63
AARHUS UNIVERSITY BUSINESS AND SOCIAL SCIENCES DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS How tax morale and tax ethics affect tax compliance rates in EU? Research on determinants shaping tax morale and ethics in tax resistant countries. Author Arkadiusz Slawomir Winnicki AW89815 Supervisor Anna Piil Damm 1/5/2013 Character count (excluding spaces) : 89 620

How tax morale and tax ethics affect tax compliance rates ...pure.au.dk/portal/files/53748402/bachelor_thesis_Winnicki.pdf · How tax morale and tax ethics affect tax compliance rates

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

AARHUS UNIVERSITY BUSINESS AND SOCIAL SCIENCES

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

How tax morale and tax ethics affect tax

compliance rates in EU? Research on determinants shaping tax morale

and ethics in tax resistant countries.

Author Arkadiusz Slawomir Winnicki AW89815

Supervisor Anna Piil Damm

1/5/2013

Character count (excluding spaces) : 89 620

2

Abstract

Many scholars have described current global society as a tax civilization. Most of the

people in the world are being under governance of authorities that have been elected in a more or

less democratic way. It has been done to provide more security to individuals’ lives and more

welfare to the society. Tax revenues are necessary for the government to implement social and

economic initiatives, therefore high tax compliance rates have to be maintained.

The paper strives to examine how tax ethics and tax morale differ between members of

EU and to highlight areas where tax compliance is significantly lower. Historical data proved

that the CEE members, especially those that have undergone transition process represent stronger

willingness to resist taxes. The further analysis of the troubled areas is trying to determine factors

responsible for such situation.

In order to provide the basis for the discussion this paper mixes social and taxation

theories and models together with empirical data on demographical determinants of tax

compliance and social representations on tax deterrence methods. Afterwards, five main aspects

such as: post-socialistic history, trust, corruption, effectiveness of legislation and state authorities

and effectiveness of redistribution, have been chosen for further research.

Overall, there has been a correlation between chosen aspects and deterioration of tax

ethics and morale. Post-socialistic past had very strong impact on social resistance towards

personal income taxation in the first years on transition process. Corruptive practices and

exhibited lack of efficiency of state authorities in tax collection and distribution led to decrease

in social trust in government’s initiatives and institutions.

Lack of trust and transparency in government’s actions seemed to be revealed as the most

significant aspect that led to many illegal practices on both sides. The key findings are relatively

consistent, due to further implications that come from the lack of honesty in the individual-

government financial transactions. Western models to increase tax compliance cannot be adopted

in CEE countries until social trust would overcome the barrier built up between both sides.

3

Table of Contents 1. Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 4

2. Description of historical data........................................................................................................... 8

Between transition period and late 90’s ............................................................................................. 10

Changes in recent decade .................................................................................................................. 13

3. Theoretical framework ................................................................................................................... 14

The Social Contract Theory ............................................................................................................... 14

Social representations ....................................................................................................................... 16

Relevant pro-social behavior theories ................................................................................................ 17

The Allingham – Sandmo – Model (1972) and extensions ................................................................... 18

Yitzhaki’s extension (1974) ............................................................................................................ 19

Andreoni’s extension (1992) .......................................................................................................... 20

Engler’s tax evasion dynamics model (1999)...................................................................................... 21

Fundamentals of tax analysis ............................................................................................................. 23

Shadow economy’s estimation methods .............................................................................................. 24

The currency demand approach ..................................................................................................... 24

The physical input method ............................................................................................................. 26

4. Empirical studies on tax morale and ethics .................................................................................... 27

Demographic studies ......................................................................................................................... 28

Social representations on tax deterrence methods .............................................................................. 31

Fairness and institutional quality ....................................................................................................... 32

5. Determinants of tax compliance in CEE countries ............................................................................. 33

History .............................................................................................................................................. 34

Trust .................................................................................................................................................. 35

Corruption......................................................................................................................................... 36

Efficiency of state institutions and tax regulations .............................................................................. 38

Efficiency of tax redistribution ........................................................................................................... 40

6.Conclusions ........................................................................................................................................ 42

7.References .......................................................................................................................................... 45

Appendixes ............................................................................................................................................ 50

4

1. Introduction Taxes, according to Oliver Wendell Holmes Jr. (1841-1935), are the price we pay for the

civilization. This sentence is carved on the façade of the Internal Revenue Service building in

Washington, DC (Block, 1997) as a memorandum to the society that current order is maintained

thanks to their contributions from their personal incomes. It can be argued that the argument

stating that governments could not exist without taxes is biased, due to other revenues that they

are collecting from fees, lotteries and other voluntary contributions. Yet it has to be said, that this

level of income would not allow the government to function at current level. The scope of the

government would have to be seriously cut back, if tax revenues were to disappear (McGee,

2012).

Work of many authors has proven that despite this knowledge, society does avoid

taxation. The level of shadow economy in OECD countries has sharply increased between 1970

and 1998 (Schneider, 2000) and so did the individuals’ level of risk attitude in order to avoid tax

burden (Dynan et al., 2008). Most researchers examine individuals’ lack of tax compliance from

a legal or fiscal point of view. However, some of the authors take more philosophical approach,

focusing on taxpayers’ ethics and morality in order to find the cause of the problem. (McGee,

1994).

There is no one definition of tax morale, nor just few determinants of it, which makes the

topic interesting and worth researching. According to Torgler (2007) tax morale is an intrinsic

motivation to pay taxes, measured as willingness to pay taxes in the light of moral obligation and

belief that paying them contributes to society. The concept of tax morale is closely related with

taxpayer’s ethics, which can be defined as “the norms of behavior governing citizens as

taxpayers in their relationships with the government” (Song and Yarbrough, 1978 in Alm, 2006).

Feld and Frey (2002), argue that tax morale is shaped by the nature of fiscal exchange between

government and taxpayers, indicating trust as a major determinant of positive attitude towards

taxation. They also state that the study of tax morale is, unfortunately, taken from the wrong

perspective. Very often it is considered as individual preference, which is used to describe

uncertainty in tax avoidance, rather than a factor determining tax compliance. What should be

focused on is how tax morale can be raised and later on maintained in order to improve tax

revenues.

5

In 2004, European Union has experienced connection between Eastern and Western

Europe, which has been the biggest accession in the history called as “Big Bang” enlargement

(Noutcheva, 2008 in Torgler, 2011). According to Baldwin (1995), the gains from such

connection with Eastern Europe were supposed to be potentially enormous for the whole revenue

system. What was not taken into consideration was the possibility of existence of a different tax

subculture in post-communistic Eastern Europe with its own set of unwritten rules (Lewis, 1982,

in Frey, 2007). It is often mentioned that in developing and transition countries, tax compliance

is low and tax evasion is widespread and present far more serious consequences than in

developed countries (Torgler, 2007). Rose-Ackerman (2001) points out that despite generally

low tax morale in those countries, Central and Eastern European countries present generally

higher tax compliance compared to Former Soviet Union countries.

To conclude, study of tax morale and taxpayer’s ethics is important due to incapability of

standard expected utility theories to explain lack of tax compliance (Spicer and Becker, 1980, in

Frey, 2007),. In Allingham and Sandmo’s model (1972, in Torgler, 2011) taxpayers are people

who are risk-averse, yet willing to maximize their net income and their willingness to evade is

based on a net tradeoff between the possible gains and possibility of being detected and fined.

The morality here is the matter of choice, whether or not to try to evade, which together with

social representations presented by differing in many aspects, yet in so many ways related, EU

countries provide a very interesting field for research to be done.

As the debts of European Countries increase studies are required in order to assess the

determinants of people’s lack of compliance. However, studies with economical and legal

approach, concerning matters such as tax rates and complexities of legal frameworks, did not

yield exhaustive conclusions, due to the fact that nearly 20% of tax compliance is being

explained by people’s tax morale and tax ethics in their countries (McGee, 2012). Moreover, due

to accession of Central European Countries, with different historical background and ethics

shaped by different factors resulting in tax resisting culture (Lewis, 1982), the topic is really

worth further researching.

The main purpose of this paper is, first, to compare the level of tax compliance and

tax morale between European Union member countries and, second, to investigate what

determines cross-country differences in tax morale.

6

The paper reflects on attitudes of people living in CEE countries, which are members of

the EU, however still amongst developing ones, towards tax compliance and to compare them

with their Western neighbors. The objective of this thesis is to show, how different approaches of

EU Member’s towards tax collection and administration together with relation between

taxpayers and government affect the tax morale and ethics. Much emphasis will be put on taking

into consideration differences arising due to the history and belonging to communistic welfare

system of majority of CEE countries.

Moreover, in order to provide relevant answers, matters such as trust, institutional

effectiveness, corruption, social integration, demographic traits and post-communistic tax

attitude in CEE countries will be taken into account. They will be included in order to be able to

indicate determinants of tax morale and possible ways of showing how it can be raised and

maintained in the future.

In the end, the work would like to present the governmental flaws that are being

constantly overlooked in EU countries, which result in lowered tax compliance rates. If possible,

some discussion will be drawn in order to provide advices on how the situation might be

improved in the future, leading to rise in tax morale and possibly finding a way to maintain that

level.

This study has several delimitations, the most important one stating, that the work will

focus mainly on the before mentioned 20% (McGee, 2012) of tax compliance which cannot be

explained by economic and legal aspects. Thus it will not take a look at matters such as tax

legislation itself, tax rates, individual income and the economical situation of the country. It will

also not focus on effects of peoples’ willingness to pay taxes, such as tax administration and tax

compliance costs arising due to state authorities’ policy to prevent tax crimes (Slemrod, 2000).

The three most commonly recognized ways of decreasing the tax compliance rate are the

following. Tax avoidance referring to usage of legal means in order to reduce the tax burden. Tax

evasion which uses illegal means to reduce tax burden. Finally, tax flight, which employs means

of relocation in order to escape taxation (Schneider, 2001). Since all methods have similar

effects, namely a reduction of tax revenue and are based on the same motive to reduce tax

7

burden, it is suggested by economists that they should be analyzed jointly (Shaw, 1982), thus the

work will take tax compliance rate as general, not differentiate between particular methods.

Moreover, while discussing morality as a matter of personal choice the work will not

justify any of the actions. It will be based on the idea that is people’s choice, based on their

personal beliefs and ethics to answer the question – whether or not to comply with taxes?

(Uslaner, 2007). Thus it is not my objective to answer, whether or not, tax evasion can be

justified. Nor, shall I advice any changes to legal framework that should be introduced by tax

authorities in order to help provide such a judgment.

