77
1 16.4 Competitive Market Efficien Pareto Efficient »No alternate allocation of inputs and goods makes one consumer better off without hurting another consumer If another allocation improves AT LEAST ONE CONSUMER (without making anyone else worse off), the first allocation was Pareto

16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

  • Upload
    zhen

  • View
    27

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency. Pareto Efficient No alternate allocation of inputs and goods makes one consumer better off without hurting another consumer - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

1

16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

Pareto Efficient»No alternate allocation of inputs and goods makes one consumer better off without hurting another consumer

If another allocation improves AT LEAST ONE CONSUMER (without making anyone else worse off), the first allocation was Pareto Inefficient.

Page 2: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

2

16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

Pareto Efficiency has three requirements:

1)Exchange Efficiency Goods cannot be traded to make a

consumer better off

2) Input Efficiency Inputs cannot be rearranged to

produce more goods

Page 3: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

3

16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

3) Substitution Efficiency Substituting one good for another

will not make one consumer better off without harming another consumer

Page 4: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

4

1) Exchange Efficiency Model Assumptions

• Assumptions:–2 people–2 goods, each of fixed quantity

This allows us to construct an EDGEWORTH BOX – a graph showing all the possible allocations of goods in a two-good economy, given the total available supply of each good

Page 5: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

5

1) Edgeworth Box Example

• Two people: Maka and Susan• Two goods: Food (f) & Video Games (V)• We put Maka on the origin, with the y-axis

representing food and the x axis representing video games

• If we connect a “flipped” graph of Susan’s goods, we get an EDGEWORTH BOX, where y is all the food available and x is all the video games:

Page 6: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

6

1) Maka’s Goods Graph

Video Games

Food u

O xMaka

Ou is Maka’s food, and Ox is Maka’s Video Games

Page 7: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

7

1) Edgeworth Box

Video Games

Food u

O xMaka

O’w is Susan’s food, and O’y is Susan’s Video Games

w

r y O’Susan

s

Total food in the market is Or(=O’s) and total Video Games is Os (=O’r)

Each point in the Edgeworth Box represents one possible good allocation

Page 8: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

8

1) Edgeworth and utility

• We can then add INDIFFERENCE curves to Maka’s graph (each curve indicating all combinations of goods with the same utility) – Curves farther from O have a greater utility

• We can then superimpose Susan’s utility curves– Curves farther from O’ have a greater utility

Remember that: y

xxy MU

MUMRS

F

VVF MU

MUMRS

Page 9: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

9

1) Maka’s Utility Curves

Video Games

Food

OMaka

Maka’s utility is greatest at M3

M1

M2

M3

Page 10: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

10

1) Edgeworth Box and Utility

Video Games

Food

OMaka

Susan has the highest utility at S3

r O’Susan

s

At point A, Maka has utility of M3 and Susan has Utility of S2

M1

M2

M3

S1S2

S3

A

Page 11: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

11

1) Edgeworth Box and Utility

Video Games

Food

OMaka

If consumption is at A, Maka has utility M1 while Susan has utility S3

r O’Susan

s

By moving to point B and then point C, Maka’s utility increases while Susan’s remains constant

M1M2

M3

S3A B

C

Page 12: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

12

1) Exchange Efficiency

Video Games

Food

OMaka

Point C, where the indifference curves barely touch is EXCHANGE EFFICIENT, as one person can’t be made better off without harming the other.

r O’Susan

s

M1M2

M3

S3C

Page 13: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

13

1) Pareto Improvement

• When an allocation is NOT exchange efficient, it is wasteful (at least one person could be made better off)…

• A PARETO IMPROVEMENT makes one person better off without making anyone else worth off (like the move from A to C)…

• However, there may be more than one pareto improvement:

Page 14: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

14

1) Pareto Improvements

Video Games

Food

OMaka

If we start at point A:-C is a pareto improvement that makes Maka better off-D is a pareto improvement that makes Susan better off-E is a pareto improvement that makes both better off

r O’Susan

s

M1M2

M3

S3C

S5S4

A

D

E

Page 15: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

15

1) The Contract Curve• Assuming all possible starting points, we can

find all possible exchange efficient points and join them to create a CONTRACT CURVE

