26
1 The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential Regimes: Armenia, Croatia, Russia and Ukraine Compared Esther Seha Center for the Study of Democracy, Leuphana University Lüneburg Contact information: [email protected] (Work in progress. Please do not quote without author’s permission.) Abstract Semi-presidentialism is a prominent topic in the comparative study of political institutions, especially since it represents a popular choice of government for third wave democracies. This is particularly true for Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, where semi-presidential regimes – in both the president- parliamentary and the premier-presidential variant - have been the most prevalent regime choice. While much research has been conducted on the origins and ef- fects of semi-presidentialism, less attention has been drawn to the evolution of semi-presidential systems over time. While they have overall proven to be rela- tively stable in the first two decades of transition, there have been attempts at re- ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often struggle with the consequences of excessive presidential powers, reforms that limit the powers of the executive can however – as the literature states – be potentially beneficial to the overall development of democracy. The paper therefore aims at uncovering similarities and differences in processes of constitutional reform in four president-parliamentary countries.

The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

1  

 

The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential Regimes: Armenia, Croatia, Russia and Ukraine Compared

Esther Seha

Center for the Study of Democracy, Leuphana University Lüneburg

Contact information: [email protected]

(Work in progress. Please do not quote without author’s permission.)

Abstract  

Semi-presidentialism is a prominent topic in the comparative study of political institutions, especially since it represents a popular choice of government for third wave democracies. This is particularly true for Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, where semi-presidential regimes – in both the president-parliamentary and the premier-presidential variant - have been the most prevalent regime choice. While much research has been conducted on the origins and ef-fects of semi-presidentialism, less attention has been drawn to the evolution of semi-presidential systems over time. While they have overall proven to be rela-tively stable in the first two decades of transition, there have been attempts at re-ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often struggle with the consequences of excessive presidential powers, reforms that limit the powers of the executive can however – as the literature states – be potentially beneficial to the overall development of democracy. The paper therefore aims at uncovering similarities and differences in processes of constitutional reform in four president-parliamentary countries.

Page 2: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

2  

 

1. Introduction

Under what circumstances can the formal powers of presidents be reduced? The

comparative literature on executive-legislative relations commonly claims that, in

the context of newly democratizing countries, an excessive amount of power vest-

ed in the office of the president proves detrimental to the consolidation of democ-

racy. Two decades after Juan Linz (1990a; 1990b) has advanced his tenet on par-

liamentarism’s superiority over presidentialism, scholarship in comparative poli-

tics has still not unequivocally embraced the assumption that parliamentary re-

gimes trump presidential ones in promoting successful democratic consolidation

(Mainwaring/Shugart 1997; Bernhard 2005; Cheibub 2007). Yet, the general

skepticism about the concentration of power in the office of the president remains

to this day (Stepan/Skach 1993; Foweraker/Landman 2002; Hiroi/Omori 2009).

With the emergence of a large number of semi-presidential regimes – particularly

in the post-socialist region – the classic debate on constitutional design has subse-

quently experienced both a geographic as well as a conceptual extension

(Shugart/Carey 1992; Shugart 2005; Elgie/Moestrup 2008). While semi-

presidentialism has for the most part been ascribed the negative effects of presi-

dentialism (Linz 1994: 52; Merkel 1996: 45)1, the general finding is that – given

their institutional heterogeneity – semi-presidential systems do not per se have

adverse effects on democratic consolidation and stability (Skach 2007: 121; Elgie

2010: 31f.). More specifically, empirical research has found that semi-presidential

systems of the premier-presidential type are generally unobjectionable while their

president-parliamentary counterparts should better be avoided (Elgie/Moestrup

2008: 256; Sedelius 2008: 255f.; Elgie/Schleiter 2011: 58). As a result, both

scholars and constitutional reformers have stressed the conduciveness of reducing

the formal powers of presidents in president-parliamentary regimes (Elgie 2011:

4). This particularly holds true for the post-socialist region where virtually all

countries in which president-parliamentary regimes have been institutionalized

                                                                                                                         1 Despite being eyed with suscpicion, semi-presidentialism has also found advocates – among them, most prominently perhaps Giovanni Sartori – who commend the regime type for the sake of its constitutional flexibility (Sartori 1994: 135ff.; Pasquino 1997: 136f.; Frison-Roche 2007: 73).

Page 3: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

3  

 

fall into the category of hybrid regimes and manifest obvious flaws in the horizon-

tal division of powers (Beliaev 2006: 394; Protsyk 2011: 111).

Despite the common understanding that the cutback of presidential powers can

potentially be beneficial to the overall development of democracy, existing re-

search on semi-presidentialism has predominantly dealt with the origins and ef-

fects of this constitutional format (Schleiter/Morgan-Jones 2009) and has so far

only drawn little attention to the evolution of semi-presidential systems over time

(Newton/Van Deth 2010: 99).2 Yet, the primary focus on semi-presidentialism as

an independent variable not only conceals the empirical finding that there have

been various attempts at limiting presidential powers in several of the post-

socialist states with president-parliamentary constitutions (Protsyk 2011; Samu-

els/Shugar 2010). It also leaves another key question unanswered: How do we

explain why presidents actually consent to a reduction of formal powers that make

presidents the most powerful players in the political game?

On the basis of this theoretical and empirical puzzle, the article pursues a twofold

objective: First, it seeks to uncover why countries shift their constitutional set-up

from president-parliamentarism to premier-presidentialism and what factors de-

termine the formal success of reform. Second, the study attempts to assess the

potential benefits of regime type reform for the prospect of democratization. I

argue that the reform processes themselves suggest the potential to which extent a

change in the constitutional structure is likely to contribute to the promotion of

democratic progression. To allow for comparable conditions, this study analyzes

regime type development in four post-socialist hybrid democracies (Armenia,

Croatia, Russia and Ukraine from 1990-2009). These countries are highly similar

on significant parameters except for the reform outcome. While the reform of the

executive-legislative system has in all countries been introduced to the political

agenda, institutional development has across cases widely differed both with re-

                                                                                                                         2 A notable exception is Protsyk’s (2011) study on the development of post-socialist semi-presidential regimes. While Protsyk has made a great contribution to the mapping of institutional change over time, he offers only little systematic analysis of the underlaying reform processes and dynamics. Further studies have been conducted by Armingeon   and   Careja   (2008)   as   well   as  Roberts   (2009).  However,   their  analyses  deal  with  constitutional  change   in  general  and  do  not  soley  focus  on  the  executive-­‐legislative  format.