My thesis are mainly based on literature review grounded on publications of academics

and scholars within fields of taxation, economics, philosophy and ethics. Meaning that,

secondary data is used as the main source of information and neither quantitative nor qualitative

experiments were conducted by me in order to gather primary data.

Programs such as Google Scholar were used in order to find documents, which had

keywords such as “tax morality”, “tax avoidance”, “tax ethics”. Taking into account the way

how Google Scholar works, papers from first two pages were taken into consideration, as the

ones who had been searched the most and with the highest reliability rate.

My literature search for journals, articles, books and reports used the three classic criteria

of high-quality research, reliability, validity and generalizability (Eriksson, 2008). I selected

sources based on the names of the authors and the institutions or journals for which they were

prepared. First, as regard the reliability criterion, I gave priority to well-known universities,

institutions (for ex. EU, NBER) or authors, whose books and publications have already been

approved by academic environment. Secondly, as regard the validity criterion, the sources were

selected based on their relevance for the problem of interest. Thus, I gave higher priority to

studies on aspects of tax avoidance, tax morality and ethics, especially regarding EU area.

Finally, as for the last criterion, my literature review also includes scientific studies of general

relevance, such as ones explaining theories that could be applicable no matter where.

After the first selection of scientific studies, I checked the lists of references of those

studies in order to find useful journals quoted by the respective authors. Assuming that those

academics had proper knowledge in assessing sources used in order to conduct their research,

8

only criterion of relevance to the topic of interest was applied; no further quality assessments

from my side were made.

In the case of empirical data, my biggest concern was relevance and reliability. Surveys

and data gathered by governmental, economical or social research institutions such as WVS, EU

and NBER were regarded as reliable. By relevance, I mean relevance for the topic and

geographical area of interest.

The next chapter will describe the current level of tax morale and tax compliance rates

among EU countries. The idea behind it is to divide countries into culturally similar areas and

taking one of them for analysis as a representative of given group. The purpose is to indicate

geographical areas, where the situation is worse than average and where probability of an

incident with a motive to decrease tax burden is higher. It shall also discuss most important

determinants of such situation.

The third chapter will present the theoretical framework. The fourth chapter will present

empirical studies on the determinants of tax morale. The joint objective of chapters 3 and 4 is to

present the concept of taxation and social theories, tax morale and tax ethics and their effects on

the topic of interest.

The last part will use the theoretical and empirical insights from the third and fourth

chapter to explain the descriptive findings in the second chapter and discuss on how tax morale

can be raised in low tax compliance countries and how those government’s can maintain it

afterwards. The last chapter will draw conclusions based on my analysis and suggest directions

for future further research.

2. Description of historical data

Nobody likes paying taxes (Frey,2007) that is a fact leading to tax crimes and shadow

economic activities all around the world. Despite all the efforts, undertaken by governments, to

control this worldwide phenomenon through the means of education, punishment and

prosecution the problem still occurs and cannot be ignored. Due to the lack of crucial data it is

9

very difficult to take a real estimate of the frequency and magnitude of illegal activities. Most of

the people involved in illegal actions prefer to remain unidentified and, if possible, unnoticed,

hence the estimation of the real scope of the problem may not be accurate. (Schneider, 2000).

Taxation is not a new concept and over the centuries four basic views concerning the

ethics of tax evasion have emerged (McGee, 2012). The first could be summarized in well

known words “Ask not what your country can do for you – ask what you can do for your

country” (Kennedy, 1961). It states that citizens have a duty to the state to pay taxes, no matter

how high they are and how efficiently they are going to be used by the state authorities. This

ethic is especially seen in democracies with strong belief that the matter of the society is more

important than the matter of an individual. The duty to contribute to the community is shown as

the most important ethical consideration a citizen has to make, showing freeloaders as the

negative variables in the well being of the society. The second view might be considered as

anarchistic, while it states that taxation is unethical and the government behaves as a thief

whenever it is taking money from its citizens. The authorities rule only because they were given

such an opportunity by the society and they do not possess any moral authority and privilege to

take anything from others without their approval. The third view is more moderate, seeking a

way to achieve balance between two previous ones. It states that tax avoidance can be moral, in

some cases, depending on how we feel about the efficiency of redistribution and the

government’s actions. It is closely related to the last view, which main point is based on the

concept of efficiency. Government is liable to corruption, inefficient regulations and agencies,

while private sector is more concerned about efficiency in order to not to get out of the business.

That is why, by avoiding taxation to the inefficient state authorities, people keep the money in

the private sector, which is more organized and result-oriented (McGee, 2012).

Those are just basic theories, which had many more moral implications developed

differently under different regimes, cultures and societies. For example, the morality of

Scandinavian countries influenced by the big welfare system changed the way of thinking and

proclaimed social ethics of taxation. In that case, the most ethical argument seems to be the one

stating that since we receive benefits, therefore we must pay our taxes. Even though not

everyone can agree on what those benefits should be, the society has to receive something that

would be generally approved. Unfortunately, there is no way of giving someone something,

10

without forcing others to pay for it (Rawls,1971). It is contrary to what is seen in Eastern

European countries, where people are not satisfied with benefits, if any are granted, thus they do

not want to pay their taxes, especially social contributions. The reasoning behind it is that since

people do not get what they pay for, why should they continue doing it (McGee, 2012)?

In Economics, the differentiation between Western and Eastern Europe is due to the

transition process, which has taken place and caused disorientation and a heavy economic burden

(Frey, 2007). This period caused vacuum in many countries’ budgets and required people to give

their financial contributions to the wellbeing of the state. This was something, inexperienced

before by the citizens of post-socialistic regimes. Many citizens of transition countries have

never before been subdued to personal income taxation or any other tax regulations (Kornai,

1990). This led to a significant social resistance and had a strong influence on shaping of a new

tax morality. Unfortunately, under those conditions it was hard to predict, whether the emerging

tax morality will be similar to the general European level (Alm, 2006).

Of course, it has to be said that in every country radical argument states, that if you do

not like the government and do not want to pay taxes you can always leave. Unfortunately, such

option, depending on the country of individual’s residence, might not present any improvement

to the economical or social situation (McGee, 2012). Nevertheless, this chapter is not supposed

to discuss morality behind such a choice, but to present the situation after the transition process.

Between transition period and late 90’s

Due to lack of personal income taxation in some of the countries in the 90’s, the

comparison of tax compliance rates should be done by comparing the level of shadow economy

in given countries. The term “shadow economy” includes all underground economic activities,

both monetary and nonmonetary that aim to evade or illegally decrease the tax burden

(Schneider, 2000).

By the use of input method many academics tried to estimate the size of the shadow

economy in the 90’s in transition countries. Based on their study, first signs of deterioration in

11

Eastern Europe’s tax morale were visible already in the beginning of the post-communistic

period.

Table 1. Size of shadow economy in CEE members of EU that were under transition

process in percent of GDP

Country Average

1989-90

Average

1990-93

Average

1994-1995

Bulgaria 26.1 32.7 35.0

Czech Rep. 23.0 28.7 23.2

Estonia 19.5 35.9 37.0

Hungary 25.1 30.9 30.5

Latvia 18.4 32.2 43.4

Lithuania 19.0 38.1 47.0

Poland 27.2 31.8 25.9

Romania 20.9 29.0 31.3

Slovakia 23.0 30.6 30.2

Slovenia 26.8 28.5 24.0

Average 22.9 31.84 32.75

Sources: Own calculations using values from Schneider (2000, table 3, p.11)(Appendix 1)

As shown in the table above, general level of shadow economy in those countries was on

average more than 20% of GDP, which was an enormous expense for governments under

financially demanding reforms. What is not surprising is the fact that as the investments and

reforms demanded more money, therefore increasing personal tax burden in those countries, the

social resistance became stronger. The level of shadow economy was ranging from 22,9 % of

cumulative GDP in 1989, reaching the level of 32.75% in 1995. From ethical point of view, it is

understandable that people who were living for a half of the century under repressive and

corrupted regimes had a little respect and trust to their new governments. Those attitudes fueled

their tax evasion incentives and began process of long-lasting struggles between taxpayer and tax

authorities in CEE countries (McGee, 2012).

12

In the case of Western European countries currency demand method was used in order to

estimate the size of illegal economic activities undergone by individuals.

Table 2. Size of the shadow economy in Western European members of EU and OECD in

percentage of GDP

Country Average

1989-90

Average

1990-93

Average

1994-1995

Average

1996-1997

Austria 5.1 6.1 7.0 8.6

Belgium 19.3 20.8 21.5 22.2

Denmark 10.8 15.0 17.8 18.2

France 9.0 13.8 14.5 14.8

Germany 11.8 12.5 13.5 14.8

Great Brit. 9.6 11.2 12.5 13.0

Greece NA NA 29.6 30.1

Ireland 11.0 14.2 15.4 16.0

Italy 22.8 24.0 26.0 27.2

Netherlands 11.9 12.7 13.7 13.8

Portugal NA NA 22.1 22.8

Spain 16.1 17.3 22.4 23.0

Sweden 15.8 17.0 18.6 19.5

Average 13.02 14.96 18.05 18.77

Sources: Own calculations based on Schneider (2000, table 4, p.12 and table 7, p.14)(Appendix 1.)

Table 2 shows that the average rate of shadow economy in Western countries is ranging

from 13.02% of cumulative GDP in 1990 to 18.77% in 1997. Western results, even at their peak

are still below lowest Eastern European rates. The numbers, though not alarming for developed

countries, are still high in some of the member states. It could be argued that in the case of

Western European countries, the ones placed in the South are having problems with keeping

their tax compliance rates high. Both Greece and Italy show numbers that are at the same level or

even higher as some of the Eastern European countries. The lowest rates are amongst centrally

located countries, such as Netherlands, Germany and Austria.

13

Changes in recent decade

Changes in regulations and efficiency of tax authorities have lead to two different

outcomes in the case of tax morality and tax compliance rates within transition countries. Tax

ethics researchers say that in the period between 1998 and 2008 the tax morale has decreased in

7 out of 10 countries with Romania and Baltic States leading the deterioration scale (Torgler,

2011). One of the mentioned reasons of such situation is increased social awareness, which made

people more interested in government’s affairs. In countries where police and courts are not able

to control corruption and where people cannot see that their personal contributions to social

welfare do not actually make people wealthier, there is no big reason to believe that citizens have

faith in their government (Uslaner, 2007).

