28
1 Business cycles characteristics and fiscal procyclicality in resourcerich countries 1 Leonor Coutinho 2 Europrism Dimitrios Georgiou 3 University of Cyprus Alexander Michaelides 4 University of Cyprus and Imperial College Maria Heracleous 5 University of Cyprus Stella Tsani 6 Europrism Europrism Working Paper 13/1 December 2013 Abstract We analyse business cycles in resourcerich countries, fiscal procyclicality and its links to macroeconomic volatility in a systematic manner. We find that resourcerich countries experience higher volatility compared to resourcepoor ones. Among the group of countries analyzed, resourcerich developing countries are found to record the highest macroeconomic volatility. Fiscal policy in resourcerich countries is also found to be on average more procyclical than in resourcepoor countries. Panel data estimations provide robust evidence of the latter. Investigation of the links between fiscal procyclicality and macroeconomic volatility showed that they are positively correlated. Estimations confirm that fiscal procyclicality is associated with greater macroeconomic volatility. This is illustrated to be the case particularly for resourcerich countries. 1 This research falls under the Cyprus Research Promotion Foundationʼs Framework Programme for Research, Technological Development and Innovation 20092010 (DESMI 20092010), cofunded by the Republic of Cyprus and the European Regional Development Fund, and specifically under Grant ΑΝΘΡΩΠΙΣΤΙΚΕΣ/ΟΙΚΟΝ/0311(ΒΙΕ)/04. 2 Corresponding Author, Europrism Research Centre, Office, B21, Thessalonikis 5, Nicosia 2113, Cyprus, [email protected] 3 University of Cyprus, Lefkosia, 1678, [email protected] 4 Department of Finance, Imperial College Business School, South Kensington Campus, London, SW7 2AZ, UK: [email protected] 5 Department of Economics, University of Cyprus, Lefkosia, 1678, Cyprus: [email protected] 6 Europrism Research Centre, Office, B21, Thessalonikis 5, Nicosia 2113, [email protected]

Businesscyclescharacteristicsandfiscalpro-cyclicalityin resource-rich countries

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

1    

Business  cycles  characteristics  and  fiscal  pro-­‐cyclicality  in  resource-­‐rich  countries1  

Leonor  Coutinho2  

Europrism  Dimitrios  Georgiou3  

University  of  Cyprus  

 Alexander  Michaelides4  

University  of  Cyprus  and  Imperial  College  

 Maria  Heracleous5  

University  of  Cyprus  Stella  Tsani6  

Europrism    

Europrism  Working  Paper  13/1  

 

December  2013  

 

Abstract  

We   analyse   business   cycles   in   resource-­‐rich   countries,   fiscal   procyclicality   and   its   links   to  macroeconomic   volatility   in   a   systematic   manner.   We   find   that   resource-­‐rich   countries  experience  higher  volatility  compared  to  resource-­‐poor  ones.  Among  the  group  of  countries  analyzed,   resource-­‐rich   developing   countries   are   found   to   record   the   highest  macroeconomic   volatility.   Fiscal   policy   in   resource-­‐rich   countries   is   also   found   to   be   on  average  more   procyclical   than   in   resource-­‐poor   countries.   Panel   data   estimations   provide  robust   evidence   of   the   latter.   Investigation   of   the   links   between   fiscal   procyclicality   and  macroeconomic   volatility   showed   that   they   are   positively   correlated.   Estimations   confirm  that   fiscal   procyclicality   is   associated   with   greater   macroeconomic   volatility.   This   is  illustrated  to  be  the  case  particularly  for  resource-­‐rich  countries.    

                                                                                                                         1  This  research  falls  under  the  Cyprus  Research  Promotion  Foundationʼs  Framework  Programme  for  Research,  Technological  Development  and  Innovation  2009-­‐2010  (DESMI  2009-­‐2010),  co-­‐funded  by  the  Republic  of  Cyprus  and  the  European  Regional  Development  Fund,  and  specifically  under  Grant  ΑΝΘΡΩΠΙΣΤΙΚΕΣ/ΟΙΚΟΝ/0311(ΒΙΕ)/04.  2  Corresponding  Author,  Europrism  Research  Centre,  Office,  B21,  Thessalonikis  5,  Nicosia  2113,  Cyprus,  [email protected]    3  University  of  Cyprus,  Lefkosia,  1678,  [email protected]    4  Department  of  Finance,  Imperial  College  Business  School,  South  Kensington  Campus,  London,  SW7  2AZ,  UK:  [email protected]    5  Department  of  Economics,  University  of  Cyprus,  Lefkosia,  1678,  Cyprus:  [email protected]    6  Europrism  Research  Centre,  Office,  B21,  Thessalonikis  5,  Nicosia  2113,  [email protected]    

2    

1 Introduction  Previous   studies   have   documented   with   a   wide   range   of   econometric   techniques   that  countries   that   are   rich   in   oil   or   other   natural   resource   wealth   have   failed   to   grow   more  rapidly   than   those   that   are   less   endowed.   This   phenomenon   has   been   labelled   in   the  literature   as   the   “resource   curse”.   There   have   been   several   studies   trying   to   identify   the  reasons  behind  the  “resource  curse”  of  endowment-­‐rich  economies  (see  Frankel,  2010,  and  references  therein,  for  instance).  One  important  possible  reason  identified,  to  which  various  other   reasons   can   be   tracked   down,   is   the   pro-­‐cyclicality   of   fiscal   policies,   which   tend   to  exacerbate  business  cycle  volatility   in   resource-­‐rich  countries,   contributing   to  an   increased  macroeconomic  volatility  which  hampers  economic  growth.  

The   importance   of   macroeconomic   volatility   to   economic   growth   has   received   significant  attention   both   in   the   theoretical   and   the   empirical   economic   literature.   Recent   theories  have   challenged   the   traditional   approaches   that   have   studied   apart   long-­‐run   growth   and  volatility   (for   a   review   of   the   literature   see   Fatás,   2002).   Growing   empirical   evidence   has  established   a   strong   connection   between   volatility   and   long-­‐run   performance   (see   among  others   Ramey   and   Ramey,   1995   and  Deaton   and  Miller,   1996).   Empirical   evidence   on   the  direction  of  the  relationship  between  volatility  and  growth  has  varied,  but  it  can  be  argued  that   comprehensive   empirical   evidence   has   been   found   for   the   hypothesis   that   cyclical  fluctuations   reduce   long-­‐term   growth   (see   Priesmeier   and   Stahler,   2011,   for   a   recent  survey).    

There  is  an  important  difficulty  however  in  estimating  the  effect  of  volatility  on  growth,  due  to   the   possibility   of   reverse   causality.   Recent   studies   that   address   this   issue   in   a   more  systematic  way  confirm  the  significant  negative  effects  of  volatility  on  growth  (see  Fatás  and  Mihov,  2006;  Loayza  et  al,  2007  and  Aghion  et  al,  2010).  In  the  specific  case  of  resource-­‐rich  countries,   studies   highlight   the   importance   of   the   relationship   between   volatility   and  economic   growth   in   explaining   the   “resource   curse”.   van   der   Ploeg   and   Poelhekke   (2008)  find  evidence  that  natural  resources  adversely  affect  economic  growth  through  the  indirect  negative  impact  of  volatility  on  the  latter.    

Given  this  growing  evidence  on  the  importance  of  macroeconomic  stability  for  growth,  this  paper   analyses   the  business   cycle   characteristics  of   resource-­‐rich   countries,   and   compares  them  to  those  of  resource-­‐poor  countries,  with  the  aim  of  identifying  a  link  between  natural  resource   abundance   and   volatility.   In   addition   we   also   analyse   the   link   between  macroeconomic   volatility   and   fiscal   policy   procyclicality   in   a   systematic   way.   For   this   we  firstly  document  the  stylized  facts  regarding  output  volatility   in  resource-­‐rich  countries  and  compare   these   to   the   statistics   observed   for   resource-­‐poor   economies,   using   standard  business  cycle  techniques  to  analyse  “growth  cycles”.  Secondly,  we  study  the  behaviour  of  fiscal   policy   in   resource-­‐rich   countries,   following   the   contributions   of   Alesina   et   al.   (2008)  and   Itzelski   and   Vegh   (2008).   Finally,   we   estimate   the   conditional   correlation   between  macroeconomic   volatility   and   fiscal   procyclicality,   to   gauge   the   significance   of   the   links  between  the  two.    

We  use  a   large  database  comprising  of  189  countries,  carefully  split   into  resource-­‐rich  and  resource-­‐poor  countries,  according  to  their  ratios  of  commodity  exports  to  GDP,  commodity  

3    

exports  to  total  exports,  and  two  main  commodity  exports  to  total  exports.  The  data  covers  the  period  1962-­‐2011,   but   not   all   data   is   available   for   all   countries   for   this   sample  period  giving  rise  to  an  unbalanced  panel.   It   is   important  to  note  also  that  the  availability  of  fiscal  data  is  particularly  poor,  leading  to  a  very  short  sample  for  a  significant  number  of  countries.  For  this  reason,  the  results  must  be  interpreted  with  caution.  

The   results   indicate   that   macroeconomic   volatility   (measured   by   the   volatility   of   GDP)  appears  to  be  indeed  higher  in  resource-­‐rich  countries.  Moreover,  there  is  evidence  that  this  increased   volatility   is   more   of   a   resource   phenomenon   than   a   developing   country  phenomenon.  Although  developing  countries  do  show  higher  volatility   than  higher   income  countries,   the   group  of   resource-­‐rich   developing   countries   is   the  one   showing   the  highest  volatility.  

Graphical   analysis   indicates   that   fiscal   procyclicality   is   positively   related   to   resource  abundance,  special  within  the  set  of  resource-­‐rich  countries.  Individual  countries’  regression  results   indicates   that  on  average  resource-­‐rich  countries  seem  to  be  more  procyclical   than  resource-­‐poor,   however   the   results   need   to   be   treated  with   caution   due   to   small   sample  limitations   and   their   statistical   significance.   In   order   to   shed  more   light   into   this   issue  we  take   advantage   of   the   panel   of   countries   and   estimate   instead   a   pooled   regression.   The  pooled   results   indicate   that   fiscal   policy   not   only   tends   to   be   procyclical   in   resource-­‐rich  countries,   but   also   it   is   strongly   procyclical,   since   the   estimates   point   to   an   increase   in  government  consumption  of  about  2%,  following  an  1%  increase  in  GDP.  

The   results   regarding   the   links   between  macroeconomic   volatility   and   fiscal   procyclicality  indicate  the  existence  of  positive  correlation  between  the  two.  Other  interesting  results  are  unveiled   in   this  analysis.  Macroeconomic  volatility  appears  to  be  positively  related  to  poor  political  rights.   It   is  also  positively  related  to   initial   income  per  capita.  This  result,  although  counter-­‐intuitive   is   consistent   with   micro-­‐econometric   estimates   which   show   that   the  variability  of  wealth  is  positively  related  to  initial  wealth,  since  individuals  with  higher  wealth  are   also   those   that   are   able   to   take   more   risk.   Finally,   macroeconomic   volatility   appears  negatively   related   to   financial   development.   High   levels   of   financial   development   allow  hedging  against  different  types  of  risk,  and  also  borrowing  in  bad  times,  and  saving/repaying  in  good  times,  in  order  to  smooth  consumption  and  output.  

