25

Click here to load reader

users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Chapter 14: Shareholder Voting

Additional reading

When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase price was exorbitant. So who was responsible for this decision? Facebook is a uniquely structured corporation, with Mark Zuckerberg—the founder—retaining 57% of the voting rights of the company. Although Zuckerberg owns far less than a majority of the outstanding shares, he previously purchased the voting proxy from other investors to give him majority control. As a result, he has a decisive say in the future of Facebook.

Chapter 15: Shareholder Information Rights

Scavenger hunt -

To give you a sense for how voting works in a public corporation, I’ve chosen the 2014 annual shareholders meeting of GE.  Please look through the questions in the attached “scavenger hunt” to get a sense for the “proxy materials” used by GE for the meeting.  

 Here are the documents you’ll be looking through:o Proxy statement (for 2014 annual meeting)  [pdf]o Proxy card (for 2014 annual meeting) [pdf]o Annual report (FY 2013)  [pdf]

In addition, you’ll find in interesting to browse the information available on the GE "investor relations" website (typical of public corporations) and the voting results of the 2014 GE shareholders’ meeting:

o Investor Relations - Financial Reporting o Voting results (4-23-14 annual meeing) / SEC Form 8-K (4-28-14)

Happy scavenging!

Overview

This chapter introduces you to --

how shareholders obtain corporate information under state law – namely, state inspection statutes -- to facilitate their voting and to exercise their other shareholder rights

disclosure by the corporation to voting shareholders as required under both state law and the federal proxy regime

the elements of proxy fraud actions:o the implied federal proxy fraud action (including the elements of materiality,

culpability, reliance/causation, damages)o the state-based duty of disclosure and how it compares to the federal duty

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Page 2: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Inspection rights cover the mundane (names of directors and officers), somewhat interesting (shareholder lists) and really useful (books and records about corporate business/affairs)

Stockholders (record or beneficial) can seek to inspect books and records upon meeting certain procedural requirements

o must make written request under oatho with proper purpose (DGCL 220)o often subject to confidentiality stipulationo must be "long" (not necessarily "net long")

Proper purpose must relate to a shareholder's financial interest in corporationo must articulate some vote, voice, sue, sell - agenda to advance SWMo other purposes can exist (according to Delaware courts)o non-SWM purpose of antiwar activist is not valid (Pillsbury v. Honeywell case)

Shareholder ownership / record listo in public corporations, stock held by intermediary DTC (CEDE)o clients of brokerage firms must not object to being revealed to managemento inspecting shareholder receives list of ownership only if management already has

them Federal law, specifically SEC rules, requires that any solicitation of shareholders in a

public company must include a disclosure document called a “proxy statement” o A “public company,” under SEC rules, is a company that has a class of securities

listed on a stock exchange, or has a class of equity securities owned by 500 or more holders of record and assets of at least $10 million.

Public companies are prohibited under SEC Rule § 14a-9 from making “false or misleading statements” in a proxy statement

o Federal courts have fashioned an implied private right of action under Rule § 14a-9, on the theory that the SEC cannot review every proxy statement to ensure its accuracy. [see Virginia Bankshares, Inc. v. Sandberg]

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

DGCL § 220 Securities Exchange Act of 1934 §14(a) Securities Exchange Act of 1934 §12(b), (g) Securities Exchange Act of 1934 §14a-9

Chapter 16: Public Shareholder Activism

Overview

This chapter introduces you to --

various theories explaining the role of shareholders in a public corporation – given the separation of ownership and control in such corporations

various phenomena in the modern public corporation affecting shareholder activism, including the prisoner’s dilemma and deretailization

shareholder voting procedures in public corporations (including reimbursement of expenses and shareholder communications) and the increasing role of institutional shareholders

Page 3: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

the SEC shareholder proposal rule, its operations, and its substantive exclusions

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Public shareholders exercise their role by voting on board nominees, board-approved initiatives, and shareholder proposals

Shareholder activism is becoming increasingly institutionalized with large institutional investors having the loudest voice, hence control, over the corporation

