6
Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market H. Günsel Doğrul a,b,1 , Ugur Soytas b, a Vocational School of Kütahya, Dumlupınar University, Turkey b Dept. of Business Administration, Middle East Technical University, Turkey abstract article info Article history: Received 2 June 2010 Received in revised form 16 September 2010 Accepted 19 September 2010 Available online 26 September 2010 JEL classication: Q43 E24 C32 Keywords: Unemployment rate Real interest rate Oil price While the interrelation between oil price changes, economic activity and employment is an important issue that has been studied mainly for developed countries, little attention has been devoted to inquiries on uctuations in the price of crude oil and its impact on employment for small open economies. Adopting an efciency wage model for equilibrium employment that does not require any assumptions regarding labor supply, this paper contributes to the literature by investigating the causality between unemployment and two input prices, namely energy (crude oil) and capital (real interest rate) in an emerging market, Turkey for the period 2005:012009:08. Applying a relatively new technique, the TodaYamamoto procedure, we nd that the real price of oil and interest rate improve the forecasts of unemployment in the long run. This nding supports the hypothesis that labor is a substitute factor of production for capital and energy. © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Unemployment is an important macroeconomic and political problem all economies confront. Due to its social and economic consequences, it is essential for policy makers to identify the factors that are affecting the unemployment rate the most. Furthermore, policy makers must also realize that the dynamics of unemployment and other factors may differ among countries at different stages of economic development. Developing countries are known to have higher unemployment rates than developed countries, with the former having higher economic growth rates than the latter. High level of unemployment has been also observed in Turkey, playing a major role in both the government's internal and international economic policies. Considering unemployment in a supplydemand framework, it can be argued that the level of employment depends on factors such as the productivity of labor, wages, price level, and prices of other factors of production. On a macroeconomic level, unemployment rate will also follow closely the local factors such as the state of the economy, business cycles, the technology level, and population demographics, as well as global factors like energy prices. Policy makers need a clear understanding of the dynamics and microeco- nomic fundamentals through which factors inuence the unemploy- ment rate in the long run, in order to devise sound macroeconomic programs. In this paper we follow an efciency wage framework that enables us to theoretically relate real oil price, real interest rate, and unemployment. Applying the TodaYamamoto procedure which avoids some of the problems other techniques face, we nd that real input prices positively Granger cause unemployment in Turkey. This result is inline with the theory and the results of other studies that mostly focus on developed countries. 2. Theoretical background Previous studies document various transmission channels through which oil price shocks may have an impact on the economic activity (Davis and Haltiwanger, 2001; Brown and Yucel, 2002; Lardic and Mignon, 2008). First, there is a classical supply side effect according to which an oil price increase leads to reduction in output since the price increases signaling the reduced availability of basic input to production. As a result, growth rate and productivity decline. Slowing productivity growth decreases real wage growth and increases the unemployment rate (Brown and Yücel, 1999, 2002). Oil price shocks can increase the marginal cost of production in many industries reducing the production and thus increasing the unemployment. Since relocation of specialized labor and capital from one industry to Energy Economics 32 (2010) 15231528 Corresponding author. Tel.: +90 312 210 2010; fax: +90 312 210 7962. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (H.G. Doğrul), [email protected] (U. Soytas). 1 Tel.: +90 274 227 0450 210. 0140-9883/$ see front matter © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2010.09.005 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Energy Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/eneco

Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market

Energy Economics 32 (2010) 1523–1528

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Economics

j ourna l homepage: www.e lsev ie r.com/ locate /eneco

Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from anemerging market

H. Günsel Doğrul a,b,1, Ugur Soytas b,⁎a Vocational School of Kütahya, Dumlupınar University, Turkeyb Dept. of Business Administration, Middle East Technical University, Turkey

⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: +90 312 210 2010; faxE-mail addresses: [email protected] (

[email protected] (U. Soytas).1 Tel.: +90 274 227 0450 210.

0140-9883/$ – see front matter © 2010 Elsevier B.V. Aldoi:10.1016/j.eneco.2010.09.005

a b s t r a c t

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:Received 2 June 2010Received in revised form 16 September 2010Accepted 19 September 2010Available online 26 September 2010

JEL classification:Q43E24C32

Keywords:Unemployment rateReal interest rateOil price

While the interrelation between oil price changes, economic activity and employment is an important issuethat has been studied mainly for developed countries, little attention has been devoted to inquiries onfluctuations in the price of crude oil and its impact on employment for small open economies. Adopting anefficiency wage model for equilibrium employment that does not require any assumptions regarding laborsupply, this paper contributes to the literature by investigating the causality between unemployment and twoinput prices, namely energy (crude oil) and capital (real interest rate) in an emerging market, Turkey for theperiod 2005:01–2009:08. Applying a relatively new technique, the Toda–Yamamoto procedure, we find thatthe real price of oil and interest rate improve the forecasts of unemployment in the long run. This findingsupports the hypothesis that labor is a substitute factor of production for capital and energy.