The   remainder   of   the   paper   is   organized   as   follows.   Section   2   describes   the  methodology  employed   and   the   data   used   in   the   analysis.   Section   3   summarizes   the   results   regarding  macroeconomic  volatility,   fiscal  procyclicality  and  the  results  obtained  on  the   link  between  macroeconomic  volatility  and  fiscal  procyclicality.  Last  section  concludes.  

2 Methods  and  data  To   explore   the   questions   associated   with   business   cycles,   fiscal   procyclicality   and  macroeconomic   volatility   we   utilize   an   annual   frequency7   data   set   that   includes   GDP,  

                                                                                                                         7  We  use  annual  data  to  avoid  the  selection  bias  that  might  arise  from  focusing  on  countries  for  which  only  quarterly  data  are  available.  This  allows  us  to  extend  substantially  both  the  number  of  countries  and  the  time  span,  resulting  in  a  relatively  large  dataset.  

4    

government   consumption   and   measures   of   institutional   and   financial   variables.   Sample  countries   are   classified   into   resource-­‐rich   and   resource-­‐poor   ones.   The   literature   provides  different  approaches  to  defining  countries  as  resource-­‐rich.  The  most  widely  used  proxy  for  resource  dependence  is  the  ratio  of  resource  exports  to  GDP  (see,  among  others,  Sachs  and  Warner,  1995  and  Arezki  and  van  der  Ploeg,  2011),  but  other  measures  are  also  used  in  the  literature,   including   the   ratio   of   commodity   exports   in   total   exports,   and   the   ratio   of  resource  revenues  in  total  fiscal  revenues.  For  instance,  IMF  (2010),  Kalyuzhnova  (2008)  and  Tsani   (2013)   define   as   resource-­‐rich   the   countries   where   the   share   of   resource   exports  (fuels,   ores,  minerals,  metals)   over   total  merchandise   exports   is   equal   or  more   than   40%.  Collier   and   Hoeffler   (2009)   define   as   high-­‐rent   countries   those   where   resource   revenues  account  for  10%  or  more  of  GDP.    

We   construct   the   resource-­‐rich   sample   using   a   combination   of   definitions   that   generate  aggregate   dependence   on   natural   resource   revenues.   Specifically,  we   define   resource-­‐rich  countries   as   those   countries   that   have   a   ratio   of   commodity   exports   to   GDP   equal   to,   or  above  8%,   combined  with   revenues   from  commodity   exports   to   total   exports   equal   to,   or  above  60%,  provided  that  the  revenues  from  their  two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of  total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.  This  last  condition  ensures  that  we  do  not  include  in  the  sample  countries  that  are  relatively  diversified  in  their  commodity  trade.  Such  countries  might  not  be  considered  as  dependent  on  a  major  revenue  source  and  therefore  might  be  significantly  less  affected  by  fluctuations  in  a  particular  commodity  price.    

Note  that  we  consider  a  relatively  high  share  of  commodity  exports  in  total  exports  as  one  of  our  benchmarks  because  our  dataset  include  data  from  the  1960s  and  1970s  when  the  share  of  commodity  exports  to  total  exports  was  relatively  high  for  all  countries   in  general8.  As  a  validation  check,  we  compare  the  resulting  classification  with  the  IMF  definition  of  resource-­‐rich  countries,  provided  in  the  Fiscal  Rules  Dataset  2012  (Schaechter  et  al.,  2012),  and  find  a  similar  categorization  for  the  countries  that  appear  in  both  samples.  

Based  on  the  above  criteria  87  countries  in  the  sample  are  classified  as  resource-­‐rich,  three  of   which   are   dropped   from   the   analysis   due   to   data   restrictions,   resulting   in   a   set   of   84  resource-­‐rich  countries9.  The  sample  of  resource-­‐rich  countries  is  summarized  in  Appendix  A.  

2.1 Business  cycles  To   analyze   the   characteristics   of   business   cycles   in   resource   rich   countries   and   compare  them  to  those  of  resource  poor  countries  we  will  use  the  concept  of  “growth”  cycles,  where  the  underlying   idea   is   that   the  business  cycle  can  be   identified  as  a  deviation   relative   to  a  trend   (rather   than   in   terms   of   absolute   changes).     Two   types   of   filtering   approaches   that  have  become  standard  methods  of  removing  trends  in  the  business  cycle  literature  are  used  in  our  analysis.  The  first  one  implements  the  Hodrick-­‐Prescott  (HP)  (1980,  1997)  filter,  which  is   a   model-­‐free   approach   to   decomposing   a   time   series   into   its   trend   and   cyclical  components.   To   test   the   robustness   of   the   results   we   also   implement   the   Christiano-­‐

                                                                                                                         8  The  average  share  of  commodity  exports  to  total  exports  between  1962  and  2011  for  the  whole  sample  of  countries  is  about  62%.  9  We  drop  from  the  resource-­‐rich  sample  The  Bahamas,  because  the  export  share  in  GDP  is  above  100%;  and  Greenland  and  Somalia,  due  to  lack  of  fiscal  data.  

5    

Fitzgerald   (CF)   filter   (2003)   in   detrending   the   data   and   estimating   the   business   cycle  component  of  the  real  GDP  which  is  the  variable  of  interest  in  our  study.    

The   HP   filter  was   proposed   by   Hodrick   and   Prescott   (1997)   as   a   trend-­‐removal   technique  that  could  be  applied  to  data  that  came  from  a  wide  class  of  data-­‐generating  processes.  The  HP   filter   is   an   algorithm   that   “smooths”   the   original   time   series   yt   to   estimate   its   trend  component,   τt.   The   cyclical   component   is   then   defined   as   the   difference   between   the  original  series  and  its  trend,  i.e.,  ct  =  yt    -­‐  τt  where  τt  is  constructed  to  minimize:  

∑ ∑−

−+ −−−+−T T

tttttty1

1

2

211

2 )]()[()( ττττλτ  

The  smoothness  of  the  trend  depends  on  a  parameter  λ.  The  trend  becomes  smoother  as  λ  approaches   1,   and   Hodrick   and   Prescott   (1997)   recommended   setting   λ   to   1,600   for  quarterly   data.   For   annual   data,   as   is   the   case   in   our   dataset,   we   follow   the   Ravn-­‐Uhlig  (2002)  rule  and  set  the  smoothing  parameter  λ=6.25.  

As  an  alternative  to  the  HP  filter  we  also  apply  the  Christiano-­‐Fitzgerald   (CF)   (2003),  band-­‐pass  filter  to  our  real  GDP  data.  This  method  places  two  important  restrictions  on  the  mean  squared  error   problem   that   this   filter   solves.   First,   the  CF   filter   is   restricted   to   be   a   linear  filter  and  second,  yt  is  assumed  to  be  a  random-­‐walk  process.  The  CF  filter  is  the  best  linear  predictor  of  the  series  filtered  by  the  ideal  band-­‐pass  filter  when  yt  is  a  random  walk.    Since  the  real  GDP  may  well  be  approximated  by  a  random  walk  plus  drift  process,  we  decided  to  also  utilize   this  method  of  decomposing  our  data   into   trend  and   cyclical   components.   The  minimum  and  maximum  periods   for   filtering  out   stochastic   cycles   are   set   to     2     and  8,   as  typically  used  in  the  literature.  

2.2 Fiscal  procyclicality  To  analyse  the  cyclical  behavior  of  fiscal  policy  we  estimate  measures  of  fiscal  pro-­‐cyclicality  following  Alesina  et  al.   (2008),  Catão  and  Sutton   (2002)  and  Gavin  and  Perotti   (1997).  Our  methodology  consists  of  estimating  equation  (1)  separately  for  each  country:  

∆𝐹! = 𝛽𝑦𝑔𝑎𝑝! + 𝛾𝑍! + 𝜆𝐹!!! + 𝑒!                    (1)  

where  F   is   government   consumption,   our   fiscal   policy   indicator;   ygap   is   a  measure   of   the  business  cycle  (log-­‐deviation  of  GDP  from  its  trend),  and  Z  is  a  set  of  control  variables,  which  in   the   final   specification   include   the   lag   of   the   dependent   variable.   The   estimated  coefficients   β   for   each   country   provide   us   with   country   specific   measures   of   fiscal   pro-­‐cyclicality.    

Such  a  regression  clearly  suffers  from  endogeneity  since  GDP  and  government  consumption  are  jointly  determined.  One  possible  way  of  identifying  the  causal  effect  from  GDP  growth  to  fiscal   policy   is   to   use   instrumental   variable   techniques.   The   problem   associated   with   the  instrumental   variables   approach,   however,   is   finding   appropriate   instruments.   For   an  instrument   to  be  valid,   it  needs   to   fulfill   both   the  criteria   for   instrument   relevance   (in  our  case  sufficiently  correlated  with  GDP  growth)  and  of  exogeneity  (that  the  instrument  is  not  

6    

correlated   with   the   error   term,   that   is,   the   instrument   has   no   partial   effect   on   the   fiscal  stance  once  GDP  growth  is  controlled  for).      

In   the   fiscal   policy   procyclicality   literature,   a   number   of   instruments   have   been   used.   For  example,  Gali  and  Perotti   (2003)  analyze  European  countries  and  the  US  and  suggest  using  the   US   output   gap   to   instrument   the   output   gap   of   EU   countries,   and   EU   GDP   as   an  instrument   for   the   US   output   gap.   Jaimovich   and   Panizza   (2007)   suggest   instead   using   as  instrument   the   trade-­‐weighted   average   of   rest-­‐of-­‐the-­‐world   GDP.   In   several   cases   lagged  GDP   growth   (or   the   lagged   output   gap)   is   also   used   as   an   additional   instrument,   but   as  pointed   out   by   Ilzetzki   and   Vegh   (2008)   the   strong   serial   correlation   of   GDP   may   make  lagged  GDP   an   imperfect   instrument,   as   GDP   at   time   t−1  may   still   be   correlated  with   the  error  term  at  time  t.  Alesina  et  al.  (2008)  use  a  version  of  this  methodology  and  instrument  the  output   gap  of   each   country  with   the  output   gap  of   its   neighbors   (regional   output   gap  excluding  the  country).  

To   address   endogeneity   problems   we   estimate   equation   (1)   by   instrumental   variables,  instrumenting   the   output   gap   of   each   country   on   the   regional   output   gap   (excluding   the  country  analysed).   For   resource-­‐rich   countries  we  use  an  additional   instrument   that  arises  naturally   for   this   set  of   countries,   namely   the   growth   in   the  price  of   the  main   commodity  export.  Arguably  commodity  prices  are  determined  in  world  markets  and  can  thus  provide  a  textbook-­‐type   exogenous   variation   to   the   income   earned   by   a   particular   country.  We   use  this  exogenous  variation   to  give  a   causal   interpretation  on  how   fiscal  policy   reacts   to  GDP  changes.  We  use   the   lagged   resource  price  growth   to   instrument   for   current  GDP  growth.    We  use  the  lagged,  and  not  the  contemporaneous  commodity  price  growth,  to  account  for  possible  delays  in  the  transmission  of  commodity  price  shocks  to  the  economy  and  to  guard  against  the  effects  of  serially  correlated  measurement  error.    