On the good side, with the increased importance of Personal Income Taxes (PIT) in

countries’ GDP, the tax compliance rates have also been pushed up. In most of mentioned

countries, there was a general increase in compliance rates, probably due to reforms of tax

legislations, which made it more difficult for employed individuals to avoid it. In some countries,

such as Poland, PIT is being automatically transferred to tax authorities from income transfers

made by employer to employee’s bank account (Christie, 2006). Hence it is hard to say, whether,

in case of employee being able to choose whether to comply or evade paying taxes the results

would be the same. Nevertheless, during given period in Eastern Europe PIT compliance rates

varied between 45%-70% and social security charges ranged from 50% to 75% showing

improvements of tax authorities in effectiveness of tax revenue collection (Christie, 2006).

Countries differ in their income taxation rates; however that, by itself, does not explain

why so many different individual approaches have been visible with different outcomes. In case

of Czech Republic, where tax rates remained constant for the whole period, the general tax

compliance rates have been steadily increasing. In the case of Latvia a flat personal income tax

rate of 25% was introduced. Despite having a low tax rate for the European Standards, Latvian

tax compliance has not followed positive trend, it has been steadily deteriorating (Christie,

2006). Therefore the question is whether, among generally decreasing income tax rates in

Eastern Europe, the actions taken by government and morality are not the dominant determinants

of people’s willingness to pay.

14

As for the Western European countries, mentioned in table 2, during the whole period

they present, comparably, higher values for tax morality and tax compliance rates. In case of

PIT, numbers vary between 60% and 80%, and social security charges, start from 70% up to

95% (Christie, 2006).

This is a good reason to believe that the tax rates and the complexity of calculation of PIT

do not affect the compliance rates in a highly dominant way. In the case of CEE countries, the

ones with the simplest personal taxation have the lowest tax compliance and morality rates. In

Western Europe many tax brackets and higher tax burden does not increase incentives to avoid

or evade taxation. The reasons are more complex and are touching more personal level, but will

be discussed further on in the work.

3. Theoretical framework

This chapter will focus on some of models and theories related to the researched topic in

order to provide a lead on angle from which it has been studied.

The Social Contract Theory

The social contract theory, with its roots in the XVI century is probably one of the most

important ones for the topics in the field of taxation. It shaped our current civilization and led to

creation of governments that require tax revenues in order to survive and continue to exist. It can

be summed up as an agreement between a group of individuals, which gathered at some time and

created a government. They have sacrificed some of their sovereignty in order to give better

protection to their lives, liberty and property (McGee, 2012).

Despite the generally good idea of the theory’s founding fathers, Thomas Hobbes (1588-

1679) and John Locke (1632-1704), nowadays it might be outdated and unjustified. Although,

the contract was generally accepted by the previous century’s philosophers, the idea that anyone

15

has ever made a written agreement where they transfer their rights to someone else seems absurd

for nowadays lawyers (Kary, 2000).

According to Hobbes, in a "state of nature" individual’s life would be affected by human

nature and be poor, dirty, violent and short. He defined contract as the mutual transferring of

rights. However, the belief that an individual had a right to self-governance leads him to an idea

that the contract is not about acquiring rights but about renouncing them. Every individual has

rights to anything by nature, there are only obstacles that hinder him from obtaining them (Kary,

2000). Unfortunately, in the absence of political order and law everyone would have unlimited

natural freedoms which would result in crimes, violence and “war of all against all" (bellum

omnium contra omnes) (Hobbes, 1588-1679).

What both philosophers don’t agree on is the reason of getting into a contract. People

have voluntarily submitted their rights and freedoms to a ruler, who would provide protection

and order in their lives, but based on different reasoning. According to Hobbes, it was a rational

choice, rather than empirical evidences that pushed people to choose one sovereign lord that will

protect them from invaders. They have obliged themselves to contribute to the commonwealth

and submitted their will to the ruler. A contradicting implication was the fact that people agreed

that under the authority of the chosen one, his successors would continue to rule. They have

voluntarily foregone their right to vote for their ruler. (Kary, 2000). Locke argued that the

reason of such a contract was more based on historical evidences and empirical experiences. The

need itself was dictated by the history, yet the terms of the agreement by the reasoning. Unlike

Hobbes, he did not devote a lot of time considering what people should do in the contract and

how to make it work. He simply accepted a main rule, that people are obliged to keep their part

of the deal and promises. (Kary, 2000).

Current mentality and legal frameworks make the concept outdated. The social contract

theory was an unwritten agreement made by a, comparably, worse educated society, yet it

continued to have its effect throughout centuries. Many lawyers consider it as not rightful

agreement, which cannot be considered as a contract, under current regulations, and in the effect

shaping of many regimes as unjustified (Kary, 2000). Nevertheless, the contribution of this

theory in shaping of current political situation and governments was invaluable. Governments

16

require funding in order to provide their obligations, thus it had also big impact on the

development of taxation.

Social representations

Tax ethics and morale are aspects that are being shaped collectively, meaning that society

in which we live determines our tax compliance in the long term. That is why it is important to

discuss social representations, as the influence of our environment, in order to closely analyze

researched topic.

Social representations, in literature, are defined as collective sum of shared ideas,

attitudes and opinions in the society (Moscovici, 1981). They represent a broad concept, which

in the same way as myths, beliefs and ideologies tries to capture the social reality of an

individual in given place and time. The concept can be extended towards common-sense theories

(Hewstone, 1983)

Social representations are used by social sciences to establish coherence within groups

and to create distinctions between them (Schneider, 2001). There are three aspects of social

representations that affect the creation of groups and their perception of reality. The first one

contains all the relevant opinions, evaluations and attitudes towards an object showing how

people think about it. The second one is based on all available information, easiness to gather

them and knowledge about given object. The last one provides all the emotional, motivational

and cognitive factors associated by an individual with the object focusing on how people feel

about and are affected by it (Verges, 1987)

Social representations can also be divided based on how closely are they related to

individual’s personal opinion. Central core and peripheral system can be distinguished. Central

core is a stable, solid and resistant to changes part of representation, carried further by the

society. Peripheral system takes into account inter-individual differences between members of

the group towards the subject (Abric, 1996).

17

It is important to consider the influence of social representations in researched topic, due

to their effect on individual’s behavior. They represent the influence of the society in which one

lives and might affect individual’s decisions.

Relevant pro-social behavior theories

Social context is a significant aspect in the field of tax compliance and it cannot be

denied an important place in the individual’s decision making process. The understanding of the

other tax payers’ behavior and its effect on individual is crucial to understand tax compliance.

Taxpayers’ willingness to comply with taxes might be conditional. Therefore as the society is

being perceived as honest with its taxes, the willingness of an individual to be honest is higher.

That is why, theories of pro-social behavior are considered as promising for further research of

tax ethics (Torgler, 2007).

Theory of equity points out that satisfaction and behavior are linked when taxpayer is

being compared with other individuals. The theory applies not only for objective outcome levels

but also for subjectively perceived ones (Tyler, 1998). Lack of equity between the taxpayer’s

own tax rate and the rate of other taxpayers causes a sense of ambiguity. Higher tax rate

stimulates anger and willingness to decrease the tax burden, while lower ones create feeling of

guilt and willingness to comply. Awareness of those inequalities can lead to different actions,

such as tax avoidance, in order to restore equality (Homans, 1961 in Torgler, 2007).

The theory of reciprocity is striving to explain conditional cooperation. In the field of

taxation, it would imply that people would follow general pattern of tax compliance. If many

citizens showed their willingness to pay, an individual would also feel obliged to contribute and

to comply. On the other hand, social resistance against taxes would make an individual more

opposed to the tax burden. (Falk, 2002)

Theory of conformity focuses on individual’s willingness to comply with social norms. It

states that a behavior of a taxpayer might be influenced by the need to fulfill social needs and to

obey the rules. Therefore, paying taxes would be more dictated by social pressure rather than

18

personal incentives (Henrich, 2004). Some academics discuss, that conformists would contribute

to any public good as long as others comply as well. It gives many social complications, due to

blind obedience to a group which leads to individuals’ lack of interest in the public goods

management and distribution’s efficiency (Bardsley, 2006).

Conditional cooperation is also influenced by past behavior and social information. Their

effect is especially visible among indifferent individuals. Information about other taxpayers’

actions will not affect people who have always been against or after something. Unexpectedly,

indifferent individuals once informed about positive actions of others tend to try to make their

own contribution more significant (Torgler, 2007). Another study showed that information about

high compliance in a group makes each member of it more willing to comply (Heldt, 2005). The

level of contribution has also been proven as a significant factor in measuring people’s

willingness to pay. As the members of the society tend to give higher contributions, the higher

the willingness of individuals to join and comply (Croson, 1998).

The Allingham – Sandmo – Model (1972) and extensions

Tax compliance literature follows many trends, one of them, the modeling approach,

includes classical model presented by Allingham and Sandmo and its extensions discussed

below. The basic assumption for the whole model is that taxpayer is being driven exclusively by

the need to maximize his utility function. Moreover, his utility function depends mostly on his

expected income net of fines. Taxpayer is modeled as risk-averse, expected net income

maximizing agent, which has the possibility to under-report his income, but by doing so he

increases his chances to get audited and fined. His choice is often based on the tradeoff between

possible gains and losses (Christie, 2006).

Equation 1: Expected utility model of a taxpayer

All taxable income (y) is fixed, while only the taxpayer’s amount to report is chosen. The

risk-averse taxpayer chooses to report (x) and decides on the amount of unreported income (y-x),

19

in order to maximize his expected utility. The von Neumann-Morgenstern’s utility function

(U( ) ) represents the individuals attitude towards risk, while assuming the probability (p) of the

payoff per dollar (t) from understatement. The model can be generally summed up as a

gambling game, where the choice of whether and how much to evade is similar to making a bet

(Slemrod, 2000).

Yitzhaki’s extension (1974)

The model and equation 1 created many issues, which have been discussed by other

authors. Schlomo Yitzhaki focused on the determinant of the penalty for discovered evasion. The

base model was dependant on the income understatement, while many countries were more

interested in tax understatement. This was an important implication, due to its effect on the tax

evasion gamble. The tax rate, itself, has no effect on the attitude towards taking risk, however the

higher the rate the higher the reward from successful understatement and the cost of being

detected (Slemrod, 2000).

The extension also predicts that a risk-neutral taxpayer’s compliance would be solely

determined by his action’s expected payoff. A positive outcome for tax evasion would result in

no tax statement, while negative in total compliance. In the case of risk-averse taxpayer,

mentioned by the base model, the probability of detection has to be taken into account. The

margin gain in expected value of tax evasion has to be calculated including increased risk-

bearing and probability of detection (Slemrod, 2000).

Equation 2: The extended model

The expected payoff per dollar of evaded income becomes (1-p)t-p*t. Additionally,

Yitzhaki introduces equation that takes into account audited income ) and unaudited income

( ) that is affecting the marginal utility of tax evasion.

