25
1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments * The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest) Junior Research Fellow (Institute for Political Science, Hungarian Academy of Sciences) [email protected] Abstract Political movements have embodied the utopia of anti-politics. This normative burden and de- politicized perception keep the sociological social movement theory in captivity, which prevents the creation of a realistic overview of collective actions. Hence I elucidate the movements’ role and function in the politi- cal processes and in the functioning of democracy with the means of political theory. According to my presupposition the three rival theories of democracy deliberative -, participatory -, neoclassical repre- sentative - and leader democracy (Pakulski-Körösényi 2012) are connected logically to the forms of direct democracy, such as classical direct -, referendum - and the populist protest-democracy(Sartori 1987). Thus various movement concepts could be set up and compared to each other to point out their differences and show the limits of the bottom-up approaches. The hypothesis of my research is that the nature of movements is fundamentally political in a Schmittian sense and the direction of these collective actions is mainly top-down, which makes them the leaders’ instruments easily as the leader-centric view of democracy shows. Keywords: political theory democracy ▪ direct democracy political leadership political movements But surely those who have supposed the masses to be all powerful, or at least well on their way to triumph, are wrong. In our time (…) the influence of autonomous collectivities within political life is in fact diminishing. Furthermore, such influence as they do have is guided; they must now be seen not as publics acting autonomously, but as masses manipulated at fo- cal points into crowds of demonstrators. For as publics become masses, masses some- times become crowds.” C Wright Mills (1956: 309) Movements are a constant and integral part of political processes. They shape and influence eve- ry- day politics and public policies with their actions, protests and marches. Moreover in critical and revolutionary moments their activities can lead to radical transformations, from authoritarian or totalitarian regime to a democratic one and vice versa. These collective actions are more or less part of extraordinary politics, which differs greatly from parliamentarian and electoral poli- tics of normal times. Thus the question arises: what kind of function and role do movements have in a democracy The sociological movement research is not able to answer this question sufficiently, be- cause the subject of its research is depoliticized in itself. The label of ‘social movements’ * This paper is a draft of my PhD dissertation.

The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

1

The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments*

The Role of Political Movements in Democracy

Rudolf Metz

PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

Junior Research Fellow (Institute for Political Science, Hungarian Academy of Sciences)

[email protected]

Abstract

Political movements have embodied the utopia of anti-politics. This normative burden and de- politicized

perception keep the sociological social movement theory in captivity, which prevents the creation of a

realistic overview of collective actions. Hence I elucidate the movements’ role and function in the politi-

cal processes and in the functioning of democracy with the means of political theory. According to my

presupposition the three rival theories of democracy – deliberative -, participatory -, neoclassical repre-

sentative - and leader democracy (Pakulski-Körösényi 2012) – are connected logically to the forms of

direct democracy, such as classical direct -, referendum - and the populist ‘protest-democracy’ (Sartori

1987). Thus various movement concepts could be set up and compared to each other to point out their

differences and show the limits of the bottom-up approaches. The hypothesis of my research is that the

nature of movements is fundamentally political in a Schmittian sense and the direction of these collective

actions is mainly top-down, which makes them the leaders’ instruments easily as the leader-centric

view of democracy shows.

Keywords: political theory ▪ democracy ▪ direct democracy ▪ political leadership ▪ political movements

“But surely those who have supposed the masses to be all powerful, or at least well on their

way to triumph, are wrong. In our time (…) the influence of autonomous collectivities within

political life is in fact diminishing. Furthermore, such influence as they do have is guided;

they must now be seen not as publics acting autonomously, but as masses manipulated at fo-

cal points into crowds of demonstrators. For as publics become masses, masses some- times

become crowds.” C Wright Mills (1956: 309)

Movements are a constant and integral part of political processes. They shape and influence eve-

ry- day politics and public policies with their actions, protests and marches. Moreover in critical

and revolutionary moments their activities can lead to radical transformations, from authoritarian

or totalitarian regime to a democratic one and vice versa. These collective actions are more or

less part of extraordinary politics, which differs greatly from parliamentarian and electoral poli-

tics of normal times. Thus the question arises: what kind of function and role do movements have

in a democracy

The sociological movement research is not able to answer this question sufficiently, be-

cause the subject of its research is depoliticized in itself. The label of ‘social movements’

* This paper is a draft of my PhD dissertation.

Page 2: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

2

symbolizes a normative legitimation, which some authors refer to the activist movement the-

ory (Barker et al. 2001: 1-2.). The movements are usually seen as ‘non-political actors’, which

stand independent above the parties. In this sense they are rivals (Jenkins – Klandermans 1995:

5) and saviors (Cas- tells 2010, Dalton – Kuechler 1990; Flacks 1994; Offe 1985; della Porta

2013) of the representative institutions as well as of the declining liberal democracy. Moreover

the research field is mostly narrowed down to left-wing movements such as global justice -, hu-

man rights -, alternative – and green movements by the introducing of so-called ‘new social

movements’, which in time became an unavoidable barrier to the building of a comprehensive

theory. (Pichardo 1997: 412-413, 1. footnote) Consequently the major part of the literature con-

nects the movements to deliberative-participatory democracy. (della Porta 2005; 2009; 2012;

2013; della Porta - Diani 2006: 239-245; della Porta – Rucht 2013). Thus the concept of move-

ment is impregnated with the ethos of direct political participation and the normative ideal of

anti-political self-governance, which prevents the understanding of the phenomenon.

However, agreeing with Robert C. Tucker (1995:78) the political science literature has

over- concentrated on the analyzing of established polities (as the structure) and given too little

systematic attention to political movements (as a kind of the agency). In this paper my aim is to

elucidate the role and function of movements in democracies with the means of political theory

and the political process theory of movement research. Based on this, I define movements as

collections of comprehensive collective actions, whose nature is primarily political. Thus they

can become competitors, alternatives, and even complements of the established political parties

and actors. Their actions not only point out a social problem, a crisis or extraordinary situation,

but also introduce a new narrative about them and offer possible solutions. Hence they manage

to influence the preferential environment, decision making and agenda setting with their various

actions as well as establish the identity of their supporters and activists and organizational struc-

tures, which do not cross over the frame of goal-rationality.

I will build my analysis on the assumption that the classic theoretical debate between di-

rect and representative democracy has become obsolete and solvable (Körösényi 2009c: 23-26).

Based on Giovanni Sartori’s (1987: 111-123.) implicit distinction, the various forms, institutions

and practices of direct democracy – in a conceptually broad and flexible view1

– can be connect-

ed with other major systems describing theories of democracy (Pakulski-Körösényi 2012). With-

in this frame- work, we can set up and compare to each other three different movement concepts:

In the deliberative-participatory theory, - in which classic direct democracy can

be framed - embodies self-governance resting on real and active participation and de-

liberative interactions. Here movements are the participants and special forums of de-

liberation

Page 3: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

3

The neoclassical theory is connected to the institution of referendum democracy,

which enables self-governance through direct and autonomous decision-making (vot-

ing) on specific matters. Thus the role of movements is to be independent advocacy

groups, lobbying and informing the governmental actors about preferences and their

changes.

The populist ‘protest-democracy’ related to the leader democracy model focuses

on direct, activist participations generated by leaders. In this sense the movements fit

primarily in a top-down political process, where they are subordinated by political

circumstances and competition, thus they could easily became the means of political

ambitions.

The direct democratic forms and the movement concepts, which I will specify hereinafter, logi-

cally fit into the theoretically environment. Moreover, according to the underlying presumptions

of the theories they allow varying space and scope for direct political action and emphasis on dif-

ferent segment of the activity.