: +90 312 210 7962.H.G. Doğrul),

l rights reserved.

© 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction

Unemployment is an important macroeconomic and politicalproblem all economies confront. Due to its social and economicconsequences, it is essential for policy makers to identify the factorsthat are affecting the unemployment rate the most. Furthermore,policy makers must also realize that the dynamics of unemploymentand other factors may differ among countries at different stages ofeconomic development. Developing countries are known to havehigher unemployment rates than developed countries, with theformer having higher economic growth rates than the latter. Highlevel of unemployment has been also observed in Turkey, playing amajor role in both the government's internal and internationaleconomic policies.

Considering unemployment in a supply–demand framework, itcan be argued that the level of employment depends on factors suchas the productivity of labor, wages, price level, and prices of otherfactors of production. On a macroeconomic level, unemployment ratewill also follow closely the local factors such as the state of theeconomy, business cycles, the technology level, and populationdemographics, as well as global factors like energy prices. Policy

makers need a clear understanding of the dynamics and microeco-nomic fundamentals through which factors influence the unemploy-ment rate in the long run, in order to devise sound macroeconomicprograms.

In this paper we follow an efficiency wage framework that enablesus to theoretically relate real oil price, real interest rate, andunemployment. Applying the Toda–Yamamoto procedure whichavoids some of the problems other techniques face, we find thatreal input prices positively Granger cause unemployment in Turkey.This result is inline with the theory and the results of other studiesthat mostly focus on developed countries.

2. Theoretical background

Previous studies document various transmission channels throughwhich oil price shocks may have an impact on the economic activity(Davis and Haltiwanger, 2001; Brown and Yucel, 2002; Lardic andMignon, 2008). First, there is a classical supply side effect according towhich an oil price increase leads to reduction in output since the priceincreases signaling the reduced availability of basic input toproduction. As a result, growth rate and productivity decline. Slowingproductivity growth decreases real wage growth and increases theunemployment rate (Brown and Yücel, 1999, 2002). Oil price shockscan increase the marginal cost of production in many industriesreducing the production and thus increasing the unemployment.Since relocation of specialized labor and capital from one industry to

Page 2: Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market

2 Stern (2000) is probably the first to consider energy in a multivariate productionfunction along with labor and capital.

1524 H.G. Doğrul, U. Soytas / Energy Economics 32 (2010) 1523–1528

another is costly, workers do not relocate immediately but wait forconditions to get better and thus aggregate employment declines.After an oil shock, since the investment determines the potentialoutput capacity in the long run, higher input prices caused by oil priceshocks reduce the investments thus output decreases (Brown andYücel, 2002).

Second transmission channel is the wealth transfer effectemphasizing the shift in purchasing power from oil importing nationsto oil exporting nations (Fried and Schultze, 1975; Dohner, 1981). Theshift in purchasing power parity leads to reduction in the consumerdemand for oil importing nations and increases consumer demand inoil exporting nations. Consequently, world consumer demand forgoods produced in oil importing nations is reduced and the worldsupply of savings is increased. Increasing supply of savings causes realinterest rates to decrease. Diminishing world interest rate shouldstimulate investment that balances the reduction in consumption andleaves aggregate demand unchanged in the oil importing countries. AsBrown and Yücel (2002) emphasized, if prices are downward sticky,the reduction in demand for goods produced in oil importingcountries will further reduce the GDP growth. If the price level cannotfall, consumption spending will fall more than increases in invest-ments leading to the fall of aggregate demand and further slowingeconomic growth.

Real balance effect is the third transmission channel discussed byPierce and Enzler (1974) and Mork (1994). According to the realbalance effect, increase in oil prices would lead to increase in moneydemand. When monetary authorities fail to increase money supply tomeet growing money demand, interest rate will rise deteriorating thegrowth rate. Brown and Yücel (2002) discussed the impact ofmonetary policy giving more detail.

Inflation effect is another transmission channel which establishes arelationship between domestic inflation and oil prices. When theobserved inflation is caused by oil price-increased cost shocks, acontractionary monetary policy can deteriorate the long-term outputby increased interest rate and decreased investment (Tang et al., 2009).

