environmental protection. Much of this work focuses on two key issues: the structure

and effectiveness contracts (e.g. Deacon and Murphy (1997), Soest and Lensink

(2000)) and the conditions that must be satisfied for such contracts to be self

enforcing (Chambers et al (1996)). To our knowledge none of this literature has

assessed the effectiveness of transfers when policies are influence by special interest

group lobbying.

The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. Section II outlines the

main structure of the model. Sections III and IV derive the equilibria under trade

sanctions and transfers respectively. Section V concludes the paper.

II The ModelThe main objective of this paper is to examine whether trade sanctions and

other international policy interventions strengthen or weaken the influence of lobby

groups on the harvesting decisions of a self interested government. We therefore

consider a situation where the government is responsible for management of a

resource and determines the harvest by issuing quotas. The quotas define the

maximum allowable harvest in any period. The harvester seeks to influence the

government's decisions by offering political contributions to the government.

8

Let x denote the stock of the renewable resource at a given point in time. The

biological growth of the resource F(x), is a function of the existing stock. It is

assumed that Fxx < 0.6 Changes in the stock depend on the biological growth rate

(F(x)) and the harvest rate (h):

dxx F(x) h

dt= = −& (1)

It is well known that under conditions of open access there is a strong

incentive for firms to over-harvest a renewable resource. The causes and solutions to

this problem have been extensively studied in the literature. However, less attention

has been paid to the role of lobby groups on resource management issues. To isolate

the effects of lobbying on policy decisions, this paper abstracts from open access

problems. Instead it is assumed that a single firm is granted a license to harvest the

resource.7 For simplicity it is further supposed that the firm's property rights are

adequately defined, in the sense that the firm has an incentive to maximise long run

profits.

The net present value of the firm's profits are defined as:

t t

t 0 t 0

e dt e (b(p,x)h S)dt∞ ∞

− −

= =

Π = −∫ ∫δ δ (2a)

where: δ is the given discount rate, p is the given world price of the resource, h is the

harvest, b(p, x) is the per unit profits from harvesting which depends on the price (p)

and available stocks of the resource (x). S defines the political contributions of the

firm in each period. In keeping with the existing literature it is supposed that bp > 0,

bx > 0, bxx ≤ 0, bpx = 0 (see, e.g., Schulze (1996)). Finally, for simplicity it is assumed

that the entire harvest is exported overseas at a given world price (p). This stylised

6 Subscripts denote partial derivatives.7 As noted in later sections the analysis extends to the case of n > 1 firms.

9

assumption allows us to focus on the interaction between trade policy and resource

management.

Profits in equation (2a) are maximised subject to two constraints8. The first is

equation (1), which describes the growth of the resource. In addition, since the

government determines the maximum allowable harvest, the harvest rate in any period

cannot exceed the allowable quota (hk). Thus the second constraint is given by:

h ≤ hk (2b)

In what follows, we assume that the constraint in (2b) always binds so that the actual

harvest rate depends on the government's allocation decisions.9

For any given harvest rate determined by the government (hk), the firm will

choose its lobbying contributions (S) to maximise the net present value of profits,

subject to the constraints in equations (1) and (2b). In the Appendix it is

demonstrated that lobbying contributions satisfy the necessary condition:

b(p,x) - xh

x

b hS

F=

−δ(3)

In what follows attention is focused only on long run steady state equilibria.

Thus, F(x) = h must be satisfied for the long run equilibrium stock. Note that b(p,x) -

x

x

b hF−δ

is the usual net bio-economic return from harvesting. Equation (3) reveals

that profit maximising contributions are defined by the condition that the marginal

cost of lobbying for a greater harvest (i.e. Sh), equals the net marginal benefit of the

harvest.

Resource harvesting often generates externalities. In keeping with the existing

literature it is assumed that there are non-consumptive values associated with the

8 In the current context maximising the net present value of profits would be rational if the firm knowsthat its political contributions influence allocation decisions and hence current and future harvest rates.9 If this were not the case, then on the margin lobbying would not influence harvesting.

10

resource. For forests, these may include watershed protection, salinity prevention,

soil conservation, wildlife habitat and tourism. These are defined by D(x). Non-

consumptive values are increasing in resource stocks at a non-increasing rate:

x xxD 0,D 0.> ≤

The Welfare Maximising Benchmark:

We begin by describing the welfare maximising equilibrium, which is used as

a benchmark for comparison with the lobbying equilibrium. In the absence of

lobbying, the government will choose a harvest rate to maximize the net present value

of social welfare. Welfare in any period is given by the sum of utility of all agents in

the model10:

W(h) = b(p,x)h + D(x) (4a)

The welfare maximising harvest rate is determined by the solution to:

t

ht 0

M a x e W(h)dtδ∞

=∫ (4b)

subject to: x F(x) h= −&

In a steady state, the long run equilibrium harvest satisfies:11

b(p,x) x x

x

D b hF

+−

−δ= 0 (5)

where F(x) = h must hold in the long run equilibrium.

As is well established, in the welfare maximising equilibrium the marginal bio-

economic return to the firm is equated to the marginal loss from resource depletion.

IV The Political Equilibrium

10 Welfare is thus defined by profits plus non-consumptive benefits. Clearly, political contributionscancel out, since contributions paid by the firm are received by the government.11 See the Appendix for details.