Page 4: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

4  

 

spect to the frequency and the dynamic of reform endeavors. Hence, these coun-

tries offer ideal circumstances for studying the driving forces of institutional re-

form and for assessing whether institutional adjustments can actually satisfy the

hopes that are generally put into them.

The central finding is that, in the majority of cases, reforms were aimed at pro-

moting the self-interest of the president rather than at restoring the overall balance

of power in the institutional framework. The study therefore suggests that, in gen-

eral, institutional reform has not fulfilled the hopes that were set into it. Rather

than being the wished for magic bullet that would make a country’s democracy

thrive, it rarely proved to be a viable means to advance democracy. While this

conclusion might suggest that presidential leverage on institutional reform has

been unlimited, process-tracing analysis has shown that both internal and external

veto players as well as situational factors have, for all intents and purposes, prov-

en to be significant in influencing the presidential agenda. Despite the fact that

presidents could for the most part steer the reforms in their favor, reform process-

es have seldom evolved without the emergence of unexpected events that at times

even changed the entire course of reform.

The article is organized as follows. The next section outlines the theoretical and

analytical framework on which the study builds and spells out key research as-

sumptions. In the third section, this framework will be applied to the empirical

material by tracing each country’s reform endeavors in broad strokes. The article

concludes by discussing both the empirical findings as well as their implications

for the comparative study of political institutions and their presumed impact on

processes of democratization.

2. The reform of executive-legislative institutions under presidential dominance: Analytical considerations

One of the goals of this study is to identify the conditions under which the formal

powers of presidents are reduced. For the purpose of instructing the empirical

analyses of executive-legislative reform in Armenia, Croatia, Russia and the

Page 5: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

5  

 

Ukraine, I have developed an analytical framework that draws on both the notions

of the policy cycle (Jann/Wegrich 2007) and actor-centered institutionalism

(Scharpf 1997). In a last step, this framework is linked with general assumptions

about the role of presidents in the reform process.

Generally, the article draws on more recent efforts in comparative politics which

conceptualize formal institutional change as a specific type of policy reform

(Moe/Caldwell 1994: 173; Kaiser 2002: 21). Based on the notion that the formal

structures of government result from goal-oriented human action and are thus

“subject to deliberate choice” (Dahl 1996: 179), this study uses the policy cycle as

a model to subdivide the reform process into distinct phases (Schneider/Janning

2006; Blum/Schubert 2011). While the stages heuristic has been widely criticized

for its inadequacy to capture the actual course of policy creation (Jann/Wegrich

2007: 55ff.), it does in the present context however offer a useful heuristic tool for

tracing reform processes. As the analysis is primarily interested in uncovering

under what circumstances the reform of the regime type enters the political agen-

da, how and with what content a reform bill is formulated and under which condi-

tions the process leads to a formal change in the executive-legislative setup, the

study’s heuristic framework only includes the phases of agenda setting, policy

formulation and decision-making and leaves aside the stages of policy implemen-

tation and evaluation.

While the stages heuristic is instructive in distinguishing analytically useful re-

form sequences, this approach does in itself not generate theoretical assumptions

about potential causes of reform. These will be spelled out in what follows. As

reforms of the institutional format are “conscious outcomes of political activities”

(Tsebelis 1990: 92) this study is tied in with the idea that actors are the crucial

entity in institutional reform processes (Sołtan 1998: 49; Kaiser 1997: 434). Un-

like instances of institutional choice or “constitutional moments” (Ackerman

1991), which have generally found to be affected less by a fixed set of institution-

al rules and to be predominantly shaped by rational, goal seeking and utility max-

imizing actors (Colomer 1995; Geddes 1996), subsequent institutional reforms are

to a significant degree also conditioned by the institutional framework and partic-

ularly by formal amendment procedures. It therefore stands to reason to build this

Page 6: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

6  

 

analysis on the assumptions of actor-centered institutionalism. A research heuris-

tic which was coined by Renate Mayntz and Fritz W. Scharpf (1995) and argues

that institutions do not completely determine politics but nevertheless stimulate,

facilitate or constrain actors in their actions (Mayntz/Scharpf 1995: 43). Hence,

the reform of political institutions can essentially be understood as a result of ac-

tors who interact within the boundaries laid down by the institutional framework

(Kaiser 2002: 20; Scharpf 2000: 66). Accordingly, actors, interactions and institu-

tions can be considered the key dimensions of explanation. While each of these

dimensions is generally relevant at every stage of the reform process, they are for

heuristic purposes assigned to one of the three reform sequences (see figure 1).

Finally, the reform stages and dimensions are combined with the potential role of

presidents in the institutional reform process. Post-socialist presidents have, un-

like other political personalities, been the key figures in transformation and con-

solidation processes of the region (Taras 1997; Bos/Helmerich 2006). Both theo-

retical and empirical evidence suggests that powerful presidents, particularly in

hybrid regimes, will be either bent on maintaining or expanding their constitution-

al powers (O’Donnell 1994: 61f.; Roberts 2009: 107). A reduction of presidential

prerogatives in turn appears counterintuitive. Based on these considerations, a

cutback in presidential powers can therefore potentially follow one of three differ-

ent scenarios: First, reforms can take place against the will of the president. Se-

cond, reforms can be initiated by presidents themselves. Third, a change in the

institutional setup can be undertaken in cooperation with the president. Subject to

the respective point of origin, three distinct courses of reform are likely to ensue.

The first scenario builds on the initial consideration that presidents will attempt to

maintain their institutional status quo (Alexander 2001: 256). A reform of the ex-

ecutive-legislative order is therefore only to be expected under the condition that a

reform is initiated against the will of the president. For this to occur not only will

a shift in political majorities be required. The ensuing reform process is also likely

to be highly conflictive and will only then result in a formal constitutional change

if the reform camp can garner a coalition large and stable enough to surmount the

amendment hurdle (Kitschelt 1994: 18). In addition to reforms against the will of

the president, there are two further scenarios that can lead to a reduction of presi-

Page 7: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

7  

 

dential power. On the one hand, the president can himself initiate a reform pro-

cess. Due to the prerogatives vested in his office, he will thus be likely to domi-

nate the entire course of the reform event in both form and content. Depending on

the majorities at hand, the reform process can, however, also take a contentious

turn. As the presidential reform project also hinges on meeting the institutional

thresholds, the amendment procedure can therefore potentially play an important

role and can require the president to make concessions to other actors should he

lack a majority of his own (Cortell/Peterson 1999: 190f.). On the other hand, the

reduction of presidential powers can also occur as a result of a cooperative com-

mitment by both the president and the opposition (Mahoney 2000: 523ff.). Grant-

ed that the reform project is based on a shared reform agenda, in all likelihood

neither the stage of policy formulation nor of decision-making will turn out to be

contested and problematic to the point of a reform’s failure. The formal amend-

ment requirements can therefore assumedly be neglected and, should majorities be

lacking, a reasonable trade-off be expected (Colomer 1991: 1287).

