39
J. Math. Sci. Univ. Tokyo 5 (1998), 747–785. Pricing of Passport Option By Izumi Nagayama Abstract. Passport options are derivatives on actively managed funds. There is no known explicit formula for the price of passport options in general. We estimate and analyze the value function, and give the condition that the optimal strategy becomes trivial. We also show an approximation theorem which enables us to compute the value function numerically. Finally we give the explicit formula for the value function in the case that the interest rate is zero by using stochastic analytic approach. This is somehow done in symmetric case by Hyer, Lipton-Lifschitz, and Pugachevsky using partial differential equation approach. 1. Introduction Many traded securities are managed in the trading account. The value of the trading account is the wealth accumulated by trading the securities following to some trading strategies. The derivative security called “Pass- port option” is the contract that an option holder has the right to gain the positive part of trading account at maturity. The option holder executes a trading strategy (fictitiously) which is chosen by himself in the class of strategies specified in the contract, and whenever the option holder changes the position, he has to report the amount of security to the option writer. In this paper we suppose that there is one traded security whose value process S t follows Black & Scholes model [1], i.e. under the risk neutral measure P , S t satisfies dS t = S t (rdt + σdB t ), (1.1) where r and σ are constants and B is a P -Brownian motion. The value X θ,x t of trading account at time t under the strategy θ with initial value x 1991 Mathematics Subject Classification . Primary 90A09; Secondary 60J55. Key words: passport option, Black & Scholes model, local time, Skorohod’s Theorem, stochastic control. 747

Passport Option

  • Upload
    caqrlos

  • View
    16

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Passport Option

Citation preview

  • J. Math. Sci. Univ. Tokyo5 (1998), 747785.

    Pricing of Passport Option

    By Izumi Nagayama

    Abstract. Passport options are derivatives on actively managedfunds. There is no known explicit formula for the price of passportoptions in general. We estimate and analyze the value function, andgive the condition that the optimal strategy becomes trivial. We alsoshow an approximation theorem which enables us to compute the valuefunction numerically. Finally we give the explicit formula for the valuefunction in the case that the interest rate is zero by using stochasticanalytic approach. This is somehow done in symmetric case by Hyer,Lipton-Lifschitz, and Pugachevsky using partial dierential equationapproach.

    1. Introduction

    Many traded securities are managed in the trading account. The value

    of the trading account is the wealth accumulated by trading the securities

    following to some trading strategies. The derivative security called Pass-

    port option is the contract that an option holder has the right to gain the

    positive part of trading account at maturity. The option holder executes

    a trading strategy (ctitiously) which is chosen by himself in the class of

    strategies specied in the contract, and whenever the option holder changes

    the position, he has to report the amount of security to the option writer.

    In this paper we suppose that there is one traded security whose value

    process St follows Black & Scholes model [1], i.e. under the risk neutral

    measure P , St satises

    dSt = St(rdt+ dBt),(1.1)

    where r and are constants and B is a P -Brownian motion. The value

    X,xt of trading account at time t under the strategy with initial value x

    1991 Mathematics Subject Classication. Primary 90A09; Secondary 60J55.Key words: passport option, Black & Scholes model, local time, Skorohods Theorem,

    stochastic control.

    747

  • 748 Izumi Nagayama

    is expressed as

    X,xt = x+

    t0sdSs.(1.2)

    Let 1 < 2. We denote by (1, 2) the set of predictable processes

    satisfying 1 t 2 for any t 0. The passport option whose pay-o isa positive part of trading account at maturity T is evaluated by

    C(T, x) = sup(1,2)

    E[erT (X,xT )+].(1.3)

    We dene Zt as a process which satises

    dZt = Zt(rdt+ dBt), Z0 = 1

    and dene

    (t, y) = r,1,2(t, y)def= sup

    (1,2)E[(y +

    t0udZu)

    +].

    Then, we have C(T, x) = S0erT(T,

    x

    S0).

    The optimal strategy which attain the supremum in (1.3) does not al-

    ways exist in the strategy class (1, 2), and the explicit formula of (1.3)

    is not known in general.

    In Section 2 we give the denition of passport option and show that its

    price is given by (1.3).

    In Section 3 we assume that r 0, 1 = 1, and 2 = 1. And letting

    0(t, y) = r,0 (t, y)

    def= E[(y +

    t0dZu)

    +] = E[(y + Zt 1)+],

    we estimate (t, y) and examine the conditions for = 0. Let (x) =12

    ex2

    2 and (x) =

    x

    (y)dy. We have the following theorem as the

    estimation of (t, y).

    Theorem 1.1. For any c > 0, t > 0, and y R,(t, y) 0(t, y)

    (e2t 1) 122

    ( c

    t

    )+ 2

    |y|

    ec

    (1 e2t)

    14

    e3r2

    22t.

  • Pricing of Passport Option 749

    For each T > 0, we dene

    R(T )def= inf{r > 0 : r,(t, y) = r,0 (t, y)

    for all r r, t [0, T ], and y R}.We show the following results.

    Theorem 1.2. Let c be the solution of c(

    1 c) = 1 c (

    1 c). Then

    R(T ) = 2c+3c(1 32c)

    1 cT

    4c{c2(1 2c)16(1 c)5/2 +

    131c3 270c2 + 168c 3248(1 c)2

    }T + o(T ),

    as T 0.

    Theorem 1.3. R(T ) = 2 2 log(22T )

    2(2T + 1)+ o

    (1

    T 2

    ), as T .

    Theorem 1.4. For any r, there exists T0 = T0(r, 2) > 0 such that

    0(t, y) = (t, y), for any t [0, T0] and y 1.

    In Section 4, we prove that the value function of passport option can be

    derived as the limit of discrete time approximation.

    In Section 5, we consider the case that r = 0. Hyer, Lipton-Lifschitz

    and Pugachevsky [2] derived the explicit formula in the case that 1 =

    2 using partial dierential equation approach. We derive the explicitformula in general case that 1 2 using stochastic analytic approach.By introducing the Equivalent Martingale Measure P with respect to the

    numeraire St, we show that the problem of passport option valuation comes

    down to the problem of calculation of an expected value E[(Y yT )+] where

    Y yt is the solution of

    dYt = (1 + |Yt|)dBt, Y0 = y.

  • 750 Izumi Nagayama

    Using Skorohods Theorem, we derive the explicit formula for valuation of

    passport options (see Theorem 5.6).

    In Section 6, by numerical calculations we illustrate the functions r(t)and (r(t), t) introduced in Section 3. Furthermore numerical experiencesin the discrete time framework discussed at Section 4 are reported.

    The author expresses her sincere thanks to Professors Shigeo Kusuoka

    and Freddy Delbaen for their kind advice and discussion.

