45
What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns Po-Hsuan Hsu * Yiming Yang Tong Zhou January 12, 2018 We thank Hyun Joong Im, Shigang Li, Chi-Yang Tsou, Yi Wu, and seminar participants in Peking University HSBC Business School and Sun Yat-Sen University for their constructive comments. * Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong. Email: [email protected]. Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong. Email: [email protected]. Lingnan College, Sun Yat-Sen University, China. Email: [email protected].

What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

What Follows Innovation Awards?

R&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns

Po-Hsuan Hsu* Yiming Yang† Tong Zhou‡

January 12, 2018

We thank Hyun Joong Im, Shigang Li, Chi-Yang Tsou, Yi Wu, and seminar participants in Peking University HSBC

Business School and Sun Yat-Sen University for their constructive comments.

* Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong. Email: [email protected]. † Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong. Email: [email protected]. ‡ Lingnan College, Sun Yat-Sen University, China. Email: [email protected].

Page 2: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

1

What Follows Innovation Awards?

R&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns

January 12, 2018

Abstract: This paper connects product market segmentation to asset pricing through a

prestigious award for technology breakthroughs in product inventions: the R&D 100

Award. We argue that award-winning events have asset pricing implications because

award-winning firms can promote their products to the high-end market, which

increases profitability in a procyclical way and results in higher systematic risk. We

find that, compared with their matched industry peers, award-winning firms are

associated with higher future gross profit margins and net sales. Moreover, award-

winning firms outperform their matched industry peers by 3% in annual return. To

explain this intriguing pattern, we develop an investment-based model to connect

growth opportunities, R&D investments, product awards, and stock returns. The model

also suggests that the award-return relation increases with R&D investments and

aggregate consumption, which receive empirical support.

Key words: Innovation Award, Product Segmentation, Growth Opportunity, Stock

Returns

JEL classification: E23, G12, L22, O31

Page 3: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

2

1. Introduction

Product awards are a specific titles or marks of recognition granted to products and

producers in honor of particular achievements or unique features of such products.

These awards, especially prestigious ones, serve as important indicators of the quality

and merits (in various dimensions) of firms and products and are highly regarded by

industry professionals and communities. Thus, product awards likely attract market

attentions, enhance company image, and help firms differentiate their products from

competitors. Award-winning firms consider prestigious awards as cornerstones of

company reputations and list them on the webpages of company history and honors to

highlight such achievements and legacies.1 The asset pricing implications of product

awards, however, are underexplored in the finance literature to our knowledge and thus

call for further investigation.

In this paper, we focus on the R&D 100 Award, which is granted by R&D Magazine

since 1965 to honor great R&D pioneers and their revolutionary ideas in science and

technology. It is often known as “Oscar of Innovation” based on its prestige and long

history.2 Over past five decades, R&D Magazine announced the application process to

the public in spring or summer, and formed judge panels to select and grant awards to

the 100 most technologically significant new products and services (in any technology

area) that are incorporated into commercial products or services in the last year.3 The

winner is announced at the end of summer or fall. When a product is selected and

granted with the award, the producer is entitled to use the term and logo of “R&D 100

Award” in making announcements and in marketing and promotion of the product. The

1 For example, Goodyear and United Technologies list their awards on the webpages of company history

(https://corporate.goodyear.com/en-US/about/history.html and http://www.utrc.utc.com/our-history.html). 3M lists

their awards on the webpage of company profile and awards (http://solutions.3m.com/wps/portal/3M/en_US/3M-

Company/Information/Profile/Awards/ ). 2 The term “Oscar of Innovation” is also used by many award-winning firms and organizations including NASA

(https://technology.grc.nasa.gov/featurestory/rd100-press-release), Mercedes-Benz

(http://mercedesblog.com/mercedes-benznanoslide-technology/), Toyota

(https://www.toyota.com/usa/environmentreport2014/carbon.html), and Los Alamos National Lab

(http://www.lanl.gov/discover/news-release-archive/2016/November/11.15-rd-100-awards.php). 3 There is no further ranking within the 100 winning products and services. Applicants can be companies, individuals,

or non-profit institutes such as universities and national laboratories. Judge panels consist of outside experts with

experience in the areas they are judging, such professional consultants, university faculty members, and industrial

researchers. Judges must also be unbiased and must possess no conflicts of interest with any entries they may be

judging.

Page 4: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

3

award thus offers recipient firms a chance to signal the novelty of their award-winning

products to buyers,4 to differentiate the products from other competitors’, and to charge

higher prices.

Intel’s marketing strategy for its award-winning product, Intel Core processor

family, is a prominent example for the marketing value of the R&D 100 Award. From

1994 to 2010, the Central Processing Unit (CPU) market is dominated by Intel, with

Pentium aiming for mid-to-high-end markets and Celeron for low-end markets.

However, the demand of the high-end computation-efficient markets, driven by work

stations and advanced electric game players, are expanding rapidly but unfilled. In 2011,

R&D Magazine announces the Intel Core processor family as a recipient of the R&D

100 Award. In the same year, Intel targets its Core processors to the mid-to-high end,

moving the Pentium to the entry level and bumping the Celeron to low end. 5 Intel

treats the reception of R&D 100 Award as a key determinant of their successful

marketing of the new high-end products, as it lists this accomplishment on their website

of the Core processors and poses its case on the R&D 100 Award website as a successful

example connecting this award to product commercialization.

We argue that winning the R&D 100 Award has asset pricing implications because

awarded firms gain access to more growth opportunities because the positive image and

credit associated with the award enable these firms to market their products on the high

end of the market. Such a market position likely increases award-winning firms’

profitability; in fact, it also makes these firms’ profits more procyclical, which results

in higher systematic risk. To examine the asset pricing implications of the award, we

collect total 5144 award records that were granted to U.S. public firms in the sample

period 1965 to 2014: these awards were granted to 601 unique firms.6 Due to rarity of

4 Some most recent studies have started to use R&D 100 Award to measure firms’ technological breakthroughs (e.g.

Lev and Sougiannis (1996); Ait‐Sahalia, Parker, and Yogo (2004); Verhoeven, Bakker, and Veugelers (2016); and

Chen et al. (2017)). 5 The winning announcement of 2010 Intel Core processor family is unveiled in the webpage of R&D100 in 2011

(https://www.rd100conference.com/awards/winners-finalists/926/next-generation-processors-enhance-graphics-

speed/), and Intel also advertises their winning award on the webpage of company

newsroom (https://newsroom.intel.com/chip-shots/chip-shot-intel-core-snags-rd-100-award/). 6 The average probability for a public firm to win one or more awards in a year is 0.5%. Awards can be

downloaded via https://www.rd100conference.com/awards/winners-finalists/year/2015/

Page 5: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

4

the awards, we define a firm as an award-winner if it receives at least one award over

the past five years.

Since a firm that is able to create award-winning breakthroughs may be quite

different from most of the other firms, we construct a comparable benchmark to each

awarded firm following the methodology of Daniel et al. (1997). Specifically, we

identify an unawarded firm as a comparable benchmark to the awarded firm if it falls

in the same quintile of market capitalization, in the same quintile of book-to-market

ratio, in the same quintile of momentum, and in the same 12-industry classification by

Fama and French (1995) by the same year end. Our summary statistics suggests that

the realized awarded firms and the benchmarked unawarded firms are highly

comparable in many dimensions, including R&D expenses.

Our empirical tests provide empirical evidence consistent with the notion that

award-winning firms perform better in profitability through access to high-end product

markets. We find that, compared with their benchmarked counterparts, award-winning

firms generate higher gross profit margins and higher net sales, spend higher SG&A

costs and advertising expenditures, hold less cash, and invest more in R&D and physical

capital over the next five-year horizon.

The aforementioned tests are only suggestive and subject to endogeneity problem,

though, as a firm with more growth opportunities and potential will endogenously

choose to invest more in R&D, and therefore have a higher chance to win the award

and continue to have more growth opportunities in the future. To address this concern

and further deliver asset pricing implications of the award outcome, we build an

investment-based model that formulates the relations among growth opportunities,

R&D investments, and award outcomes. Specifically, we assume that a firm is endowed

with a certain number of growth opportunities (such as talents, initial market positions,

and brand images) to commercialize its products in high-end markets, which generate

more procyclical profits than the low-end markets. However, the profits of these high-

end markets can be realized only if the firm wins the award. Winning an award requires

the firm to invest in R&D – higher R&D investment leads to higher award-winning

Page 6: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

5

probability and access to high-end markets. The model suggests that in equilibrium, a

firm endowed with more growth opportunities indeed invests more in R&D and

therefore have a higher chance to win the award. This relation is supported in our

empirical analysis.

Three testable model implications are derived from our model. As we assume that

both the profits of high-end markets and the profits of low-end markets are procyclical

to aggregate consumption risk, awarded firms with more growth opportunities have

higher future exposure to systematic consumption risks than unawarded firms. Since

awarded firms are riskier, in equilibrium awarded firms demand higher expected stock

returns than unawarded firms (Proposition 1). Proposition 2 posits that the risk premium

of awarded firms is higher in higher R&D investment subgroup, as in equilibrium the

intensity of R&D investment reflects the number of growth opportunities for each firm.

Lastly, the risk premium of awarded firms varies with aggregate consumption.

Proposition 3 proposes that the risk premium of awarded firms is higher during periods

of high aggregate consumption.