The fifth transmission channel works via effects of oil shocks on thelabor market by changing relative production costs in some industries.As Loungani (1986) discussed, if the oil price increases are long-lasting, itcan change the production structure and have an important impact onunemployment. Oil price shock can increase the marginal cost ofproduction inmany sectors that are oil intensive and canmotivate firmsto adopt newproductionmethods that are less-oil intensive. This changein turn generates capital and labor reallocation across sectors that canaffect unemployment in the long run. Since the workers have industry-specific-skill and job search is time consuming, labor absorption processtends to take time increasing the amount of unemployment. In otherwords, higher dispersion of sectoral shocks cause higher unemploymentrate by increasing the amount of labor reallocation.

The classical model of macroeconomics states that the amount ofactual employment will be the equilibrium amount that equates thequantity of labor to the quantity of labor supplied given the assumptionof perfectly flexible wages and prices. The real wages will adjust toequate the number of available jobs with the number of qualified jobapplicants. In other words at equilibrium there is no involuntaryunemployment (Borjas, 1996). But the impact of business cycles onemployment is greater than the classical theory claimed. Hamilton(1988) investigates a general equilibriummodel of unemployment andthebusiness cycle. Hepoints out that a rational expectationsequilibriumwith flexible prices can exhibit unemployment. The business cyclemechanism explored by Hamilton (1988) brings forth the possibilitythat an energy price increase would depress consumer purchases ofenergy using goods. The decline in product demand in return causescyclical and structural unemployment.

Another dimension through which energy prices may influenceunemployment is through the relative prices of factors of production.According to Carruth et al. (1998), the efficiency wagemodels provide

an attractive framework to investigate the relationship betweenenergy prices and employment for at least 3 reasons. First, thecriticism regarding the different relative sizes of changes in wages andemployment in classical models is avoided. Second, it allowsvoluntary unemployment. The third reason is the most importantone that is also motivating this paper. That is, the link betweenunemployment and other factor prices, including oil, has a theoreticalexplanation in the efficiency wage framework. Carruth et al. (1998)point out that without any assumptions regarding the elasticity oflabor supply, the change in the equilibrium in labor market can beattributed to demand changes triggered by changes in input prices.

Probably, except only for Carruth et al. (1998), efficiency wagemodels either ignore energy or treat it as a secondary input in theproduction process. Beaudreau (2005) however, argues that energymust be considered as a primary factor of production, as no work ispossible without energy from an engineering point of view.2 We followthe efficiency wage model proposed by Carruth et al. (1998). Theirmodel startswith the followingwage equation fromShapiro and Stiglitz(1984) (see Carruth et al. (1998) for the derivation of Eqs. (1) and (2):

logw = log b + f +f × s

1−p uð Þ½ � 1−sð Þ : ð1Þ

Where, w is the wage rate, b represents any unemploymentbenefits, f is effort, s is the probability of shirking successfully, u is theunemployment rate, and p(u) is the probability by which anunemployed person finds a job. Assuming constant returns to scaleproduction function which is homogeneous of degree one and perfectcompetition in the final good market, Carruth et al. (1998) show thatthere exists a relationship between real input prices.

μ = C w; r; epð Þ: ð2Þ

Here, the interest rate r reflects the capital rental rate and ep is theenergy price. Carruth et al. (1998) derive the equilibrium unemploy-ment rate from Eqs. (1) and (2):

U* = U* r; ep;b μð Þ; f ; sð Þ: ð3Þ

As a result of comparative static analysis Carruth et al. (1998)show that the equilibrium unemployment rate depends on the realinterest rate and the real energy price; whereas, it is neutral to totalsupply and technology. A rise in oil price erodes profits and theeconomy must adjust to equilibrium where there are no economicprofits or losses. Assuming that workers do not shirk, this adjustmenttakes place through an increase in equilibrium unemploymentbecause wages and unemployment are inversely related. A similaradjustment also takes place when interest rates rise. Carruth et al.(1998) see unemployment as a “discipline device”. As real input pricesrise, wages decline leading to higher unemployment rates.

Following the Carruth et al. (1998) model we investigate therelationship between the unemployment rate, real energy prices, andthe real interest rate in Turkey.

3. Empirical evidence

There are several studies addressing the relationship between oilprice changes and employment directly for developed countries. Using adispersion index from 1947 to 1982 for 28 industries, Loungani (1986)examines the effect of world oil market disruptions on the reallocationprocess in the U.S. labor market. His analysis shows that oil priceincreases in the 1950s and 1970s seem to account for unusual amount oflabor reallocated across industries thereby increasing theunemployment

Page 3: Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market

3 We considered alternative interest rates, but the results are insensitive to differentinterest rates.

4 See Maddala and Kim (1998) for an excellent treatment of ADF, PP, KPSS, and DF-GLS; and Ng and Perron (2001) for more on NP.