• All along the contract curve, opposing indifferent curves are TANGENT to each other

• Since each individual maximizes where his indifference curve is tangent to his budget line:

F

VSusanVf

MakaVf P

PMRSMRS

Page 16: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

16

1) The Contract Curve

Video Games

Food

OMaka

r O’Susan

s

Page 17: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

17

1) Example: House and ChaseAssume that House and Chase have the following

utilities for books and coffee:CCChaseHHHouse CBUCBU ,

The Exchange Efficiency Condition therefore becomes:The Exchange Efficiency Condition therefore becomes:

CCHH

ChaseC

ChaseB

HouseC

HouseB

ChaseBC

HouseBC

BCBC

MUMU

MUMU

MRSMRS

//

Page 18: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

18

1) MATH – House and ChaseIf there are 10 books, and 4 cups of coffee, then the

contract curve is expressed as:

)10/()4(/

,HHHH

ChaseBC

HouseBC

BCBC

MRSMRS

If House has 6 books, an exchange efficient allocation If House has 6 books, an exchange efficient allocation would be:would be:

4.2

2410

)4(64

)610/()4(6/

H

H

HH

HH

C

C

CC

CC

Page 19: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

19

1) MATH – House and ChaseTherefore, House would have 6 books and 2.4 cups of coffee,

and Chase would have 4 (10-6) books and 1.6 (4-2.4) cups of coffee, for utilities of:

52.2)6.1(4

79.3)4.2(6

CCChase

HHHouse

CBU

CBU

Page 20: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

20

2) Input EfficiencyModel Assumptions

• Assumptions:–2 producers/firms–2 inputs (Labor and Capital), each of

fixed quantityThis lead to a EDGEWORTH BOX FOR

INPUTS– a graph showing all the possible allocations of fixed quantities of labor and capital between two producers

Page 21: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

21

2) Edgeworth Box For Inputs Example

• Two firms: Apple and Google• Two inputs: Labor (L) and capital (K)• We put Apple the origin, with the y-axis

representing capital and the x axis representing labor

• If we connect a “flipped” graph of Google’s inputs, we get an EDGEWORTH BOX FOR INPUTS, where y is all the capital available and x is all the labor:

Page 22: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

22

2) Apple’s Input Graph

Labor

Cap

ital

u

O xApple

Ou is Apple’s capital, and Ox is Apple’s labor.

Page 23: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

23

2) Edgeworth Box For Inputs

Labor

Cap

ital

u

O xApple

O’w is Google’s capital, and O’y is Google’s labor

w

r y O’Google

s

Total capital in the market is Or(=O’s) and total labor is Os (=O’r)

Each point in the Edgeworth Box represents one possible input allocation

Page 24: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

24

2) Edgeworth and Production

• We can then add ISOQUANT curves to APPLE’s graph (each curve indicating all combinations of inputs producing the same output) – Curves farther from O produce more

• We can then superimpose Google’s Isoquants– Curves farther from O’ produce more

Remember that the slope of the Isoquant is MRTS and:

K

LLK MP

MPMRTS

Page 25: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

25

2) Apple’s Isoquants

Labor

Cap

ital

OApple

Apple produces the mostat A3

A1

A2

A3

Page 26: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

26

2) Edgeworth Box for Inputs

Labor

Cap

ital

OApple

Google produces the most at G3

r O’Google

s

At point A, Apple makes A3 Google produces G2

A1

A2

A3

G1G2

G3

A

Page 27: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

27

2) Edgeworth Box and Utility

O

If production is at A, Apple produces A1 while Google produces G3

r O’

s

By moving to point B and then point C, Apple produces more while Google’s production remains constant

A1A2

A3

G3A B

C

Labor

Cap

ital

Apple

Google

Page 28: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

28

2) Input Efficiency

O

Point C, where the isoquant curves barely touch is INPUT EFFICIENT, as one firm can’t produce more without the other firm producing less.