We implement portfolio sorting to examine the award-return relation and find

supportive evidence for Proposition 1. We form an awarded portfolio that takes equal

positions in all awarded firms that win at least one award from year t−4 to year t, and

hold this portfolio from July of year t+1 and June of year t+2.7 We also form an

unawarded portfolio that takes equal positions in all benchmarked unawarded firms,

and hold this portfolio from July of year t+1 and June of year t+2. Lastly, we construct

an awarded-minus-unawarded (AMU) portfolio by going long in the awarded portfolio

and going short in the unawarded portfolio, and hold it from July of year t+1 and June

of year t+2. The return from the AMU portfolio ranges from 0.19% to 0.32% per month

under different factor models (but all statistically significant at the 5% level).

We document that the risk premium of awarded firms differs in subgroups of R&D

investments and subperiods of aggregate consumption, which supports Propositions 2

7 We use equal-weighted stock returns for two reasons: first, the number of awarded firms is not big; and second,

the awarded firms and the benchmarked unawarded firms are constructed to be highly comparable in firm size.

Page 7: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

6

and 3. Using two-way sequential portfolio sorting, we document that the monthly return

of the AMU portfolio ranges from 0.47% to 0.78% in the high R&D investment

subgroup and ranges from -0.13% to 14% in the low R&D investment subgroup. We

also find that the monthly return of the AMU portfolio mainly comes from the non-

crisis periods, which are defined by NBER and proxy for periods of high aggregate

consumption. This evidence supports our argument of growth opportunities and

consumption risk.

This study is related to Ait‐Sahalia, Parker, and Yogo (2004), which uses the

import data of 70 French luxury good manufacturers to identify luxury consumption

and shows that the cross-section of stock returns can be explained by the loadings on

luxury consumption growth. Different from their approach that estimates stocks’

exposure to aggregate luxury consumption and associated risk, we propose to directly

use the R&D 100 Award to measure firm-level access to high-end markets and to sort

portfolios.

Our paper also adds to the stream of asset pricing literature on product market

competition. Hou and Robinson (2006) focus on concentration of firm sales within

industry and document that higher competition leads to lower stock returns. Hoberg and

Phillips (2012) use text analysis to define product market rivals and find that product

uniqueness does not have any explanatory power on future stock returns. We also focus

on product market development but from a completely different angle – while they

study the existent structure of product markets (e.g., “red seas”), we pay more attention

to the asset pricing implications of growth opportunities in new product markets (e.g.,

“blue seas”). Growth opportunities are key drivers of firm risks and asset prices and

therefore more value-relevant.

Our study also provides new evidence to the literature on technological innovation

in finance. Prior studies investigate the relation between asset prices and the dynamics

of technological innovation.8 Different from prior studies based on R&D and patent

8 These studies include Pakes (1985), Lev and Sougiannis (1996), Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell (2001), Berk,

Green, and Naik (1999), Deng, Lev, and Narin (1999), Chan, Lakonishok, and Sougiannis (2001), Hobijn and

Jovanovic (2001), Bloom and Reenen (2002), Gomes, Kogan, and Zhang (2003), Laitner and Stolyarov (2003),

Page 8: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

7

data, our paper focuses one important channel through which technological innovation

influences equity pricing – product awards and high-end market demand. Moreover, we

provide evidence to confirm that R&D investments, innovative products, and asset

prices are interlinked.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides suggestive

evidence examining the difference in future product-market performance between

awarded firms and unawarded firms. In Section 3, we present a tractable model that

explains the relations among growth opportunities, R&D investments, award-winning

outcomes, and asset prices. We test our model implications in Section 4. Section 5

concludes.

2. Awards and Future Firm Operations

In this section, we investigate the relation between a firm’s receipt of the R&D 100

Award and its future product-market performance. To do so, we manually collect the

full list of products receiving the “R&D 100 Award” published by R&D Magazine from

1965 to 2014. We further match these products to their developers as U.S. public

companies if these firms are listed as the co-developers of the awarded products. In our

sample of 2014, the 100 awarded products are co-developed by 88 unique firms, among

them 30 unique public firms. From our full sample from 1965 to 2014, we end up with

5144 award-winning records granted to 601 unique U.S. public firms.

Figure 1 Panel A illustrates the distribution of awarding outcomes across the Fama-

French 12 industries (Fama and French, 1995). The four industries winning the most

R&D 100 awards in our sample are Durables (8%), Manufacturing (31%), Chemicals,

(12%) and Business Equipment (32%). Panel B further implies that even in these

industries dominating the awards, the awarding outcomes vary significantly over time.

[Figure 1 here.]

Kogan (2004), Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004), Zhang (2005), Aguerrevere (2009), Hsu (2009), Pastor and

Veronesi (2009), Abel and Eberly (2011), Papanikolaou (2011), Garleanu, Panageas, and Yu (2012), Lin (2012), Ai

and Kiku (2013), Kogan and Papanikolaou (2014), Kogan et al. (2017), and , Zhou (2017) among others.

Page 9: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

8

Since we argue that an awarded product may grant a firm with the access to the

high-end markets and therefore generate higher product value and profit margins in the

long term, we identify a firm as awarded by year t if it receives at least one award in

the previous five years from year t-4 to t due to the rarity of the award. In our sample,

total 1862 firm-year observations are “awarded firms”.

To compare the operational performance of awarded firms with that of unawarded

firms, we first construct a comparable benchmark to each awarded firm following the

methodology of Daniel et al. (1997). Specifically, we identify an unawarded firm as a

comparable benchmark to the awarded firm if it falls in the same quintile of market

capitalization, in the same quintile of book-to-market ratio, in the same quintile of

momentum, and in the same 12-industry classification according to Fama and French

(1995) by the end of year t. As we compare awarded firms with their counterparts in

the same industry, our results are immune to industry heterogeneity. Our stock

transaction data is extracted from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP)

database and the accounting data is from Compustat.

Table 1 Panel A shows that, on an average year, we identify 57 awarded firms and

258 benchmarked unawarded firms. The ratio of awarded firms over benchmarked

unawarded firms is stable around 0.24 with the time-series standard deviation of 0.07,

but this ratio is largely dispersed across industries with the mean of 0.51 and the

standard deviation of 0.49. Panel B compares the median of the unawarded group with

the median of the awarded group and confirms that our benchmarked unawarded firms

are highly comparable to the awarded firms, in terms of market capitalization ($945m

vs. $954m), book-to-market ratio (0.59 vs. 0.62), momentum (9.64% vs. 8.83%), total

assets ($706m vs. $827m), R&D expenses ($16m vs. $30m), R&D-to-total asset ratio

(4% vs. 6%), sales ($749m vs. $928m), profit margins (5% vs. 5%), and cash holdings

(6% vs. 6%).

[Table 1 here.]

Then we examine whether the awarded firms outperform their benchmarked

counterparts in product markets over the next five-year horizon. To do so, we consider

Page 10: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

9

four direct measures of product market operations: gross profit margin (the difference

between sales and the cost of the goods sold divided by the sales), net sales, costs of

selling, general, and administration (SG&A), and advertising expenditures. These four

measures are scaled by total assets to eliminate firm size effect. Under the notion that

awarded firms have more access to high-end product markets, we expect that the future

gross profit margin, net sales, SG&A costs, and advertising expenditures of the awarded

firms are higher than those of their unawarded benchmarks. We also consider three

variables that are related to firms’ product market operations: R&D expenditures scaled

by total assets, capital expenditures by total assets, and cash holdings (cash and short-

term investments divided by sales). Facing higher growth opportunities, the awarded

firms are expected to spend more cash in R&D investment and capital expenditure.

Table 2 presents the results when we regress one of the seven above-mentioned

variables averaged across year t+1 to t+5 as dependent variable on a dummy indicating

whether the firm is awarded at year t (from year t-4 to t) or not. We also control for the

following variables in year t to mitigate any bias caused by the ex-ante heterogeneity

in firm characteristics: market capitalization, book-to-market ratio, stock price

momentum, year fixed effects, and industry fixed effects.

Panels A-D suggest that the awarded firms are expected to have higher gross profit

margins, higher net sales, higher SG&A costs, and higher advertising expenditures than

their unawarded benchmarks by 1%-2%, 4%-5%, 1%-2%, and 0.2%, respectively.

These coefficients are all statistically significant at the 10% level and vary only little

under different sets of control variables. Such outperformance in product markets is

considerable and translated into 4-8% of the sample mean of gross profit margin, 4-5%

of the sample mean of net sales, 5-10% of the sample mean of SG&A costs, and 10%

of the sample mean of advertising expenditures.9 We also observe in Panels E-G that

awarded firms invest significantly more in R&D and physical capital and hold

significantly less cash in the next five years. In sum, the empirical evidence in Table 2

9 The sample means of gross profit margin, net sales, SG&A costs, and advertising expenditures are 27%, 108%,

22%, and 2%, respectively.

Page 11: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

10

supports our argument that awarded firms have higher growth opportunities in product

markets than their benchmarked unawarded peers.

[Table 2 here.]

3. Model and Asset Pricing Implications

In the previous section, we document that firms winning the awards have more

growth opportunities in high-end product markets, as indicated by their higher gross

profit margins, higher net sales, higher SG&A costs, and higher advertising

expenditures in the future. One major concern of our empirical analysis in the last

section is related to endogeneity – a firm with higher growth opportunities will

endogenously choose to invest more in R&D, and therefore have a higher chance to

receive the award and continue to have higher growth opportunities in the future. To

address this concern and further deliver asset pricing implications of the award outcome,

we build an investment-based model that takes into account the relations among growth

opportunities, R&D investments, award outcomes, and stock returns.