1525H.G. Doğrul, U. Soytas / Energy Economics 32 (2010) 1523–1528

rate in those periods. Hamilton (1983) finds that oil price change has astrong causal andnegative correlationwith real GNPgrowth andpositivecorrelation with unemployment from 1948 to 1980 in the U.S.A. usingGranger causality. When the sample period is extended to 1988:2 thecorrelation becomes only marginally significant and more importantlythat there is an asymmetry in effects. Using different data and methods,Burbidge and Harrison (1984) examine the impact of oil price shocks onsome macroeconomic variables for developed countries such as Canada,U.K., Japan and Germany using VAR models. They show that the1973–1974 oil embargo explains a substantial part of the behavior ofindustrial production in the countries examined. However, for the oilprice changes in 1979–1980, they find little evidence that the changes inoil prices had an effect on industrial production. Using Hamilton's dataGisser and Goodwin (1986) examine the relationship between crude oilprice shocks and employment. They also searchwhether oil price shockshave a different effect on the macro economy before 1973 than after buttheir empirical findings do not support the hypothesis. They find similarresults with Hamilton (1983) and Burbidge and Harrison (1984) for therelationship between oil prices and unemployment. Uri (1996) studiesthe effect of changes in the price of crude oil on agricultural employmentin the USA for the period 1947–1995 using Granger causality. Hedocuments a significant empirical relationship between the variables.Using annual data, Mory (1993) shows that rise and fall of the real oilprices have asymmetric effects on output and unemployment in the USfrom 1951 to 1990. As parallel to other studies in the literature, Hooker(1996) finds that the explanatory power of oil shocks onmacro variablesdiminishes as the sample is further updated. Lee et al. (1995) resultssuggest that the real oil price shock variable is statistically significant inexplaining GNP growth and unemployment over different sampleperiods. Their results imply that the impact of sudden jumps in oil priceson GNP growth and unemployment is greater in an environment whereoil prices are stable before the increases. Applying several differentfilters,Ewing and Thompson (2007) find that oil prices are negatively andcontemporaneously correlated with unemployment cycles in the U.S.Andreopoulos (2009), using quarterly U.S. data from 1953:2 to 2007:2and applying theMarkov SwitchingVector Autoregression, examines thecausality between unemployment and real input prices, the real prices ofenergy (crude oil) and capital (real interest rate). His results show thatthe real price of oil helps forecast unemployment in recessions only,while the real interest rate forecast unemployment in expansions. Thecommon feature of the studies above is that they study the relationshipbetween oil price shocks and employment in developed countries,mostly in theU.S. These studies generally show that the effects of oil priceincreases and decreases have asymmetric effects on the economy andeffects vary across time and countries.

The literature on developing countries is not as deep. In an analysis ofthe Greek economy Papapetrou (2001) confirms the immediate andnegative effect of an oil price shock on employment usingmonthly datafor theperiod1989:1 to 1999:6. EmployingVARanalysis, it is also arguedthat oil prices play an important role in affecting economic activity andemployment and oil price shocks explain a significant proportion of thefluctuations in output growth and employment growth. Robalo andSalvado (2008) conduct a related study for the Portuguese economy.Using the VAR methodology and different specifications of oil pricevariations, they find a significant effect of variations on the price of oilover the unemployment rate for thefirst time interval (1968–1985). Themagnitude of the coefficients become smaller for the second sub sample(1986–2005) indicating the change of the nature of the relationshipbetweenall economic variables andoil price shocks for Portugal from the1980s on as for most industrialized countries.

Empirical studies for the Turkish economy generally focusattention on energy demand and its effect on output and prices orthe relation between stock returns, crude oil prices, interest rates andoutput (see for example Soytas and Sari, 2003; Sari and Soytas, 2004,2005, 2006; Alper and Torul, 2008). Sari and Soytas (2005) resultsseem to differ from the literature since oil price shocks do not appear

to have significant impact on real stock returns in the İstanbul StockExchange. Alper and Torul's (2008) study is probably the first toreport for Turkey that the negative response of real output to oil priceincreases have decreased since the early 2000s. But in addition tousing standard variables such as oil price changes and real outputgrowth, they also include variables to account for global liquidityconditions. When they include the global liquidity conditions in theirmodel, the impact of oil price changes on aggregate economic activitybecomes significant even in the post-2000 period.