r O’

s

A1A2

A3

G3C

Labor

Cap

ital

Apple

Google

Page 29: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

29

2) Pareto Improvement

• When an input allocation is NOT input efficient, it is wasteful (at least one firm COULD produce more)…

• A PARETO IMPROVEMENT allows one firm to produce more without reducing the output of the other firm(like the move from A to C)

• However, there may be more than one pareto improvement:

Page 30: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

30

2) Pareto Improvements

O

If we start at point A:-C is a pareto improvement where Apple produces more-D is a pareto improvement where Google produces more-E is a pareto improvement where both firms produce more

r O’

s

A1A2

A3

G3C

G5G4

A

D

E

Labor

Cap

ital

Apple

Google

Page 31: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

31

2) Input Contract Curve• Similar to the goods market, a contract curve

can be derived in the input market:• All along the contract curve, opposing isoquant

curves are TANGENT to each other• Since each firm maximizes where their

isoquant curve is tangent to their isocost line:

rwMRTSMRTS Google

klApplekl ,,

Page 32: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

32

2) Input Contract Curve

O

r O’

sLabor

Cap

ital

Apple

Google

Page 33: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

33

2) Example: Apple and GoogleAssume that Apple and Google have the following

production functions:3/23/13/13/2 4, klQklQ GoogleApple

The Exchange Efficiency Condition therefore becomes:The Exchange Efficiency Condition therefore becomes:

Googlekl

Applekl MRTSMRTS ,,

Page 34: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

34

The isoquant slope for Apple is:The isoquant slope for Apple is:

Apple

AppleApplekl

Applekl

Applek

ApplelApple

kl

lk

MRTS

kl

klMRTS

MPMPMRTS

231

32

,

3/23/2

3/13/1

,

,

Page 35: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

35

The isoquant slope for Google is:The isoquant slope for Google is:

AppleTotal

AppleTotal

Google

GoogleGooglekl

Googlekl

Googlek

GooglelGoogle

kl

llkk

lk

MRTS

kl

klMRTS

MPMPMRTS

)(2238

34

,

3/13/1

3/23/2

,

,

Page 36: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

36

2) MATH – Apple and GoogleIf there are 1000 workers, and 125 capital in Silicon

valley, then the contract curve is expressed as:

Apple

Apple

Apple

Apple

Googlekl

Applekl

lk

lk

MRTSMRTS

1000)125(22

,,

Page 37: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

37

2) MATH – Apple and GoogleIs the market input efficient if Apple has 200 workers and

50 capital?

16\316/82001000

)50125(2)200()50(2

1000)125(22

Apple

Apple

Apple

Apple

lk

lk

No – Apple needs fewer capital (Google needs more capital) AND/OR

Google needs fewer workers (Apple needs more workers)

Page 38: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

38

3) Substitution Efficiency• Substitution Efficiency can be analyzed using

the PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES CURVE/FRONTIER– The PPC shows all combinations of 2 goods that

can be produced using available inputs– The slope of the PPC shows how much of one

good must be SUBSTITUTED to produce more of the other good, or MARGINAL RATE OF TRANSFORMATION (x for y) (MRTxy)

Page 39: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

39

Production Possibilities CurveR

obot

s

Pizzas

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

9

10Here the MRTSpr is equal to (7-5)/(2-1)=-2, or two robots must be given up for an extra pizza.