Given   that   the  small   sample  size  of  many  countries   limits   the  statistical   significance  of   the  coefficients  obtained,  we  further  test  for  the  presence  of  fiscal  procyclicality  in  resource-­‐rich  countries  using  panel  data  analysis.  Thus  we  estimate  the  following  equation:  

𝛥𝐹!" = 𝑎! + 𝜇! + 𝛽𝑦𝑔𝑎𝑝 + 𝛾𝐹!"!! + 𝑒!"                                      𝑖 = 1,2,… ,𝑁                        𝑡 = 1,2,… ,𝑇!                    (2)  

where   𝐹!"   is   our   preferred   fiscal   policy     indicator   for   year,𝑦𝑔𝑎𝑝!"  is   the   measure   of   a  country’s  business  cycle.   In  addition,  we   include   the   lagged  dependent  variable   to  capture  empirically  observed  policy  persistence.  Country  fixed  effects  denoted  by  𝑎!  are  included  to  account   for   differences   in   the   average   fiscal   stance   across   countries,   while   time-­‐decade  effects   (𝜇!)   are   also   included   to   control   for   unobserved   factors   that   are   common   across  countries  and  might  be  influencing  fiscal  policy  over  time.  The  error  term  is  denoted  by  𝑒!"  .  

We  use  as  instrument  the  real  rest-­‐of-­‐the-­‐region  GDP  and  for  resource-­‐rich  countries  we  use  the   main   commodity   price   (lagged   resource   price   growth)   as   both   an   alternative   and   an  additional  instrument.  

2.3 Volatility  and  fiscal  procyclicality  To   test   the   hypothesis   of  whether   countries  with  more   pro-­‐cyclical   fiscal   policies   are   also  those   that   experience   more   volatile   business   cycles   we   analyse   the   correlation   between  

7    

business   cycle   volatility   and   fiscal   policy   procyclicality,   controlling   for   a   set   of   other  characteristics   including   political   institutions,   financial   development,   exchange   rate  arrangements,  and  initial  GDP  per  capita.    

Evidence   in   the   literature   has   been  pointing   on   the   role   of   institutions   to  macroeconomic  volatility   arguing   that   institutions   that   fail   to   control   political   elites   are   associated   with  higher  volatility  (see  Acemoglu  et  al,  2002  and  Barseghyan  and  DiCecio,  2009).  Initial  income  has   also   been   associated   with   macroeconomic   volatility.   When   wealth   is   high   economic  agents’   reaction   is   less  sensitive   to  shocks  and  the  economy  may  be  more  robust   to  crisis.  When   wealth   is   low,   the   economy   becomes   vulnerable   to   fluctuations   and   can   be   more  volatile  (see  Perri  and  Heathcote,  2012).  

The  empirical  evidence  tends  to  support  the  view  that  more  flexible  exchange  rate    regimes  tends  to  insulate  the  economy  better  when  facing  terms  of  trade  shocks.  Broda  (2002)  based  on  a  sample  of  developing  countries,  documents  that  in  response  to  negative  terms  of  trade  shocks   countries   with   fixed   exchange   regimes   experience   large   and   significant   declines   in  real  GDP.   The  opposite  occurs   in   the   case  of   flexible   exchange   rate   regimes.   Edwards   and  Levy  Yeyati  (2003)  show  that  the  terms  of  trade  shocks  are  amplified  in  countries  that  have  more  rigid  exchange  rate  regimes.    

Further   evidence   indicates   that   financial   depth   may   also   play   part   in   explaining  macroeconomic   volatility.   Deeper   financial   systems   relax   borrowing   constraints   and  promote   risk   sharing,   thus   enhancing   the   economy’s   ability   to   absorb   shocks.   Deeper  financial   systems   can   dampen   volatility   by   alleviating   firms’   cash   constraints,   especially   in  economies  with  tight  international  financial  constraints  (Caballero  and  Krishnamurty,  2001).  Aghion  et  al.   (1999)  show  that  economies  with  poorly  developed  financial  systems  tend  to  be  more  volatile,  as  both  the  demand  for  and  supply  conditions  for  credit  tend  to  be  more  cyclical.  Deeper  financial  systems  may  also  facilitate  greater  diversification,  reducing  risk  and  dampening  fluctuations  (Acemoglu  and  Zilibotti,  1997).    

We   estimate   a   cross-­‐sectional   empirical   model   in   which   the   dependent   variable   is   our  measure  of  business  cycle  volatility  (the  standard  deviation  of  de-­‐trended  GDP  series).  The  explanatory  variables   include  the  correlation  of   fiscal  balances  with   the  business  cycle  and  the  set  of  control  variables  mentioned  above.  The  model  is  summarised  by  equation  (3):  

𝜎! = 𝑎 + 𝑏𝛽! + 𝛿𝑋! + 𝜀!      (3)  

where   𝜎!  is   the   estimated   business   cycle   volatility   of   country   i,   a   is   a   constant,   𝛽!   is   the  measure  of  fiscal  pro-­‐cyclicality  of  country  i  (correlation  of  the  fiscal  indicator  with  the  cycle)  and  Xi  is  a  vector  of  control  variables  for  country  i.  With  this  framework  we  test  in  particular  whether   the   estimated   parameter  b   is   positive   and   significant,   indicating   that  more   fiscal  pro-­‐cyclicality  is  associated  with  more  business  cycle  volatility.    

In  this  manner  we  assess  whether  the  general  perception  that  resource-­‐rich  countries  with  more   pronounced   business   cycles   also   have  more   pro-­‐cyclical   (structurally   adjusted)   fiscal  policies.   To   avoid   working   with   negative   numbers,   we   scale   the   measure   of   fiscal  

8    

procyclicality  𝛽!  using  a  standard  methodology  (𝛽!-­‐min(β))/(  𝛽!-­‐max(β)).  This  transformation  yields  a  measure  of  procyclicality  between  zero  and  one.  

2.4 Data  We   make   use   of   a   large   set   of   data   extracted   from   the   IMF   database   (World   Economic  Outlook-­‐WEO);   the   World   Bank   databases   (World   Development   Indicators-­‐WDI,   Global  Economic  Monitor-­‐GEM,  Global  Financial  Data-­‐GDF  and  Worldwide  Governance   Indicators-­‐WGI);   the   UN   COMTRADE   database   and   the   Polity   IV   database.   The   dataset   covers   the  period  1962-­‐2011  for  many  variables  but  for  other  variables  the  series  extend  over  shorter  periods.   Data   on   macroeconomic   and   fiscal   variables   such   as   GDP   and   government  consumption  are  obtained  from  the  World  Bank  WDI  database  (Table  1).  

Table  1:  Macroeconomic  and  fiscal  data  and  sources  

Variable   Description   Source   Max  Sample  

Countries  

GDP     Gross   Domestic   Product   (local   currency,  current  prices,  units)  

WDI   1962-­‐2011   190  

GDP  (US  $)   Gross   Domestic   Product   (   US   Dollars,  current  prices,  units)  

WDI   1962-­‐2011   188  

Government  Consumption  

General   Government   Consumption  Expenditure   (local   currency,   current  prices,  units)  

WDI   1962-­‐2011   177  

GDP  Deflator   GDP   Deflator   (base   year   varies   by  country-­‐recalculated  with  2005  base  year  for  all  countries)  

WDI   1962-­‐2011   181  

CPI   Consumer   Price   Index,   local   currency,  (2005=100)  

WDI   1962-­‐2011   176  

Notes:  WDI:  World  Development  Indicators  

Real   Government   Consumption   is   constructed   by   deflating   the   nominal   series   taken   from  WDI  database  with  the  2005  CPI  deflator.  We  have  constructed  real  GDP  variable  using  the  GDP  deflator  from  WDI  using  2005  as  the  base  year.  Growth  rates  have  been  generated  by  taking  the  difference  of  the  natural  logarithm  of  real  GDP  and  multiplying  the  result  by  100.  For   the   rest-­‐of-­‐region   GDP   growth   variable  we   have   first   categorized   each   country   into   a  region  according  to  the  Word  Bank  classification.  The  Word  Bank  defines  the  regions  in  the  following   way:   High-­‐Income   OECD,   High-­‐Income   non-­‐OECD,   East   Asia   and   Pacific,   Eastern  Europe  and  Central  Asia,  Latin  America  and  Caribbean,  Middle  East  and  North  Africa,  South  Asia  and  Sub-­‐Saharan  Africa.  We  then  have  calculated  GDP  in  Purchasing  Power  Parity  (PPP)  adjusted  (year  2005)  terms  by  dividing  the  Real  GDP  by  the  PPP  conversion  factor  for  2005.  The  Real  GDP  in  PPP-­‐adjusted  terms  for  each  region  is  constructed  by  summing  up  the  Real  GDP   in  PPP   terms  of  each  country  within  a   region.  To  compute   the   rest-­‐of-­‐region-­‐GDP   for  each  country  i,  we  simply  subtract  the  real  GDP  in  PPP  of  country  i  from  the  Real  GDP  in  PPP  of  the  region.  Taking  the  difference  of  its  natural  logarithm  times  100,  produces  the  growth  rate  of  real  rest-­‐of-­‐region-­‐GDP.  

9    

Commodity  export  and  prices  data  have  been  extracted  from  the  UN  COMTRADE  database.  The  data  on  commodity  exports  include  a  group  of  12  variables  which  contains  information  on   the   value   of   exports   by   export   category   (Table   2).   The   categories   are   the   broad  commodity   categories   from   the   UN   COMTRADE   and   refer   to   the   standard   International  Trade  Classification,  Revision  1  (SITC,  Rev.1).  The  variables  of  this  group  have  been  used   in  own  calculations  on  total  exports.    

Table  2:  Commodity  exports  related  variables  

Variable   Description   Source   Max  Sample  

Countries  

Category  0   Exports,  Food  and  live  animals,  US$   UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   191  

Category  1   Exports,  Beverages  and  tobacco,  US$   UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   188  

Category  2   Exports,   Crude   materials,   inedible,  except  fuels,  US$  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   191  

Category  3   Exports,   Mineral   fuels,   lubricants   and  related  materials,  US$  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   190  

Category  4   Exports,   Animal   and   vegetable   oils   and  fats  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   188  

Category  5   Chemicals,  US$   UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   190  

Category  6   Exports,  Manufactured   Goods,   classified  chiefly  by  material,  US$  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   191  

Category  6672   Exports,   Diamonds,   not   industrial,   not  set  or  strung,  US$  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   128  

Category  68   Exports,  Non-­‐ferrous  metals,  US$   UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   187  

Category  7   Exports,   Machinery   and   transport  equipment,  US$  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   190  

Category  8   Exports,   Miscellaneous   manufactured  articles,  US$  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   191  

Category  9   Exports,   Commodities   and   transactions,  not  classified  according  to  kind,  US$  

UN  COMTRADE  

1962-­‐2011   191  

 

Following   Sachs   and   Warner   (1995)   resource   intensity   is   defined   as   the   ratio   of   primary  exports  to  GDP.  Both  variables  are  measured  in  US  dollars.  Primary  exports  are  defined  to  be  the  sum  of  the  UN  COMTRADE  categories  0,  1,  2,  3,  4  and  68.  We  expand  this  definition  to  also   include   category   6672   -­‐   Diamonds,   not   industrial,   not   set   or   strung.   The   source   for  primary  exports  data   is   revision  1  of   the  Standard   International  Trade  Classification   (SITC).  Total   Exports   is   created   by   adding   up   the   main   UN   COMTRADE   commodity   categories,  namely  0,  1,  2,  3,  4,  5,  6,  7,  8  and  9.  These  categories  are  from  revision  1  of  the  SITC.  Total  Exports  are  measured  in  US  dollars.  