20

Equation 3: Marginal utility of audited and unaudited income

Comparison to the base model shows, that in this case increases in t would proportionally

increase the reward from successful understatement. However, the penalty increases less than

proportionally, thus making the tax evasion more attractive (Slemrod, 2000).

What both models agree on, is that no matter what determines the penalty, more risk-

averse individuals will tend to evade less. In general individuals with higher income will evade

more eagerly as long as absolute risk aversion is decreasing, however the amount of

understatement (in the percentage of income) depends on individual’s relative risk attitude

(Slemrod, 2000).

Andreoni’s extension (1992)

The basic model can be extended to deal with other uncertainties. Given extension

introduces a temporal nature to the tax evasion decision. It assumes that tax crime, if detected, is

penalized after the tax saving is achieved. Moreover, due to uncertainty the amount of income

stated by taxpayer and the shadow price of income fluctuates (Slemrod,2000).

Provided that non-monetary penalties are high enough to force compliance in repayment

of tax fines, Andreoni argues that tax evasion is a way of “borrowing” from tax authorities.

Individuals evade taxation in order to smooth their income streams, thus state can be seen here as

a lender. The repayment of the “loan” occurs when the situation of the lender gets better or after

the fine is issued (Slemrod, 2000).

The taxpayer decides on how much to report and how big are the fluctuations in the

reported monthly income. Theoretically, the bigger the dispersion from the possible assessed

mean, the lower the risk of being audited. It is due to decreased possibility of perceiving the

21

declared mean as insufficient by the tax authorities, hence increasing the marginal benefits

(Slemrod, 2000).

Aggregate noncompliance, is a true aggregate tax liability minus tax paid. Andreoni,

stresses that the uncertainty does reduce aggregate noncompliance, but does not have a

significantly strong effect on tax evasion. Some taxpayers will be trying to balance out their

assessed mean, therefore paying more than they are obliged to. This might reduce aggregate level

of tax evasion, but not individual level (Slemrod, 2000).

Engler’s tax evasion dynamics model (1999).

It is not possible to determine for a taxpayer, whether or not he will be audited. This

creates an uncertainty and might influence taxpayer’s willingness to comply in incoming years.

A taxpayer, who evades a lot during one year, might be more willing to comply in next year. It

has also its reasoning in the cumulative effect of the penalty. The tax audit will take under its

scope previous years, thus long-term evasion tends to create higher fines (Engel, 1999).

The model of dynamics of tax evasion shows how the past events and the possibility of

audit influence people’s choice. The model implies that increases in tax rates and income tend to

create higher willingness to evade, as a fraction of income. On the other hand, higher intensity

and efficiency of tax audits tend to discourage any tax crime activities. It also assumes that

taxpayers, who have successfully managed to evade taxes, tend to be more aware of their

liabilities, therefore more willing to comply. As a general matter, those individuals tend to evade

less in the next years in order to remain unnoticed. Moreover, people who have been complying

before tend to, after comparison with successful evaders, be more willing to cheat (Engel, 1999).

Equation 4: Dynamics of tax evasion

22

In selecting the amount of income to report in one year, the individual has to be aware of

the effect of this year’s evasion on all future tax liabilities. In equation 4 an individual with given

amount of undiscovered tax liabilities ( ) for year (t-1) has an expected discounted

present value ( ) for the period (t) for all future tax liabilities. Moreover, model involves

interest paid ( ) on unreported period in case of audit and individual’s one-period subjective

discount factor ( (Engel, 1999).

The model starts from denoting tax payments in given period (t) before and audit takes

place. The second term presents expected tax payments for the next period (t+1), discounted and

assumed not prone to be audited. The last term describes the effect of taxpayer being audited in

given period (t), including penalties and interest on all evasion in year (t) and that all previous (t-

1) activities must be repaid and future tax liabilities would not be subject to recent evasion.

(Engel, 1999).

While equation 4 shows the importance of the dynamic considerations, equation 5

focuses on t the changes in individual’s perception after being caught.

Equation 5: Effect of audit on individual’s perception towards tax evasion

If the audit does not include previous years then the expected value ( ) becomes

constant. The equation 5 shows that even after being caught, the tax rate and the level of income

will not have effect on the individual’s willingness to comply. The reason is that the savings and

penalty from evading are both homogenously affected by the tax rate and income, thus the

changes in those factors will not have effect on the individual. The level of next year’s evasion,

as a fraction of income, is determined by the taxpayer’s risk aversion (Engel, 1999).

The model carries a lot of implications, with the most important one stating that

taxpayers with significant undiscovered tax evasion will tend to comply in next years to avoid

suspicions. The function of current evasion is convex, leading to higher chances of being audited

as levels of evasion, conditional on income, increase. Audits are assumed to be successful at

discovering all shadow activities, however it also assumes that once audited, taxpayer will be

23

eager to comply afterwards. Results however prove that there is high incentive from an

individual to evade, once audit is performed, since there is not much to lose in the first couple of

years (Engel, 1999)

Fundamentals of tax analysis

After discussion of social theories and models of tax evasion it would be advisable to

take a closer look on a normative analysis of taxation. The base of tax analysis is created by two

criteria equity and efficiency. (Slemrod, 2000).

The criterion of equity is based on the idea of horizontal and vertical equity. Horizontal

equity states that all individuals in the same tax frame and rate should be treated in the same

way. The assessment should be based solely on tax calculations, not determined by any other set

of irrelevant characteristics. The vertical equity states that all taxpayers no matter of income

should be treated in the same way, if caught evading (Slemrod, 2000). Moreover, both aspects

imply that no matter what is the taxpayer’s origin, the evasion shall be treated equally by the

state authorities.

The criterion of tax efficiency is based on the theory of tax incidence, which is based on

three basic principles of allocation of tax burden to individual. The first principle is grounded on

the rule that all tax burdens must be traced back to respective individuals, meaning that every

taxpayer should pay for what he is obliged to. The second one, states that individual’s elasticity

towards taxed goods tends to affect his willingness to comply with tax burden. The third

principle states that in the long run, in case of levying taxes, it does not matter which party is

obliged to pay taxes to the government. They have to be repaid, unless said otherwise (Slemrod,

2000).

The Allingham – Sandmo’s model together with horizontal equity produce some

behavioral tax evasion implications. One of them is the fact that the horizontal effect is

influenced by individual’s tax aversion. The less-risk averse taxpayer will gain more from the

gamble in comparison of individual’s expected value. Moreover, the horizontal inequity is

24

determined by the honesty of each individual. Although, the idea of honesty is an artificial

distinction between citizens, due to the fact that each of them is in the real world a utility-

maximizer (Slemrod, 2000). Perceived honesty or dishonesty depends on the taxpayer’s utility

function and willingness to achieve it. Some people are simply not interested in entering a

gamble with tax authorities, hence are more eager to comply with their tax burden and to

sacrifice some of their maximal utility, while others will do anything to achieve it (Steuerle,

1985, in Slemrod,2000).

Shadow economy’s estimation methods

Academics cannot decide which of the methods of estimation is the most accurate in case

of the shadow economy. Therefore there are many approaches used in order to get the results. In

this work, I would like to present two of them, which created outputs used in previous chapter.

The currency demand approach

Philip D. Cagan (1927-2012), was the first one to develop the model of currency demand

in the context of shadow economy. The main concept of it was the correlation of the currency

demand and the tax pressure, which were the determinant of people’s willingness to evade tax

burden (Schneider, 2000).

The model has been developed in order to create a mathematical function, which would

not be affected by biases in correlation. The extended model assumed that the most of the

shadow transactions are done in cash, in order to remain traceless for the state authorities. Thus

the increased demand for money would result in pumping up the correlation with the shadow

economy. An econometric equation had to be developed in order to make the model more

accurate (Tanzi, 1983).

25

Equation 6: Linear regression of the currency demand approach

Given model is a logarithm that takes under its scope the ratio of cash holdings to current

and deposit accounts (C/ . The regression uses four variables. The weighted average tax rate

(TW), which is used to proxy changes in the size of the shadow economy. The proportion of

wages and salaries in national income (WS/Y), which captures changes in payment and money

holding patterns. The interest paid on savings deposits (R), which represents the opportunity

costs of holding cash. The last variable represents the income per capita (Y/N) (Tanzi, 1983)

Figures for the size and development of the shadow economy can be estimated by

comparing the difference between the development of currency, when the direct and indirect tax

burden with government regulations are held on the lowest possible and current values. The

same income velocity for currency used both in the shadow economy and the official one has to

be assumed. Otherwise, the size of the shadow economy could not be computed and compared to

GDP (Schneider, 2000).

Despite being the most commonly used approach the model has not avoided criticism. It

was argued that not all shadow activities involve cash (roughly 80% do) and that the role of the

barter was not taken into consideration (Isachsen, 1980, in Schneider, 2000).Moreover, the

regression does not focus on personal attitudes and other factors that are not directly calculated

from official statistics (Schneider, 2000). The assumption of equal velocity of money in both

economies has also been criticized, due to large uncertainty and lack of accuracy in estimations

for both official and unofficial one. Therefore, it cannot be certainly assumed that they are equal

and that produced output is significant (Klovland, 1984, in Schneider, 2000).

26

The physical input method

The physical input approach assumes that electric-power consumption can be regarded as

the best physical indicator of overall economic activity. The model has been appraised for its

simplicity, however there has been a division between the academics, on how it should be

calculated and interpreted. The two most knows are the Kaufmann-Kaliberda’s (1996) and

Lacko’s (1998) methods (Schneider, 2000).

The first one argues that overall economic activity and electricity consumption have been

observed to move in a lockstep with the elasticity (electricity/GDP) usually close to one. The

proxy measurements for the overall economy can be used to determine the size of the unofficial

economy. The subtraction of the estimates for the official economy from the overall result can

create an estimate for the shadow economy (Kaufmann – Kaliberda, 1996).

This would mean that the shadow economy can be simply derived from the gross

differences between the registered usage of electricity and the overall result. This method,

despite its simplicity is criticized on many grounds. Most common critique is concerning the

used determinant of the shadow economy. There are many energy sources available, not only

electricity, that could be used to aid illegal activities and their consumption is affected by the

technological progress. Moreover, countries differ in their electricity production’s efficiency,

therefore it is difficult to assume that the method could be used worldwide (Schneider, 2000).

The second approach is more concerned about household usage of electricity and

production of goods. Households might be involved in do-it-yourself production and non-

registered activities and services. The main argument here is that, when in country the shadow

economy is mainly associated with household activities, higher usage of electricity would also

mean higher shadow economy (Lacko, 1998).

