Chapter 2: Demand Theory · PDF filebounded set, then the solution to such optimization...

Preview:

Citation preview

Demand Theory

Utility Maximization Problem

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

Utility Maximization Problem

โ€ข Consumer maximizes his utility level by selecting a bundle ๐‘ฅ (where ๐‘ฅ can be a vector) subject to his budget constraint:

max๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

s. t. ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค

โ€ข Weierstrass Theorem: for optimization problems defined on the reals, if the objective function is continuous and constraints define a closed and bounded set, then the solution to such optimization problem exists.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 3

Utility Maximization Problem

โ€ข Existence: if ๐‘ โ‰ซ 0 and ๐‘ค > 0 (i.e., if ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค is closed and bounded), and if ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is continuous, then there exists at least one solution to the UMP.โ€“ If, in addition, preferences are strictly convex, then the

solution to the UMP is unique.

โ€ข We denote the solution of the UMP as the ๐š๐ซ๐ ๐ฆ๐š๐ฑ of the UMP (the argument, ๐‘ฅ, that solves the optimization problem), and we denote it as ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค). โ€“ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is the Walrasian demand correspondence, which

specifies a demand of every good in โ„+๐ฟ for every possible

price vector, ๐‘, and every possible wealth level, ๐‘ค.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 4

Utility Maximization Problem

โ€ข Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)at bundle A is optimal, as the consumer reaches a utility level of ๐‘ข2 by exhausting all his wealth.

โ€ข Bundles B and C are not optimal, despite exhausting the consumerโ€™s wealth. They yield a lower utility level ๐‘ข1, where ๐‘ข1 < ๐‘ข2.

โ€ข Bundle D is unaffordable and, hence, it cannot be the argmax of the UMP given a wealth level of ๐‘ค.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 5

Properties of Walrasian Demand

โ€ข If the utility function is continuous and preferences satisfy LNS over the consumption set ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ , then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) satisfies:

1) Homogeneity of degree zero:

๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ฅ(๐›ผ๐‘, ๐›ผ๐‘ค) for all ๐‘, ๐‘ค, and for all ๐›ผ > 0

That is, the budget set is unchanged!

๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+๐ฟ : ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค = ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ : ๐›ผ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐›ผ๐‘ค

Note that we donโ€™t need any assumption on the preference relation to show this. We only rely on the budget set being affected.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 6

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 7

โ€“ Note that the preference relation can be linear, and homog(0) would still hold.

x2

x1

2 2

w w

p p

1 1

w w

p p

x(p,w) is unaffected

2) Walrasโ€™ Law:

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ค for all ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

It follows from LNS: if the consumer selects a Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค), where ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ < ๐‘ค, then it means we can still find other bundle ๐‘ฆ, which is ฮตโ€“close to ๐‘ฅ, where consumer can improve his utility level.

If the bundle the consumer chooses lies on the budget line, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘ค, we could then identify bundles that are strictly preferred to ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ, but these bundles would be unaffordable to the consumer.

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 8

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 9

โ€“ For ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค), there is a bundle ๐‘ฆ, ฮตโ€“close to ๐‘ฅ, such that ๐‘ฆ โ‰ป ๐‘ฅ. Then, ๐‘ฅ โˆ‰ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค).

1x

2x

x x

y y

Properties of Walrasian Demand

3) Convexity/Uniqueness:

a) If the preferences are convex, then the Walrasian demand correspondence ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)defines a convex set, i.e., a continuum of bundles are utility maximizing.

b) If the preferences are strictly convex, then the Walrasian demand correspondence ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)contains a single element.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 10

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Convex preferences Strictly convex preferences

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 11

2

w

p

1

w

p

Unique x(p,w)

x2

2

w

p

1

w

p

,x x p w

x2

x1 x1

UMP: Necessary Condition

max๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ s. t. ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค

โ€ข We solve it using Kuhn-Tucker conditions over the Lagrangian ๐ฟ = ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ + ๐œ†(๐‘ค โˆ’ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ),

๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โˆ’ ๐œ†๐‘๐‘˜ โ‰ค 0 for all ๐‘˜, = 0 if ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

โˆ— > 0

๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐œ†= ๐‘ค โˆ’ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโˆ— = 0

โ€ข That is, in a interior optimum, ๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜= ๐œ†๐‘๐‘˜ for every

good ๐‘˜, which implies๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

=๐‘๐‘™

๐‘๐‘˜โ‡” ๐‘€๐‘…๐‘† ๐‘™,๐‘˜ =

๐‘๐‘™

๐‘๐‘˜โ‡”

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 12

UMP: Sufficient Condition

โ€ข When are Kuhn-Tucker (necessary) conditions, also sufficient?

โ€“ That is, when can we guarantee that ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is the max of the UMP and not the min?

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 13

UMP: Sufficient Condition

โ€ข Kuhn-Tucker conditions are sufficient for a max if:

1) ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) is quasiconcave, i.e., convex upper contour set (UCS).

2) ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) is monotone.3) ๐›ป๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) โ‰  0 for ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ .โ€“ If ๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ = 0 for some ๐‘ฅ,

then we would be at the โ€œtop of the mountainโ€ (i.e., blissing point), which violates both LNS and monotonicity.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 14

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x * โˆˆ x (p,w)

slope = - p2

p1

Ind. Curve

UMP: Violations of Sufficient Condition

1) ๐’–(โˆ™) is non-monotone:

โ€“ The consumer chooses bundle A (at a corner) since it yields the highest utility level given his budget constraint.

โ€“ At point A, however, the tangency condition

๐‘€๐‘…๐‘† 1,2 =๐‘1

๐‘2does not

hold.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 15

UMP: Violations of Sufficient Condition

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 16

x2

x1

A

B

C

Budget line

โ€“ The upper contour sets (UCS) are not convex.

โ€“ ๐‘€๐‘…๐‘† 1,2 =๐‘1

๐‘2is not a

sufficient condition for a max.

โ€“ A point of tangency (C) gives a lower utility level than a point of non-tangency (B).

โ€“ True maximum is at point A.

2) ๐’–(โˆ™) is not quasiconcave:

UMP: Corner Solution

โ€ข Analyzing differential changes in ๐‘ฅ๐‘™ and ๐‘ฅ๐‘™, that keep individualโ€™s utility unchanged, ๐‘‘๐‘ข = 0,

๐‘‘๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™ +

๐‘‘๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ = 0 (total diff.)

โ€ข Rearranging,

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™= โˆ’

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

= โˆ’๐‘€๐‘…๐‘†๐‘™,๐‘˜

โ€ข Corner Solution: ๐‘€๐‘…๐‘†๐‘™,๐‘˜ >๐‘๐‘™

๐‘๐‘˜, or alternatively,

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅโˆ—

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™>

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅโˆ—

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜, i.e.,

the consumer prefers to consume more of good ๐‘™.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 17

UMP: Corner Solution

โ€ข In the FOCs, this implies:

a)๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โ‰ค ๐œ†๐‘๐‘˜ for the goods whose consumption is

zero, ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โˆ—= 0, and

b)๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™= ๐œ†๐‘๐‘™ for the good whose consumption is

positive, ๐‘ฅ๐‘™โˆ—> 0.

โ€ข Intuition: the marginal utility per dollar spent on good ๐‘™ is still larger than that on good ๐‘˜.

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™= ๐œ† โ‰ฅ

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 18

UMP: Corner Solution

โ€ข Consumer seeks to consume good 1 alone.

โ€ข At the corner solution, the indifference curve is steeper than the budget line, i.e.,

๐‘€๐‘…๐‘†1,2 >๐‘1

๐‘2or

๐‘€๐‘ˆ1

๐‘1>

๐‘€๐‘ˆ2

๐‘2

โ€ข Intuitively, the consumer would like to consume more of good 1, even after spending his entire wealth on good 1 alone.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 19

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

slope of the B.L. = - p2

p1

slope of the I.C. = MRS1,2

UMP: Lagrange Multiplier

โ€ข ๐œ† is referred to as the โ€œmarginal values of relaxing the constraintโ€ in the UMP (a.k.a.โ€œshadow price of wealthโ€).

โ€ข If we provide more wealth to the consumer, he is capable of reaching a higher indifference curve and, as a consequence, obtaining a higher utility level.