 

 

10    

Table  3:  Commodity  prices  variables  Variable   Description   Source   Max  Sample   Countries  Aluminium   Aluminum,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   5  Bananas   Bananas,  US$,  $/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   7  Beef   Meat,   beef,   US$   cents/kg,   nominal   US$  

cents  GEM   1962-­‐2011   3  

Coal   Coal,  Australia,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1970-­‐2011   1  Cocoa  Beans   Cocoa,  US$  cents/kg,  nominal  US$  cents   GEM   1962-­‐2011   5  Coconuts   Coconut  oil,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   1  Coffee   Coffee,   average,   Arabica,   Robusta,   US$  

cents/kg,  nominal  US$  cents  GEM   1962-­‐2011   12  

Copper   Copper,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   8  Copra   Copra,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   2  Cotton   Cotton,  A   Index,  US$  cents/kg,  nominal  US$  

cents  GEM   1962-­‐2011   9  

Diamonds   Average   One   Carat   D   Flawless,   US$/Carat,    nominal  US$  

Ajediam10   1962-­‐2011   5  

Fish   Fish   (salmon),   Price   index   Farm   Bred  Norwegian  Salmon,  export  price,  2005=100    

WEO   1980-­‐2011   8  

Gold   Gold,  US$/toz,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   6  Groundnuts   Groundnut  oil,  US  $/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   3  Hides   Hides,  Price   Index  Heavy  native  steers,  over  

53   pounds,   wholesale   dealer’s   price,  2005=100    

WEO   1980-­‐2011   1  

Iron   Iron  ore,US$  cents/dmtu,  nominal  US$  cents   GEM   1962-­‐2011   3  Natgas   Natural   gas,   average,   Europe,   US,   US$  

dollars/mmbtu,  nominal  US$  GEM   1962-­‐2011   16  

Nickel   Nickel,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   1  Oil   Crude   oil,   average,   spot,   US$/bbl,   nominal  

US$  GEM   1962-­‐2011   31  

Rice   Rice,  Thailand,  5%,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   1  Rubber   Rubber,   Singapore,   US$   cents/kg,   nominal  

US$  cents  GEM   1962-­‐2011   1  

Shrimp   Shrimp,  Mexico,  US$  cents/kg,  nominal  US$  dollar  cents  

GEM   1975-­‐2011   1  

Soybeans   Soybeans,  US$/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   2  Sugar   Sugar,   world,   US$   cents/kg,   nominal   US$  

cents  GEM   1962-­‐2011   5  

Tea   Tea,   auctions   (3)   average,   US$   cents/kg,  nominal  US$  cents  

GEM   1962-­‐2011   3  

Timber   Agr:   Raw:1   Timber,   Price   Index,   nominal  US$,  2005=100  

GEM   1962-­‐2011   6  

Tin   Tin,  US  $  cents/kg,  nominal  US$  cents   GEM   1962-­‐2011   1  Tobacco   Tobacco,  US  $/mt,  nominal  US$   GEM   1962-­‐2011   2  Uranium   Uranium,  US$/pound,  nominal  US  dollars   GFD   1968-­‐2011   1  

Notes:  GEM:  Global  Economic  Monitor,  World  Bank;  GFD:  Global  Financial  Data    

                                                                                                                         10  Ajediam,  Antwerp  Jewels  &  Diamond  Manufacturers  

11    

Data  on  commodity  prices  include  nominal  prices  and  price  indices  for  a  set  of  twenty  nine  commodities  (Table  3).  These  variables  have  been  used  in  order  to  calculate  price  indices  for  the  first  two  exporting  commodities  of  each  country  included  in  the  dataset.  Data  on  export  prices   have   been   extracted   from   the  World   Bank   databases   (GEM   and   GFD)   and   the   IMF  database  (WEO).  Data  on  diamond  prices  have  been  extracted  from  datastream  and  Ajediam  Antwerp  Jewels  &  Diamond  Manufacturers.    

The  nominal  price  of  each  commodity  is  measured  in  US  dollars  (world  prices).  We  use  the  exchange   rate   (local   currency   per   US   dollar)   from   the   WDI   to   express   the   nominal  commodity  prices   in   local   currency.  We   then  construct  an   index  of   commodity  prices  with  2005  as  the  base  year  and  derive  the  Real  Commodity  Price  using  the  2005  CPI.  Finally,  we  construct  Real  Commodity  Price  Growth  taking  the  difference  of  the  natural  logarithm  of  the  Real  Commodity  Price  times  100.  

Price   data   for   diamonds   was   available   only   for   the   2002-­‐2011   period   via   datastream.  Therefore,   to  construct  the  nominal  price  series   for  diamonds  we  used   information  from  a  graph   titled   “Historical   diamond   trade  price   trend   evolution   graph”   found  on   the  Ajediam  (Antwerp  Jewels  &  Diamond  Manufacturers)  website11.  The  graph  plots  historical  wholesale  prices   for   Average   One   Carat   D   Flawless   from   1960   to   2013.   Comparing   the   last   10  observations   of   our   constructed   data   with   the   actual   data   obtained   from   datastream  we  observe  that  they  are  quite  similar.    

To   account   for   institutions   we   use   the   Polity2   variable   obtained   from   the   Project   IV  database.  We  average  Polity2  over  the  available  years  for  each  country  and  then  create  the  dummy  variable  “Democracy”  which  takes  the  value  one  when  this   time  average   is  strictly  positive   and   zero   otherwise.   Data   on   political   rights   ranking   have   been   extracted   from  Freedom  House  Political  Rights   Index.   The   index   ranges   from  1   to  7  with  1  denoting  most  free  countries  and  7  least  free  countries.      

In   addition   we   also   use   a   set   of   institutional   controls   in   the   analysis   of   the   link   between  macroeconomic   volatility   and   fiscal   procyclicality,  which   in   the   final   specifications   include:    the   political   rights   index,   the   private   credit   to   GDP   ratio,   and   the   index   of   exchange   rate  flexibility.   The   political   rights   ranking   is   given   by   the   Freedom   House   index   which   ranges  from  1  (most  free)  to  7  (least  free).  The  democracy  variable  is  the  variable  Polity2  from  the  IV   Project   database.   Polity2   ranges   from   -­‐10   (strongly   autocratic)   to   10   (strongly  democratic).   The   exchange   rate   flexibility   is   measured   using   the   average   of   the   “coarse”  classification  in  Ilzetzki,  et  al.  (2008).  

3 Results  

3.1 Business-­‐cycle  volatility  in  resource-­‐rich  countries  We  investigate  the  relationship  between  business  cycle  volatility  and  resource  dependence  by  plotting  GDP  volatility   against   the   share  of   resource  exports   to  GDP.  Figure  1  plots   the  volatility   of   GDP   growth   against   resource   dependence   measured   as   share   of   resource  

                                                                                                                         11  http://www.ajediam.com/investing_diamonds_investment.html    

12    

exports  to  GDP  for  the  full  sample  of  countries,  while  Figure  2  only  plots  the  resource-­‐rich  ones,   defined  on   the  basis   of   resource  exports,   as   explained   in   the  previous   section.  Both  panels  illustrate  the  positive  correlation  between  resource  dependence  and  the  volatility  in  output  growth.    

Table  4  and  Table  5  provide  additional  evidence  on  the  latter.  We  use  advanced  techniques,  (HP  and  CF  filter)  to  determine  the  trends  in  GDP  and  explore  the  characteristics  of  business  cycles.  We  undertake  this   investigation   for  both  resource-­‐rich  and  resource-­‐poor  countries  and  compare   the   results  obtained  on   the   two  groups.  The  variable  of   interest   is   real  GDP.  Resource-­‐rich   countries   record   larger   expansions   and   contractions   in   terms   of   amplitude  compared   to   resource-­‐poor   countries.   Resource-­‐rich   countries   are   found   to   record   larger  gaps  in  good  times  but  also  to  record  larger  downturns  when  times  are  bad.  The  findings  are  confirmed  when  alternative  methodologies  are  employed  (HP,  CF  filter).    When  looking  into  more  detail  into  the  sample  countries,  the  results  show  that  volatility  is  more  of  a  resource-­‐rich  country  phenomenon  rather  than  a  developing-­‐country  phenomenon.  Volatility  is  found  higher   in   countries   dependent   on   natural   resources   compared   to   developing   ones   and  particularly  high  for  developing  resource-­‐rich  countries.      

Figure  1:  Volatility  of  GDP  growth  and  resource  dependency:  Evidence  from  full  sample  of  countries  

 

Notes:   Resource   Exports/GDP   is   the   ratio   of   primary   exports   to   GDP.   Primary   exports,   are   defined  according  to  Sachs  and  Warner  (1995),  as  the  sum  of  non-­‐fuel  commodity  categories  (UN  comtrade  categories   0,   1,   2,   4   and   68)   and   fuels   (category   3).   We   expand   the   definition   by   also   including  category  6672   (diamonds).  The  source   for  primary  exports   is  UN  Comtrade,  SITC  revision  1,  and   for  GDP  the  WDI  database  from  the  World  Bank.      

IRQ LBR

LBN ARM AZE

TJK

TJK

VNMNOR

NAMSGP

LTU

SYC

KIRMDA

OMN

SAU

AGO

KAZ

QATTTO

CHE

ZWEGNB

TKM

05

1015

20

S.D

of Y

early

GD

P G

row

th

0 20 40 60 80Average Resource Exports/GDP

13    

Figure  2:  Volatility  of  GDP  growth  and  resource  dependency:  Evidence  from  resource-­‐rich  countries  sample  

 

Notes:   Resource   Exports/GDP   is   the   ratio   of   primary   exports   to   GDP.   Primary   exports,   are   defined  according  to  Sachs  and  Warner  (1995),  as  the  sum  of  non-­‐fuel  commodity  categories  (UN  comtrade  categories   0,   1,   2,   4   and   68)   and   fuels   (category   3).   We   expand   the   definition   by   also   including  category  6672   (diamonds).  The  source   for  primary  exports   is  UN  comtrade,  SITC   revision  1,  and   for  GDP   the  WDI  database   from   the  World  Bank.  We  define   resource-­‐rich   countries  as   those   countries  that  have  a  ratio  of  commodity  exports  to  GDP  equal  to,  or  above  8%,  combined  with  revenues  from  commodity  exports   to   total  exports  equal   to,  or  above  60%,  provided   that   the   revenues   from   their  two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of  total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.    Table  4:  Business  cycle  characteristics  in  resource-­‐rich  and  resource-­‐poor  countries  

    Expansions   Contractions  HP-­‐Filter   Average  

Amplitude  Maximum  Amplitude  

Average  Incidence  

%  

Average  Amplitude  

Maximum  Amplitude  

Average  Incidence  

%  Resource-­‐Rich   2.5   8.6   50   -­‐2.6   -­‐9.3   50  Resource-­‐Poor   2.0   6.3   49   -­‐1.9   -­‐7.2   51  CF-­‐Filter   Average  

Amplitude  Maximum  Amplitude  

Average  Incidence  

%  

Average  Amplitude  

Maximum  Amplitude  

Average  Incidence  

%  Resource-­‐Rich   2.4   8.2   50   -­‐2.5   -­‐8.8   50  Resource-­‐Poor   1.9   6.0   50   -­‐2.0   -­‐6.9   50  

Notes:   Business   cycle   is   identified   as   a   deviation   in   real   GDP   relative   to   the   trend.   Trends   are  determined  with  Hodrick-­‐Prescott  (HP)  filter  and  Christiano-­‐Fitzerald  (CF)  filter.  Average  Amplitude  is  the  mean  of   the  positive  gaps;   Incidence   is   the  percentage  of  years  with  a  positive/negative  gap   in  percent  of  available  years.  We  define  resource-­‐rich  countries  as  those  countries  that  have  a  ratio  of  commodity  exports  to  GDP  equal  to,  or  above  8%,  combined  with  revenues  from  commodity  exports  to  total  exports  equal  to,  or  above  60%,  provided  that  the  revenues  from  their  two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of  total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.  