A corporation may be required to reimburse the expenses of an insurgency proxy voteo Reimbursement for incumbent directors, if grounded in a policy questiono Reimbursement for a successful insurgency, if voted on by shareholderso Modern movement toward reimbursement regardless of insurgency outcome

Federal regulations limit corporate free speech to prevent influencing shareholder voting—depending on the relationship of the speaker to the corporation, such speech may be considered a proxy solicitation

The shareholder proposal rule, SEC Rule § 14a-8, allows any shareholder who meets the ownership requirements, and who properly formats his proposal and submits it before the deadline, to have a proposal included in the company’s proxy materials for a vote at the shareholders’ annual meeting.

o To be eligible to submit a shareholder proposal, a person must have continuously held at least 1% or $2,000 worth of the company’s voting shares for at least one year. The shareholder must then continue to hold the shares and present the proposal at the meeting.

o The shareholder proposal cannot exceed 500 words, and must be submitted to the company not less than 120 calendar days before the date of the company’s last-year proxy statement

o SEC Rule § 14a-8(i) provides thirteen substantive grounds whereby a company can lawfully exclude a shareholder proposal from its proxy materials.

o If the company fails to include a shareholder proposal in its proxy materials, it must notify the SEC by filing the proposal and the company’s reasons for exclusion. If the SEC, upon review, determines that this exclusion is appropriate it will issue a “no action” letter. If the SEC determines that the exclusion is not appropriate, it may pursue an enforcement action against the company.

Additional reading

You can see how voting works:

Is corporate voting strained like political voting (see the 2000 presidential election in Florida)? There are signs the corporate proxy system may not be up to the task of dealing with custodial ownership, high trading volumes by dispersed owners, and short selling/derivatives. Is an overhaul necessary to make the system more efficient and transparent? {more >>>]

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

Page 4: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Securities Exchange Act of 1934 §14a-1 Securities Exchange Act of 1934 §14a-8

Chapter 17: Shareholder Litigation

Overview

This chapter introduces you to --

the basic right of shareholders to sue and initiate litigation (this is one of the three major rights of shareholders: vote, sue, sell)

the two basic types of shareholder litigation: derivative and direct the requirements to qualify as a shareholder plaintiff: adequacy and standing the policy considerations that arise and make shareholder litigation a controversial issue

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Shareholders have a right to sue and initiate shareholder litigation; this type of lawsuit may be derivative or direct.

o Derivative—the lawsuit is brought by the shareholder on behalf of the corporation in which he is a stockholder, to assert rights belonging to the corporation.

o Direct—the lawsuit is brought by the shareholder on his own behalf, to assert a violation of his rights.

There are special considerations for derivative lawsuits that do not apply to direct lawsuits.

o Demand requirement—in a derivative lawsuit the plaintiff is required, pursuant to F.R.C.P. 23.1, to “allege with particularity the efforts, if any, made by the plaintiff to obtain the action plaintiff desires from the directors.” If the court decides that this demand requirement is not met then the case is dismissed. [Note: pleading “demand futility” is no longer a valid way of satisfying the demand requirement; see Aronson]

o SLC (special litigation committee)—a committee formed on behalf of the corporation to offer a recommendation to the court of how to respond to a derivative lawsuit. The SLC is made up of independent persons (typically independent directors not named as parties, as well as hired lawyers and advisors). More often than not the SLC recommends that the case be dismissed.

o The standard of review for the recommendation that the SLC makes to the court may be the lenient business judgment rule (Auerbach) or a heightened standard of review (Zapata).

In order to initiate a shareholder lawsuit, the party must satisfy the adequacy and standing requirements.

o Adequacy—the plaintiff must be capable of adequately and fairly representing the interests of the shareholders in a direct lawsuit or the corporation in a derivative lawsuit.

o Standing—in order to have standing in a lawsuit, a party must have suffered an injury. In a derivative lawsuit, the injury is alleged on behalf of the corporation, and standing is limited to those with an equity interest in the corporation, which is determined on the basis of three factors: the nature of the holding, timing, and the plaintiff’s countervailing interests.