โ€“ We want to measure the change in utility resulting from a marginal increase in wealth.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 20

x1

x2

w 0

p2

{x +: u(x) = u 1}2

{x +: u(x) = u 0}2

w 1

p2

w 0

p1

w 1

p1

UMP: Lagrange Multiplier

โ€ข Let us take ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) , and analyze the change in utility from change in wealth. Using the chain rule yields,

๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

โ€ข Substituting ๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) = ๐œ†๐‘ (in interior solutions),

๐œ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 21

UMP: Lagrange Multiplier

โ€ข From Walrasโ€™ Law, ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ค, the change in expenditure from an increase in wealth is given by

๐ท๐‘ค ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = 1

โ€ข Hence, ๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐œ† ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

1

= ๐œ†

โ€ข Intuition: If ๐œ† = 5, then a $1 increase in wealth implies an increase in 5 units of utility.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 22

Walrasian Demand: Wealth Effects

โ€ข Normal vs. Inferior goods

๐œ•๐‘ฅ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค

><

0 normalinferior

โ€ข Examples of inferior goods:

โ€“ Two-buck chuck (a really cheap wine)

โ€“ Walmart during the economic crisis

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 23

Walrasian Demand: Wealth Effects

โ€ข An increase in the wealth level produces an outward shift in the budget line.

โ€ข ๐‘ฅ2 is normal as ๐œ•๐‘ฅ2 ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค> 0, while

๐‘ฅ1 is inferior as ๐œ•๐‘ฅ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค< 0.

โ€ข Wealth expansion path: โ€“ connects the optimal consumption

bundle for different levels of wealth

โ€“ indicates how the consumption of a good changes as a consequence of changes in the wealth level

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 24

Walrasian Demand: Wealth Effects

โ€ข Engel curve depicts the consumption of a particular good in the horizontal axis and wealth on the vertical axis.

โ€ข The slope of the Engel curve is:

โ€“ positive if the good is normal

โ€“ negative if the good is inferior

โ€ข Engel curve can be positively slopped for low wealth levels and become negatively slopped afterwards.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 25

x1

Wealth, w

ลต

Engel curve for a normal good (up to income ลต), but inferior

good for all w > ลต

Engel curve of a normal good, for all w.

Walrasian Demand: Price Effects

โ€ข Own price effect:๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜

<>

0UsualGiffen

โ€ข Cross-price effect:๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘๐‘™

><

0Substitutes

Complements

โ€“ Examples of Substitutes: two brands of mineral water, such as Aquafina vs. Poland Springs.

โ€“ Examples of Complements: cars and gasoline.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 26

Walrasian Demand: Price Effects

โ€ข Own price effect

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 27

Usual good Giffen good

Walrasian Demand: Price Effects

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 28

โ€ข Cross-price effect

Substitutes Complements

Indirect Utility Function

โ€ข The Walrasian demand function, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , is the solution to the UMP (i.e., argmax).

โ€ข What would be the utility function evaluated at the solution of the UMP, i.e., ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ?

โ€“ This is the indirect utility function (i.e., the highest utility level), ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค โˆˆ โ„, associated with the UMP.

โ€“ It is the โ€œvalue functionโ€ of this optimization problem.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 29

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

โ€ข If the utility function is continuous and preferences satisfy LNS over the consumption set ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ , then the indirect utility function ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค satisfies:

1) Homogenous of degree zero: Increasing ๐‘ and ๐‘คby a common factor ๐›ผ > 0 does not modify the consumerโ€™s optimal consumption bundle,๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค), nor his maximal utility level, measured by ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 30

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 31

x1

x2

wp2

ฮฑ wฮฑ p2

=

wp1

ฮฑ wฮฑ p1

=

x (p,w) = x (ฮฑp,ฮฑ w)

v (p,w) = v (ฮฑp,ฮฑ w)

Bp,w = Bฮฑp,ฮฑw

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

2) Strictly increasing in ๐‘ค:

๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) for ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.

3) non-increasing (i.e., weakly decreasing) in ๐‘๐‘˜

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 32

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 33

W

P1

w2

w1

4) Quasiconvex: The set ๐‘, ๐‘ค : ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โ‰ค าง๐‘ฃ is convex for any าง๐‘ฃ.

- Interpretation I: If (๐‘1, ๐‘ค1) โ‰ฟโˆ— (๐‘2, ๐‘ค2), then (๐‘1, ๐‘ค1) โ‰ฟโˆ— (๐œ†๐‘1 +(1 โˆ’ ๐œ†)๐‘2, ๐œ†๐‘ค1 + (1 โˆ’ ๐œ†)๐‘ค2); i.e., if ๐ด โ‰ฟโˆ— ๐ต, then ๐ด โ‰ฟโˆ— ๐ถ.

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

- Interpretation II: ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is quasiconvex if the set of (๐‘, ๐‘ค) pairs for which ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค < ๐‘ฃ(๐‘โˆ—, ๐‘คโˆ—) is convex.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 34

W

P1

w*

p*

v(p,w) < v(p*,w

*)

v(p,w) = v1

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

- Interpretation III: Using ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ2 in the axis, perform following steps:

1) When ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, then ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

2) When ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ, then ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ

3) Both ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ induce an indirect utility of ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ฃ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ = เดค๐‘ข

4) Construct a linear combination of prices and wealth:

เต ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ = ๐›ผ๐‘ + (1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ)๐‘โ€ฒ

๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ = ๐›ผ๐‘ค + (1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ)๐‘คโ€ฒ ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ

5) Any solution to the UMP given ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ must lie on a lower indifference curve (i.e., lower utility)

๐‘ฃ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ โ‰ค เดค๐‘ข

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 35

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 36

x1

x2

Bp,wBpโ€™,wโ€™Bpโ€™โ€™,wโ€™โ€™

x (p,w)

x (pโ€™,wโ€™ )

Ind. Curve {x โˆˆโ„2:u(x) = ลซ}

WARP and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข Relation between Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘คand WARP

โ€“ How does the WARP restrict the set of optimal consumption bundles that the individual decision-maker can select when solving the UMP?

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 37

WARP and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข Take two different consumption bundles ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ , both being affordable ๐‘, ๐‘ค , i.e.,

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‰ค ๐‘ค and ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘ค

โ€ข When prices and wealth are ๐‘, ๐‘ค , the consumer chooses ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค despite ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ is also affordable.

โ€ข Then he โ€œrevealsโ€ a preference for ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค over ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒwhen both are affordable.

โ€ข Hence, we should expect him to choose ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค over ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ when both are affordable. (Consistency)

โ€ข Therefore, bundle ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค must not be affordable at ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ because the consumer chooses ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ . That is,

๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค > ๐‘คโ€ฒ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 38

WARP and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข In summary, Walrasian demand satisfies WARP, if, for two different consumption bundles, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‰  ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ ,

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘ค โ‡’ ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค > ๐‘คโ€ฒ

โ€ข Intuition: if ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ is affordable under budget set ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, then ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค cannot be affordable

under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 39

Checking for WARP

โ€ข A systematic procedure to check if Walrasian demand satisfies WARP:โ€“ Step 1: Check if bundles ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are

both affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค. That is, graphically ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ have to lie on

or below budget line ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

If step 1 is satisfied, then move to step 2.

Otherwise, the premise of WARP does not hold, which does not allow us to continue checking if WARP is violated or not. In this case, we can only say that โ€œWARP is not violatedโ€.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 40

Checking for WARP

- Step 2: Check if bundles ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

That is, graphically ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค must lie on or below budge line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

If step 2 is satisfied, then this Walrasian demand violates WARP.

Otherwise, the Walrasian demand satisfies WARP.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 41

Checking for WARP: Example 1

โ€ข First, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are both affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

โ€ข Second, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is not affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

โ€ข Hence, WARP is satisfied!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 42

x1

x2

w p2

wp1

Bp,w

Bp ,w

x (p,w)

x (p ,w )

Checking for WARP: Example 2

โ€ข The demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒunder final prices and wealth is not affordable under initial prices and wealth, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.โ€“ The premise of WARP

does not hold.

โ€“ Violation of Step 1!

โ€“ WARP is not violated.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 43

Checking for WARP: Example 3

โ€ข The demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒunder final prices and wealth is not affordable under initial prices and wealth, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.โ€“ The premise of WARP

does not hold.

โ€“ Violation of Step 1!

โ€“ WARP is not violated.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 44

Checking for WARP: Example 4

โ€ข The demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒunder final prices and wealth is not affordable under initial prices and wealth, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.โ€“ The premise of WARP

does not hold.

โ€“ Violation of Step 1!

โ€“ WARP is not violated.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 45

Checking for WARP: Example 5

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 46

x1

x2

w p2

wp1

Bp,w

Bp ,w x (p,w)x (p ,w )

โ€ข First, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are both affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

โ€ข Second, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ, i.e., ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค < ๐‘คโ€ฒ

โ€ข Hence, WARP is NOTsatisfied!