Equation 7: Lacko’s household electricity method

27

The model starts with taking a logarithm of household electricity consumption (E) in

given country (i). It is calculated based on five variables. The first is the real consumption of

households per capita (C), excluding the consumption of electricity in given country in US

dollars at purchasing power parity. The next variable is the real price of consumption of 1kwh of

residential electricity (PR) in US dollars at purchasing power parity. The model also focuses on

the number of months of heating needed in houses (G) and the ratio of energy sources other than

electricity energy to all household energy consumption (Q) in given country. Lastly the model

uses the output of the hidden economy per capita (H), which is derived as a regression of 3

variables: the ratios of both the sum of paid indirect and direct taxes (T) and public social

welfare expenditures (S) to GDP and the sum on number of inactive earners over 14 years, per

100 active earners (D) (Lacko, 1998).

Unfortunately, the model itself is not able to give concrete results on how big is the size

of the shadow economy, due to inability to calculate how much GDP is produced from one unit

of energy. The econometric estimation can be used to establish an ordering of the countries with

respect to the electricity usage in their shadow economies. In order to assess the actual sizes,

secondary data about country’s electric usage and GDP have to be calculated together with

results of the estimation (Schneider, 2000).

4. Empirical studies on tax morale and ethics

To comply or not with taxes is a complex decision, determined by variety of factors

affect by tax payer’s tax morale and ethics. Those aspects can be both dependable on personal

traits and environment influencing individual both directly and indirectly. Theoretical studies are

very often subjected to different biases, due to omitting personal opinions and attitudes of

individuals or groups involved in the study. Following chapter will present empirical data

gathered on demographic traits, social attitudes towards tax crimes and governments that were

gathered in order to highlight some of the factors determining tax morale and ethics.

28

Demographic studies

This paragraph will discuss results of analysis on demographic traits, such as gender

(appendix 2.1), age (appendix 2.2), education level (appendix 2.3), religion (appendix 2.4),

marital status (appendix 2.5) and income level and will try to show their effect on general tax

compliance. Such an analysis will be based mostly on data gathered during surveys for the WVS

on tax related topics.

As it is generally said, women are from Venus and men are from Mars (John Gray,

1992), hence I would like to start from analyzing gender’s effect on tax ethics and morality.

What is clearly visible is the lack of one general opinion for this aspect, due to different results,

determined by individual’s belonging to different culture and different ethical questions stated.

Women are more detail oriented than men, thus differently stated, similar question, could

produce different thoughts and answers (McGee, 2012).

In the studies, where women were considered as more ethical many of the researchers

concluded that it was due to their upbringing leading to deference of authorities. In the case of

less ethical results, it was assumed that the new way of living and liberation from traditional

household roles created more masculine views. In other words, self-aware women are becoming

more masculine in their way of living also in their tax compliance. And it was proven that under

same moral and ethical conditions, men are more eager than women to avoid taxes, whenever

legislation makes it possible (McGee, 2012).

There are many views on how gender, especially culture and differences in upbringing of

women and men, affect tax compliance. What most of the researchers agree on is that particular

personal traits associated with genders have an impact on tax morale. People who possess more

“feminine characters”, both men and women, are more likely to be tax compliant and to defer

authorities. On the other hand, those who posses more “masculine characters” tend to have more

risk seeking attitudes and try to defer taxes. It has also been proven that the prenatal testosterone

levels have no significant impact on those results (Kastlunger, 2010).

Age is another significant factor determining tax compliance. However, it is worth

mentioning, that the age studies were mostly including students, which possess higher level of

29

education than an average individual. The effect of education will be discussed further on, yet

studies determining age had to take this aspect into account (McGee, 2012)

Social science studies concerning ethics and taxation do not produce one significant

result regarding age as a tax compliance determinant. However, all things equal, it has to be said

that older people have more respect for rules and regulations, thus are more willing to obey

authorities. It can be concluded, after trying to disregard of differences made by education level,

that young people tend to present less ethical attitude towards willingness to pay taxes

(McGee,2012).

One of the mentioned limitations of these studies is that most of the opinions gathered

came from students. People, who tend to be younger, and present higher educational level than

an average individual. Nevertheless, their opinion is of vital matter since students represent the

voice of the country’s future opinion leaders and elites. (McGee, 2012.)

Studies on the level of education show three significant correlations. The first of them,

states that the higher the level of education, the more ethical attitude. It has been proven by

comparing answers of undergraduate students with graduate ones. The study concluded that,

graduates tend to be more ethical than their less educated colleagues. The second correlation

shows that the higher the level of education the bigger the shift, whenever tax crime is to be

considered, from tax evasion to tax avoidance. In other words, more educated people tend to be

more aware of the effects of tax evasion and possibilities of legal decrease of tax burden. The

third correlation shows that, despite general positive correlation, studies related to economical

and business areas tend to create more tax ethical attitudes. An interesting implication was the

fact that in all of the cases, women tended to score higher in tax ethics than men at the same level

of education (McGee, 2012).

Religion as a spiritual area is, in my opinion, a very interesting trait to be researched in

the matter of tax compliance. Different views, ethics and cultures shaped by religion tend to vary

from ultra ethical, where not to pay your taxes is to commit a mortal sin against the God (Saint

Antoninus, 1571), to lack of concern towards taxation at all. Muslim literature was interpreted to

say that tax evasion is ethical, whenever tax is meant to increase the price or value of the

good(Yusuf 1971, in McGee 2012).

30

There were quite few studies examining religion as a demographic determining attitude

towards tax evasion and they produced significant but not coherent results. As a significant

factor could be taken the location of where the studies have taken place. In general, Buddhists

were stated as the ones with the highest tax compliance, followed by Muslims, Catholics, Hindus

and Protestants. However there is a big discrepancy in results of the studies of differences

between Catholics and Muslims, probably, based on the location of the study. In general

overview, Catholics are being shown as the more opposing to tax evasion. However, a German

study that differentiates Muslims on different categories shows that especially Turkish ones are

more opposed to tax crimes than Christians (McGee, 2009 and McGee, 2011 in McGee, 2012).

The WVS conducted research on how marital status affects people’s willingness to

comply with taxes in order to show its significance in the tax ethics matter. Marital status is

likely to affect the general wealth of the household, hence it should be seen as an important

indicator favoring married couples (McGee, 2012).

The results showed indeed that married couples are one of the most ethical groups,

however unexpectedly, widowed individuals seem to be the most tax compliant. It might be due

to the fact that death of a spouse leads to many wealth transfers and tax implications, which force

compliance. On the other side, never married single people and divorced ones are the least tax

ethical. Nevertheless, once again there is a significant result that in all of those groups, women

seem to be more opposed to tax crimes than men (McGee, 2012).

The last but not the least trait taken under scope of the WVS was the level of income of

individuals and the effect on their tax compliance. The study here had many assumptions that

academics tried to resolve. One of them shows high incomers as less tax ethical, because of the

feeling of being overtaxed and exploited by state authorities. On the other hand, there was also a

thought that the same thing might happen to the poorest ones, due to their inability to pay

(McGee, 2012).

What the studies show, is that a general trend cannot be drawn for all countries. The

attitudes of the groups differ, due to cultural and social reasons. Studies in Hungary showed that

middle income people were more ethical than high and low incomers, while Portugal produced

outcomes that were quite opposite (McGee, 2012). It might be the case that in Hungary the

31

middle class was not as developed as in Portugal, thus they did not want to be involved in any

risk concerning taxation. However, that is merely just a speculation without any proofs.

.

Social representations on tax deterrence methods

Empirical evidence indicates that tax knowledge is significantly correlated with tax

compliance, however there is no agreement between scholars on how exactly it does. One study

says that in depth knowledge of taxes implies lower tax compliance (Groenland, 1983 in

Schneider, 2001), while other states that low tax knowledge results in lower willingness to pay

(Kirchler, 2001 in Schneider, 2001). Although, studies showed that higher tax knowledge leads

to stricter social representations on tax crimes. Individuals considered their tax evasion as more

serious, the tax brackets as fairer and became stricter towards other people’s tax evasion

(Eriksen, 1996 in Schneider, 2001).

Generally, there are three ways of reducing tax burden: tax avoidance, tax evasion and

tax flight. Each of them uses different means but strive to achieve the same goal. The conducted

study was supposed to show, how different ways are being perceived by individuals in order to

show the most unethical one (appendix 3).

Tax avoidance uses legal means, such as loopholes in regulations, in order to decrease the

tax burden. While asked about it individuals described it as a legal intention to save taxes. It was

often mentioned together with cleverness, good ideas and some costs to gather information. It

was considered as a moral choice, which uses regulations in order to achieve its goal.

Acceptance of tax reductions, allowances, searching for legal ways of reducing tax, horizontal

justice and tax loopholes were mentioned as a way to achieve tax avoidance (Schneider, 2001).

Tax evasion is an opposite to tax avoidance. It is not concerned about the legality of its

means to achieve its goals. While asked for associations with it, individuals were coherent in

their answers. It was considered as an illegal and immoral choice, which included a lot of risk in

order to save on taxes. For many responders, it was considered as a part of shadow economy,

involving fraud, black money, faulty tax declarations and vertical justice. Moreover, it also

32

created more repressive associations, such as audit, penalties and sanctions. It is seen as an

opportunity for an individual to save bigger amount of money, compared to tax avoidance, but

also considered as more unethical and risky (Schneider, 2001).

Tax flight uses means of relocation to save on taxes. It does take into consideration

different laws and regulations in different economical areas or countries in order to achieve its

goal. Surprisingly, individuals when asked for their opinion about it said that it is indeed legal

but immoral thing to do. On the one hand people consider it as a clever thing, because of ability

to use tax agreements, other tax regimes and tax havens to save money. On the other hand, it

requires many bureaucratic activities, involves relocation costs and very often can be

unprofitable and lead to problems for the company. What was, probably, considered as the most

immoral was the fact that it is an open critique of the tax system of the home country. Moreover,

leaving a country decreases tax revenues and general wealth of the society (Schneider, 2001).

In the statistical experiments based on gathered data, the highest moral value was given

to tax avoidance followed by tax flight and tax evasion. Moreover, higher tax knowledge, related

to the profession of the responder, also affected general fairness of the three tax deterrence

methods. The higher the knowledge, the higher was the perceived fairness of tax avoidance and

the lower the knowledge the higher was perceived fairness of tax evasion. Stating that more

educated people in the field of taxation tend to be more aware of the distinction between an

illegal and a legal mean to decrease tax burden (Schneider, 2001).