Page 5: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

There are several policy issues that make shareholder litigation a controversial topic:o Agency costs of litigation—the plaintiffs’ attorney typically has a much greater

financial stake than any individual shareholder in the outcome of the litigation, and collective action problems limit the ability of shareholders to effectively act in concert.

o Challenges of settlements—because plaintiffs’ attorneys typically work on a contingent fee basis, they may have an incentive to settle rather than go to trial. In some lawsuits the best interests of the shareholders may be served by going to trial. Ultimately, it is up to the court to approve the fairness of any settlement.

o Attorneys’ fees—the prevailing party in shareholder litigation is typically not entitled to attorneys’ fees, but when attorneys’ fees are appropriate the attorneys may have a financial incentive either to settle the case more rapidly or to prolong the litigation depending upon how this award is calculated.

Additional reading

In April 2013, News Corp. agreed to the largest ever settlement in a derivative lawsuit: $139 million. The lawsuit alleged that Rupert Murdoch turned a blind eye to criminal activity within News Corp., and used the corporation to “pursue his quest for power, control and political gain and to enrich himself and his family members, at the Company’s and its public shareholders’ expense.”

Rules

These rules are relevant:

F.R.C.P. 23 F.R.C.P. 23.1

Chapter 18: Board Decision Making

Overview

This chapter --

considers the operation of the business judgment rule and justifications for the policy of judicial abstention

reviews Shlensky v. Wrigley, an iconic case that applied the business judgment rule in the context of a baseball team’s unprofitable decision

analyzes Smith v. Van Gorkom, a landmark case that addressed the fiduciary duties owed in the context of a merger decision that was purportedly uninformed

provides an overview of the ways that directors are insulated from personal liability: exculpation clauses, indemnification, D&O insurance

Summary

Page 6: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

The main points of the chapter are --

A board of directors has a fiduciary duty to act in an honest and informed manner, in good faith and without self dealing to promote the interests of corporation.

Despite this relatively straightforward requirement, directors have powerful defenses to claims that they violated the duty of care or the duty of loyalty.

Sklensky v. Wrigley illustrates the business judgment rule at work, which protects directors from liability for business decisions even when those decisions result in losses to the corporation.

Smith v. Van Gorkom, a landmark case, is essential reading for understanding how courts assess the actions of a board of directors, particularly with regard to the fiduciary requirement that a board decision is “informed.”

o DGCL§102(b)(7)—implemented by Delaware legislature in response Smith v. Van Gorkom, allows corporations to adopt charter provisions to insulate directors from personal liability for certain decisions.

There are three ways that directors can avoid liability for board decisions:o Exculpation—many states (including Delaware, see above §102(b)(7)) have

initiated legislation that allows a corporation to absolve directors of monetary liability for specific types of board decisions.

o Indemnification—the corporation is often allowed to directly pay for monetary damages that a director is held liable for, or to reimburse the director for his payment of these damages (this is also the case in Delaware; see §145). There are three types of indemnification: permissive (the corporation may indemnify the director), mandatory (the corporation must indemnify the director), and prohibited (the corporation cannot indemnify the director).

o D&O insurance—the corporation purchases insurance policies to cover any monetary damages it may owe as a result of prohibited conduct by a director/officer (for Delaware, see §145(g)).

Additional reading

When News Corp., in April 2013, agreed to the largest ever settlement in a derivative lawsuit, the entire settlement was entirely covered by D&O insurance. To some commentators, the fact that the underlying (perhaps egregious) conduct was insured raised serious issues for insurance companies providing D&O insurance.

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

MBCA § 8.30 DGCL § 102(b)(7) MBCA § 2.02(b)(4) DGCL § 145

Chapter 19: Board Oversight

Page 7: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Overview

This chapter --

introduces the “oversight” role of directors, particularly their responsibility in managing the financial and regulatory risks of the corporation

presents Francis v. United Jersey Bank, a “classic” case of director oversight in the context of a somewhat dysfunctional family-run corporation

dissects In re Caremark Litigation, a very important modern case that illustrates the complexities of director oversight

delves into Stone v. Ritter, a case that helped clarify the meaning of “good faith” action

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

A corporation’s shareholders delegate the power to manage and direct the corporation’s affairs to its directors; in turn, the directors delegate some of this power to the officers and employees of the corporation.