    2. Notation and Problems

    Let (Bt)0t

  • Pricing of Passport Option 751

    To prove this proposition, we need some preparations. Let Zt be a

    process given by the following S.D.E.

    dZt = Zt(rdt+ dBt), Z0 = 1,

    i.e. Zt = exp(Bt 122t+rt). Let U ,xt = sup

    E

    [(X,xt +

    TtudSu)

    +|Ft]

    for , x R, and t [0, T ]. Let

    (t, y) = r,1,2(t, y)def= sup

    (1,2)E[(y +

    t0udZu)

    +].

    Then it is easy to see that 0 (t, y2) (t, y1) y2 y1 for y1 y2 andthat U ,xt = St(T t, X

    ,xtSt

    ). Then we have the following.

    Lemma 2.2. {U ,xt }0tT is a non-negative supermartingale.

    Proof. E[|U ,xT |

    ]= E

    [|X,xT |

    ]

  • 752 Izumi Nagayama

    Therefore (T t, X,xt

    St) = lim

    nE

    (X,xt

    St+

    Ttns dZs

    )+Ft, a.s. Then

    by the dominated convergence theorem we have

    E[U ,xt |Fs] = limnE[(X,xt +

    TtnudSu)

    +

    Fs]

    sup

    E

    [(X,xt +

    TtudSu)

    +

    Fs].

    Proof of Proposition 2.1. Suppose that C(T, x, S, 1, 2) sup

    E

    [erT (X,xT )

    +S0=S

    ]. Then we

    sell the passport option by value C(T, x, S, 1, 2). Suppose the option

    holder takes a trading strategy . From Lemma 2.2, {erTU ,xt }0tT is anon-negative supermartingale, so it has a unique decomposition erTU ,xt =M ,xt A,xt , where {M ,xt } is a square integrable martingale and {A,xt } isa non-decreasing predictable process with A0 = 0. Let St = e

    rtSt, thenwe have dSt = StdBt and S is a P -martingale. From the representation

    theorem of Brownian martingales, there exists an adapted process {Ht} suchthat E[

    T0 H

    2s S

    2sds]

  • Pricing of Passport Option 753

    U ,xT +erTA,xT = (X

    ,xT )

    ++erTA,xT . Then we will have the gain erTA,xT 0

    at time T . Since the initial gain was C(T, x, S, 1, 2) M ,x0 > 0, it is anarbitrage.

    For any positive constant , by considering the passport option

    whose underlying is times the original underlying, we have that

    C(T, x, S, 1, 2) = C(T, x, S, 1, 2). And by changing time, we have

    Cr,(T, x, S, 1, 2) = Cr/2,1(2T, x, S, 1, 2).

    Proposition 2.3. (t, y) is convex, increasing, and Lipschitz with re-

    spect to y. Moreover if 1 0 2, (t, y) is increasing in t.

    Proof. For any convex function g and 0 1, we have

    sup

    E[g(x+ (1 )y + t0udZu)]

    sup

    [E[g(x+

    t0udZu)] + (1 )E[g(y +

    t0udZu)]

    ]

    sup

    E[g(x+

    t0udZu)] + (1 ) sup

    E[g(y +

    t0udZu)].

    Therefore (t, ) is convex. We can easily see that (t, y) is increasing andLipschitz with respect to y. Let 1 0 2 and s < t, then

    (t, y) = sup

    E[(y +

    t0udZu)

    +] sup

    E[(y +

    s0udZu)

    +] = (s, y).

    3. The Estimation of the Value Function

    In this section, we assume r 0, 1 = 1, and 2 = 1. By Proposition2.1, C(t, x, S) = Sert(t, xS ). Let

    0(t, y) = r,0 (t, y)

    def= E[(y+

    t0dZu)

    +] = E[(y+Zt1)+] , t 0, y R.

    Then obviously we have (t, y) 0(t, y). Let

    (x) =12

    ex2

    2 and (x) =

    x

    (y)dy.

  • 754 Izumi Nagayama

    Theorem 3.1. For any c > 0,

    (t, y) 0(t, y)

    (e2t 1) 122

    ( c

    t

    )+ 2

    |y|

    ec

    (1 e2t)

    14

    e3r2

    22t.

    Proof. For each , let = inf{t > 0 : y + t0 sdZs = 0}. First,let us assume that y 0. Then we have

    (t, y) = sup

    (E[y +

    t0sdZs] + E[(y +

    t0sdZs)

    , t > ])

    0(t, y) + sup

    E[(y +

    t0sdZs)

    , t > ].

    Recall that dZt = Zt(rdt+dBt). Dene a P -equivalent probability measure

    Q by (dQdP )t = tdef= exp( rBt r

    2

    22t). Since Wt

    def= r t+Bt is a Q-Brownian

    motion, Z is a Q-square integrable martingale. Then, for each , wehave

    E

    [(y +

    t0sdZs)

    , t > ] E

    [ t0sdZs

    I{t>}]

    = EQ[ t0sdZs

    I{t>} 1t]

    EQ[ t0sdZs

    2] 1

    2

    EQ[I{t>}]14EQ

    [1

    4t

    ] 14

    .

    Here we have EQ[

    1

    4t

    ]= E

    [1

    3t

    ]= E

    [exp

    (3r

    Bt +

    3r2

    22t

    )]= e

    6r2

    2t. Let

    Mt =

    t0sdZs, then we have

    [M,M ]t =

    t02sd[Z,Z]s

    t02Z2sds =

    2 t0

    exp(2Ws 2s)ds.

    Therefore we have

    EQ[ t0sdZs

    2] 2

    t0e

    2sds = (e2t 1).

  • Pricing of Passport Option 755

    By Knights theorem (see Ikeda and Watanabe [3]) there exists a Q-

    Brownian motion {Wt}t[0,) such that Ms = W[M,M ]s . Therefore we havefor any c > 0

    EQ[I{t>}] = Q[

    inf0st

    Ms < y]

    = Q

    [inf

    0s[M,M ]tWs < y

    ]

    Q[inf{Ws : 0 s (1 e2t) exp(2 max

    0utWu)} < y

    ]

    Q[

    max0ut

    Wu c]

    +Q

    [inf

    0s(1e2t)e2cWs < y

    ].

    It is well known that Q[ max0ut

    Wu a] = 2( a

    t

    )for a > 0. So we have

    EQ[I{t>}] 2( c

    t

    )+ 2

    y

    ec

    (1 e2t)

    . Therefore we have

    our assertion in the case that y 0.We can prove the case of y < 0 similarly.

    By Theorem 3.1, we can easily prove that for any p > 0, there exists

    cp > 0 such that (t, y) 0(t, y) + cp|y|p/2, |y| 1. Therefore we have

    limy(t, y) = 0, limy

    1

    y(t, y) = 1, and

    limy

    +

    y+(t, y) = lim

    y

    y(t, y) = 1.

    In the rest of this section, we examine the condition such that = 0is satised.

    Remark 3.2. We can easily see the following.

    0(t, y) =

    (r,y,t,)

    (y + etx 1

    22t+rt 1)e

    x22

    2dx if y < 1

    y + ert 1 if y 1

    where (r, y, t, ) = log(1 y) 122t+ rt

    t

    for t > 0, y < 1.