IRQ LBR

ARM AZE

TJK

GNB

NOR

KIR

SYCOMN

KAZ

AGO

BRNQAT

TKM

NAM

SAU

TTO

ZWE

05

1015

20

S.D

of Ye

arly

GDP

Grow

th

0 20 40 60 80Average Resource Exports/GDP

14    

Table  5:  Macroeconomic  volatility  and  natural  resources  

    Resource-­‐rich  Countries  

Resource-­‐poor  Countries  

Resource-­‐rich  Developing  Countries  

Resource-­‐poor  Developing  Countries  

Standard  Deviation  of  Output  Gap  in  %  (HP  filter)  

3.5   2.7   3.6   3.1  

Standard  Deviation  of  Output  Gap  in  %  (CF  filter)  

3.3   2.6   3.4   3.1  

Standard  Deviation  of  the  growth  rate  of  GDP  in  %  

6.2   4.7   6.3   5.5  

Notes:  Unweighted  average  of  countries.  Trends  are  determined  with  Hodrick-­‐Prescott  (HP)  filter  and  Christiano-­‐Fitzerald  (CF)  filter.  We  define  resource-­‐rich  countries  as  those  countries  that  have  a  ratio  of   commodity   exports   to   GDP   equal   to,   or   above   8%,   combined   with   revenues   from   commodity  exports   to   total   exports   equal   to,   or   above   60%,   provided   that   the   revenues   from   their   two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of  total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.  

3.2 Cyclicality  of  fiscal  policy  in  resource-­‐rich  countries  Individual  country  regression  results  show  that  on  average,  resource  rich  countries  are  more  pro-­‐cyclical   than   resource-­‐poor  countries   (Table  6).  However   the   results   should  be   treated  with  caution  as  in  most  instances  they  are  not  statistically  significant  and  they  are  subject  to  small  sample  problems12.  We  extend  the  investigation  of  the  procyclicality  of  fiscal  policy  by  plotting   the   estimated   coefficients   from   individual   country   regressions   against   resource  dependence  measured  as  the  share  of  resource  exports  to  GDP.  Several  plots  are  considered  making   use   of   alternative   samples   (world   countries   and   sample   of   resource-­‐rich   countries  only)   and  GDP   filters   (HP   and  CF).  Graphical   analysis   shows   that   procyclicality   is   positively  related  to  resource  abundance  particularly  in  the  case  of  resource-­‐rich  countries  (see  Figure  4  and  Figure  6).      

Table  6:  Average  estimates  of  fiscal  procyclicality  

GDP  filter  

Full  Sample  

Resource-­‐Rich  Countries  

Resource-­‐Rich  and  Developing  Countries  

Resource-­‐  Poor  Countries  

HP   -­‐28.890   1.625   0.242   -­‐53.134  

CF   0.369   3.630   4.463   -­‐2.120  

Notes:  Average  of  β  coefficients  of  output  gap  resulting  from  individual  country  regressions  specified  in   equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government  Consumption  Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV  estimations  which  use  Rest-­‐of-­‐Region  GDP  growth  as  an  instrument.   We   define   resource-­‐rich   countries   as   those   countries   that   have   a   ratio   of   commodity  exports   to   GDP   equal   to,   or   above   8%,   combined  with   revenues   from   commodity   exports   to   total  exports  equal  to,  or  above  60%,  provided  that  the  revenues  from  their  two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of  total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.  GDP  trends  determined  with  Hodrick-­‐Prescott  (HP)  filter  and  Christiano-­‐Fitzerald  (CF)  filter.  

                                                                                                                         12  To  save  space  in  the  paper  and  for  the  benefit  of  the  reader  we  report  only  average  of  individual  regression  results.  Individual  country  regression  results  can  be  made  available  by  the  authors  upon  request.    

15    

Figure  3:  Fiscal  procyclicality  and  resource  intensity,  Evidence  from  world  sample  countries  (GDP  filter:  HP)    

   

Notes:  Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government  Consumption  Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV  estimations  which  use  Rest-­‐of-­‐Region  GDP  growth  as  an  instrument.   GDP   trends   determined  with   Hodrick-­‐Prescott   (HP)   filter.   Resource   Exports/GDP   is   the  ratio  of  primary  exports  to  GDP.  Primary  exports,  are  defined  according  to  Sachs  and  Warner  (1995),  as   the   sum  of  non-­‐fuel   commodity   categories   (UN  comtrade  categories  0,  1,  2,  4  and  68)  and   fuels  (category   3).  We  expand   the  definition  by   also   including   category   6672   (diamonds).   The   source   for  primary  exports  is  UN  comtrade,  SITC  revision  1,  and  for  GDP  the  WDI  database  from  the  World  Bank.    

ALB

ARGATG

AUS

BDI

BELBENBFA

BGD BGR BHRBLZBOLBRABRB BRN

BTN

BWA

CAF

CAN

CHE

CHN CMR COG

COL

CPV CRICYPDEU

DMADNKDOM DZA

ECU

EGY

ESPETHFIN FJIFRA GABGBRGEO

GHA

GMB

GRC GRDGTMGUYHND

HRV

IDN

IND IRL IRNISLISRITA

JORJPNKEN

KGZ

KNA

KOR

KWT

LBRLCALKALSOLUX

LVA

MAR

MDGMEXMLIMLT

MOZ MRTMUS MWI

MYSNAMNER NICNLDNORNPL

NZL OMNPAK

PAN PER

PHL

PNGPOLPRT

PRY

RWA SAUSDN

SENSGPSLE

SLV SUR

SVK

SWESWZSYC

SYRTCD

TGOTHA

TJKTON

TTO

TUN

TUR

UGA

URYUSA VCTVUT

ZAF

ZAR

ZMB

-50

0

50

100

Bet

as

0 20 40 60 80Average Resource Exports/GDP (Whole Sample)

16    

Figure  4:  Fiscal  procyclicality  and  resource  intensity,  Evidence  from  the  sample  of  resource-­‐rich  countries  (GDP  filter:  HP)    

 

Notes:  Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government   Consumption   Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV   estimations   which   use   Rest-­‐of-­‐Region   GDP   growth   and  commodity   price   growth   as   instruments.   GDP   trends   determined   with   Hodrick-­‐Prescott   (HP)   filter.  Resource  Exports/GDP  is  the  ratio  of  primary  exports  to  GDP.  Primary  exports,  are  defined  according  to  Sachs  and  Warner  (1995),  as  the  sum  of  non-­‐fuel  commodity  categories  (UN  comtrade  categories  0,  1,  2,  4  and  68)  and   fuels   (category  3).  We  expand   the  definition  by  also   including  category  6672  (diamonds).   The   source   for   primary   exports   is  UN   comtrade,   SITC   revision   1,   and   for  GDP   the  WDI  database  from  the  World  Bank.  We  define  resource-­‐rich  countries  as  those  countries  that  have  a  ratio  of   commodity   exports   to   GDP   equal   to,   or   above   8%,   combined   with   revenues   from   commodity  exports   to   total   exports   equal   to,   or   above   60%,   provided   that   the   revenues   from   their   two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of  total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.  

 

In   order   to   investigate   further   this   issue   and   overcome   sample   problems   associated   with  individual   country   regressions   we   take   advantage   of   the   panel   dataset   and   estimate   a  pooled   regression.   The   pooled   results   indicate   that   fiscal   policy   not   only   tends   to   be  procyclical   in   resource-­‐rich   countries,   but   also   is   strongly   procyclical,   since   the   estimates  point   to  an   increase   in  government  consumption  of  about  2%,   following  an  1%   increase   in  GDP.  

 

AUS

BHRBLZ

BOLBRN

BWA

CAF

CMR

COG

COLCRI DZA

ECU

FJI GAB

GHA

GMB

GTM HNDIDN IRN

ISL

KEN

KWT

LCA

LKA

MARMLI

MOZ MRT

MWI

NORPER

PNG

PRY

SAUSDN

SENSYC

SYR

TGO

TTOURY

VCTVUT

ZAR

ZMB

-20

-10

0

10

20

Bet

as

0 20 40 60 80Average Resource Exports/GDP (Resource Rich)

17    

Figure  5:  Fiscal  procyclicality  and  resource  intensity,  Evidence  from  world  sample  (GDP  filter:  CF)    

 

Notes:  Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government  Consumption  Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV  estimations  which  use  Rest-­‐of-­‐Region  GDP  growth  as  an  instrument.  GDP  trends  determined  with  Christiano-­‐Fitzerald  (CF)  filter.  Resource  Exports/GDP  is  the  ratio  of  primary  exports  to  GDP.  Primary  exports,  are  defined  according  to  Sachs  and  Warner  (1995),  as   the   sum  of  non-­‐fuel   commodity   categories   (UN  comtrade  categories  0,  1,  2,  4  and  68)  and   fuels  (category   3).  We  expand   the  definition  by   also   including   category   6672   (diamonds).   The   source   for  primary  exports  is  UN  comtrade,  SITC  revision  1,  and  for  GDP  the  WDI  database  from  the  World  Bank.    

 

Table  7  presents   the   results   from  regressing   real  government  consumption  growth  on  real  GDP   growth.   Column   (1)   shows   that   the   positive   correlation   exists   even   with   an   OLS  regression.   Column   (2)   reports   the   results   when   the   growth   rate   in   the  main   commodity  price   export   is   used   to   instrument   for   GDP   growth.   The   positive   coefficient   is   statistically  significant   at   the   1%   level,   and   indicates   that   1   percent   increase   in   GDP   generates   a   2.7  percent  increase  in  real  government  consumption  growth.  The  weak  instrumental  variables  (WID)   hypothesis   is   rejected   when   using   the   Cragg-­‐Donald   F-­‐Statistic   for   i.i.d.   error  disturbances  since  it  exceeds  the  Staiger  and  Stock  (1997)  rule  of  thumb  of  ten  to  reject  the  hypothesis   of   weak   IVs,   therefore   passing   the   instrument   relevance   test   (see   Cragg   and  Donald,  1993).  

