32
Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza [email protected]

Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza [email protected]

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

Econ 384

Intermediate Microeconomics II

Instructor: Lorne Priemaza

[email protected]

Page 2: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A. Intertemporal Choice

A.1 Compounding

A.2 Present Value

A.3 Present Value Decisions

A.4 Lifecycle Model

Page 3: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.1 CompoundingIf you invest an amount P for a return r,

After one year:You will make interest on the amount P Total amount in the bank = P(1+r) = P + Pr

After another year:You will make interest on the initial amount PYou will make interest on last year’s interest PrTotal amount in the bank = P(1+r)2

This is COMPOUND INTEREST. Over time you make interest on the interest; the interest compounds.

Page 4: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.1 CompoundingInvestment: $100 Interest rate: 2%

Year Calc. Amount

1 100 100.00

2 100*1.02 102.00

3 100*1.022 104.04

4 100*1.023 106.12

5 100*1.024 108.24

Derived Formula:

S = P (1+r)t

S = value after t years

P = principle amount

r = interest ratet = years

Page 5: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.1 Compounding ChoiceGiven two revenues or costs, choose the one with the greatest value after time t:

A: $100 now B:$115 in two years, r=6%(find value after 2 years)

S = P (1+r)t

SA =$100 (1.06)2 = $112.36

SB =$115

Choose option B

Page 6: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.1 Compounding Loss ChoiceThis calculation also works with losses, or a combination of gains or loses:

A: -$100 now B: -$120 in two years, r=6%(find value after 2 years)

S = P (1+r)t

SA =-$100 (1.06)2 = -$112.36

SB =-$120

Choose option A. (You could borrow $100 now for one debt, then owe LESS in 2 years than waiting)

Page 7: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.2 Present Value What is the present value of a given sum

of money in the future?

By rearranging the Compound formula, we have:

PV = present valueS = future sumr = interest ratet = years

tr

SPV

)1(

Page 8: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.2 Present Value Gain Example

What is the present value of earning $5,000 in 5 years if r=8%?

403,3$

)08.1(

000,5$

)1(

5

PV

PV

r

SPV

t

Earning $5,000 in five years is the same as earning $3,403 now.

PV can also be calculated for future losses:

Page 9: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.2 Present Value Loss Example

You and your spouse just got pregnant, and will need to pay for university in 20 years. If university will cost $30,000 in real terms in 20 years, how much should you invest now? (long term GIC’s pay 5%)

PV = S/[(1+r)t]= -$30,000/[(1.05)20]= -$11,307

Page 10: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.2 Present Value of a Stream of Gains or Loses

If an investment today yields future returns of St, where t is the year of the return, then the present value becomes:

TT

o r

S

r

S

r

SSPV

)1(...

)1()1( 221

If St is the same every year, a special ANNUITY formula can be used:

Page 11: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

PV = A[1-(1/{1+r})t] / [1- (1/{1+r})]PV = A[1-xt] / [1-x] x=1/{1+r}A = value of annual paymentr = annual interest raten = number of annual payments

Note: if specified that the first payment is delayed until the end of the first year, the formula becomes

PV = A[1-xt] / r x=1/{1+r}

A.2 Annuity Formula

Page 12: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

Consider a payment of $100 per year for 5 years, (7% interest)

PV= 100+100/1.07 + 100/1.072 + 100/1.073

+ 100/1.074

= 100 + 93.5 + 87.3 + 81.6 + 76.3 = $438.7

OrPV = A[1-(1/{1+r})t] / [1- (1/{1+r})]PV = A[1-xt] / [1-x] x=1/{1+r}PV = 100[1-(1/1.07)5]/[1-1/1.07] =

$438.72

A.2 Annuity Comparison

Page 13: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.3 Present Value Decisions When costs and benefits occur over

time, decisions must be made by calculating the present value of each decision

-If an individual or firm is considering optionX with costs and benefits Ct

x and Bt

x in year t, present value is calculated:

T

XT

XT

XXXXXXX

r

CB

r

CB

r

CBCBPV

)1(

)(...

)1(

)(

)1(

)()(

22211

00

Where r is the interest rate or opportunity cost of funds.

Page 14: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.3 PV Decisions ExampleA firm can:1)Invest $5,000 today for a $8,000

payout in year 4.2)Invest $1000 a year for four years,

with a $2,500 payout in year 2 and 4If r=4%,

112,2$

)04.1(

)000,8()000,50(

)1(

)()(

1

31

3

13

131

010

1

PV

PV

r

CBCBPV

Page 15: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.3 PV Decisions Example2) Invest $1000 a year for four years,

with a $2,500 payout in year 2 and 4If r=4%,

850$

333,1925442,1000,1

)04.1(

)000,100,5,2(

)04.1(

)000,1(

)04.1(

)000,1500,2()000,1(

)1(

)(

)1(

)(

)1(

)()(

1

1

321

3

13

13

2

12

12

11

111

010

1

PV

PV

PV

r

CB

r

CB

r

CBCBPV

Option 1 is best.

