48
1 Target price forecasts: Fundamental and non- fundamental factors Peter Clarkson UQ Business School, The University of Queensland and Beedie School of Business, Simon Fraser University [email protected] Alexander Nekrasov The Paul Merage School of Business, University of California, Irvine [email protected] Andreas Simon Graziadio School of Business and Management, Pepperdine University [email protected] Irene Tutticci UQ Business School, The University of Queensland [email protected] Keywords: target price forecasts, 52-week high, investor sentiment, rounding JEL Classification: D81, D82, G12, G14, M41. Current Version: 17 December 2015 *Acknowledgements: We appreciate helpful comments from Mark Arnold, Philip Brown, David Hirshleifer, Russell Lundholm, John Nowland, Gordon Richardson, Siew Hong Teoh, and seminar participants at The Australian National University, The University of British Columbia, the University of California Irvine, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, the Hong Kong Polytechnic University, The University of Melbourne, The University of Queensland, Simon Fraser University, the University of Western Australia, and the 2009 AFAANZ Conference.

Target price forecasts: Fundamental and non- fundamental ... price forecasts... · Target price forecasts: Fundamental and non-fundamental factors ABSTRACT This paper reveals both

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    17

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 1

    Target price forecasts: Fundamental and non-

    fundamental factors

    Peter Clarkson

    UQ Business School, The University of Queensland and

    Beedie School of Business, Simon Fraser University

    [email protected]

    Alexander Nekrasov

    The Paul Merage School of Business, University of California, Irvine

    [email protected]

    Andreas Simon Graziadio School of Business and Management, Pepperdine University

    [email protected]

    Irene Tutticci

    UQ Business School, The University of Queensland

    [email protected]

    Keywords: target price forecasts, 52-week high, investor sentiment, rounding

    JEL Classification: D81, D82, G12, G14, M41.

    Current Version: 17 December 2015

    *Acknowledgements: We appreciate helpful comments from Mark Arnold, Philip Brown, David Hirshleifer,

    Russell Lundholm, John Nowland, Gordon Richardson, Siew Hong Teoh, and seminar participants at The

    Australian National University, The University of British Columbia, the University of California Irvine, The

    Chinese University of Hong Kong, the Hong Kong Polytechnic University, The University of Melbourne, The

    University of Queensland, Simon Fraser University, the University of Western Australia, and the 2009

    AFAANZ Conference.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]://exchange.uq.edu.au/owa/redir.aspx?C=9d7599d3e6474e3d9dc18e14adc23023&URL=mailto%3aandreas.simon%40pepperdine.edumailto:[email protected]

  • 2

    Target price forecasts: Fundamental and non-fundamental factors

    ABSTRACT

    This paper reveals both fundamental and non-fundamental factors play an important role in analysts’

    target price formation. Analysts’ forecasts of short-term earnings and long-term growth are shown to

    be important explanatory variables for target prices; equally, the following salient non-fundamental

    factors are also shown to explain target price levels and especially target price biases: the 52-week

    high price and recent market sentiment. Here, increases in the 52-week high and market sentiment

    measures of one standard deviation correspond to increases in positive target price bias of 4.8% and

    14.7%, respectively. Initially our analysis is constrained to analysts who provide long-term growth

    forecasts, however, our findings are robust to the removal of this constraint and the broader set of

    analysts. Our analysis reveals that analysts place greater weight on these non-fundamental factors in

    settings with greater task complexity and/or resource constraints, and when they rely on valuation

    heuristics as opposed to more rigorous valuation methodology, and that this greater weight is

    associated with increased optimistic bias. Finally, our results show that analysts’ target prices are

    useful in predicting future stock returns beyond earnings forecasts and commonly used risk proxies.

    However, in an internally consistent fashion, the informativeness of target prices for future returns is

    significantly reduced when greater weight is placed on either the 52-week high or recent market

    sentiment in the target price formation process.

    Keywords: target price forecasts, 52-week high, investor sentiment, rounding

    JEL Classification: D81, D82, G12, G14, M41.

  • 3

    1. INTRODUCTION

    As financial market information intermediaries, equity analysts provide forecasts of a number of key

    summary measures relevant to firm value.1 These summary measures are forecast on the basis of various

    observable and unobservable inputs. Our study focuses on one of the key summary measures disseminated by

    analysts - target price forecasts. To shed light on factors associated with analysts’ target price forecasts, we

    consider the roles that both fundamental inputs and non-fundamental factors play in their derivation, their

    accuracy and their association with future returns. Informed by prior research (e.g., Heath et al., 1999; Shiller,

    2005; Baker and Wurgler, 2006; Baker et al., 2009), the specific non-fundamental factors we consider are the

    52-week high price and recent market sentiment. Our research is motivated in part by Gleason et al. (2013) who

    direct future researchers to consider analysts’ use of valuation heuristics using other judgment and decision-

    making settings, as their results question the extent to which analysts rigorously adhere to methods of

    fundamental valuation.

    Analysts’ target price forecasts are a prediction of a stock’s future price, generally over the 12 months

    following the release date (Asquith et al., 2005). This forecast is a point estimate that provides investors with a

    benchmark against which to directly compare stock price in the short run.2 As Gleason et al. (2013, pg. 86)

    state, target prices are more “granular, verifiable, and comparable across analysts than buy-sell

    recommendations.” Research on how analysts’ form target price forecasts and the factors associated with the

    accuracy of these forecasts is a growing area of researcher focus.3 One reason for why target prices have

    previously been overlooked by researchers may be the expectation of a natural overlap between stock

    recommendations, analysts’ forecasts of fundamentals (earnings forecasts), and target prices. However,

    research indicates an element of ‘mismatch’ between target prices and stock recommendations, and this leads

    to questions about the extent to which the two measures substitute for each other (Asquith et al., 2005;

    Bradshaw, 2002; Gleason et al., 2013). Further, since many analysts invest additional time and effort in

    1 Brown (1993) and Bradshaw (2011) provide broad reviews of the literature. 2 Target prices have become increasingly available to both researchers and individual investors. For example, finance.yahoo.com

    displays consensus target price forecasts on the summary page for most companies that are followed by analysts. 3 Research on analysts’ forecasts of target prices includes studies by Bradshaw (2002), Brav and Lehavy (2003), Bradshaw et al. (2012),

    Bonini et al. (2010), and Gleason et al. (2013).

  • 4

    generating a target price and then publicly announce this forecast, it is likely they perceive a net benefit in doing

    so.

    In a survey of the content of analysts’ reports, Asquith et al. (2005) find that the three most common

    methods used by analysts to determine target prices are earnings or cash flow multiples, discounted cash flow

    models, and asset multiples. Their investigation reveals that price earnings multiples are used in 99% of the

    analysts’ reports they examine. Prior research also provides some evidence of analysts’ forecasts of short-term

    earnings and long-term growth being associated with target price (Bandyopadhyay et al., 1995; Gleason et al.,

    2013). Directly, Gleason et al. (2013) show that incorporating analysts’ forecasts of earnings and long-term

    growth in the residual income model or PEG ratio heuristic results in pseudo target prices that have substantial

    explanatory power for actual analysts’ target prices (with adjusted R2s in excess of 50% in most years from

    1997 to 2003).

    Prior research has additionally established that target price announcements have information content for

    investors (Brav and Lehavy, 2003; Asquith et al., 2005). Notwithstanding, two recent empirical studies by

    Bonini et al. (2010) and Bradshaw et al. (2012) find the accuracy of target price forecasts to be relatively

    limited.4 We might expect that if an analyst’s estimates of future earnings and long-term growth are more

    accurate, they would translate to better target price forecasts. In fact, research demonstrates that forecasts of

    earnings and stock recommendations have some level of accuracy and that investors who follow the investment

    advice of the most accurate earnings forecasters can earn abnormal returns (Ertimur et al., 2007; Loh and Mian,

    2006; Simon and Curtis, 2011). However, Bradshaw et al. (2012) find that although analysts do exhibit

    persistent, differential abilities in forecasting stock prices, these differences are economically small. Gleason et

    al. (2013) find superior target-price investment performance when analysts are most likely to be using rigorous

    valuation techniques (the residual income model) rather than simple heuristics (the PEG ratio heuristic).

    Consistent with Asquith et al. (2005), their findings also indicate that the majority of analysts use simple

    heuristics and do not exhibit significant ability in forecasting future stock prices. Thus, our study contributes to

    4 Bradshaw et al. (2012) show that returns based on target prices on average exceed actual returns by 15%, and absolute target price

    forecast errors average 45%. Asquith et al. (2005) find that only 54% of target price forecasts from the Institutional Investor’s “All

    American” team analysts are achieved at any time during the one-year forecast horizon.

  • 5

    the existing research by providing a preliminary investigation of factors that may contribute to the observed bias

    in target price forecasts.