As can be understood from the studies on Turkey, the relationshipbetween oil price changes, unemployment and real interest rate for theTurkish economy is not directly addressed. The aim of this paper is to fillthis gap. van Wijnbergen (1985) argues that unemployment due to oilprice shock in 1974 was neoclassical in developed countries, butKeynesian in less developed countries. This suggests that the dynamiclink between oil prices and unemployment differs for countries atdifferent levels of development. Hence, individual country studies mayprove to be fruitful. In that respect, following the model of Carruth et al.(1998), we focus on the link between unemployment and real inputprices in Turkey. Our study differs from Carruth et al. (1998) in at leasttwo aspects. First, we examine the equilibrium unemployment rate andreal input prices in an emerging market, Turkey. Second, we apply aprocedure which does not necessitate estimation of a cointegratingequation (hence there is no risk of carrying any bias in the estimationprocedure further in the analysis) andcanbeappliedeven if the series areintegrated of arbitrary orders (Toda and Yamamoto, 1995). Our resultsare, nevertheless, consistent with Carruth et al. (1998) results for the US.

4. Data properties and the empirical model

In this paper, based on the efficiency wage model of Carruth et al.(1998), our aim is to examine the dynamic relationship between oilprices, unemployment rate and real interest rate in Turkey. We employthe relatively new time series technique known as the Toda–Yamamoto(TY) procedure (Toda and Yamamoto, 1995) to test for a long runGranger causality between the series. Since there are no differencedterms in any of the equations in this procedure, in the literature theresults due to this procedure are referred to as long run Grangercausality. To explore the relationship between the real interest rate, thereal price of energy and the unemployment rate, we use monthly datafrom 2005:1 to 2009:8 (56 observations) where 2005:1 is the earliestdate for which monthly unemployment rates are available. Theunemployment rate (UNEMP) and oil price (OPRICE) data are takenfrom IMF's data base. Interest rate (TBILL) data is from the Public FinanceStatistics reportedby theUndersecretariatof Treasury inTurkey. The realinterest measure is an auction-accepted average Treasury bill ratesdeflated by consumer price indexes.3 Unemployment is the civilianunemployment rate in percent and the oil price series is the U.S. dollarper barrel market price of crude oil deflated by consumer price indexes.All data are used in natural logarithms.

Toda and Yamamoto (TY) tests are valid for variables that havearbitrary orders of integration and unlike the Johansen-Juseliusprocedure it does not necessitate a pre-test for cointegration. TheTY procedure requires the knowledge on the maximum order ofintegration that the series in concern have. In order to assess thestationarity properties of the variables employed, we utilized 5different unit root tests; augmented Dickey and Fuller (1979) (ADF),Phillips and Perron (1988) (PP), Elliot et al. (1996) Dickey-Fuller GLSdetrended (DF-GLS) and Point Optimal (ERS-SPO), Kwiatkowski et al.(1992) (KPSS), and Ng and Perron's (2001) MZα (NP).4 The results ofthe unit root tests are in Table 1.

Page 4: Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market

Table 1Unit root test results.

ADF ADF GLS PP KPSS NP-Za

LevelsIntercept OPRICE −3.076871b (2) −2.321248b (1) −2.257319 0.112515a −11.3498b (1)

UNEMP −1.501397 (0) −1.511736 (0) −1.900218 0.398689a −4.78443 (0)TBILL 0.381763 (1) 0.929404 (1) 0.239047 0.567551a 2.29251 (1)

Intercept and trend OPRICE −3.050036 (2) −3.032816c (2) −2.271704 0.110694a −26.0304a (2)UNEMP −2.260552 (0) −1.909750 (0) −2.559470 0.165247a −6.30228 (0)TBILL −0.018190 (0) −1.277840 (1) −0.616249 0.142264a −6.77829 (1)

First differencesIntercept OPRICE −4.254035a (0) −4.187609a (0) −4.265351a 0.075181a −22.0422a (0)

UNEMP −5.802912a (0) −5.781488a (0) −5.802912a 0.130561a −28.1417a (0)TBILL −5.08112 a (0) −3.913259a (0) −5.014946a 0.228086a −16.9263a (0)

Intercept and trend OPRICE −4.207325a (0) −4.322329a (0) −4.224333a 0.047208a −21.3494b (0)UNEMP −5.870748a (0) −5.918339a (0) −5.866548a 0.035078a −26.4414a (0)TBILL −5.286137a (0) −4.778387a (0) −5.210917a 0.140217a −21.5348b (0)

All variables in natural logs, lag lengths are determined via SIC and are in parentheses. The null of all tests are unit roots, except for KPSS.a Indicates significance at 1%.b Indicates significance at 5%.c Indicates significance at 10%.