AGO

ALB ARG

AUSAUT

BDI

BELBEN

BFABGD

BGR BHRBLR

BLZ

BOL

BRABRB BRN

BTN

BWACAFCANCHECHN

CMR

COG

COL

CRICYPDEU DMADNK

DOM

DZA

ECU

EGYESPETHFIN FJIFRA

GABGBRGEO

GHA

GMB

GRC

GRD

GTM

GUY

HND

HUN

IDN

INDIRL

IRNISL

ISRITA

JORJPN KENKGZ

KNAKOR

KWT

LBRLCALKALSOLUX

LVA

MAR

MDGMEX

MKDMLIMLT MNGMOZMUS MWI MYS

NER

NICNLDNORNPL

NZL

OMN

PAK

PAN PERPHLPNGPOL

PRT

PRY

ROM

RWA SDN

SEN

SGPSLE

SLVSUR

SVK

SVNSWE

SWZ

SYC

SYRTCD

TGO

THATON

TTOTUN

TUR

UGAUKR

URYUSA

VCTVNM

VUT

ZAF

ZAR

ZMB

-50

0

50

100

Bet

as

0 20 40 60 80Average Resource Exports/GDP (Whole Sample)

18    

Figure  6:    Fiscal  procyclicality  and  resource  intensity,  Evidence  from  the  sample  of  resource-­‐rich  countries  (GDP  filter:  CF)    

 

Notes:   Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government   Consumption   Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV   estimations   which   use   Rest-­‐of-­‐Region   GDP   growth   and  commodity  price  growth  as  instruments.  GDP  trends  determined  with  Christiano-­‐Fitzerald  (CF)  filter.  Resource  Exports/GDP  is  the  ratio  of  primary  exports  to  GDP.  Primary  exports,  are  defined  according  to  Sachs  and  Warner  (1995),  as  the  sum  of  non-­‐fuel  commodity  categories  (UN  comtrade  categories  0,  1,  2,  4  and  68)  and   fuels   (category  3).  We  expand   the  definition  by  also   including  category  6672  (diamonds).   The   source   for   primary   exports   is  UN   comtrade,   SITC   revision   1,   and   for  GDP   the  WDI  database  from  the  World  Bank.  We  define  resource-­‐rich  countries  as  those  countries  that  have  a  ratio  of   commodity   exports   to   GDP   equal   to,   or   above   8%,   combined   with   revenues   from   commodity  exports   to   total   exports   equal   to,   or   above   60%,   provided   that   the   revenues   from   their   two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of  total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.  

Column  (3)  uses  the  regional  GDP  growth  as  an  IV  and  the  results  are  similar  in  terms  of  sign,  as  the  procyclicality  coefficient  remains  positive  and  statistically  significant  but  rises  from  2.7  to   3.8   (but  with  wider   confidence   intervals)13.  Using  both   IVs   in   (4)  we   get   similar   results,                                                                                                                            13  Comparing  the  first  stage  F-­‐statistics  across  the  two  specifications,  it  looks  like  the  commodity  price  IV  is  more  relevant  than  the  regional  GDP  one  (the  first  stage  F-­‐statistic  is  21.10  in  the  first  case  versus  4.21  in  the  second).  Thus,  the  rest-­‐of-­‐region  GDP  turns  out  to  be  a  weaker  instrument  for  our  particular  sample  of  resource-­‐rich  countries.  This  is  also  illustrated  by  the  p-­‐value  in  the  Angrist-­‐Pischke  (AP)  test  statistic  that  rises  from  0  to  0.04  (still  a  valid  IV  nevertheless  at  the  five  percent  level  of  statistical  significance).  

AUSBHR

BLZ

BOL

BRN

BWA

CAF

CMR

COG

COL

CRI DZA

ECU

FJI GAB

GHA

GMB

HND

IDN

IRNISL

KENKWTLCALKA

MARMDG

MLI

MOZ

MWI

NORPER

PNG

PRYSAU

SDNSEN

SYCSYR

TGO

TTO

URY

VCT

VUT

ZMB

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

Bet

as

0 20 40 60 80Average Resource Exports/GDP (Resource Rich)

19    

with   the  coefficient   remaining  strongly   statistically   significant  at   the  one  percent   level  and  remaining   stable   at   around   2.6.   The   Cragg-­‐Donald   and   AP   statistics   illustrate   how   both  instruments   remain   relevant.   Also,   according   to   the   Sargan   test   for   overidentified  restrictions,  where  the  joint  null  hypothesis  is  that  the  instruments  are  valid,  the  p-­‐value  is  0.1549,  suggesting  that  we  cannot  reject  instrument  validity.  

Table  7  :  Cyclicality  of  real  government  consumption  growth  

  (1)   (2)   (3)   (4)  

  OLS   IV  Prices   IV  RR  GDP  IV  Prices  +  RR  

GDP  

GDP  Growth   0.778***  (0.057)  

2.674***  (0.745)  

3.806*  (1.978)  

2.615***  (0.721)  

         

Real  Government  Consumption  Growth  (t-­‐1)  

0.103***  (0.019)  

0.019  (0.040)  

0.008  (0.051)  

0.014  (0.037)  

         Observations   2317   2153   2275   2113  Number  of  Groups   76   72   74   71  Average  Group   30.49   29.90   30.74   29.76  R2  overall   0.11   0.09   0.09   0.09  First  Stage  F-­‐statistic   -­‐   21.10   4.209   10.74  AP  (p-­‐value)   -­‐   0.0000   0.0403   0.0000  Cragg-­‐Donald  F-­‐statistic   -­‐   21.10   4.209   10.74    Notes:    Dependent  variable:  Real  Government  Consumption  Growth.  All   regressions   include  country  fixed  effects  and  time-­‐decade  effects  (not  reported).  Standard  errors  in  parentheses.    *  Significant  at  10%,  **  significant  at  5%,  ***  significant  at  1%.  OLS  estimation  is  in  Column  (1)  and  IV  estimations  are  in  Columns  (2),  (3)  and  (4).  Column  (2)  uses  Real  Commodity  Price  Growth  as  an  instrument;  Column  (3)   uses  Rest-­‐of-­‐Region  GDP  growth  as   an   instrument,   Column   (4)   uses  both  Real   Commodity  Price  Growth  and  Rest-­‐of-­‐Region  GDP  Growth  as  instruments.  Weak  identification  tests  are  also  reported.  The  Cragg-­‐Donald  Wald  F-­‐statistic  and  the  p-­‐value  of  the    Angrist-­‐Pischke  (AP)  multivariate  F-­‐test  (the  Cragg-­‐Donald   Wald   F-­‐statistic   and   the   F-­‐test   from   a   first-­‐stage   regression   in   the   case   of   a   single  endogenous  regressor  are  equivalent).    

The   estimates   from   Table   7   are   also   economically   significant.   They   indicate   that   a   1%  exogenous  rise  in  GDP  growth  leads  to  a  2.6%  rise  in  real  government  consumption  growth.  This  illustrates  quite  a  large  procyclical  response  of  fiscal  policy  to  GDP  changes  and  justifies  the  focus  on  understanding  commodity  price  booms  and  busts  to  guide  policy  makers  (see  for   instance   Deaton   and   Laroque,   1996).   These   results   support   the   hypothesis   that   fiscal  policy   is   strongly   procyclical   in   resource-­‐rich   countries,   both   in   terms   of   statistical  significance  and  economic  magnitude.    

3.3 Fiscal  procyclicality  and  macroeconomic  volatility  In  order  to  analyse  the  links  between  fiscal  procyclcialcity  and  macroeconomic  volatility  we  need   heterogeneity   in   fiscal   procyclicality,   hence   we   must   rely   on   the   individual   country  

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                             

20    

regressions   estimates   of   procyclicality,   which   were   not   statistically   significant   in   many  instances.   Nevertheless,   following   the   literature   we   use   these   estimates   as   indicators   of  procyclicality.   To   motivate   the   discussion   on   fiscal   procyclicality   and   macroeconomic  volatility  we  plot  the  volatility  of  GDP  growth  against  the  beta  coefficients  resulting  from  the  individual   country   regressions   discussed   in   the   previous   section.  We  plot   volatility   of  GDP  growth  against  betas  for  the  sample  of  resource  rich  countries  and  for  the  whole  sample  of  countries.  Betas  estimations  when  both  GDP  lifters  i.e.  HP  and  CF  are  used  are  reported.  The  plots   illustrate   the   positive   relationship   between   macroeconomic   volatility   and   fiscal  procyclicality  particularly  with  regards  to  resource-­‐rich  countries.    

Figure  7:  Volatility  and  fiscal  procyclicality:  Evidence  from  world  sample  countries  (GDP  filter:  HP)    

 

Notes:  Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government  Consumption  Growth  (t-­‐1).  IV  estimations  which  use  Rest-­‐of-­‐Region  GDP  as  instrument.  GDP  trends  determined  with  Hodrick-­‐Prescott  (HP)  filter.    

 

 

 

ALB

ARGATG

AUS

BDI

BELBENBFABGD

BGRBHR

BHS

BLZBOL

BRABRB

BRN

BTNBWA CAF

CAN CHE

CHNCMR

COG

COLCPVCRICYP

DEU

DMA

DNK

DOMDZA

ECUEGYESP

ETH

FINFJI

FRA

GAB

GBR

GEO

GHAGMB GRC

GRD

GTM

GUY

HND HRVIDN INDIRL

IRN

ISLISR

ITA

JOR

JPN

KEN

KGZ

KNAKOR

KWT

LAO

LBR

LCA

LKA

LSO

LUX

LVA

MARMDG

MEXMLIMLT

MOZMRT

MUS

MWI

MYSNAM

NERNIC

NLDNORNPLNZL

OMN

PAK

PANPER

PHLPNG

POLPRTPRY

RWA

SAUSDN

SENSGP

SLE

SLV

SUR SVK

SWE

SWZ

SYC

SYR

TCD

TGO

THA

TJK

TONTTOTUN

TUR

UGA

URY

USA

VCTVUT

ZAF

ZAR ZMB

0

.05

.1

.15

Vola

tility

of G

DP

Gro

wth

-50 0 50 100Betas

21    

Figure  8:  Volatility  and  fiscal  procyclicality:  Evidence  from  resource-­‐rich  countries  (GDP  filter:  HP)    

 Notes:  Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government   Consumption   Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV   estimations   which   use   Rest-­‐of-­‐Region   GDP   growth   and  commodity  price  growth  as  instruments.  GDP  trends  determined  with  Hodrick-­‐Prescott  (HP)  filter.  We  define   resource-­‐rich   countries   as   those   countries   that   have   a   ratio   of   commodity   exports   to   GDP  equal  to,  or  above  8%,  combined  with  revenues  from  commodity  exports  to  total  exports  equal  to,  or  above  60%,  provided  that   the  revenues   from  their   two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of   total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.  

Figure  9:  Volatility  and  fiscal  procyclicality:  Evidence  from  world  sample  countries  (GDP  filter:  CF)    

 

Notes:  Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government   Consumption   Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV   estimations   which   use   Rest-­‐of-­‐Region   GDP   growth   as  instrument.  GDP  trends  determined  with  Christiano-­‐Fitzgerald  (CF)  filter.    