Page 8: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

8  

 

Figure 1: Stages and characteristics of reform processes

Reform against the

president

Reform by the presi-

dent

Reform with the

president

Agenda setting

(actors)

• initiated by opposi-

tion

• initiated by opposi-

tion

• initiated in coopera-

tion with opposition

Policy formulation

(interactions)

• highly contested • potentially contest-

ed

• consensual

Decision-making

(institutions)

• constitutional ma-

jorities key

• constitutional ma-

jorities potentially

important

• constitutional ma-

jorities secondary

Notes: As mentioned above, the stages of the reform process cannot be distinguished clearly. Par-ticularly, the phases of policy formulation and decision-making are likely to bleed into each other in anticipation of the final vote on reform. As a heuristic device and framework for the process-tracing analysis, this subdivision does however prove to be instructive.

What do these general theoretical assumptions suggest with regard to the potential

impact of institutional reform on democratization? While the reduction of presi-

dential powers is by no means bound to have a favorable effect on democracy in

any of the three scenarios, an amelioration of regime performance appears to be

most likely if it refers to shared need for reform and in this manner reflects the

readiness of all political decision-makers to abide by the new rules of the demo-

cratic game. Of the three modes of reform presented above, the third scenario

therefore is most likely to entail such a beneficial effect.

Page 9: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

9  

 

3. The reduction of presidential powers in hybrid regimes: Armenia, Croatia, Russia and the Ukraine compared

In the upcoming section, the analytical framework for analyzing the reform of

executive-legislative institutions will be applied to four post-socialist hybrid de-

mocracies. It will start off with a general overview of events and will then contin-

ue with an analysis of the reform processes themselves. Following the most simi-

lar systems approach (Przeworski/Teune 1970) and Lijphart’s comparable-cases

strategy (Lijphart 1975), Armenia, Croatia, Russia and the Ukraine provide a

markedly good opportunity to comparatively analyze under which conditions a

reduction in presidential power takes place and which factors account for the re-

form of the constitutional order. All of these countries have at the outset of their

post-socialist transformation institutionalized president-parliamentary constitu-

tions and have thereafter, due to the dominant position of presidents vis-à-vis

governments and parliaments, experienced a manifest impairment of the horizon-

tal division of powers. These defects in the institutional structure have across

countries culminated in a total of eight efforts to reform the formal authority

structure of the executive. There has, however, been a significant variation in the

overall outcome and dynamics of reform. Of all countries under investigation,

Russia is the only one to not have undergone a formal change in executive-

legislative organization between 1990 and 2009. The remaining three countries

have seen a formal reform of their constitutional framework. Yet, institutional

development in the countries where reforms have formally succeeded exhibit

marked differences with regard to both the frequency and the dynamics of reform.

While reform efforts in both Russia and Croatia have been one-time phenomena,

they have, with two instances of reform in Armenia and four in the Ukraine, been

more numerous.3 As figure 2 highlights, the empirical analysis has further yielded

                                                                                                                         3 Apart from attempts to reduce presidential power, in 2000, president Kuchma has tried to in-crease his presidential powers. After the reduction of presidential powers succeeded in 2004, there have until the end of 2009 been various attempts at both limiting as well as expanding presidential prerogatives (Simon 2008; Luchterhandt 2010). However, none of them has formally succeeded and for the most part these attempts have not even reached the stage of agenda setting. The at-tempts at extending presidential powers have been included both for the sake of completeness and because they represent the frame conditions for the reforms during which an opposite agenda was pursued.

Page 10: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

10  

 

that there have been no attempts at reform against the will of the president. On the

contrary, the majority of cases clusters in the second category of reform and, as

previously identified, have found to be initiated by the presidents themselves. The

Croatian case deviates from the plurality of cases in that it resulted from a cooper-

ative project initiated by both the president and the opposition. As mentioned

above, the Russian case doesn’t only prove to be an exception with regard to its

lack of formal reform success. It is also different in that it is the sole case that

eludes clear categorization in either one of the two scenarios. While the actual

reform process was launched on the initiative of the president, formal responsibil-

ity was later transferred to the prime minister who tried to convert the process into

a concerted endeavor. The Russian case is therefore placed in a median category.

In addition to the general distribution of cases, figure 2 highlights two points:

First, the compilation shows that all reform processes within one country follow

the same pattern in that reform efforts within one country do not switch from sce-

nario to another. Second, these findings reveal that a specific scenario of reform is

not causally related to a particular outcome. More precisely, the variance of out-

comes within the first category of reform suggests that the formal success of ex-

ecutive-legislative restructuring cannot be attributed to how and by whom the

reform processes were initiated. It further highlights that reforms driven by presi-

dents aren’t automatically bound to end in formal success. The set of explanatory

factors responsible for reform outcomes thus appears to be more complex than the

respective reform scenarios suggest and thus merit a more thorough analysis. The

following paragraphs will in broad strokes give an account of the main similarities

and differences that can be derived from both inter- as well as cross-case compari-

son. The analysis is structured according to the three stages of reform that have

initially been identified.

Page 11: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

11  

 

Figure 2: Types of reform and distribution of cases

Reform by the president Reform with the president

Armenia

(1998; 2004)

I (-) II (+)

Ukraine

(2000; 2003; 2004; 2007ff.)

I (-) II (-) III (+) IV (-)

Russia

(1998)

(-)

Croatia

(2000)

(+)

Note: The table lays out all instances of reform for each of the countries under investigation and indicates either their formal success (+) or failure (-). The year specifications given for each case refer to the point in time at which reforms were either successfully adopted or when the reform process ended through either failed adoption or failure at an earlier stage of the reform process.

Agenda setting

At the outset I argued that presidents would presumably be reluctant to reduce the

formal competences of the office that they themselves hold. Nonetheless the em-

pirical investigation has revealed that, across countries, institutional reform was

placed on the political agenda on the initiative of presidents themselves. Yet, de-

spite this commonality, empirical analysis has uncovered that the motivation to

push the reduction of presidential prerogatives varies significantly between cases.

The following account aims at highlighting why presidents have undertaken seem-

ingly self-damaging reforms and investigating the underlying motives for institu-

tional change.