Table 2Diagnostic test results.

Equation Adj. R2 B-G test ARCH LM Ramsey RESET

UNEMP 0.8032329 4.1780a 10.9007(2)a 0.36704OPRICE 0.887985 0.4248 12.9081(2)a 0.77139TBILL 0.922550 2.0098b 3.8734(2) 1.38095

a Indicates significance at 1%.b Indicates significance at 10%.

Table 3Granger causality test results.

From To Test statistic p-value

OPRICE UNEMP 6.3553 0.0417a

OPRICE TBILL 1.2695 0.5301TBILL UNEMP 16.6089 0.0002b

TBILL OPRICE 1.1773 0.5551UNEMP OPRICE 0.4274 0.8076UNEMP TBILL 1.3723 0.5035

1526 H.G. Doğrul, U. Soytas / Energy Economics 32 (2010) 1523–1528

Based on the results in Table 1, although there are slightlyconflicting results, we can safely assume that the maximum order ofintegration is 1 (d=1). Since all series appear to be I(1), we proceedwith the TY procedure. The procedure involves a VAR in levels;therefore, there is no loss of information due to differencing. A Waldtest is conducted on the first k parameters of augmented VAR(k+d)model and the statistic follows an asymptotic Chi-square distributionwith k degrees of freedom (X2(k)). In our case, optimum lag length k isdetermined to be 2 by final prediction error (FPE) and likelihood ratiotest (LR). Hence, when we augment the VAR with maximum order ofintegration, the lag length becomes 3 (k+d=3). The estimated VAR(3) system is as below:

Vt = αv + β1Vt−1 + β2Vt−2 + β3Vt−3 + evt ð4Þ

where Vt=(UNEMPt, OPRICEt, TBILLt)′, αv is a (3×1) vector ofconstants, ß1, ß2, ß3 are (3×3) coefficient matrices, and εvt denoteswhite noise residuals.

In addition to checking the stability of the VAR, we subject allequations in the VAR to a series of diagnostic tests to assess theconformity to common assumptions. The diagnostic test results aresummarized in Table 2.

As Table 2 shows, there are violations of the heteroscedasticityassumptions, especially for the unemployment equation. TheBreusch–Godfrey (BG) test statistics appear to be significant for thefirst and second equations at 1% and 10% significant level. There is alsoevidence of an ARCH effect. Lagrangemultiplier test for autoregressiveconditional heteroscedasticity (ARCH LM) reveals problems with thefirst and second equations. There is no evidence of parameterinstability as indicated by Ramsey RESET tests for all equations.Although, Table 2 indicates some problems, when we consider thecorrelograms of residuals and squared residuals and the Ljung–Box Qstatistics, we observe that there is no serial correlation and partialcorrelations at all lags and Q statistics are insignificant with large pvalues. We also subject all equations to the CUSUM and CUSUM ofsquares tests for any parameter instability, but we could not find any.Furthermore, the Chow breakpoint tests indicate that the equationsare robust with respect to a possible break in 2008:06 and 2008:07due to oil crisis. The VAR(3) satisfies the stability condition in that noroots are outside the unit circle.5 Hence, these diagnostic test resultsallow us to confidently apply the Wald test for Granger causality.

5 Correlograms of residuals and squared residuals, CUSUM and CUSUM of squares,are available from authors upon request.

5. Long run granger causality and generalized impulse responses

The Granger causality framework allows for testing the existenceand the direction of causality between variables. The TY procedureallows us to conduct long run Granger causality tests without anyneed for testing cointegration and estimating the cointegrationequation. The test results are based on the first k lags in Eq. (4) foreach variable and are summarized in Table 3.

We observe that there are only two significant results. Oil price andinterest rate Granger cause unemployment in the long run. Hence,knowledgeof real priceof oil and interest ratemay improve the forecastsof the unemployment rate. The reverse does not hold, therefore thecausality is not bi-directional. Our finding of the positive link betweenenergy price and unemployment is inline with Papapetrou (2001) whofound the causality between oil price and employment in Greece.However, Andreopoulos (2009) argue that only in recessions that thereal price of oil forecasts the unemployment in theUS. Hence, our resultssupport the hypothesis that changes in the input prices affectunemployment in the case of the Turkey. Our overall results alsoconfirm the efficiency wage framework, in that increases in the realprices of other inputs lead the unemployment rate to rise.