Fairness and institutional quality

There is a strong argument, stating that tax ethics is shaped by the perception of quality

and fairness of the state authorities. Whenever they are considered as fraudulent or not working

in the interest of the nation, tax evasion could even be considered as an ethical way to show

social disapproval (Cummings, 2005).

In the study striving to expose the correlation between fairness and quality of state

authorities with tax compliance, researchers wanted to prove its effect on shaping of tax ethics in

33

society. Study had to take into consideration enforcement resources available to the government,

which does affect the results and shows that tax compliance rates might be inconsistent with

rational behavior. The role of uncertainty in auditing plays a substantive role, due to subjectivity

of its probability for each individual. State is not obliged, nor has the incentive, to reveal the

entire auditing mechanism or identities of observed taxpayers (Alm, 1988).

It is hard to generally say what determines fairness and high quality of state authorities,

however the study produced some common associations. Individuals believe that tax system that

treats everyone equally, implementing horizontal justice is considered as fair. While the quality

comes when people can see that tax revenues are used to provide valuable goods and services in

an efficient way. They would also be more eager to contribute to a government that is willing to

spend their money in a proper way, increasing the welfare of the society (Cummings, 2005).

Individuals should consider the government as trustworthy, taxes as fair and clear, fiscal

exchange between taxpayer and authorities as beneficial and trust should be seen on both sides.

The results demonstrate that those aspects have stronger effect on individual, than enforcement

methods used by governments. The individual’s positive perceptions about the government and

tax system are very important determinant of tax compliance. It can be argued that, indeed,

increased enforcement leads to higher tax revenues, but the perception that paying taxes is

beneficial for the society is more important in creation of tax ethics.

5. Determinants of tax compliance in CEE countries

Tax morale and ethics in CEE countries is a very interesting example, which cannot be

easily discussed based solely on demographic studies. In general, they represent a group of

sometimes contradicting characteristics, due to their different demographics compared to

Western Europe.

In general, Eastern Europe has lower average age of an individual and score higher in

Hofstede’s masculinity index than Western Europe. It also has higher proportion of students

among younger population and illiterates among older than their western neighbors. Due to their

34

higher commitment to religion and traditional family lifestyle, there is higher probability of long-

lasting marriage. At the same time, in comparison with Western countries, a couple achieves on

average lower mutual income (Tamas, 2007).

After chapter 4, it cannot be said with 100 percent certainty, that demographics can be a

significant determinant of tax compliance in CEE countries. Other determinants, such as history,

trust, efficiency of state authorities in different aspects have to be included to take a closer look

on why the average tax compliance rate in CEE is lower than in Western Europe.

History

Some of the historical facts have been already mentioned in previous chapters. Therefore,

here I would like to simply present the most important implications of the socialistic past of CEE

countries, which have affected their tax compliance rates and low tax morale.

Before the transition period most of the citizens of socialistic countries were not aware of

individual tax burden. In most of the cases the state revenues were from government owned

companies, which had unlimited access to credit facilities. In 1980, the Polish budget estimated

that approximately 97.5% of its revenues would come from those enterprises. Therefore, proving

how insignificant was personal tax income (Owsiak, 2007). Most of the individuals were not

under any taxation and were not aware of their personal contribution to the commonwealth

(Torgler, 2007).

The post-socialistic history is especially important, due to the fact that the transition

period started in early 90’s, thus majority of nowadays taxpayers have somehow been influenced

by that period. People in their 20’s and more have experienced at least slightly the socialist

administration and might have developed already, common to post-socialistic societies, weak

voluntary compliance (Torgler, 2011). In such circumstances introduction of personal taxes and

creation of a tax based civilization is especially difficult.

35

Trust

Morality exists where there is a possibility of making a choice. Whenever there is a

choice that includes two individuals, who are not aware of their actions, honesty is in price

(McGee, 2012). Creation of trust is based on exhibition of honesty and goodwill from the other

involved party.

There are very good reasons for a correlation between trust both in the government-

taxpayer and inter-taxpayers relations and tax compliance rates (Uslaner, 2007) (Appendix 4.1).

First of all, we do not pay taxes to our society, we pay them to the government. The willingness

to comply with taxes is a proof of social trust in authorities. It is the belief, that what they are

doing is honest and benefits us, the taxpayers. The social trust reflects social solidarity, due to

redistributive function of the taxes. A trustworthy government, which supports economic and

social programs, will receive support allowing it to operate (Uslaner, 2007).

Moralistic trust is a term describing moral commandment to treat people as if they were

trustworthy. The main point is the belief that most people share fundamental moral values,

therefore the majority will share similar views and will remain honest to each other (Uslaner,

2007). When others share our basic set of values and ideas, there is lower risk when agreements

including trust, relying on individuals goodwill, are being agreed upon (Selingman, 1997 in

Uslaner, 2007). Moralistic trust is a determinant of strong solidarity community. In general,

people belonging to those groups are willing to trust others and to participate in actions tending

to improve the welfare of the group (Lindenberg, 1988 in Janky 2007). In the tax matter, they

would be more willing to comply to support the redistributive function of taxes. This type of

solidarity is observed in Western European societies. The opposite, weak solidarity, is more of a

characteristic of CEE members of EU (Janky, 2007).

In the EU a collision of social solidarity is easily visible. The West shows concern about

collectivist norms and equality of the citizens, while the East, very often disappointed with

socialistic times, strives for the goals and career of an individual. The lack of solidarity can be

shown by an anecdote on how, in 1997, a Russian civil servant asked a Swedish political

scientist how is it possible that almost all Swedes are honest with their taxes, while in Russia it

36

was a common practice to cheat (Rothstein, 2001 in Uslaner, 2007). Russians represent here the

attitude of many post-socialist countries, where lack of moralistic trust undermines tax revenues.

In the recent case of Polish media-tax, social resistance towards the public TV and lack of belief

in the honesty of other taxpayers led to critically low tax compliance rate. The lack of trust and

belief that the money will not be spent properly, together with relatively low compliance rates

empowered other individuals to avoid taxation as well (Uslaner, 2007).

Post-socialistic countries, despite the social resistance towards taxation, low tax ethics

and morale and general lack of trust in government of the citizens, are an interesting case, where

governmental coercion keeps tax compliance on an acceptable level. The use of coercion, in

democratic states might be a presentation of institutional quality, while in post-socialistic states it

very often undermines general governmental trust (Uslaner, 2007). In a state where every single

citizen is treated as a tax offender and tax authorities have enormous power, the taxpayer will be

more resistant to comply and trust will not be achieved (Owsiak, 2007). Trust is an important

matter, determining positive financial interactions between taxpayers and their governments.

Nevertheless it cannot be achieved overnight and in order to establish it both sides need to show

their honest intentions and willingness to comply.

Corruption

There have been many studies on the correlation between corruption and tax evasion

(appendix 4.2). Many studies have shown that as the corruption in the government spreads, the

feeling of moral duty to pay taxes among individuals decreases (McGee, 2012). People comply

with taxes believing that their money will be redistributed to increase overall wealth of the

society. When money is not used in the promised way and ends up on private accounts,

compliance rates drop as a social response (Uslaner, 2007).

The study of corruption experienced a huge increase in interest once the transformation

process of CEE countries began. The lack of the rule of the law, accountability of the

government and good management led to an outbreak of many corruptive activities (Torgler,

2007). There were situations in which administrational weaknesses lead to bribery, which in

37

some branches reach significant amounts of money. High complexity of tax law, frequent

meetings between taxpayers and tax authorities, low wages of tax administrators and their

relatively high influence on tax decisions are amongst the most common ones (Tanzi, 2002 in

Torgler, 2007).

There is a correlation between trust and corruption, which is one of the determinants of

the level of inequality in a country. Countries with high levels of trust have low levels of

corruption and are more likely to be influenced by, if any, economical inequalities. Corruptive

actions tend to increase inequalities, which in organized societies are more visible and tend to

have a stronger negative impact on the trust to government. This leads to a so called inequality

trap, because a decrease in trust leads to more corruption, hence more inequality. Moreover, the

inequality trap is a two-sided game. For more equal, high trusting societies (mostly Scandinavia

and Western Europe) the game would end up in low corruption and high level of tax compliance.

Otherwise, (for most of the CEE countries) inequalities will affect negatively trust, increase

corruption and decrease tax compliance rates (Uslaner, 2007).

The great power involves great responsibility (Franklin D. Roosevelt, 1882-1945), which

is often the case in transition countries, where the power of authorities is often higher than in

other countries. Behavior and norms that come from informal sectors tend to disturb the way the

formal ones work (Ott, 2007). Corrupt bureaucracy does not strive for efficiency, but supports

initiatives that are in some, material or non-material, way connected to the authorities. Therefore,

it increases the costs and time delays of the investments, which, if noticed, have negative impact

on tax morale (Torgler, 2007).

Corruption was and still is a great obstacle for transition countries, which stops

economical growth and increases the size of the informal sector. Lack of transparency,

accountability and the feeling of impunity erode social trust to the government and the quality of

the institutions (Ott, 2007). In many CEE countries, corrupt politicians are not being sentenced in

a way appropriate to their crimes. This, if noticed by citizens, decreases the motivation to comply

with taxes, since they do not provide the wealth that they are supposed to. The tax ethics and

morale decrease, creating more incentives to decrease tax burden (Torgler, 2007).

38

Efficiency of state institutions and tax regulations

Tax regulations are being developed to make the unpleasant duty of taxpaying as easy

and transparent as possible, while the state institutions are supposed to ensure proper collection

and usage of tax revenues. However, it might happen that the regulations are not clear or tax

authorities waste the money instead of using it to increase commonwealth. Does it allow

taxpayers to chose lesser evil, evade taxation, in order to shorten the inefficient actions? (McGee,

2012).

In order to ensure proper tax structure, the state has to ensure that fundamental rules of

tax civilization are applied. The most important are: the stability of the tax system, efficient

operation of democratic institutions, accurate tax laws, a simple tax system, efficient collection

and penalizing mechanisms and transparency in tax operations (Owsiak, 2007). A well-ordered

tax structure increases the trust in the government, decreasing the incentives to get involved in

illegal tax activities. The confidence in the state and willingness to comply increases as the

perception of a strong judiciary system is more common. People are more willing to comply

when they are treated equally by the tax law and state authorities (Uslaner, 2001).

Stability of the tax system and its simplicity are one of the most important determinants

of tax compliance (appendix 4.3). Frequent changes in the regulations have a negative impact on

the creation of tax ethics, tax complexity and motivation to comply. Very often, such actions are

perceived by the society as the willingness of the state authorities to hide their true intentions

(Owsiak, 2007).