Overall, analysis across countries has revealed two basic incentives for reform.

While reform efforts have on the one hand – as would be expected – shown to

serve immediate presidential self-interests, they have on the other hand been a

response to both external as well as internal triggers and didn’t initially reflect a

genuine desire to reform the institutional framework in the direction of a more

balanced system of powers. For instance, Armenia’s recent history of democrati-

zation and the nature of executive-legislative relations did not suggest that, in

Page 12: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

12  

 

1998, president Kocharyan himself would come out for creating a constitutional

framework geared in favor of parliament (Manutscharjan 1999: 57). On closer

inspection, however, the incitement for reform turned out to be quite plain: Arme-

nia had in 1996 applied for membership in the Council of Europe. Yet, the Cauca-

sus republic’s admission to the organization came along with the requirement to

adapt the system of executive-legislative relations to European constitutional

standards and thus the institutionalization of a premier-presidential regime (Abra-

hamyan 2005; Parliamentary Assembly of the Council of Europe 2000). Hence,

external parameters have accounted for the fact that the reform of the institutional

setup was pushed on the political agenda by the president himself. While institu-

tional reform has entered the Russian political agenda for similar reasons, the ac-

tual trigger for reform was not of international but of domestic origin. Executive-

legislative reform had been a prominent subject of contention between Yeltsin and

parliament since the former had forced the adoption of a new Russian constitution

in 1993 (Slater 1994: 3; Mommsen 2003: 39). However, attempts at reform had

led nowhere until in 1998, the reduction of presidential power had conveniently

lend itself as a bargaining chip in the resolution of the government crisis in the fall

of 1998 (Sharlet 1999: 442). While the demand for a reform of the constitutional

framework had in both Armenia and Russia not been unheard-of, the reform of the

institutional setup was – in the final analysis – a means to and end rather than the

means itself.

Unlike in Armenia and Russia, where presidents have more or less perceived the

reform project as a concession to external circumstances, reform endeavors in the

Ukraine can clearly be traced back to president Kuchma’s institutional self-

interest. While in the year 2000 he had initially attempted to further concentrate

institutional powers in the office of the president, his reform efforts had taken a

180-degree turn in the run-up to the 2004 presidential elections and the oncoming

end of his second and final term in office (Bos 2006: 91; Christen-

sen/Rakhimkulov/Wise 2005: 219f.). His course of action was clearly based on

the consideration that, upon having to leave the presidency, he didn’t want to see

the position be filled by a successor who would have ample institutional powers at

his disposal. Even more so as Kuchma allegedly entertained the plan to assume

Page 13: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

13  

 

the post of prime minister upon leaving the presidency (Bos 2006: 92; Sedeli-

us/Berglund 2012: 33). The Croatian case resembles the Ukrainian case insofar as

executive-legislative reform proved to be in the interest of the president. Yet, un-

like the Ukraine, the Croatian president’s agenda represented a general consensus

and was supported across the political spectrum as a mutual effort to renew Croa-

tia’s political institutions and to institutionally substantiate Croatia’s revitalized

attempt to advance democratization after the decade-long reign of Franjo Tudjman

(Prpić 2001: 41).

In summary, empirical analysis has uncovered that presidents have across coun-

tries proven to be the driving forces in hoisting the reform of executive-legislative

institutions to the political agenda. While the presidents of the Ukraine and Croa-

tia came out for reform based on either personal or general interest, the decision to

initiate institutional change in both Armenia and Russia turned out not to be en-

tirely self-determined in that it was imposed on the presidents due to either inter-

nal or external pressure.

Policy formulation

For the stage of policy formulation the argument was put forward that presidents

would on the basis of both their formal and informal powers be likely to have un-

restrained authority over the reform process in both form and content. Based on

the diverse starting points of reform, one would be led to expect that presidents

would be keen on navigating the reform processes in accordance with their re-

spective self-interests and use their prerogatives to that effect. While one could

assume the Ukrainian president to put significant thrust behind his reform plat-

form, actions by both the Armenian and the Russian president would presumably

turn out to be more restrained. As neither had initiated reform on their own accord

one could expect both of them to make an explicit effort to use their formal and

informal powers to keep a check on the institutional remake and only concede to

the demands as much as absolutely necessary.

In principle, empirical analysis has confirmed this supposition. In the Ukraine, the

president has sought to shape each reform process in ways that best promoted his

self-interests. For instance, president Kuchma, in both 2000 and 2002, tried to

Page 14: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

14  

 

lead his reform project to success by bypassing the formal amendment procedures

laid down in the constitution and choosing procedures that would be more condu-

cive to the realization of his objectives. He has both times resorted to involving

the public and rallying support for the changes in the institutional framework from

outside the narrow circle of politics. Further, he willingly resorted to the violation

of the amendment rules in order to advance his institutional reform agenda

(Beichelt/Pavlenko 2005). In quite the same way, Armenia’s president Kocharyan

aimed at retaining control over the reform process by putting himself in charge of

the reform project and thus being the key figure that could pull all strings. For

example, he appointed the presidential commission responsible for the elaboration

of the proposal and – within the Council of Europe’s requirements – also set the

parameters of reform. In order for it not to take unexpected turns, the policy for-

mulation process was at all times closely monitored by the president (Manutschar-

jan 1999: 57).

This did not hold true for either the Russian or the Croatian case. While the Croa-

tian policy formulation stage was from the outset intended to be a non-partisan

project by engaging an expert commission in the preparation of a general reform

proposal (Working Group of the President of the Republic of Croatia 2000), the

Russian reform process has – after having started out as a presidential initiative –

taken a similar turn in that responsibility was shifted from president Yeltsin to

prime minister Primakov. By this means the policy formulation’s character

changed from being unilateral to being multilateral in that it approximated the

Croatian mode of consensual reform by instituting a working group with equal

representation by all decision-makers (von Steinsdorff 2001: 297f.). Despite mi-

nor divergences with regard to questions of detail between the Croatian president

and prime minister, the expert proposal has successfully served as a blueprint

throughout the negotiations in that it reflected an overall reform consensus. Even

though – as will be seen in the next section – the Russian reform effort quickly

took a controversial turn, the Russian and Croatian projects of institutional change

hence bore similarities in that a shared need for reform was reflected in the way

the policy formulation process was organized.

Page 15: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

15  

 

In addition to these general findings about how presidents have shaped the policy

formulation process, empirical investigation has further generated instructive in-

sights into the degree of presidential leverage on the course of reform. Analysis

has revealed that a president’s capacity to navigate executive-legislative reform in

his favor was restricted by both internal and external veto players as well as situa-

tional factors and thereby refuting the assumption of presidential almightiness.