Implications of WARP

โ€ข How do price changes affect the WARP predictions?โ€ข Assume a reduction in ๐‘1

โ€“ the consumerโ€™s budget lines rotates (uncompensated price change)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 47

Implications of WARP

โ€ข Adjust the consumerโ€™s wealth level so that he can consume his initial demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค at the new prices.

โ€“ shift the final budget line inwards until the point at which we reach the initial consumption bundle ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค (compensated price change)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 48

Implications of WARP

โ€ข What is the wealth adjustment?๐‘ค = ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค under ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐‘คโ€ฒ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค under ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ

โ€ข Then,โˆ†๐‘ค = โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

where โˆ†๐‘ค = ๐‘คโ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ค and โˆ†๐‘ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘.

โ€ข This is the Slutsky wealth compensation: โ€“ the increase (decrease) in wealth, measured by โˆ†๐‘ค, that we must

provide to the consumer so that he can afford the same consumption bundle as before the price increase (decrease), ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 49

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Suppose that the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค satisfies homog(0) and Walrasโ€™ Law. Then, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค satisfies WARP iff:

โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ โˆ†๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0

whereโ€“ โˆ†๐‘ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ and โˆ†๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

โ€“ ๐‘คโ€ฒ is the wealth level that allows the consumer to buy the initial demand at the new prices, ๐‘คโ€ฒ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

โ€ข This is the Law of Demand: quantity demanded and price move in different directions.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 50

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Does WARP restrict behavior when we apply Slutsky wealth compensations? โ€“ Yes!

โ€ข What if we were not applying the Slutsky wealth compensation, would WARP impose any restriction on allowable locations for ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ ?โ€“ No!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 51

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 52

โ€ข See the discussions on the next slide

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Can ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lie on segment A?1) ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are both affordable under

๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

2) ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ. โ‡’ WARP is violated if ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lies on segment A

โ€ข Can ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lie on segment B?1) ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, but ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ is

not. โ‡’ The premise of WARP does not holdโ‡’ WARP is not violated if ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lies on segment B

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 53

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข What did we learn from this figure?1) We started from ๐›ป๐‘1, and compensated the wealth of

this individual (reducing it from ๐‘ค to ๐‘คโ€ฒ) so that he could afford his initial bundle ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค under the new prices. From this wealth compensation, we obtained budget line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

2) From WARP, we know that ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ must contain more of good 1. That is, graphically, segment B lies to the right-hand side of

๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

3) Then, a price reduction, ๐›ป๐‘1, when followed by an appropriate wealth compensation, leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of this good, โˆ†๐‘ฅ1. This is the compensated law of demand (CLD).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 54

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Practice problem:โ€“ Can you repeat this analysis but for an increase in

the price of good 1? First, pivot budget line ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค inwards to obtain ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘ค.

Then, increase the wealth level (wealth compensation) to obtain ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

Identify the two segments in budget line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ, one to the right-hand side of ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and other to the left.

In which segment of budget line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ can the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ) lie?

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 55

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Is WARP satisfied under the uncompensated law of demand (ULD)?โ€“ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under

budget line ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, but ๐‘ฅ(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ค) is not. Hence, the premise of WARP is

not satisfied. As a result, WARP is not violated.

โ€“ But, is this result implying something about whether ULD must hold? No! Although WARP is not violated,

ULD is: a decrease in the price of good 1 yields a decrease in the quantity demanded.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 56

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Distinction between the uncompensated and the compensated law of demand:โ€“ quantity demanded and price can move in the same

direction, when wealth is left uncompensated, i.e.,

โˆ†๐‘1 โˆ™ โˆ†๐‘ฅ1 > 0as โˆ†๐‘1 โ‡’ โˆ†๐‘ฅ1

โ€ข Hence, WARP is not sufficient to yield law of demand for price changes that are uncompensated, i.e.,

WARP โ‡Ž ULD, butWARP โ‡” CLD

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 57

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Let us focus now on the case in which ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is differentiable.

โ€ข First, note that the law of demand is ๐‘‘๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0(equivalent to โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ โˆ†๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0).

โ€ข Totally differentiating ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ,๐‘‘๐‘ฅ = ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘‘๐‘ + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘‘๐‘ค

โ€ข And since the consumerโ€™s wealth is compensated, ๐‘‘๐‘ค = ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘ (this is the differential analog of โˆ†๐‘ค = โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)).โ€“ Recall that โˆ†๐‘ค = โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) was obtained from the

Slutsky wealth compensation.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 58

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Substituting,

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ = ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘‘๐‘ + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘๐‘‘๐‘ค

or equivalently,

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ = ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)๐‘‡ ๐‘‘๐‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 59

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Hence the law of demand, ๐‘‘๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0, can be expressed as

๐‘‘๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)๐‘‡ ๐‘‘๐‘

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ

โ‰ค 0

where the term in brackets is the Slutsky (or substitution) matrix

๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค =๐‘ 11 ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‹ฏ ๐‘ 1๐ฟ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

โ‹ฎ โ‹ฑ โ‹ฎ๐‘ ๐ฟ1 ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‹ฏ ๐‘ ๐ฟ๐ฟ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

where each element in the matrix is

๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค =๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 60

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Proposition: If ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is differentiable, satisfies Walrasโ€™ law, homog(0), and WARP, then ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘คis negative semi-definite,

๐‘ฃ โˆ™ ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฃ โ‰ค 0 for any ๐‘ฃ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ

โ€ข Implications:โ€“ ๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค : substitution effect of good ๐‘™ with respect to

its own price is non-positive (own-price effect)โ€“ Negative semi-definiteness does not imply that

๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is symmetric (except when ๐ฟ = 2). Usual confusion: โ€œthen ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is not symmetricโ€, NO!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 61

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Proposition: If preferences satisfy LNS and strict convexity, and they are represented with a continuous utility function, then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘คgenerates a Slutsky matrix, ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค , which is symmetric.

โ€ข The above assumptions are really common. โ€“ Hence, the Slutsky matrix will then be symmetric.

โ€ข However, the above assumptions are not satisfied in the case of preferences over perfect substitutes (i.e., preferences are convex, but not strictly convex).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 62

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Non-positive substitution effect, ๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ค 0:

๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘คsubstitution effect (โˆ’)

=๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘™

Total effect:โˆ’ usual good

+ Giffen good

+๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

Income effect:+ normal good

โˆ’ inferior good

โ€ข Substitution Effect = Total Effect + Income Effect

โ‡’ Total Effect = Substitution Effect - Income Effect

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 63

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equation

๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘คsubstitution effect (โˆ’)

=๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘™

Total effect

+๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

Income effect

โ€ข Total Effect: measures how the quantity demanded is affected by a change in the price of good ๐‘™, when we leave the wealth uncompensated.

โ€ข Income Effect: measures the change in the quantity demanded as a result of the wealth adjustment.

โ€ข Substitution Effect: measures how the quantity demanded is affected by a change in the price of good ๐‘™, after the wealth adjustment.โ€“ That is, the substitution effect only captures the change in demand due to variation

in the price ratio, but abstracts from the larger (smaller) purchasing power that the consumer experiences after a decrease (increase, respectively) in prices.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 64

โ€ข Reduction in the price of ๐‘ฅ1. โ€“ It enlarges consumerโ€™s set of feasible

bundles. โ€“ He can reach an indifference curve

further away from the origin.

โ€ข The Walrasian demand curve indicates that a decrease in the price of ๐‘ฅ1 leads to an increase in the quantity demanded.โ€“ This induces a negatively sloped

Walrasian demand curve (so the good is โ€œnormalโ€).

โ€ข The increase in the quantity demanded of ๐‘ฅ1 as a result of a decrease in its price represents the total effect (TE).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 65

Implications of WARP: Slutsky EquationX2

X1

I2

I1

p1

X1

p1

A

B

a

b

โ€ข Reduction in the price of ๐‘ฅ1.โ€“ Disentangle the total effect into the

substitution and income effectsโ€“ Slutsky wealth compensation?

โ€ข Reduce the consumerโ€™s wealth so that he can afford the same consumption bundle as the one before the price change (i.e., A).โ€“ Shift the budget line after the price change

inwards until it โ€œcrossesโ€ through the initial bundle A.

โ€“ โ€œConstant purchasing powerโ€ demand curve (CPP curve) results from applying the Slutsky wealth compensation.