The marginal cost of the 3rd pizza, or MCp=2 robots

The marginal cost of the 6th and 7th robots, or MCr=1 pizza

Therefore, MRTxy=MCx/MCy

Therefore, MRTpr=2/1=2

Page 40: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

40

3) Substitution Efficiency and Production• If production is possible in an economy, the

Pareto efficiency condition becomes:PersonBxy

PersonAxyxy MRSMRSMRT

Assume MRTpr=3 and MRSpr=2.-Therefore Maka could get 3 more robots by transforming 1 pizza-BUT Maka would exchange 2 robots for 1 pizzas to maintain utility-Therefore 1 pizza is sacrificed for 3 robots, increasing Maka’s utility through the 3rd robot-The Market isn’t Pareto Efficient

Page 41: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

41

The First Fundamental Theorem Of Welfare Economics

IF1) All consumers and producers act as perfect

competitors (no one has market power)and

2) A market exists for each and every commodity

ThenResource allocation is Pareto Efficient

Page 42: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

42

First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics Proof:

• From microeconomic consumer theory, we know that:

y

xPersonAxy P

PMRS

Since prices are the same for all people:Since prices are the same for all people:PersonBxy

PersonAxy MRSMRS

Therefore perfect competition leads to Therefore perfect competition leads to exchange efficiencyexchange efficiency

Page 43: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

43

First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics Proof:

• From microeconomic theory of the firm, we know that:

rwMRTS FirmAkl ,

Since each firm in an industry faces the same Since each firm in an industry faces the same wages and rents:wages and rents:

FirmBkl

FirmAkl MRTSMRTS ,,

Perfect competition leads to input efficiencyPerfect competition leads to input efficiency

Page 44: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

44

First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics Origins

• From the PPF, we know that

xyxy MRSMRT Therefore a perfectly competitive market is Therefore a perfectly competitive market is

Pareto Efficient:Pareto Efficient:

y

xPersonBxy

PersonAxy

y

xxy P

PMRSMRSMCMCMRT

Page 45: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

45

Efficiency≠Fairness• If Pareto Efficiency was the only concern, competitive markets

automatically achieve it and there would be very little need for government:–Government would exist to protect property rights

• Laws, Courts, and National Defense• But Pareto Efficiency doesn’t consider distribution. One person could get

all society’s resources while everyone else starves. This isn’t typically socially optimal.

Page 46: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

46

Fairness

Video Games

Food

OMaka

r O’Susan

s

A

C

B Points A and B are Pareto efficient, but either Susan or Maka get almost all society’s resources

Many would argue C is better for society, even though it is not Pareto efficient

Page 47: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

47

Fairness• For each utility level of one person, there is

a maximum utility of the other

• Graphing each utility against the other gives us the UTILITY POSSIBILITIES CURVE:

Page 48: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

48

Utility Possibilities Curve

Susan’s Utility

Mak

a’s

Util

ity

OMaka

All points on the curve arePareto efficient, while all points below the curve are not.Any point above the curve is unobtainable

A

C

B

Page 49: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

49

Fairness•Typical utility is a function of goods consumed:

U=f(x,y)

•Societal utility can be seen as a function of individual utilities: W=f(U1,U2)

•This is the SOCIAL WELFARE FUNCTION, and can produce SOCIAL INDIFFERENCE CURVES:

Page 50: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

50

Typical Social Indifference Curves

Susan’s Utility

Mak

a’s

Util

ity

OMaka

An indifference curve farther from the origin represents a higher level of social welfare.

Page 51: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

51

Fairness• If we superimpose social indifference curves on top of the

utilities possibilities curve, we can find the Pareto efficient point that maximizes social welfare

• This leads us to the SECOND FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF WELFARE ECONOMICS

Page 52: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

52

Maximizing Social Welfare

Susan’s Utility

Mak

a’s

Util

ity

OMaka

ii is preferred to i, even though ii is not Pareto efficienti

ii

iii

The highest possible social welfare, iii, is Pareto efficient

Page 53: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

53

Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics

The SECOND FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF WELFARE ECONOMICS states that:

Society can attain any Pareto efficient allocation of resources by: 1) making a suitable assignments of original endowments, and then

2) letting people trade

Page 54: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

54Video Games

Food

OMaka

r O’Susan

s

Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics

StartingPoint

Goal

By redistributing income, society can pick the starting point in the Edgeworth box, therefore obtaining a desired point on the Utility Possibility Frontier:

Page 55: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

55

Why Is Government so Big?