AUS

BHRBLZBOL

BRN

BWACAF CMRCOG

COL

CRI

DZA

ECUFJI

GAB

GHAGMB

GTMHNDIDN

IRN

ISLKEN

KWTLCA

LKA

MARMLI

MOZMRT MWI

NOR

PERPNG

PRY

SAUSDN

SEN

SYC

SYRTGO

TTO

URY

VCTVUT

ZARZMB

0

.05

.1

.15

Volat

ility o

f GDP

Grow

th

-20 -10 0 10 20Betas

AGO

ALB

ARG

AUSAUT

BDI

BEL

BENBFABGD

BGRBHR

BHS

BLR

BLZ BRABRB

BRN

BTN BWACAF

CANCHE

CHN

CMRCOG

COL

CRICYPDEU

DMA

DNK

DOM

DZA

ECU EGY

ESP

ETH

FINFJI

FRA

GAB

GBR

GEO

GHAGMB GRCGRD

GTM

GUYHUN

IDNINDIRL

IRN

ISLISR

ITA

JOR

JPN

KEN

KGZ

KNAKORLAO

LBR

LCA

LKA

LSO

LUX

LVA

MAR MDGMEX

MKD

MLI

MLT

MNGMOZ

MUS

MWI

MYS

NER

NIC

NLDNORNPL

NZL

OMN

PAK

PANPER

PHL

PNG

POLPRTPRY

ROM

RWA

SDN

SENSGP

SLE

SLV

SUR

SVK SVNSWE

SWZ

SYC

SYR

TCD

TGO

THATON

TTOTUN

TURUGA

UKRURY

USA

VCT

VNM

VUT

ZAFZARZMB

0

.05

.1

.15

Volat

ility o

f GDP

Grow

th

-40 -20 0 20 40Betas

22    

Figure  10:    Volatility  and  fiscal  procyclicality:  Evidence  from  resource-­‐rich  countries  (GDP  filter:  CF)    

 

Notes:  Betas  are   individual   country   regression  estimations   (β   coefficient)  of  output  gap   specified   in  equation   (1).   Dependent   variable:   Real   Government   Consumption   Growth.   Controls:   Real  Government   Consumption   Growth   (t-­‐1).   IV   estimations   which   use   Rest-­‐of-­‐Region   GDP   growth   and  commodity  price  growth  as  instruments.  GDP  trends  determined  with  Christiano-­‐Fitzgerald  (CF)  filter.  We  define  resource-­‐rich  countries  as  those  countries  that  have  a  ratio  of  commodity  exports  to  GDP  equal  to,  or  above  8%,  combined  with  revenues  from  commodity  exports  to  total  exports  equal  to,  or  above  60%,  provided  that   the  revenues   from  their   two  main  commodity  exports  as  a  share  of   total  exports  are  equal  to,  or  greater  than,  40%.    

 

To  test  the  hypothesis  that  countries  with  more  procyclical  fiscal  policies  record  also  greater  macroeconomic   volatility   we   look   into   the   correlation   among   the   latter   controlling   for  additional  characteristics  of  political  institutions,  financial  development,  exchange  rates  and  initial   GDP.   Regression   results   are   summarized   in   Table   8.   Column   (1)   reports   the   results  when  measures  of  fiscal  procyclicality  (beta  coefficients)  employed  result  from  IV  regression  estimations  when  rest-­‐of-­‐region  GDP   is  used  as   instrument.  Column  (2)   reports   the  results  when  measures  of  fiscal  procyclicality  (beta  coefficients)  employed  result  from  IV  regression  estimations   when   rest-­‐of-­‐region   GDP   and   growth   in   commodity   price   are   used   as  instruments.  Estimations  on  fiscal  procyclicality  are  found  positive  and  statistically  significant  in  both   specifications,   indicating   that   fiscal   procyclicality   and  macroeconomic   volatility   are  positively  correlated.  Correlation  is  found  higher  for  resource-­‐rich  countries.    

Further   interesting   findings   show   that  macroeconomic   volatility   is   positively   correlated   to  poor   political   rights.   These   results   confirm   earlier   findings   in   the   literature  which   suggest  

AUS

BHRBLZ BOL

BRN

BWA CAFCMRCOG

COL

CRI

DZA

ECUFJI

GAB

GHAGMB HND IDN

IRN

ISL KEN

KWTLCA

LKA

MARMDG MLIMOZMWI

NOR

PERPNG

PRYSAU

SDN

SEN

SYC

SYRTGO

TTO

URY

VCTVUT

ZMB

0

.05

.1

.15

Vola

tility

of G

DP

Gro

wth

-15 -10 -5 0 5 10Betas

23    

that   weak   institutions   which   fail   to   constrain   politicians   and   political   elites   or   to   enforce  property   rights   are   associated   with   higher   volatility   (see   Acemoglu   et   al,   2002   and  Barseghyan   and   DiCecio,   2009).   In   contrast   macroeconomic   volatility   is   found   to   be  negatively   correlated   to   financial   development.   These   findings   add   to   the   evidence   that  financial   depth   plays   an   important   part   in   dampening   macroeconomic   volatility   (Dabla-­‐Norris  and  Srivisal,  2013)  and  support   the   theory   that  more  efficient   financial  markets  can  contribute   to   lower   macroeconomic   volatility   through   risk   amelioration,   improvement   of  corporate   governance,   mobilization   of   savings,   reduction   of   transaction   and   information  costs,  and  promotion  of  specialization  (Bencivenga  and  Smith,  1992  and  Levine,  1997).    

Table  8:  Macroeconomic  volatility  and  fiscal  procyclicality  

  (1)   (2)  

  One  Instrument   Combined  Instruments  

Fiscal  Procyclicality   0.00758***   0.00797***  

  (0.00212)   (0.00196)  

Political  Rights  Ranking   0.0270***   0.0231***  

  (0.00690)   (0.00587)  

Private  Credit  to  GDP  Ratio   -­‐0.000164***   -­‐0.000154***  

  (0.0000427)   (0.0000444)  

Democracy   0.000497   0.00219  

  (0.00325)   (0.00285)  Exchange  Rate  Flexibility  Index  

-­‐0.000185   -­‐0.000453  

  (0.00142)   (0.00122)  

Initial  GDP  per  Capita  (log)   0.00351**   0.00323***  

  (0.00137)   (0.00122)  

N   130   120  

r2   0.280   0.281  

r2_a   0.245   0.242  

F   22.45   24.22  

Column   (1)   reports   the   results   when  measures   of   fiscal   procyclicality   (beta   coefficients)   employed  result   from   IV   regression   estimations   when   rest-­‐of-­‐region   GDP   is   used   as   instrument.   Column   (2)  reports  the  results  when  measures  of  fiscal  procyclicality  (beta  coefficients)  employed  result  from  IV  regression   estimations   when   rest-­‐of-­‐region   GDP   and   growth   in   commodity   price   are   used   as  instruments.   The  dependent   variable   is   the   volatility   of   estimated  output   gaps   (HP   filter).   Standard  errors  in  parentheses.  Constant  Omitted.  *  p<0.10,  **  p<0.05,  ***  p<0.01    

Last  macroeconomic  volatility  appears  to  be  positively  related  to  the  initial  income  level.  The  result   is   consistent   with   evidence   that   when   wealth   is   high   consumers   demand   is   not  sensitive  to  unemployment  expectations  and  the  economy  is  robust  to  crisis.  When  wealth  is  

24    

low,  consumers'  demand  is  sensitive  to  unemployment  expectations;  the  economy  becomes  vulnerable  to  fluctuations  and  it  is  in  general,  more  volatile  (see  Perri  and  Heathcote,  2012).  

4 Conclusions  We  analysed  business  cycle  characteristics  in  resource-­‐rich  and  resource-­‐poor  countries  and  its  links  to  fiscal  policy  procyclicality.  Standard  business  cycle  techniques  to  analyse  “growth  cycles”  showed  that  volatility  is  indeed  higher  in  resource-­‐rich  countries  and  that  increased  macroeconomic   volatility   is   a   resource-­‐rich   country   phenomenon  more   than   a   developing  country  phenomenon.    

The  study  also  found  fiscal  procyclicality  to  be  higher  in  resource-­‐rich  countries  compared  to  resource-­‐poor  ones.  Although   individual   country   estimates  of   fiscal   pro-­‐cyclicality  must  be  taken  with   reservation  given   the   short   sample  available   for   fiscal   variables   in  a  number  of  countries,   panel   data   estimates   confirm   the   pro-­‐cyclicality   of   fiscal   policy   in   resource-­‐rich  countries.    

In   identifying   the   links   between   fiscal   procyclicality   and   macroeconomic   volatility   the  analysis   presented   has   showed   that   they   are   positively   correlated.   Factors   related   to  institutional  quality  and  financial  depth  among  others  have  also  been  found  to  be  correlated  to   volatility.   Although   it   is   difficult   to   establish   causality   in   this   analysis,   the   positive  correlation   between   fiscal   procyclicality   and   business-­‐cycle   volatility   indicates   that   booms  and   busts   in   fiscal   spending   caused   by   ups   and   downs   in   resource   prices   are   likely   to   be  exacerbating  macroeconomic  fluctuations  in  resource-­‐rich  countries  rather  than  dampening  it.  The  question  is  whether  it  may  be  possible  to  discipline  fiscal  policy  in  these  countries  to  contain  these  effects.  

Based   on   this   evidence   we   aim   to   extend   this   research   by   looking   at   the   factors   that  contribute  to  procyclical  fiscal  policy   in  resource-­‐rich  countries  with  particular  emphasis  on  institutions.   Recent   studies   have   suggested   that   countries   that   have   been   able   to   address  the   fiscal   policy   challenges   associated   with   the   natural   resource   endowments   have   been  those   that   have   put   in   place   strong   fiscal   institutions.   Nevertheless   empirical   and   country  evidence  on  this  matter  remains  inconclusive,  and  a  systematic  analysis  of  fiscal  policy  pro-­‐cyclicality  and  of  the  fiscal  arrangements  which  can  contribute  to  macroeconomic  stability  in  resource  rich  countries  can  offer  valuable  contributions  to  this  debate.  

 

 

   

25    

5 References  Acemoglu,  D.,  Johnson,  S.,  Robinson,  J.  and  Thaicharoen,  Y.  (2002).    ‘Institutional  causes,  macroeconomic  symptoms:  Volatility,  crises  and  growth’.  NBER  Working  Paper  9124.  NBER  Working  Paper  Series.  

Aghion,  P.;  Angeletos,  G.-­‐M.;  Banerjee,  A.  &  Manova,  K.  (2010).  'Volatility  and  growth:  Credit  constraints  and  the  composition  of  growth.',  Journal  of  Monetary  Economics  57,  246-­‐265.  

Alesina,  A.;   Tabellini,  G.  &  Campante,   F.   R.   (2008),   'Why   is   fiscal   policy  often  procyclical?',  Journal  of  the  European  Economic  Association  6(5),  1006-­‐1036.  

Arezki,   R.,   &   van   der   Ploeg,   F.   (2011).   ‘Do   Natural   Resources   Depress   Income   Per  Capita?’  Review  of  Development  Economics,  15(3),  504-­‐521.  