11

Having described the welfare maximising outcome, we now turn to the

political equilibrium. The government is assumed to be self interested and derives

utility from lobby group contributions and social welfare. Following Grossman and

Helpman (1994), the government’s objective function is given by a weighted sum of

the political contributions it receives and aggregate social welfare. The discounted

payoffs to the government are defined by:

G(h) = t

t 0

e δ∞

=∫ (S + αW(h))dt (6a)

where α ≥ 0 is the weight given to aggregate social welfare (W(h)), relative to

political contributions (S).

Note that α represents the government’s willingness to set policies that deviate

from the welfare maximizing level, in return for contributions. Accordingly, α may

be interpreted as a measure of the level of corruption. This is consistent with the

World Bank's (1999) definition of "… corruption as the use of public office for

private gain”.

Given the profit maximising contributions as defined in equation (3), the

government chooses the harvest rate to maximise its discounted utility (i.e. equation

6a), subject to the resource growth constraint in equation (1). In the Appendix it is

shown that the harvest which maximises the government's payoffs satisfies:

x x

x x

b h D(b )(1 ) 0

F F− + − =

− −α

αδ δ

(6b)

As noted earlier, attention is focused on long run steady state equilibria where h =

F(x).

It is instructive to briefly compare the welfare maximizing harvest, with that

under lobbying. Observe that in (6b) terms which relate to the lobbyist's payoffs

12

receive a weight of (1 + α) in equilibrium, while all other terms are given a weight of

α. The government therefore behaves as if it were maximizing a welfare function

which gives the lobbyist's utility a weight of (1 + α) and that of all other agents a

weight of α. Hence, the political equilibrium policy is distorted in favor of the lobby

group's preferences. Alternatively, this may be seen by noting that as α → 0,

equation (6b) converges to the necessary condition under profit maximising:

x

x

b hb 0

F− =

−δ. This suggests that when social welfare considerations are completely

ignored, the lobbyist's preferred solution eventuates.12 This result is summarised in

the following Proposition.

Proposition 1: Ceteris paribus, the harvest rate in the political equilibrium exceeds

that in the welfare maximising equilibrium.

Proof: See Appendix.

For future reference we now outline an important property of the political

equilibrium. Recall that the government selects the harvest rate, while the firm

chooses contributions. Thus, an equilibrium for this game is a contribution and a

harvest for each period, such that: (i) the contribution is feasible 13; (ii) the harvest

policy hL maximizes the government’s welfare, G(hL), taking the contribution as

given (Grossman and Helpman (1994)). From Lemma 2 of Bernheim and Whinston

(1986) the following necessary conditions yield an equilibrium of the political game:

(MI) hL Maximises G(h); subject to x F(x) h= −&

(MII) hL Maximises J )h(Gdt)h(e0t

t +Π∫≡∞

=

δ− ; subject to x F(x) h= −&

12 Conversely, when α → ∞ the solution in equation (6b) approaches that of the welfare maximisingequilibrium in (4c).

13

Condition (MI) asserts that the equilibrium harvest hL must maximize the

government’s payoff, given the contribution offered. Condition (MII) requires that hL

must also maximize the joint payoffs of the firm and the government. If this

condition is not satisfied, the firm will have an incentive to alter its strategy to induce

the government to change the harvest rate, and capture more of the surplus. In the

Appendix we show that maximizing (MI) and (MII) and performing the appropriate

substitutions, yields the political equilibrium contribution schedule of the lobby

group, which satisfies:

b(p,x) - xh

x

b hS

F=

−δ(7a)

Equation (7a) reveals that in equilibrium, the change in the firm’s political

contributions (i.e. Sh), equals the effect of the harvest on its payoffs (i.e. b(p,x) -

x

x

b hF−δ

). Thus, as noted by Grossman and Helpman (1994), the political contributions

are locally truthful.14

Observe that the contributions required to satisfy the political equilibrium of

the game (equation (7a)), are exactly equal to the individually rational contributions

of the firm as defined in equation (3). This equivalence implies that the individually

rational (Nash) contributions that maximise a firm's profits (i.e. (3)), are equal to the

contributions necessary for an equilibrium of the political game (i.e. (7a)). More

significantly, it can be demonstrated that this result generalizes to the case of a lobby

group with n > 1 firms. That is, if each firm takes the contribution levels of its rivals’

as given, its Nash contribution will satisfy condition (7a). This suggests that the

political equilibrium does not require contributions from firms in a lobby group

13 In this context this is taken to imply that the contribution must be non-negative. That is the lobbygroup cannot "tax" the government.

14

beyond the individually rational level. Thus, lobbying is not constrained by free-

riding in this model. 15

Finally, we note that the equilibrium level of contributions to the government

is given by the difference in social welfare when resource stocks are at their welfare

maximizing level (xw), and at the political equilibrium (xL) (Grossman and Helpman

(op cit)). Specifically, the necessary contribution to the government from the lobby

group is defined by

S = w L[W(x ) W(x )],α − (7b)

Note that w L[W(x ) W(x )]α − defines the utility loss to the government when resource

stocks deviate from the welfare maximizing level. Thus, the contributions perfectly

compensate the government for the welfare loss associated with the participation of

the industry lobby group in the policy process. The welfare loss is weighted by α in

order to adjust for its importance in the government’s objective function.