โ€“ The quantity demanded for ๐‘ฅ1 increases from ๐‘ฅ1

0 to ๐‘ฅ13.

โ€ข When we do not hold the consumerโ€™s purchasing power constant, we observe relatively large increase in the quantity demanded for ๐‘ฅ1 (i.e., from ๐‘ฅ1

0 to ๐‘ฅ12 ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 66

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equationx2

x1

I2

I1

p1

x1

p1

I3

CPP demand

A

B

C

a

bc

โ€ข Reduction in the price of ๐‘ฅ1.โ€“ Hicksian wealth compensation (i.e.,

โ€œconstant utilityโ€ demand curve)?

โ€ข The consumerโ€™s wealth level is adjusted so that he can still reach his initial utility level (i.e., the same indifference curve ๐ผ1as before the price change).โ€“ A more significant wealth reduction than

when we apply the Slutsky wealth compensation.

โ€“ The Hicksian demand curve reflects that, for a given decrease in p1, the consumer slightly increases his consumption of good one.

โ€ข In summary, a given decrease in ๐‘1produces: โ€“ A small increase in the Hicksian demand for

the good, i.e., from ๐‘ฅ10 to ๐‘ฅ1

1. โ€“ A larger increase in the CPP demand for the

good, i.e., from ๐‘ฅ10 to ๐‘ฅ1

3. โ€“ A substantial increase in the Walrasian

demand for the product, i.e., from ๐‘ฅ10 to ๐‘ฅ1

2.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 67

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equationx2

x1

I2

I1

p1

x1

p1

I3

CPP demand

Hicksian demand

โ€ข A decrease in price of ๐‘ฅ1 leads the consumer to increase his consumption of this good, โˆ†๐‘ฅ1, but:

โ€“ The โˆ†๐‘ฅ1 which is solely due to the price effect (either measured by the Hicksian demand curve or the CPP demand curve) is smaller than the โˆ†๐‘ฅ1 measured by the Walrasian demand, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , which also captures wealth effects.

โ€“ The wealth compensation (a reduction in the consumerโ€™s wealth in this case) that maintains the original utility level (as required by the Hicksian demand) is larger than the wealth compensation that maintains his purchasing power unaltered (as required by the Slutsky wealth compensation, in the CPP curve).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 68

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equation

Substitution and Income Effects: Normal Goods

โ€ข Decrease in the price of the good in the horizontal axis (i.e., food).

โ€ข The substitution effect (SE) moves in the opposite direction as the price change.

โ€“ A reduction in the price of food implies a positive substitution effect.

โ€ข The income effect (IE) is positive (thus it reinforces the SE).

โ€“ The good is normal.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 69

Clothing

FoodSE IE

TE

A

B

C

I2

I1

BL2

BL1

BLd

Substitution and Income Effects: Inferior Goods

โ€ข Decrease in the price of the good in the horizontal axis (i.e., food).

โ€ข The SE still moves in the opposite direction as the price change.

โ€ข The income effect (IE) is now negative (which partially offsets the increase in the quantity demanded associated with the SE). โ€“ The good is inferior.

โ€ข Note: the SE is larger than the IE.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 70

I2

I1

BL1 BLd

Substitution and Income Effects: Giffen Goods

โ€ข Decrease in the price of the good in the horizontal axis (i.e., food).

โ€ข The SE still moves in the opposite direction as the price change.

โ€ข The income effect (IE) is still negative but now completely offsets the increase in the quantity demanded associated with the SE. โ€“ The good is Giffen good.

โ€ข Note: the SE is less than the IE.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 71

I2

I1BL1

BL2

Substitution and Income Effects

SE IE TE

Normal Good + + +Inferior Good + - +Giffen Good + - -

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 72

โ€ข Not Giffen: Demand curve is negatively sloped (as usual)โ€ข Giffen: Demand curve is positively sloped

Substitution and Income Effects

โ€ข Summary:1) SE is negative (since โ†“ ๐‘1 โ‡’ โ†‘ ๐‘ฅ1)

SE < 0 does not imply โ†“ ๐‘ฅ1

2) If good is inferior, IE < 0. Then,

TE = เธ“SEโˆ’ เธ•

โˆ’ เธ“IEโˆ’

+

โ‡’ if IE><

SE , then TE(โˆ’)TE(+)

For a price decrease, this impliesTE(โˆ’)TE(+)

โ‡’โ†“ ๐‘ฅ1

โ†‘ ๐‘ฅ1

Giffen goodNonโˆ’Giffen good

3) Hence,a) A good can be inferior, but not necessarily be Giffenb) But all Giffen goods must be inferior.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 73

Expenditure Minimization Problem

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 74

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข Expenditure minimization problem (EMP):

min๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ

s.t. ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ข

โ€ข Alternative to utility maximization problem

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 75

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข Consumer seeks a utility level associated with a particular indifference curve, while spending as little as possible.

โ€ข Bundles strictly above ๐‘ฅโˆ— cannot be a solution to the EMP:โ€“ They reach the utility level ๐‘ขโ€“ But, they do not minimize total

expenditure

โ€ข Bundles on the budget line strictly below ๐‘ฅโˆ— cannot be the solution to the EMP problem:โ€“ They are cheaper than ๐‘ฅโˆ—

โ€“ But, they do not reach the utility level ๐‘ข

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 76

X2

X1

*x

*UCS( )x

u

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข Lagrangian๐ฟ = ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ + ๐œ‡ ๐‘ข โˆ’ ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

โ€ข FOCs (necessary conditions)๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜= ๐‘๐‘˜ โˆ’ ๐œ‡

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โ‰ค 0

๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐œ‡= ๐‘ข โˆ’ ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅโˆ— = 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 77

[ = 0 for interior solutions ]

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข For interior solutions,

๐‘๐‘˜ = ๐œ‡๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜or

1

๐œ‡=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜

for any good ๐‘˜. This implies, ๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™or

๐‘๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘™=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

โ€ข The consumer allocates his consumption across goods until the point in which the marginal utility per dollar spent on each good is equal across all goods (i.e., same โ€œbang for the buckโ€).

โ€ข That is, the slope of indifference curve is equal to the slope of the budget line.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 78

EMP: Hicksian Demand

โ€ข The bundle ๐‘ฅโˆ— โˆˆ argmin ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ (the argument that solves the EMP) is the Hicksian demand, which depends on ๐‘ and ๐‘ข,

๐‘ฅโˆ— โˆˆ โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

โ€ข Recall that if such bundle ๐‘ฅโˆ— is unique, we denote it as ๐‘ฅโˆ— = โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 79

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Suppose that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, satisfying LNS defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . Then for ๐‘ โ‰ซ0, โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) satisfies:1) Homog(0) in ๐‘, i.e., โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = โ„Ž(๐›ผ๐‘, ๐‘ข) for any ๐‘, ๐‘ข,

and ๐›ผ > 0. If ๐‘ฅโˆ— โˆˆ โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is a solution to the problem

min๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ

then it is also a solution to the problemmin๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐›ผ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ

Intuition: a common change in all prices does not alter the slope of the consumerโ€™s budget line.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 80

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข ๐‘ฅโˆ— is a solution to the EMP when the price vector is ๐‘ = (๐‘1, ๐‘2).

โ€ข Increase all prices by factor ๐›ผ

๐‘โ€ฒ = (๐‘1โ€ฒ , ๐‘2

โ€ฒ ) = (๐›ผ๐‘1, ๐›ผ๐‘2)

โ€ข Downward (parallel) shift in the budget line, i.e., the slope of the budget line is unchanged.

โ€ข But I have to reach utility level ๐‘ข to satisfy the constraint of the EMP!

โ€ข Spend more to buy bundle ๐‘ฅโˆ—(๐‘ฅ1

โˆ—, ๐‘ฅ2โˆ—), i.e.,

๐‘1โ€ฒ ๐‘ฅ1

โˆ— + ๐‘2โ€ฒ ๐‘ฅ2

โˆ— > ๐‘1๐‘ฅ1โˆ— + ๐‘2๐‘ฅ2

โˆ—

โ€ข Hence, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = โ„Ž(๐›ผ๐‘, ๐‘ข)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 81

x2

x1

Properties of Hicksian Demand

2) No excess utility:

for any optimal consumption bundle ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข , utility level satisfies ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ข.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 82

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x โ€™

x โˆˆ h (p,u)

uu 1

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Intuition: Suppose there exists a bundle ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข for which the consumer obtains a utility level ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ข1 > ๐‘ข, which is higher than the utility level ๐‘ข he must reach when solving EMP.