  • 756 Izumi Nagayama

    For each T > 0 and > 0, dene

    R(T ) = inf{r > 0 : r,(t, y) = r,0 (t, y)for all r r, t [0, T ], and y R}.

    Let V ,xt = V,x,r,t

    def= St

    r,0

    (T t, X

    ,xt

    St

    ), for , x R, 0 t T .

    Then {V 1,xt }0tT is a martingale. Let

    F (r, y, t, ) = r0y

    (t, y) y220y2

    (t, y).

    Lemma 3.3. For any T > 0 and > 0,

    R(T ) = inf {r : F (r, y, t, ) 0, for any y (0, 1), t (0, T ]} .

    Proof. Noting that V ,xT =

    (x+

    T0tdSt

    )+, we have the following

    from the proof of Proposition 2.1.

    R(T ) = inf{r > 0 : {V ,x,r,t }0tT is a P -supermartingale,for all r r, x R, and }.

    So it is sucient to show that {V ,x,r,t }0tT is a P -supermartingale forall and x R if and only if F (r, y, t, ) 0 for all y (0, 1) andt (0, T ]. Let

    Y ,ytdef=

    X,xtSt

    , x = yS0.(3.1)

    Then by Itos formula we have

    dY ,yt = (t Y ,yt )(rdt+ dBt 2dt)

    and

    dV ,x,r,t = V (St, Y

    ,yt , t, T t)dBt + V (St, Y ,yt , t, T t)dt,

  • Pricing of Passport Option 757

    where

    V (S, y, , t) = S( y)0y

    (t, y) + S0(t, y)

    V (S, y, , t) = rS( y)0y

    (t, y) S0t

    (t, y)

    +1

    2S( y)22

    20y2

    (t, y) + rS0(t, y).

    Since {V 1,x,r,t }0tT is a martingale, we have V (S, y, 1, t) = 0 for allt (0, T ]. Note that {V ,x,r,t }0tT is supermartingale if and only ifV (S, y, , t) 0 = V (S, y, 1, t) for any y R, S > 0, t (0, T ], || 1.This is equivalent to

    r0y

    (t, y) +2

    2( + 1 2y)

    20y2

    (t, y) 0,(3.2)for y R, t (0, T ], || 1.

    Since 0(t, y) is convex in y, we have20y2

    0, and so the condition (3.2)is equivalent to that

    F (r, y, t, ) = r0y

    (t, y) y220y2

    (t, y) 0, t (0, T ](3.3)

    for all y R. Here we have0y

    (t, y) =

    {1 if y 1((r, y, t, )) if y < 1

    20y2

    (t, y) =

    {0 if y 1

    1(1y)t((r, y, t, )) if y < 1.

    So in the case that y 1 or y 0, condition (3.3) is satised for allt (0, T ]. This proves our assertion.

    Remark 3.4. From Remark 3.2, we have the following.

    F (r, y, t, ) = r((r, y, t, )) y(1 y)t((r, y, t, ))(3.4)

    F

    r(r, y, t, ) = ((r, y, t, ))(3.5)

  • 758 Izumi Nagayama

    +((r, y, t, ))

    {t

    r +

    y

    1 y(r, y, t, )}

    F

    y(r, y, t, ) =

    ((r, y, t, ))

    (1 y)2t3

    {(r 2)t 1

    22ty y log(1 y)

    }(3.6)

    F

    t(r, y, t, ) = ((r, y, t, ))

    {y

    2(1 y)t3

    (3.7)

    +

    (r +

    y(r, y, t, )

    (1 y)t

    )log(1 y) 122t+ rt

    2t3

    }.

    Lemma 3.5. R(T ) 2.

    Proof. From (3.5), we haveF

    r(r, y, t, ) 0 for all r 2, y (0, 1)

    and t (0, T ]. So it is sucient to show that F (2, y, t, ) 0 for ally (0, 1) and t (0, T ]. From (3.6), we have

    F

    y(2, y, t, )

    { 0 if 0 < y 1 e 122t 0 if 1 e 122t y < 1.

    It is sucient to show that F0(t)def= F (2, 1 e 122t, t, ) 0 for all t > 0.

    Since F 0(t) =(e

    122t 1)2t3

    (t) 0, F0(t) is an increasing function.

    Also,

    limt0

    F0(t) = limt0

    2(t) lim

    t0(e

    122t 1)t

    (t) =

    2

    2.

    Therefore F (2, 1 e 122t, t, ) 22 for all t > 0.

    Lemma 3.6. Let r < 2. Then for each t > 0, there exists a unique

    (r, t) (0, 1) such that F (r, (r, t), t, ) = miny(0,1)

    F (r, y, t, ).

    Proof. Note that((r, y, t, ))

    (1 y)2t3

    > 0. So from (3.6),F

    y(r, y, t, ) > 0

    (< 0) if and only if f(y) = (r 2)t 122ty y log(1 y) > 0 (< 0,

  • Pricing of Passport Option 759

    respectively). Note that f (y) = 122t log(1 y) + y

    1 y . So f(y) is

    increasing in y (0, 1). Also we have f (0) = 122t < 0, lim

    y1f (y) = ,

    f(0) = rt 2t < 0, and limy1

    f(y) = . So we see that the equationF

    y(r, y, t, ) = 0 in y has a unique solution and it gives the minimum of

    F (r, , t, ).

    Remark 3.7. The proof of Lemma 3.6 shows that (r, t) is a solution

    ofF

    y(r, y, t, ) = 0. Therefore (r, t) is characterized as a solution of

    log(1 (r, t)) = rt 2t

    (r, t) 1

    22t, 0 < (r, t) < 1.(3.8)

    Then we have

    (r, (r, t), t, ) =2 r(r, t)

    t+

    rt

    .(3.9)

    By (3.8) we see that limt0{(r, t) log(1 (r, t))} and lim

    t{(r, t)

    log(1 (r, t))} = . This implies

    limt0

    (r, t) = 0 and limt

    (r, t) = 1.(3.10)

    Lemma 3.8. For r (0, 2), (r, t) =t(2 r) + r

    4t+ o(t) as t 0.

    Proof. Note that we have log(1 x) = x(1 +R(x)), where R(x) =i=1

    1

    i+ 1xi, for |x| < 1. From Equation (3.8), we have

    (r, t)2(1 +R((r, t))) 122t(r, t) (2 r)t = 0.

    Since (r, t) (0, 1), we have

    (r, t) =t2t+

    4t+ 16(2 r)(1 +R((r, t)))

    4(1 +R((r, t))).(3.11)

  • 760 Izumi Nagayama

    So limt0

    (r, t)t

    =2 r. Let f(t) = (r, t)2 rt . Then from (3.8)

    we have

    (t(2 r) + f(t)) log(1

    t(2 r) f(t))

    +1

    22t(

    t(2 r) + f(t)) + (2 r)t = 0.