For example, the Armenian attempt to change the constitutional system was

heavily influenced by the Venice Commission. After the unexpected failure of the

first Armenian reform attempt in 2003, the commission had decided to assume a

more active role in the reform process. Despite the president’s ability to retain the

key position in the overall negotiations, the Venice Commission’s commitment

did by all means extort concessions from President Kocharyan and made the over-

all reform project less controllable for the Armenian head of state (Markarov

2006: 164). Likewise, President Kuchma’s reform agenda was thwarted but some-

times also boosted by both the supreme and constitutional courts as well as for-

eign and domestic agents which have in turn significantly affected the reach of the

president’s reform strategy (Ott 2002: 93; Bredies 2011: 43).

In a nutshell, the analysis of the policy formulation process has essentially af-

firmed the assumption that presidents tried and for the most part also succeeded in

shaping the course of reform in a way that best served their respective objectives.

Yet, process tracing of cases across countries has also revealed instances where

presidential leverage was significantly restricted by actions of both external and

internal veto players.

Decision-making

It is quasi-common knowledge that formal amendment thresholds are crucial for

the formal success of constitutional reform (Lutz 1995; Lijphart 1999). Generally,

a reform is expected to succeed upon the condition that a constitutional majority

willing to support the initiative exists. In the absence of such majorities, prospects

for reform success of contentious issues are, albeit not necessarily, likely to be

meager. The formal success of constitutional amendments seems particularly like-

ly in case executive-legislative reform is spearheaded by presidents who them-

selves command the majority required for passing a reform bill. The study of ex-

Page 16: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

16  

 

ecutive-legislative reform in the four post-socialist countries under investigation

has on principle confirmed that constitutional majorities prove to be essential for

the formal adoption of institutional reform. However, the empirical review of re-

form instances has also disclosed that situational factors can absorb either the

presence or the absence of a reform majority and thus can at times make formal

reform thresholds secondary conditions for success. Both the Armenian as well as

the Ukrainian reform development offer relevant evidence for this assumption.

Given that Armenia’s president Kocharyan was in command of a reform majority

of his own, the failure of the first attempt at reform, which was caused by not

meeting the quorum requirements for the constitutional referendum, was not fore-

seeable. The outcome of reform was insofar remarkable because the president’s

leverage in society could have easily been utilized to decide the referendum in his

favor. Presidential attention was however geared to the upcoming parliamentary

elections, which had pushed constitutional reform to the background (Markarov

2006: 164). Thereupon the referendum’s success was, as the reform’s potential

Achilles heel, safeguarded by an extensive media campaign when the vote was

repeated in 2004. Unlike Armenia, the Ukraine’s constitutional framework un-

derwent reform despite the lack of a constitutional majority in favor of the presi-

dent. While Kuchma’s attempt to forge a reform coalition with the help of votes

outside of his own camp failed in the run-up to the presidential elections in the fall

of 2004, he had come out on top in his attempt to replace the president-

parliamentary with a premier-presidential system due to the exceptional circum-

stances of the Orange revolution (Hale 2011: 590).4

The careful tracing of events has thus shown, that the formal outcome of reforms

was at times determined by unanticipated incidents rather than formal amendment

rules. That constitutional majorities turned out to be of secondary importance in

the Croatian case comes as little surprise. A reform process whose initiation and

implementation on the basis of a shared reform agenda significantly facilitated the

passing of the final bill (Helmerich 2006: 244). In Russia, it was impossible to

                                                                                                                         4 Similarly Kuchma’s alledgedly foolproof initiative to expand the power portfolio of the presi-dency remained unfinished due to the Gongadse scandal. A scandal which revolved around the death of an oppositional journalist which president Kuchma was accused of having been involved in (Helmerich 2003: 157).

Page 17: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

17  

 

emulate such a pattern because neither did the reform process start from a consen-

sual stance, nor did parties achieve to overcome their differences with regard to

the politics of the day (von Steinsdorff 2001: 297f.; Sharlet 1999: 445f.). Moreo-

ver, the imminent end of Yeltsin’s second term in office and the quest for a poten-

tial successor who would guarantee the incumbent president exemption from pun-

ishment soon shifted attention away from questions regarding the institutional

foundation of the Russian political system. While initiatives of constitutional re-

form in hybrid regimes have thus shown to be affected by formal amendment pa-

rameters, they have to a certain extent also proven to be less predictable and con-

tingent on situational factors.

From this brief summary of executive-legislative reform in the four post-socialist

countries under investigation, three general conclusions can be drawn. First, em-

pirical analysis has uncovered multiple triggers for reform of regime type and has

shown that causes for institutional reform are not one-dimensional. While political

actors initiated institutional reform out of a desire to bring the political rules of the

game in line with the democratic balance of powers, reforms have for the most

part served the fulfillment of presidents’ general or specific power-political inter-

ests. Second, presidents have proven to be all but omnipotent in the formulation

stage of the institutional reform process. Even though their formal and informal

power portfolio has enabled presidents to significantly shape the negotiations both

in form and content, they were still reigned in by both external and internal veto

players such as institutions of democracy promotion and courts. Finally, the anal-

ysis has revealed that formal amendment rules did neither have predictable nor

standard effects. While the presence or absence of a reform majority generally

suggested either the success or failure of reform, situational factors have in some

instances proven to trump the assumed effect of formal amendment rules.

4. Conclusion

The preceding analysis has shown, through a comparison of the development of

executive-legislative institutions in Armenia, Croatia, Russia and the Ukraine, that

Page 18: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

18  

 

countries with dominant presidents have not only chosen to take the path of reduc-

ing presidential powers but that surprisingly many cases of reform have actually

resulted in formal constitutional change. Yet, the results from the analysis of ex-

ecutive-legislative reform during 1990-2009 cast reasonable doubt on the hoped

for impact of institutional modifications and the prospects for the democratization

of hybrid regimes stated in the literature (Elgie 2011; Samuels/Shugart 2010).