The main thesis is that the nature of movements is top-down and vertical in practice and

therefore they could easily just enrich the toolbar of (outsider or insider) political leaders and

leadership2. In this sense these collective actions could be drawn in leader-follower interac-

tions. However, it is crystal clear: this relationship is characterized by interdependence. On the

one hand, the movements are connected to the political process as determined and reactive ac-

tors: they fit into the political competition, where they are subordinated by dominant actors (par-

ties and leaders) or they are forced to assimilate, transform to parties and high- light the leaders

and elite of the movements, which is key to political success and survival. On the other hand,

great leaders’, such as Gandhi, King, Malcolm X, Mandela, Lenin, Trotsky, Stalin, Mussolini,

Hitler, Nehru, Nasser, Ben-Gurion, Nkrumah, Ben Bella, Tito, Castro, and de Gaulle, efforts,

even with the exceptional capabilities and skills they have, would have failed, if there hadn’t been

any movements behind them. This mutual dependence, the importance of collective action and

nonconventional political actors and the crucial role of leaders, is emphasized by the theorists of

mass society theory – Hannah Arendt (1975), William Kornhauser (1959), Gustave Le Bon

(2002), Robert Michels (1959) and Charles Wright Mills (1956) –, as well as Carl Schmitt (2007)

in his partisan theory, Max Weber in quasi-latent conception of ‘charismatic movement’

(Tucker 1968; 1995; Kalyvas, 2008).

The following paper is divided into three major parts. The first part introduces the rival –

deliberative and neoclassical – movement concepts and shows their limitations. The second

part sets up the movement based concept of leader-democracy, in which I will touch upon the

arguments for the necessity of leadership and the limits of this approach. Finally, in the third

section I summarize the results and take account of the possible implications.

Page 4: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

4

I. THE RIVAL MOVEMENTS CONCEPTIONS

I.1. The deliberative movement conception and its limit

The theory of deliberative and participatory democracy, which stemmed from the doctrine of Jür-

gen Habermas’ ideal speech situation and his discourse ethics as well as the Rawlsian theory of

justice, sets two main requirements for democracy. First, it is crucial that participation is realized

in a non- coercive way and based on equal-access and limited self-interest, which according to

John Stuart Mill improves the competences of citizens and increases the level of information for

them. The second postulate is directed towards decision making. In all cases, open and rational

debate results in consensus, which embodies the common good. (Elster 1997; 1998; Pakulski-

Körösényi 2012)

Within this framework classical direct democracy could be interpreted in the clearest and

widest sense, since it is based on real and (pro)active participation and deliberative interaction

(della Porta 2013). The formal and informal deliberation could affect each issue and the oppor-

tunity is given to discuss them comprehensively and completely. The outcome of negotiation –

the consensus – always has decisive, unquestionable power. This, absolutization of consensus,

forced activity out from the world of ‘politicum’, which is limited to decisions on technical (pol-

icy) issues. The theorists look at movements, especially the American civil rights movement, as

organizations which realize the deliberative idea (Gutmann-Thompson 1996: 133.; Rawls 1993:

247-54.; 1999: 131-80.). Here the collective action is a product of deliberation, which creates and

shapes as a specific forum in itself as well. On the other hand, the movements take part in the

nationwide deliberation and help build a consensus through bringing new premises and propagat-

ing new arguments. The nature of process is network-like, horizontal and bottom-up. Thus the

relationship between formal and informal actors is characterized by symmetry, in which the

movements could be equally partners and rivals of established political actors.

However, we should see that this concept could easily lead us to swampy ground. First

of all, we should take into account the inherent coercion, violence and intense emotions of

movements. At this point it is worth to recall the partisan theory of Carl Schmitt. The partisan,

interpreted as an internal enemy, is characterized by irregularity, increased mobility and intensive

political engagement and telluric nature (Schmitt 2007). The first two features can easily be ap-

preciated, but the latter two characteristics seem to be critical. ‘The invasion of space, territory’

and the expansion of the playing field are integral parts of collective action. Therefore the institu-

tional political actors don’t have any choice: they have to take up the fight in new arenas of poli-

tics. Of course, we might think with good reason that movements would give up their strategy, if

conventional politics accommodates them. However, this may result in the disappearance of

Page 5: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

5

the collective action. Their actions, such as the blockade of meeting room and the occupation of

public spaces, make fair negotiation between the stakeholders impossible, because it inherently

embodies violence and extortion, which is always there during the consultation process to re-

strict, manipulate and influence the opponents (Young, 2001; Medearis 2005). Intense political

engagement and emotions classify the participation and its quality (Berelson 1952: 317.; Sartori

1987: 118-120.). It’s clear, that emotions are more important than rational arguments. In short,

the movements go far beyond commonsense and rationality and apply the politics of force, in

which the end justifies the means and not the means justify the end, as it is suggested by the

theorists of deliberative democracy.3

Secondly, there are lots of empirical observable group psychological barriers which can

emerge in cases of collective action. The strong cohesion of the group and its isolation strength-

ens conformity and has the tendency of narrowing down real alternatives. The phenomenon of

‘group deficit’ indicates that the group can rarely fully use its resources. Such barriers are insuf-

ficient co- ordination, the unequal weight of arguments (speaker vs. audience) and declining mo-

tivation and concentration. In addition, the phenomenon of group thinking is also a very danger-

ous trap which is reflected in a number of symptoms. The ‘illusion of invulnerability’ encourages

the optimism and irrational actions of the members, the values of the group become overrated and

there is a lack of questioning about it. Stereotyping and demonization of outsiders, direct pressure

on representatives of different opinion, the illusion of unanimous decision and implicit censorship

might also happen, while self-appointed opinion leaders, might block the group from exter-

nal/internal opposition, antagonistic information and opinions. (Femia 2009)

Thirdly, the classical problem of the size of the assembly should also be seen (Sartori,

1987: 111.), which implies that participation, the access to the ‘game of deliberation’ has real

physical barriers. Donatella della Porta’s (et al. 2009) empirical results show, that the extent of

organization and the lack of personal relation and integration is the biggest and most important

barrier for deliberation among the variety of structural and cultural factors. Besides, the recently

emerging internet- based communication, the so-called ‘e-democacy’ (della Porta et al. 2009,

della Porta 2013) pro- vides a seemingly perfect ground, in which numerous movements (occupy

movements and the movement of One Million People for the Freedom of the Hungarian Press)

and revolutions (Arab Spring, Euromaiden) could easily grow. We could admit that, the web 2.0

has changed the patterns of mobilization and reduced its costs. However, the real deliberation

does not come from the existence of a forum. After all, the movements do not really want to take

a part in the building of the consensus, rather they try to get over the distance and create an own

virtual habitat, network, identity to inform, influence and manipulate the followers and their pref-

Page 6: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

6

erences, which boosts the chances for the realization of participation.4

I.2. The Neoclassical Movement Concept and its Limits

The neoclassical democratic theory (Pakulski-Körösényi 2012:88-93.), as an umbrella term in-

corporates the modern versions of the classical theory of democracy coined by Joseph Schum-

peter (1987: 250-268.). One of them is Robert Dahl’s pluralist democracy, in which the political

process is indicated and controlled by the independent and competing interest in society, which

set bounds to the tyranny of the majority and minority (Dahl 1956: 63-89.; 1982). Another popu-

lar approach of representative democracy is the aggregative democracy and the theory of median

voter brought to life by Anthony Downs. According to this view the political process is deter-

mined by the ex-ante given popular will, which is created by office-orientated politicians with the

aggregation of preferences, designing compromise and finding the median voter. (Downs 1957)

The idea of referendum democracy could be matched logically to this theory, which can be de-

scribe as a set of political actions concentrated around a vote on a ballot question, plebiscite or an

election. Here, compared to the previous concept, there is more focus on the aggregation of votes,

the institution of election and parties, but less on participation. Thus the quality of participation

decreases, because the number of negotiable issues and the depth of negotiations are limited.

In this process the non-conventional political actors, such as movements are valorized,

who use various campaigns to follow direct decision situations. In the Dahlian polyarchy the

different interest groups got equal access to governance. Accordingly, the necessity of independ-

ent organizations lay upon the plural interest articulation and mutual control. In the Downsian

aggregative democracy the associations from society and economy as lobby organizations, aim

to overcome the world of incomplete information. They inherently possess extra information.