    There is growing evidence in the finance and accounting literature that stock prices are affected by

    reference to non-fundamental factors such as the 52-week high price and past market sentiment. Thus, it is quite

    possible that target price forecasts are also influenced by these factors. Equally, given the difficulty of

    forecasting future stock prices and the possibility that analysts do not have sufficiently strong incentives to

    spend the additional time and effort required to rigorously forecast target prices (Bradshaw et al., 2012; Gleason

    et al., 2013), it is possible that an analyst may reduce a more complex task to a simpler judgment in order to

    save time and effort (Gleason et al., 2013). Support for this view is also provided by Tversky and Kahneman

    (1974) who suggest that individuals are likely to rely on anchors and reference points when a decision-making

    task is complex. As such, we might expect a target price to be a noisy measure of fundamental value, reflecting

    aspects of the analyst’s estimate of fundamental value based on some valuation process as well as salient

    measures as a reference point for what price will achieve in the short run. Thus, we argue that when compared

    to earnings forecasts, target price forecasts provide a direct and powerful setting to study the effect of two

    prominent non-fundamental factors on important market intermediaries such as financial analysts - (1) the 52-

    week high price and (2) recent market sentiment.5 Our focus on these two non-fundamental factors is supported

    by Shiller (2005) who suggests that possible anchors for stock price include past prices, particularly where the

    price has had a reasonable level of focus, and the nearest milestone of an index such as the Dow Jones.

    A number of empirical studies have linked investors’ judgment regarding investment decisions to anchors

    such as the 52-week high (Baker et al., 2009; Li and Yu, 2012; Zuckerman, 2009). Empirical studies have also

    shown that recent market sentiment affects stock returns at the firm and market levels (Baker and Wurgler,

    2006, 2007) and helps to explain bias in analyst forecasts (Bagnoli et al., 2009; Ke and Yu, 2009; Hribar and

    McInnes, 2012). Thus, in conjunction with our analysis of the level of the target price forecast, we also examine

    whether these non-fundamental factors help explain ex post target price forecast errors (the difference between

    5 Since reported earnings are determined by accounting which does not reflect the non-fundamental factors that affect stock price, there

    is less reason to expect that analysts’ earnings forecasts will reflect non-fundamental factors since earnings forecast accuracy is rewarded.

  • 6

    the target price and the 12-month-ahead stock price). From an ex post perspective, target prices may turn out to

    be incorrect due to many factors including changes in expectations of future earnings. In this study, we are

    interested in how the initial inputs (both fundamental and non-fundamental) relate to the forecast error. We

    argue that if we can identify ex ante factors that systematically bias target price forecasts, then analysts may be

    able to improve their target price estimates. Here, Tversky and Kahneman (1974) observe that although

    sometimes useful, judgment heuristics lead to potentially severe systematic error. Finally, we examine the

    usefulness of target price forecasts to investors by investigating the relation between target price forecasts and

    future stock returns conditional on our ex ante non-fundamental variables.6

    Our study contributes to the current vein of research that finds evidence of systematic bias in target price

    estimates. Bradshaw (2013) provides evidence of both analyst-level incentives and country-level characteristics

    influencing the level of optimistic bias, with analysts from countries with strong institutional infrastructure

    displaying less optimistic bias in their target prices. Further, Dechow and You (2014) in distinguishing a

    predictable noise component and a signal component in the bias observed in implied target price returns find

    that the market does not quickly impound the predictable bias into share price, allowing a trading strategy based

    on the predictable component to earn significant returns in the short run. Neither study considers the influence

    of the non-fundamental factors we identify in ours study as proxies for common behavioral biases of investors.

    Our sample consists of 26,746 target price forecasts for U.S. firms over the period 1999 to 2007

    representing data from 4,148 firms and 3,518 analysts. Analyst data are sourced from Thomson Reuters I/B/E/S.

    In developing our sample, we restrict our attention to analysts who report their target price forecasts in

    conjunction with both long-term growth (LTG) and short-term earnings (STE) forecasts given the fundamental

    role these forecasts play in the valuation process. As fewer analysts report LTG forecasts, this restriction greatly

    reduces the available set of observations. Notwithstanding, we view the tradeoff as defensible under the

    expectation that these forecasts also likely represent important fundamental inputs into the formulation of target

    prices. While prior research has questioned the usefulness and accuracy of analysts’ LTG forecasts (e.g., Liu

    6 Since target price forecasts are equivalent to forecasts of (ex-dividend) returns, a “good” target price forecast should predict future (ex-

    dividend) return.

  • 7

    and Thomas, 2000), more recently Jung et al. (2012) suggest that LTG forecasts positively signal the effort and

    ability of the analyst in analyzing long-term prospects. In support, they find that the market responds more

    strongly to recommendations issued with LTG forecasts. Equally, earlier studies by Block (1999) and Bradshaw

    (2002) find that LTG forecasts are important determinant for favorable stock recommendations. Dechow and

    You (2014) also include a long term growth variable in their model explaining implicit target price returns.

    Inclusion of LTG forecasts in our analysis allows us to assess the extent to which the firm’s long-term prospects

    are associated with target prices, thereby providing us with further insights into the nature of target prices. As

    an aside, when for sensitivity purposes, we remove the restrictive requirement for LTG forecasts we find all

    results based on the expanded sample to be qualitatively unaffected.

    Our results indicate that, as expected, analysts’ forecasts of short-term earnings and long-term growth help

    explain target price forecasts. Importantly, we also find that the non-fundamental factors are important

    determinants, with higher target price forecasts being associated with both higher 52-week high prices and

    higher recent market sentiment. Further, each set of factors has incremental explanatory power relative to the

    other. In this sense, the results reveal a direct role for non-fundamental factors incremental to any effect that

    they may indirectly have on target price through their influence on forecasts of short-term earnings or long-term

    earnings growth. Further, we find that the roles played by these factors are enhanced when stocks are more

    difficult to value (measured by firm size and earnings volatility), when analysts are less well positioned to make

    a forecast (measured by analyst experience and brokerage size), or when analysts rely on less rigorous valuation

    techniques (as revealed by the valuation model ratio (VRM) (Gleason et al., 2013).

    The results from our model of ex post target price errors indicate that there is a larger positive bias when

    forecasts of short-term and long-term earnings growth are high. In conjunction, we also find, in a manner

    consistent with their enhanced role in the target price formation process, that higher values of the 52-week high

    and recent market sentiment are associated with a larger positive bias in target price. An increase in the 52-week

    high and recent market sentiment of one standard deviation corresponds to an increase in target price bias of

    4.8% and 14.7%, respectively, effects that are economically meaningful when compared with the mean target

    price bias of 15.6%. Further, the model incorporating just the non-fundamental factors explains more of the bias

  • 8

    in target price than a model containing just the fundamentals, consistent with reliance on non-fundamental

    factors producing less reliable forecasts than reliance on the fundamentals. Lastly, in a parallel fashion to our

    findings for the target price forecast, the bias introduced by the 52-week high and past market sentiment

    increases with greater task complexity, greater resources constraints, and when analysts rely on less rigorous

    valuation techniques (as revealed by the VRM).

    Finally, we find a positive association between target prices and future stock returns. However, this

    association is significantly weaker when the 52-week high is high relative to the current price and when recent

    market sentiment is relatively more positive. Thus, while target price forecasts appear informative for future

    returns, the degree to which they are is significantly improved when the non-fundamental factors play a

    relatively reduced role in the target price derivation process and thus when they make a reduced contribution to

    the optimistic bias in target price.

    Overall, we view our results as consistent with the nature of a target price, which is not designed to be an

    accurate estimate of fundamental value but rather is analyst noisy measure of where the analyst price will go

    to over the next year.7 From this perspective, roles for both fundamental and non-fundamental factors emerge.

    For example, if analysts are not convinced that the stock price will reflect fundamental value in the short term,

    they may adjust the target price forecast to fit recent market expectations. Alternatively, the results may reflect

    analysts’ reliance on short cuts to generate a forecast for which there is possibly limited direct benefit of

    estimating accurately (Bradshaw et al., 2012), or in circumstances where they are less well positioned to make

    the forecast. Finally, our results also add to the general finding of prior research that analysts’ forecasts are

    optimistically biased. They suggest that the optimistic bias may, at least in part, result from analysts’ relying on

    past stock and market highs. Thus, the results consistently support the inference that although analysts use

    fundamental inputs in deriving target price forecasts, they are also influenced by highly visible reference points

    77 The common view is that target price forecasts are a prediction of price out to one year. However, the ability of analysts to on average make such longer term forecasts is questioned by the finding of Dechow and You (2014) who shows an association between consensus implied target returns and one month ahead stock returns but no association with longer returns.