3.1 Model setup

Only one firm operates in three periods, t, t+1, and t+2, in the economy. Its

stochastic operating profit (𝐹𝜏) in each period is given by the following equation:

𝐹𝜏 = 𝐿𝜏 + 𝐷𝜏 ∙ 𝑛𝐻𝜏, (1)

where 𝐿𝜏 is the stochastic profit generated from the low-end products and 𝐻𝜏 is the

stochastic profit generated from the high-end products. The parameter (constant across

all periods) 𝑛 captures the number of growth opportunities (talents, initial market

positions, and brand images) in high-end markets. We assume that the focal firm can

access the high-end product markets only if it is recognized by the award. Therefore,

𝐷𝜏 takes the value of zero when the firm is not awarded, and takes the value of one

when it is awarded.

Page 12: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

11

At Date t, the firm maximizes its firm value and invests a lump-sum amount 𝐼 to

develop innovative products. To model the relation between R&D investments and

award outcome, we assume that the magnitude of 𝐼 determines the probability of

receiving the award (denoted by 𝜋𝐴) at Date t+1. The relation between 𝜋𝐴 and 𝐼 is

further assumed to follow two inequalities: 𝑑𝜋𝐴 𝑑𝐼⁄ > 0 and 𝑑2𝜋𝐴 𝑑𝐼2⁄ > 0 . The

economic interpretation of these two inequalities is that on the one hand, as the firm

increases its intensity of R&D, its probability of achieving novel design is higher; on

the other hand, the marginal benefit of investment diminishes.

𝐿𝜏 and 𝐻𝜏 are assumed to comove with the same aggregate consumption shock,

i.e.,

𝐿𝜏 = 𝐶𝜏𝜃𝐿 , and (2)

𝐻𝜏 = 𝐶𝜏𝜃𝐻 . (3)

where 𝜃𝐿 and 𝜃𝐻 are the degrees of cyclicality of low-end products and high-end

product, respectively. Following Ait‐Sahalia, Parker, and Yogo (2004), we assume

𝜃𝐻 > 𝜃𝐿. Under this inequality, the profits of high-end products are more cyclical to

aggregate consumption than the profits of low-end products. In other words, given the

same positive (negative) shock to aggregate consumption, the profits of high-end goods

increase (decrease) by a larger amount than the profits of low-end goods.

The process of aggregate consumption 𝐶𝜏 is given by the following geometric

Brownian motion:

ln 𝐶𝜏+1 = ln𝐶𝜏 + 𝜇 + 𝜎𝜀𝜏+1, (4)

where 𝜀𝜏+1~𝑁(0,1) is the market-wide demand shock, 𝜇 is the parameter of the drift

term, and 𝜎 is the parameter of the variance term. Correspondingly, the stochastic

discount factor 𝑀𝜏 is assumed to follow a geometric Brownian motion, i.e.,

ln𝑀𝜏+1 = ln𝑀𝜏 − 𝛾 − 𝜅𝜀𝜏+1, (5)

where 𝛾 is a parameter of the risk-free rate and 𝜅 is a parameter of the variance.

Restrictions are assumed on these parameters to ensure the existence of risk-neutral

Page 13: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

12

pricing: 𝛾 + 𝜅𝜎 − 1

2𝜅2 > 0.

3.2 Solution and comparative statics

To derive the optimal investment 𝐼 at Date t, we solve the firm value in backward

induction. The value of an awarded firm at Date t+1 is:

𝑉𝑡+1𝐴 = 𝐸𝑡+1 [

𝑀𝑡+2

𝑀𝑡+1(𝐿𝑡+2 + 𝑛𝐻𝑡+2)], (6)

and the value of a unawarded firm at Date t+1 is:

𝑉𝑡+1𝑈 = 𝐸𝑡+1 [

𝑀𝑡+2

𝑀𝑡+1(𝐿𝑡+2)]. (7)

The maximization problem of the firm at Date t is given below:

max𝐼

{𝐿𝑡 − 𝐼 + 𝐸𝑡 [𝑀𝑡+1

𝑀𝑡(𝐿𝑡+1 + 𝜋𝐴𝑉𝑡+1

𝐴 + (1 − 𝜋𝐴)𝑉𝑡+1𝑈 )]}.

Re-arranging the maximization problem with Equations (2)-(7), the first-order

condition can be solved in the following equation:

𝑛𝑑𝜋𝐴

𝑑𝐼𝐸𝑡+1 [

𝑀𝑡+2

𝑀𝑡𝐻𝑡+2] = 1. (8)

This first-order condition in Equation (8) implies that the firm will invest so that

the marginal benefit of R&D investments, which is calculated as the increment of award

probability multiplied by the present value of the increased firm value, equals to the

marginal cost of investment, which is assumed to be one and constant. Taking derivative

with respect to 𝑛 on both sides of Equation (8), we can derive the following inequality:

𝜕2𝜋𝐴𝜕𝐼∗𝜕𝑛

< 0.

Following the chain rule of derivative, we obtain:

𝜕𝐼∗

𝜕𝑛=

𝜕2𝜋𝐴

𝜕𝐼∗𝜕𝑛/𝜕2𝜋𝐴

𝜕𝐼∗2> 0, (9)

which leads to the following Lemma 1.

Lemma 1 The firm’s R&D investments in innovative products increase with the

Page 14: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

13

number of growth opportunities in high-end markets, i.e., 𝜕𝐼∗ 𝜕𝑛⁄ > 0.

Remark 1 The mechanism is that, given the R&D investments and thereby the

probability of being awarded, the present value of being awarded is higher when the

number of growth opportunities in high-end markets is larger, and therefore, the firm

with more growth opportunities invests more at the first place. Lemma 1 is consistent

with previous studies documenting the relation between R&D investments and growth

opportunities, such as Berk, Green, and Naik (1999), Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino

(2004), Garleanu, Panageas, and Yu (2012), and Ai and Kiku (2013), among others.

After solving the optimal investment, we can derive the ex-dividend firm value at

Date t as:

𝑉𝑡 = 𝐸𝑡 [𝑀𝑡+1

𝑀𝑡𝐿𝑡+1 +

𝑀𝑡+1

𝑀𝑡(𝜋𝐴𝑉𝑡+1

𝐴 + (1 − 𝜋𝐴)𝑉𝑡+1𝑈 )].

The expected stock return at Date t is given by the following equation:

𝑟𝑡 ≡𝐸𝑡[𝑉𝑡+1+𝐿𝑡+1]

𝑉𝑡. (10)

Re-organizing Equation (10) with Equations (2)-(7), we can show that 𝑟𝑡 increases in

𝑛, i.e.,

𝜕𝑟𝑡𝜕𝑛

> 0.

Therefore, we obtain the following inequality and Lemma 2 following the chain

rule of derivative:

𝜕𝑟𝑡𝜕𝐼∗

=𝜕𝑟𝑡𝜕𝑛

/𝜕𝐼∗

𝜕𝑛 > 0.

Lemma 2 The expected stock return of the firm increases with its R&D investments in

innovative products, i.e., 𝜕𝑟𝑡 𝜕𝐼∗⁄ > 0.

Remark 2 Lemma 2 is true under our assumption of 𝜃𝐻 > 𝜃𝐿 and confirms that the

mechanism of the positive relation between R&D investments and expected stock return

is that a firm with higher R&D investments is the one with more growth opportunities,

which have higher exposure to aggregate consumption shock, and therefore, its firm

Page 15: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

14

value loads more on the aggregate consumption shock and generates higher expected

stock return. Lemma 2 is consistent with the evidence documented in Lev and

Sougiannis (1996) and Chan, Lakonishok, and Sougiannis (2001) showing that R&D

expenditure is a positive return predictor.

Next, we turn to the discussion on the effect of awards on stock returns. The net-

of-announcement-return stock return of the unawarded firm at Date t+1 is given as:

𝑟𝑡+1𝑈 =

𝐿𝑡+2

𝑉𝑡+1𝑈 ,

and the net-of-announcement-return stock return of the awarded firm at Date t+1 is

given as:

𝑟𝑡+1𝐴 =

𝐿𝑡+2 + 𝑛𝐻𝑡+2

𝑉𝑡+1𝑁 .

Following the asset pricing literature, the firm’s exposure to systematic (consumption)

risk is defined as the inverse of the ratio of its covariance between the (log) return and

the stochastic discount rate over the variance of the discount rate. Therefore, we can

derive the systematic risk exposures of the unawarded firm and the awarded firm in the

following two equations10, respectively:

𝛽𝑡+1𝑈 = −

𝐶𝑜𝑣𝑡+1[ln(𝑀𝑡+2𝑀𝑡+1

),ln𝑟𝑡+1𝑁 ]

𝑉𝑎𝑟𝑡+1[ln(𝑀𝑡+2𝑀𝑡+1

)]= 𝜃𝐿 ∙

𝜎

𝜅, and (11)

𝛽𝑡+1𝐴 = −

𝐶𝑜𝑣𝑡+1[ln(𝑀𝑡+2𝑀𝑡+1

),ln𝑟𝑡+1𝐴 ]

𝑉𝑎𝑟𝑡+1[ln(𝑀𝑡+2𝑀𝑡+1

)]=

𝜃𝐿∙𝐶𝑡+1𝜃𝐿 𝜇𝜃𝐿+𝜃𝐻∙𝑛∙𝐶𝑡+1

𝜃𝐻𝜇𝜃𝐻

𝐶𝑡+1𝜃𝐿 𝜇𝜃𝐿+𝑛∙𝐶𝑡+1

𝜃𝐻𝜇𝜃𝐻∙𝜎

𝜅. (12)

From Equations (11) and (12), we obtain:

𝛽𝑡+1𝐴 > 𝛽𝑡+1

𝑈 ,

which leads to the following Lemma 3.