Trade sanctions have often been proposed as a tool to reduce harvesting and

encourage sustainable resource management practices. Such policies have been

justified on the grounds that they lower profits and thus diminish the incentive to

deplete resources (see, e.g., Daly and Cobb (1989)). We now determine the effect of

trade sanctions on the government's harvesting policy in the political equilibrium.

Following Barbier and Schulze (1997) and Schulze (1996), for simplicity it is

assumed that trade sanctions lower the price received by producers of the resource.

14 As in Bernheim and Whinston (1986), this can be extended to global truthfulness wherecontributions accurately represents the preferences of the lobbyist for all feasible h.15 Free-riding does not prevent lobbying in the model because the political equilibrium is sustained bythe profit maximising contributions of each firm. This issue appears to have been overlooked in theliterature and it has generally been assumed that lobbying can be undermined by free-riding in thismodel. Moreover, the political equilibrium is identical whether the lobbyists are assumed to be"groups" representing an entire industry or simply the firms acting individually. Intuitively, this followsdirectly from the local truthfulness condition . Since the focus of this paper is on resource policy issuesrather than free-riding in lobby groups, these important issues are ignored for brevity.

15

Proposition 2: If the government places sufficient weight on political contributions,

then trade sanctions may lower equilibrium stocks of the natural resource.

(i.e. A necessary condition for dx/dp > 0 is that Fx > 0 and Fx is declining in α (i.e.

Fxα < 0). Hence for sufficiently low α, dx/dp > 0)

Proof: See Appendix

Intuitively this result may be explained as follows. Recall that α is the weight

given to social welfare in the government's objective function. Thus, when α is low,

political contributions are (relatively) highly valued by the government. Since trade

sanctions lower prices then, ceteris paribus, profits will decline. We know that

political contributions are locally truthful and mirror the profitability of any harvest

policy (i.e. equation (7a)). Thus, as profits decline, by local truthfulness, political

contributions fall. A government that places a high value on political donations will

seek to mitigate the decline in contributions. It does this by increasing the lobbyist's

access to the resource. Hence resource stocks decrease.

This result has important policy consequences. It suggests that sanctions

imposed on highly corrupt regimes, which place a low weight on social welfare

considerations, may worsen environmental outcomes. This occurs because a given

harvest yields a smaller benefit (i.e. contribution) to the government. If contributions

vary with resource access, a corrupt government responds to sanctions by increasing

the harvest rate in order to restore its contributions. While this conclusion may seem

obvious, it does not appear to have been identified in the literature.

16

IV. International Transfers

Since lobbying can render trade sanctions ineffective, it is important to

determine whether international transfers could be used to induce more sustainable

harvesting practices. Examples of such initiatives include debt-for-nature swaps and

the World Bank's Global Environmental Fund (GEF)16. The distinguishing feature of

these schemes is that the transfer is conditional upon environmental improvements

being undertaken in the recipient nations. Countries are thus are rewarded rather than

coerced to optimally manage their resources. For simplicity we focus on the common

element in these schemes and consider the effects of a transfer which is increasing in

stocks of the resource.

Let R(x) be the per period transfer schedule that is offered to the harvesting

nation. It is supposed that the transfer is increasing in resource stocks. Thus, Rx > 0.

At this stage we place no restriction on the shape of the transfer function. Hence, the

sign of the second derivative, Rxx, is left unrestricted.17

Since the government is assumed to be self interested and corrupt, it is

possible that part (or all) of the transfer may be subverted by the government for

either personal or political purposes. We allow for this by assuming that (1 - θ)R(x)

of the funds are embezzled by the government for its own uses18 The remaining

θR(x) of the funds, are distributed to the population in a lump sum manner. Thus, the

government's objective function is given by:

G(h) = t

t 0

e δ∞

=∫ (S + (1 - θ)R(x) + α(b(p,x)h+D(x) + θR(x))dt (8a)

16 Debt-for-nature swaps usually involve a portion of national debt being converted at a discount to anenvironmental fund. On the other hand, GEF provides direct funding for environmental projects infour key categories: bio-diversity preservation, climate change, water pollution and ozone depletion.17 The timing of events is as follows. In the first stage the donor country offers the transfer function.The following stage determines the political equilibrium in which the firm chooses contributions andthe government the quota. In the final stage the firm selects its harvest rate.

17

In the Appendix it is shown that the political equilibrium harvest is defined by the

condition:

x x x

x x

b h D R(b )(1 ) 0

F F +

− + − = − −

α σα

δ δ(8b)

where: σ = (1 - θ(1 - α)).

In equilibrium the weighted marginal payoff to the lobbyist is equated to the weighted

marginal loss from resource depletion and the marginal reduction in transfers. Note

that terms which directly increase the government's payoffs (i.e. factors that determine

political contributions and the proportion of transfer funds diverted by the government

for it's own use) are given greater weight than all other terms.

We now assess the impact of a transfer on the lobbying equilibrium. We

begin by investigating the effects on the level of lobby group contributions.

Proposition 3a: Ceteris paribus, the offer of a higher transfer per unit of the resource

conserved, leads to more intense lobbying by the harvesting firm.

(i.e. Sr

∂∂

> 0)

Proposition 3a reveals that an increase in transfers results in higher contributions by

the harvesting firm. The intuition for this result is as follows. Recall from equation

(7b) that the harvest is increased beyond the welfare maximising equilibrium, only if

the lobbyist adequately compensates the government for the utility loss that it suffers.