โ€ข But we can then find another bundle ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘ฅ๐›ผ, where ๐›ผ โˆˆ (0,1), very close to ๐‘ฅ (๐›ผ โ†’ 1), for which ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโ€ฒ) > ๐‘ข.

โ€ข Bundle ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ:โ€“ is cheaper than ๐‘ฅ since it contains fewer units of all goods; andโ€“ exceeds the minimal utility level ๐‘ข that the consumer must reach in his

EMP.

โ€ข We can repeat that argument until reaching bundle ๐‘ฅ.

โ€ข In summary, for a given utility level ๐‘ข that you seek to reach in the EMP, bundle โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข does not exceed ๐‘ข. Otherwise you can find a cheaper bundle that exactly reaches ๐‘ข.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 83

Properties of Hicksian Demand

3) Convexity:

If the preference relation is convex, then โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข is a convex set.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 84

Properties of Hicksian Demand

4) Uniqueness:

If the preference relation is strictly convex, then โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ขcontains a single element.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 85

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Compensated Law of Demand: for any change in prices ๐‘ and ๐‘โ€ฒ,

(๐‘โ€ฒโˆ’๐‘) โˆ™ โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โˆ’ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข โ‰ค 0โ€“ Implication: for every good ๐‘˜,

(๐‘๐‘˜โ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘˜) โˆ™ โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โˆ’ โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข โ‰ค 0

โ€“ This is true for compensated demand, but not necessarily true for Walrasian demand (which is uncompensated):โ€ข Recall the figures on Giffen goods, where a decrease in

๐‘๐‘˜ in fact decreases ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข when wealth was left uncompensated.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 86

The Expenditure Function

โ€ข Plugging the result from the EMP, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข , into the objective function, ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ, we obtain the value function of this optimization problem,

๐‘ โˆ™ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

where ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) represents the minimal expenditure that the consumer needs to incur in order to reach utility level ๐‘ข when prices are ๐‘.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 87

Properties of Expenditure Function

โ€ข Suppose that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, satisfying LNS defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . Then for ๐‘ โ‰ซ 0, ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)satisfies:

1) Homog(1) in ๐‘,

๐‘’ ๐›ผ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐›ผ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโˆ—

๐‘’(๐‘,๐‘ข)

= ๐›ผ โˆ™ ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

for any ๐‘, ๐‘ข, and ๐›ผ > 0.

We know that the optimal bundle is not changed when all prices change, since the optimal consumption bundle in โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) satisfies homogeneity of degree zero.

Such a price change just makes it more or less expensive to buy the same bundle.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 88

Properties of Expenditure Function

2) Strictly increasing in ๐’–: For a given price vector, reaching a higher utility requires higher expenditure:

๐‘1๐‘ฅ1โ€ฒ + ๐‘2๐‘ฅ2

โ€ฒ > ๐‘1๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘2๐‘ฅ2

where (๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ2) = โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)and (๐‘ฅ1

โ€ฒ , ๐‘ฅ2โ€ฒ ) = โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ขโ€ฒ).

Then,๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ขโ€ฒ > ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 89

x2

x1

x2

x1

Properties of Expenditure Function

3) Non-decreasing in ๐’‘๐’Œ for every good ๐’Œ:Higher prices mean higher expenditure to reach a given utility level. โ€ข Let ๐‘โ€ฒ = (๐‘1, ๐‘2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐‘˜

โ€ฒ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐ฟ) and ๐‘ =(๐‘1, ๐‘2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐‘˜, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐ฟ), where ๐‘๐‘˜

โ€ฒ > ๐‘๐‘˜.โ€ข Let ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข and ๐‘ฅ = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข from EMP under

prices ๐‘โ€ฒ and ๐‘, respectively.โ€ข Then, ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข) and ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข).

๐‘’ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

โ€“ 1st inequality due to ๐‘โ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘โ€“ 2nd inequality: at prices ๐‘, bundle ๐‘ฅ minimizes EMP.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 90

Properties of Expenditure Function

4) Concave in ๐’‘:

Let ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โ‡’ ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโˆ€๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ, e.g., ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅand ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โ‡’ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโˆ€๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ, e.g., ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅwhere าง๐‘ฅ = ๐›ผ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ

This implies๐›ผ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐›ผ๐‘โ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅ

๐›ผ เธ‘๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ

๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘ข)

+ 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ

๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ,๐‘ข)

โ‰ค [๐›ผ๐‘โ€ฒ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ

าง๐‘

] าง๐‘ฅ

๐›ผ๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข) + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ, ๐‘ข) โ‰ค ๐‘’( าง๐‘, ๐‘ข)

as required by concavity

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 91

x2

x11/ 'w p

2/w p

2/ 'w p

2/ ''w p

xโ€™โ€™

xโ€™

x

u

1/w p1/ ''w p

Connections

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 92

Relationship between the Expenditure and Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Letโ€™s assume that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, representing preferences that satisfy LNS and are strictly convex and defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . For all ๐‘ and ๐‘ข,

๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘,๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข for every good ๐‘˜

This identity is โ€œShepardโ€™s lemmaโ€: if we want to find โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข and we know ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข , we just have to differentiate ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข with respect to prices.

โ€ข Proof: three different approaches1) the support function2) first-order conditions 3) the envelope theorem (See Appendix 2.2)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 93

Relationship between the Expenditure and Hicksian Demand

โ€ข The relationship between the Hicksian demand and the expenditure function can be further developed by taking first order conditions again. That is,

๐œ•2๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜2 =

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜

or๐ท๐‘

2๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

โ€ข Since ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) provides the Slutsky matrix, ๐‘†(๐‘, ๐‘ค), then

๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐ท๐‘2๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

where the Slutsky matrix can be obtained from the observable Walrasian demand.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 94

Relationship between the Expenditure and Hicksian Demand

โ€ข There are three other important properties of ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข), where ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is ๐ฟ ร— ๐ฟ derivative matrix of the hicksian demand, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข :1) ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is negative semidefinite

Hence, ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is negative semidefinite.

2) ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is a symmetric matrix Hence, ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is symmetric.

3) ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข ๐‘ = 0, which implies ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ = 0.

Not all goods can be net substitutes ๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™(๐‘,๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜> 0 or net

complements ๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™(๐‘,๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜< 0 . Otherwise, the multiplication

of this vector of derivatives times the (positive) price vector ๐‘ โ‰ซ 0 would yield a non-zero result.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 95

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข When income effects are positive (normal goods), then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is above the Hicksian demand โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) .โ€“ The Hicksian demand

is steeper than the Walrasian demand.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 96

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x1

p1

wp1

p1

p1

x*1 x1

1 x21

h (p,ลซ)

x (p,w)

p1

I1

I3

I2x1

x 3x 2

x*

SE IE

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข When income effects are negative (inferior goods), then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is below the Hicksian demand โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) .โ€“ The Hicksian demand

is flatter than the Walrasian demand.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 97

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x1

p1

wp1

p1

p1

x*1 x1

1x21

h (p,ลซ)

x (p,w)

p1

I1

I2

x1

x 2x*

SE

IE

a

bc

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข We can formally relate the Hicksian and Walrasian demand as follows:โ€“ Consider ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, representing

preferences that satisfy LNS and are strictly convex and defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ .โ€“ Consider a consumer facing ( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค) and attaining utility

level เดค๐‘ข.โ€“ Note that เดฅ๐‘ค = ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข). In addition, we know that for any

(๐‘, ๐‘ข), โ„Ž๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข๐‘ค

). Differentiating this

expression with respect to ๐‘๐‘˜, and evaluating it at ( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข), we get:

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜Advanced Microeconomic Theory 98

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข Using the fact that ๐œ•๐‘’( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข),

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘,๐‘’( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘,๐‘’( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘คโ„Ž๐‘˜( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข)

โ€ข Finally, since เดฅ๐‘ค = ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข) and โ„Ž๐‘˜ าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข =

๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ าง๐‘, ๐‘’ าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข = ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค , then

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘˜( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 99

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข But this coincides with ๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค that we discussed in the Slutsky equation.

โ€“ Hence, we have ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข

๐ฟร—๐ฟ

= ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

โ€“ Or, more compactly, ๐‘†๐ธ = ๐‘‡๐ธ + ๐ผ๐ธ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 100

Relationship between Walrasian Demand and Indirect Utility Function

โ€ข Letโ€™s assume that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, representing preferences that satisfy LNS and are strictly convex and defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . Suppose also that ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is differentiable at any (๐‘, ๐‘ค) โ‰ซ 0. Then,

โˆ’

๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค

= ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค) for every good ๐‘˜

โ€ข This is Royโ€™s identity.