Lemma 3 The systematic risk exposure of the awarded firm is higher than that of the

unawarded firm, i.e., 𝛽𝑡+1𝐴 > 𝛽𝑡+1

𝑈 .

Remark 3 As we assume that the profits of high-end markets are more procyclical than

10 Equation (12) can be derived by applying Taylor expansion to 𝑟𝑡+1

𝐴 around 𝜀𝑡+2 = 0.

Page 16: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

15

the profits of low-end markets, the awarded firms with more growth opportunities have

higher exposure to market-wide risks. Previous literature, such as Berk, Green, and

Naik (1999), Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004), Aguerrevere (2009), and

Garleanu, Panageas, and Yu (2012), among others, has documented that growth

options are riskier than assets in place. It is noteworthy that 𝛽𝑡+1𝐴 increases with 𝑛

(and thereby 𝐼∗ ) and 𝐶𝑡+1 but 𝛽𝑡+1𝑈 is uncorrelated with these two variables.

Therefore, Lemma 3 is consistent with Propositions 2 and 3 in that the systematic risk

exposure and expected stock return of awarded firms not only increases with R&D

investments but also are procyclical to aggregate consumption.

The expected stock return of the firm at Date t+1 contingent on not receiving the

award can be derived as:

𝐸𝑡+1[𝑟𝑡+1𝑈 ] = exp{𝛾 + 𝜃𝐿𝜎𝜅 −

1

2𝜅2}. (13)

The expected stock return of the firm at Date t+1 contingent on receiving the award can

be written as:

𝐸𝑡+1[𝑟𝑡+1𝐴 ] = 𝑟𝑡+1

𝑈 [1 +Ψ(𝑛)

1+Ψ(𝑛)(exp{(𝜃𝐻 − 𝜃𝐿)𝜎𝜅} − 1)], (14)

where Ψ(𝑛) is defined as the following function of 𝑛:

Ψ(𝑛) = 𝑛𝐶𝑡+1𝜃𝐻−𝜃𝐿 exp {((𝜃𝐻 − 𝜃𝐿)𝜇 +

1

2(𝜃𝐻

2 − 𝜃𝐿2)𝜎2 − (𝜃𝐻 − 𝜃𝐿)𝜎𝜅)} > 0.

(15)

Note that Ψ(𝑛) is increasing in 𝑛 and 𝐶𝑡+1.

From Equations (13) and (14), we can derive that the awarded-minus-unawarded

return spread (𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈), which is the difference between the expected stock return of an

awarded firm (𝑟𝑡+1𝐴 ) and the expected stock return of an unawarded firm (𝑟𝑡+1

𝑈 ) (also

known as the risk premium of awarded firms):

𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑁 ≡ 𝑟𝑡+1

𝐴 − 𝑟𝑡+1𝑁 = 𝑟𝑡+1

𝑁 Ψ(𝑛)

1+Ψ(𝑛)(𝑒(𝜃𝐿−𝜃𝐵)𝜎𝜅 − 1) > 0. (16)

Inequality (16) leads to Proposition 1.

Page 17: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

16

Proposition 1 The expected stock return of the awarded firm is higher than that of the

unawarded firm, i.e., 𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈 > 0.

Remark 4 Awarded firms are expected to have higher growth opportunities to high-

end (riskier) market. Therefore, their operational profits are more procyclical to

aggregate consumption and higher expected stock returns are required.

We can also show that the risk premium of awarded firms increases with R&D

investments. Since Ψ(𝑛) is an increasing function of 𝑛 (Equation (15)), we can

derive the following inequality (17):

𝜕𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈

𝜕𝑛> 0. (17)

Therefore, combining Inequalities (9) and (17) and applying the chain rule of

derivative, we can obtain:

𝜕𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈

𝜕𝐼∗=𝜕𝑟𝑡+1

𝐴𝑀𝑈

𝜕𝑛

𝜕𝐼∗

𝜕𝑛⁄ > 0.

The above inequality can be interpreted into the following Proposition 2.

Proposition 2 The risk premium of the awarded firm is higher when the firm’s R&D

investment is higher, i.e., 𝜕𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈 𝜕𝐼∗⁄ > 0.

Remark 5 Lemma 1 proposes that firms endowed with more growth opportunities

endogenously choose to invest more on in R&D. Thus, the intensity of R&D investment

is a proxy for the number of growth opportunities. Under the notion that the awarded

firms are entitled access to potential high-end markets whereas the unawarded firms

are not, the awards realize more growth opportunities, bring higher additional

systematic risks (Lemma 3), and demand higher risk premium for firms with higher

R&D investments.

The risk premium of awarded firms varies with aggregate consumption. To show

this, we derive the partial derivative of 𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈 with respect to 𝐶𝑡+1. As indicated in

Equation (15), Ψ(𝑛) is an increasing function of 𝐶𝑡+1 . Thus, we can derive the

following inequality from Equation (16):

Page 18: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

17

𝜕𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈

𝜕𝐶𝑡+1> 0. (18)

Inequality (18) can be summarized in the following Proposition 3.

Proposition 3 The risk premium of the awarded firm is procyclical to aggregate

consumption is higher, i.e., 𝜕𝑟𝑡+1𝐴𝑀𝑈 𝜕𝐶𝑡+1⁄ > 0.

Remark 6 When the aggregate consumption follows the geometric Brownian motion,

the expected growth rate and volatility of consumption are higher if the current

consumption is higher. Therefore, the awarded firms, which have higher exposure to

new high-end product markets and thereby higher risk exposure (Lemma 3), should

demand higher risk premium in periods of higher consumption.

4. Empirical Tests

In the previous two sections, we empirically document the positive impact of the R&D

100 Award on future product market performance and theoretically derive the

corresponding asset pricing implications. Three hypotheses are developed: awarded

firms have higher expected stock returns than unawarded firms (Proposition 1), the

award-return relation is more pronounced for firms with higher R&D investments

(Proposition 2), and the award-return relation is more pronounced during periods of

high aggregate consumption (Proposition 3). In this section, we implement direct

empirical tests to the model.

4.1 R&D investments and the probability of winning awards

The key assumption of our model is that higher R&D investment leads to higher

probability of being awarded. We test this assumption by running the following logit or

probit regressions with the whole universe of public firms: the dependent variable is a

dummy variable indicating whether the focal firm receives the award in year t+1 or not,

and the key explanatory variable of interest is the average R&D investment, which

denotes the arithmetic average of R&D expenditure scaled by total assets during the

Page 19: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

18

previous five years from t-4 to t. Other firm characteristics by the end of year t are also

controlled, such as market capitalization, book-to-market ratio, and stock price

momentum.

Table 3 shows that the average R&D investment in the previous five years

positively predicts awarding outcome in the next year. This coefficient is statistically

significant at the 1% level in different model specifications and no matter we include

other control variables or not. Its magnitude is economically meaningful – for example,

the coefficient of 1.96 under logit regression and 0.77 under probit regression are

translated into a marginal effect of 3%. Given that the sample standard deviation of

R&D investment is 10%, a one-standard-deviation increase in R&D investment leads

to a 0.3% increase in awarding probability, which is huge relative to the average

awarding probability of 0.5% among public firms.

[Table 3 here.]

4.2 Awards and expected stock returns

In our model, we propose that firms recognized by innovation awards outperform their

unawarded peers in the stock returns (Proposition 1). We conduct the portfolio sorting

analysis to test this model implication. Specifically, at the end of year t from 1969 to

2013, we consider a firm to be an awarded firm if it receives at least one award in the

previous five years (year t−4 to year t). Using the same methodology in Section 2, we

build the comparison benchmark of each awarded firm as the subgroup of unawarded

firms of similar size, book-to-market ratio, and momentum in the same industry. We

form an awarded portfolio that takes equal positions in all awarded firms that win at

least one award from year t−4 to year t, and hold this portfolio from July of year t+1

and June of year t+2.11 We also form an unawarded portfolio that takes equal positions

in all benchmarked unawarded firms, and hold this portfolio from July of year t+1 and

June of year t+2. To compare the difference in expected stock returns of awarded firms

11 We use equal-weighted stock returns for two reasons: first, the number of awarded firms is not big; and second,

the awarded firms and the benchmarked unawarded firms are constructed to be highly comparable in firm size.

Page 20: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

19

and their benchmarked unawarded firms, we construct an awarded-minus-unawarded

(AMU) portfolio by going long in the awarded portfolio and going short in the

benchmarked unawarded portfolio, and hold it over the next twelve months from July

of year t+1 and June of year t+2.12 Since the awarded firms and the benchmarked

unawarded firms are already highly comparable in firm characteristics (as shown in

Table 1), we compare the equally weighted average stock returns of awarded firms with

those of their unawarded counterparts.