Page 16: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.4 Lifecycle ModelAlternately, often an individual

needs to decide WHEN to consume over a lifetime

To examine this, one can sue a LIFECYCLE MODEL*:

*Note: There are alternate terms for the Lifecycle Model and the curves and calculations seen in this section

Page 17: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.4 Lifecycle Budget Constraint

Assume 2 time periods (1=young and 2=old), each with income and consumption (c1, c2, i1, i2) and interest rate r for borrowing or lending between ages

If you only consumed when old,

c2=i2+(1+r)i1

If you only consumed when young:

c1=i1+i2 /(1+r)

Page 18: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

18

Lifecycle Budget Constraint

Young Consumption

Old

Con

sum

ptio

n

O i1+i2 /(1+r)

The slope of this constraint is (1+r).

Often point E is referred to as the endowment point.

i1

i2

i2+(1+r)i1

E

Page 19: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.4 Lifecycle Budget Constraint

Assuming a constant r, the lifecycle budget constraint is:

1122

12

r)c(1-r)i(1i

lope)c(-

c

sInterceptc

Note that if there is no borrowing or lending, consumption is at E where c1=i1, therefore:

22

1122

i

r)c(1-r)c(1i

c

c

Page 20: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

20

A.4 Lifetime Utility

• In the lifecycle model, an individual’s lifetime utility is a function of the consumption in each time period:

U=f(c1,c2)

• If the consumer assumptions of consumer theory hold across time (completeness, transitivity, non-satiation) , this produces well-behaved intertemporal indifference curves:

Page 21: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

21

A.4 Intertemporal Indifference Curves

• Each INDIFFERENCE CURVE plots all the goods combinations that yield the same utility; that a person is indifferent between

• These indifference curves have similar properties to typical consumer indifference curves (completeness, transitivity, negative slope, thin curves)

Page 22: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

22

U=√2

U=2

c1

c2

Consider the utility function U=(c1c2)1/2.

Each indifference curve below shows all the baskets of a given utility level. Consumers are indifferent between intertemporal baskets along the same curve.

0 1 2 4

1

2

Page 23: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

23

Marginal Rate of Intertemporal Substitution (MRIS)

• Utility is constant along the intertemporal indifference curve

• An individual is willing to SUBSTITUTE one period’s consumption for another, yet keep lifetime utility even– ie) In the above example, if someone starts with

consumption of 2 each time period, they’d be willing to give up 1 consumption in the future to gain 3 consumption now

• Obviously this is unlikely to be possible

Page 24: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

24

A.4 MRIS• The marginal rate of substitution (MRIS) is the gain

(loss) in future consumption needed to offset the loss (gain) in current consumption

• The MRS is equal to the SLOPE of the indifference curve (slope of the tangent to the indifference curve)

1

2constantutility

1

2

c

c

c

cMRIS

Page 25: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

25

A.4 MRIS Example

)()(

)(

122

121

21

1

2

12

2

21

cccccMRIS

cUc

cMRIS

cUc

ccU

Page 26: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

26

A.4 Maximizing the Lifecycle Model

• Maximize lifetime utility (which depends on c1 and c2) by choosing c1 and c2 ….

• Subject to the intertemporal budget constraint– In the simple case, people spend everything, so

the constraint is an equality• This occurs where the MRIS is equal to the slope of

the intertemporal indifference curve:

1122

21),(

r)c(1-r)i(1i ..

),(max21

cts

ccUcc

Page 27: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

27

c2

c1

•IIC2

IBL

0

C •• B

• IIC1

A

D

Point A: affordable, doesn’t maximize utilityPoint B: unaffordablePoint C: affordable (with income left over) but doesn’t maximize utilityPoint D: affordable, maximizes utility

Page 28: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

28

A.4 Maximization Example

)1(

)1(

)1(:, ,

21

12

1

212

1

221

rcc

ccr

rc

cIBCcc

c

cMRISccU

2))1((

)1(

)1()1(

122

2122

1122

iric

ciric

criric

2)1(

)1(2))1((

)1(

12

1

121

21

iri

c

riric

rcc

Page 29: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

29

A.4 Maximization Example 25%r $100,000,i ,$1,500,000 , 2121 iccU

500,837$

2)000,500,1)$05.1(000,100$(

2))1((

2

2

122

c

c

iric

619,797$2

000,500,1$)05.1(

000,100$

2)1(

1

1

12

1

c

c

iri

c

316,817

)619,797)(500,837($

)619,797)(500,837($

21

U

U

U

ccU

Page 30: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

A.4 Maximization Conclusion

Lifetime utility is maximized at 817,316 when $797,619 is consumed when young and $837,500 is consumed when old.

*Always include a conclusion

Page 31: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

31

c2

c1

0

U=817,316

12

21),(

r)c(1-r)$100,000(1000,500,1$ ..

),(max21

cts

ccUcc

12 r)c(1-r)$100,000(1000,500,1$ c

500,837$2 c619,797$1 c

Page 32: Econ 384 Intermediate Microeconomics II Instructor: Lorne Priemaza Lorne.priemaza@ualberta.ca

32

A. Conclusion

1) Streams of intertemporal costs and benefits can be compared by comparing present values

2) To examine consumption timing, one can use the LIFECYCLE MODEL:

a) An intertemporal budget line has a slope of (1+r)

b) The slope of the intertemporal indifference curve is the Marginal Rate of Intertemporal Substitution (MRIS)

c) Equating these allows us to Maximize