โ€ข Powerful result, since in many cases it is easier to compute the derivatives of ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค than solving the UMP with the system of FOCs.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 101

Summary of Relationships

โ€ข The Walrasian demand, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , is the solution of the UMP.โ€“ Its value function is the indirect utility function,

๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

โ€ข The Hicksian demand, โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข), is the solution of the EMP. โ€“ Its value function is the expenditure function,

๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 102

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 103

x(p,w)

v(p,w) e(p,u)

h(p,u)

The UMP The EMP

(1) (1)

Summary of Relationships

โ€ข Relationship between the value functions of the UMP and the EMP (lower part of figure):

โ€“ ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ค, i.e., the minimal expenditure

needed in order to reach a utility level equal to the maximal utility that the individual reaches at his UMP, ๐‘ข = ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , must be ๐‘ค.

โ€“ ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) = ๐‘ข, i.e., the indirect utility that can be reached when the consumer is endowed with a wealth level w equal to the minimal expenditure he optimally uses in the EMP, i.e., ๐‘ค = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข), is exactly ๐‘ข.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 104

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 105

x(p,w)

v(p,w) e(p,u)

h(p,u)

The UMP The EMP

e(p, v(p,w))=w

v(p, e(p,w))=u

(1) (1)

(2)

Summary of Relationships

โ€ข Relationship between the argmax of the UMP (the Walrasian demand) and the argmin of the EMP (the Hicksian demand):โ€“ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข , i.e., the (uncompensated)

Walrasian demand of a consumer endowed with an adjusted wealth level ๐‘ค (equal to the expenditure he optimally uses in the EMP), ๐‘ค = ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข , coincides with his Hicksian demand, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข .

โ€“ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) = ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , i.e., the (compensated) Hicksian demand of a consumer reaching the maximum utility of the UMP, ๐‘ข = ๐‘ฃ (๐‘, ๐‘ค), coincides with his Walrasian demand, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 106

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 107

x(p,w)

v(p,w) e(p,u)

h(p,u)

The UMP The EMP

e(p, v(p,w))=w

v(p, e(p,w))=u

(1) (1)

(2)

3(a) 3(b)

Summary of Relationships

โ€ข Finally, we can also use:โ€“ The Slutsky equation:

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

to relate the derivatives of the Hicksian and the Walrasian demand.โ€“ Shepardโ€™s lemma:

๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

to obtain the Hicksian demand from the expenditure function.โ€“ Royโ€™s identity:

โˆ’

๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜

๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค๐œ•๐‘ค

= ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

to obtain the Walrasian demand from the indirect utility function.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 108

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 109

x(p,w)

v(p,w) e(p,u)

h(p,u)

The UMP The EMP

e(p, v(p,w))=w

v(p, e(p,w))=u

(1) (1)

(2)

3(a) 3(b)

4(a) Slutsky equation

(Using derivatives)

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 110

x(p,w)

v(p,w) e(p,u)

h(p,u)

The UMP The EMP

e(p, v(p,w))=w

v(p, e(p,w))=u

(1) (1)

(2)

3(a) 3(b)

4(a) Slutsky equation

(Using derivatives)

4(b) Royโ€™s

Identity 4(c)

Appendix 2.1: Duality in Consumption

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 111

Duality in Consumption

โ€ข We discussed the utility maximization problem (UMP) โ€“ the so-called primal problem describing the consumerโ€™s choice of optimal consumption bundles โ€“ and its dual: the expenditure minimization problem (EMP).

โ€ข When can we guarantee that the solution ๐‘ฅโˆ— to both problems coincide?

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 112

Duality in Consumption

โ€ข The maximal distance that a turtle can travel in ๐‘กโˆ— time is ๐‘ฅโˆ—.โ€“ From time (๐‘กโˆ—) to distance

(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

โ€ข The minimal time that a turtle needs to travel ๐‘ฅโˆ— distance is ๐‘กโˆ—.โ€“ From distance (๐‘ฅโˆ—) to time

(๐‘กโˆ—)

โ€ข In this case the primal and dual problems would provide us with the same answer to both of the above questions

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 113

Duality in Consumption

โ€ข In order to obtain the same answer from both questions, we critically need that the function ๐‘€(๐‘ก)satisfies monotonicity.

โ€ข Otherwise: the maximal distance traveled at both ๐‘ก1and ๐‘ก2 is ๐‘ฅโˆ—, but the minimal time that a turtle needs to travel ๐‘ฅโˆ— distance is ๐‘ก1.

โ€ข Hence, a non-monotonic function cannot guarantee that the answers from both questions are compatible.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 114

Duality in Consumption

โ€ข Similarly, we also require that the function ๐‘€(๐‘ก)satisfies continuity.

โ€ข Otherwise: the maximal distance that the turtle can travel in time ๐‘กโˆ— is ๐‘ฅ2 , whereas the minimum time required to travel distance ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ2 is ๐‘กโˆ— for both distances.

โ€ข Hence, a non-continuous function does not guarantee that the answers to both questions are compatible.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 115

Distance

Time, t

M(t)

x2

t*

Jumping turtlex1

Duality in Consumption

โ€ข Given ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is monotonic and continuous, then if ๐‘ฅโˆ— is the solution to the problem

max๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) s.t. ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค (UMP)

it must also be a solution to the problem

min๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ s.t. ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ข (EMP)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 116

Hyperplane Theorem

โ€ข Hyperplane: for some ๐‘ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ and ๐‘ โˆˆ โ„, the set of points in โ„๐ฟ

such that๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ: ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘

โ€ข Half-space: the set of bundles ๐‘ฅ for which ๐‘ โˆ™๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘. That is,

๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ: ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 117

Half-space

Hyper plane

Hyperplane Theorem

โ€ข Separating hyperplane theorem: For every convex and closed set ๐พ, there is a half-space containing ๐พ and excluding any point าง๐‘ฅ โˆ‰ ๐พoutside of this set. โ€“ That is, there exist ๐‘ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ and ๐‘ โˆˆ โ„ such that๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ for all elements in the set, ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐พ๐‘ โˆ™ าง๐‘ฅ < ๐‘ for all elements outside the set, าง๐‘ฅ โˆ‰ ๐พ

โ€“ Intuition: every convex and closed set ๐พ can be equivalently described as the intersection of the half-spaces that contain it. As we draw more and more half spaces, their intersection

becomes the set ๐พ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 118

Hyperplane Theorem

โ€ข If ๐พ is a closed and convex set, we can then construct half-spaces for all the elements in the set (๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ2, โ€ฆ ) such that their intersections coincides (โ€œequivalently describesโ€) set ๐พ.โ€“ We construct a cage (or

hull) around the convex set ๐พ that exactly coincides with set ๐พ.

โ€ข Bundle like าง๐‘ฅ โˆ‰ ๐พ lies outside the intersection of half-spaces.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 119

K

x

Hyperplane Theorem

โ€ข What if the set we are trying to โ€œequivalently describeโ€ by the use of half-spaces is non-convex?โ€“ The intersection of half-spaces does not coincide

with set ๐พ (it is, in fact, larger, since it includes points outside set ๐พ). Hence, we cannot use several half-spaces to โ€œequivalently describeโ€ set ๐พ.

โ€“ Then the intersection of half-spaces that contain ๐พ is the smallest, convex set that contains ๐พ, known as the closed, convex hull of ๐พ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 120

Hyperplane Theorem

โ€ข The convex hull of set ๐พ is often denoted as เดฅ๐พ, and it is convex (unlike set ๐พ, which might not be convex).

โ€ข The convex hull เดฅ๐พ is convex, both when set K is convex and when it is not.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 121

K

Shaded area is the convex hull

of set K

Support Function

โ€ข For every nonempty closed set ๐พ โŠ‚ โ„๐ฟ, its support function is defined by

๐œ‡๐พ ๐‘ = inf๐‘ฅ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ for all ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐พ and ๐‘ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ

that is, the support function finds, for a given price vector ๐‘, the bundle ๐‘ฅ that minimizes ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ.โ€“ Recall that inf coincides with the argmin when the

constraint includes the boundary.