    Since we have

    log(1t(2 r)f(t)) = log(1

    t(2 r)) f(t)

    1t(2 r)(1+R(t))

    where R(t) = R

    (f(t)

    1t(2 r))

    , f(t) is the solution of the following

    equation.

    Atf(t)2 +Btf(t) + Ct = 0,

    where At = 1 + R(t)1t(2 r)

    Bt = log(1t(2 r))

    t(2 r)(1 + R(t))1t(2 r) +

    1

    22t

    Ct =t(2 r) log(1

    t(2 r))

    +1

    22t

    t(2 r) + (2 r)t.

    Since limt0At = 1, limt0

    Btt

    = 22 r, and lim

    t0Ctt3

    = 12(2 r)3/2 +

    1

    222 r, we have lim

    t0f(t)

    t=r

    4.

    We can show the following lemma similarly to Lemma 3.8.

    Lemma 3.9. For r (0, 2),

    (r, t) =t(2 r) + r

    4t+

    3r2 12r(2 r) 16(2 r)2962 r t

    3/2

    +o(tt) as t 0.

  • Pricing of Passport Option 761

    Let G(r, t) = F (r, (r, t), t, ). Then we have the following.

    Proposition 3.10. For each t > 0, the equation G(r, t) = 0 in r has a

    unique solution r(t) in (0, 2). Moreover r(t) is continuous in t (0,).

    Proof. Note that by (3.5) we have

    G

    r(r, t) = ((r, (r, t), t, ))

    +((r, (r, t), t, ))

    t

    r +

    (r, t)

    1 (r, t) r2(r,t) t+ rt

    t

    > 0 for 0 r < 2.

    From (3.8) we have (r, t) = 1exp{

    (r 2)t(r, t)

    122t

    }. Since 0 < (r, t) 0 from (3.8), so limr2

    (r, t) = 1 e 122t. This

    implies that limr2

    G(r, t) = F (2, 1 e 122t, t, ) 2

    2(see the proof of

    Lemma 3.5). So we have the rst assertion and we complete the proof by

    implicit function theorem.

    Corollary 3.11. R(T ) = max0tT

    r(t). In particular, R(T ) < 2.

    Proposition 3.12. limt0

    r(t) = c2 , where c is the solution of

    c(

    1 c) = 1 c(1 c).

    Proof. Let G0(r) = limt0

    G(r, t). Then we have

    G0(r) = r

    (1

    2 r

    )

    2 r

    (1

    2 r

    ),

    and

    G0(c2) = c2(

    1 c) 21 c(1 c) = 0.

  • 762 Izumi Nagayama

    Since G0(r) = (

    1

    2 r

    )> 0, we have G0(c

    2 8) < 0 < G0(c2 + 8),for any 8 > 0. So by Proposition 3.10 lim

    t0r(t) = c2.

    We get c = 0.2945... by numerical calculation.

    Proposition 3.13. R(T ) = 2c+3c(1 32c)

    1 cT+o(

    T ), as T 0.

    Proof. Let H(t, a) = G(c2 + at, t), where c is the value dened in

    Proposition 3.12. By Lemma 3.8 we have

    (c2 + at, t) =

    1 ct

    (a

    2

    1 c c2

    4

    )t+ o(t).

    Therefore we have from (3.9)

    (c2 + at, (c2 + a

    t, t), t, )

    =2(1 c) at

    2

    1 c(

    a2

    1c c3

    4

    )t

    + ct+ o(

    t)

    =

    1 c+ h(a)t+ o(t),

    where h(a) = a22

    1 c +

    3

    4c. And we have

    (c2 + at, t)

    (1 (c2 + at, t))t =2

    1 c(

    a2

    1c c3

    4

    )t

    1 1 ct+(

    a2

    1c c2

    4

    )t

    + o(t)

    = 2

    1 c+ k(a)t+ o(t),

    where k(a) = a2

    1 c + 3 3c

    3

    4. Since (x + z) = (x) + (x)z +

    o(z) as z 0 and (x+ z) = (x) x(x)z + o(z) as z 0 , we have

    H(t, a) = (c2 + at){(1 c) + (1 c)h(a)t+ o(t)}

    (21 c+ k(a)t){(1 c)1 c(1 c)h(a)t+ o(t)}.

  • Pricing of Passport Option 763

    Therefore from the denitions of c, we have

    H0(a) = limt0

    H(t, a)t

    = (

    1 c){c2h(a)+a

    1 cc

    +2(1c)h(a)k(a)}.

    Noting that H 0(a) = (

    1 c) 1 2cc

    1 c > 0 and H0(3c(1 32c)

    1 c

    )= 0,

    we see H0(3c(1 3

    2c)

    1c 8) < 0 < H0(3c(1 3

    2c)

    1c + 8) for any 8 > 0. So r(t) =

    c2 +3c(1 32c)

    1 ct+ o(

    t). By Corollary 3.11, we have our assertion.

    We can also show the following. Although we need ner computation,

    the idea of the proof is similar and so we omit the proof.

    Theorem 3.14.

    R(T ) = 2c+3c(1 32c)

    1 cT

    4c{c2(1 2c)16(1 c)5/2 +

    131c3 270c2 + 168c 3248(1 c)2

    }T

    +o(T ), as T 0.

    We also have the following theorem.

    Theorem 3.15. R(T ) = 2 2 log(22T )

    2(2T + 1)+ o

    (1

    T 2

    ), as T .

    Proof. For each h R, set r0(h, t) = 2 2 log(22t)

    2(2t+ 1)+h

    t2. Then,

    (3.8) yields

    0(h, t) = (r0(h, t), t)) = 1 e2

    2t exp

    (

    2t log(22t)

    2(2t+ 1)0(h, t)+

    h

    t0(h, t)

    )

    = 1 o(e2

    2t) as t ,

  • 764 Izumi Nagayama

    and we have from (3.9)

    0(h, t)def= (r0(h, t), 0(h, t), t, )

    = t+

    (2t log(22t)

    2(2t+ 1) htt

    )(1

    0(h, t) 1

    )

    as t .Then we have

    (0(h, t))t(1 0(h, t))

    = exp

    ( log(2

    2t)

    2(2t+ 1) h

    t

    )

    exp12

    (2t log(22t)

    2(2t+ 1) htt

    )2 (1 0(h, t)0(h, t)

    )2 .

    Therefore we have

    G(r0(h, t), t) = r0(h, t)(0(h, t)) 0(h, t) (0(h, t))t(1 0(h, t))

    =

    {2

    2 log(22t)

    2(2t+ 1)+

    h

    t2

    }(1

    0(h,t)

    (x)dx

    )

    20(h, t) exp( log(2

    2t)

    2(2t+ 1) h

    t

    )

    exp12

    (2t log(22t)

    2(2t+ 1) htt

    )2 (1 0(h, t)0(h, t)

    )2

    =h

    t2+2h

    t+ o

    (1

    t

    )as t .