They are more sensitive for the changes of preferential environment than established parties.

Consequently, the direction of process is vertical and bottom-up; the relationship with established

political actors is asymmetric, which is in favor of them because of the general hunger for infor-

mation. Hence the movements are established to entry politics to influence political decision.

However, the neoclassical approaches also take us onto thin ice. There are two clearly

distinguishable difficulties to face. The first is the uncertainty of the relationship. The interests

and relatively strong preferences transmitted by movements can unexpectedly emerge – out of

nowhere –, but could also suddenly disappear. The question could easily arise from the profes-

sional politicians: ‘How reasonable it would be to support a movement, if the investment may

not prove a long- lasting one?’ One further question is how the incumbents can be sure that the

preferences of the activists are similar to the median voters. It is clear, that such decisions are

really fraught with enormous risks. Uncertainty is further strengthened by the fact that move-

Page 7: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

7

ments don’t have a stable, durable formal institutional framework and decision-making mecha-

nism (moreover it’s nearly amorphous) which makes the mutual accountability impossible. In

such situation with dubious out- comes the political stakes are high.

The second difficulty is the high costs associated with collective action. In his works,

Albert O. Hirschman (1970; 1985) takes account of costs for both sides’. For the traditional ac-

tors it is expensive to maintain the citizens’ loyalty, which leads them from desertion and exodus

to protests, in which they formulate, articulate their messages about their changing preferences.

The exit could mean emigration or seeking and joining a new political force (Hirschman 1970).

In parallel the costs of activist appear in getting over the disappointment. The political apathy

(exit) and participation, as two forms of political activity stem from each other’s disappoint-

ment. If the magnitude of disappointment in the public sphere, the intensity of political conflict

exceeds the costs of the action, the citizens vote with their feet (Hirschman 1985). The junction

of the two cycles of collective action shows antagonistic pictures. Because this frustration is im-

plicitly possessed by decreasing of the trust and fidelity, therefore the question could arise,

should the activists protest and introduce new information or desert. The objection creates the

need for change inside the organization and institution. Thus in spite of the disappointment the

fidelity is sustainable. Here costs grow in a greater extent for the activists, because dissatisfac-

tion is neither to great, nor the cost of loyalty increases drastically. However exit is cheaper for

movements, because the greater disillusionment undermines trust utterly. Hence, the costs of

maintaining loyalty raise significantly. Thus the movements as potential sources of information

are expensive for everyone. Nevertheless, there are less expensive, more accurate and reliable

sources (regular surveys and polls). Moreover as a result the independence of movements without

conventional sources is also questioned, which is a critical component of this approach.5

To sum up, both the deliberative-participative and the neoclassical conception of movements are

encumbered by many contradictions; therefore they cannot explain the function and role of col-

lective action sufficiently. However, these theories, as logically separated paradigms of de-

mocracy, weren’t undermined. In the following part of the study a more realistic conception is

provided, which could be helpful to get a more comprehensive picture about this phenomenon.

Page 8: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

8

II. THE MOVEMENT CONTCEPT OF LEADERDEMOCRACY

The first two approaches are based on the idea of self-governance. According to the Weberian

and Schumpeterian theory of democracy, which try to go beyond this, political processes are kept

in motion not by the voters’ preferences and the interests of social groups, but by the leaders and

aspi- rations and ambitions of the political elite. Therefore, they are the active actors in poli-

tics, whose aim is not the building of consensus or compromise but to acquire and maintain polit-

ical support. In the electoral race they don’t take their cue from the preferential environment cre-

ated by citizens, but they rather form, shape or manipulate that, (Körösényi 2009:b; 2010) be-

cause the voters are not so competent and informed as it is assumed and required (Schumpeter

1987). Thus the ex-post originated preferences are produced by the vertical and top-down politi-

cal process. Adam Przeworski’s minimalist definition of democracy gives the normative ground

for this theory. According to him the only sufficient expectation of democracy is that the citi-

zens are able to replace the bad and in- competent leaders through elections without bloodshed

(Körösényi, 2005; 2009:d; Pakulski- Körösényi, 2012; Przeworski, 1999).

The protest democracy, is logically related to this theory, which emphasizes that collec-

tive actions or activist participation are generated directly or indirectly by the political elite and

leaders. The focus of action is placed on the demonstrations, protests or other forms of public

involvements, which express political will and ‘power’. Hence, the content of participation, un-

like other models presented so far, is very shallow and limited. According to the conception the

leader has a critical role in collective action whether we speak about internal or external leader-

ship. The literature (Aminzade, 2001; Barker et al., 2001; Goldstone 2001; Morris – Staggenborg.

2004; Pappas. 2008; Rucht, 2012) emphasizes uniformly, that there are some functions that only

the leaders are able to effectively fill. Beyond simple technical and organizational duties they

have also some cosmological task to deal with. The leaders set the agenda, identify problems,

introduce new narratives, set goals, give reasons for them and assign tools to them and decide

who are their allies as well as who could be counted as an adversary. Moreover they trigger and

focus the construction of collective action and identity.

The model thus allows less room for movements and for direct participation in general.

On the one hand, the audience of the movements fits into a mostly one-sided communication

scheme. The various actions, such as protests are can be characterized mostly responsive. In

demonstrations not everyone can give a speech, or take part in actions like occupying private or

public buildings because of the limitation of the temporal and spatial constraints, the asymmetry

of strength of preferences and the unequal distribution of information and competences. After

all, some people are born with rhetorical skills, while others do not possess such abilities; in

Page 9: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

9

addition some of them feel a strong urge to go public, while others are not desperate and manful

enough to act in the same way. However the leaders have to pay attention to the audience and

its reactions. The expected effects can easily fail, the enthusiasm could disappear, and moreover

the speech could go wrong and be- come counterproductive, if it does not meet the most basic

requirements of the participants. There- fore, the leaders’ personal skills are especially important

(Grint 2001), which become one of the key catalysts of collective action.

The asymmetry is another critical aspect of Weberian and Schumpeterian approach

stemmed from the political monopoly (monopoly on violence and monopolistic political mar-

ket). Political decisions could be the catalysts and the medicine for problems, crisis situations and

conflicts as well as produce directly or indirectly collective actions at the same time. Most of the

movements respond to an undesirable decision or miss a particular decision. Therefore, the key to

the solution and thus the real political action is in the hands of politicians. Because of the short-

age of resources they are, who consider, which decisions are important and which ones are not.

They choose the issues to deal with, and to support according to their own interests. They calcu-

late the possible consequences of their decisions. On the other hand, the incumbents possess mo-

nopoly over the legitimate use of power. Thus they are the only ones, who could change and in-

fluence the political opportunity structure which mostly determinates the success of movements.

This notion, introduced by Peter Eisinger and conceptualized by many (Meyer-Minkoff 2004),

refers to the circumstance that the appearance, strategies, institutionalization, the dominant or-

ganizational form, and the nature of mobilization of movements depend on the political environ-

ment and context (Rucht 1996). Here we could mention the political culture (cleavages, will-

ingness to participate, institutional trust), the party system and the level and effect of access to

policy decision-making, the policy effectiveness of government and the nature of political com-

petition. Unlike other social and cultural factors all of these could be easier influenced by the

political elite. Beyond the simple institutional changes made by laws, the elite choose the way of

competition, the relevant cleavages and the openness of political process. All of these are the

result of political decisions. Consequently, the incumbents can shape the structure of oppor-

tunities with more success than the movements themselves, which makes them strongly de-

termined.

The reactive and determinative nature of movements suggests that in this view the agency

looks more decisive than structure; however we cannot separate the environment from the actor.