  • 9

    such as the 52-week stock price high and recent investor sentiment, and further that reliance on these factors

    explains some of the observed bias in target prices and ultimately their usefulness as predictors of future returns.

    Our study contributes to the literature in several ways. First, it documents the importance of non-

    fundamental factors in the target price formation process. While much of the prior literature has focused on the

    analysts’ use of fundamentals, our paper shows that the 52-week high price and recent market sentiment play

    economically significant roles beyond the fundamental factors. Second, it sheds light on a key source of target

    price errors, revealing the 52-week high and market sentiment as more important in explaining target price

    biases than are analysts’ forecasts of earnings and long-term growth. Third, we contribute to the literature on

    the usefulness of analysts’ target prices in predicting future stock returns. Prior literature finds that target prices

    can be used to predict future stock returns when analysts use more rigorous valuation techniques or more

    accurate earnings forecasts (Gleason et al., 2013). We find that target prices have significant explanatory power

    with respect to future stock returns beyond earnings forecasts and commonly used risk proxies, but more so

    when the influence of the non-fundamental factors is relatively low. Finally, our paper contributes to the

    growing literature on the economic effects of non-fundamental factors. Extant research finds that non-

    fundamental factors affect stock prices, the exercise of options, and mergers and acquisitions. We document the

    effect of these factors on target prices issued by important market participants, financial analysts, and viewed

    as informative by investors.

    The remainder of this document is organized as follows. In the next section, we review the literature that

    informs our expectations regarding the target price derivation process. Section 3 describes our sample data, and

    Section 4 the methodology. The empirical results are presented in Section 5 and Section 6 concludes.

    2. RELATED RESEARCH

    A number of studies relating to investment decisions have relied on theories from psychology to explain

    why prices might reflect information other than fundamental value (e.g., Baker et al., 2009; Heath et al., 1999).

    Tversky and Kahneman (1974) describe three heuristics that are used by individuals to predict value:

    representativeness, availability, and anchoring. Representativeness refers to the tendency of individuals to rely

  • 10

    on one item because it is highly representative of (resembles) another item. Within our context, for example,

    past stock price highs and market sentiment could be considered representative of future prices. Tversky and

    Kahneman refer to the “illusion of validity,” in which confidence in a decision is based on the fit between a

    predicted outcome and the input information. Availability refers to the tendency of individuals to rely on events

    that are easily brought to mind. Characteristics that enhance availability are the familiarity of an occurrence and

    how recently the event took place. Finally, anchoring refers to the tendency of individuals to make an estimate

    by starting from an initial value, which is then adjusted to determine the final result.

    Each of these heuristics could be used to describe the use of non-fundamental factors by analysts in their

    determination of a target price forecast. Forecasting a target price involves a large number of uncertainties with

    different probabilities of eventuating. Applications of financial theory often employ historic values to infer

    expectations of future values because of the difficulty of generating values of future events. In this sense, past

    prices and investor sentiment could be seen as representative of future prices. Further, because recent prices

    and investor sentiment are easily observable by analysts, they satisfy the description of availability.

    These heuristics suggest that the 52-week high and recent market sentiment may serve as reference points

    or judgment anchors for estimating target price.8 Baker et al. (2009) utilize this theory in explaining merger and

    acquisition activity. In particular, they identify the 52-week high as a judgment anchor. A number of the

    justifications they provide for this metric as an anchor are also salient to issues faced by analysts in estimating

    target prices. Specifically, the 52-week high is a value that is widely published and is the focus of analysts,

    investors and corporate executives. In fact, the 52-week high price appears prominently in the summary

    information on the front page of many analysts’ reports. It is often viewed as a high price that the company has

    achieved and may recover through good management. Given prior research indicates positive bias in analysts’

    forecast outputs and recommendations, we expect that the 52-week high could well provide an anchor point for

    analysts’ target price forecasts, a point that is adjusted for other considerations such as their forecast of

    fundamental value and recent market sentiment. A number of studies have found the prior year’s high price to

    8 The use of these behavioural anchors may be done consciously or unconsciously by analysts in forming target price. This study does

    not make this distinction. It is unlikely that the analyst would reveal that their valuation was in some way linked to the 52-week high

    price unless they believed that there was some rationality to this. In fact, use of the 52-week high price as a value indicator is evident in

    trading strategies of technical analysts and is known as the ‘breakout strategy’.

  • 11

    be salient in investment decisions. For example, Baker et al. find it to be influential in the valuation of mergers

    and acquisitions while Heath et al. find that the exercise of options by employees doubles when the share price

    exceeds the prior year high. In explaining returns to momentum investing, George and Hwang (2004) suggest

    that investors may anchor on the 52-week high as a reference point from which to assess the incremental value

    of new information, since traders are slow to react, or overreact, to good news. Using nearness to the 52-week

    high as a proxy for recent good news, they find that this is a better predictor of future returns than are past

    returns, suggesting that investors focus on price levels rather than price changes. When price is close to its 52-

    week high, there is a reluctance to bid it higher even where a higher price would be supported by information.

    Eventually the price does increase, revealing the information. A similar behavior occurs in the event of bad

    news. Thus, price is sticky at values closest to, and farthest away from, the 52-week high. Li and Yu (2012)

    attempt to predict aggregate excess market returns and find that both nearness to the 52-week high and nearness

    to the historical high dominate the ability of past market returns to predict future aggregate market returns, with

    the strongest results for horizons of less than one year.

    A burgeoning literature also provides links between analysts’ forecasts and market sentiment. Using Baker

    and Wurgler’s (2007) market sentiment index, a number of studies show that sentiment explains bias in analysts’

    earnings forecasts, long-term growth forecasts, and recommendations (e.g., Bagnoli et al., 2009; Ke and Yu,

    2009; Hribar and McInnes, 2012). Bagnoli et al. show that analysts’ stock recommendations are correlated with

    investor sentiment when analysts follow a greater number of industries and companies, and when they issue a

    greater number of earnings forecasts. One possible interpretation is that analysts take short cuts in order to

    produce a certain quantity of research in a limited time. However, the results also appear to suggest an

    underlying belief on the part of analysts that sentiment affects asset prices or that reliance on sentiment can

    substitute for a more labor intensive analysis of fundamental value. Nevertheless, while higher market sentiment

    might provide a rationale for higher stock recommendations, Bagnoli et al. find that reliance on it is associated

    with less profitable stock recommendations.

    A few recent studies have provided evidence that investor sentiment influences short-term earnings

    forecasts. For example, Hribar and McInnes (2012) find that investor sentiment affects analyst expectations

  • 12

    across all stocks, with earnings forecasts becoming more optimistic when sentiment is high and less optimistic

    when sentiment is low. Ke and Yu (2009) show that the translation of analysts’ forecasts into profitable stock

    recommendations is adversely affected by periods of extreme investor sentiment and a high reliance on trading

    commissions. They also find that institutional ownership and insider trading have a negative effect.

    In a study of stock returns, Baker and Wurgler (2007) show that certain types of firms are more likely to

    be sensitive to market-wide sentiment: small firms, young firms, high volatility firms, unprofitable firms, non-

    dividend-paying firms, extreme growth firms, and distressed firms. They argue that such firms are more difficult

    to value, which means that valuation mistakes are more likely. They also point out that stocks of such firms tend

    to be the riskiest and costliest to arbitrage. This means that prices will not always reflect fundamental value.

    In sum, we expect that analysts’ forecasts of fundamentals, the 52-week high price and recent market

    sentiment will each be positively related to their forecasts of target price. Further, the use of non-fundamental

    factors is likely to induce bias in target price; thus, we expect that a greater reliance on these factors will lead to

    larger target price errors and thereby likely introduce noise into the association between the target price and

    future stock returns.

    3. METHOD

    3.1 Target Price Forecast

    To examine whether, in addition to fundamentals, analysts utilize the 52-week high stock price and recent

    investor sentiment as reference points when setting their target price forecasts, we estimate the following

    regression model:

    TPijt = 0 + 1 STE1ijt + 2 DIFFSTEijt + 3 LTGijt + 4 52WHit + + 5 SENTt

    + γ CONTROLit + εijt (1)

    where

    TPijt = analyst j’s target price forecast for firm i at time t deflated by the closing price on the

    trading day before the target price announcement date;

    STE1ijt = analyst j’s forecast at time t of one-year-ahead earnings for firm i scaled by the closing

    price on the trading day before the target price announcement date;

  • 13

    DIFFSTEijt = the difference between analyst j’s forecast at time t of two-year-ahead and one-year-

    ahead earnings for firm i scaled by the closing price on the trading day before the

    target price announcement date;

    LTGijt = analyst j’s growth rate forecast at time t for firm i’s earnings over the next three to

    five years;

    52WHit = the highest stock price for firm i over the 52-week period preceding the target price

    announcement date t scaled by the closing price on the trading day before the target

    price announcement date;

    SENTt = the monthly Baker and Wurgler (2007) investor sentiment index for the month prior

    to the target price announcement month;9

    and CONTROL is a vector of ten control variables considered relevant to target price (discussed below). All

    variables are measured at the time the target price forecast is released. The models are run as pooled time-series,

    cross-sectional regressions with corrections for clustering of standard errors by firm and month (Petersen, 2009).