Ceteris paribus, an increase in transfers raises the government's payoffs from

conserving resource stocks. To compensate for this, the lobby group is therefore

compelled to increase its contributions. Stated differently, higher transfers raise the

18 Clearly we assume that θ ≤ 1.

18

opportunity cost to the government of resource depletion. This in turn necessitates a

larger contribution from the resource extractor.

Having determined the impact of transfers on political contributions we now

turn to the effect on resource stocks. Proposition 3b identifies the circumstances

under which the transfer may fail to curb over-harvesting of the resource.

Proposition 3b: If initial stocks of the resource are sufficiently low, then the offer of a

higher transfer per unit of the resource conserved may fail to induce the government

to increase resource stocks.

(i.e. dx/dr< 0 if Fx > Ψ > 0)

Proof: See Appendix

The intuition for this result is as follows. The offer of a higher transfer perturbs the

initial equilibrium in a number of conflicting ways. Firstly, it raises the payoffs to the

government from conserving resource stocks (i.e. the opportunity cost of resource

depletion increases). Moreover, by Proposition 3a an increase in the transfer also

induces higher political contributions and more intense lobbying. The government

must therefore trade-off the higher benefits from conservation against those from

resource depletion. Clearly, if the payoffs from increased political contributions

exceed those from the transfer, the government will find it optimal not to raise

resource stocks. Proposition 3b reveals that this is likely to occur when harvesting is

highly profitable, so that (by local truthfulness) political contributions are relatively

high and resource stocks are low19 An implication of this result is that transfers will

19 Note that when harvesting is highly profitable, then ceteris paribus stocks tend to be relatively low.Thus, this result obtains when resource stocks are relatively low. Formally, since Fxx < 0, then arelatively large value of Fx corresponds to lower stocks. Hence, the result in Proposition 3b hold forvalues of Fx > Ψ > 0.

19

be less effective in curbing over-harvesting in corrupt regimes with well organized

lobby groups.

It is worth noting that this conclusion is broadly consistent with the empirical

results of Deacon and Murphy (1997), who find that the probability of a debt-for-

nature swap being accepted is increasing in the level of democracy in the recipient

country. Proposition 3b may provide a theoretical explanation for the Deacon and

Murphy findings, if regimes which place a greater weight on political contributions

are also less democratic.

Since transfers may be ineffective when resource stocks are low, it is

important to determine whether it is possible to design a transfer function which

overcomes this problem. 20 This issue is addressed in Proposition 3c.

Proposition 3c: If the transfer function rises sufficiently steeply at low stock levels

(i.e. is sufficiently concave in resource stocks), then higher transfers always lead to

higher equilibrium resource stocks.

(i.e. dx/dr > 0 if Rxx < Ω ≡ ( )( )x xx xx xx1

b F b b F (1 ) Dδ − − + α − ασ

)

Proof: See Appendix.

Intuitively this result may be explained as follows. Recall that a concave transfer

function rises relatively steeply at low stock levels. Hence, it strengthens the

government's incentive to maintain stocks when they are at low levels. However, this

20 The need for corrective policies might be most urgent if harvesting leads to a high utility loss whenstocks are low. This may occur if the risk of species extinction is greater at low stock levels. Notable,though little publicized examples of such situations, include logging in the Sumatran forests which arethe last remaining refuge of the Sumatran tiger (Panthera tigris sumatrae) which is listed as criticallyendangered by the IUCN, timber felling in Kaziranga Protected Area in India which is one of the fewremaining habitats of critically endangered species such as the one-horned rhino (Rhinocerosunicornus) and the Bengal tiger (Panthera tigris tigris) (Sanctuary Asia, December 2000).

20

is precisely when contributions are relatively high. Hence, a sufficiently concave

transfer function can mitigate the influence of the lobbyist and encourage more

sustainable harvesting. Moreover, if there are significant cross-border externalities

associated with the resource, such transfers may be viewed as a means of internalizing

externalities and promoting more efficient resource usage.

V Conclusions and Implications

This paper has examined how trade and lobbying influence the resource

management policies of a self interested government. It was shown that lobbying by

resource extractors will result in over-exploitation of the resource. The paper thus

considered whether trade sanctions could be used to induce more sustainable resource

harvesting policies. It was demonstrated that trade sanctions lead to lower stocks of

the renewable resource in equilibrium if the government values political donations

sufficiently. This occurs because sanctions lower the profits obtained from a given

harvest. The resource therefore yields a smaller benefit (i.e. contribution) to the

government. A government that values political donations sufficiently will adopt

policies to mitigate the decline in profits and contributions. It does this by increasing

the harvest rate. This result suggests that in corrupt regimes, which place a high value

on political contributions, trade sanctions may be counterproductive. Accordingly,

caution may need to be exercised in using trade interventions as a resource

management tool.

It was further demonstrated that transfers, if properly designed, can be used to

induce more sustainable harvesting practices. For this to occur it is necessary for the

payoffs to the government from higher transfers to exceed those from lobbying. This

requires that the transfer function rises sufficiently steeply at low stock levels, thus

21

strengthening the government's incentive to conserve stocks when contributions are

likely to be relatively high.

It is worth noting that this paper has ignored a number of important issues.