Changes in the tax system might vary, starting from movements of the tax margins,

through imposition of new taxes on goods to introduction of new ways of tax reporting or

relieving. Frequent changes in tax rates might provide incentives for individuals to substitute

some of their goods, depending on the tax structure, in order to help them avoid or evade some of

the taxes (Slemrod, 2001). It can also be an incentive for a taxpayer to shelter some of his wealth

to prevent it from being overly taxed due to the changes in regulations. Sheltering is not always

associated with evasion. It could use a way of property rights transfer or abroad transfer in order

to decrease the tax base or avoid the taxation in given country. There is no evidence supporting

39

that all sheltering individuals are evaders, nor that they are not evaders only because of the

attention that sheltering draws (Cowell, 1990). Excessive introduction of new regulations that

might sometimes contradict themselves increases the general complexity of the system, therefore

making tax compliance difficult. Taxpayers are being forced to invest time in order to learn

about the changes and new rules. At the same time, they are getting more aware of their

possibilities to avoid taxes. It could be seen from two ways. It could be motivation for the

individual to get to know regulations and to comply with them, if for example the costs of

learning would be tax deductible. Therefore, changes would not impose any additional costs for

the individual. On the other hand, those additional costs might serve as a decreased opportunity

cost to evade. Tax compliance would be more expensive for the tax payer, therefore less risk-

averse individual might see evasion as a way of leaving the income unaffected (Cross, 1982)

The efficiency of the tax authorities in collecting revenues, tracing frauds and penalizing

tax offenders is important to keep tax compliance high. The probability of being audited is an

uncertainty for each individual. The strength of its impact on the taxpayer’s willingness to

comply is based on the individual risk attitude. The higher the probability of accurate audit, the

less risk-aversion is needed to comply with taxes (Klepper, 1989). However, important aspect

here is based on the quality of information gathered by the state authorities. For an auditor there

is a significant difference between being aware that someone is cheating and being able to prove

who is doing that. The data collection process requires time, money and the outcome is very

often dependant on the accessibility of information (Slemrod, 2001). The tax authorities cannot

treat each individual as a tax offender, if they do not want to lose social belief in the efficiency of

their actions and institutions (Owsiak, 2007).

Transition countries are a good example of the importance of the efficiency of institutions

and complexity of the regulations as determinants of tax compliance. CEE countries had big

problems with tax revenues due to administrative issues that have arisen after 1990. The tax

administration was inefficient due to legal, institutional and managerial weaknesses, which had a

serious impact on the creation of tax morale in CEE countries (Trasberg, 2005).

Many authors, especially, from the post-socialistic countries have described the actions of

their authorities as simply irresponsible. Many tax modifications have been introduced, while

still in the conceptual phase, leaving many loopholes and partially implemented regulations that

40

contradicted themselves. Many of those reforms were made in order to ensure financial stability

after the economic vacuum, but in reality they were nothing more than just a way of finding new

sources of funding. The feeling of impunity allowed politicians to ignore the complexity, legal

contradictions and arising future complications caused by their actions, since in 4 years there

would be others dealing with that (Owsiak, 2007).

Generally, the state authorities were not able to ensure proper tax collection and

enforcement. A new market-based economy with large number of taxpayers was something that,

poorly equipped and inexperienced in personal income tax collection administration could not

handle (Trasberg, 2005).. The information gathering methods, corruptive practices and negative

attitude towards taxpayer’s honesty did not help to create social trust.

Efficiency of tax redistribution

Angelus of Clavisio (died in 1495) stated that there is no ethical obligation for an

individual to pay taxes, if the authorities that collect them do not provide any common good. It

could also be applied in cases where tax revenues support unjust policies, are being wasted or

provide negative externalities to the society (McGee, 2012).

Merit wants are goods that society needs and sometimes is unable to afford (medical care,

education, public transportation). Government has to decide on how to use tax revenues in order

to purchase the most necessary merit goods. There is no single explanation on what merit goods

are and which are the most important ones, but they could be generalized in order to serve their

purpose. Merit wants, can be categorized as “good” and “bad” and it is the state’s responsibility

to make that distinction. Good ones should be supported by the government, (e.g., education)

while bad ones discouraged (e.g., alcohol consumption) (Block, 2012).

With merit goods, the value judgments play important role and they might differ, the

median voter might not be satisfied with what the government offers. In general, the money that

is being redistributed can be considered as a good that the government gives away. It might end

up in the form of infrastructure investment, policy support or financial help to the certain groups

41

of individuals (e.g. poor, disabled). Depending on the needs of the taxpayers it should be decided

on how the money should be spent. However, individuals differ in the terms of income,

household situation and etc. which makes it hard for the government to establish one general

merit want. The goods considered as the most important, hopefully benefiting the society, have

to be chosen even if they produce dissatisfaction of minority (Block, 2012).

What is very often commented on is the fact, that many states, while choosing programs

to support do not take into consideration its efficiency. Many financial aids or investments are

considered by public as waste of resources, because they do not provide expected results or

support more important needs. Thus very often there is a question whether or not that money

should be kept in private sector instead (McGee, 2012).

One of the challenges of the government while redistributing the goods is the

transparency of the whole procedure (Owsiak, 2007). In many post-socialistic countries, there is

very often a question whether current governments are not just a mere replacement of previous

ones, with taxes instead of citizen oppression. In the last half of the century, lack of transparency

made it impossible for the taxpayer to realize what his money was used for, assuming he was

subjected to taxes (Owsiak, 2007)

As mentioned before, taxpayers are ready to accept their personal tax burden if they are

aware, how it is being used. Many of CEE countries still have large bureaucratic administrations

in charge of important aspects, such as education or public health. For example, in Poland, NFZ

(National Health Fund) operates in a very bureaucratic way, which involves many transfers

leading to millions of PLN being consumed in the process before they are being redistributed in

the society, leading to short backs and sometimes financial problems in state governed hospitals

or universities. (Owsiak, 2007) The governments instead of taking care of those problems are

more interested in more visible initiatives, which could be observed in the recent case of EURO

2012 organized in Poland and Ukraine. While Polish hospitals lacked funding and construction

of highways was under crisis, sport infrastructure has been erected despite social, also mine,

disapproval due to enormous costs and lack of plans on how to manage them afterwards.

Unfortunately, the truth is that many of CEE members of EU are poorer than their

Western neighbors. If they want to become richer, they should be able to redistribute more

42

efficiently to aspects that matter, such as public infrastructure, education and so on (Torgler,

2011). People living in those countries are aware of the inequalities and problems that affect the

public administration. Taxation rates might not be considered as the most important way of

reducing those inequalities, however the way of redistribution of tax revenues is definitely one of

them. People would like to live in less stratified society and the government should support their

wishes and needs (Badescu, 2007).

6.Conclusions

The aim of this work was to present the relevance of tax ethics and morale in the field of

taxation. Moreover, by the means of comparison of EU member’s tax attitudes the areas with

lower tax compliance rates were supposed to be highlighted. In the end, this paper wanted to

show the determinants, which create tax morale and how their deterioration affected the creation

of tax culture and therefore tax compliance rates.

The study began with description of the tax compliance rates between members of the

EU. The distinction between Eastern and Western Europe is easily visible from the beginning.

The history shows that starting from early 90’s tax evasion was widely spread in CEE countries

and on average the mean compliance rate for those countries was 20% below Western Europe’s.

Therefore, those countries were taken under closer look in order to find the most important

determinants of their low tax morale.

To give an insight on how the study was determined important social theories and tax

models were included and supported with empirical studies on tax evasion. The main point was

to represent taxpayer’s as risk-averse utility maximizers, which while engaging in illegal tax

activities are taking risk against the uncertain probability of audit. Moreover, the empirical study

was supposed to represent a profile of an expected tax evader, with respect to gender, age,

education level, religion, marital status and income, as well as to show social representations on

the different ways of lowering tax burden. While generally more masculine societies were

described as less willing to comply, there was a different response on the ways of doing so. The

43

respondents in the research answered that tax avoidance is moral and legal, tax evasion is

immoral and illegal and tax flight is immoral and legal.

In order to find the most important aspects of determinants of tax ethics and morale in

CEE countries they had to be taken through the scope of their post-socialistic past and the

transition process. Due to erosion of social norms and public administration, I have decided to

choose post-socialistic history, trust, corruption, complexity and efficiency of tax system and

administration and efficiency of redistribution of tax revenues to further discussion. The

influence of those aspects was crucial on creation or deterioration of tax ethics in CEE countries.

Post-socialistic history and its lack of personal taxation is a very important distinction

between Eastern and Western Europe. It is a direct reason of very low tax ethics and compliance

in the beginning of 90’s in CEE countries. Lack of trust in financial interactions between

government and taxpayers is very important here. Lack of transparency in the operations

undertaken by tax authorities and treatment of majority of taxpayer’s as potential criminals does

not increase individual’s willingness to comply. Corruption, widely spread in some of the CEE

countries, leads to lack of trust and deterioration of moral obligations to pay taxes. People are

willing to contribute to benefit the society not to enrich individuals. Impunity in creation of tax

legislation, which makes the tax system too complex for an individual to comply, sometimes also

involving additional costs, increases incentive to evade. Inefficiency of tax collection decreases

the uncertainty of audit, making taxpayers more eager to take risk and to get involved in tax

crimes. The authorities should be able not only to say that someone is evading, they should also

know who exactly is doing that. Accusations and prosecutions of random people will not lead to

creation of tax morale, they can only artificially push up tax compliance rates. In the end the

efficiency of distribution is a very important matter as well. People are willing to contribute only

if they see that their money is spent properly. Compliance is treated as an award for the good

performance of the government, therefore inefficient usage or bureaucratic money vacuums

decrease willingness to pay taxes.

If I were to choose the most important factors determining the low tax compliance in

CEE countries, I would have to say that it is the lack of trust and transparency. It is clearly

visible that people do not have trust in their governments and do not believe that their money is

being spent properly or enhancing social commonwealth. Many corruptive practices, bad

44

investments, bureaucratic vacuums and lack of efficiency of state institutions have led to huge

deterioration in social trust. As mentioned before, trusting societies are more willing to both

contribute and redistribute. Transparency in how the governments operate with tax revenues

would help to prove to the society that tax revenues are used properly and beneficiary for

individuals. It might not be possible to use the same merit goods to satisfy all taxpayers, due to

personal differences in value judgments. It should be possible, though, to provide goods

approved by the majority of the society.

If the authorities of CEE countries want to increase tax compliance rates and then

maintain those levels, they should definitely start their reforms from themselves. They should

punish those responsible for the deterioration of social trust and begin the process of building a

society where taxpayer and government are partners in building the commonwealth.