    For ease of reference, Table 1 summarizes the independent variables of primary interest along with their

    predicted signs for this and subsequent regression models.

    Within this model, analysts’ forecasts of fundamentals are captured by STE1, DIFFSTE, and LTG.10 Based

    on the conceptual arguments underlying a valuation model and the results of prior research (e.g.,

    Bandyopadhyay et al., 1995), we expect a positive association between each of these variables and the target

    price forecast, TP (1, 2, 3 > 0). Alternatively, the variables designed to capture the selected non-fundamental

    factors are 52WH and SENT. If analysts use the 52-week high as a reference point in forming their target price

    forecasts, we would expect the coefficient on 52WH to be positive (4 > 0). Similarly, if investor sentiment has

    an influence on the setting of the target price, we expect the coefficient on SENT to be positive (5 > 0). Note,

    given model specification, any role played by the non-fundamental factors in the setting of the target price is

    incremental to their influence on either the short-term earnings or long-term earnings growth forecasts.

    As noted, our econometric model includes ten control variables considered relevant to target price

    derivation. The first is a measure of whether the target price forecast is rounded to a whole dollar amount, and

    9 Monthly investor sentiment is accessed from www.stern.nyu.edu/~jwurgler. The investment sentiment variable is originally defined

    using annual data in Baker and Wurgler (2006) in equation (3) and denoted as SENTIMENT┴. 10 We use DIFFSTE instead of two-year-ahead earnings forecast, STE2, because STE1 and STE2 are highly correlated at around 87%.

    DIFFSTE captures the incremental contribution of STE2 over STE1 and can be interpreted as a measure of short-term earnings growth.

    http://www.stern.nyu.edu/~jwurgler

  • 14

    for the remaining nine, four relate to analyst/brokerage characteristics and five to firm-specific characteristics.

    To begin, we measure rounding as follows:

    ROUNDijt = rounding, measured as a categorical variable set equal to 1 if analyst j’s target price

    forecast for firm i at time t is rounded to the nearest dollar, and 0 otherwise

    We include rounding following Shiller’s (2005) comment that market participants will rely on the nearest

    round number when making judgments about value. Support follows from, among others, Dechow and You

    (2012) who find that 46.3% of their sample EPS forecasts are rounded to the nearest five cents. They argue that

    analysts are motivated to use round numbers where the costs of generating a more accurate forecast of EPS

    outweigh the benefits, and suggest that rounding reflects analysts’ views of the lack of precision in forecasting.

    Evidence of price clustering is also well established, with a number of rational and behavioral explanations

    being advanced to explain the phenomenon.11 Rational explanations argue that market participants round

    numbers in circumstances of uncertainty to reduce various costs (e.g., the resolution hypothesis by Ball et al.,

    1985 and the negotiation hypothesis by Harris, 1991). Ikenberry and Weston (2007) find that the extent of

    clustering on the NYSE and Nasdaq around increments of 5 and 10 cents cannot be completely explained by

    rational economic theories and suggest that the phenomenon is also a function of a fundamental psychological

    bias for prominent numbers. They refer to the psychology literature that finds rounding bias in the context of

    various numeric-based tasks. This literature suggests that some numbers are easier to process than others, and

    that this is reflected by the rounding of numbers during tasks that are time-based, involve large numbers, and

    have high levels of difficulty (Shepard et al., 1975; Hornick and Zakay, 1994; Loomes, 1988). On this basis,

    we predict that price clustering will also be observed in analysts’ target price forecasts, since the task of

    forecasting future stock prices involves a high level of uncertainty and high information seeking costs. Thus,

    we expect the coefficient on ROUND to be positive.

    The analyst/brokerage characteristics we include in the model are:

    REP = analyst reputation, measured as a categorical variable set equal to 1 if the analyst is

    named as an “All American” team analyst by the Institutional Investor, and 0

    otherwise;

    11 Evidence of price clustering has been found for the US equity markets (Harris 1991; Christie and Schulz, 1994; Grossman et al.,

    1996), gold markets (Ball et al., 1985; Grossman et al., 1996), foreign exchange markets (Grossman et al., 1996), and the London equity

    index futures and options markets (Gwilym et al., 1998).

  • 15

    EXP = analyst experience in forecasting firm i, measured as the number of years in which

    the analyst has issued target price forecasts for the firm;

    B_SIZE = brokerage size, measured as the number of analysts associated with a particular

    broker in a given year; and

    CONFLICT = a measure of possible investment banking-related conflicts of interest that may

    influence analysts’ opinions which, following Ertimur et al. (2007), is based on the

    Carter and Manaster (1990) rankings as updated by Loughran and Ritter (2004);

    following Gleason et al. (2013), we assign a value of 1 if the brokerage firm has the

    top investment banking reputational rank, 0.5 if it has a lower reputational rank, and

    0 if it does not have a Carter-Manaster reputational rank.

    Prior research indicates that analysts’ estimates of summary measures – forecasts of earnings and stock

    recommendations – vary in accuracy and often display optimistic bias (Loh and Mian, 2006; Ertimur et al.,

    2007; Bradshaw, 2002; Bradshaw et al., 2012), with various factors at both the analyst and brokerage levels

    identified as contributing to this variation. We thus include the three common analyst- and broker-level variables

    identified above (REP, EXP, and B_SIZE) to control for the influence of these factors on analysts’ target price

    forecasts. Each has generally been positively associated with the accuracy of forecasting and recommendations

    (Stickel, 1990; Park and Stice, 2000; Gleason et al., 2013). Since the optimistic bias in analysts’ forecasts and

    stock recommendations has also been associated with investment banking relations, we additionally include

    CONFLICT to capture any inflation in the target price induced by such bias (Lin and McNichols, 1998; Dechow

    et al., 2000; O’Brien et al., 2005; Gleason et al., 2013). Note, since each of these characteristics is associated

    with bias in analysts’ forecasts and stock recommendations, we expect them to be related to both the bias in,

    and the level of, TP since characteristics associated with more upward bias should result in a higher target price

    relative to the current market price. As such, we include the same analyst and broker controls in both the target

    price model and the target price error model (discussed in the next section).

    The control variables included in the model to capture firm-specific characteristics are:

    β = the firm’s CAPM beta, estimated from a regression of firm returns minus the risk-free

    (one-month T-bill) rate on the value-weighted market index minus the risk-free rate over

    a period of 60 months preceding the target price month;

    SIZE = firm size, measured as the log of market capitalization on the trading day before the target

    price announcement date t;

    BM = the book-to-market ratio, calculated as the book value of equity divided by the stock price

    at the end of the previous fiscal year;

  • 16

    RETt-1 = the past one-year return calculated as the 250-trading-day buy-and-hold return ending one

    day before the target price announcement date; and

    RETstd = return volatility, measured as the daily return volatility over the 250-trading-day period

    ending one day before the target price announcement date.

    These firm-specific characteristics are included as they have been shown to be associated with analyst

    following and their ability to forecast accurately. Target price, as a forecast of value, will be a function not only

    of the forecast of earnings and long-term growth but also of expectations of risk, both systematic and

    unsystematic (Kerl, 2011). We include β, BM, SIZE and RETstd to proxy for a firm’s risk (Lui et al., 2007).

    Firms with higher betas, higher book-to-market ratios, and smaller market capitalization are viewed as riskier

    and therefore more difficult to value accurately. Also, higher risk can result in a higher discount factor being

    used to discount future cash flows and hence a lower fundamental value and target price. We include past

    returns, RETt-1, to control for analyst bias in target price arising from selecting past winners to follow. Hayes

    (1998) argues that analysts’ incentives to gather and provide information are strongest for stocks that are

    expected to perform well. Ertimur et al. (2007) provide empirical evidence that analysts initiate

    recommendations following high returns and prior growth. Again, the inclusion of these firm-specific

    characteristics in both the target price and target price error models is based on the argument that characteristics

    associated with more upward bias should result in a higher target price forecast and hence greater target price

    forecast error.