Barseghyan,  L.,  and  DiCecio,  R.  (2009).  ‘Institutional  causes  of  macroeconomic  volatility’.  Federal  Reserve  Bank  of  St.  Louis  Working  Paper  2008-­‐021C  

Beetsma,  R.,  and  Giuliodori,  M.  (2010).  ‘The  Macroeconomic  Costs  and  Benefits  of  the  EMU  and  Other  Monetary  Unions:  An  Overview  of  Recent  Research’.  Journal  of  Economic  Literature,  vol.  48(3):  603-­‐641.  

Bencivenga,  V.R.  and  Smith,  B.D.  (1992).  ‘Financial  intermediation  and  endogenous  growth’.  Review  of  Economic  Studies,  58,  195-­‐209.    

Bénétrix,  Agustín,  and  Philip  Lane,  2010.  ‘International  differences  in  fiscal  policy  during  the  global  crisis’.  NBER  Working  Papers  16346.  

Catão,  L.  &  Sutton,  B.  (2002).  'Sovereign  defaults  the  role  of  volatility'.  IMF  Working  Paper.  

Christiano,   L.,   I.,   and   Fitzgerald,   T.   (2003).   ‘The   Band   Pass   Filter’.  International   Economic  Review,  44(2),    435-­‐465.  

Collier,   P.   &   Hoeffler,   A.   (2009).   'Testing   the   neocon   agenda:   Democracy   in   resource-­‐rich  societies'.  European  Economic  Review  53(3),  293-­‐308.  

Cragg,  J.G.  and  Donald,  S.G.  (1993).  ‘Testing  identifiability  and  specification  in  instrumental  variables  models’..  Econometric  Theory,  9,  222-­‐240.  

Dabla-­‐Norris,  E.,  and  Srivisal,  N.  (2013).  ‘Revisiting  the  link  between  finance  and  macroeconomic  volatility’.  IMF  Working  Paper  13/09.  International  Monetary  Fund.    

Deaton,  A.,  and  Laroque,  G.    (1996).  ‘Competitive  storage  and  commodity  price  dynamics’.  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  104  (5),  896-­‐923.  

Deaton,   A.   and   Miller,   R.   (1996).   'International   commodity   prices,   macroeconomic  performance  and  politics  in  Sub-­‐Saharan  Africa'.  Journal  of  African  Economies  5(3),  99-­‐191.  

Fatás,  A.  and  Mihov,   I.   (2006).   'The  macroeconomic  effects  of   fiscal   rules   in   the  US  states',  Journal  of  Public  Economics,  90(1-­‐2),  101-­‐117.  

Frankel,  J.  (2010).  'The  natural  resource  curse:  A  survey'.  NBER  Working  Paper  15846.  

Gali,   J.   &   Perotti,   R.   (2003).   'Fiscal   policy   and   monetary   integration   in   Europe'.   Economic  

26    

Policy  18(37),  533-­‐572.  

Gavin,   M.   and   Perotti,   R.   (1997).   'Fiscal   policy   in   Latin   America'.   NBER   Macroeconomics  Annual  12,  11-­‐72.  

Hodrick,  Robert  J.,  and  Edward  C.  Prescott  (1980).  ‘Postwar  U.S.  Business  Cycles:  An  Empirical  Investigation’.  Carnegie  Mellon  University  discussion  paper  no.  451  (1980).  

Hodrick,  Robert  J.,  and  Edward  C.  Prescott,(1997).’  Postwar  U.S.  Business  Cycles:  An  Empirical  Investigation’.    Journal  of  Money,  Credit  and  Banking  29:1  (1997),  1–16.  

IMF  (2010).  'Managing  natural  resource  wealth'.  Program  Document.  

Ilzetzki,  R.,  and  Rogoff,  K.    (2008),  “Exchange  Rate  Arrangements  Entering  the  21st  Century:  Which  Anchor  Will  Hold?”,  Unpublished  Paper,  Harvard  University.  

Ilzetzki,  E.  and  Vegh,  C.  A.  (2008).   'Procyclical  fiscal  policy   in  developing  countries:  Truth  or  fiction?'.  NBER  Working  Papers  14191.  

Jaimovich,   D.,   and   Panizza,   U.   (2007).   ‘Procyclicality   or   Reverse   Causality?’.   IDB   Working  Paper  No.  501.    

Kalyuzhnova,   Y.   (2008).   Economics   of   the   Caspian   Oil   and   Gas   Wealth:   Companies,  Governments,  Policies,  Palgrave  MacMillan.  

Kaminsky,  G.,  Reinhart,  C.,  and  Vegh,  C.  (2004).  ‘When  it  rains,  it  pours:  Procyclical  capital  flows  and  macroeconomic  policies’.  NBER  Working  Papers  10780,  NBER.  

Levine,  R.  (1997).    ‘Financial  development  and  economic  growth:  Views  and  agenda’.  Journal  of  Economic  Literature,  35,  688-­‐726.  

Loayza,   N.;   Rancière,   R.;   Servén,   L.   and   Ventura,   J.   (2007),   'Macroeconomic   volatility   and  welfare   in   developing   countries:   An   introduction'.   The   World   Bank   Economic   Review,   21,  343-­‐357.  

Morten   O.   Ravn   and   Harald   Uhlig   (2002).   ‘On   adjusting   the   hodrick-­‐prescott   filter   for   the  frequency  of  observations’.  The  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  May  2002,  84(2):  371–380.  

Perri,  F.  and  Heathcote,  J.  (2012).  ‘Wealth  and  volatility’,  2012  Meeting  Papers  914,  Society  for  Economic  Dynamics.  

Priesmeier,  C.and  Stähler,  N.  (2011).  'Long  dark  shadows  or  innovative  spirits?  The  effects  of  (Smoothing)   business   cycles   on   economic   growth:   A   survey   of   the   literature'.   Journal   of  Economic  Surveys  25(5),  898-­‐912.  

Ramey,   G.and   Ramey,   V.   A.   (1995).   'Cross-­‐country   evidence   on   the   link   between   volatility  and  growth'.  The  American  Economic  Review  85(5),  1138-­‐1151.  

Ravn,  M.  O.,  and  H.  Uhlig  (2002).  ‘On  adjusting  the  Hodrick–Prescott  filter  for  the  frequency  of  observations’.  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics  84:  371–376.  

Sachs,  J.  D.    and  Warner,  A.  M.  (1995).  'Natural  resource  abundance  and  economic  growth'.  NBER  Working  Paper  No.  5398.  

27    

Schaechter,A.,   Kinda,   T.   Budina,   N.   and  Weber,   A.   (2012).   ‘Fiscal   rules   in   response   to   the  crisis-­‐towards   the   ’Next-­‐Generation’   rules.   A   new   dataset’.   IMF   Working   Papers   12/187,  International  Monetary  Fund.  

Staiger,  D.,  and  Stock,   J.   (1997).   ‘Instrumental  variables  regression  with  weak   instruments’.  Econometrica,  65(3),  557-­‐586.  

Tsani,   S.   (2013).   ‘Natural   resources,   governance   and   institutional   quality:   The   role   of  resource  funds',  Resources  Policy,  38(2),  181-­‐195.  

Van   der   Ploeg,   F.and   Poelhekke,   S.   (2008).   'Volatility   and   the   natural   resource   curse'.    Oxcarre  Research  Paper  No  2008-­‐03,  Department  of  Economics,  University  of  Oxford.  

 

               

28    

Appendix  A:  Sample  of  resource-­‐rich  and  resource-­‐poor  countries  Resource-­‐rich  countries  Algeria,  Angola,  Armenia,    Australia,  Azerbaijan,  Bahamas,  The  Bahrain,  Belize,  Bolivia,  Botswana,  Brunei  Darussalam,    Cameroon,  Central  African  Republic,  Chile,  Colombia,  Congo  Dem.  Rep.,  Rep.  Congo,  Costa  Rica,  Cote  d'Ivoire,  Cuba,  Ecuador,  Faeroe  Islands,  Fiji,  Gabon,    Gambia,  The  Ghana,  Greenland,  Grenada,  Guatemala,  Guinea,  Guyana,  Honduras,  Iceland,  Indonesia,  Iran,  Islamic  Rep.,  Iraq,  Kazakhstan,  Kenya,  Kiribati,  Kuwait,  Liberia,  Libya,  Madagascar,  Malawi,  Maldives,  Mali,  Mauritania,  Moldova,  Mongolia,  Montenegro,  Morocco,  Mozambique,  Namibia,  New  Zealand,  Nicaragua,  Niger,  Nigeria,  Norway,  Oman,  Papua  New  Guinea,  Paraguay,  Peru,  Qatar,  Russian  Federation,  Saudi  Arabia,  Senegal,  Seychelles,  Sierra  Leone,  Solomon  Islands,  Somalia,  Sri  Lanka,  St.  Lucia,  St.  Vincent  and  the  Grenadines,  Sudan,  Syrian  Arab  Republic,  Tajikistan,  Togo,  Trinidad  and  Tobago,  Turkmenistan,  United  Arab  Emirates,  Uruguay,  Vanuatu,  Venezuela,  Virgin  Islands  (U.S.),  Yemen,  Zambia,  Zimbabwe  Resource  poor  countries  Aruba,  Andorra,  Afghanistan,  Albania,  Argentina,  American  Samoa,  Antigua  and  Barbuda,  Austria,  Burundi,  Belgium,  Benin,  Burkina  Faso,  Bangladesh,  Bulgaria,  Bosnia  and  Herzegovina,  Belarus,  Bermuda,  Brazil,  Barbados,  Bhutan,  Canada,  Switzerland,  China,  Comoros,  Cape  Verde,  Cayman  Islands,  Cyprus,  Czech  Republic,  Germany,  Djibouti,  Dominica,  Denmark,  Dominican  Republic,  Egypt,  Eritrea,  Spain,  Estonia,  Ethiopia,  Finland,    France,  United  Kingdom,  Georgia,  Guinea-­‐Bissau,  Greece,  Croatia,  Haiti,  Hungary,  India,  Ireland,  Israel,  Italy,  Jamaica,  Jordan,  Japan,  Kyrgyz  Republic,  Cambodia,  St.  Kitts  and  Nevis  Korea,  Lao  PDR,  Lebanon,  Lesotho,  Lithuania,  Luxembourg,  Latvia,  Mexico,  Macedonia  FYR,  Malta,  Myanmar,  Mauritius,  Malaysia,  New  Caledonia,  Netherlands,  Nepal,  Pakistan,  Panama,  Philippines,  Poland,  Portugal,  French  Polynesia,  Romania,  Rwanda,  Singapore,  El  Salvador,  Serbia,  Suriname,  Slovak  Republic,  Slovenia,  Sweden,  Swaziland,  Turks  and  Caicos  Islands,  Chad,  Thailand,  Tonga,  Tunisia,  Turkey,  Tuvalu,  Tanzania,  Uganda,  Ukraine,    United  States,  Vietnam,  West  Bank  and  Gaza,  Samoa,  South  Africa  Notes:  We  define  resource-­‐rich  countries  as  those  countries  that  have  a  ratio  of  commodity  exports  to  GDP  equal  to,  or  above  8%,  combined  with  revenues  from  commodity  exports  to  total  exports  equal  to,  or  above  60%,  provided  that  the  revenues  from  their  two  main