The empirical analysis has shown that the reform of the constitutional format gen-

erally occurs in either one of two ways. While it can take the form of a consensual

project with the shared goal of distributing political power more evenly between

president, government and parliament and making the revised democratic rules

“the only game in town” (Przeworski 1991: 26), reforms can also serve as vehi-

cles for the realization of presidential self-interest. The majority of cases studied

in the research at hand fall into the latter category and therefore mitigate expecta-

tions regarding the democratizing potential of reform. This conclusion is further

substantiated by the fact that the successful reduction of formal presidential power

– as witnessed in Armenia, Croatia and the Ukraine – did not automatically give

rise to defect-free horizontal systems of government (Freedom House 2012). The

level of democracy has only improved significantly in Croatia. Ukraine has seen a

bout of improvement after the reform was adopted in 2004, however, democratic

development has like in Armenia more or less stagnated. The study has provided

no proof for the fact that the lack of formal executive-legislative reform in Russia

is to be held responsible for Russia’s democratic decline in the mid 2000’s. Yet,

the Russian reform does suggest that it could have well had a beneficial impact. It

goes without saying that institutional reform is on no account likely to be the sole

driver of democratization. However, as recent analysis of the impact of formal

constitutional change has shown, the potential to fuel democratic reform is not to

be undervalued (Hale 2011).

These findings have considerable implications for both the comparative study of

political institutions as well as empirical democratization research. For one thing,

while helpful in conceptually differentiating between various systems of execu-

tive-legislative design, the classification of multiple semi-presidential regime

types (Shugart/Carey 1992) in itself offers little systematic evidence of the ex-

Page 19: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

19  

 

pected impact of subtypes on democratic performance. Institutional performance

is contingent on a panoply of cultural, economic and historic parameters. Thus,

this study further underlines the assumption that democratization is caused by

more than just political institutions (von Mettenheim 1997; Bernhard 2005). The

reform of the institutional framework does not represent the magic bullet that can

compensate for a lack of democratic elite behavior that is underpinned by infor-

mal institutions (Lauth 2000; Helmke/Levitsky 2004). Despite the fact that prem-

ier-presidentialism does therefore not present a guarantee for the advancement of

hybrid regimes, the present findings nonetheless illustrate that the reduction of

presidential powers in defective democracies can potentially hold beneficial ef-

fects and thereby generally underline the importance of formal institutions

(McGregor 1996; Rüb 2007).

Future research should aspire to identify conditions under which institutional re-

form stands a chance at being conducive to regime development. On that score

scholars should especially draw their attention to the role of external actors in

domestic institutional reform. In two out of four post-socialist countries, foreign

agents have facilitated the reform endeavors and have, despite obvious restrictions

and domestic constellations, played a significant roll in the overall processes of

institutional adjustment. Political science should try to gain a more detailed under-

standing of outside contributions to domestic reform and particularly its unintend-

ed consequences (Carothers 2009; Levitsky/Way 2006; Pevehouse 2002). Such

findings could – beyond theoretical gains for the discipline – also deliver insight

into the practice of external democracy promotion and would thereby represent a

fruitful research agenda at the interface of both comparative politics and interna-

tional relations.

Page 20: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

20  

 

References  

Abrahamyan, Anna 2005: Armenia’s constitutional reform, in: Inside Europe, 22. November 2005. http://www.insideeurope.org/news/armenias-constitutional-reform (21.11.2012).

Ackerman, Bruce A. 1991: We the people. Foundation. Cambridge: Harvard Uni-versity Press.

Alexander, Gerard 2001: Institutions, Path Dependence, and Democratic Consoli-dation, in: Journal of Theoretical Politics 13/3, 249-270.

Armingeon, Klaus/Careja, Romana 2008: Institutional change and stability in postcommunist countries, 1990–2002, in: European Journal of Political Research 47/4, 436–466.

Beichelt, Timm/Pavlenko, Rostyslav 2005: The Presidential Election and Consti-tutional Reform, in: Kurth, Helmut/Kempe, Iris (eds.): Presidential Election and Orange Revolution. Implications for Ukraine’s Transition. Kiew: Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, 50-85.

Beliaev, Mikhail V. 2006: Presidential Powers and Consolidation of New Post-communist Democracies, in: Comparative Political Studies 39/3, 375-398.

Bernhard, Michael 2005: Institutions and the Fate of Democracy: Germany and Poland in the Twentieth Century. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

Blum, Sonja/Schubert, Klaus 2011: Politikfeldanalyse. 2nd edition. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

Bos, Ellen 2006: Leonid Kutschma: “Spieler” mit demokratischen Institutionen, in: Bos, Ellen/Helmerich, Antje (eds.): Zwischen Diktatur und Demokratie. Staatspräsidenten als Kapitäne des Systemwechsels in Osteuropa. Berlin: LIT Verlag Berlin, 79-116.

Bos, Ellen/Helmerich, Antje 2006: Osteuropäische Staatspräsidenten zwischen Diktatur und Demokratie: eine vergleichende Bilanz, in: Bos, Ellen/Helmerich, Antje (eds.): Zwischen Diktatur und Demokratie. Staatspräsidenten als Kapitäne des Systemwechsels in Osteuropa. Berlin: LIT-Verlag, 251-277.

Bredies, Ingmar 2011: Verfassungspolitik und Verfassungsentwicklung in der Ukraine unter der Präsidentschaft Viktor Juščenkos, in: Besters-Dilger, Julia-ne/Woldan, Alois (eds.): Die Ukraine auf dem Weg nach Europa. Die Ära Juschtschenko. Frankfurt am Main: Peter Lang, 35-57.

Page 21: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

21  

 

Carothers, Thomas 2009: Democracy Assistance: Politcal vs. Developmental?, in: Journal of Democracy 20/1, 5-19.

Cheibub, José Antonio 2007: Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Christensen, Robert K./Rakhimkulov, Edward R./Wise, Charles R. 2005: The Ukrainian Orange Revolution brought more than a new president: What kind of democracy will the institutional changes bring?, in: Communist and Post-Communist Studies 38/2, 207-230.

Colomer, Josep M. 1991: Transitions by agreement: Modeling the Spanish Way, in: The American Political Science Review 85/4, 1283-1302.

Colomer, Josep M. 1995: Strategies and Outcomes in Eastern Europe, in: Journal of Democracy 6/2, 74-85.

Cortell, Andrew P./Peterson, Susan 1999: Altered States: Explaining Domestic Institutional Change, in: British Journal of Political Science 29/1, 177-203.

Dahl, Robert A. 1996: Thinking about Democratic Constitutions: Conclusions from Democratic Experience, in: Shapiro, Ian/Hardin, Russell (eds.): Political Order. New York: New York University Press, 175-206.

Elgie, Robert 2004: Semi-Presidentialism: Concepts, Consequences and Contest-ing Explanations, in: Political Studies Review 2/3, 314-330.