Table 4 reports the average monthly excess returns of the awarded portfolio and

the benchmarked unawarded portfolio, in which monthly excess return is monthly stock

return in excess of the one-month Treasury bill rate. In the first column, we document

that the awarded portfolio on average have higher expected return than the

benchmarked unawarded portfolio – the average excess return of the awarded portfolio

is 1.1% while the average excess return of the benchmarked unawarded portfolio is

0.84%. This return difference is positive, about 0.26% per month, and statistically

significant at the 1% level, which supports Proposition 1.

Although our awarded firms and benchmarked unawarded firms are matched in

the same industry and with similar size, book-to-market ratio, and momentum, we

further control for their exposure to the size factor (SMB) and the value factor (HML)

in the three-factor model (FF3) of Fama and French (1993), the momentum factor

(UMD) in the four-factor model (FF4) of Carhart (1997), the profitability factor (RMW)

and the investment factor (CMA) in the five-factor model (FF5) of Fama and French

(2015) and the six-factor model (FF6) of Fama and French (2017), and the R&D factor

by Chan, Lakonishok, and Sougiannis (2001). The results show that the perhaps

different exposure to these risk factors cannot explain the risk premium of awarded

firms. For instance, when we control for the Fama-French three factors, the monthly

risk premium of the awarded portfolio is 0.29% and the monthly risk premium of the

benchmarked unawarded portfolio is zero. Such a difference is about 0.28% per month,

12 We use a six-month lag to form portfolios in order to make out results comparable to priors studies such as Fama

and French (1993) and Fama and French (2015).

Page 21: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

20

even higher than the one when we do not control for any risk factor, and statistically

significant at the 1% level. The risk premium of the awarded portfolio is still significant

at the 5% level when we control for R&D factor in addition to the Fama-French six

factors, even though its economic magnitude is 0.2% and a little lower.

[Table 4 here.]

Figure 2 implies that the performance of our long-short strategy based on awarding

outcomes is robust in our sample period from 1970 to 2014. Besides year 2000

accompanied with a significant shoot-up, the performance of our strategy is stable over

different time periods. Moreover, our long-short strategy does not experience large

draw-backs during the crisis periods, such as 1987 and 2008.

[Figure 3 here.]

We further explore the long-term performance of our long-short strategy up to a

five-year horizon. Specifically, we trace the cumulative returns of investments in both

the awarded portfolio and the benchmarked unawarded portfolio from July of year t

(the 1st month since the portfolio is formed) to June of year t+5 (the 60th and last

portfolio month). Figure 3 shows that the curves illustrating the cumulative returns of

both the awarded portfolio and the benchmarked unawarded portfolio are upward

sloping during the 60-portfolio-month window. Further comparison implies that the

performance of the awarded portfolio is persistently superior to that of benchmarked

unawarded portfolio – the cumulative return of the former portfolio is always higher

than that of the latter portfolio, and by the end of the 60th portfolio month, the average

cumulative return of the awarded portfolio reaches 185% while the average cumulative

return of the benchmarked unawarded portfolio reaches 175%. This long-lasting

outperformance of the awarded portfolio supports our model implication that the

awarded firms are exposed to higher long-term systematic risks due to access to more

growth opportunities.

Generally speaking, consistent with the model, we empirically document that the

awarded firms have higher expected stock returns than their benchmarked counterparts.

Page 22: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

21

Such an award-return relation last up to five years, which probably reflects the higher

long-term risks of the awarded firms rather than any behavioral bias or market frictions.

[Figure 3 here.]

4.3 Award-return relation and R&D investments

The second prediction of our model is that the award-return relation is more pronounced

for firms with higher R&D investments (Proposition 2). To test this model implication,

we perform two-way sequential portfolio sorting analysis to examine the risk premium

of awarded firms across different subgroups of R&D intensity.13 Specifically, at the

end of year t from 1969 to 2013, we consider a firm to be an awarded firm if it receives

at least one award in the previous five years. These awarded firms with non-missing

R&D values are stratified into three subgroups based on the 30th and 70th percentiles of

R&D expenditure scaled by total assets at the same fiscal year end. Following the

similar methodology in Section 2, we identify a subgroup of unawarded firms of each

awarded firm if these firms are of similar size, book-to-market ratio, momentum, and

similar R&D expenditure. To compare the difference in expected stock returns of

awarded firms and their benchmarked unawarded firms in different subgroups of R&D

investments, we construct an awarded-minus-unawarded (AMU) portfolio by going

long in the awarded portfolio and going short in the benchmarked unawarded portfolio

in that R&D subgroup, and hold it over the next twelve months from July of year t+1

and June of year t+2. The equally weighted average stock returns of awarded firms are

compared with those of their unawarded counterparts, since the two types of firms are

already highly comparable in firm size.

Table 5 Panel A reports the average monthly excess returns of the awarded

portfolio and the benchmarked unawarded portfolio for both subgroups of high and low

13 Sequential sorting fits our theoretical setting – we argue that endogenously R&D investment predicts the

probability of being awarded and the award-return relation strengthens with R&D investments. In data, we find

consistent correlation between R&D investments and awarding outcomes. As the results, if we employ the standard

independent sort procedure, the underlying correlation might lead to suboptimal performance and poor

diversification (Lambert, Fays, and Hubner, 2016; Lambert and Hubner, 2013).

Page 23: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

22

R&D investments. We document that the risk premium of awarded firms differs

significantly in different subgroup of R&D investments. For instance, the average

monthly excess stock return of the awarded portfolio is 1.56% and that of the

benchmarked unawarded portfolio is 0.96%. The difference is 0.6% per month and

statistically significant at the 1% level. However, the risk premium of awarded firms is

not significant in the low R&D investments subgroup.

We also control for their exposure to a bunch of systematic risk factors as in

Section 4.2 to relieve the concern that the risk premium of awarded firms is driven by

the distinct characteristics of the awarded firms and thereby higher exposure to certain

risk factors. The results show that under whatever factor models, the risk premium of

awarded firms is significant in the high R&D investments subgroup while it remains

insignificant in the low R&D investment subgroup. For example, the “abnormal” return

of the awarded portfolio relative to the unawarded portfolio is 0.58% under the Fama-

French three factor model and 0.55% under the Fama-French six factor model – it

appears the controlling these risk factors brings very little change to our estimation of

the risk premium of awarded firms in the high R&D investment subgroup. However,

such a premium remains statistically and economically significant in all factor models

we consider. In sum, our empirical evidence is strongly supportive to the model

prediction that the award-return relation is more pronounced among R&D-intensive

firms.

[Table 5 here.]

4.4 Award-return relation and aggregate consumption

Our final model prediction is that the award-return relation is more pronounced

during periods of high aggregate consumption (Proposition 3). To test this model

implication, we use the NBER recession (crisis) periods to proxy for periods of low

aggregate consumption, and use NBER expansion (non-crisis) periods to proxy for

periods of high aggregate consumption. From our full sample from 1970 to 2014, we

Page 24: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

23

end up with 13 years of recessions and 32 years of expansions.

Table 5 Panel B reports the risk premium of awarded firms during recession and

expansion periods. We find that this risk premium mainly comes from the expansion

periods. For example, during the expansion periods, the risk premium of awarded firms

is 0.32% per month. It remains significant and does not change much under different

factor models. However, the magnitude of the award-return relation is much weaker

during recession periods, only 0.13% per month, and it is statistically insignificant.

Therefore, this evidence implies that the award-return relation is procyclical to

aggregate consumption and supports our argument of growth opportunities through

product market segmentation.

5. Concluding Remarks

In this paper, we study the asset pricing implications of product market

segmentation by focusing on a prestigious award for innovative products: the R&D 100

Award. This award is published by R&D Magazine and receives significant publicity

over fifty years. We first document suggestive evidence confirming that a firm

recognized by the award is more likely to perform better in product markets over the

next five-year horizon, which confirms the positive effect of the R&D 100 Award on

product market segmentation.

We then develop an investment-based asset pricing model, which takes into

account the relations among growth opportunities, R&D investments, award outcomes,

and stock prices, and propose three model implications. Empirical evidence supports

these implications: i) the monthly equal-weighted stock returns of awarded firms

outperform their benchmarked counterparts by 0.19% to 0.32%; ii) the difference in

monthly returns between awarded and unawarded firms in the high R&D investment

subgroup is 0.47% to 0.78% higher than that in the low R&D investment subgroup; and

iii) the difference in monthly returns between awarded and unawarded firms is

significantly higher in high-aggregate-consumption periods. Our results are robust to

Page 25: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

24

industry heterogeneity, to different methods to construct awarded and benchmarked

unawarded firms, and in different factor models.

Overall, our findings collectively support a role of product awards in asset pricing:

product awards enable firms to commercialize its growth opportunities in the high-end

markets, and such a shift in product market segmentation leads to higher systematic risk

that requires higher expected stock returns as risk premium.

Page 26: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

25

References

Abel, Andrew B, and Janice C Eberly. 2011. "How q and cash flow affect investment without frictions:

An analytic explanation." The Review of Economic Studies no. 78 (4):1179-1200.

Aguerrevere, Felipe L. 2009. "Real options, product market competition, and asset returns." The Journal

of Finance no. 64 (2):957-983.

Ai, Hengjie, and Dana Kiku. 2013. "Growth to value: option exercise and the cross section of equity

returns." Journal of Financial Economics no. 107 (2):325-349.