Transparency in the management and redistribution of tax revenues would be, in my opinion, one

of the best ways to build up a trustworthy tax system. Trustworthy authorities should not have

problems in the future with their taxpayers’ incentives to cheat on taxes.

The problem leaves a lot of space for further research, especially in field of increasing

and maintaining CEE countries’ tax ethics and morality. The post-socialistic history and another

twenty years of not trustworthy, democratic governance have left a mark on the society.

Researchers have to focus on how this mark could be removed from the CEE taxpayers if they

would like to create a tax civilization in that area. Special characteristics of the countries

involved, their politics and practices used that deteriorated social trust have to be examined. The

tax history of this region, in my opinion, would not allow for quick changes and, probably,

introduction of Western models would need even more time. It is important to consider a new

way of increasing tax morale and ethics easily adoptable to given circumstances that would

improve the situation and build up the social trust.

45

7.References

Books

Block, Walter (2012), The failure of public finances, In: McGee, Robert W. (2012), The ethics of

tax evasion, p.229-247, North Miami: Springer Publishing

Gandullia, Luca (2005), An overview of taxation, In: Bernardi, Luigi (2005),Tax systems and tax

reforms in new EU members, p.3-30, London: Routledge Studies in the Modern World

Economy,

Janky, Bela (2007), Social structure, transition and public attitudes towards tax evasion in

Hungary, In: Hayoz, Nicolas (2007),Tax evasion, trust and state capabilities. How good is tax

moral in Central and Eastern Europe,p.269-287 ,Bern: Peter Lang International Academic

Publishers

McGee, Robert W. (2012), Four views on the ethics of tax evasion, In: McGee, Robert W.

(2012), The ethics of tax evasion,p. 3-34, North Miami: Springer Publishing

McGee, Robert W. (2012), An analysis of some arguments, In: McGee, Robert W. (2012), The

ethics of tax evasion,p. 47-72, North Miami: Springer Publishing

McGee, Robert W.(2012), Tax evasion opinion in Estonia, In: McGee, Robert W. (2012), The

ethics of tax evasion, p.285-300, North Miami: Springer Publishing

McGee, Robert W. (2012), Cheating on taxes if you have a chance: A comparative study of tax

evasion opinion in Turkey and Germany, In: McGee, Robert W. (2012), The ethics of tax

evasion, p.357-370, North Miami: Springer Publishing

McGee, Robert W. (2012), Gender and the ethics of tax evasion: An empirical study of 82

countries, In: McGee, Robert W. (2012), The ethics of tax evasion,p.415-440, North Miami:

Springer Publishing

McGee, Robert W. (2012), Education level and the ethics of tax evasion, In: McGee, Robert W.

(2012), The ethics of tax evasion,p.451-458, North Miami: Springer Publishing

46

McGee, Robert W. (2012), Marital status and the ethics of tax evasion, In: McGee, Robert W.

(2012), The ethics of tax evasion,p. 475-484, North Miami: Springer Publishing

McGee, Robert W. (2012), Income level and the ethics of tax evasion, In: McGee, Robert W.

(2012), The ethics of tax evasion, p.485-498, North Miami: Springer Publishing

Ott, Katarina (2007), What do state capacity and trust have to do with the evolution of the

informal economy and tax evasion in Croatia, In: Hayoz, Nicolas (2007),Tax evasion, trust and

state capabilities. How good is tax moral in Central and Eastern Europe,p.289-305 ,Bern: Peter

Lang International Academic Publishers

Owsiak, Stanislaw (2007), Taxes in post-communistic countries – old and new challenges, In:

Hayoz, Nicolas (2007),Tax evasion, trust and state capabilities. How good is tax moral in Central

and Eastern Europe,p. 187-223 ,Bern: Peter Lang International Academic Publishers

Paivi, Eriksson (2008), Qualitative research evaluation, In: Paivi, Eriksson (2008), Qualitative

methods in business research, p.290-297, London: Sage Publishing

Rawls, John (1971) , A theory of justice , Cambridge: Harvard University Press

Torgler, Benno (2007), Tax morale in Central and Eastern European countries, In: Hayoz,

Nicolas (2007),Tax evasion, trust and state capabilities. How good is tax moral in Central and

Eastern Europe, p.155-183,Bern: Peter Lang International Academic Publishers

Trasberg, Viktor (2005), Tax administration and the shadow economy, In: Bernardi, Luigi

(2005),Tax systems and tax reforms in new EU members, p. 96-109, London: Routledge Studies

in the Modern World Economy,

Tyler, Tom (1998), Social justice and social movements, In: Gilbert T.D (1998), The Handbook

of social psychology, p. 595-629, Boston: McGraw-Hill publishing

Uslaner, Eric. M (2007), Tax evasion, trust and the strong arm of law, In: Hayoz, Nicolas

(2007),Tax evasion, trust and state capabilities. How good is tax moral in Central and Eastern

Europe,p.17-49 ,Bern: Peter Lang International Academic Publishers

Journals.

47

Abric, J. C. (1996), Specific processes of social representations. Papers on Social

Representations – Textes sur les Représentations Sociales, No. 5, p. 77-80.

Alm, James (1988), Uncertain tax policies, individual behavior, and welfare,” American

Economic Review, No. 78, p. 237-245

Alm, James (2006), Culture differences and tax morale in the United States and in Europe,

Journal of Economic Psychology, No.27, p.224-246

Baldwin, R. E. (1995). The Eastern enlargement of the European Union, European Economic

Review. No. 39, p. 474-481

Bardsley, Nicholas (2006), Conformism and reciprocity in public good provision. Journal of

Economic Psychology. In press

Block, Julian: 1997, ‘Tax Report: The Judicial View of Taxes’, The Network Journal 5 (3),

No. 20,

Chrisite, Edward (2006), What explains tax evasion? An empirical assessment based on

European data, WIIW Working Paper, No. 40

Cowell, Frank (1990), Tax sheltering and the cost of evasion, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 42,

No. 1, p. 231-243,

Croson, Rachel (1998), Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity: Evidence from linear

public good games, Working Paper Series, Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania

Cross, Rodney (1982), On the economics of tax aversion, Public Finance, Vol. 37, No. 1, p. 36-

47

Cummings, Ronald G. (2005), Effects of tax morale on tax compliance: experimental and survey

evidence, Journal of Economical Literature, No. H20

Dynan, Karen E. (2008),The evolution of household income volatility,The Brookings Institution,

Engel, Eduardo M.R.A (1999), Understanding tax evason dynamics, NBER Working Paper

Series, No.6903

Falk, Armin (2002), Psychological foundations of incentives, European Economic Review, No.

46, p.687–724

48

Feld, L. P., & Frey, B. S. (2002). Trust breeds trust: How taxpayers are treated, Economics of

Governance,No. 3, p.87–99

Frey, Bruno S. (2007), Tax morale and conditional cooperation, Journal of Comparative

Economics, No.35, p.136-159

Heldt, Tobias (2005), Conditional cooperation in the field: Cross-country skiers? Behavior in

Sweden, Uppsala University.

Henrich, Joseph (2004), Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale

cooperation. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, No. 53, p. 3–35

Hewstone, M. 1983. Social representations and social explanations: From the "naive" to the

"amateur" scientist, Oxford, Blackwell

Kastlunger, Barbara (2010), Sex differences in tax compliance: Differentiating between

demographic sex, gender-role orientation, and prenatal masculinization (2D:4D). Journal of

Economic Psychology, No. 31, p. 542–552

Kary, Joseph (2000), "Contract Law and the Social Contract: What Legal History Can Teach Us

About the Political Theory of Hobbes and Locke", Ottawa Law Review, No.31, p.73-91

Kaufmann, Daniel and Kaliberda, Aleksander (1996), Integrating the unofficial economy into the

dynamics of post-socialistic economies. A framework of analyses and evidence, The World

Bank, Policy Research Working Paper, No.1691

Klepper, Steven (1989), The anatomy of tax evasion, Journal of Law, Economics, and

Organization, Vol. 5, No. 1, p. 1-24

Kornai, Janos (1990), The affinity between ownership forms and coordination mechanism: The

common experience of reform in socialistic countries. Journal of Economic Perspective, No. 4,

p.131–147

Landier, Augustin (2011), Inequality, tax avoidance and financial instability, CEPR Working

Paper, No. 8391

Lacko, Maria (1998), The hidden economies of Vise grad countries in international comparison:

a household electricity approach, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

Moscovici, S. (1981), On social representations, London, London Academic Press.

Rose-Ackerman, S. (2001). Trust and Honesty in Post-Socialist Societies, KYKLOS. No. 54,

p.415-444

49

Schneider, Friedrich (2000), Shadow economies around the world, IMF working paper, No.

WP/00/26

Schneider, Friedrich (2001), Social representations on tax avoidance, tax evasion and tax flight.

Do legal differences matter? , Johannes Keppler University Linz Working Paper, No. 0104

Shaw, Keith (1982). The evasion-avoidance choice: A suggested approach.

National Tax Journal, no.34, p.489-491

Slemrod, Joel (2000), Tax avoidance, evasion and administration, NBER Working Paper, No.

7473

Tamas, Andy (2007), Geert Hofstede’s dimensions of culture and Edward T. Hall’s time

orientations, An Intercultural Organization Development Tamas Consulting Group

Tanzi, Vito (1983), The underground economy in US: Annual estimates, 1930-1980, Staff papers

International Monetary Fund, Vol.30,No.4, p. 283-305

Torgler, Benno (2007), The impact of tax morale and institutional quality on the shadow

economy, CESifo Working Paper, No. 1899

Torgler, Benno (2011), Tax morale, Eastern Europe and European enlargement, Policy Research

Working Paper, No. 5911

Vergès, P. (1987), A social and cognitive approach to economic representations, Cambridge,

Cambridge University Press

Vogel, Lukas (2012), Tax avoidance and fiscal limits: Laffer curves in an economy with

informal sector, European Commission Economic Paper, No.448

50

Appendixes

Appendix 1. Table 3, 4 and 7 (Schneider, 2000)

51

52

53

Appendix 2: Empirical evidences on demographic studies (McGee, 2012)

Appendix 2.1: Gender

Appendix 2 2: Age

54

Appendix 2.3: Education level

Appendix 2.4: Religion (including differentiation of Muslims)

55

Appendix 2.5: Marital status

56

Appendix 3: Study on social representations (Schneider, 2001).

57

58

Appendix 4: Empirical evidences on CEE determinants of tax compliance

(Uslaner, 2007).

Appendix 4.1: Trust

59

60

61

Appendix 4.2: Corruption

62

Appendix 4.3: Efficiency of state institutions and tax regulations

63