โ€ข From the support function of ๐พ, we can reconstruct ๐พ.โ€“ In particular, for every ๐‘ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ , we can define half-spaces

whose boundary is the support function of set ๐พ. That is, we define the set of bundles for which ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐œ‡๐พ ๐‘ . Note

that all bundles ๐‘ฅ in such half-space contains elements in the set ๐พ, but does not contain elements outside ๐พ, i.e., าง๐‘ฅ โˆ‰ ๐พ .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 122

Support Function

โ€ข Thus, the intersection of the half-spaces generated by all possible values of ๐‘ describes (โ€œreconstructsโ€) the set ๐พ. That is, set ๐พ can be described by all those bundles ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ such that

๐พ = ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ : ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐œ‡๐พ ๐‘ for every ๐‘

โ€ข By the same logic, if ๐พ is not convex, then the set

๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ : ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐œ‡๐พ ๐‘ for every ๐‘

defines the smallest closed, convex set containing ๐พ(i.e., the convex hull of set ๐พ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 123

Support Function

โ€ข For a given ๐‘, the support ๐œ‡๐พ ๐‘ selects the element in ๐พ that minimizes ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ (i.e., ๐‘ฅ1 in this example).

โ€ข Then, we can define the half-space of that hyperlane as:

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ1

๐œ‡๐พ ๐‘

โ€“ The above inequality identifies all bundles ๐‘ฅ to the left of hyperplane ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ1.

โ€ข We can repeat the same procedure for any other price vector ๐‘.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 124

Support Function

โ€ข The above definition of the support function provides us with a useful duality theorem:โ€“ Let ๐พ be a nonempty, closed set, and let ๐œ‡๐พ โˆ™ be its

support function. Then there is a unique element in ๐พ, าง๐‘ฅ โˆˆ๐พ, such that, for all price vector าง๐‘,

าง๐‘ โˆ™ าง๐‘ฅ = ๐œ‡๐พ าง๐‘ โ‡” ๐œ‡๐พ โˆ™ is differentiable at าง๐‘

๐‘ โˆ™ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) โ‡” ๐‘’(โˆ™, ๐‘ข) is differentiable at ๐‘

โ€“ Moreover, in this case, such derivative is๐œ•( าง๐‘ โˆ™ าง๐‘ฅ)

๐œ•๐‘= าง๐‘ฅ

or in matrix notation

๐›ป๐œ‡๐พ าง๐‘ = าง๐‘ฅ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 125

Appendix 2.2:Relationship between the

Expenditure Function and Hicksian Demand

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 126

Proof I (Using Duality Theorem)

โ€ข The expenditure function is the support function for the set of all bundles in โ„+

๐ฟ for which utility reaches at least a level of ๐‘ข. That is,

๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+๐ฟ : ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ข

Using the Duality theorem, we can then state that there is a unique bundle in this set, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข , such that

๐‘ โˆ™ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

where the right-hand side is the support function of this problem.

โ€ข Moreover, from the duality theorem, the derivative of the support function coincides with this unique bundle, i.e.,

๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘,๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข for every good ๐‘˜

or๐›ป๐‘๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 127

Proof I (Using Duality Theorem)

โ€ข UCS is a convex and closed set.

โ€ข Hyperplane ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโˆ— =๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข provides us with the minimal expenditure that still reaches utility level ๐‘ข.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 128

Proof II (Using First Order Conditions)

โ€ข Totally differentiating the expenditure function ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข ,

๐›ป๐‘๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐›ป๐‘ ๐‘ โˆ™ โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข + ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)๐‘‡

โ€ข And, from the FOCs in interior solutions of the EMP, we know that ๐‘ = ๐œ†๐›ป๐‘ข(โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข ). Substituting,

๐›ป๐‘๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข + ๐œ†[๐›ป๐‘ข(โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข ) โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)]๐‘‡

โ€ข But, since ๐›ป๐‘ข โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐‘ข for all solutions of the EMP, then ๐›ป๐‘ข โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = 0, which implies

๐›ป๐‘๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข

That is, ๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘,๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข for every good ๐‘˜.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 129

Proof III (Using the Envelope Theorem)

โ€ข Using the envelope theorem in the expenditure function, we obtain

๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ• ๐‘ โˆ™ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข + ๐‘

๐œ•โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜

โ€ข And, since the Hicksian demand is already at the optimum, indirect effects are negligible,

๐œ•โ„Ž ๐‘,๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= 0,

implying๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘,๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 130

Appendix 2.3:Generalized Axiom of Revealed

Preference (GARP)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 131

GARP

โ€ข Consider a sequence of prices ๐‘๐‘ก where ๐‘ก =1,2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘‡ with an associated sequence of chosen bundles ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก.

โ€ข GARP: If bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก is revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก+1

for all ๐‘ก = 1,2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘‡, i.e., ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ2, ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ฟ๐‘ฅ3, โ€ฆ , ๐‘ฅ๐‘‡โˆ’1 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ๐‘‡, then ๐‘ฅ๐‘‡ is not strictly revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ1, i.e., ๐‘ฅ๐‘‡ โŠ ๐‘ฅ1.

โ€“ More general axiom of revealed preferenceโ€“ Neither GARP nor WARP implies one anotherโ€“ Some choices satisfy GARP, some WARP, choices for

which both axioms hold, and some for which none do.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 132

GARP

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 133

โ€ข Choices satisfying GARP, WARP, both, or none

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.1 (GARP holds, but WARP does not):โ€“ Consider the following sequence of price vectors

and their corresponding demanded bundles

๐‘1 = (1,1,2) ๐‘ฅ1 = (1,0,0)

๐‘2 = (1,2,1) ๐‘ฅ2 = (0,1,0)

๐‘3 = (1,3,1) ๐‘ฅ3 = (0,0,2)

โ€“ The change from ๐‘ก = 1 to ๐‘ก = 2 violates WARP, but not GARP.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 134

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.1 (continued):โ€“ Let us compare bundles ๐‘ฅ1 with ๐‘ฅ2.

โ€“ For the premise of WARP to hold: Since bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ2 in ๐‘ก = 1,

i.e., ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ2, it must be that ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ค ๐‘ค1 = ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1.

That is, bundle ๐‘ฅ2 is affordable under bundle ๐‘ฅ1โ€™s prices.

โ€“ Substituting our values, we find that1 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 1 + 2 ร— 0 = 1 โ‰ค 1

= 1 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 0

โ€“ Hence, the premise of WARP holds.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 135

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.1 (continued):โ€“ For WARP to be satisfied:

We must also have that ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 > ๐‘ค2 = ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2.

That is, bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is unaffordable under the new prices and wealth.

โ€“ Plugging our values yields

๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 = 1 ร— 1 + 2 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 0 = 1

๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2 = ๐‘ค2 = 1 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 = 2

โ€“ That is, ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 < ๐‘ค2, i.e., bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is still affordable under period twoโ€™s prices.

โ€“ Thus WARP is violated.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 136

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.1 (continued):

โ€“ Let us check GARP.

โ€“ Assume that bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ2, ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ2, and that ๐‘ฅ2 is revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ3, ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ3.

โ€“ It is easy to show that ๐‘ฅ3 โŠ ๐‘ฅ1 as bundle ๐‘ฅ3 is not affordable under bundle ๐‘ฅ1โ€™s prices.

โ€“ Hence, ๐‘ฅ3 cannot be revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ1,

โ€“ Thus, GARP is not violated.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 137

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.2 (WARP holds, GARP does not):

โ€“ Consider the following sequence of price vectors and their corresponding demanded bundles

๐‘1 = (1,1,2) ๐‘ฅ1 = (1,0,0)

๐‘2 = (2,1,1) ๐‘ฅ2 = (0,1,0)

๐‘3 = (1,2,1 + ๐œ€) ๐‘ฅ3 = (0,0,1)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 138

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.2 (continued):

โ€“ For the premise of WARP to hold:

Since bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ2 in ๐‘ก = 1, i.e., ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ2, it must be that ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ค ๐‘ค1 = ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1.

That is, bundle ๐‘ฅ2 is affordable under bundle ๐‘ฅ1โ€™s prices.

โ€“ Substituting our values, we find that1 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 1 + 2 ร— 0 = 1 โ‰ค 1

= 1 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 0

โ€“ Hence, the premise of WARP holds.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 139

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.2 (continued):

โ€“ For WARP to be satisfied:

We must also have that ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 > ๐‘ค2 = ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2.

That is, bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is unaffordable under the new prices and wealth.

โ€“ Plugging our values yields

2 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 0 = 2 > 1= 2 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0

โ€“ Thus, WARP is satisfied.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 140

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.2 (continued):

โ€“ A similar argument applies to the comparison of the choices in ๐‘ก = 2 and ๐‘ก = 3.