Elgie, Robert 2010: Semi-Presidentialism, Cohabitation and the Collapse of Elec-toral Democracies 1990-2008, in: Government and Opposition 45/1, 29-49.

Elgie, Robert 2011: Semi-Presidentialism. Sub-Types and Democratic Perfor-mance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Elgie, Robert/Moestrup, Sophia 2008: The impact of semi-presidentialism on the performance of democracy in Central and Eastern Europe, in: Elgie, Rob-ert/Moestrup, Sophia (eds.): Semi-Presidentialism in Central and Eastern Europe. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 239-257.

Elgie, Robert/Schleiter, Petra 2011: Variation in the Durability of Semi-Presidential Democracies, in: Elgie, Robert/Moestrup, Sophia/Wu, Yu-Shan (eds.): Semi-Presidentialism and Democracy. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 42-60.

Foweraker, Joe/Landman, Todd 2002: Constitutional Design and Democratic Per-formance, in: Democratization 9/2, 43-66.

Page 22: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

22  

 

Frison-Roche, François 2007: Semi-presidentialism in a post-communist context, in: Elgie, Robert/Moestrup, Sophia (Hrsg.): Semi-Presidentialism Outside Europe: A Comparative Study. London: Routledge, 56-77.

Geddes, Barbara 1996: Initiation of New Democratic Institutions in Eastern Eu-rope and Latin America, in: Lijphart, Arend/Waisman, Carlos H. (eds.): Institu-tional Design in New Democracies. Eastern Europe and Latin America. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 15-41.

Goodin, Robert E. 1996: Institutions and Their Design, in: Goodin, Robert E. (ed.): The Theory of Institutional Design. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1-53.

Hale, Henry E. 2011: Formal Constitutions in Informal Politics. Institutions and Democratization in Post-Soviet Eurasia, in: World Politics 63/4, 581-617.

Helmerich, Antje 2006: Kroatien unter Franjo Tuđman. Plebiszitärer Autoritaris-mus hinter demokratischer Fassade, in: Bos, Ellen/Helmerich, Antje (eds.): Zwi-schen Diktatur und Demokratie. Staatspräsidenten als Kapitäne des Systemwech-sels in Osteuropa. Berlin: LIT Verlag, 223-250.

Helmerich, Martina 2003: Die Ukraine zwischen Autokratie und Demokratie. In-stitutionen und Akteure. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

Helmke, Gretchen/Levitsky, Steven 2004: Informal Institutions and Comparative Politics: A Research Agenda, in: Perspectives on Politics 2/4, 725-740.

Hiroi, Taeko/Omori, Sawa 2009: Perils of parliamentarism? Political systems and the stability of democracy revisited, in: Democratization 16/3, 485-507.

Jann, Werner/Wegrich, Kai 2007: Theories of the Policy Cyle, in: Fischer, Frank/Miller, Gerald J./Sidney, Mara S. (eds.): Handbook of Public Policy Analy-sis. Theory, Politics and Methods. Boca Raton: CRC Press, 43-62.

Kaiser, André 1997: Types of Democracy. From Classical to New Institutional-ism, in: Journal of Theoretical Politics 9, 419-444.

Kaiser, André 2002: Mehrheitsdemokratie und Institutionenreform. Verfassungs-politischer Wandel in Australien, Großbritannien, Kanada und Neuseeland im Vergleich. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag.

Kitschelt, Herbert 1994: Rationale Verfassungswahl? Zum Design von Regie-rungssystemen in neuen Konkurrenzdemokratien. Antrittsvorlesung an der Hum-boldt-Universität zu Berlin, 2. Mai 1994.

Lauth, Hans-Joachim 2000: Informal Institutions and Democracy, in: Democrati-zation 7/4, 21-50.

Page 23: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

23  

 

Levitsky, Steven/Way, Lucan A. 2006: Linkage versus Leverage. Rethinking the International Dimension of Regime Change, in: Comparative Politics 38/4, 379-400.

Lijphart, Arend 1975: The Comparable-Cases Strategy in Comparative Research, in: Comparative Political Studies 8/2, 158-177.

Lijphart, Arend 1999: Patterns of Democracy. Government Forms and Perfor-mance in Thirty-Six Democracies. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Linz, Juan J. 1990a: The Perils of Presidentialism, Journal of Democracy 1/4, 51-69.

Linz, Juan J. 1990b: The Virtues of Parliamentarism, Journal of Democracy 1/4, 84-91.

Linz, Juan J. 1994: Presidential and Parliamentary Democracy: Does it Make a Difference?, in: Linz, Juan J./Valenzuela, Arturo (eds.): The Failure of Presiden-tial Democracy. Comparative Perspectives, Volume 1. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 3-87.

Luchterhandt, Otto 2010: Der Kampf um das „richtige“ Regierungssystem in der Ukraine, in: Habdas, Magdalena/Wudarski, Arkadiusz (eds.): Ius est ars boni et aequi. Festschrift für Stanlisława Kalus. Frankfurt am Main: Peter Lang, 253-270.

Lutz, Donald S. 1995: Toward a Theory of Constitutional Amendment, in: Levin-son, Sanford (ed.): Responding to Imperfection: The Theory and Practice of Con-stitutional Amendment. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 237-274.

Mahoney, James 2000: Path dependence in historical sociology, in: Theory and Society 29/4, 507-548.

Mainwaring, Scott/Shugart, Matthew S. 1997: Juan Linz, Presidentialism, and Democracy. A Critical Appraisal, in: Comparative Politics 29/4, 449-471.

Manutscharjan, Aschot 1999: Das Regierungs- und Parteiensystem Armeniens, in: Mangott, Gerhard (Hrsg.): Brennpunkt Südkaukasus: Aufbruch trotz Krieg, Ver-treibung und Willkürherrschaft? Wien: Braumüller, 19-60.

Markarov, Alexander 2006: MacroInstitutional Political Structures and Their De-velopment in Armenia, in: Demokratizatsiya 14/2, 159-170.

Mayntz, Renate/Scharpf, Fritz W. 1995: Der Ansatz des akteurzentrierten Institu-tionalismus, in: Mayntz, Renate/Scharpf, Fritz W. (eds.): Gesellschaftliche Selbst-regelung und politische Steuerung. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, 39-72.

Page 24: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

24  

 

McGregor, James P. 1996: Constitutional Factors in Politics in Post-communist Central and Eastern Europe, in: Communist and Post-Communist Studies 29/2, 147-166.