Ait‐Sahalia, Yacine, Jonathan A Parker, and Motohiro Yogo. 2004. "Luxury goods and the equity

premium." The Journal of Finance no. 59 (6):2959-3004.

Berk, Jonathan B., Richard C. Green, and Vasant Naik. 1999. "Optimal investment, growth options, and

security returns." The Journal of Finance no. 54 (5):1553-1607.

Bloom, Nicholas, and John Van Reenen. 2002. "Patents, real options and firm performance." Economic

Journal no. 112 (478):C97–C116.

Carhart, Mark M. 1997. "On persistence in mutual fund performance." The Journal of Finance no. 52

(1):57-82.

Carlson, Murray, Adlai Fisher, and Ron Giammarino. 2004. "Corporate investment and asset price

dynamics: implications for the cross‐section of returns." The Journal of Finance no. 59

(6):2577-2603.

Chan, Louis K. C., Josef Lakonishok, and Theodore Sougiannis. 2001. "The stock market valuation of

research and development expenditures." The Journal of Finance no. 56 (6):2431-2456.

Chen, I‐Ju, Po-Hsuan Hsu, Micah S Officer, and Yanzhi Wang. 2017. "The Oscar goes to…: takeovers

and innovation envy." Working Paper.

Daniel, Kent, Mark Grinblatt, Sheridan Titman, and Russ Wermers. 1997. "Measuring mutual fund

performance with characteristic-based benchmarks." The Journal of Finance no. 52 (3):1035-

1058.

Deng, Zhen, Baruch Lev, and Francis Narin. 1999. "Science and technology as predictors of stock

performance." Financial Analysts Journal no. 55 (3):20-32.

Fama, Eugene F, and Kenneth R French. 1993. "Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds."

Journal of Financial Economics no. 33 (1):3-56.

———. 1995. "Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns." The Journal of Finance no. 50

(1):131-155.

———. 2015. "Incremental variables and the investment opportunity set." Journal of Financial

Economics no. 117 (3):470-488.

———. 2017. "International tests of a five-factor asset pricing model." Journal of Financial Economics

no. 123 (3):441-463.

Garleanu, Nicolae, Stavros Panageas, and Jianfeng Yu. 2012. "Technological growth and asset pricing."

The Journal of Finance no. 67 (4):1265-1292.

Gomes, Joao, Leonid Kogan, and Lu Zhang. 2003. "Equilibrium cross section of returns." Journal of

Political Economy no. 111 (4).

Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell. 2001. "Long-run implication of investment-specific

technological change." American Economic Review no. 87 (3).

Hoberg, Gerard, and Gordon M. Phillips. 2012. "The stock market, product uniqueness, and comovement

of peer firms." Working Paper.

Hobijn, Bart, and Boyan Jovanovic. 2001. "The information-technology revolution and the stock market:

Page 27: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

26

evidence." American Economic Review no. 91 (5).

Hou, Kewei, and David T. Robinson. 2006. "Industry concentration and average stock returns." The

Journal of Finance no. 61 (4):1927–1956.

Hsu, Po-Hsuan. 2009. "Technological innovations and aggregate risk premiums." Journal of Financial

Economics no. 94 (2):264-279.

Kogan, Leonid. 2004. "Asset prices and real investment." Journal of Financial Economics no. 73

(3):411-431.

Kogan, Leonid, and Dimitris Papanikolaou. 2014. "Growth opportunities, technology shocks, and asset

prices." The Journal of Finance no. 69 (2):675-718.

Kogan, Leonid, Dimitris Papanikolaou, Amit Seru, and Noah Stoffman. 2017. "Technological innovation,

resource allocation, and growth." The Quarterly Journal of Economics no. 132 (2):665-712.

Laitner, John, and Dmitriy Stolyarov. 2003. "Technological change and the stock market." The American

Economic Review no. 93 (4):1240-1267.

Lambert, Marie, Boris Fays, and Georges Hubner. 2016. "Size and value matter, but not the way you

thought." Working Paper.

Lambert, Marie, and Georges Hubner. 2013. "Comoment risk and stock returns." Journal of Empirical

Finance no. 23:191-205.

Lev, Baruch, and Theodore Sougiannis. 1996. "The capitalization, amortization, and value-relevance of

R&D." Journal of Accounting & Economics no. 21 (1):107-138.

Lin, Xiaoji. 2012. "Endogenous technological progress and the cross-section of stock returns." Journal

of Financial Economics no. 103 (2):411-427.

Pakes, Ariel. 1985. "On patents, R&D, and the stock market rate of return." Journal of Political Economy

no. 93 (2):390-409.

Papanikolaou, Dimitris. 2011. "Investment shocks and asset prices." Journal of Political Economy no.

119 (4):639-685.

Pastor, Lubos, and Pietro Veronesi. 2009. "Learning in financial markets." Annu. Rev. Financ. Econ. no.

1 (1):361-381.

Verhoeven, Dennis, Jurriën Bakker, and Reinhilde Veugelers. 2016. "Measuring technological novelty

with patent-based indicators." Research Policy no. 45 (3):707-723.

Zhang, Lu. 2005. "The value premium." The Journal of Finance no. 60 (1):67-103.

Zhou, Tong. 2017. "Medical innovation, labor productivity, and the cross section of stock returns."

Working Paper.

Page 28: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

27

Tables

Table 1: Summary Statistics of Industrial Design Awards

We manually collect awarding information of R&D 100 Award, one of the most prestigious international design competitions. The original sampling period for R&D

100 Award ranges from 1965 to 2014. By matching Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code in the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP), we merge data

of awardees with all other public firms in the United States. We restrict to stocks with Fama-French 12-industries (FF12) classification. We also adopt the characteristic-

based sorting method proposed by Daniel, Grinblatt, Titman, and Wermers (DGTW) (1997) to identify comparable benchmark firms to the awarded firms - matched

unawarded firms are selected if they are in the same FF12 industry and the same quintiles of market capitalization, book-to-market ratio, and momentum by the end of

each fiscal year. Considering that the effect of the award on the firm may last for several years, we further define a firm as awarded if it receives at least one award in

the previous five years. After applying the same approach of data processing, the sampling interval for matched R&D 100 Award is 1969 - 2014. Panel A summarizes

the basic statistics of five-year matched sample. Awarded #, Unawarded #, Total # report the average of annual count of firms in each group. Annual Awarded/Unawarded

and Annual Awarded/Unawarded by Industry report the statistics of the ratio of awardees to non-awardees. Panel B compares the median values of indicators between

awarded and unawarded group. Data are collected from matched firms’ annual balance sheets and income statements. Several characteristics are considered: Market

Capitalization (Size, in billions), Book-to-market Ratio (B/M), Momentum (MOM, in percentages), Total Assets (in millions), R&D-to-total asset ratio (R&D Intensity),

Net Sales (Sales, in in millions), Profit Margins, which is defined as net income divided by net sales, and Cash Holdings, which is computed as cash and short-term

investments scalded by net sales.

Panel A: Five-year Computed Measures

Mean Median Std dev. Mean Median Std dev.

57 258 315 0.24 0.23 0.07 0.51 0.33 0.49

Panel B: Characteristics of Awarded Firms vs. Unawarded Firms

Group Market Cap B/M Momentum Total Assets R&D Intensity Sales Profit Margins Cash Holdings

Unawarded 944.87 0.59 9.64 705.87 0.04 749.16 0.05 0.06

Awarded 954.21 0.62 8.83 827.37 0.06 927.61 0.05 0.06

Awarded # Unawarded # Total #Annual Awarded/Unawarded Annual Awarded/Unawarded by Industry

Page 29: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

28

Table 2: Future Product Market Performances and Awarding Outcomes

By the end of fiscal year t, we identify awarded firms and their unawarded matched counterparts following the method elaborated in Table 1. From Panel A to Panel G,

we respectively examine the impacts of awarding outcome on seven measures of future product market performance: Gross Profit Margin, which is a profitability ratio

calculated by the difference between sales and the cost of the goods sold (COGS) divided by the sales; Net Sales (Sales), Costs of Selling, General, and Administration

(SG&A), Advertising Expenditures, R&D Expenditures, and Capital Expenditures (Capex) are all scaled by total assets; Cash Holdings, which is a liquidity ratio

defined as cash and short-term investments divided by sales. For each variable, we consider the arithmetic average of its future five-year values from year t+1 to t+5

as dependent variable, and use the corresponding lagged value in year t as independent variable. We employ different specifications of firm-level panel regressions to

test the award influence by further considering the following control variables at year t: market capitalization (Size, in hundred trillions); book-to-market ratio (B/M);

12-month momentum factor with one month reversal (MOM). Numbers without parentheses report parameter estimates, and numbers with parentheses show robust t-

values clustered by industry and year. ***, **, and * indicate the significance level of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively.