1) Government has to ensure property laws are protected. (1st Theorem)

2) Government has to redistribute income to achieve equity. (2nd Theorem)

3) Often the assumptions of the First Welfare Theorem do not hold (Econ 350)

Page 56: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

56

Why Trade and Not Tax?Taxes and penalties punish income-enhancing behavior, encouraging

people to work less.Subsidies and incentives give an incentive to stay in a negative state to

keep receiving subsidies and incentives.Lump sum transfers have the least distortion,

AND TRADE ALWAYS BENEFITS BOTH PARTIES…

Page 57: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

57

16.5 Gains From Free Trade• Trade ALWAYS makes society better off

by increasing the productivity of scarce resources

• The basis for the gains from specialization and trade is Comparative Advantage

Page 58: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

58

Theory of Comparative Advantage:• Production Possibilities :

–Carl and Mike: retired neighbours: hobbies are making wine and beer

Carl’s ProductionPossibilities

Mike’s ProductionPossibilitiesA B C

A B C

Wine (btls) 0 30 100Beer (btls.) 1,000 700 0

0 40 80 80 40 0

PPF’s for 1 month’s production:

Page 59: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

59

Carl’s Proposition

• “Lets each of us do what we do best and trade. This will give each of us more than we now have without either of us working any harder.”

• Notice that voluntary trade does not take place unless both parties benefit.

Page 60: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

60

Mike’s Production Possibilities/ Opportunity Costs

Bottles of beer

A•C

In a month Mike can produce either 80 bottles of wine or 80 bottles of beerOpp cost of 80 wine is 80 beer Opp cost of 1 wine is 1 beer Opp cost of 80 beer is 80 wine Opp cost of 1 beer is 1 wine

Bottles of wine

••BConsumption choice before trade8040

40 80

Page 61: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

61

Carl’s Production Possibilities/ Opportunity Costs

0

Bottles of beer

A•

C•

Opp cost 100 wine is 1000 beer Opp Cost 1 wine is 10 beerOpp cost of 1000 beer is 100 wine Opp Cost 1 beer is 1/10 wine

Bottles of wine

•B Consumption choice before trade700

100

30 100

Page 62: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

62

Opportunity Cost Table

Opportunity cost of 1 beer

Opportunity cost of 1 wine

Carl 1/10 wine 10 beer

Mike 1 wine 1 beer

• When producer A has a lower opportunity cost of producing good A compared to another producer, then producer A is said to have a comparative advantage in the production of good A.

Theory of Comparative Advantage:

Page 63: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

63

Comparative Advantage: Specialization• Carl has a “comparative advantage” (lowest

opportunity cost producer) in the production of beer and therefore specializes in beer production.

• Mike has a “comparative advantage” in the production of wine and therefore specializes in wine production

• As long as opportunity costs differ, there is comparative advantage

Page 64: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

64

Comparative Advantage: SpecializationComparative Advantage: Specialization

Theory of Comparative AdvantageTheory of Comparative Advantage • if specialization takes place according to comparative advantage (the lowest opportunity cost producer) and then trade takes place…. both parties can benefit: that is, move outside their current PPF’s.

Page 65: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

65

Carl & Mike Before Specialization & Trade

Carl Produces & Consumes

Mike Produces & Consumes

Total Consumption+ =

Wine (btls.)Beer (btls.)

30700

4040

70740

Carl & Mike After Specialization, but Before Trade

Mike Produces & Can

Consume+ =

Wine (btls.)Beer (btls.)

01,000

800

801,000

Carl Produces & Can

Consume

Total Production & Consumptio

n

Total Gains

+10+260

Page 66: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

66

• Carl proposes, after specialization, that he trade Mike 175 beer for 35 wine.