    Finally, we conduct our analysis in three stages. First, we consider four variants of our primary model

    (equation 1) in which we include the sets of fundamental and non-fundamental factors, and the set of control

    variables, in various combinations. Second, for robustness purposes, we extend the model to alternatively

    include the one-year lagged target price forecast, analyst recommendations, and the two pseudo-target prices

    developed by Bradshaw (2004) and Gleason et al. (2013), one based on the residual income model (RIM) (VRIP)

    and one based on PEG ratio heuristic (VPEGP). Here, we follow the procedures described in Gleason et al. to

    determine each of these pseudo target prices. Third, since our arguments envisage an enhanced role for the non-

    fundamental anchors in situations where stocks are more difficult to value and/or when analysts are less well

    positioned to make a forecast, we re-run the model with a series of interaction effects. Specifically, we interact

    both the fundamental and non-fundamental factors in turn with each of firm size (SIZE), earnings volatility

  • 17

    (EV), analyst experience (EXP), and brokerage size (B_SIZE) under the argument that smaller firms and firms

    with greater earnings volatility will be more difficult to value, while analysts with less experience and from

    smaller brokerages will be in a weaker position to make a forecast. In conjunction, we also run a model in which

    we interact these factors with the valuation model ratio (VMR) developed by Gleason et al. As described by

    Gleason et al., the VMR facilitates inferences about valuation model usage, with values of VMR exceeding one

    indicative of the analysts favoring the PEG valuation heuristic and alternatively, for values less than one,

    favoring RIM. Based on the findings in Gleason et al. of an improved target price process when the forecasts

    are derived using a more rigorous valuation technique rather than an heuristic, we expect analyst reliance on the

    non-fundamental factors to be positively related to the VMR. For this final analysis, we set the operational

    notion of VMR equal to 1 if the firm’s VMR exceeds the median VMR and 0 otherwise.

    3.2 Target Price Error

    The fact that analysts’ target price forecasts are influenced by the non-fundamental factors does not

    necessarily imply that this influence is detrimental to the target price forecast accuracy. To test whether the

    influence of these factors is indeed detrimental, we estimate the following target price error model:

    TPerrorijt = δ0 + δ1 STE1ijt + δ2 DIFFSTEijt + δ3 LTGijt + δ4 52WHit + δ5 SENTt

    + γ CONTROLit + υijt (2)

    where all variables with the exception of TPerror are as previously defined, and the vector of control measures

    includes rounding, and the same analyst/brokerage and firm-specific characteristics employed in the target price

    model above (equation (1)).12 As noted, Table 1 provides a summary of the primary independent variables along

    with their descriptions and predicted signs.

    Following Bradshaw et al. (2012), we define target price error, TPerrorijt as the difference between the

    one-year-ahead stock price (Pt+1) and the target price forecast, each scaled by the closing price on the trading

    day before the target price announcement date (Pt) (i.e., TPerrort = (Pt+1/ Pt) – TPt). A negative value of TPerror

    therefore implies an optimistic bias in the target price forecast. Alternatively, if a firm is delisted, Pt+1 is not

    12 As explained in the previous section, both sets of characteristics have been shown to be associated with biases in analysts’ forecasts

    and recommendations, so they are also likely to be related to both the level of and errors in analysts’ target prices. As we discussed in

    Section 4 and revealed in Table 3, our sample target price forecasts do indeed exhibit a positive (optimistic) bias, on average.

  • 18

    available. In these instances, to avoid look-ahead bias, we use the return to the firm’s shares over the period

    prior to delisting (Rt+1), determining the target price forecast error as (Rt+1 + 1) – TPt.

    As argued within the context of the target price forecast model above, we expect that a higher 52-week

    high share price and more positive recent investor sentiment will each map into a higher target price forecast.

    To the extent that these forces lead analysts to a more optimistic target price forecast, we expect a reliance on

    them to result in a larger (more negative) target price forecast error. Thus, we expect the coefficients on each of

    52WH and SENT to be negative (δ4 < 0 and δ5 < 0). Again, the role played by the non-fundamental factors is

    incremental to any error they introduce into forecasts of short-term earnings and long-term earnings growth.

    Finally, we adopt the same three-stage strategy underlying the analysis of the target price forecast as

    described in the previous section. Again, the models are run as pooled time-series cross-sectional regressions

    with standard errors clustered by firm and month (Petersen, 2009).

    3.3 Predictability of Future Stock Returns

    If our findings reveal that a reliance on the two selected non-fundamental factors, the 52-week high price

    and recent market sentiment, induces biased target prices, we might expect the association between target prices

    and future stock returns to decline as the influence of these measures increases. This approach follows Gleason

    et al. (2012) where target price accuracy is measured as the ability of the target price to accurately forecast

    future returns. If, for example, when the 52-week high price is significantly above the current stock price, it

    influences analysts pulling their target price forecasts away from the fundamental value implied by the forecasts

    of fundamentals, we might expect to find a weak, or perhaps even no, association between target prices and

    future returns. In contrast, when the 52-week high is close to the current price, the effect of the 52-week high

    on the target price forecast should be relatively small. We might then expect a relatively stronger positive

    association between target prices and future returns for such stocks. In a similar fashion, we would expect that

    when recent market sentiment is relatively high, there will be a larger ‘sentiment induced’ bias in target prices

    and therefore a weaker relation between the target price forecast and future returns. Prior research indicates that

    these non-fundamental values may be associated directly with stock price, however, our measures of 52 week

  • 19

    high and market sentiment are lagged relative to our measure of future returns. As such, we it is unclear ex ante

    whether these factors will be associated with our measure of future returns.

    To test the influence of the non-fundamentals on target price bias, we estimate the following regression

    model of future stock returns on target prices and control variables:

    RETt+1 = λ0 + λ1 TPijt + λ2 TPijt*52WHit + λ3 TPijt*SENTt +

    + λ4 STE1ijt + λ5 DIFFSTEijt + λ6 52WHit + λ7 SENTt + φ CONTROL*it + πijt (3)

    where RETt+1 is the raw ex-dividend stock return measured over the 250-trading-day period following the target

    price announcement day (t) using daily ex-dividend returns from CRSP, CONTROL* is a vector of control

    variables limited to rounding (ROUND) and the firm-specific variables (, lnSIZE, BM, and RETt-1),13 and all

    variables are as previously defined. Within the context of this model, if the target price forecast predicts future

    stock price, we would expect a positive association between TP and future returns (λ1 >0). Further, if higher

    values of 52WH and SENT have an increased influence on analysts thereby pulling their target price forecasts

    further away from the value implied by the forecasts of fundamentals, we would expect the coefficients on the

    interaction terms, TP*52WH and TP*SENT, to be negative (λ2 >0 and λ3 >0). Note, we exclude LTG because,

    as Table 2 reveals, the requirement for long-term growth forecasts significantly reduces sample size and thus

    the power of the returns tests.14 We estimate this model as a pooled time-series cross-sectional regression and

    correct t-statistics for clustering of standard errors by firm and month (Petersen, 2009). Again, Table 1 provides

    a summary of the primary independent variables and their predicted signs.

    4. SAMPLE DATA

    To construct our sample, analyst forecasts of target prices, earnings, and long-term growth were collected

    from the Thomson Reuter I/B/E/S Detail History file over the period January 1999 to December 2007. Financial

    data were then collected from CRSP and COMPUSTAT, monthly returns, daily returns, the risk-free rate and

    the market value of equity from CRSP and the book value of equity from COMPUSTAT. The final sample

    13 Since we do not expect that individual analyst and broker specific characteristics will help to explain firm-level future returns, we

    include only firm specific controls that have been found to be associated with future stock returns. 14 Since returns tests usually have relatively low explanatory power (adjusted R2s), sample size is especially important for such tests. As

    discussed in Section 5.5, our results for the returns model are robust to the inclusion or exclusion of these variables.

  • 20

    consists of 26,746 target price forecasts for 4,148 U.S. firms issued by 3,518 analysts. Table 2 presents the

    sample selection criteria. As revealed, the sample size is greatly reduced by the requirement that an analyst must

    also provide short-term earnings and long-term growth forecasts on the date of their target price forecast.15

    Table 3 presents descriptive statistics. All variables except future ex-dividend stock returns, RETt+1, are

    winsorized at the top and bottom 1% level. As revealed, the mean (median) value of the target price forecast

    scaled by the closing price on the previous day (TP) is 1.228 (1.185), with a standard deviation of 0.276.16 Thus,

    on average, a target price forecast is a prediction that the stock price will exceed its current level by 22.8% in

    the next 12 months. The mean (median) target price forecast error, also scaled by the previous day closing price

    (TPerror), is -0.156 (-0.139), with a standard deviation of 0.566. These statistics reveal a positive bias, with the

    scaled target price forecast exceeding the scaled realized price by 15.6% on average.17 Finally, the mean

    (median) one-year-ahead ex-dividend stock return over the sample period is 7.6% (3.5%).