As I mentioned above the political movement is not an element of normal politics, which is mo-

nopolized by constituted and establish actors, such as the political elite, entrenched interest

groups, bureaucratic parties, rigid institutionalized procedures, the principle of representation,

Page 10: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

10

and parliamentary-electoral process. In ordinary times politics run with low popular participation,

civic privatism, depoliticization and passivity and this process is carried out mostly by profes-

sional bureaucrats and technocrats. On the contrary in cases of extraordinary politics or in the

state of emergency or exception the conventions are breached, and processes become unpredicta-

ble, uncertainty and risks grow dramatically. In these circumstances the level of collective mobi-

lization is higher, leading to the emergence of irregular political actors and informal public spac-

es, extra-institutional groups, which directly challenge the established balance of forces and the

political status quo (Kalyvas 2008:6-7.). As Andreas Kalyvas highlighted “the democratic poli-

tics of the extraordinary refers to those infrequent and unusual moments when the citizenry,

overflowing the formal borders of institutionalized politics, reflectively aims at the modification

of the central political, symbolic, and constitutional principles and at the redefinition of the con-

tent and ends of a community.” (Kalyvas 2008:7)

The Weberian ‘charismatic movement’ arises at this point, when constituted and institu-

tionalized leadership, authority fails to define the situation characterized by dissatisfaction and

distress. Therefore the movements dedicate themselves to change through reforms or revolutions.

They pro- vide a new narrative, a new diagnose of the situation focusing upon such circumstanc-

es that do not even exist, but in which people are willing to believe. In the same time they pro-

pose changes and publicly urge their acceptance. They challenge the existing widespread system

of beliefs and values that maintain the legitimacy of the political and juridical order, before this

‘revolutionary’ moment spill over into the dimension of polity (Kalyvas 2008, Tucker 1968;

1977: 384-385.; 1995). Tucker in his work summarizes this phenomenon, and calls it ‘situational

charisma’ “Why leaders of movements for change would often be the objects of such loyalty and

enthusiasm is understandable: the leader, by virtue of personal attributes combined with the diag-

nosis of the situation as wrong but remediable and the formula for remedying it, embodies in the

minds of distressed followers the promise of salvation from distress, a way out of the impasse

that confronts them and the society. In short, a charismatic leader is the one perceived by the

followers as a savior, a messiah.” (Tucker 1995: 94.) Thus it seems necessary for leaders of

movements to create a symbiotic relationship with this context as many students of leadership

(Grint 2001; Greenstein 1992; Nye 2008, Schabert 2005). However, in such extraordinary and

uncertain environment characterized by perpetual motion, chaos the situational charisma (Tucker

1968: 743-44.) contextual intelligence (Nye 2008), and creativity (Schabert 2005) is far more

important than in normality, when the politics are predictable due to well-functioning institutions

and procedures. In this aspect leaders use the power, force of movements to define the situation

nationwide and introduce narrative and possible screenplays for change.

Page 11: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

11

Hence, the engine of collective action, the dominant ‘agency’ is the political leader and

the elite of movement, who are not aggregating and articulating the various interests or partici-

pating in a societal deliberation, but are joining to a wider political competition. In this point of

view the movements are just tools in the hand of leaders, which they try to shape their environ-

ment (preferences, agenda, and legitimation) and invest more sources with. Therefore, the per-

sonal skills and abilities of leaders are valorized and became more and more critical. It largely

depends on them, if the mass becomes ‘crowds of demonstrators’ (Mills 1956: 309.) and will be

successful, but they de- pend on their follower as well.

II.1. The need for leadership

In the foregoing, I have presented the inherent relationship and interdependence of movements

and leadership. As it could be seen the nature of extraordinary, extra-institutional politics makes it

inevitable that the actors understand properly changing environments, capitalize on trends, and

use the flow of events to implement strategies. In the following, therefore I examine the motiva-

tions of leaders, movements and established parties especially in the light of empirically ob-

served trends, which encourage them externally to develop transformation and use seemingly

new tools and methods. In this sense, I will set up four arguments for the need for leadership.

They are the following: the argument of assimilation, legitimacy, identity and mass communica-

tion.

The argument of assimilation

According to the argument of assimilation, based on the theory of Robert Michels, entering into

the political space is a kind of ‘self-transformation’ for movements, in which they are forced to

con- form to the habits and norms of their competitors by such structural factors as participation

in political discourse, conditions of being visible in media, electoral system, and the parliamen-

tary work. Due to taking over the rules of the game the movements transform to so-called ‘latent

movements’ (Kitchelt 1993), ‘pseudo-movements’ (Kolinsky-Patterson 1976: 336.) or ‘move-

ment parties’ (Gunther-Diamond 2003). However, they became highly formalized and institu-

tionalized, and they do not have any or enough strong affection for movements, they make

claims for the identity of movements. The phenomenon is presented perfectly by the constant

waves of green, New Left and radical right, far right-wing and populist movements. But this

professionalization benefits mostly the leaders. The people with stronger political ambition and

ability emerge in front of us, while others scuttle, step aside or even go against the organization.

Other good, spectacular examples are the movements of the Central and Eastern European tran-

sition. Most of them provided a perfect base and preference points for the new party systems as

well as a perfect springboard for leaders, such as Lech Wałęsa, Václav Havel, Vladimír Mečiar,

Page 12: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

12

József Antall and Viktor Orbán.

This compulsive metamorphosis is determined by the above-mentioned opportunity struc-

ture. Two ways of institutionalization are given for the movements, which mostly depend on

the kind of role in which they could represent their interests effectively. In a weak (two-)party

system the explicit and implicit entry thresholds are high and the parties do not prevail in the

space of politics. The appearance of a third party is nearly impossible, thus the movements rather

petrify and become pressure or interest groups. In Hirschmanian sense, the possible ways to ‘es-

cape’ are diminished, thus there is no other choice than to protest and fit in the background world

of parties. In a strong (multi-)party system, the thresholds are traditionally lower and the parties

are more dominant. The movements here take advantage of the opportunity to exercise greater

influence, and thus they turn easily into parties. (Tarrow 1991: 20; Rucht 1996., Kitschelt 1993:

27-28) This doesn’t mean that parties do not dominate the movement sector in both cases, they

just do it in a different way (as we will see in the next point.) Diarmuid Maguire (1995) shows

how both the British Campaign for Nuclear Disarmament (CND) and the Italian peace move-

ment depended on support from established parties. The CND initially grew and seemed likely to

gain success when the Labour Party supported it externally; and yet as soon as Labour literally

decided to end the partnership, its chances for success dropped to zero and its support dried up.

The Italian peace movement had an even weaker position, because it “could emerge only within

PCI (Italian Communist Party) support, and it was organizationally and financially dependent on

the party” (1995: 225.).

The argument of legitimacy

There are two revealing tendencies connected to parties and leaders. Firstly, we can observe the

functional change or decay of parties in the last two decades. During cartelization (Katz-

Mair 2001.) parties secede or move away from their social roots and invade and occupy the state,

also simultaneously, the growth of partisan de-alignment and the decline in party membership

and the weakening public trust in direct political institutions can be observed (Dalton - Kuechler

1990; Dalton - Wattenberg 2000; della Porta 2012). Another trend is emerging of political leaders

informally and formally from their parties and government, which diminish the political weight

of parliament and the representative institutions (Poguntke – Webb 2005; Webb et al. 2012).