Perhaps the most significant is the open access problem which has been neglected for

two reasons. First as noted earlier, open access issues have been extensively analyzed

in the literature and are ignored in this paper in order to focus on the effects of

lobbying by harvesters. More importantly, we abstract from open access problems

because lobbying and other rent seeking activities cannot be sustained under

conditions of complete free entry. To see why, observe that if incumbents

successfully lobby for greater access to a resource, this will attract new entrants into

the industry. New entry will erode the higher profits obtained through lobbying.

Thus, a rational incumbent will have little incentive to lobby, since this would allow

potential entrants to free ride on its lobbying efforts. This suggests that lobbying is

individually rational only when entry into the industry is at least partly restricted. The

assumption of restricted entry is arguably a reasonable stylized description of the

commercial (i.e. non- subsistence) forestry sector in a number of countries such as

Malaysia, India and Indonesia where logging concessions have been awarded to a few

established players. The relevance to other resource issues such as poaching of

wildlife, where open access problems are more pervasive, is questionable.21

A further simplification in the model is the assumption that the lobbyist has

secure future access to the resource and thus maximises long run profits. It can be

shown that all the qualitative conclusions of this paper hold for the case where the

lobbyist is granted a license for only one period and thus maximises one period

21 Note also that this paper does not consider other causes of deforestation arising from rural activitiessuch as fuelwood collection, grazing and agriculture, all of which have been analysed in the literature.

22

payoffs22. The conclusions in this paper are thus robust to variations in the temporal

distribution of property rights.

Finally, it is important to note that the analysis is restricted to the long run

steady state properties of the political equilibrium. In a dynamic framework, current

actions will depend upon the history of the game. In order to render the analysis

tractable, this paper has focused upon steady state equilibria where the history of the

game is stationary. 23 It may be useful in future research to explore a political

economy equilibrium in which current decisions depend upon a time varying history

of the game. This would involve a major extension of the common agency model

which may not be amenable to an analytical solution. However, this is a problem that

warrants further investigation.

22 An appendix proving the results for one period maximisation is available upon request.23 Alternatively, if a dynamic programming framework were adopted a stationary history could berepresented by analyzing the Markov perfect equilibria.

23

APPENDIXDerivation of Equation (3):Given a harvest rate (h), the current-value Hamiltonian of the problem is:

H b(p,x)h S (F(x) h)= − + −µ (A1)where µ is the costate variableAssuming an interior solution the first-order conditions for the control problem are:

SdH

(b(p,x) )h 1 0dS

= − − =µ (A2)

x xb h F= − −&µ δµ µ (A3)dH

x F(x) hdµ

= = −& (A4)

Following Grossman and Helpman (1994), it is assumed that hs > 0.24 In a long runequilibrium x 0µ= =& & , using this condition, performing the appropriate substitutionsand rearranging yields:

b(p,x) - xh

x

b hS

F=

−δ(A5)

Derivation of Equation (5):The current-value Hamiltonian of the welfare maximising problem is:

H = b(p,x)h + D(x) +µ(F(x) - h) (A6)

Assuming an interior solution the first-order conditions for the control problem are:dH

b(p,x)dh

= − µ = 0 (A7)

x x x(b h D F )= − + +&µ δµ µ (A8)dH

x F(x) hdµ

= = −& (A9)

In a long run equilibrium x 0µ= =& & , thus:

b(p,x) - x x

x

D b hF

+−δ

= 0 (A10)

Derivation of Equation (6b):As noted in the text, it is assumed that h= hk. For notational brevity the superscript(k) is ignored hereafter. The current-value Hamiltonian of the government's utilitymaximising problem is:

H = S + αW+µ(F(x) - h) (A11)Assuming an interior solution the first-order conditions are:

hdH

S b 0dh

= + − =α µ = 0 (A12)

x x x( b h D F )= − + +&µ δµ α α µ (A13)dH

x F(x) hdµ

= = −& (A14)

In a long run equilibrium x 0µ= =& & , moreover, condition (A5) must also hold, thus:

24 Since hs > 0, for all feasible h and S, this implies that the inverse of h exists, so that Sh = 1/hs. Thiscondition is used in (A5).

24

x x

x x

b h D(b )(1 ) 0

F Fα

αδ δ

− + − =− −

(A15)

Derivation of Equation (7):After rearrangement, the current-value Hamiltonian of the problem in (MII) is:

H = (1+α)b(p,x)h + α Dn(x)) +µ(F(x) - h) (A16)The necessary conditions for a long run equilibrium include:

hdH

S b 0dh

= + − =α µ (A17)

x x x(b h(1 ) D F )= − + + +&µ δµ α α µ = 0 (A18)In addition, in equilibrium condition (MI) must also be satisfied which implies that(A12)- (A14) must hold. Combining and rearranging yields:

b(p,x) - xh

x

b hS

F=

−δ(A19)

Proof of Proposition 1:Let superscript w denotes terms in the welfare maximising equilibrium. Comparingequations (6b) and (5), note that if xw = x, then w w w w

x x x x x xF F , b b,b b ,D D= = = = . Itfollows that (5) can only hold if hw < h.25

Proof of Proposition 2:The proof proceeds in three stages. First we prove that dx/dp > 0 only if Fx >0. Thenit is shown that Fx> 0 must hold in the lobbying equilibrium. Finally, we demonstratethat Fx is declining in α. Hence for sufficiently small α, dx/dp > 0.The equilibrium condition is given by:

x x xZ b(1 )( F ) (1 )b F D 0= + − − + − =α δ α α (A20)Implicitly differentiating:

p

x

Zdxdp Z

= − (A21)

where: p p xZ b (1 )( F )= + α δ − > 0 (the signs follows from the fact that (A20) can only

hold if x( F ) 0δ − > and by assumption bp> 0.)

x x x xx xx x x xxZ b (1 )( F ) b(1 )F (1 )(b F b F ) D= + α δ − − + α − + α + − α

Thus by (A21) dxdp

> 0 if xZ < 0.