    So we have tG(r0(h, t), t) 2h as t . Consequently, we have r(t) =2

    2 log(22t)

    2(2t+ 1)+ o

    (1

    t2

    )as t , since G is increasing in r by Propo-

    sition 3.10. So Corollary 3.11 implies our assertion.

    Theorem 3.16. For any r > 0, there exists T0 = T0(r, 2) > 0 such

    that

    0(t, y) = (t, y), 0 t T0, y 1.

  • Pricing of Passport Option 765

    In order to prove this theorem, we show some propositions. Let Y ,yt be

    the process given by (3.1). Note that we have the following by Itos formula.

    d(ertS1t ) = ertS1t (dBt 2dt).

    Let tdef= exp

    (Bt 122t

    )and dene the probability measure P by(

    dP

    dP

    )t

    = t. Then Btdef= t + Bt is a P - Brownian motion. Since

    ertS1t is a martingale under the measure P , P is EMM with respect to thenumeraire St. By applying Itos formula to (3.1), we have

    dY ,yt = (t Y ,yt )(dBt + rdt), Y ,y0 = y.(3.12)

    Moreover by denition of P , we have E[erTX] = S0E[S1T X] for any FTmeasurable random variable X, where E[ ] denotes the expectation under

    P . So we have

    C(T, x, S) = S sup

    E[(Y

    ,x/ST )

    +].(3.13)

    Let (t, y) = sup

    E[(Y ,yT )

    +]

    and 0(t, y) = E[(Y 1,yT )

    +]. Then (t, y) =

    ert(t, y) and 0(t, y) = ert0(t, y), so (t, y) = 0(t, y) if and only if

    (t, y) = 0(t, y).

    Proposition 3.17. Y 1,yt 1, P -a.s, for all y 1.

    Proof. From (3.12) we have that Y 1,yt = 1+(y1)eBtrt122t 1

    if y 1.

    Proposition 3.18. (1) E[Y 1,yt Y ,yt ] = r t0 e

    r(st)E[(1 s)]ds, forall and t > 0.(2) E[(Y 1,yt Y ,yt )2] 22e2

    2t t0 E[(1 s)2]ds, for all and t > 0.

    Proof. (1) Let Ut = Y1,yt Y ,yt . Then{

    dUt = {(1 t) Ut}(dBt + rdt)U0 = 0.

  • 766 Izumi Nagayama

    Therefored

    dtE[Ut] = rE[1 t] rE[Ut] . So E[Ut] = r

    t0er(st)E[(1

    s)]ds.

    (2) Similarly we have by Itos formula,

    d

    dtE[U2t ] = 2rE[{(1 t) Ut}Ut] + 2E[{(1 t) Ut}2]

    = (2 2r)E[U2t ] + 2E[(1 t)2] + 2(r 2)E[Ut(1 t)] {(2 2r) + |2 r|}E[U2t ] + (2 + |2 r|)E[(1 t)2].

    Therefore we have from Gronwalls inequality

    E[U2t ] (2 + |2 r|) exp({(2 2r) + |2 r|}t) t0E[(1 s)2]ds

    22e22t t0E[(1 s)2]ds.

    Proposition 3.19. There exists a constant K = K(r, 2) such that

    P ( sup0st

    |Y 1,ys Y ,ys | > 1) KtE[ t0

    (1 s)2ds],for any and t [0, 1].

    Proof. Letting Ut = Y1,yt Y ,yt , we have

    Ut =

    t0

    (1 s)dBs t0UsdBs + r

    t0

    (1 s)ds r t0Usds.

    So we have

    P ( sup0st

    |Us| > 1) P( sup

    0st| s0

    (1 u)dBu| > 14

    )

    +P

    ( sup

    0st| s0UudBu| > 1

    4

    )

    +P

    (r

    t0|1 s|ds > 1

    4

    )+ P

    (r

    t0|Us|ds > 1

    4

    ).

  • Pricing of Passport Option 767

    Note that

    P

    (r

    t0|1 s|ds > 1

    4

    ) 16r2E

    [( t0|1 s|ds

    )2]

    16r2tE[ t

    0(1 s)2ds

    ].

    Also by Proposition 3.18 (2)

    P

    (r

    t0|Us|ds > 1

    4

    ) 16r2tE

    [ t0U2s ds

    ]

    32r22e22ttE[ t

    0(1 s)2ds

    ].

    By Doobs inequality

    P

    ( sup

    0st| s0UudBu| > 1

    4

    ) 162E

    [sup

    0st| s0UudBu|2

    ]

    642E[| t0UsdBs|2

    ]

    = 642E

    [ t0U2s ds

    ]

    1284e22ttE[ t

    0(1 s)2ds

    ].

    By Burkholders inequality there exists some constant C4 such that

    P

    ( sup

    0st| s0

    (1 u)dBu| > 14

    ) 444E

    [sup

    0st| s0

    (1 u)dBu|4]

    C44E[(

    t0

    (1 s)2ds)2] 4C44tE

    [ t0

    (1 s)2ds].

    Proof of Theorem 3.16. If x 1 and y R, then

    x+ y+ = x y 1{y0}|y| x y 1{|xy|1}|x y|.

    Therefore for each , if ertr (82Ke22t)1/2t1/2 0

    E[(Y 1,yt )+] E[(Y ,yt )+]

  • 768 Izumi Nagayama

    E[Y 1,yt Y ,yt ] E[|Y 1,yt Y ,yt |, |Y 1,yt Y ,yt | 1] E[Y 1,yt Y ,yt ] E[|Y 1,yt Y ,yt |2]1/2P (|Y 1,yt Y ,yt | 1)1/2

    rE[ t0er(st)(1 s)ds]

    {

    22E[e22t t0

    (1 s)2ds]}1/2 {

    KtE[

    t0

    (1 s)2ds]}1/2

    (ertr (82Ke22t)1/2t1/2)E[ t0

    (1 s)ds] 0.

    We can obtain similar results in the case of r < 0 similarly.

    4. Discrete Time Approximation

    Let us x T > 0 and assume r 0. We introduce the discrete timeframework. Let N be any positive integer, and let

    = N =T

    N,

    N = { : t = n, for t [n, (n+ 1)), n = 0, 1, , N 1},

    Y N,N ,y

    t = y +N1n=0

    (Nn Y N,N ,y

    n )

    {(Bt(n+1) Btn) + r(t (n+ 1) t n)},

    and

    N (m, y) = supNN

    E[(Y N,N ,y

    m )+].

    We will consider the optimal trading strategy in the case of discrete time

    framework.

    Proposition 4.1. N (m, ) is convex and

    N (m, y) = max{E[N

    (m 1, y + (2 y)(B + r)

    )],

    E[N

    (m 1, y + (1 y)(B + r)

    )]}.