A key question that arises is how much are directors expected to do?o Standard of conduct—a director is generally expected to act in good faith, and in

a manner that he reasonably believes to be in the best interests of the corporation. When becoming informed of impending decisions or risks, he is expected to use the care that a like person in the same position would use.

Another major question is what is the standard that directors required to do, and when will they be held liable?

o Liability—a director may be held liable for failing to adequately discharge his responsibility of oversight. This liabilty often arises not because of an affirmative act, but rather as a result of a failure to act appropriately under the circumstances.

The application of these principles to the conduct of directors is often very fact specific, and the case law provides crucial precedents for scenarios involving (wrongful) delegation, (lack of) attentiveness, and (im)proper receipt of a financial benefit.

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

MBCA § 8.30 MBCA § 8.31 MBCA § 8.24 Sarbanes-Oxley 404

Page 8: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Chapter 20: Director Conflicts

Overview

This chapter --

provides an overview of the “traditional” duty of loyalty, which arises when a director enters into a transaction with the corporation and there is a risk of self-dealing

reviews statutory approaches to the duty of loyalty, along with the three factors that these statutes tend to focus on: board approval, shareholder approval, and fairness

introduces the corporate opportunity doctrine, which forbids a director, officer, or managerial employee from diverting a business opportunity that “belongs” to the corporation

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Contemporary statutes governing director interested transactions do not make such deals automatically invalid; rather, these statutes assume that a director may enter into a valid exchange with the corporation that does not violate the duty of loyalty

o Safe harbor—modern statutes often attempt to create certainty for directors entering into such transactions that certain actions cannot be successfully challenged as violating the duty of loyalty. [see MBCA Subchapter F; DGCL §144]

Director conflict statutes typically focus on three factors to determine if an improper director conflict exists:

o Fairness—for a potentially self-dealing transaction to be fair, the deal must be procedurally fair as well as well as substantively fair. Procedural fairness considers how the transaction was approved, the disclosure given to those making the decision, the ability of the directors to be objective, and the effect of

Page 9: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

shareholder ratification. Substantive fairness often has been distilled to a single question: “whether the proposition submitted would have commended itself to an independent corporation.”

o Board approval—a potentially self-dealing transaction must have been approved by “disinterested” and “independent” directors. A disinterested director is one who does not receive a material benefit as a result of the challenged transaction that is greater than what is received by other shareholders. An independent director is one whose decision did not result from his being controlled by another director.

o Shareholder approval—a potentially self-dealing transaction must be approved (or subsequently ratified) by disinterested shareholders, and the corporation must have disclosed to shareholders the material facts of the transaction and the director’s personal interest. When the interested directors are also majority shareholders in the corporation, additional complications will arise.

A director may violate the duty of loyalty through a transaction with a third party, if the transaction involves a corporate opportunity that “belonged” to the corporation

o Corporate opportunity doctrine—a director, officer, or managerial employee cannot take a business opportunity for himself that the corporation could financially undertake, is within the corporation’s line of business, is advantageous to the corporation, and is one in which the corporation had an interest or reasonable expectancy.

Additional reading

A recent decision in Illinois offers a clear-cut example of the corporate opportunity doctrine at work. The President of a steel company, Star Forge, secretly entered into employment and sales commission agreements with rival steel companies while still working for the company. Star Forge filed a lawsuit alleging that this was a subversion of corporate opportunities that belonged to the corporation. The trial court agreed, granting summary judgment to Star Forge and assessing $700,000 in damages. This decision was affirmed on appeal.

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

MBCA Subchapter F ALI Principles - Section 5.05 (Corporate Opportunities) DGCL § 144 DGCL § 122(17)

Chapter 21: Executive Compensation

Overview

This chapter --

Page 10: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

provides an overview of the methods by which executives are compensated tells the story of one case of executive compensation - Dennis Koslowsky of Tyco

International (be forewarned, the story ends sadly for Mr. Koslowsky) considers the federal and state law that applies to executive compensation describes the Disney litigation in which the Delaware courts outlined a duty of "good faith"

in board pay-setting decisions (the story ends happily for Mr. Ovitz, and perhaps sadly for Disney shareholders)

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Executive compensation presents an inherent conflict of interest for shareholders: they want corporate managers to be incentivized to work hard to maximize profits, but a higher level of executive compensation necessarily reduces the cash that can be distributed to shareholders.