Note that by assumption bx > 0, Fxx < 0, bxx < 0, Dxx < 0. Hence, a necessary

condition for dxdp

> 0 is Fx > 0.

We now show that Fx > 0 in the lobbying equilibrium.Let x x< , then since Dxx < 0 it follows that:

x xD D> . (A22) Hence condition (A20) can only hold if:

x xb(1 )( F ) b F+ − −α δ α > x xb(1 )( F ) b F+ − −α δ α (A23)

25 A similar argument holds for xw > x.

25

Since by assumption bx > 0, bxx < 0 then: x xb b,b b< > and since Fxx < 0 then

x xF F> . It follows that the inequality in (A23) can only hold if:F F<

Since x x< , this implies that Fx > 0.Now we show that Fxis declining in α.Upon differentiating Fx with respect to α:

2

xxF x

Fx∂ ∂

=∂ ∂α ∂α

.

By assumption Fxx < 0, thus 2

xF

Fx α∂

≡∂ ∂α

< 0 if x∂

∂α >0.

To sign x∂

∂α consider the welfare function. Recall that as the weight given to welfare,

α, increases, the harvest approaches the welfare maximising rate and welfareapproaches its maximum level. Thus,

x x xW x

(b F bF D )∂ ∂

= + +∂α ∂α

> 0 ∀ α∈ (0, ∞) (A24)

By assumption x xb 0,F 0,b 0,D 0> > > > and it has been shown that xF 0> . Hence

x x x(b F bF D )+ + > 0 . Thus, (A24) can only hold if x∂

∂α > 0. It follows that

2

xF

Fx α∂

≡∂ ∂α

< 0.

Derivation of Equation (8b):The current-value Hamiltonian of the government's utility maximising problem is:H = S + (1 - θ)R(x) + α(b(p,x)h + D(x)+θR(x)) +µ(F(x) - h) (A25)The first-order conditions are:

hdH

S b 0dh

= + − =α µ = 0 (A26a)

x x x x x((1 )R (b h D R ) F )= − − + + + +&µ δµ θ α θ µ (A26b)dH

x F(x) hdµ

= = −& (A26c)

Using the fact that: Sh = b - bxF/(δ - Fx), the steady state equilibrium harvest is givenby:

x x x

x x

b F D R(b )(1 ) 0

F F +

− + − = − −

α σα

δ δ(A26d)

where σ = (1-(θ(1-α))

Proof of Proposition 3a:We first establish the following Lemma which is used to prove the result.Let y = f(x, z) be a continuous differentiable function with fx > 0, fz > 0, fxx < 0 andfzz < 0. Let x' < x" and y' < y"Lemma 1: If fxz> 0 then f(x",z") - f(x",z') > f(x',z") - f(x',z').

Proof: Rearrange the above inequality:f(x",z") - f(x',z") > f(x",z') - f(x',z') (I)

26

Which implies that:f(x' ,z") f(x',z')

x x∂ ∂

>∂ ∂

(II)

Thus:f(x',z") f(x',z')

0x x

∂ ∂− >

∂ ∂(III)

Which implies:

fxz = 2f(x',z')

0x z

∂>

∂ ∂(IV)

Q.E.D.By equation (7b):

S = α(W(xw) - W(xL))Where xwis the welfare maximising stock and xL is the political equilibrium stock andxW > xL.Thus:

w LS W(x ) W(x )R R R

∂ ∂ ∂= α − ∂ ∂ ∂

By Lemma 1 S

0R

∂>

∂ if

2W(x)x R

∂∂ ∂

> 0.

Using equation (8a):W(x) = b(p,x)F(x) + D(x) + R(x)

Thus:

x x x xW

b F bF D Rx

∂= + + +

∂ > 0 (A27)

To sign (A27) note that by assumption bx > 0 , Dx > 0 , Rx > 0 and in Proposition 2 weshow that Fx > 0 in the political equilibrium. Hence (A27) is positive.To assess the effects of a change in R(x) we follow much of the existing literature andintroduce a shift parameter r in (A27) such that dR/dr > 0 (see, e.g. Skonhoft (1999)and Schulze and Skonhoft (1996)). We then represent changes in the transfer byassessing changes with respect to r. This simple device has been frequently employedin the renewable resource literature and obviates the need to restrict the analysis byspecifying particular functional forms.26

Hence:2W

0x r

∂>

∂ ∂.

Thus S

0r

∂>

∂.

Proof of Proposition 3b:To assess the effect of an increase in the transfer, we add a shift parameter r to thetransfer term in (A26d) and rearrange such that this condition is defined as: x x x xZ (b( F ) b F)(1 ) D (r R ) 0≡ − − + − − + =δ α α σ (A28)

26 For instance, if R = a +bxn, then ∂R/∂r > 0 (r = a, b). Hence we can represent increases in the levelor slope of the transfer function.