The test statistics follow a X2 distribution with 2 degrees of freedom.a Indicates significance at 5%.b Indicates significance at 1%.

Page 5: Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Response of UNEMP to OPRICE

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Response of UNEMP to TBILL

Fig. 1. Generalized impulse responses of unemployment to other variables.

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Response of OPRICE to UNEMP

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Response of OPRICE to TBILL

Fig. 2. Generalized impulse responses of oil price to other variables.

1527H.G. Doğrul, U. Soytas / Energy Economics 32 (2010) 1523–1528

The TY procedure is a way to examine the long run Grangercausality relationship among the series. However it does not provideinformation on how each variable responds to innovations in othervariables, and whether the shock is permanent or not. This can bedone via generalized impulse response analysis by Koop, et al. (1996)and Pesaran and Shin (1998). The generalized impulse responseanalysis does not suffer from the orthogonality critique and the resultsare not sensitive to the ordering of the variables in the VAR, which arethe main problems faced by traditional impulse responses. Figs. 1 to 3show the responses of unemployment, oil price and interest rate toone standard deviation shocks to other variables in the VAR. In allfigures, the impacts tend to die off rapidly. It is clear from anexamination of Fig. 1 that shocks to oil price and interest rate haverespectively negative and insignificant initial impacts on unemploy-ment. Shocks in oil price have positive impact on interest rate andtend to die off quickly. Shocks in the unemployment have initiallynegative significant impact on oil price and then become insignificant.

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Response of TBILL to UNEMP

-

-

-

Fig. 3. Generalized impulse responses

6. Conclusions

This paper investigates the relationship between oil prices, unem-ployment and interest rate in Turkey based on an efficiencywagemodelof Carruth et al. (1998). A considerable body of economic literatureindicates the adverse economic impact of oil price shocks for thedeveloped economies. But, there are not enough empirical studies onTurkey and other developing countries. By employing the TY procedure,we were able to support the evidence that input prices, including oilprice, affect the unemployment in Turkey.Our results suggest that in thelong run both the real price of oil and the real interest rate have an effecton the unemployment rate in Turkey, confirming Carruth, et al. (1998)results for the U.S. The Andreopoulos (2009) results for U.S. duringrecessions are also similar. Our results also suggest that labor is asubstitute factor of production for capital and energy in Turkey. Weunderstand that oil shocks operate mainly through conventionalaggregate channels, transmitting oil price increases to the labor market

.3

.2

.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Response of TBILL to OPRICE

of interest rate to other variables.

Page 6: Relationship between oil prices, interest rate, and unemployment: Evidence from an emerging market

1528 H.G. Doğrul, U. Soytas / Energy Economics 32 (2010) 1523–1528

in Turkey, as Hamilton (1988) suggested. This study brings forth aquestion of whether the theory also holds for other developingcountries.

References

Alper, C.E., Torul, O., 2008. Oil prices, aggregate economic activity and global liquidityconditions: evidence from Turkey. Economics Bulletin 17 (4), 1–8.

Andreopoulos, S., 2009. Oil matters: real input prices and U.S. unemployment revisited.The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 9 (1), 1–29.

Beaudreau, B.C., 2005. Engineering and economic growth. Structural Change andEconomic Dynamics 16 (2), 211–220.

Borjas, J.G., 1996. Labor Economics. The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., United States.Brown, S., Yucel, M., 1999. Oil prices and U.S. aggregate economic activity: a question of

neutrality. Economic and Financial Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas SecondQuarter, pp. 16–23.

Brown, S., Yucel, M., 2002. Energy prices and aggregate economic activity: aninterpretative survey. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 42 (2), 193–208.

Burbidge, J., Harrison, A., 1984. Testing for the effects of oil-price rise using vectorautoregression. International Economic Review 25 (1), 459–484.

Carruth, A., Hooker, M., Oswald, A., 1998. Unemployment equilibria and input prices:theory and evidence from the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics 80,621–628.

Davis, S., Haltiwanger, J., 2001. sectoral job creation and destruction responses to oilprice changes. Journal of Monetary Economics 48 (3), 465–512.

Dickey, D.A., Fuller, W.A., 1979. Distribution of the estimators for autoregressive timeseries with a unit root. Journal of the American Statistical Society 75, 427–431.

Dohner, R.S., 1981. Energy Prices, Economic Activity and Inflation: Survey of Issues andResults. In: Mork, K.A. (Ed.), Energy Prices, Inflation and Economic Activity.Ballinger, Cambridge, MA.

Elliot, G., Rothenberg, T.J., Stock, J.H., 1996. Efficient tests for an autoregressive unit root.Econometrica 64, 813–836.