    Turning to the non-fundamental factors, we find that the mean 52-week high price (52WH) is 51.7% higher

    than the stock price on the day prior to the target price announcement, while the median is 18.5% higher. Perhaps

    coincidentally, the median value of 52WH (1.185) is the same as the median value for the target price forecast

    measure, TP. However, the range for TP is narrower than the range of 52WH. These summary statistics appear

    consistent with our expectation that analysts rely on past price data. The proximity of the target price forecast

    to the 52-week high (PROX_52WH) is, on average, 151 days (0.414 × 365 days).

    To further illustrate the relation between TP and 52WH, we plot the density distribution of the target price

    relative to the 52-week high (Figure 1, Panel A). The plot reveals a sharp spike and the absolute maximum of

    the density at the 52-week high. A binomial test rejects the null hypothesis that the number of observations in

    the interval that includes 52-week high equals the average of the two immediately adjacent intervals at less than

    the 1% level.18 To check the robustness of this result, we also change the scale variable from the stock price to

    15 Since as noted, Jung et al. (2012) find that analysts that publicise LTG forecasts are signalling effort in their recommendations, it

    seems less likely that such analysts would consciously rely on non-fundamental factors and hence, this sampling constraint is likely to

    skew our analyses against finding a role for the identified behavioural factors. Notwithstanding, in order to improve the generalizability

    of our study we also rerun our analysis removing the constraint of the LTG forecast (see Section 5.5). 16 This figure is comparable to Asquith et al. (2005). 17 The direction and magnitude of the bias are consistent with Bradshaw et al., 2012, who find that the average target price error in their

    sample is -15%. 18 The binomial test is similar to the test Burgstahler and Dichev (1997) use for the discontinuity of earnings distribution around zero.

  • 21

    the 52-week high price (Panel B) and the size of each interval from 0.01 to 0.001 (Panel C). The plots in both

    Panel B and Panel C exhibit similar spikes, and absolute maximums, in the target price density at the 52-week

    high.

    Returning to Table 3, we find that the sample mean (median) for investor sentiment, SENT, is 0.086 (-

    0.060). Thus, while the mean is suggestive of positive investor sentiment, on average, the negative median value

    indicates that observations for more than one-half of the sample are derived from periods when investor

    sentiment was low. Additionally, the mean value of the rounding measure (ROUND) is 0.874, indicating that

    for 87.4% of our sample firms, the target price forecast is presented as an even dollar amount .

    Finally, Table 3 reveals that less than 10% of our analysts are classified as “All American” team analysts

    (the mean value of REP is 8.8%) and that analysts have on average approximately two years of experience

    forecasting target prices for a given firm in our sample (based on their target price forecasts collected by I/B/E/S,

    the mean value of EXP is 2.097). Investment banking relations for our sample brokers is also toward the lower

    end, with a median value for CONFLICT is 0.500.

    Lastly, Table 2 indicates we lose 169,642 observations due to the lack of a long-term growth forecast. To

    assess whether there are any substantial differences between our sample and the sample of firms without LTG

    forecasts, we compare summary statistics between the two samples. The untabulated results indicate that the

    greatest differences relate to analyst and broker characteristics. Analysts who provide LTG forecasts tend to be

    less experienced (the mean value of EXP is 2.097 years for the LTG sample and 2.600 years for the non-LTG

    sample). Further, the CONFLICT measure has a mean of 0.352 for the LTG sample and a mean of only 0.277

    for the non-LTG sample, suggestive of greater investment banking activity between the firm and the broker for

    firms with LTG forecasts.

    5. RESULTS

    5.1 Univariate Correlations

    Pearson pair-wise correlations for the variables used in the models are presented in Table 4. Consistent

    with our expectation that analysts appeal to the 52-week high price when forecasting target price, the table

  • 22

    shows an economically significant correlation of 29.2% between the TP and 52WH. The investor sentiment

    measure is also positively associated with analysts’ forecasts of target price and long-term growth, and the 52-

    week high price. Turning to fundamentals, the two-year-ahead growth, DIFFSTE, and long-term growth, LTG,

    are positively correlated with TP, while higher forecasts of STE1 are associated with lower TP. The latter result

    is likely to be driven by a trade-off between the next-year and longer-term forecasts, with higher one-year-ahead

    earnings forecasts being associated with lower two-year-ahead and long-term growth forecasts. This is

    consistent with the expectation that extreme earnings revert to an average level over time, and it highlights the

    importance of the multivariate analysis presented in the next section.

    Correlations for the control variables (not tabulated) indicate the following relations. Analyst reputation

    (REP) is positively associated with experience (EXP) and broker size (B_SIZE). That is, “All American” team

    analysts are more experienced and more likely to work for larger brokers. Further, analysts are more likely to

    provide lower target price, DIFFSTE, and LTG forecasts when they are “All American” team analysts, have

    more experience, or are from larger brokerages. Investment banking relations are associated with optimistic bias

    in target price forecasts as indicated by a negative correlation between the CONFLICT measure and the target

    price error.

    5.2 Target Price Forecast Model Results

    Table 5 presents results based on the target price forecast model (equation (1)). As described in Section

    3.1, we conduct our analysis in three stages. First, we consider four variants of the model in which we include

    fundamental and non-fundamental factors in various combinations. Following, for robustness purposes, we

    extend the model to alternatively include a lagged target price forecast, analyst recommendations, and the two

    pseudo-target price forecasts developed by Gleason et al. (2013). Finally, we run a series of models with various

    interaction effects to explore whether the roles played by the non-fundamental factors are enhanced when stocks

    are more difficult to value, when analysts are less well positioned to make a forecast, or when analysts rely on

    less rigorous valuation techniques.

    5.2.1 Primary Model Results

  • 23

    Results for the following four variants of the model are presented in Panel A of Table 5: Model 1 includes

    only the fundamental factors, Model 2 includes only the non-fundamental factors, Model 3 includes both sets

    of factors, and finally, Model 4 includes both sets of factors along with the control variables. Here, to begin, the

    adjusted R2s are 16.5% for Model 1 with only the fundamental factors, 9.8% for Model 2 with only the non-

    fundamental factors, and 22.7% for the composite model (Model 3). Thus, while it appears that the fundamental

    factors play a stronger role in explaining target price forecasts, the non-fundamental factors also play an

    (incrementally) important role. This conclusion is supported by the Vuong test statistics (not reported)

    comparing the adjusted R2s among the three models, with the null hypothesis of no difference being rejected at

    the 1% level for all comparisons.19

    Turning to the individual factors, given the similarity in results across models, for parsimony, we restrict

    our discussion to the results for Model 4, the complete model inclusive of the control variables. For the

    fundamental factors, the coefficients on STE1, DIFFSTE, and LTG are 0.986, 4.060, and 0.411, each significant

    at better than the 0.001 level. Thus, as expected within a valuation framework, the target price forecast is

    increasing in forecasts of both short-terms earnings and long-term earnings growth. Equally, the coefficients on

    the non-fundamental factors 52WH and SENT of 0.035 and 0.038, respectively, are also each significant at better

    than the 0.001 level. Thus, incremental to any indirect effect that these non-fundamental factors might have

    through the fundamentals, each also appears to play a direct role in the target price formation process, with the

    forecast increasing in the 52-week high (52WH) and in the level of recent investor sentiment (SENT). The

    magnitude of regression coefficients indicates that an increase in 52WH and SENT of one standard deviation

    corresponds to an increase in the target price (scaled by price) of 4.0% (0.035*1.151) and 2.3% (0.038*0.618),

    respectively. Thus, the identified non-fundamental factors explain an economically meaningful proportion of

    the overall target price variation (from Table 3, the standard deviation of TP is 27.6%).

    Finally, within this model, the coefficient on ROUND is 0.029 (p < 0.001). Hence, when a target price

    forecast is presented as a round number, it is 2.9% higher, on average. Of the remaining control variables,

    19 Similar inference obtain when the three models are run with the control variables. Here, the adjusted R2’s are 22.8% and 16.9% for

    the analogues of Models 1 and 2, and the Vuong tests now comparing Models 1, 2, and 4 are again all significant at the 1% level.

  • 24

    B_SIZE, CONFLICT, SIZE, BM, and RETstd are each significant at better than the 5% level while the other

    measures are insignificant at conventional levels.

    5.2.2 Additional Considerations

    First, to control for unobserved analysts’ incentives and characteristics, we add the one-year lagged value

    of TP (LagTP) for the same analyst and firm to the model. The results are presented as Model 5 in Panel B of

    Table 5. As revealed, the lagged measure (LagTP) is highly significant (0.406, p < 0.001) and its inclusion

    results in a significant increase in model adjusted R2 (0.370 relative to 0.251 for Model 4 in Panel A).