  • Pricing of Passport Option 769

    Proof. This can be shown inductively. Let us assume that N (m 1, y) is convex in y. Then we have

    N (m, y) = sup1k2

    E[ supN ,0=k

    E[(y + (k y)(B + r)

    +m1n=1

    (n Y N,,yn )((B(n+1) Bn) + r))+|F]]

    = sup1k2

    E[N (m 1, y + (k y)(B + r))]

    max{E[N (m 1, y + (1 y)(B + r))],

    E[N (m 1, y + (2 y)(B + r))]}.

    The opposite side of the inequality is trivial. And so N (m, y) is convex in

    y.

    Lemma 4.2. sup

    E[(Y ,yt )2] (y2 + 22 max{21, 22}t)e2

    2t.

    Proof. Since d(Y ,yt )2 = 2Y ,yt (tY ,yt )(dBt+rdt)+2(tY ,yt )2dt

    for any , we have the following similarly to Proposition 3.18 (2).d

    dtE[|Y ,yt |2] {(2 2r) + |2 r|}E[(Y ,yt )2] + (2 + |2 r|)E[2t ].

    Therefore we have

    E[|Y ,yt |2] (y2 + 22 t0E[2s ]ds) exp(2

    2t)

    (y2 + 22 max(21, 22)t)e22t.

    Lemma 4.3. Let b 0, c 0 and let {an}n0 be a sequence of numberssuch that a0 = 0 and

    an b+ cn1k=0

    ak, n 1.

    Then an b(1 + c)n1.

  • 770 Izumi Nagayama

    Proof. We show our assertion by induction. It is easy to verify it in

    case of n = 1. Let an b+ cn1k=0

    ak b(1 + c)n1. Then we have

    an+1 b+ cn

    k=0

    ak b(1 + c)n1 + can b(1 + c)n.

    Lemma 4.4. There exists a sequence {CN} such that CN 0 as N such that

    E[|Y ,yT Y N,,yT |2

    ](

    1 + 4(2 + r2T )T

    N

    )N1CN ,

    for any N .

    Proof. Let N . From the denitions of Y N,,yT and Y ,yT we have

    E[|Y ,yN Y N,,yN |2

    ] 2(2 + r2T )E

    [N1n=0

    (n+1)n

    |Y ,yt Y N,,yn |2dt]

    = 4(2 + r2T )N1n=0

    (n+1)n

    E[|Y ,yt Y ,yn |2

    ]dt

    +4(2 + r2T )N1n=0

    E[|Y ,yn Y N,,yn |2

    ].

    Since we have Y ,yt = Y,yn +(

    NnY ,yn )(1 e(BtBn)(

    2

    2+r)(tn)) for

    n t < (n+ 1), we have (n+1)n

    E[|Y ,yt Y ,yn |2

    ]dt

    =

    (n+1)n

    E

    [(Nn Y ,yn )2(1 e(BtBn)(

    2

    2+r)(tn))2

    ]dt

    K(

    2r(1 er) + 12r + 2 (e

    (2r+2) 1)),

    where K = 2(y2 +22 max{21, 22}T )e22T +2 supN E[(Y ,yn Nn)2].

    Therefore

    E[|Y ,yN Y N,,yN |2

    ]

  • Pricing of Passport Option 771

    4(2 + r2T )KN(

    2(1 er)

    r+e(2r+2) 12r + 2

    )

    +4(2 + r2T )N1n=0

    E[|Y ,yn Y N,,yn |2

    ].

    So by Lemma 4.3

    E[|Y ,yN Y N,,yN |2

    ]

    4(2 + r2T )KN(

    2(1 er)

    r+e(2r+2) 12r + 2

    )

    (1 + 4(2 + r2T )

    )N1.

    Since 2(1 er)

    r+e(2r+2) 12r + 2 = O

    (2)

    , we have our assertion.

    Proposition 4.5. limN

    N (t, y) = (t, y).

    Proof. Lemma 4.4 and N imply thatlim supN

    supN

    E[(Y N,,yt )+] = lim sup

    NsupN

    E[(Y ,yt )+] (t, y).

    On the other hand, for each , there exists a sequence of strategies{N}N=1 such that N N and lim

    NE

    [ T0

    (t Nt )2dt]

    = 0. Then,

    E[|Y ,yt Y

    N ,yt |2

    ]= 2(2 + r2T )E

    [ t0|(s Ns ) (Y ,ys Y

    N ,ys )|2ds

    ]

    4(2 + r2t) t0E[(s Ns )2

    ]ds

    +4(2 + r2t)

    t0E[|Y ,ys Y

    N ,ys |2

    ]ds.

    By Gronwalls inequality

    E[|Y ,yt Y

    N ,yt |2

    ] 4(2 + r2t)E

    [ t0

    (s Ns )2ds]e4(

    2+r2t)t 0,as N .

  • 772 Izumi Nagayama

    Lemma 4.2 implies that for each N there exists a sequence {(N,n) n}nsuch that E

    [|Y (N),yT Y n,

    (N,n),yT |2

    ] 0 as n uniformly with respect

    to N . Therefore we have subsequence {(N,n(N))}N such that E[|Y ,yT

    Yn(N),(N,n(N)),yT |2

    ] 0 as N . Therefore lim

    NE[(Y

    n(N),(N,n(N)),yT )

    +] =

    E[(Y ,yT )+]. Therefore lim inf

    NN (T, y) (T, y).

    5. Closed Form of Valuation in the Case of r = 0

    In this section we assume that r = 0. Then, under the measure P , we

    have

    dY ,yt = (t Y ,yt )dBt.Letting 1 < 2, we derive the closed form for valuation of passport call

    option. Let =2 + 1

    2, =

    2 12

    and x T > 0. We consider the

    discrete time approximation dened in the previous section.

    Lemma 5.1. For any convex function g, we have

    sup(1,2)

    E

    [g

    ( t0sdBs

    )]= E[g(iBt)],

    where i =

    {2 if |1| |2|1 if |1| > |2|.

    Proof. Let B be a Brownian motion independent of B. Then for any

    E

    [g

    ( t0sdBs

    )]= E

    [g

    (E

    [ t0

    (sdBs + (2i 2s)1/2dBs)|Ft

    ])]

    E[g

    ( t0

    (sdBs + (2i 2s)1/2dBs)

    )]= E [g (iBt)] .

    Corollary 5.2.

    N (m, y) =

    E[N

    (m 1, y + (2 y)B

    )]if y

    E[N

    (m 1, y + (1 y)B

    )]if y > .

  • Pricing of Passport Option 773

    Proof. This follows from Lemma 5.1 and the following.

    N (m, y) = sup12

    E[N (m 1, y + ( y)B)]

    = sup1y2y

    E[N (m 1, y + B)].

    By Corollary 5.2 the optimal strategy N in the discrete framework isinductively given by the following.

    Nt ={1 if Y

    N,N,yn >

    2 if YN,N,yn ,

    n t < (n+ 1),

    where

    Y N,N,y

    t = y +N1n=0

    (Nn Y N,N,y

    n )(Bt(n+1) Btn)

    = y N1n=0

    [sign

    (Y N,

    N,yn

    ) (+

    Y N,N,yn )

    (Bt(n+1) Btn)].