27

The effect of a marginal increase in the transfer is then determined by dx/dr. As notedabove this is a common technique which has been widely used in renewable resourceproblems (see e.g. Skonhoft (1999)).Upon differentiation and rearrangement:

r

x

dx Zdr Z

= − (A29)

where: Zr = -σ < 0;

x x x xx xx x x xx xxZ b (1 )( F ) b(1 )F (1 )(b F b F ) D R= + α δ − − + α − + α + − α − σ (A30)Since bx > 0, Fxx < 0, bxx < 0, Dxx < 0, and Rxx> (<) 0, then a necessary condition forZx < 0 is Fx > 0. Upon rearrangement of Zx, note that Zx < 0 if:

Fx > xx xxx xx xx

x

R D 1b F b b F ( )

1 2b− σ − α δ − − + ≡ Ψ + α

(A31)

Thus dxdr

< 0 if Fx > Ψ.

Proof of Proposition 3cRearranging (A30), it can be verified that Zx > 0 if:

Rxx < ( )( )x xx x x xx xx1

b F b 2b F b F (1 ) Dδ − − − + α − α ≡ Ωσ

.

Thus, anddxdr

> 0 if Rxx < Ω.

28

REFERENCESBarbier, E. D. and C. E. Schulz (1997) "Wildlife, biodiversity and trade"

Environmental and Development Economics 2: 145-172.Baron (1994) “Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters”

American Political Science Review, 88: 33-47.Bernheim, B.D. and M.D. Whinston (1986), “Menu Auctions, Resource Allocation,

and Economic Influence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101(1): 1-31.Brander, J. A. and M. Scott Taylor (1997a),"International Trade and Open Acess

Renewable Resources: The Small Open Economy Case" Canadian Journal ofEconomics, 30, 526-552.

Brander, J. A. and M. Scott Taylor (1998) "Open Access Renewable Resources: Tradeand Trade Policy in a Two-Country Model" Journal of International Economics, 44,181-209.

Broad, R. (1995) "The Political Economy of Natural Resources: Case Studies ofIndonesia and the Phillipines" Journal of Developing Areas, 29: 317- 340.

Bromley, D. W. (1999) "Deforestation - Institutional Causes and Solution" In WorldForests, Society and Environment ed M. Palo and J. Uusivuori, Dordecht, TheNetherlands

Chambers, P. E., R Jensen and J. C. Whitehead (1996) " Debt for Nature Swaps asNoncooperative Outcomes" Ecological Economics, 19, 135-46/

Chichilinksky, G. (1994) "North South Trade and the Global Environment" AmericanEconomic Review, 84, 851-874.

Daly H. E. and J. B. Cobb (1989) For the Common Good, Beacon Press, BostonDeacon, R and P Murphy (1997) "The structure of an Environmental Transaction:

Debt for Nature Swap" Land Economics, 73, 1-24.Desai, U (1998) Ecological Policy and Politics in Developing Countries, SUNY

Press, New York.Fredriksson P. G. (1997) "The Political Economy of Pollution Taxes in a Small Open

Economy", Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 33: 44-58.Fredriksson, P.G. (1999), “The Political Economy of Trade Liberalization and

Environmental Policy,” Southern Economic Journal 65(3): 513-25.Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman (1994), “Protection for Sale,” American Economic

Review 84(4): 833-50.Hafner, O (1998) "The Role of Corruption in the Misappropriation of Tropical Forest

Resources and in Tropical Forest Destruction" Transparency International WorkingPaper

Leidy, M.P. and B.M. Hoekman (1994), “’Cleaning Up’ while Cleaning Up?Pollution Abatement, Interest Groups and Contingent Trade Policies,” PublicChoice 78: 241-58.

Schulz, C. E. (1996), "Trade Policy and Ecology" Environmental and ResourceEconomics, 8:15-38.

Schulz,C.E and A Skonhoft,(1996) "Wildlife Management, Land-Use and Conflicts"Environment-and-Development-Economics; 1(3), 265-80..

Skonhoft, A (1999) "On the Optimal Exploitation of Terrestrial Animal Species"Environmental-and-Resource-Economics; 13, 45-57..

Swanson (1994), "Regulating Endangered Species" Economic Policy, 16: 185-205.Van Soest, D and R lensink (2000) "Foreign Tranfers and Tropical Deforestation:

What Terms of Conditionality" American Journal of Agricultural Economics,

29

82, 389-99.

CIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The CIES Discussion Paper series provides a means of circulating promptly papers ofinterest to the research and policy communities and written by staff and visitors associatedwith the Centre for International Economic Studies (CIES) at the Adelaide University. Itspurpose is to stimulate discussion of issues of contemporary policy relevance among non-economists as well as economists. To that end the papers are non-technical in nature andmore widely accessible than papers published in specialist academic journals and books.(Prior to April 1999 this was called the CIES Policy Discussion Paper series. Since then theformer CIES Seminar Paper series has been merged with this series.)

Copies of CIES Policy Discussion Papers may be downloaded from our Web site athttp://www.adelaide.edu.au/cies/ or are available by contacting the Executive Assistant,CIES, School of Economics, Adelaide University, SA 5005 AUSTRALIA. Tel: (+61 8) 83035672, Fax: (+61 8) 8223 1460, Email: [email protected]. Single copies are free onrequest; the cost to institutions is US$5.00 overseas or A$5.50 (incl. GST) in Australia eachincluding postage and handling.