Carl gets wine for a reduced sacrifice–35 wine for 175 beer instead of 350 beer, the opportunity cost before trade

Mike gets beer for a reduced sacrifice–175 beer for 35 wine instead of 175 wine, the opportunity cost before trade

(terms of trade: 5 beer for 1 wine)

Trade: The Benefits of Specialization

Page 67: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

67

Terms of Trade: 1 Wine for 5 Beer• Since voluntary trade requires that both parties

benefit from the trade.• Before trade:

• Carl: 1 wine “trades” for 10 beer

• Mike: 1 wine trades for 1 beer

After trade 1 wine “trades” for 5 beer

•The Terms of Trade are between the personal ones that exist before trade, thus producing gains for both parties participating in the trade

Carl is better off as he now only has to give up 5 beer for a wine

Mike is better off as he now only has to give up 1/5 wine for a beer

Page 68: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

68

Trade Between Carl & Mike

1 Wine trades for 5 Beeror

1 Beer trades for 1/5 WineMike

(specializes in wine)

Carl (specializes

in beer)

175 Bottles of Beer To

Trades away

35 Bottles of Wine Trades awayTo

Before trade Mike gave up 1 wine to get 1 beer, after trade1/5 wineBefore trade Carl gave up 10 beer to get a wine, after trade 5 beer

Page 69: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

69

Carl & Mike After Specialization & Trade

Carl

Mike

ProducesTradesFor (+)Away (-)

ConsumesAfterTrade

Produced & ConsumedBefore Trade

GainsfromTrade

Wine (btls.) Beer (btls.)

01,000

+35-175

35825

30700

+5+125

Produces

TradesFor (+)Away (-)

ConsumesAfterTrade

Produced & ConsumedBefore Trade

GainsfromTrade

Wine (btls.)Beer (btls.)

800

-35+175

45175

4040

+5+135

Page 70: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

70

Mike’s Production Possibilities After TradeBottles of

beer

A•C

Bottles of wine

••B•D Consumption after trade

Mike produces 80 wine and then trades 35 wine for 175 beer, leaving him with 45 wine and 175 beer, point D

8040

40 80

175

45

Page 71: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

71

Carl’s Production Possibilities/ Opportunity Costs, After Trade

0

Bottles of beer

A•

C• Bottles of wine

•BD• Consumption after trade

Carl produces 1000 beer and trades 175 beerto Mike for 35 wine, leaving him with 825 beerand 35 beer, point D

700

100

30 100

825

35

Page 72: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

72

Absolute Advantage

• When a producer with of set of inputs can produce more output than another with the same inputs, the first producer has an absolute advantage in production of the output.

• Carl has an absolute advantage in the production of both wine and beer.

Page 73: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

73

Gains from Specialization and Trade

• Specialization produces gains for both traders, even when one trader enjoys an absolute advantage in both endeavors.

• Unless two people/firms/countries have IDENTICAL opportunity costs, Trade is always beneficial

Page 74: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

74

Why No Free Trade?1) Misunderstanding: people misunderstand the

facts or hold to political or ideological dogma, or confuse voluntary jobs with enforced slavery

2) Short-run effects: in the SHORT-RUN, there may be some unpopular adjustments:

a) Richer, developed countries may lose jobs to developing countries with a comparative advantage

b) Poorer, developing countries may have short-run environmental damage until the higher incomes lead to environmental protection

Page 75: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

75

Chapter 16 Conclusions1) General equilibrium requires

simultaneous equilibrium in multiple markets

2) One change can cause a cascade of changes through markets until a new equilibrium is reached

3) An equilibrium is Pareto Efficient if no other allocation of inputs can make one person better off without making another worse off.

Page 76: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

76

Chapter 16 Conclusions4) Pareto Efficiency requires exchange

efficiency (goods can’t be traded), input efficiency (more can’t be produced) and substitution efficiency (substituting production won’t improve outcome)

5) The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics states that if all perfectly competitive markets exist, allocations are Pareto Efficient

Page 77: 16.4 Competitive Market Efficiency

77

Chapter 16 Conclusions6) The Second Fundamental Theorem of

Welfare Economics states that governments can redistribute wealth to reach any pareto efficient outcome

7) Free Trade is always beneficial to all parties

8) Economic truths, when properly applied and explained, can cut through ideologies and make people cry