    Let BN,$t be given inductively by

    BN,$t = BN,$n sign(Y N,

    N,yn )(Bt Bn), n < t (n+ 1).

    Then {BN,$t } is another P -Brownian motion and we have

    Y N,N,y

    t = y +N1n=0

    ((+

    Y N,N,yn )(BN,$t(n+1) BN,$tn)).

    Now let

    Y N,$,yt = y +N1n=0

    ((+

    Y N,$,yn )(Bt(n+1) Btn)) .

  • 774 Izumi Nagayama

    Then Y N,N,y

    t and YN,$,yt have the same distribution and we have

    E[(Y N,N,y

    t )+] = E[(Y N,$,yt )

    +]. And let Y $,yt to be the solution of the fol-

    lowing S.D.E.

    dY $,yt =(+

    Y $,yt )dBt, Y $,y0 = y.(5.1)Then we have lim

    NE[|Y N,$,yT Y $,yT |2] = 0 by Euler-Maruyama approxima-

    tion (see Kloeden and Platen [5]), and so limN

    E[(Y N,$,yT )+] = E[(Y $,yT )

    +].

    Therefore by Proposition 4.5 we have (T, y) = E[(Y $,yT )+].

    Remark 5.3. From the form of N, one may guess that the optimalstrategy is given by the following.

    t ={1 if Yt >

    2 if Yt , n t < (n+ 1)

    where Y is given by

    dYt = sign(Yt )(+ |Yt |)dBt, Y0 = y.For simplicity, let 1 = 1 and 2 = 1. Then recalling that Bt = Bt + t isP -Brownian motion, we see that Xt = YtSt satises

    dXt = sign(Xt)dSt, X0 = y,(5.2)under the measure P . It is well known as Tanakas counter-example that

    S.D.E. (5.2) does not have any strong solutions. Therefore such an adapted

    process does not exist.

    Now we derive the formula for pricing the passport option. Let Y ytdef=

    1

    (Y $,y+t

    ). Then we have

    dY yt = (1 + |Y yt |)dBt.Let f Y

    0(y : t)dy = P [Y 0t dy] and q(a, b, t;)dadb = P [Bt + t da,

    min0st

    (Bs + s) db]. It is well known(see Karatzas & Shreve [4]) that

    q(a, b, t;) =2(a 2b)

    2t3exp

    ((a 2b t)

    2

    2t+ 2b

    ).

  • Pricing of Passport Option 775

    Skorohods Theorem implies the following lemma.

    Lemma 5.4.

    f Y0(y : t) =

    1

    (1 + |y|)2{

    1

    t

    ( log(1 + |y|)

    t

    +1

    2t

    )

    +1

    2

    ( log(1 + |y|)

    t

    +1

    2t

    )}.

    Proof. We have

    d(log(1 + |Y 0t |)) = sign(Y 0t )dBt + dL0t 1

    22dt = dBt + dL

    0t

    1

    22dt,

    where L0t is the local time of Y0 at 0, and Bt =

    t0 sign(Y

    0s )dBs. Dene a P -

    equivalent probability measure Q by (dQ

    dP)t = t

    def= exp(

    2Bt

    2

    8t). Then

    BQtdef= Bt

    2t is Q-Brownian motion, and we have d

    (1

    log(1 + |Y 0t |)

    )=

    dBQt + dL0t . Let Wt

    def=

    1

    log(1 + |Y 0t |). From Skorohods Theorem, we have

    Wt = BQt min

    0utBQu (See Ikeda and Watanabe [3]). Since

    Q[Wt dw,BQt db] = q(b, b w, t, 0)dwdb

    =2(2w b)

    2t3exp

    ((2w b)

    2

    2t

    )dwdb,

    we have

    g(w : t)def=

    d

    dwP [Wt w] = d

    dwEQ[I{Wtw}

    1t ]

    =

    w

    e182t 1

    2b d

    2

    dwdbQ[Wt w,BQt b]db

    = 2ew{

    1

    t

    ( w

    t+

    1

    2t

    )+

    1

    2

    ( w

    t+

    1

    2t

    )},

    t, w 0.Then,

    f Y0(y : t) =

    1

    2(1 + |y|)g(1

    log(1 + |y|) : t)

  • 776 Izumi Nagayama

    =1

    (1 + |y|)2{

    1

    t

    ( log(1 + |y|)

    t

    +1

    2t

    )

    +1

    2

    ( log(1 + |y|)

    t

    +1

    2t

    )}.

    Lemma 5.5.

    C(T, S, S, 1, 2)

    = S

    [

    2

    {(1 +

    Td1(T ))(d1(T )) +

    T(d1(T ))

    }

    ++ + ||2

    (d2(T ))

    ]

    where d1(T ) = 1T

    log+ ||

    +T

    2and d2(T ) = d1(T )

    T .

    Proof. Note that C(T, S, S, 1, 2) = SE[(Y $,T )

    +]. Then we have

    E[(Y $,T )

    +]

    = E

    [(Y 0T +

    )+]=

    (y + ) f Y0(y : T )dy

    =

    ||

    (y + ) f Y0(y : T )dy + 2+

    ||

    0f Y

    0(y : T )dy

    =

    d1(T )

    (e

    Tz+ 1

    22T +

    )eTz 1

    22T

    ((z) +

    T

    2(z)

    )dz

    +2+ 1

    2T

    d1(T )eTz 1

    22T

    ((z) +

    T

    2(z)

    )dz

    =

    2

    {(1 +

    Td1(T ))(d1(T )) +

    T(d1(T ))

    }

    ++ + ||2

    (d2(T )).

    Theorem 5.6.

    C(T, x, S, 1, 2)

  • Pricing of Passport Option 777

    = SeTf2(x,T )

    (f2(x, T ) f3(x, T )+ +

    2

    T

    )

    S( sign(x S))(f2(x, T ) f3(x, T )+

    2

    T

    )

    +SeTf2(x,T )( sign(x S))

    (f2(x, T ) f3(x, T )+

    2

    T

    )

    S(f2(x, T ) f3(x, T )+ +

    2

    T

    )+ x1{x0} 1{x 0

    if sign(x S) 0gx(t) = f2(x, t)

    t

    (f2(x, t) +

    1

    2t

    ).

    Proof. Note that C(T, x, S, 1, 2) = SE[(Y

    $,x/ST )

    +]

    and let y =

    inf{t > 0 : Y $,yt =

    }= inf

    {t > 0 : Y yt = 0

    }, where y =

    y

    . Then, we

  • 778 Izumi Nagayama

    have

    E[(Y $,yT )

    +]

    = E[(Y $,yT )

    +, T y]+ E

    [(Y $,yT )

    +, T < y].

    And

    dY yty ={(1 + Y yty)dBty if y 0(1 Y yty)dBty if y < 0.