The occupation of the state and centralization in party organization are critical aspects of

the cartelization. On the one hand this blurs the difference between the party members and

non-members, which entails unavoidably the decline of party membership. On the other hand,

the party moves away from civil society and becomes independent, which also increases the vot-

er’s disillusionment and political apathy. In parallel, presidentialization highlights the leaders in

Page 13: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

13

parties and government, which weakens the legislature. Putting together these tendencies we can

see, that politics can run into a ‘vacuum’ because the leaders and their parties lose their legitimate

base. Another consequence is the above-mentioned appearance of movement parties. The differ-

ent party types interact with each other and take up each other's habits. Thus the establishment

actors’ motivation draws reverse direction from that follows the argument of assimilation (Dalton

– Kuechler 1990; Katz-Mair 2001):

The politicians try to cure this legitimation crisis by taking over tactics from movement

par- ties’, so they proceed to spin-off strategy or ‘activist enterprise’. The leaders are ‘forced’ to

seek a connection with society in a more populistic way. They create a movement or find already

existing ones to lead, to get around the unpopular parties. Such self-legitimation strategy of lead-

ers was/is quite common in totalitarian regimes, where the political elite tries/tried to borrow and

gain the credibility of the political system with mass events (Nuremberg Rally, the International

Workers’ Day in the communist era) and movements (youth and female movements of ruling

parties). Martin Kolinsky and William E. Patterson use the notion of quasi-movement (1976:

336.) to describe those movements, which typically emerge from inside organization and institu-

tion and because of this relationship is based on loyalty the movement identity cannot develop

properly. Roberta Ash Garner and Mayer N. Zald (1987: 312.) highlight through the instances

of Italian Communist Party (PCI) and France Communist Party (PCF) that the creating of quasi-

movements characterizes typically the strongly centralized parties. The political elite and leaders

have made an attempt to use this symbolical power (Pappas, 2008) for example with the left-

wing Civil Circles, Civil Unity Forum and their peace marches and Democratic Charta in Hunga-

ry or with the American Tea Party in the US.

The argument of identity

A collective identity enables the harmonic relationship between leaders and followers, which

underlies collective action and leadership (Boda 2013; Grint 2001). As Keith Grint highlights that

“imaginary communities may well be considerably stronger than ‘real’ communities” (Grint,

2001:6.). Under the conditions of decay traditional social institutions (Fromm 1968), disappeared

with classical mass parties so modern people have completely or partially lost their identity

which has grounded their rituals and existence leading them in a ’identity-vacuum’, which could

easily cause existential dread or distress. Thus creating collective identity satisfies essential psy-

chological needs for safety, and reduces the costs of participation. For example Gandhi with his

movements introduced a new collective identity for the people of India, on which the societal

and political changes were based.

Page 14: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

14

Belonging to a community provides the psychological need of experiencing simultane-

ously the difference and sameness of people as well. In this sense, participation, going public

with your own preferences, results in long lasting and stable self- persuasion, since a safe envi-

ronment and the feeling of sameness are positive feedbacks for the individual. Thus, the cycle of

mobilization and realization of participation is a self-perpetuating process, which stabilizes and

strengthens the individuals’ preferences and identity. The collective action not just amplifies the

subjective sense of security, but it also offers benefits from the success of the movement and the

mobilized power and energy. In the case of intense conflicts these relative benefits definitely

increase, because the political stake grows and the changes that are desired to realize are divisive.

Therefore they are not favorable and beneficial for everyone. In addition, collective identity en-

sures goals and life experiences for the activists (Castells 2010). These orientation points and

schemes of interpretation reduce the costs of participation. A similar phenomenon is shown by

Downs, who points out, that ideological scope and self- identification cure the expensive deci-

sion of joining a movement in situations characterized by the lack of information. Thus it could

be easy to fill the gaps of knowledge with narratives. In this sense identity is a kind of setting

pattern for preference. Their strength, which Hirschman saw in the intensity of disappointment,

determines and sets the collective action, i.e. the stronger the preferences we have, the more like-

ly we will take a part in an action. (Berelson 1952: 317.; Sartori 1987: 118-120.). The aim of

movements and leaders is clear: they must strengthen the preferences to reduce the variation of

preferences and reactions which in turn increases the possibility for the realization of participa-

tion.

In tense situations and conflicts identity is even more important. In these situations the

collectively created protection and political force become more and more valuable to individuals.

The trends discussed above suggest that in these situations established political identities, tradi-

tional institutions such as parties lose their power to create identity. In Castel’s identity typology

(2010: 6-12.) these are called legitimizing identities, while movements are connected to re-

sistance and project identity. The legitimizing identity is introduced by the dominant institutions

to extend and rationalize their domination and to realize their authority. The resistance identity is

generated by those actors who are in positions/conditions devalued and/or stigmatized by the

logic of domination so they are forced to build trenches of resistance and survive. While the pro-

ject identity is focused on creating a brand new identity, which redefines the position of move-

ments in society and seeks the transformation of overall social structure. The question is clear:

What kind of reaction could be triggered if the dominant societal and political organizations lost

their ability to create and sustain identity. The suspicion is strong, that in this case, which shows

Page 15: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

15

weakening parties and representative institutions, the race for creating identity to fill the vacuum

becomes more and more general. This struggle aggravates the conflicts and the political land-

marks which could keep them under control and on track disappear. In this situation, the demand

increases to build distinctive identity such as movements do.

In a social and political sense identities are always constructed (Castells 2010; Grint

2001) The role of the leader is critical in creating, stabilizing and strengthening identity (Boda

2013; Grint 2001). This could be linked to Burns’ (1978) transformative leader, which contrary

to the transactional leader’s pragmatic approach reinforces the internal motivations of the mem-

bers, shares his vision, establishes common goals, these also give meaning to the actions and

makes it a special experience. A specific form of this is moral leadership, extends the identity

with (quasi-)universal values, such as the nation, the people, the freedom, the equality or the

justice. With these kinds of incentives the political stake of the action always decrease, which

clearly stimulates the citizens to act as it is needed. The leader constructs identities to make the

behavior of followers more and more predictable and to achieve desired obedience easier and

cheaper. Thus he stabilizes his environment and determinates the range of triggered responses.

It is worth mentioning the implications of the ‘us and them’ distinction. The identi-

ty- building leaders often refer to this dichotomy, which implies that the leaders’ politics and

communication tend toward populism. Nevertheless, anti-establishment political atmosphere and

populism are closely related phenomena. (Ilonszki-Lengyel 2009: 9., Szabó 2007:a: 1246-

1247.; 2007:b: 176-178., Körösényi et al. 2007: 328.) Without reference to ideological orienta-

tion, populism - and its logical roots – is observable in every movement because of strong identi-

cal frames. If we distinguish ourselves from the political and economic elite on the basis of that

we – the people, the nation, the working class, a group of environmentalists or feminists – are

more competent than who exercise the power, therefore we should govern and it doesn’t matter

for what reason – because of specific knowledge (intellectuals, environmentalists) or experience

(farmers, laborers) we hold our- selves more competent.

Page 16: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

16

1. figure: The motivations of actors

The argument of mass communication

The media and the political movements mutually depend on each other. (Vliegenthart – Wal-

grave 2012) In the politics structured by media the aim of competition is not just for political

positions, but also for media attendance and attention, since if we are not shown or our massages

are not transmitted by TV or radio channels or the press, than we don’t simply exist in a political

sense. (Mazzoleni 2002: 91.) The movements, as not or barely institutionalized actors, have an

asymmetric relation with media. Thus in every situation they always have to struggle for the

attention, for the only way to reach their potential supporters with their massages. It is relatively

easy to see, that for the movements to be presented by the media it is necessary for them to live

and be alive. There-fore the movements generally build their own network of media, which is

even more important, if they are marginalized by the political elite and/or media.

In the mediatized political environment the trends, which we can experience such as tab-

loidization and personalization (Kiss 2003), suggest that the demand is increasing for extraordi-

Page 17: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

17

nary political events. Therefore mass media also needs movements to produce with their

actions for news. It is really difficult to get into the declining numbers of political news with

simple parliamentary work. Thus the political actors try to exceed the established political prac-

tice, create scandals and attract attention. With mobilizations and actions they direct attention to

specific issues to create decision-making situations, set the agenda and provide alternatives. This

can be illustrated by different kinds of parliamentary performances – such as showing up news-

papers, signs and banners or throwing notes, wearing badges of movements – or even with the

use of physical aggression (fights in Ukrainian or South-Korean parliament).

II.2. Limits and lessons of conception

The movement concept of leader democracy compared to the approaches discussed so far seems

to be a more realistic view of the collective action. However, this doesn’t mean that this approach

is certainly the panacea of collective action because of its own normative and empirical limits.