For a full list of CIES publications, visit our Web site at http://www.adelaide.edu.au/cies/or write, email or fax to the above address for our List of Publications by CIES Researchers,1989 to 1999 plus updates.

0114 Damania, Richard, and E. Barbier, "Lobbying, Trade and Renewable ResourceHarvesting," April 2001.

0113 Anderson, Kym, " Economy-wide dimensions of trade policy and reform," April2001. (Forthcoming in a Handbook on Developing Countries and the Next Round ofWTO Negotiations, World Bank, April 2001.)

0112 Tyers, Rod, "European Unemployment and the Asian Emergence: Insights from theElemental Trade Model," March 2001. (Forthcoming in The World Economy, Vol.24, 2001.)

0111 Harris, Richard G., "The New Economy and the Exchange Rate Regime," March2001.

0110 Harris, Richard G., "Is there a Case for Exchange Rate Induced ProductivityChanges?", March 2001.

0109 Harris, Richard G., "The New Economy, Globalization and Regional TradeAgreements", March 2001.

0108 Rajan, Ramkishen S., "Economic Globalization and Asia: Trade, Finance andTaxation", March 2001. (Forthcoming in ASEAN Economic Bulletin, 2001.)

0107 Chang, Chang Li Lin, Ramkishen S. Rajan, "The Economics and Politics ofMonetary Regionalism in Asia", March 2001. (Forthcoming in ASEAN EconomicBulletin, 2001.)

0106 Pomfret, Richard, "Reintegration of Formerly Centrally Planned Economies into theGlobal Trading System", February 2001. (Forthcoming in ASEAN EconomicBulletin, 2001).

0105 Manzano, George, "Is there any Value-added in the ASEAN Surveillance Process?"February 2001. (Forthcoming in ASEAN Economic Bulletin, 2001).

0104 Anderson, Kym, "Globalization, WTO and ASEAN", February 2001. (Forthcoming inASEAN Economic Bulletin, 2001).

0103 Schamel, Günter and Kym Anderson, "Wine Quality and Regional Reputation:Hedonic Prices for Australia and New Zealand", January 2001. (Paper presented atthe Annual Conference of the Australian Agricultural and Resource EconomicsSociety, Adelaide, 23-25 January 2001.)

0102 Wittwer, Glyn, Nick Berger and Kym Anderson, "Modelling the World Wine Marketto 2005: Impacts of Structural and Policy Changes", January 2001. (Paperpresented at the Annual Conference of the Australian Agricultural and ResourceEconomics Society, Adelaide, 23-25 January 2001.)

0101 Anderson, Kym, "Where in the World is the Wine Industry Going?" January 2001.(Opening Plenary Paper for the Annual Conference of the Australian Agriculturaland Resource Economics Society, Adelaide, 23-25 January 2001.)

0050 Allsopp, Louise, "A Model to Explain the Duration of a Currency Crisis", December2000.(Forthcoming in International Journal of Finance and Economics)

0049 Anderson, Kym, "Australia in the International Economy", December 2000.(Forthcoming as Ch. 11 in Creating an Environment for Australia's Growth, editedby P.J. Lloyd, J. Nieuwenhuysen and M. Mead, Cambridge and Sydney: CambridgeUniversity Press, 2001.)

0048 Allsopp, Louise, " Common Knowledge and the Value of Defending a FixedExchange Rate", December 2000.

0047 Damania, Richard, Per G. Fredriksson and John A. List, "Trade Liberalization,Corruption and Environmental Policy Formation: Theory and Evidence", December2000.

0046 Damania, Richard, "Trade and the Political Economy of Renewable ResourceManagement", November 2000.

0045 Rajan, Ramkishen S., Rahul Sen and Reza Siregar, "Misalignment of the Baht,Trade Imbalances and the Crisis in Thailand", November 2000.

0044 Rajan, Ramkishen S., and Graham Bird, "Financial Crises and the Composition ofInternational Capital Flows: Does FDI Guarantee Stability?", November 2000.

0043 Graham Bird and Ramkishen S. Rajan, "Recovery or Recession? Post-DevaluationOutput Performance: The Thai Experience", November 2000.

0042 Rajan, Ramkishen S. and Rahul Sen, "Hong Kong, Singapore and the East AsianCrisis: How Important were Trade Spillovers?", November 2000.

0041 Li Lin, Chang and Ramkishen S. Rajan, "Regional Versus Multilateral Solutions toTransboundary Environmental Problems: Insights from the Southeast Asian Haze",October 2000. (Forthcoming in The World Economy, 2000.)

0040 Rajan, Ramkishen S., "Are Multinational Sales to Affiliates in High Tax CountriesOverpriced? A Simple Illustration", October 2000. (Forthcoming in EconomiaInternazionale, 2000.)

0039 Ramkishen S. Rajan and Reza Siregar, "Private Capital Flows in East Asia: Boom,Bust and Beyond", September 2000. (Forthcoming in Financial Markets andPolicies in East Asia, edited by G. de Brouwer, Routledge Press)

0038 Yao, Shunli, "US Permanent Normal Trade Relations with China: What is at Stake?A Global CGE Analysis", September 2000.

0037 Yao, Shunli, "US Trade Sanctions and Global Outsourcing to China", September2000.

0036 Barnes, Michelle L., "Threshold Relationships among Inflation, Financial MarketDevelopment and Growth", August 2000.