The high level of executive compensation in relationship to average worker pay raises several important policy questions:

o What is “fair” pay for executives, and in what way should stock options be used to incentivize performance?

o What process should be used to determine executive pay? Both federal and state law governs executive compensation

o Federal law previously focused primarily on the disclosure of executive pay in public companies, but more recently has shifted focus to creating substantive rights for shareholders seeking to challenge executive pay. Federal law now prohibits public companies from giving loans to directors and executive officers, requires the disgorgement of executive pay when an executive misstated the company’s performance, allows shareholders the right to vote on “golden parachute” packages, requires the “clawback” of executive compensation for the three previous years if a public company is required to restate its financials, and requires a “say on pay” vote whereby shareholders in a public company have the right to an advisory vote on executive compensation.

o State law focuses primarily on the process for setting executive compensation, however the business judgment rule applies. When executive compensation is judicial reviewed, the standards of waste, care, and fairness govern the analysis.

Despite these checks on excessive compensation, the saga regarding Michael Ovitz’s severance package (Disney litigation) illustrates that executive compensation may be legally acceptable even when both the process for setting it and the substantive amount are less than ideal.

Additional reading

Executive compensation continues to soar, as a recent NY Times article titled “Executive Pay: Invasion of the Supersalaries” describes.

Statutes

Page 11: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

These statutes are relevant:

26 U.S.C. § 162(m) Securities Exchange Act § 13(k) Sarbanes-Oxley § 402 Sarbanes-Oxley § 304 15 U.S.C. § 7243

Chapter 23: Securities Markets

Overview

This chapter --

provides an overview of U.S. securities markets and the regulatory framework under federal law

describes the federal registration requirements for raising capital on public securities markets

outlines the exemptions from registration that permit private placements and small securities offerings

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Market efficiency is an important concept behind the regulation of securities markets: the prices of securities will be most accurate when correct information about a company is rapidly disseminated, and false or misleading information is quickly dispelled.

In part because of this emphasis on market efficiency, misrepresentations in securities disclosures may lead to legal liability under the ’33 Act

In order to raise capital on the public securities markets (e.g. through an IPO) certain federal registration requirements are necessary, including prospectus disclosures and proxy voting. The ’33 Act § 5 offers three key protections:

No person can offer a security unless the registration statement for that security has been filed with the SEC

Sale of a security is allowed only after the registration statement has become effective

A “statutory prospectus”—which includes the most important information in the registration statement—must be delivered to the buyer before or when the security is sold.

Certain securities are exempt from registration under the ’33 Act § 3, 4. The following are major registration exemptions:

Stock trading—under ’33 Act § 4(1), registration is not required for “transactions by any person other than the issuer, underwriter, or dealer.” This allows other parties, including the general public, to trade in previously issued securities.

Statutory private placement—under ’33 Act § 4(2), registration is not required for “transactions by an issuer not involving any public offering.” This exemption hinges on whether the potential purchasers are sufficiently sophisticated, whether the investor has access to all material investment information, whether the issuer has actually distributed information to offerees, whether the offerees are few in number, and whether the offering looks like a public offering.

Page 12: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Intrastate offering-- under ’33 Act § 3(a)(11), registration is not required for any security that is part of an issue offered and sold exclusively to “persons resident within” one state by a corporation “incorporated by and doing business within” that state.

Small offering and private placement—under Regulations A and D, offerings may either be subject to no registration or only a “mini-registration” as determined under Rules 504, 505, and 506.

Resale of securities issued pursuant to an exemption—under Rule 147, the resale of securities to nonresidents (not covered under § 3(a)(11)) are permitted after the original distribution to residents has “come to rest” in the hands of in-state residents.

Additional reading

How do the securities laws interact with new forms of currency, like bitcoin? A Federal judge ruled in 2013 that bitcoin is a currency, like cash, subject to U.S. securities laws. The SEC subsequently charged the co-owner of two bitcoin websites with violating ’33 Act § 5(a) and 5(c) because he published prospectuses on the internet soliciting investors without registering these offerings with the SEC.