    Therefore

    Y yty = sign(y)[(1 + |y|) exp

    {sign(y)Bty 1

    22(t y)

    } 1

    ].

    Then, we have

    y =

    inf{t > 0 : Bt = 1( log(1 + y) + 122t

    )} if y 0

    inf{t > 0 : Bt = 1( log(1 y) + 122t

    )} if y < 0

    = inf

    {t > 0 : Bt = sign(y)

    1

    ( log(1 + |y|) + 1

    22t

    )}.

    Then

    E[(Y $,yT )

    +, T < y]

    = E

    [(Y yT +

    )+, T < y

    ]

    =

    0 1

    log(1+|y|)

    ( b

    q(a, b, T ;2)

    {sign(y)((1 + |y|)ea 1) + }+da

    )db

    =

    0f

    ( b(f+h)

    q(a, b, T ;2)

    {(1 + y)ea

    }da

    )db

    if y > 0

    0f

    ( b(f+h)b

    q(a, b, T ;2)

    {(y 1)ea + +

    }da

    )db

    if y < 0

    where

    f = 1

    log(1 + |y|)

    h =

    {1 log

    sign(y) if sign(y) > 0

    if sign(y) 0.

  • Pricing of Passport Option 779

    Since

    ( eaq(a, b, T ;

    2)da

    )db

    = e[

    (2

    T+

    2

    T

    )

    (2

    T+

    2

    T

    )]

    e[

    (2

    T+

    2

    T

    )

    (2

    T+

    2

    T

    )],

    ( beaq(a, b, T ;

    2)da

    )db

    =

    (T

    2

    T

    )

    (T

    2

    T

    )

    +e[

    (2

    T+

    2

    T

    )

    (T

    +

    2

    T

    )]

    +e[

    (T

    +

    2

    T

    )

    (2

    T+

    2

    T

    )], for ,

    and

    q(a, b, T ;2) = eaq(a, b, T ;

    2),

    we have

    E[(Y $,yT )

    +, T < y]

    = (+ |y |)(f + h

    +

    T

    +

    2

    T

    )

    ( sign(y))(f + h

    +

    T

    2

    T

    )

    + sign(y)

    (+ |y |)

    (f h+

    T

    2

    T

    )

    (f h+

    T+

    2

    T

    )

    1{y

  • 780 Izumi Nagayama

    Next, we have

    E[(Y $,yT )

    +, T y]

    =

    T0g

    y(T t)E

    [(Y $,t )

    +]dt

    =

    T0g

    y(T t)

    [

    2

    {(1 +

    td1(t))(d1(t)) +

    t(d1(t))

    }

    ++ + ||2

    (d2(t))

    ]dt

    =

    T0g

    y(T t)

    [

    2

    {(1 log + ||

    +2t

    2)(d1(t)) +

    t(d1(t))

    }

    ++ + ||2

    (d2(t))

    ]dt

    where

    gy(t)

    def=

    d

    dtP [y t] = log(1 + |y|)

    t3

    ( log(1 + |y|)

    t

    +1

    2t

    )

    = ft3

    (ft

    +1

    2t

    ).

    Since

    T0g

    y(T t)dt =

    (fT

    +

    2

    T

    )+ (1 + |y|)

    (fT

    2

    T

    ) T0g

    y(T t)(d1(t))dt =

    (d1(T ) +

    fT

    ) T0g

    y(T t)(d2(t))dt = (1 + |y|)

    (d2(T ) +

    fT

    ),

    we have

    E[(Y $,yT )

    +, T y]

    = +[

    (fT

    +

    2

    T

    )+ (1 + |y|)

    (fT

    2

    T

    )]

    +

    2

    (1 log + ||

    +2t

    2

    )

    (d1(T ) +

    fT

    )

  • Pricing of Passport Option 781

    2

    + ||2

    (1 + |y|)(d2(T ) +

    fT

    )

    +

    2

    T0g

    y(T t)

    {2t

    2(d1(t)) +

    t(d1(t))

    }dt.

    6. Remarks and Numerical Calculations

    We examined the functions r(t) and (r(t), t) with = 1by numerical calculations based on Equation (3.8) and the denition

    of r(t) in Proposition 3.10. Figure 1 depicts the function r(t) and its

    approximation functions r0(t) = c +c(1 32c)

    1 ct c

    {c2(1 2c)

    16(1 c)5/2 +131c3 270c2 + 168c 32

    48(1 c)2}t and r(t) = 1

    log(2)

    2(t+ 1)which are exam-

    ined in Theorem 3.14 and 3.15. Figures 2 and 3 show these approximation

    errors respectively. In Figure 4, we illustrate the function (r(t), t) with its

    approximation function 0(r(t), t) =

    t(1 r(t))+ r(t)4 t+

    {r(t)2

    32

    1r(t)

    Figure 1.

  • 782 Izumi Nagayama

    Figure 2.

    Figure 3.

    r(t)8

    1 r(t) 16(1 r(t))3/2

    }tt which are examined in Lemma 3.8.

    Figure 5 shows approximation error.

    As numerical experiences we also examined the area where the optimal

    trading strategy is 1 in the discrete time framework discussed in Propo-sition 4.1, when 1 = 1, 2 = 1, and = 1. We calculate the value ofN by using numerical integration technique inductively. Figures 6 and 7

    show the case of r = 0.35(> c) and r = 0.25(< c) respectively. The sym-

    bol in these gures indicates the points where the optimal strategy is

  • Pricing of Passport Option 783

    Figure 4.

    Figure 5.

  • 784 Izumi Nagayama

    Figure 6.

    Figure 7.

    1, in the coordinate (y, t) where y is the value of trading strategy dividedby the current value of the security, and t is the remaining life time of

  • Pricing of Passport Option 785

    passport option. By numerical calculation we have r(0.075) 0.35 and(0.35, 0.075) 0.225. The symbol in Figure 6 indicates the pointwhere y = 0.225 and t = 0.075.

    References

    [1] Black, F. and M. Scholes, The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,J. Political Economy 81 (1973), 637654.

    [2] Hyer, T., Lipton-Lifschitz, A. and D. Pugachevsky, Passport to Success, Risk10 (1997), September, 127131.

    [3] Ikeda, N. and S. Watanabe, Stochastic dierential equations and diusionprocesses, 2nd ed, North Holland/Kodansha, 1988.

    [4] Karatzas, I. and S. E. Shreve, Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus,Springer-Verlag, 1988.

    [5] Kloden, P. E. and E. Platen, Numerical Solution of Stochastic DierentialEquations, Springer-Verlag, 1991.

    (Received May 21, 1998)(Revised July 21, 1998)

    Graduate School of Mathematical ScienceThe University of Tokyo3-8-1 Komaba, Meguro-kuTokyo 153-8914, Japan, andThe Bank of Tokyo-Mitubishi Ltd.Derivative and Structured Products Division2-7-1 Marunouchi, Chiyoda-kuTokyo 100-0005, JapanE-mail: izumi [email protected]