Merkel, Wolfgang 1996: Theorien der Transformation: Die demokratische Konso-lidierung postautoritärer Gesellschaften, in: von Beyme, Klaus/Offe, Claus (eds.): Politische Theorien in der Ära der Transformation (=PVS Sonderheft 26). Wies-baden: Westdeutscher Verlag, 30-58.

Moe, Terry M./Caldwell, Michael 1994: The Institutional Foundations of Demo-cratic Government: A Comparison of Presidential and Parliamentary Systems, in: Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150/1, 171-195.

Mommsen, Margareta 2003: Wer herrscht in Rußland? Der Kreml und die Schat-ten der Macht. München: Verlag C. H. Beck.

Newton, Kenneth/Van Deth, Jan W. 2010: Foundations of Comparative Politics. Democracies of the Modern World. 2. Auflage. Cambridge: Cambridge Universi-ty Press.

O’Donnell, Guillermo 1994: Delegative Democracy, in: Journal of Democracy 5/1, 55-69.

Ott, Alexander 2002: Präsident, Parlament, Regierung – Wie konsolidiert ist das System der obersten Machtorgane?, in: Simon, Gerhard (ed.): die neue Ukraine: Gesellschaft – Wirtschaft – Politik. Köln: Böhlau, 75-98.

Parliamentary Assembly of the Council of Europe 2000: Armenia’s application for membership of the Council of Europe, Opinion 221 (2000). http://assembly.CoE.int/Main.asp?link=/Documents/AdoptedText/ta00/EOPI221.htm (19.11.2012).

Pasquino, Gianfranco 1997: Semi-presidentialism: A political model at work, in: European Journal of Political Research 31/1, 128-137.

Pevehouse, Jon C. 2002: Democracy from the Outside-In? International Organiza-tions and Democratization, in: International Organization 56/3, 515-549.

Protsyk, Oleh 2011: Semi-Presidentialism under Post-Communism, in: Elgie, Robert (eds.): Semi-presidentialism and Democracy. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 98-116.

Prpić, Ivan 2001: Die Kinderkrankheiten des kroatischen Parlamentarismus, in: Stability Pact for South Eastern Europe (ed.): Kroatien ein Jahr nach dem Um-bruch – erste Bilanz. Zagreb: Heinrich Böll Stiftung, 41-48.

Page 25: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

25  

 

Przeworksi, Adam 1991: Democracy and the Market: Political and economic re-forms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Przeworski, Adam/Teune, Henry 1970: The logic of comparative social inquiry. New York: Wiley-Interscience.

Roberts, Andrew 2009: The politics of constitutional amendment in postcom-munist Europe, in: Constitutional Political Economy 20/2, 99-117.

Rüb, Friedbert W. 2007: Gewaltenteilung in Mittel- und Osteuropa – Gelungener Konstitutionalismus oder exzessiver Exekutionalismus?, in: Kropp, Sabine/Lauth, Hans-Joachim (eds.): Gewaltenteilung und Demokratie: Konzepte und Probleme der „horizontal accountability“ im interregionalen Vergleich. Baden-Baden: No-mos, 237-260.

Samuels, David J./Shugart, Matthew Søberg 2010: Presidents, Parties, and Prime Ministers. How the Separation of Powers Affects Party Organization and Behav-ior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Sartori, Giovanni 1994: Comparative constitutional engineering. An inquiry into structures, incentives and outcomes. Houndmills: Macmillan.

Scharpf, Fritz W. 1997: Games real actors play: actor-centered institutionalism in policy research. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press.

Schleiter, Petra/Morgan-Jones, Edward 2009: Review Article: Citizens, Presidents and Assemblies: The Study of Semi-Presidentialism beyond Duverger and Linz, in: British Journal of Political Science 39/4, 871-892.

Schneider, Volker/Janning, Frank 2006: Politikfeldanalyse: Akteure, Diskurse und Netzwerke in der öffentlichen Politik. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissen-schaften.

Sedelius, Thomas 2008: The Tug-of-War between Presidents and Prime Minis-ters: Semi-Presidentialism in Central and Eastern Europe. Saarbrücken: VDM Verlag Dr. Müller.

Sedelius, Thomas/Berglund, Sten 2012: Towards Presidential Rule in Ukraine: Hybrid Regime Dynamics Under Semi-Presidentialism, in: Baltic Journal of Law and Politics 5/1, 20-45.

Sharlet, Robert 1999: Russian Constitutional Change: An Opportunity Missed, in: Demokratizatsiya 7/3, 437-447.

Shugart, Matthew Søberg 2005: Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive and Mixed Authority Patterns, in: French Politics 3/3, 323-351.

Page 26: The Reduction of Presidential Powers in Semi-presidential ... · ducing presidential powers in almost all president-parliamentary countries in the region. Since these countries often

26  

 

Shugart, Matthew Søberg/Carey, John M. 1992: Presidents and assemblies. Con-stitutional design and electoral dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Simon, Gerhard 2008: Die politische Krise in der Ukraine, in: Ukraine-Analysen 49, 2-6. http://www.laender-analysen.de/ukraine/pdf/UkraineAnalysen49.pdf (25.03.2013).

Skach, Cindy 2007: The “newest” separation of powers: Semipresidentialism, in: International Journal of Constitutional Law 5/1, 93-121.

Slater, Wendy 1994: Russia’s Plebiscite on a New Constitution, in: RFE/RL Re-search Report 3/3 (21. Januar 1994), 1-7.

Sołtan, Karol Edward 1998: Institutions as products of politics, in: Sołtan, Karol Edward/Uslaner, Eric M./Haufler, Virginia (eds.): Institutions and Social Order. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press, 45-64.

Stepan, Afred/Skach, Cindy 1993: Constitutional Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation: Parliamentarism versus Presidentialism, in: World Politics 46/1, 1-22.

Taras, Ray (Hrsg.) 1997: Postcommunist Presidents. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-versity Press.

Tsebelis, George 1990: Nested Games: Rational Choice in Comparative Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press.

von Mettenheim, Kurt 1997: Presidential Institutions and Democratic Politics, in: Ders. (eds.): Presidential Institutions and Democratic Politics. Comparing Re-gional and National Contexts. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1-15.

von Steinsdorff, Silvia 2001: Parlament und Demokratie in Russland. Die Ent-wicklung repräsentativer Institutionen vom Zarismus bis in die Gegenwart. Mün-chen: unveröffentlichtes Manuskript.

Working Group of the President of the Republic of Croatia 2000: The Expert Grounds for a Proposal to Amend the Constitution, in: Zbornik Pravnog Fakulteta U Zagrebu 50/3, 451-473.