Ewing, B.T., Thompson, M.A., 2007. Dynamic cyclical comovements of oil prices withindustrial production, consumer prices, unemployment, and stock prices. EnergyPolicy 35, 5535–5540.

Fried, E.R., Schultze, C.L., 1975. Higher Oil Prices and The World Economy. TheBrookings Institution, Washington D.C.

Gisser, M., Goodwin, T.H., 1986. Crude oil and macroeconomy: tests of some popularnotions. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 18, 95–103.

Hamilton, J., 1983. Oil and the macroeconomy since World War II. Journal of PoliticalEconomy 91, 228–248.

Hamilton, J., 1988. A neoclassical model of unemployment and the business cycle.Journal of Political Economy 96, 593–617.

Hooker, M.A., 1996. What happened to the oil price-macroeconomy relationship?Journal of Monetary Economics 38, 195–213.

Koop, G., Pesaran, M.H., Potter, S.M., 1996. Impulse response analysis in nonlinearmultivariate models. Journal of Econometrics 74, 119–147.

Kwiatkowski, D., Phillps, P.C.B., Schmidt, P., Shin, Y., 1992. Testing the null hypothesis ofstationary against the alternative of a unit root. Journal of Econometrics 54,159–178.

Lardic, S., Mignon, V., 2008. Oil prices and economic activity: an asymmetriccointegration approach. Energy Economics 30 (3), 847–855.

Lee, K., Ni, S., Ronald, A., 1995. Oil Shocks and the macroeconomy: the role of pricevolatility. Energy Journal 16, 3–56.

Loungani, P., 1986. Oil price shocks and the dispersion hypothesis. Review of Economicsand Statistics 58, 536–539.

Maddala, G.S., Kim, I., 1998. Unit Roots, Cointegration, and Structural Change.Cambridge Unversity Press, Cambridge.

Mork, K.A., 1994. Business cycles and the oil market. The Energy Journal 15, 15–38.Mory, J.F., 1993. Oil prices and economic activity: is the relationship symmetric? Energy

Journal 14, 151–161.Ng, S., Perron, P., 2001. Lag length selection and the construction of unit root tests with

good size and power. Econometrica 69, 1519–1554.Papapetrou, E., 2001. Oil price shocks, stockmarket, economic activity and employment

in Greece. Energy Economics 23, 511–532.Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., 1998. Generalized impulse response analysis in linear

multivariate models. Economics Letters 58, 17–29.Phillips, P.C.B., Perron, P., 1988. Testing for a unit root in time series regressions.

Biometrica 75, 335–346.Pierce, J.L., Enzler, J.J., 1974. The effects of external inflationary shocks. Brookings Paper

on Economic Activity 1, 13–61.Robalo, P. B. and Salvado, J. C. (2008). “Oil Price Shocks and the Portuguese Economy

Since 1970s”. FEUNL Working Paper Series No. 529. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=13091172.

Sari, Ramazan, Soytas, Ugur, 2004. Disaggregate energy consumption, employment;and income in Turkey. Energy Economics 26, 335–344.

Sari, Ramazan, Soytas, Ugur, 2005. Inflation, stock returns and real activity: evidencefrom a high inflation country. The Empirical Economics Letters 4, 181–192.

Sari, R., Soytas, U., 2006. The relationship between stock returns, crude oil prices,interest rates, and output: evidence from a developing economy. The EmpiricalEconomics Letters 5 (4), 205–220.

Shapiro, C., Stiglitz, J.E., 1984. Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device.The American Economic Review 74 (3), 433–444.

Soytas, U., Sari, R., 2003. Energy consumption and GDP: causality relationship in G-7countries and emerging markets. Energy Economics 25, 33–37.

Stern, D.I., 2000. A multivariate cointegration analysis of the role of energy in the USmacroeconomy. Energy Economics 22, 267–283.

Tang, W., Wu, L. and Zhang, Z. X. (2009). “Oil Price Shocks and Their Short- and Long-Term Effects on The Chinese Economy”. East West Center Working Paper No. 102.Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1396943.

Toda, H.Y., Yamamoto, T., 1995. Statistical inference in vector autoregression withpossibly integrated processes. Journal of Econometrics 66, 225–250.

Uri, N.D., 1996. Changing crude oil price effects on US agricultural employment. EnergyEconomics 18 (3), 185–202.

van Wijnbergen, S., 1985. Oil price shocks, unemployment, investment and the currentaccount: an intertemporal disequilibrium analysis. The Review of Economic Studies52 (4), 627–645.