However conflict is an inherent part of politics, but it doesn’t necessary’s lead to blood-

shed as the normative ground of concept, the minimalist definition of democracy suggests. The

only guarantee to preventing this outcome is the procedure of election, through which the citizens

can change the bad leader to a better one. They requite good leaders for their service and bad

ones for their perfidy. This means that activism should not cause violence because it would go

beyond the minimum limits of democracy. However, this might still happen: for instance demo-

cratic transition in Romania, the anti-globalization protest called ‘Battle of Seattle’ in 1999, the

Hungarian anti- governmental protest, called ‘Hot Fall’ in 2006, Arab Spring in 2011, protests

in Turkey in 2013 and the Ukrainian ‘Euromaiden’ and so on. The degree of violence, which is

analytically connected to extraordinary politics, depends greatly on the magnitude of change ar-

ticulated by movements. Based on Schmitt’s popular assemblies and Arendt’s voluntary associa-

tions and civil disobedience Kalyvas (2008) underlined that in a democratic framework these

‘self-organized’ political entities are extra institutional, but not always extraconstitutional, like-

wise Tucker, who distinguishes reform and revolutionary movements (1995:77-113.). Still

permanent fight is an essential element of movement’s, along with struggle and the use of co-

ercion and verbal or even physical violence. Therefore movements are still double-edged swords,

which make them so uncertain and an elusive phenomenon from the view point of democracy.

This is not a simple critic of the leader democracy’ movement concept, because it shows that

movements are fundamentally related to politics and not just to democratic societies. Thus with

a broader set of normative frames we are able to understand the nature, role and function of

movements not just in democratic contexts but also in more critical circumstances such as civil

wars, revolutions and coups or even in non-democratic regimes.

Page 18: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

18

On an empirical level the concept trembles also, in cases when the leaders cannot be seen

or observed. The problem of invisible leadership could easily arise in the case of movements,

which ideologically reject leadership, for instance in alternative, New Left and green movements.

The task of researchers can be even more difficult if the movement hadn’t reached the level of

publicity yet, where their organizational features, such as decision making, external and internal

communication and the elite of the movement had already been outlined. Dieter Rucht (2012)

emphasizes that a minimal leadership is unavoidable, even if the ideology of the group

doesn’t allow somebody to lead explicitly, visibly and relevantly. There are two cases men-

tioned by the author. The first, when an informal leadership has been developed like Marcos for

Zapatista Army of National Liberation. The second, when the members of the movement scru-

pulously ensure to avoid leadership, but a core of the members or an informal elite exit(s) in

this case too, who fulfills these crucial functions. Of course, in such an environment other styles

of leadership could be realized compered to leader- centric typically right-wing groups, which is

actually pointed out by the follower/context/situation- centric leadership theories (Hollander

1992; for a review see Bass, 1990; Goethals 2004). According to Colin Barker (et al. 2001:b: 1-

4.) the critical problem in activists social movement research, in which activists write for activ-

ists about movements, is the dominant and prevailing, underlining assumptions against leader-

ship. Therefore, if we rejected the importance or denied the existence of leadership, claiming the

leader to be invisible or even irrelevant, we would miss the opportunity to understand or recog-

nize leadership in a contingent environment, which produced the non- institutionalized move-

ments and contemporary tendencies mentioned above.

III. CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS

So far we have seen what kind of movement concepts the direct democratic forms associated with

theories of democracy implicate, and what controversies they face. These approaches due to the

different presumptions and logic they approach emphasize on other dimension or segment of col-

lective action. In the deliberative and neoclassical concept of democracy politics/policy or pro-

cedures – the deliberation and the aggregation of independent interests and preferences – are far

more important, than results and consequences, because the proper, appropriate methods not just

result, but also legitimate the decisions and answers. Conversely, in the leader democracy goals

determine the available means, which is the case in political movements as well. These goals,

according to my argumentation are always political: seeking and getting power, creating and

using political force, influencing the preferences and political processes.

Page 19: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

19

Looking through the concepts and their theoretical and empirical contradictions we can

see that the leader democracy theory can capture the nature of movements the most compre-

hensively, as it draws a more realistic picture than the others. This mainly stems from its mini-

malist normative requirements that give more space to act freely and more opportunity for being

creative and using close to anything as a tool. According to my starting statement the nature of

movements is vertical and top-down in practice and movements typically enrich the toolbar of

political leaders. This relationship between the master and the means, as I have stressed earli-

er in different dimensions, is based on interdependence. As a musician depends on his instru-

ment, so does the leader on his movements and followers. But, how nice and perfect the music is

mostly rests on the skills, creativity and knowledge of the musicians. Thus the leader is no leader

without its followers, but the mean would also become easily dysfunctional, if it is not connected

to political will, creativity and desire. In this sense movements are a result of the

(re)constructing of followers, which is beneficial for both sides.

The aim of this study primarily was to reflect to the question of the relationship between

democracy and movements, which is surrounded by growing interest from the academia, (della

Porta 2005; 2009; 2012; 2013; della Porta - Diani 2006. 239-245.; della Porta - Rucht 2013) the

leadership in movements (Aminzade 2001; Barker et al. 2001; Goldstone 2001; Morris – Stag-

genborg 2004; Pappas. 2008; Rucht 2012), as well as the normative biases associated to move-

ments. In addition, during research the need formulated latently to set up a new horizon for lead-

ership studies. Associating the political leadership- and movement research can have major po-

tential. It is not difficult to see that leadership is not simply about leaders, but rather is a complex

social and political process and relation. Without elucidating the followers and the environment

and context of political action it is unimaginable to draw a realistic picture about leadership

(Blondel 1987; Burns 1978; Grint 2001). However without leadership we cannot understand po-

litical action as Aristotle pointed out political activity splits out leadership and followership but if

somebody wants to rule, then he should first have been ruled (Arist.PA VII.14, 1332b15-1333a

trans. C.D.C. Reeve) Thus the socio- logical movement research with its stable means and con-

cepts should be treated carefully and a leadership theory stemmed from democratic theory com-

plement each other. On the whole, my theoretical work may open a door for future research in

this area of political science.

Page 20: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

20

Table 1. The three movement conception

Direct democracy Referendum democracy Protest democracy

Theoret-

ical

frame-

work

Deliberative democracy Neoclassical democracy Leader democracy

Input Rational individuals and communities

Self-interest orientated individ-ual and independent associa-tions

Irrational, incompetent individuals’ mass, crowds of demonstrators and ac-tivists, political leaders

Direction of col-

lective action Horizontal, bottom-up Vertical, bottom-up Vertical, top-down

Emphasis of ac-

tion

Procedure orientated Procedure orientated Goal orientated

Scope and depth

of action Broad and comprehensive Narrow (case specific) and

partly comprehensive Narrow (case specific) and shallow

Nature of action Self-governance based on true active participation, direct interactions, inter-personal relation- ships.

Self-governance through direct decision (voting)on certain is-sues, which is framed by civil campaigns and lobbying

Collective actions are based on direct – activist

- participation, which

are initiated, catalyzed

and utilized by political

leaders

Role of move-

ment Independent, autonomous participants and forum of deliberation, rival of repre-sentative institutions

Movements are partly inde-pendent, but complement nec-essarily the representative insti-tutional procedure

Movements are depend-ent, determined and just a tool for demonstrating force in the hand of lead-ers, which makes them rivals of representative institution

Party-

movement re-

lation

Symmetric, equal Asymmetric and movement dominated

Asymmetric and party (leader) dominated

1 This requires a minimal definition of direct democracy. We could define it as participation without medi-

ation in a political process (demonstration), a policy decision (referendum, strike) or a mixture of them

(town meeting) without reference to effectiveness of action as well as the quality and nature of participa-

tion. 2 By political leader(s), I mean one more person, who play(s) active and dominant role in interpersonal

relations permanently or temporarily. This specific interactions and behavior could be called leadership. 3 The notion of contentious politics denotes this disruptive phenomenon, which refers to the coercion

which lies in collective action (Tilly-Tarrow, 2007: 4-11.). 4 Story of Wael Ghoneim illustrates perfectly this phenomenon. Ghoneim was an employee of Google,

who was mobilizing Egyptian society on Facebook which became later a revolution. 5 This dilemma arise when the ‘astrosturf’ Tea Party financed and initiated by Republicans, Occupy Wall

Street movement financed and initiated by anti-consumerist and pro-environment Adbusters Media Foun-

dation or oppositional movements in European hybrid regimes (Slovakian OK’98, Serbian Otpor , Geor-

gian Kmart, Croatian Glas 99 and Ukrainian Pora supported by Western Foundations had appeared.