    Importantly, the results for both the fundamental and non-fundamental factors are consistent with those for the

    primary analysis reported in Panel A, with all coefficients remaining significant at the 0.001 level. Thus, results

    and conclusion are robust to the inclusion of the lagged measure of the dependent variable as a control within

    the model.

    Second, we add two measures to identify whether the target price forecast is accompanied by a

    recommendation, and if so, the nature of the recommendation. Specifically, we set IncREC equal to 1 if the

    target price forecast is accompanied by a recommendation, and 0 otherwise. We then capture the nature of the

    recommendation using RECOMM, set equal to 1 for a sell recommendation, 2 for a hold, 3 for a buy, and 4 for

    a strong buy. If there is no recommendation (IncREC = 0), we set RECOMM to 0. While there is some question

    as to whether recommendations lead target price or target price lead recommendations, as previously discussed,

    overall the research indicates that target prices provide a more ‘granular’ indicator to shareholders of an

    analysts’ view of the stock than a recommendation. The results indicate that when accompanied by a

    recommendation, the target price forecast is significantly higher; the coefficient on IncREC is 0.265 (p < 0.001).

    Further, the results indicate that higher target price forecasts are associated with better recommendations; the

    coefficient on RECOMM is 0.121 (p < 0.001). Importantly, given our central focus, the coefficients on the

    fundamental and non-fundamental factors remain highly significant (p < 0.001) and have a similar magnitude

    to that reported for Model 4 in Panel A. Of note, inclusion of the two recommendation measures leads to a

    significant increase in model adjusted R2 (to 0.326 from 0.251 for Model 4).

    Third, as an alternative approach to address issues surrounding model specification, we add the two pseudo

  • 25

    target prices constructed by Gleason et al. (2013) to the model, one based on the residual income model (RIM)

    (VRIP) and one based on PEG ratio heuristic (VPEGP). Here, while the coefficient on each measure is positive

    and significant at better than the 1% level, their inclusion does not alter our base conclusions and adds relatively

    little to the model’s explanatory power. Specifically, the model adjusted R2 increases only marginally with the

    inclusion of the pseudo target price forecasts (to 0.256 from 0.251 in Model 4). Further, each of the fundamental

    and non-fundamental factors remains significant in the predicted direction at better than the 0.001 level. Thus,

    results and conclusions are also robust to the inclusion the two pseudo target prices constructed by Gleason et

    al. within our econometric model.20

    5.2.3 Interactive Model Results

    Panel C of Table 5 presents results for a series of five interactive models designed to provide insights into

    the settings where the non-fundamental factors are most important in the development of the target price

    forecast. Here, the first two sets of columns present results for the models where the fundamental and non-

    fundamental factors are interacted with firm-related characteristics (size and earnings volatility), the third and

    fourth sets of columns present results where the factors are interacted with analyst and brokerage characteristics

    (analyst experience and brokerage size), and the fifth set of columns where they are interacted with the VRM

    ratio designed to capture the relative use by analysts of the RIM valuation model versus the less rigorous PEG

    valuation heuristic (Gleason et al., 2013).

    The results are largely (although not universally) consistent with expectations. To illustrate, consider first

    the results for the model interacted with firm size presented in the first set of columns. Here, the coefficients on

    the STE1 and LTG interaction terms are 0.770 and 0.091, respectively, while the coefficients on the 52WH and

    SENT interaction terms are -0.032 and -0.017. In each instance, the coefficient is statistically significant at better

    than the 0.01 level. Thus, on balance, for larger firms which are arguably easier for analysts to value given their

    better information environments, analysts place greater weight on the fundamental factors and reduced weight

    on the non-fundamental factors.

    20 When we alternatively include the two pseudo target prices in the model in lieu of the fundamental factors, our conclusions regarding

    a role for the non-fundamental factors is unaltered. The coefficients on each of these factors remains significant at better than the 0.001

    level. Additionally, the coefficients on each of the two pseudo target prices is also significant at better than the 0.001 level.

  • 26

    A similar conclusion follows from the results for the model interacted with analyst experience presented

    in the third set of columns. Here, the coefficients on STE1 and LTG are positive and significant while the

    coefficient on 52WH is negative and significant. Thus, again consistent with expectations, on balance analysts

    with greater experience place greater weight on the fundamental factors and reduced weight on the non-

    fundamental factors. As a final illustration, for the model interacted with VMR presented in the fifth column,

    the coefficient on LTG is negative and significant (-0.355, p = 0.005) while the coefficient on 52WH (0.020, p

    = 0.021) is positive and significant. Thus, when analysts are more likely to use valuation heuristics rather than

    a rigorous valuation model, they are more likely to refer to the 52WH.

    5.3 Target Price Forecast Error Model Results

    Table 6 presents results for the target price error model (equation (2)) designed to examine whether

    analysts’ ex ante forecasts of fundamentals and reference to non-fundamental anchors each help to explain the

    optimistic bias in target price forecasts documented in Table 3. The format of the presentation parallels that

    used for the discussion of the target price forecast results above. Panel A presents results for the same four

    variants of the model, Panel B extends the model to include alternatively one-year lagged target price error, the

    two recommendation measures, and the two pseudo target prices developed by Gleason et al. (2013) and Panel

    C presents results for the same five interactive models.

    5.3.1 Primary Model Results

    To begin, the results for the primary models presented in Panel A reveal the adjusted R2s to be 5.4% for

    the model with only the fundamental factors (Model 1), 10.5% for the model with only the non-fundamental

    factors (Model 2), and 13.8% for the composite model (Model 3). Here again, the test statistics for the Vuong

    tests (not reported) indicate that the null hypothesis of no difference in adjusted R2s is rejected at the 1% level

    for all pairwise comparisons.21 These results reveal two points of note. First, the non-fundamental factors play

    a stronger role in explaining target price forecast error than do the fundamental factors. Second, there is a role

    21 The same inferences pertain when the models are run the control variables. The adjusted R2’s are 8.2% and 13.6% for the analogues

    of Models 1 and 2, respectively, with the Vuong tests among Models 1, 2, and 4 again significant at the 1% level for all comparisons.

  • 27

    for both sets of factors, given that the composite model exhibits a statistically significant increase in explanatory

    power over either separate factor model.

    Turning to the individual factors, again given the similarity of results across models, we focus on the

    complete model, Model 4. For the fundamental factors, the coefficient on STE is insignificant (0.246, p = 0.353)

    while in contrast, the coefficients on DIFFSTE (-2.274, p < 0.001) and LTG (-0.461, p < 0.001) are both negative

    and significant. These findings are consistent with analysts overweighting longer-term measures when

    forecasting target prices and/or with the documented analyst optimism in longer-term forecasts (Frankel and

    Lee, 1998; Hughes et al., 2008; Gode and Mohanram, 2012), each of which would result in a more optimistic

    target price forecast (recall, more negative values of TPerror indicate greater optimism). For the non-

    fundamental factors, as expected all coefficients are negative and statistically significant. The coefficients on

    52WH and SENT are -0.042 and -0.238, respectively, each significant at better than the 0.001 level. Thus, the

    results indicate that there is a larger optimistic bias in the target price forecast when the 52-week high price is

    higher and when recent market sentiment is more positive. Again, this effect is incremental to any effect that

    the non-fundamental factors might have through the forecasts of fundamentals. The magnitude of the regression

    coefficients indicates that an increase in 52WH and SENT of one standard deviation corresponds to an increase

    in the target price optimistic bias (scaled by price) of 4.8% (0.042*1.151) and 14.7% (0.238*0.618. Hence, the

    identified factors explain an economically significant proportion of the overall variation in target price errors

    and the average optimistic bias (as Table 3 reveals, the standard deviation of TPerror is 56.6% and the mean

    value of TPerror is -15.6%).

    Finally, for the control variables, the coefficient on ROUND is -0.137 (p < 0.001) which corresponds to an

    increase in the target price optimistic bias of 13.7%, on average, when the target price forecast is presented as a

    round number. Of the remaining control variables, EXP, B_SIZE, and β are each significant at better than the

    5% level while the other measures are insignificant at conventional levels.

    5.3.2 Additional Considerations

    The first column of Panel B in Table 6 reveals that when the target price error model is extended to include

    the one-year lagged measure of TPerror, results for both the fundamental and non-fundamental factors are

  • 28

    consistent with those reported in Panel A for the primary analysis. For the fundamental factors, the coefficient

    on STE1 remains insignificant while the coefficients on DIFFSTE and LTG remain negative and highly

    significant. Equally, for the non-fundamental factors, the coefficient on each remains negative and highly

    significant. Additionally, the coefficient on the lagged TPerror measure is negative and highly significant, and

    the model adjusted R2 increases modestly to 0.181 from 0.151 reported for Model 4 in Panel A. Thus, results

    and conclusions are robust to the inclusion of the lagged measure of the dependent variable.