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

’33 Act § 5 Reg D

Chapter 24: Securities Fraud Class Actions

Overview

This chapter --

describes Securities Fraud Class Actions, explaining their statutory basis and comparing them to state fiduciary derivative suits

lays out the Supreme Court case law and the various congressional enactments, particularly the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

The Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 10(b) prohibits fraud in connection with securities trading, and Rule 10b-5, promulgated under § 10(b), compels honest and full disclosure in all securities-related communications.

Page 13: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

The elements of Rule 10b-5 action are judge made, although the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995 (PLSRA) tightened some of the procedures and pleading standards in securities fraud actions.

A private securities fraud class action (SFCA) requires that the plaintiff establish the following basic elements:

o materially false or misleading statements by the defendanto made with an intent to deceive (scienter)o upon which the plaintiff reliedo causing losses to the plaintiff

Additional reading

In June 2014, SCOTUS decided Halliburton v. Erica P. John Fund and made it more difficult for plaintiffs to successfully bring a securities fraud case. The court held that defendants can, at the stage of class certification, rebut the plaintiffs’ presumption of “reliance” by showing that an alleged misrepresentation did not affect the stock price.

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 10(b) Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 21(D)(b)(2)

Daily Thoughts

A man walks into a lawyer's office and inquires about the rates."Fifty dollars for three questions, "replies the lawyer."Isn't that awfully steep?" asks the man."Yes," the lawyer replies, "and what's your third question?"

Page 14: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

A lawyer awakes from surgery, and asks: "Why are all the blinds drawn?" The nurse answers: "There's a fire across the street, and we didn't want you to think you had died."

What is the difference between a catfish and a lawyer? One's a slimy scum-sucking bottom-dwelling scavenger, and the other is a fish.

Chapter 25: Insider Trading

Overview

This chapter --

provides a primer on insider trading, describing both classic insider trading and misappropriation

reviews the duties of insiders who engage in securities trading based on their relationship with the corporation, the disclosing party, and the receiving party

tracks the development of the federal regulatory regime and briefly looks at the rules under state corporate law

analyzes the triumvirate of federal cases (Chiarella, Dirks, O'Hagan) that form the foundation for modern U.S. insider trading law

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Insider trading is illegal and policy considerations concerning fairness, information efficiency, and theft of company information support the law

The federal regulatory regime governing insider trading encompasses both classic insider trading and misappropriation

The majority rule, as illustrated by Goodwin v. Agassiz, is that directors and officers have no duty to disclose material nonpublic information when they trade company securities in an open market

Under Rule 10b-5, insiders of a corporation have a duty of trust and confidence that will give rise to liability if the wrong information is disclosed to the wrong party

Chiarella illustrates the “classical theory” of insider trading law: a violation occurs when an individual has a duty to disclose information as a result of a fiduciary duty or a “relationship of trust and confidence” between parties to a transaction

As the Supreme Court held in Dirks, an outsider to a transaction—such as an underwriter, accountant, attorney, or consultant—who receives nonpublic corporate information with the expectation that it will be kept confidential violates the law when he trades on this information. This is known as tipper-tippee liability.

Insider trading can occur even when the person receiving the information owes no duty to the person with whom he trades. As the Supreme Court stated in O’Hagan, trading on the basis of material nonpublic information obtained by a person in any position of trust and confidence can constitute a Rule 10b-5 violation under the “misappropriation theory.”

Additional reading

You can see information about insider trading:

In a recent and particularly unpalatable insider trading case, a managing clerk at the law firm Simpson Thacher & Bartlett and a stockbroker were arrested for insider trading. The clerk routinely stole tips about upcoming M&A transactions at Simpson Thacher, and then

Page 15: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

met with a middleman at a bar or restaurant to pass the information along. The middleman would then meet the stockbroker near the clock in Grand Central Station to convey the information. Concerned about being found out, the middleman typically would write the stock ticker symbol of the relevant company on a napkin or post it note, and then display it to the stockbroker. After the stock broker had memorized the symbol, the middleman would place the napkin/note in his mouth, and chew and swallow it to destroy the evidence.