โ€“ Bundle ๐‘ฅ3 is affordable under the prices at ๐‘ก = 2,๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3 = 1 โ‰ค 1 = ๐‘ค2 = ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2

โ€“ But ๐‘ฅ2 is unaffordable under the prices of ๐‘ก = 3, i.e., ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2 > ๐‘ค3 = ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3, since

1 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 1 + 1 + ๐œ€ ร— 0 = 2 >1 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 0 + 1 + ๐œ€ ร— 1 = 1 + ๐œ€

โ€“ Hence, WARP also holds in this case.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 141

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.2 (continued):

โ€“ Furthermore, bundle ๐‘ฅ3 is unaffordable under bundle ๐‘ฅ1โ€™s prices, i.e., ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3 โ‰ฐ ๐‘ค1 = ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1,

๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3 = 1 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 1 = 2๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 = 1 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 0 = 1

โ€“ Thus, the premise for WARP does not hold when comparing bundles ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ3.

โ€“ Hence, WARP is not violated.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 142

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.2 (continued):โ€“ Let us check GARP.

โ€“ Assume that bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ2, and that ๐‘ฅ2 is revealed preferred to ๐‘ฅ3, i.e., ๐‘ฅ1 โ‰ฟ๐‘ฅ2 and ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ3.

โ€“ Comparing bundles ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ3, we can see that bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is affordable under bundle ๐‘ฅ3โ€™s prices, that is

๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 = 1 ร— 1 + 2 ร— 0 + 1 + ๐œ€ ร— 0 = 1โ‰ฏ 1 + ๐œ€ = ๐‘ค3 = ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 143

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.2 (continued):

โ€“ In other words, both ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ3 are affordable at ๐‘ก = 3 but only ๐‘ฅ3 is chosen.

โ€“ Then, the consumer is revealing a preference for ๐‘ฅ3 over ๐‘ฅ1, i.e., ๐‘ฅ3 โ‰ฟ ๐‘ฅ1.

โ€“ This violates GARP.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 144

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.3 (Both WARP and GARP hold):

โ€“ Consider the following sequence of price vectors and their corresponding demanded bundles

๐‘1 = (1,1,2) ๐‘ฅ1 = (1,0,0)

๐‘2 = (1,2,1) ๐‘ฅ2 = (0,1,0)

๐‘3 = (3,2,1) ๐‘ฅ3 = (0,0,1)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 145

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.3 (continued):โ€“ Let us check WARP.

โ€“ Note that bundle ๐‘ฅ2 is affordable under the prices at ๐‘ก = 1, i.e., ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2 โ‰ค ๐‘ค1 = ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1, since

1 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 = 1 โ‰ค 1= 1 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 0

โ€“ However, bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is unaffordable under the prices at ๐‘ก = 2, i.e., ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 > ๐‘ค2 = ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2, since

2 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 0 = 2 > 1= 2 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0

โ€“ Thus WARP is satisfied.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 146

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.3 (continued):โ€“ A similar argument applies to the comparison of

the choices in ๐‘ก = 2 and ๐‘ก = 3.

โ€“ Bundle ๐‘ฅ3 is affordable under the prices at ๐‘ก = 2, ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3 = 1 โ‰ค 1 = ๐‘ค2 = ๐‘2 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2

โ€“ But ๐‘ฅ2 is unaffordable under the prices of ๐‘ก = 3, i.e., ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ2 > ๐‘ค3 = ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3, since

3 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 1 + 1 ร— 0 = 2 >3 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 1 = 1 + ๐œ€

โ€“ Thus, WARP also holds in this case.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 147

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.3 (continued):โ€“ A similar argument applies to the comparison of

the choices in ๐‘ก = 1 and ๐‘ก = 3.

โ€“ Bundle ๐‘ฅ3 is affordable under the prices at ๐‘ก = 1, i.e., ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3 โ‰ค ๐‘ค1 = ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1, since

๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3 = 1 โ‰ค 1 = ๐‘ค2 = ๐‘1 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1

โ€“ But bundle ๐‘ฅ1 is unaffordable under the prices of ๐‘ก = 3, i.e., ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 > ๐‘ค3 = ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3, since

๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 = 3 ร— 1 + 2 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 0 = 3๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3 = 3 ร— 0 + 2 ร— 0 + 1 ร— 1 = 1

โ€“ Hence, WARP is also satisfiedAdvanced Microeconomic Theory 148

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.3 (continued):

โ€“ Let us check GARP.

โ€“ We showed above that ๐‘ฅ1 is unaffordable under bundle ๐‘ฅ3โ€™s prices, i.e., ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ1 > ๐‘ค3 = ๐‘3 โ‹… ๐‘ฅ3.

โ€“ We cannot establish bundle ๐‘ฅ3 being strictly preferred to bundle ๐‘ฅ1, i.e., ๐‘ฅ3 โŠ ๐‘ฅ1.

โ€“ Hence, GARP is satisfied.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 149

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.4 (Neither WARP nor GARP hold):

โ€“ Consider the following sequence of price vectors and their corresponding demanded bundles

๐‘1 = (1,1,1) ๐‘ฅ1 = (1,0,0)

๐‘2 = (2,1,1) ๐‘ฅ2 = (0,1,0)

๐‘3 = (1,2,1 + ๐œ€) ๐‘ฅ3 = (0,0,1)

โ€“ This is actually a combination of the first two examples.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 150

GARP

โ€ข Example A2.4 (continued):

โ€“ At ๐‘ก = 1, WARP will be violated by the same method as in our first example.

โ€“ At ๐‘ก = 3, GARP will be violated by the same method as in our second example.

โ€“ Hence, neither WARP nor GARP hold in this case.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 151

GARP

โ€ข GARP constitutes a sufficient condition for utility maximization.

โ€ข That is, if the sequence of price-bundle pairs (๐‘๐‘ก , ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก) satisfies GARP, then it must originate from a utility maximizing consumer.

โ€ข We refer to (๐‘๐‘ก , ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก) as a set of โ€œdata.โ€

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 152

GARP

โ€ข Afriatโ€™s theorem. For a sequence of price-bundle pairs (๐‘๐‘ก , ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก), the following statements are equivalent: 1) The data satisfies GARP.2) The data can be rationalized by a utility function

satisfying LNS.3) There exists positive numbers (๐‘ข๐‘ก , ๐œ†๐‘ก) for all ๐‘ก =

1,2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘‡ that satisfies the Afriat inequalities

๐‘ข๐‘  โ‰ค ๐‘ข๐‘ก + ๐œ†๐‘ก๐‘๐‘ก(๐‘ฅ๐‘  โˆ’ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก) for all ๐‘ก, ๐‘ 

4) The data can rationalized by a continuous, concave, and strongly monotone utility function.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 153

GARP

โ€ข A data set is โ€œrationalizedโ€ by a utility function if:

โ€“ for every pair (๐‘๐‘ก , ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก), bundle ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก yields a higher utility than any other feasible bundle x, i.e., ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ๐‘ก) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)for all ๐‘ฅ in budget set ๐ต(๐‘๐‘ก , ๐‘๐‘ก๐‘ฅ๐‘ก).

โ€ข Hence, if a data set satisfies GARP, there exists a well-behaved utility function rationalizing such data.

โ€“ That is, the utility function satisfies LNS, continuity, concavity, and strong monotonicity.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 154

GARP

โ€ข Condition (3) in Afriatโ€™s Theorem has a concavity interpretation:

โ€“ From FOCs, we have ๐ท๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก = ๐œ†๐‘ก๐‘๐‘ก.

โ€“ By concavity,

๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก โˆ’๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ๐‘ )

๐‘ฅ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘ฅ๐‘  โ‰ค ๐‘ขโ€ฒ(๐‘ฅ๐‘ )

โ€“ Or, re-arranging,๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก โ‰ค ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘  + ๐‘ขโ€ฒ(๐‘ฅ๐‘ )(๐‘ฅ๐‘ก โˆ’ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ )

โ€“ Since ๐‘ขโ€ฒ ๐‘ฅ๐‘  = ๐œ†๐‘ ๐‘๐‘ , it can be expressed as Afriatโ€™s inequality

๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก โ‰ค ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘  + ๐œ†๐‘ ๐‘๐‘ (๐‘ฅ๐‘ก โˆ’ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ )Advanced Microeconomic Theory 155

GARP

โ€ข Concave utility function

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 156

โ€“ The utility function at point ๐‘ฅ๐‘  is steeper than the ray connecting points A and B.

Recommended