Page 21: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

21

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Aminzade, Ronald R. – Goldstone, Jack A. – Perry, Elizabeth J. (2001): „Leadership Dynamics and

the Dynamics of Contention.” In: Aminzade, Ronald R. – Goldstone, Jack A. – McAdam, Doug –

Perry, Elizabeth J. – Sewell, William H. – Tarrow, Sidney – Tilley, Charles (eds.): Silence and Voice

in the Study of Contentious Politics, Cambridge, Cam- bridge University Press

Arendt, Hannah (1975): The origins of totalitarianism, New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich

Aristotle (384-322 B.C./1998): Politics. (trans. C.D.C. Reeve) Hackett P.C.:Indianapolis, Cambridge

Barker, Colin – Johnson, Alan – Lavalette, Michael (eds.) (2001): Leadership in Social Movements.

Manchester – New York, Manchester University Press

Bass, Bernard M. (1990): Bass & Stogdill's handbook of leadership: theory, research, and managerial

applications. New York : Free Press

Berelson, Bernard (1952): „Democratic Theory and Public Opinion.” The Public Opinion Quarterly,

Vol. 16, No.3 (Autumn), pp. 313-330.

Berelson, Bernard – Lazarsfeld, Paul F. – McPhee, William N. (1954): Voting: a Study of Opinion

Formation in a Presidential Campaign. Chicago, University of Chicago Press

Blondel, Jean, (1987): Political Leadership, London: Sage.

Boda Zsolt (2013): Legitimitás, bizalom, együttműködés. Kollektív cselekevés a politikában. Budapest:

Argumentum.

Burns, James MacGregor (1978): Leadership. Harper and Row, New York.

Castells, Manuel (2010): The power of identity. Cambridge, Mass: Blackwell

Dahl, Robert A. (1956): A Preface to Democratic Theory. Chicago - London, The University of Chicago

Press

Dahl, Robert A. (1982): Dilemmas of pluralist democracy: autonomy vs. control New Haven : Yale

University Press

Dalton, Russell J. – Kuechler, Manfred (eds.) (1990): Challenging the Political Order: New Social and

Political Movements in Western Democracies. Cambridge, Polity Press

Dalton, Russell J. – Wattenberg, Martin P. (eds.) (2000): Parties without Partisans: Political Change

in Advanced Industrial Democracies. Oxford, Oxford University Press

della Porta, Donatella (2005): „Making the Polis: Social Forums and Democracy in the Global Justice

Movement” Mobilization, Vol. 10. No. 2.73–94. pp.

della Porta, Donatella (2009): “Democracy in Movement: Some Conclusions.” In: della Porta,

Donatella (eds.): Democracy in Social Movements. Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan, 262-274. pp.

della Porta, Donatella (2012): Critical Trust: Social Movements and Democracy in Times of Crisis

Cambio Anno II, Numero 4/Dicembre

della Porta, Donatella (2013): Can democracy be saved?: participation, deliberation and social

movements, Cam- bridge, Polity Press,

della Porta, Donatella – Diani, Mario (2006): Social movements: an introduction. Malden, Blackwell

Publishing

della Porta, Donatella – Rucht, Dieter (2013): Meeting democracy : power and deliberation in

Page 22: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

22

global justice movements, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

Downs, Anthony (1957): An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York, Harper & Row

Elster, Jon (1997): “The Market and the Forum.” Three Varieties of Political Theory. In: Bohman,

James – Rehg, William (eds.): Deliberative Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1997:

pp. 3-34.

Elster, Jon (1998): “Introduction.” In: Elster, Jon (eds.): Deliberative Democracy. Cambridge,

Cambridge University Press, pp. 1-19.

Femia, Joe (2009): “Elites vs. the Popular Will: a False Dichotomy.” In: Femia, J. – Körösényi, A. –

Slomp, G. (eds.): Political Leadership in Liberal and Democratic Theory, Exeter, Imprint Academic,

pp. 67-78.

Flacks, Richard (1994): “The Party’s Over – So What Is to be Done?” In: Larana, Enrique – Johnston,

Hank – Gusfield, Joseph R. (eds.): New Social Movements: from Ideology to Identity. Philadelphia,

Temple University Press, pp. 330-

351.

Fromm, Erich (1968): Escape from freedom. New York: Avon Books

Garner, Roberta Ash – Zald, Mayer N. (1987): The Political Economy of Social Movement Sectors. In:

Mayer N. Zald - John D. McCarthy (eds.): Social movements in an organizational society: collected

essays, New Brunswick: Transac- tion Publishers, 293-318.

Goethals, George R. – Sorenson, Georgia L. (2004): Encyclopedia of Leadership 4 vol. set. London:

Sage

Goldstone, Jack A. (2001): Toward a Fourth Generation of Revolutionary Theory. Annual Review of

Political Science Vol. 4: pp. 139-187

Goldstone, Jack A. (eds.) (2003): States, Parties, and Social Movements. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press, 2003.

Greenstein, Fred I. (1992): Can Personality and Politics Be Studied Systematically? Political

Psychology, Vol. 13, No. 1. (Mar., 1992), pp. 105-128.

Grint, Keith (2001): The Arts of Leadership. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Gunther, Richard – Diamond, Larry (2003): “Species of Political Parties.” A New Typology. Party

Politics vol. 9 no. 2: pp. 167-199. Gutmann, Amy – Thompson, Dennis (1996): Democracy and

disagreement. Cambridge, Belknap Press of Harvard University Press

Hollander, Edwin P. (1992): Leadership, followership, self, and others. The Leadership Quarterly

Volume 3, Issue 1, Spring 1992, pp. 43–54

Hirschman, Albert O. (1970): Exit, voice, and loyalty: responses to decline in firms, organizations,

and states. Cam- bridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press

Hirschman, Albert O. (1985): Shifting involvements : private interest and public action. Oxford :

Blackwell

Ilonszki Gabriella – Lengyel György (2009): “Válaszúton: konszolidált vagy színlelt demokrácia?”

Politikatudományi Szemle 1. szám pp. 7–25.

Jenkins, J. Craig – Klandermans, Bert (eds.) (1995): The Politics of Social Protest. Comparative

Perspctives on States and Social Movements. London, University College London

Page 23: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

23

Kalyvas, Andreas (2008): Democracy and the politics of the extraordinary: Max Weber, Carl

Schmitt, and Hannah Arendt; Cambridge: Cambridge University Press

Katz, Richard S. – Mair, Peter (2001): “A pártszervezet változó modelljei és a pártdemokrácia.”

Politikatudományi Szemle 3. szám, pp. 131–156.

Kiss Balázs (2003): “Kampány és tabloidizáció. A perszonalizáció jelensége.” In: Sárközy Erika-

Schleicher Nóra (eds.): Kampánykommunikáció. Budapest, Akadémiai Kiadó, pp. 9-40.

Kitschelt, Herbert (1993): “Social Movements, Political Parties, and Democratic Theory.” Annals

of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 528, Citizens, Protest, and Democracy,

1993/Jul., pp. 13-29.

Kriesi, Hanspeter – Koopmans, Ruud – Duyvendak, Jan W – Guigni, Marco G. (eds.) (1995): New

Social Movements in Western Europe: A Comparative Analysis. Minneapolis, University of Minnesota

Press

Kolinsky, Martin – Paterson, William E. (eds.) (1976): Social and Political Movements in Western

Europe. London, Croom Helm

Koopmans, Ruud (1995): Democracy from Below: New Social Movements and the Political System in

West Germany. Boulder, Westview Press

Kornhauser, William: The Politics of Mass Society. Glencoe: Free Press, 1959.