Page 30: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

29

(Table 2 continued)

Panel A: Gross Profit Margin

Gross Profit Margin (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

0.01* 0.01** 0.02*** 0.02*** 0.01** 0.02*** 0.02*** 0.03***

(1.71) (2.30) (3.73) (4.25) (2.35) (2.93) (4.29) (4.93)

0.10*** 0.09*** 0.08*** 0.08*** 0.09*** 0.08*** 0.08*** 0.07***

(13.87) (13.59) (11.28) (11.26) (12.39) (11.86) (10.50) (10.32)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.04** -0.02 -0.02 0.01

---- ---- ---- ---- (-2.50) (-0.94) (-1.23) (0.33)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.05*** -0.06*** -0.03*** -0.05***

---- ---- ---- ---- (-9.72) (-12.54) (-5.36) (-8.34)

---- ---- ---- ---- 0.00 0.00 -0.00 -0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (0.14) (0.06) (-0.55) (-0.36)

Observations 2,729 2,729 2,636 2,636 2,689 2,689 2,599 2,599

R-squared 0.07 0.11 0.28 0.31 0.10 0.15 0.29 0.33

Year FE NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES

Industry FE NO NO YES YES NO NO YES YES

Momentum (MOM)

Awarded

Lagged Gross Profit Margin

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Page 31: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

30

(Table 2 continued)

Panel B: Sales

Sales/Total Assets (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

0.04*** 0.05*** 0.04*** 0.05*** 0.04*** 0.04*** 0.04*** 0.04***

(3.02) (4.06) (4.09) (5.05) (3.36) (3.96) (4.08) (4.73)

0.73*** 0.69*** 0.66*** 0.63*** 0.72*** 0.70*** 0.66*** 0.64***

(38.15) (36.02) (38.94) (39.00) (36.62) (34.87) (39.92) (38.48)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.06** -0.01 -0.04* 0.01

---- ---- ---- ---- (-2.12) (-1.78) (-0.38) (0.75)

---- ---- ---- ---- 0.08*** 0.06*** 0.05*** 0.03***

---- ---- ---- ---- (5.60) (5.70) (4.01) (3.12)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.05*** -0.03** -0.04*** -0.02

---- ---- ---- ---- (-3.24) (-2.27) (-3.09) (-1.55)

Observations 3,032 3,032 2,943 2,943 2,987 2,987 2,900 2,900

R-squared 0.60 0.65 0.67 0.70 0.62 0.62 0.68 0.68

Year FE NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES

Industry FE NO NO YES YES NO NO YES YES

Momentum (MOM)

Lagged Sales/Total Assets

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Awarded

Page 32: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

31

(Table 2 continued)

Panel C: Costs of Selling, General, and Administration

SG&A/Total Assets (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

0.01* 0.02*** 0.02*** 0.02*** 0.02** 0.02*** 0.02*** 0.02***

(1.84) (3.12) (3.29) (3.95) (2.42) (3.25) (3.46) (4.14)

0.70*** 0.73*** 0.67*** 0.69*** 0.72*** 0.73*** 0.68*** 0.69***

(24.34) (24.16) (18.48) (20.82) (26.22) (24.61) (19.78) (20.57)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.07*** -0.02** -0.03** 0.01

---- ---- ---- ---- (-3.90) (-2.31) (-2.53) (1.00)

---- ---- ---- ---- 0.02*** -0.00 0.01*** -0.01*

---- ---- ---- ---- (3.33) (-0.07) (3.47) (-1.85)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.02** -0.02*** -0.01 -0.01

---- ---- ---- ---- (-2.31) (-3.07) (-1.37) (-1.58)

Observations 2,510 2,510 2,427 2,427 2,471 2,471 2,391 2,391

R-squared 0.57 0.57 0.65 0.70 0.60 0.60 0.66 0.71

Year FE NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES

Industry FE NO NO YES YES NO NO YES YES

Awarded

Momentum (MOM)

Lagged SG&A/Total Assets

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Page 33: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

32

(Table 2 continued)

Panel D: Advertising Expenditures

Advertising/Total Assets (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

0.002** 0.002*** 0.002* 0.002** 0.002* 0.002* 0.002** 0.002**

(2.28) (2.76) (1.90) (2.20) (2.72) (2.72) (2.03) (2.23)

0.82*** 0.82*** 0.82*** 0.82*** 0.81*** 0.81*** 0.82*** 0.82***

(19.39) (18.62) (18.37) (17.74) (19.08) (17.98) (17.57) (16.93)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.00** -0.00 -0.00 0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (-2.48) (-0.82) (-0.33) (1.16)

---- ---- ---- ---- 0.00* 0.00 0.00 -0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (1.93) (0.69) (1.12) (-0.13)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.00* -0.00** 0.00 0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (-1.77) (-2.18) (0.12) (0.11)

Observations 1,078 1,077 1,005 1,005 1,059 1,058 986 986

R-squared 0.79 0.80 0.84 0.84 0.78 0.78 0.83 0.83

Year FE NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES

Industry FE NO NO YES YES NO NO YES YES

Awarded

Momentum (MOM)

Lagged Advertising/Total Assets

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Page 34: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

33

(Table 2 continued)

Panel E: R&D Expenditures

R&D/Total Assets (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

0.005*** 0.005*** 0.006*** 0.006*** 0.005*** 0.005*** 0.006*** 0.006***

(3.20) (2.98) (4.16) (4.14) (3.24) (3.02) (4.03) (4.02)

0.68*** 0.71*** 0.60*** 0.61*** 0.69*** 0.71*** 0.60*** 0.60***

(6.46) (6.29) (4.56) (4.63) (6.22) (6.18) (4.37) (4.43)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.00** -0.00 -0.00 0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (-2.05) (-0.36) (-1.34) (0.67)

---- ---- ---- ---- 0.00 -0.00 0.00 -0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (0.91) (-0.36) (0.09) (-1.33)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.00 -0.00 -0.00 -0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (-0.68) (-0.55) (-0.16) (-0.21)

Observations 1,244 1,244 1,187 1,187 1,239 1,239 1,182 1,182

R-squared 0.64 0.65 0.73 0.74 0.64 0.65 0.73 0.75

Year FE NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES

Industry FE NO NO YES YES NO NO YES YES

Momentum (MOM)

Awarded

Lagged R&D/Total Assets

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Page 35: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

34

(Table 2 continued)

Panel F: Capital Expenditures

Capex/Total Assets (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

0.006*** 0.007*** 0.005*** 0.006*** 0.007*** 0.007*** 0.005*** 0.006***

(4.84) (6.36) (3.94) (5.24) (5.48) (6.39) (4.32) (12.16)

0.42*** 0.39*** 0.35*** 0.33*** 0.43*** 0.39*** 0.35*** 0.34***

(13.96) (13.96) (13.14) (12.45) (14.24) (13.76) (13.36) (12.16)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.00* 0.01*** -0.01** 0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (-1.95) (2.71) (-2.13) (1.47)

---- ---- ---- ---- 0.01*** -0.00 0.01*** 0.00**

---- ---- ---- ---- (4.27) (-0.52) (5.83) (2.22)

---- ---- ---- ---- 0.00 0.00* -0.00 0.00

---- ---- ---- ---- (1.42) (1.75) (-1.18) (0.30)

Observations 2,989 2,989 2,899 2,899 2,944 2,944 2,856 2,856

R-squared 0.33 0.43 0.48 0.54 0.35 0.44 0.50 0.55

Year FE NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES

Industry FE NO NO YES YES NO NO YES YES

Momentum (MOM)

Lagged Capex/Total Assets

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Awarded

Page 36: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

35

(Table 2 continued)

Panel G: Cash Holdings

Cash Holdings (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

-0.08** -0.08*** -0.06*** -0.06*** -0.08*** -0.08*** -0.06*** -0.06***

(-2.59) (-3.18) (-3.08) (-3.83) (-2.73) (-3.12) (-3.07) (-3.62)

0.11*** 0.10*** 0.10*** 0.10*** 0.11*** 0.10*** 0.10*** 0.10***

(4.64) (4.84) (5.53) (5.79) (4.78) (4.95) (5.56) (5.76)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.02 -0.12*** 0.04 -0.02

---- ---- ---- ---- (-0.63) (-3.05) (1.53) (-0.67)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.06 0.01 -0.04 0.01

---- ---- ---- ---- (-1.18) (0.10) (-0.62) (0.07)

---- ---- ---- ---- -0.01 -0.01 0.01 0.01

---- ---- ---- ---- (-0.24) (-0.22) (0.88) (0.96)

Observations 3,026 3,026 2,936 2,936 2,983 2,983 2,895 2,895

R-squared 0.06 0.08 0.13 0.14 0.06 0.08 0.13 0.15

Year FE NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES

Industry FE NO NO YES YES NO NO YES YES

Momentum (MOM)

Lagged Cash Holdings

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Awarded

Page 37: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

36

Table 3: R&D Investments and the Probability of Winning Awards

We include the whole universe of public firms and run logistic or probit regressions to test the relation between R&D investments and the future probability of being

awarded. The dependent variable is a dummy variable indicating whether the focal firm receives the award in year t+1, and the key explanatory variable of interest is

the Average R&D Investment, which denotes the arithmetic average of R&D expenditure scaled by total assets during the previous five years from t-4 to t. Other firm

characteristics are also controlled at year t: market capitalization (Size, in hundred millions); book-to-market ratio (B/M); 12-month momentum factor with one month

reversal (MOM). Numbers without parentheses report parameter estimates, and numbers with parentheses show robust t-values. ***, **, and * indicate the significance

level of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively.