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 10b-5

Chapter 26: Sale of Control

Overview

This chapter --

describes the nature of control in the corporation and how it can be sold looks at the duty of a controller to investigate a buyer as a potential looter considers when a selling controller's control premium must be shared with non-controlling

shareholders summarizes the rules for a buyer installing his own board of directors after a sale of

control

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Shareholders have a right to sell their shares in a corporation (this is one of the three major rights of shareholders: vote, sue, sell), however there are important limitations on controlling shareholders when they sell their shares.

Controlling shares in a corporation are more valuable than non-control shares (and typically sell for a higher price, called a “control premium”) because they allow the holder to elect the board of directors, and to decide business strategy, executive pay, and dividend policy.

A party that owns controlling shares has a fiduciary duty to investigate before selling his controlling position if he has been put on notice that the purchaser is deceptive or untruthful, and thus it is likely that his control will harm the corporation.

Most courts have held that a controlling shareholder can sell his controlling interest (even when the corporation has assets of particular value to the buyer) without sharing the control premium with non-controlling shareholders or the corporation. [see Perlman v. Feldmann to understand the evolution of this rule.]

A party that purchases controlling shares in a company does not have immediate control, because control of the corporation’s business is vested in the board of directors, who are

Page 16: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

elected by the shareholders. Directors are prohibited from selling their corporate office, however it is legal for the seller and buyer to agree on resignations on the existing board of directors. [see Essex Universal Corp. v. Yates].

Daily Thoughts

The Wisdom of Yogi Berra:

“You can observe a lot by just watching.”

“If you come to a fork in the road, take it.”

“Always go to other people's funerals, otherwise they won't come to yours.”

More of the Wisdom of Homer Simpson:

“Getting out of jury duty is easy. The trick is to say you're prejudiced against all races.”

"The code of the schoolyard, Marge! The rules that teach a boy to be a man. Let's see. Don't tattle. Always make fun of those different from you. Never say anything, unless you're sure everyone feels exactly the same way you do."

“Kids, you tried your best and you failed miserably. The lesson is: never try.”

Chapter 27: Antitakeover Devices

Page 17: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Overview

This chapter --

provides an overview of antitakeover devices used to protect a corporation from a hostile takeover

considers competing arguments for and against the use of antitakeover devices in the corporate landscape

summarizes the judicial review of antitakeover devices under the business judgment rule, Unocal, and Revlon

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

There are numerous ways that directors and officers can protect a corporation from unwanted suitors. The following are some of the most common antitakeover devices:

o “Staggered” board—the corporation spaces the election of directors so that only a portion are elected each year, and thus a potential bidder must wait two election cycles to obtain control of the board.

o “Poison pill” (or “shareholder rights plan”)—the corporation issues additional “rights” that attach to its outstanding shares. These new rights cannot be traded separately and initially have terms that give them little value. However, the rights plan specifies a “triggering” event—typically when a potential acquirer buys a specified portion of the corporation’s shares—which changes the rights to give the holder the option to buy additional shares at a low price. When these shareholders exercise the option, following a “triggering” event, the acquirer’s position is diluted.

o Share repurchase—directors authorize the repurchase of shares, either by the corporation directly or through an employee stock ownership plan or pension plan, in response to action by an unwanted acquirer.

o Lock-up—directors agree to a transaction with a third-party to sell some asset of the company in order to discourage an unwanted acquirer who is particularly interested in the company because of this asset.

Antitakeover devices raise fundamental policy questions surrounding the potential conflict of interest between directors and shareholders: although directors are in a strong position to evaluate the costs and benefits of a potential acquisition and to determine when this is not ideal, shareholders want to maximize their gains and often are in favor of any deal where they can sell shares at a premium.