    Next, the second column of Panel B reveals that the optimistic bias in target price forecasts is greater when

    the target price forecast is accompanied by a recommendation, and then if the recommendation is better. The

    coefficient on IncREC is -0.262 (p < 0.001) and the coefficient on RECOMM is -0.117 (p < 0.001). Further and

    of central interest, the coefficients on DIFFSTE and LTG, and on both of the non-fundamental factors (52WH

    and SENT), remain negative and highly significant (p < 0.001), while the coefficient on STE remains

    insignificant. Here, the model adjusted R2 increasaes modestly to 0.168 from 0.151 for Model 4.

    Finally, the third column of Panel B reveals that results and conclusions are also robust to the addition of

    the two pseudo target prices to the model. With the addition of VPEGP and VRIP, the model adjusted R2

    increases only slightly to 0.152 (from 0.151). As with the primary analysis reported in Model 4 of Panel A, the

    coefficients on each of DIFFSTE and LTG remain negative and highly significant, as do the coefficients on each

    of the three non-fundamental factors.

    5.3.3 Interactive Model Results

    Panel C of Table 6 presents results for the series of the five interactive target price error models. Here, the

    results essentially parallel those for the interactive target price models (Panel C of Table 5) and are largely (but

    again not universally) consistent with expectations. For example, the coefficient on 52WH is positive and

    significant within the models interacted with firm size, analyst experience, and brokerage size. Thus, for firms

    that are larger, and for analysts with more experience analysts and those from larger brokerage firms, this factor

    contributes less to the optimistic bias in target price forecasts (consistent with analysts having referred less to

    the 52WH in making their forecasts).

  • 29

    Continuing, for the model interacted with earnings volatility, the coefficient on SENT is negative and highly

    significant, consistent with analysts placing greater weight on recent market sentiment for firms with greater

    earnings volatility. Within this model, the coefficient on 52WH is also negative but insignificant. Finally, for

    the model interacted with the valuation model ratio (VMR) presented in the fifth column, the coefficient on

    52WH is negative and highly significant, indicative that with the use of valuation heuristics as opposed to

    rigorous valuation methodology, the increased emphasis on the 52-week high price leads to greater optimism in

    the target price forecast.

    5.4 Returns Analysis Results

    As the final step, we consider the usefulness of target price forecasts by examining their association with

    subsequent stock returns, measured as the ex-dividend stock return over the 250-trading-day period following

    the target price announcement day. Of direct interest, in conjunction we also examine whether the influence of

    two of our anchors, the 52-week high and investor sentiment, affects the usefulness of the target price forecast.

    The results for this final step in our investigation into target price forecasts are presented in Table 7. In

    terms of our primary focus, Model 1 includes only TP, Models 2 and 3 add the interaction terms between TP

    and each of the non-fundamental factors individually, and finally Model 4 presents the full model. All models

    include the sets of fundamental and non-fundamental factors, as well as the set of control variables. Here, across

    all models, as might be expected within a valuation framework, the coefficients on the fundamental factors,

    STE1 and DIFFSTE, are uniformly positive and significant at better than the 0.001 level, a finding consistent

    with the notion that short-term earnings forecasts provide explanatory power for future returns. For the non-

    fundamental factors, the coefficient on 52WH is insignificant across all models and the coefficient on SENT is

    consistently negative and significant at better than the 0.001 level. The finding for SENT is consistent with

    recent market sentiment being negatively associated with future stock returns (Baker and Wurgler, 2007).

    Finally, model adjusted R2s range from 7.0% to 7.7%.

    Turning directly to evidence regarding the usefulness of target price forecasts for predicting future returns,

    across all models the coefficient on TP is positive and significant at better than the 0.001 level. Thus, in a general

    sense, it appears that target price forecasts can be used as a reference point for developing profitable trading

  • 30

    strategies. For example, in Model 4 (the complete model), its coefficient is 0.194 (p < 0.001). This coefficient

    indicates that an increase in TP of one standard deviation corresponds to an increase in the future one-year ex-

    dividend return of 5.4% (0.194*0.276).

    Importantly, however, the results for the interaction terms also indicate that the strength of the association

    is conditional on the levels of the 52-week high and recent market sentiment, with the coefficients on the

    interaction terms with 52WH and SENT each negative and significant. For example, in Model 4, the coefficient

    on TP*52WH is -0.041 (p = 0.002) and the coefficient on TP*SENT is -0.086 (p = 0.038). Thus, the target price

    forecast, TP, appears to be most informative in terms of future returns when 52WH and SENT are relatively low,

    and its informativeness decreases as these measures increase. Here, intuitively, these findings fit well with the

    findings reported in Tables 5 and 6 that higher values of both 52WH and SENT map into higher target price

    forecasts and ultimately, into larger optimistic bias in the forecast.

    Thus, overall, the results for this part of our investigation suggest that the target price forecast is

    incrementally informative for future stock returns over short-term earnings forecasts, but more so when the

    influence of the non-fundamental factors, the 52-week high and recent market sentiment, on the target price

    formation process is relatively more muted. When the 52-week high stock price is high relative to the current

    price and/or when recent market sentiment is relatively more positive, both instances where the earlier results

    suggest that these non-fundamental factors play a greater role in the development of the target price forecast

    and ultimately manifest in greater optimistic forecast bias, we find the informativeness of the target price

    forecast for future returns to be significantly diminished.

    5.5 Additional Considerations

    This section reports results from a series of tests designed to reinforce arguments and conclusions based

    on our primary analyses reported in the previous sections. First, arguments supportive of a role for the 52-high

    in the target price formation process imply that its influence should increase with proximity to the target price

    forecast date since the more recent it is, the more likely the analyst will be able to bring it to mind in determining

    the target price. To consider the effect of proximity, we interact all measures within both the target price and

    target price errors models with proximity (PROX_52WH), measured as minus one times the number of days

  • 31

    between the occurrence of the 52-week high price and the target price forecast date, scaled by 365. The results,

    reported in Panel A of Table 8, indicate that the weight placed on the 52WH variable increases with proximity

    in both models. From the first set of columns for the target price model, the coefficient on 52WH*PROX_52WH

    is 0.047 (p = 0.014) while from the second set of columns for the target price error model, the coefficients on

    52WH*PROX_52WH is -0.062 (p = 0.019). Of note, in conjunction with the relatively greater weight on the

    52WH measure, the weight on SENT is significantly reduced with increased proximity, as is the weight placed

    on the long-term growth measure (LTG). Thus, as suggested, with increased proximity, analysts appear to rely

    more heavily on the 52-week high price in developing their target price forecast but in an apparent tradeoff rely

    less on recent market sentiment.

    Second, we investigate whether the association between target price and the fundamental factors is affected

    by the level of either 52WH or SENT. For example, larger values of either could lead analysts to reduce the

    weight they place on the fundamentals. The results are reported in Panel B of Table 8. For the target price model,

    the weight placed on STE1 is reduced when either 52WH or SENT is high while the weight placed on longer-

    term forecasts is increased. One possible interpretation is that analysts increase the weight on longer-term

    forecasts in order to “support” the higher target price forecast that derives with higher values of 52WH or SENT.

    Interestingly, for the 52WH interaction model, the coefficient on SENT*52WH is insignificant whereas for the

    SENT interaction model, the coefficient on 52WH*SENT is negative and significant, suggestive that 52WH

    becomes less important when SENT is high but alternatively, the role of SENT is unaffected in the face of a high

    52WH. Finally, for the target price error model, on balance the results follow logically from those for the target

    price model with the effect of STE1 on target price optimism reduced and the effect of LTG increased when

    52WH and SENT are high.

    Third, to reinforce arguments and conclusions that the non-fundamental factors incrementally and directly

    affect target price forecasts rather than just through the valuation inputs, we ran regressions with each of the

    valuation inputs as the dependent variable (STE1, DIFFSTE, and LTG) and then each of the pseudo prices

    deflated by the closing price on the trading day before the target price announcement date as the dependent

    variable (VRIP/P and VPEGP/P). Each model included the two non-fundamental factors and the control

  • 32

    variables. The results (not tabulated) reveal that none of the non-fundamental factors has a consistently positive

    effect on either the fundamental forecasts, with the effects often negative or insignificant. For the pseudo price

    models, only SENT has a positive association with VRIP/P or VPEGP/P. Opposite expectations, the 52WH is

    negatively associated with VPEGP/P which appears the most likely valuation model used by analysts. Thus,

    overall, these results reaffirm our conclusion that the non-fundamental factors directly affect target price

    forecasts rather than acting only indirectly through the fundamentals.

    Finally, to examine whether our results and conclusions are robust to several of our design choices, we

    undertake the following additional sensitivity analysis. First, we re-run the analyses reported in Tables 4 and 5

    without LTG. This allows for a substantia