(1) (2) (1) (2)

0.63*** 0.85*** 0.33*** 0.43***

(6.32) (5.26) (6.87) (5.63)

---- 1.38*** ---- 0.73***

---- (18.55) ---- (20.13)

---- -0.37*** ---- -0.12***

---- (-6.81) ---- (-6.38)

---- -0.04 ---- -0.01

---- (-0.87) ---- (-0.86)

-5.35*** -4.85*** -2.60*** -2.44***

(-198.69) (-98.27) (-278.86) (-136.79)

Observations 295,042 189,946 295,042 189,946

R-squared 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.03

Log Likelihood -8977.10 -7218.48 -8972.22 -7180.72

AwardedLogistic

Average R&D Investment

Market Capitalization (Size)

Book-to-Market Ratio (B/M)

Momentum (MOM)

Constant

Probit

Page 38: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

37

Table 4: One-Way Portfolio Sorting

By the end of fiscal year t-1, we identify awarded firms and their unawarded matched counterparts following the method elaborated in Table 1. We then construct an

awarded-minus-unawarded (AMU) portfolio by going long in the awarded portfolio and going short in the unawarded portfolio, and allow it to perform from July of

year t to June of year t+1. We compute and compare the equally-weighted monthly returns for both the awarded portfolio and the unawarded portfolio, since the firms

in the awarded portfolio are highly comparable with the firms in the unawarded portfolio in firm size. Specifically, to compute the monthly return of the awarded

portfolio, we average the monthly stock returns of the awarded firms, and to calculate the monthly return of the (matched) unawarded portfolio, we first average the

monthly stock returns of the unawarded firms matched to the same awarded firm and then average these matched monthly returns across all awarded firms. To test the

statistical significance of abnormal returns adjusted for the exposure to risk factors, we regress the monthly returns in excess of risk-free interest rate (Excess return)

on the following risk factors. The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) simply considers the market factor (MKT). The three-factor model of Fama and French (1993)

(FF3) includes MKT, the size factor (SMB), and the value factor (HML). Carhart (1997) four-factor model (FF4) takes into account MKT, SMB, HML, and the

momentum factor (UMD). The five-factor extension in Fama and French (2015) (FF5) captures the patterns of MKT, SMB, HML, the profitability factor (RMW), and

the investment factor (CMA). Fama and French (2017) six-factor model (FF6) uses MKT, SMB, HML, RMW, CMA, and UMD. Besides, we also extend the FF3, FF5,

and FF6 models by adding an R&D factor, where this extra factor is constructed following Chan, Lakonishok, and Sougiannis (2001). Numbers without parentheses

report parameter estimate of excess return and their corresponding alphas, and numbers with parentheses show t-values. ***, **, and * indicate the significance level

of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. All estimates are in percentage.

Excess return CAPM FF3 FF4 FF5 FF6FF3

+R&D factor

FF5

+R&D factor

FF6

+R&D factor

1.10*** 0.38*** 0.29*** 0.37*** 0.35*** 0.41*** 0.26*** 0.30*** 0.34***

(3.89) (2.72) (2.79) (3.53) (3.33) (3.89) (2.70) (2.99) (3.43)

0.84*** 0.12 0.00 0.18** 0.03 0.17** -0.01 0.01 0.14*

(3.09) (1.03) (0.06) (2.52) (0.39) (2.32) (-0.14) (0.01) (1.93)

0.26*** 0.26*** 0.28*** 0.19** 0.32*** 0.24** 0.27*** 0.29*** 0.20**

(2.86) (2.88) (3.08) (2.05) (3.36) (2.58) (2.99) (3.16) (2.24)

Awarded

Unawarded

Awarded-Unawarded

Page 39: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

38

Table 5: Two-Way Portfolio Sorting

In Panel A, we conduct sequential sort to examine the awarded-minus-unawarded spread across different subgroups of R&D investment. By the end of fiscal year t-1,

we identify awarded firms and their unawarded matched counterparts following the method elaborated in Table 1. In both awarded and unawarded groups, firms with

non-missing value of R&D investments are further sorted into three subgroups based on its tertiles (e.g., we separate firms into low, medium, and high group using the

30th and 70th percentiles) in year t-1. We consider the R&D expense over total assets as an indicator of R&D investments. In Panel B, we examine the return spread of

awarded-minus-unawarded portfolio in crisis and non-crisis periods. The recessions are defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) to proxy for

periods of low aggregate consumption, which covers a period from the peak to the trough of business cycle. For each subgroup, we construct an awarded-minus-

unawarded (AMU) portfolio by going long in the awarded portfolio and going short in the unawarded portfolio, and allow it to perform from July of year t to June of

year t+1. We compute and compare the equally-weighted monthly returns for both the awarded portfolio and the unawarded portfolio, since the firms in the awarded

portfolio are highly comparable with the firms in the unawarded portfolio in firm size. To test the statistical significance of abnormal returns adjusted for the exposure

to risk factors, we regress the monthly returns in excess of risk-free interest rate (Excess return) on the following risk factors. The capital asset pricing model (CAPM)

simply considers the market factor (MKT). The three-factor model of Fama and French (1993) (FF3) includes MKT, the size factor (SMB), and the value factor (HML).

The five-factor extension in Fama and French (2015) (FF5) captures the patterns of MKT, SMB, HML, the profitability factor (RMW), and the investment factor

(CMA). Fama and French (2017) six-factor model (FF6) uses MKT, SMB, HML, RMW, CMA, and UMD. Numbers without parentheses report parameter estimate of

excess return and their corresponding alphas, and numbers with parentheses show t-values. ***, **, and * indicate the significance level of 1%, 5%, and 10%,

respectively. All estimates are in percentage.

Page 40: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

39

(Table 5 continued)

Panel A: High vs. Low R&D Investments

Excess return CAPM FF3 FF5 FF6

0.91*** 1.01*** 0.10 0.14 0.07 -0.07 -0.13

(3.30) (3.73) (0.67) (0.94) (0.52) (-0.46) (-0.88)

0.96** 1.56*** 0.60*** 0.60** 0.58** 0.71*** 0.55**

(2.45) (3.61) (2.60) (2.57) (2.48) (2.92) (2.29)

0.04 0.55 0.51* 0.47* 0.51* 0.78*** 0.68**

(0.18) (1.62) (1.88) (1.71) (1.91) (2.84) (2.47)

Panel B: Non-crisis vs. Crisis Periods

Excess return CAPM α FF3 α FF5 α FF6 α

1.15** 1.28** 0.13 0.13 0.10 0.12 0.12

(2.08) (2.26) (0.86) (0.89) (0.64) (0.70) (0.71)

0.69** 1.01*** 0.32*** 0.32*** 0.39*** 0.41*** 0.29***

(2.28) (3.17) (2.83) (2.83) (3.41) (3.61) (2.61)Non-crisis

Crisis \ Award Unawarded AwardedAwarded-Unawarded

Crisis

AwardedAwarded-Unawarded

Low

High

High-Low

Xrd \ Award Unawarded

Page 41: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

40

Figures

Figure 1: Industry Distribution of Awarding Outcome

This figure graphs the industry distribution and time-series variation of the awarding outcomes of the R&D 100 Award. The Fama-French 12 industries are defined in

the following twelve categories: (1) Consumer Non-Durables (NoDur); (2) Consumer Durables (Durbl); (3) Manufacturing (Manuf); (4) Energy (Enrgy); (5) Chemicals

(Chems); (6) Business Equipment (BusEq); (7) Telecom (Telcm); (8) Utilities (Utils); (9) Shops; (10) Health (Hlth); (11) Money ; (12) Other. The original sampling

period ranges from 1965 to 2014. Panel A exhibits the full-sample industry distribution of the awarding outcomes. The numbers imply the proportions (in percentages)

of awards received by these industries. Panel B separately displays the time-series line charts of annual awarding outcomes of total U.S. awardees and four selected

industries, which takes up the largest share. The vertical axis suggests the industry awarded share, where the percentage is computed as the number of awarded firms

in specific industry divided by the total number of awarded firms in the same year.

Page 42: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

41

(Figure 1 continued)

Panel A: Average Awarding Outcomes of FF12 Industries

Page 43: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

42

(Figure 1 continued)

Panel B: Annual Awarding Outcomes of Selected FF12 Industries

Page 44: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

43

Figure 2: Performance of Long-short Strategy along Sample Years

The curve plots the total cumulative returns of our long-short strategy exploiting the awarded-minus-unawarded spread in Table 4 starting from July 1970 to June 2014.

The total cumulative return is presented in percentages and defined as: 𝑅𝑛 = (1 + 𝑟1) ∙ (1 + 𝑟2) ∙ ⋯ ∙ (1 + 𝑟𝑛). The overlay recession bands correspond to the U.S.

recession periods defined by the NBER. For example, the last gray bar starting from Dec 2007 to June 2009 denotes the “Great Recession” period.

Page 45: What Follows Innovation Awards? R&D 100 Awards, …fmaconferences.org/SanDiego/Papers/RD100_Complete.pdfR&D 100 Awards, Product Segmentation, and Stock Returns January 12, 2018 Abstract:

44

Figure 3: Five-year Cumulative Performance by Portfolio Month

Panel A plots the cumulative returns of the investments in both the awarded and unawarded portfolios constructed in Table 4 over a five-year horizon, and Panel B

represents the total cumulative returns of long-short strategy over the same period. To trace the five-year portfolio performance, we set up the sequence of from M1 to

M60 to denote the portfolio month from July of year t (formation of the portfolios) to June of year t+5. The total cumulative return is defined as: 𝑅𝑛 = (1 + 𝑟1) ∙ (1 +

𝑟2) ∙ ⋯ ∙ (1 + 𝑟𝑛). Cumulative returns are presented in percentages.