Courts have recognized this potential conflict of interest between shareholders and directors, and have fashioned three approaches in evaluating the appropriateness of a board’s response to a perceived takeover threat:

o Under the business judgment rule, a transaction approved by a majority of independent, disinterested directors generally receives BJR protection, a judicial presumption that protects the decision from review.

o Although decisions by a board of directors are given significant leeway, the board’s response to a perceived takeover threat must be proportional to the perceived threat. Unocal is the leading case on this issue and sets out a two-pronged “proportionality” test to determine: (1) whether the board had reasonable grounds for believing a threat to the corporation existed; and (2) whether the defensive measures taken were reasonable in relation to the perceived threat.

Page 18: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

o When a corporation is up “for sale” and such a sale is inevitable, the duties of the board of directors shift under Revlon: rather than protecting the corporation against the overtures of unwanted acquirers, the board is required to take steps to maximize the price paid for the company.

Additional reading

Will a “poison pill” reduce wrinkles for directors of a target corporation? Only sometimes. In April 2014, Valeant, a pharmaceutical company, teamed up with William A. Ackman, a hedge fund manager and activist investor, in an attempt to acquire Allergan, the maker of Botox. This was the first time in history that an activist investor and a company teamed up for a bid, and the C.E.O. of Valeant directly informed Ackman of its intention to acquire Allergan. Allergan did not welcome the acquisition, and mounted a formidable defense: it implemented a “poison pill” and managed to halt the acquisition. On June 18, 2014 Valeant made an unsuccessful tender offer for Allergan. Allergan has so far held off the unwanted advances of Valeant, but the fight is not over yet. On August 1, 2014, Allergan filed a lawsuit against Valeant and Ackman, alleging that by coordinating their stock purchasing efforts they engaged in insider trading and that Ackman should be forced to disgorge the Allergan shares that he owns. The court will consider Allergan’s argument that Valeant and Ackman violated SEC Rule 14e-3, which states that “[i]f any person has taken a substantial step or steps to commence, or has commenced, a tender offer” it will be considered “a fraudulent, deceptive, or manipulative act [for] any officer, director, partner or employee or any other person acting on behalf of the offering person or such issuer, to purchase or sell” stock.

Statutes

These statutes are relevant:

DGCL § 141 DGCL § 157 DGCL § 160

Chapter 28: Deal Protection

Overview

This chapter --

introduces you to deal protection devices, which are contractual arrangements that “protect” a deal by motivating the parties to ensure that the deal goes through

provides an introduction to several common deal protection devices offers a tour through the complicated case law surrounding deal protection devices, with

the key decisions of Omnicare, Paramount v. Time, Paramount v. QVC, Chesapeake v. Shore, and Lyondell v. Ryan

Page 19: users.wfu.edu · Web viewChapter 14: Shareholder Voting Additional reading When Facebook acquired WhatsApp for $19 billion in February, 2014, many outsiders suggested that the purchase

Summary

The main points of the chapter are --

Deal protection devices have the opposite effect of antitakeover devices: rather than thwarting takeover bids by an unwanted acquirer, they attempt to ensure that a takeover will be completed with a wanted acquirer. A major reason for including a deal protection device is that negotiating an acquisition is expensive, and both parties have an incentive to make the deal work.

The following are common deal protection devices:o Termination fee—the target corporation agrees to pay a pre-agreed amount

(often between 1-5% of the share price) to the acquirer if it terminates the deal.o Lock-up—the acquirer is given the right to buy certain assets of the target at a

bargain price whether the deal goes through or not, thus preventing the target from striking a better deal for these assets.

o No-shop—the target is prohibited from soliciting other acquirers during a specified period of time.

o Voting agreement—the board of directors of the target obtains an early agreement from the shareholders to vote in favor of the merger.

Although it is not the majority view, a court may conclude, as in Omnicare, Inc. v. NCS Healthcare, Inc. that deal protection devices are invalid because they are so absolute as to preclude the board of directors from carrying out its fiduciary responsibilities.

Paramount v. Time illustrates that deal protection devices may be in direct conflict with a board’s Revlon duties, raising serious issues of fiduciary duty.

When a deal protection device interferes with the fundamental right of shareholders to vote on a transaction, as in Chesapeake Corp. v. Shore, it must have a “compelling justification” in order to be upheld.

Nonetheless, Lyondell Chem. Co. v. Walter E. Ryan, Jr. illustrates the typically deferential approach of courts to deal protection devices.