Körösényi András. (2005). “Political Representation in Leader Democracy”. Government and

Opposition 40(3): 358–78.

Körösényi András (2009a): “Beyond the Happy Consensus about Democratic Elitism”. Comparative

Sociology 8: 364–82.

Körösényi András (2009:b): “Lehangoló tudomány, vagy a politika művészete? Vezetés, manipuláció

és demokrácia.” Politikatudományi Szemle, 3. szám, pp. 33–56.

Körösényi András (2009:c): “A népszavazások és a képviseleti demokrácia viszonya.” In: Enyedi

Zsolt (eds.): A népakarat dilemmái. Népszavazások Magyarországon és a nagyvilágban. Budapest,

DKMKA – Századvég, pp. 37-62.

Körösényi András (2009:d): “Political Leadership: Classical vs. Leader Democracy”. In Joseph Femia,

András Körösényi and Gabriella Slomp (eds), Political Leadership in Liberal and Democratic Theory,

79–100. Exeter and Charlottesville, VA: Imprint Academic.

Körösényi András (2010): “Stuck in Escher’s staircase: Leadership, manipulation and democracy”.

Österreichische Zeitschrift für Politikwissenschaft (ÖZP) 39: 289–302. http://www.oezp.at/pdfs/2010-

3-3-Korosenyi.pdf (accessed May 2014).

Körösényi András – Tóth Csaba – Török Gábor (2007): A magyar politikai rendszer, Budapest, Osiris

Kiadó

Le Bon, Gustave (2002): The crowd Mineola, New York, Dover Publications

Maguire, Diarmuid (1995): “Opposition Movements and Opposiotion Parties.” In: Jenkins, J Craig –

Klandermans, Bert (eds.): The Politics of Social Protest. Comparative Perspctives on States and Social

Movements. London: University College London, pp. 199-228.

Mazzeloni, G. (2002): Politikai kommunikáció. [La communicazione politica.] Budapest: Osiris Kiadó

Medearis, John (2005): “Social Movements and Deliberative Democratic Theory.” British Journal of

Page 24: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

24

Political Science, Vol. 35, No. 1, pp. 53-75.

Meyer, David S. – Minkoff, Debra C. (2004): “Conceptualizing Political Opportunity.” Social Forces

Vol. 82, No. 4. pp.1457-1492.

Michels, Robert (1959): Political Parties: a Sociological Study of the Oligarchical Tendencies of

Modern Democracy. New York, Dover Publications

Mikecz Dániel (2012): “Új pártok, változó mozgalmak.” In: Boda Zsolt – Körösényi András

(eds.): Van irány? Trendek a magyar politikában. Budapest, MTA TK PTI, Új Mandátum Könyvkiadó

pp. 65-82.

Mills, C. Wright (1956): The power elite New York : Oxford University Press

Morris, Aldon D. – Staggenborg, Suzanne (2004): “Leadership in Social Movements” In: Snow, David

A. – Soule, Sarah A. – Kriesi, Hanspeter (ed.): The Blackwell Companion To Social Movements.

Malden-Oxford: Blackwell Publishing pp. 171-196.

Nye, Joseph S. (2008): The Powers to Lead. New York: Oxford University Press

Offe, Claus (1985): “New Social Movements: Challenging the Boundaries of Institutional Politics.”

Social Research, Vol. 52. No. 4. pp. 817-868.

Pakulski, Jan – Körösényi András (2012): Toward Leader Democracy. London – New York, Anthem

Press

Pappas, S. Takis (2008) “Political Leadership and the Emergence of Radical Mass Movements in

Democracy.” Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 41., No. 9. (August) pp. 1117-1140.

Poguntke, Thomas – Webb, Paul (2005): “The Presidentialization of Politics in Democratic Societies: A

Framework for Analyses.” In Poguntke, Thomas – Webb, Paul (eds.): The Presidentialization of

Politics: A Comparative Study of Modern Democracies. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 1-25.

Pichardo, Nelson A. (1997):”New Social Movements: A Critical Review” Annual Review of

Sociology, Vol. 23., pp. 411-430. pp.

Przeworski, Adam (1999): “Minimalist Conception of Democracy: a Defence”, In: Ian Shapiro –

Casiano Hacker-Cordón (eds.): Democracy's Value, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

Rawls, John (1993): Political liberalism. New York, Columbia University Press

Rawls, John (1999): The Law of Peoples: with, The Idea of Public Reason Revisited. Cambridge,

Harvard University Press

Rochira, Alessia – Mannarini, Terri (2011): “Deliberation and Protest: A Closer Look at Social Fora

dynamics” Inter- national Journal of Humanities and Social Science, Vol. 1 No. 8.

Rucht, Dieter (1996): “The Impact of National Contexts on Social Movement Structures: A Cross-

movement and Cross-national Comparison.” In: McAdam, Doug – McCarthy, John D . – Zald, Mayer

M. (eds.): Comparative Perspectives on Social Movements. Political Opportunities, Mobilizing

Structures, and Cultural Framings. Cambridge, Cam- bridge University Press pp. 185-204.

Rucht, Dieter (2012): “Leadership in Social and Political Movements: A Comparative Exploration.” In:

Helms, Ludger (eds.): Comparative Political Leadership. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 99-118.

Sartori, Giovanni (1987): The theory of democracy Chatham, N.J.: Chatham House

Schabert, Tilo (2005): A Classical Prince The Style of François Mitterrand In: Barry Cooper – Charles

R. Embry (eds.): Philosophy, Literature, and Politics. Essays Honoring Ellis Sandoz. University of

Missouri Press, Columbia–London, pp. 234-254.

Page 25: The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments · 1 The Leaders’ Old-New Instruments* The Role of Political Movements in Democracy Rudolf Metz PhD Student (Corvinus University of Budapest)

25

Schmitt, Carl (2007): Theory of the Partisan: Intermediate Commentary on the Concept of the

Political. New York: Telos Press

Schumpeter, A. Joseph (1987): Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. London, Unwin

Szabó Máté (2001): Társadalmi mozgalmak és politikai tiltakozás - történeti-összehasonlító

perspektívában. Budapest: Rejtjel Kiadó

Szabó Máté (2007:a): A „forró ősz” 2006-ban Budapesten- értelmezési kísérlet politológiai-politikai

szociológiai szem- pontból. . In: Sándor Péter – Vass László – Tolnai Ágnes (eds.): Magyarország

politikai évkönyve 2005-ről. Budapest Budapest: DKMKA, pp. 1241-1262.

Szabó Máté (2007:b): A tiltakozás kultúrája Magyarországon. Budapest, Rejtjel Kiadó

Tilly, Charles – Tarrow, Sidney (2007): Contentious politics. Boulder, Paradigm Publishers

Tucker, Robert C. (1968): The Theory of Charismatic Leadership Daedalus, Vol. 97, No. 3,

Philosophers and Kings: Studies in Leadership (Summer, 1968), pp. 731-756

Tucker, Robert C. (1977): Personality and Political Leadership Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 92,

No. 3 (Autumn, 1977), pp. 383-393

Tucker, Robert C. (1981/1995): Politics as leadership Columbia. Columbia, MO: University of

Missouri Press.

Vliegenthart, Rens – Walgrave, Stefann (2012): “The Interdependency of Mass Media and Social

Movements.” In: Semetko, Holli – Scammel, Margaret (eds.): The Sage Handbook of Political

Communication. London: Sage Publica- tions, pp. 387-398.

Webb, Paul – Poguntke, Thomas – Kolodny, Robin (2012): “The Presidentialization of Party

Leadership? Evaluationg Party Leadership and Party Government in the Democratic World.” In:

Helms, Ludger (eds.): Comparative Political Leadership. Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan pp. 77-98.

Young, Iris Marion (2001): “Activist Challenges to Deliberative Democracy.” Political Theory, Vol. 29,

No. 5. pp. 670-690.